Digitization and profitability Vol.:(0123456789) Information Systems and e-Business Management https://doi.org/10.1007/s10257-019-00458-z 1 3 O R I G I N A L A R T I C L E Digitization and profitability Yasushi Masuda1  · Seungjin Whang2 Received: 7 May 2019 / Revised: 26 August 2019 / Accepted: 5 November 2019 © The Author(s) 2019 Abstract Consider a monopolistic vendor who faces a known demand curve. By setting a price that equates marginal revenue with marginal cost, the vendor will maximize his profit. This logic holds true of both physical and digital goods. But since digi- tization will lower the variable production cost, it will strictly increase the profit to the vendor. Then, can we conclude that digitization always improves the vendor’s profitability? Not necessarily. Now consider what will happen on the next day of the sales. Facing deterministic demand, the physical goods vendor must have pre- pared the exact quantity of the product to sell, and thus all products are sold out. By contrast, the digital goods vendor will have no stock out, thanks to the nature of the digital good. Therefore, the rational vendor will try to sell more and achieve a higher profit after the sales date. To this end, the vendor will now lower the price to attract additional customers with lower reservation prices. The process will indefinitely continue. Knowing this would happen, customers will wait for the price reduction. Even the customers who would have purchased on the first day would defer the purchase until price gets lower. The digital goods vendor will anticipate this and accordingly lower the price on the first day and later, thereby compromising his profitability. Note that this downward spiral takes place as a result of digitization. Thus, digitization may not necessarily improve the profitability to the vendor. We develop an economic model to formally analyze the impact of digitization on the profitability to the vendor. Keywords Strategic customers · Digital goods pricing · Exponentiality * Seungjin Whang fwhang@stanford.edu 1 Keio University, Yokohama, Japan 2 Stanford University, Stanford, USA http://orcid.org/0000-0001-7557-7478 http://orcid.org/0000-0003-1094-8877 http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1007/s10257-019-00458-z&domain=pdf Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 1 Introduction Thanks to the Internet, many information goods—such as books, music and mov- ies—are transformed to pure digital goods and distributed over the Internet. Digi- tization offers numerous benefits on the supply side—zero variable production cost, no stockouts, instant deliveries, zero inventory carrying cost, zero shipping cost, and no damages or losses in handling or delivery. It, therefore, achieves an ideal form of make-to-order production-distribution system with unlimited sup- ply, just-in-time delivery and zero variable cost. Most of these benefits directly or indirectly accrue to the vendor. But does digitization guarantee a higher profit? How about social welfare? This paper investigates the questions by using a simple game-theoretic model. To start with, consider a monopolistic vendor (“he”) who faces a known demand curve. By setting a price that equates marginal revenue with marginal cost, the vendor will maximize his profit. This logic holds true of both physical and digital goods. But since digitization will lower the variable production cost, it will strictly increase the profit to the vendor. Then, can we conclude that digitiza- tion always improves the vendor’s profitability? Not necessarily. Now consider what will happen on the next day of the sales. Since the demand is known, the physical goods vendor must have prepared the exact quantity of the product to sell, and thus all products are sold out. By contrast, the digital goods vendor will have still an infinite supply of the good, thanks to the nature of the digital good. Therefore, the rational vendor will try to sell more and achieve a higher profit after the sales date. To this end, the vendor will now lower the price to attract additional customers with lower reservation prices. The process will indefinitely continue. Knowing this would happen, customers will wait for the price reduc- tion. Even the customers (“she” each) who would have purchased on the first day would reconsider buying it now, and instead choose to wait. The digital goods vendor will anticipate this and accordingly lower the price on the first day and later, thereby compromising his profitability. Note that this downward spiral takes place as a result of digitization. Thus, digitization may not necessarily improve the profitability to the vendor. This casual argument requires a more formal inves- tigation, which is the objective of the present paper. We here offer a brief literature survey. There exist three fields of research related to the present work. First, special characteristics of digital goods gen- erated research with different focuses. A recent work by Goldfarb and Tucker (2019) provide an extensive literature survey on digital economics by starting with the question of “what is different” about digital economics. They emphasize the changes in costs associated with search, replication, transportation, tracking and verification. For example, Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) study the effec- tiveness of bundling a large number of information goods, in the face of diverse tastes and uncertainties. Huang and Sundararajan (2011) study optimal nonlin- ear pricing for digital goods, when the infrastructure has discontinuous cost. Tra- ditional auction mechanisms designed for physical products need modification when applied to digital goods. In this area Goldberg et  al. (2001) analyze the 1 3 Digitization and profitability auction mechanisms designed for allocating digital goods. The existing literature do not address the implications of digitization on the multi-period interactions between vendors and customers, highlight the “infinite supply” aspect of digital goods. Our work contributes to the literature by comparing profitability of physi- cal and digital goods from such an angle. Second, there exists a well-developed literature on sequential bargaining under informational asymmetry, and some are closely related to our paper. Sobel and Taka- hashi (1983) and Cramton (1984) develop a sequential bargaining model between a buyer and a seller over infinite time. The authors characterize the limiting sequential equilibrium in closed-form expressions. The key aspect of these models is the stra- tegic behavior of customers. Instead of passive or myopic customers who either take it or leave it, strategic and fully rational customers choose the timing of purchase in anticipation of a favorable price. In this regard, Besanko and Winston (1990) com- pare the performance between strategic and myopic buyers. Hörner and Samuelson (2011) extend the model to N potential buyers in a finite deadline. Board and Skr- zypacz (2016) also study revenue management with strategic customers, when new customers continuously arrive to the market. Our model is closest to McAfee (2007) who studies sequential bargaining without information asymmetry. Assuming strate- gic customers and no information asymmetry, we obtain closed-form trajectories of prices, thresholds and profits. This result is used to compare the profits of the physi- cal and digital goods. Last, the body of work on the Coase conjecture (Coase 1972) is related to our work. In 1972 Coase conjectured that lack of commitment power and sequential rationality would drive down a durable goods monopolist’s profit to zero under cer- tain conditions. The conjecture was formalized by various authors including Stokey (1981), Bulow (1982), Gul et  al. (1986), Orbach (2004), McAfee and Te  Velde (2006), and McAfee and Wiseman (2008). We show that this conjecture also serves as a distinguishing feature of digital goods, since the conjecture does not apply to physicl goods with a finite supply. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section we introduce the model. We analyze the one-period model of physical products in Sect. 3. In Sect. 4 we study the multi-period sales of digital goods and compare the two models. In particular, we encounter the Coase conjecture that arises as a limiting phenomenon for digital goods. In Sect. 5, we investigate the welfare implications of digitization. The last section offers concluding remarks including the strategy of avoiding the Coase conjecture. 2 The model The main objective of the paper is to analyze the impact of digitization on the profit- ability to the monopolist vendor. We develop a simple mathematical model to cap- ture the essence of the issue at hand. We consider a market where a monopolistic vendor attempts to sell goods to customers. The goods may be either in the physical or digital form. Below is the detailed description of the model. Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 • (Demand) We assume that the market consists of a continuum of customers with different valuations. Each customer needs at most one unit of the good. A customer with valuation v is called the ‘type-v’ customer. The (inverse) demand function is given by p = v̄ − q for some positive v̄ , where p is the price and q the quantity sold. Equivalently, the valuations of the customers are uniformly distributed in [0, v̄] at unit density. Thus, the initial market size is v̄ , but will shrink over time as more customers buy. • (Value Depreciation) A customer’s valuation depreciates in time at a fixed rate of �(∈ (0, 1)) per period. � is here called the depreciation factor. The good valued at v at time 1 becomes worth �t−1v in period t. Note that cus- tomer ‘types’ do not depreciate over time, since types are defined at the ini- tial period. A large depreciation factor close to 1 means slow depreciation. Cash is not discounted, for simplicity. • (Production Cost) The variable production cost of the physical good is c(> 0) per unit, while that of the digital good is set to zero. We assume that the fixed cost is identical in both goods. • (Selling Periods) Physical and digital goods operate in different manners. The former has only one selling period, while the latter has an infinite num- ber of selling periods denoted by t = 1, 2, …. • (Strategic Customers) Customers are strategic in the choice of time to buy. Each customer buys in the period that maximizes her (positive) net value of the good—the value earned beyond the cost. She would not buy any if the net value is negative. • (Vendor’s Pricing) The vendor of the digital goods would set the price each period to maximize the residual (gross) profit—the total profit in the present and future periods before the fixed cost is subtracted. The case of the digital goods is thus modeled as a multi-period game played by two sets of players, who take turns in making a move. We study the decisions of the players and their resulting outcome as the equilibrium of the game and derive managerial insights. 3 Physical and digital goods 3.1 Physical goods Consider a physical goods vendor who has one period to sell his product. Facing the linear demand we assumed, the vendor will prepare the quantity Qo = (v̄ − c)∕2 at unit cost of c and set the price at po = (v̄ + c)∕2 to sell the entire stock. This will generate the total profit of Πp = (po − c)Qo = (v̄ − c)2∕4 . Consumer surplus (= the sum of consumers’ net values) will be CSp = (v̄ − po)Qo∕2 = (v̄ − c)2∕8. Social welfare Sp—the sum of the vendor profit and consumer surplus—will equal 3(v̄ − c)2∕8. Note that both the vendor profit and welfare strictly decrease in c. 1 3 Digitization and profitability 3.2 Digital goods By its nature, the digital good is never sold out at the end of each selling period. Knowing this in advance, customers wait to see the price coming down. In response, the vendor adjusts the prices now and for the future. This multi-period game is modeled in the subgame-perfect equilibrium concept. Formally speaking, the equilibrium is the sequence of strategy pairs {(pt, vt)}t=1,2,… , so that taking the history of the game so far as given, in each period t, 1. each type-v customer buys a unit if and only if v ≥ vt for some vt , meaning that customers in the aggregate choose the ‘threshold’ value vt ; and 2. t he vendor selects t he pr ice pt to maximize his residual prof it �t ∶= ∑∞ i=t pi(vi−1 − vi) in expectation of the customers’ strategies. The strategy in (1) represents the threshold policy in which only high-types of customers buy the good now while the rest wait. For now, we assume it is an opti- mal policy, and later (in Theorem 3) verify this is indeed the case. The vendor’s strategy in (2) is to “cream-skim” the customers by steadily lowering the price and selling to the next interval of customers each period, where the interval is [vt, vt−1) in period t = 1, 2, … , with v0 ∶= v̄ . Thus, in equilibrium the thresholds will form a non-increasing sequence (v1, v2, …) . Now we seek to find the explicit values of {pt} , {vt} and {�t}. To find the subgame-perfect equilibrium of the game, we work backwards in each period t. That is, given arbitrary values of (v1, v2, … , vt−1) of the previous- period values, the vendor chooses vt (for t = 1, 2, … ) by solving s.t. The objective of (1) tries to maximize the residual profit by selecting the right price pt that indirectly controls vt (via the constraints). In order to properly assess the impact of his current decision, he has to look ahead and build a prediction on the future equilibrium values (pt+i, vt+i) for i = 1, 2, … . The prediction should be correct in equilibrium. This correct prediction requirement applies to the customers as well. Under the threshold policy of customers, the incentive compatibility condition states that the threshold customer will find the two options—buy or wait—indif- ferent. Equation (2) states that for the threshold customer, the option of buying now is as good as the option of buying in the next period. Here, we assume that in every period, some customers buy a good so that the incentive compatibility condition is effective. We later show that indeed there exists an equilibrium satis- fying this assumption. (1)maxvt∶vt≤vt−1 pt(vt−1 − vt) + �t+1(vt) (2)�t−1vt − pt =� t vt − pt+1, (3)�t−1vt − pt ≥0. Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 Equation (3) is the individual rationality constraints ensuring that each type of customer gets at least zero net value; otherwise, she would not buy the good. See, for example, Mas-Colell et al. (1995) for detailed discussions of mechanism design. The equilibrium of the game is captured by the three variables—the price pt , the threshold vt and the residual profit �t to the vendor. Below we present the equilib- rium in two steps—the first-period equilibrium (Theorem 1) and the trajectories of the variables over time (Theorem 3). The equilibrium is given in a surprisingly sim- ple form, even though its derivation is rather complicated. Theorem 1 In equilibrium, (P1) of the digital system has the following solution for t = 1: (i) v∗ 1 = 1− √ 1−𝛿 𝛿 v̄ (ii) p∗ 1 = √ 1−𝛿−1+𝛿 𝛿 v̄ (iii) 𝜋∗ 1 = √ 1−𝛿−1+𝛿 2𝛿 v̄2 All proofs are delegated to the “Appendix”. The Theorem completely determines the first-period threshold v∗ 1 , the opening price p∗ 1 and total profit �∗ 1 as a function of the primitive model parameters v̄ and � for the digital system.1 In particular, note that the total profit �∗ 1 decreases in the depreciation factor. We are now in a position to compare the profits of the physical and digital systems as follows (see also Fig. 1). Fig. 1 The profit from the digital good is higher than the physical good when 𝛿 < 0.93 , where v̄ = 1 and T = ∞ 1 See McAfee (2007) who derives a similar form of total profit in a slightly different setting as a fixed point. 1 3 Digitization and profitability Theorem 2 (i) The profit Πp of the physical product is given by (v̄ − c)2∕4. (ii) The profit Πd(= �∗ 1 (1)) of the digital good is given by √ 1−𝛿−1+𝛿 2𝛿 v̄2. (iii) The digital system is more profitable than the physical system if and only if 𝛿 ≤ 4cv̄2(2v̄−c) (c2−v̄2−2v̄c)2 . Profitability of digitization thus depends on the depreciation factor � and the vari- able cost c. At a higher � , customers do not feel pressured to buy early and instead choose to wait, since most of the original value is retained over time. To counter it, the vendor is forced to lower the price fast to induce them to buy early. Also, if the physical product has a high variable cost, digitization would save much for the digi- tal goods vendor. In summary, digitization will favor the vendor when the physical product has high production cost and the product depreciates fast. Note here that to the digital goods vendor, the infinite supply or the lack of scarcity is not a blessing, but a liability. As a byproduct of the proof of Theorem 1, we can derive the trajectories of equi- librium strategies and profits over time. It turns out that the ratio v∗ t ∕v∗ t−1 for the digi- tal system is constant, independent of time t, so the thresholds take the exponential form in the digital goods model. The price p∗ t and the residual profit �∗ t also follow the exponential form. Formally, we have: Theorem 3 Let R ∶= 1− √ 1−� � and K ∶= √ 1−�−1+� 2� . Then, for every t, (i) v∗ t = v̄Rt (ii) p∗ t = 2Kv̄(𝛿R)t−1 (iii) 𝜋∗ t = Kv̄2(𝛿R2)t−1 Part (i) confirms that in every period there exist customers who buy the good, so that Eq. (2) is justified as the incentive compatibility condition. This result also shows that the individual rationality condition (Eq.  3) is satisfied in each period t, since 𝛿t−1vt − pt = v̄𝛿 t−1Rt − 2Kv̄(𝛿R)t−1 = v̄(𝛿R)t−1 ⋅ 2−𝛿−2 √ 1−𝛿 𝛿 > 0 for all t. Thus, the net value to each customer exponentially shrinks to zero as t approaches infinity. See Fig. 1. 3.3 The coase conjecture We have shown that the digital goods vendor will be worse off when the good depreciates slowly. Even worse, Theorem 3 (ii) and Fig. 1 show a prominent fea- ture of the digital good—both the opening price and total profit continuously decline to zero as � approaches 1. That is, lim �→1 p ∗ 1 = 0 and lim �→1 � ∗ 1 = 0. In the limit, the digital goods vendor is trapped in the zero-revenue paradox Coase con- jectured in his 1972 paper. Coase (1972) considered a monopolistic vendor who owns an ample stock of a durable good. Further it is assumed that the vendor sells the stock to patient customers with different valuations over an infinite number Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 of periods and cannot commit to the price in advance. In this setting Coase con- jectured that a monopolist would make zero profit. In our setting the downward spiral between customers’ deferred purchases and the vendor’s price reduction drives the result in the limit. A large literature on the Coase conjecture identified and studied the conditions under which the conjecture holds true. The Coase con- ditions include: (1) the product is durable (not consumable) (Coase 1972; Bulow 1982; Orbach 2004; 2) the cost of transacting each deal is zero (Coase 1972; 3) the price can be instantly changed (Coase 1972; 4) the depreciation factor is close to 1 (Gul et  al. 1986); and (5) the vendor has no power to commit to the future prices (McAfee 2007). One implicit condition only lightly covered in the litera- ture is that the vendor has an infinite (or sufficiently large) supply. Coase (1972) seems to have used “all the land of the United States” as a proxy for an infinite supply, but did not fully utilize the property in his analysis. Our model highlights the fact that the Coase conjecture may apply to the digital good market with its infinite supply, but not to the physical product market where there is a potential shortage due to its finite supply. What is the intuition behind the Coase conjecture in the digitization context? One way of interpreting it is as follows. A digital good is infinitely available and incurs zero variable cost. For such a product, one might anticipate zero price. Indeed, the price will “ultimately” decline to zero. However, in the early transient periods, the digital good will have strictly positive prices. In this sense, the seller is selling the “freshness” of the product, charging the buyer for early access. In the absence of depreciation (with depreciation factor close to 1), however, freshness will be main- tained for a long time, so that the value of early access is close to zero. The vendor has nothing to sell. The relationship between digitization and profitability may apply to various situ- ations. The value of the newspaper depreciates very quickly. Thus, the newspaper publisher will not fall into the trap of the Coase condition. As another example, con- sider the textbooks. Since students need a textbook as soon as the course starts, the value of the book decreases quickly. While the publisher can control the number of physical copies, he cannot do the same with its digital version, so he cannot utilize the scarcity effect. However, depreciation will be fast at the beginning of the new semester, so it will avoid the Coase conjecture or any dramatic loss of profit as a side effect of digitization. Lastly, consider the case of movies. The value of movies depreciates over time— but slower than newspapers or textbooks. A new film is first shown to the audience in a movie theater, after which it is released to the video-on-demand (VOD) service, sold in a DVD and finally, broadcast free of charge. It is reported that the number of moviegoers is decreasing. When asked why they were going to the movies less often, 24 percent said they wait for VOD (Cunningham 2015). Nevertheless, movie studios do not skip any other stage of offering movies, partly due to market com- petition and availability of new technologies, and partly because customers antici- pate so. Given the belief of the customers, the movie studio provides the product in multiple stages and stepwise lowers the price. As a whole, the movie market can be depicted as a game between the studio and customers where the studio selects the 1 3 Digitization and profitability price and customers select the time of purchase. Digitization plays a critical part of the game, and digitization may not necessarily have increased the profitability for the studios. In sum, the Coase conjecture suggests a clear and present risk to digitization. The digital goods vendor should make sure to avoid the Coase conditions. We discuss it further in the final section. 4 Social welfare We turn to the welfare implications of digitization. For the physical product case, social welfare is Sp = 3(v̄ − c)2∕8, as discussed in Sect. 3. Now consider the welfare in the digital system. Social welfare Sd can be expressed as the total value generated by the purchases. In period t the group of customers belonging to [vt, vt−1) will purchase the product. The size of this group is vt−1 − vt with the average gross value �t−1(vt−1 + vt)∕2 per customer. The total welfare across all groups is thus given by where vt is given in Theorem 4.3. Then, it can be shown that Thus, we have: Theorem 4 (i) Social welfare of the physical and digital systems Sp and Sd are respectively given by Sp = 3(v̄ − c)2∕8 and Sd = v̄2(1 + 𝛿 − √ 1 − 𝛿)∕(4𝛿). (ii) Digitization always improves social welfare. Why does digitization improve social welfare? Note that there are three factors that determine social welfare—cost of production, market penetration and the tim- ing of sales. The digital system improves welfare through lower production costs. Also, digitization increases the number of customers served. The physical goods vendor deliberately limits the quantity and only sell to high types of customers to the detriment of social welfare, while the digital goods vendor will ultimately sell to all customers over the infinite horizon. However, it does not prove that the digital system is better in terms of social welfare, because welfare also depends on how fast sales happen before the product loses its value. In this respect the physical product performs better, since all sales take place in the first period. The Theorem, however, reports that the second effect strictly dominates the third, while the first separately re-enforces the benefit of the digitization. S d = ∞ ∑ t=1 � t−1(vt−1 − vt)(vt−1 + vt)∕2 = ∞ ∑ t=1 � t−1(v2 t−1 − v2 t )∕2, S d ∶= 1 + 𝛿 − √ 1 − 𝛿 4𝛿 v̄ 2 . Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 From a broader perspective on the comparison, competition exists between the digital system’s efficiency and the physical system’s scarcity . To the profit-maxi- mizing digital goods vendor, efficiency boosts his profit, but lack of scarcity hurts it. On the other hand, both efficiency and lack of scarcity contribute to social welfare. Therefore, digitization may improve or hurt the vendor profit, but it always improves social welfare. 5 Concluding remarks We have investigated if digitization would lead to higher profitability. The answer depends on the variable cost of the physical product and the depreciation factor of the product. Digitization favors the vendor when the variable cost is high and depre- ciation is fast. In the extreme case of infinite time horizon and zero depreciation, the digital goods vendor will lower the price to zero “in the twinkle of an eye,”2 and face zero profit. The digital goods vendor should take actions to mitigate the liability of digitiza- tion driven by the infinite supply, while maintaining its advantage of low variable cost. In particular, he should by all means avoid the Coase conditions. We consider three approaches to it—a finite time horizon, a small depreciation factor and a lim- ited number of copies available. The first approach is to develop a mechanism to artificially end the sales in a finite time, say, T. A finite T, preferably a small T, will benefit the vendor. It may sound counter-intuitive, since a shorter time horizon may incur loss of sales on the tail end of the time horizon. But it changes the game dynamics as it pressures cus- tomers to buy before it is too late. In fact, the finite horizon game shows a com- pletely different pattern of profitability from our infinite horizon case. The profit in the former changes in a U-shaped curve with respect to the depreciation factor � (see Fig. 2 for T = 2 ), instead of a monotone-decreasing curve in the latter (see Fig. 1 for T = ∞ ). The largest depreciation factors offer as high profits as the lowest deprecia- tion factors. The vendor can achieve the maximum profits at the highest depreciation factors when the time horizon is finite. Moreover, this case will prevent the rise of the Coase conjecture. An example of this approach is to build a reputation of “no markdown” policy. This is equivalent to choosing T = 1 . Building such a reputation requires multiple rounds of long-term efforts, sometimes risking short-term losses. It will achieve the same profit as a physical product with zero variable cost. The second approach is to choose a smaller depreciation factor. A small deprecia- tion factor (i.e., smaller � ) has a positive effect on profitability similar to a short sell- ing season (smaller T). For example, the condition � = 0 is equal to T = 1 . In both, the downward spiral will stop before reaching the zero profit level. To execute this strategy, the vendor may shorten the effective product life cycle and introduce a new version of the product at regular intervals. He may continue to offer the current ver- sion of product (i.e., keep T at infinity) even after the new product is introduced, but 2 See Coase (1972). 1 3 Digitization and profitability the value of the product will significantly erode, thereby achieving a small depre- ciation factor. This way, scheduled obsolescence would keep the depreciation factor away from 1 and block the Coase conditions. Lastly, the vendor may create “limited editions” of the digital good. By limiting the supply and creating scarcity, the vendor would overcome the main disadvantage of digital goods such as digital arts and photography. One way is to utilize Block- chain technology [see, for example, Swan (2015)]. For example, CryptoKitties, Kodak (www.kodak .com/kodak one) and Ascribe (www.ascri be.io) offer a Block- chain-based service that enables a digital goods vendor to issue a limited number of copies. They assign a unique pair of public and private keys to each copy and track its movement on the Blockchain (Deforge 2018; Zheng 2018). The model has several limitations. First, it is a simple stylistic model compro- mised for tractable analysis. We assumed a monopolistic vendor, linear demand, a simplistic market mechanism for physical products and a simple game structure with no uncertainties in the digital system. These simplifying assumptions may admit- tedly limit the power of the model’s conclusions and applicability. The Coase con- jecture, in particular, may be viewed as an artifact of theoretical exercise. However, managers may draw qualitative insights from such extreme results. Second, we have not allowed the physical product vendor to produce extra units to sell over multiple periods and apply dynamic pricing. But it will not generate a higher profit to the vendor. Figure  2 illustrates this point, when we repurpose it for a physical product with two periods of sales and c = 0 . The profit is maximal when � is 0, or equiva- lently, when T = 1 . That is, it is not optimal for the physical product vendor to sell in multiple periods, even if the vendor is allowed to. Thus, we have not lost opti- mality with this limitation. Another limitation is, the model captures only two key differentiating features—low production cost and infinite supply—of digital goods. It left out of consideration other benefits of digitization such as instant gratification Fig. 2 The profit from the digital good is higher than the physical when � is either smaller than .45 or larger than .8, where v̄ = 1 and T = 2 http://www.kodak.com/kodakone http://www.ascribe.io Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 and ease of updating and upgrades. Further, digitization is often associated with net- work externality, which has a significant implication in pricing. However, network externality is a phenomenon associated with the demand side of the good, often in the context of multi-period market competition. This is well beyond the scope of our model and require a new setup for analysis. We hope to see more work to comple- ment our deficiencies with more sophisticated models and empirical research. Funding Funding was provided by JSPS KAKENHI (Grant No. 15K01203). Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 Interna- tional License (http://creat iveco mmons .org/licen ses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. Appendix: Proofs Proof (Theorem  1) To analyze the problem, we consider a slightly more general problem as follows. • A customer is identified by type � , where � is uniformly distributed over [0, 1]. Note we are deviating from the main text where we use v as the customer type. These are equivalent, but the new index will simplify the presentation of the proof. • The reservation value of type-� customer is given by v̄𝜃 . Thus, the highest res- ervation value among all customers is given by v̄ . Note that v and � are related through v = 𝜃v̄. • The market size is given by q̄. Thus, the inverse demand function is given by p = v̄(1 − q∕q̄) . Denote by �̄�(q̄, v̄) the total profit the vender earns from period 1 onwards. Since v̄ and q̄ are mere scal- ing factors of the reservation value and the market size, the equilibrium price p∗ t in period t is independent of q̄ and is linear in v̄ . Thus, for every 𝛼 > 0, where p∗ t (v̄) is the price in period t when the highest valuation in period 1 is v̄ . Also, it is clear that the profit �̄�(q̄, v̄) is linear in both q̄ and v̄ , i.e., Note that the problem in period 2 has the market size 𝜃1q̄ and the highest valuation 𝛿𝜃1v̄ . Thus, problem �̄�(q̄, v̄) is expressed as s.t. (4)p∗t (𝛼v̄) = 𝛼p ∗ t (v̄) (5)�̄�(q̄, v̄) = q̄v̄�̄�(1, 1). (6)�̄�(q̄, v̄) = max𝜃1,p1 p1q̄(1 − 𝜃1) + �̄�(𝜃1q̄, 𝛿𝜃1v̄) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ 1 3 Digitization and profitability where p∗ 2 is the price in period 2, which is the first period price of the problem �̄�(𝜃1q̄, 𝛿𝜃1v̄) , so that [from (4)] We now evaluate �̄�(1, 1) . From the incentive compatibility condition (9) and (6) with v̄ = 1, where p∗ 1 = p∗ 1 (1) . For now, we ignore (7) and the individual rationality condition (8). Using (4) and (5) and setting q̄ = v̄ = 1 in (6), we have where �̄� = �̄�(1, 1) . Thus, Solving these three equations w.r.t. 𝜃∗ 1 , �̄� and p∗ 1 , we obtain We see that these formulas indeed satisfy (7) and (8). Thus, Theorem 1 holds true. ◻ Proof (Theorem  3) Consider �̄�(q̄, v̄) . Clearly, its solution 𝜃∗ 1 (q̄, v̄) is independent of the scaling factors q̄ and v̄ . Since the original problem in period t is given by �̄�(v∗ t−1 , 𝛿t−1v∗ t−1 ) , 𝜃∗ t (1, v̄) = 𝜃∗ 1 (v∗ t−1 , 𝛿t−1v∗ t−1 ) is independent of t. Thus, the ratio v∗ t ∕v∗ t−1 is given by �∗ 1 = �∗ 1 (1) in (11) for all t, proving Part (i). From (4), (13) and Part (i), p∗ t (v̄) = p∗ 1 (𝛿t−1v∗ t−1 ) = 𝛿t−1v∗ t−1 p∗ 1 (1) = 2Kv̄(𝛿R)t−1 , proving Part (ii). From (7)�1 ≤1, (8)𝜃1v̄ − p1 ≥0, (9)𝜃1v̄ − p1 =𝛿𝜃1v̄ − p ∗ 2 . (10)p∗2 = p ∗ 1 (𝛿𝜃1v̄) = 𝛿𝜃1p ∗ 1 (v̄). p1 = �1 − ��1 + ��1p ∗ 1 �̄� = max 𝜃1 (𝜃1 − 𝛿𝜃1 + 𝛿𝜃1p ∗ 1 )(1 − 𝜃1) + 𝛿𝜃 2 1 �̄�, 𝜃 ∗ 1 = 1 − 𝛿 + 𝛿p∗ 1 2 − 2𝛿(1 + �̄� − p∗ 1 ) �̄� =p∗ 1 (1 − 𝜃∗ 1 ) + 𝛿𝜃∗2 1 �̄� p ∗ 1 =𝜃∗ 1 − 𝛿𝜃∗ 1 + 𝛿𝜃∗ 1 p ∗ 1 . (11)�∗ 1 =(1 − √ 1 − �)∕� (12)�̄� = � √ 1 − 𝛿 − 1 + 𝛿 � ∕(2𝛿) (13)p∗ 1 =( √ 1 − � − 1 + �)∕�. Y. Masuda, S. Whang 1 3 (5), (12) and Part (i), 𝜋∗ t (v̄) = �̄�(v∗ t−1 , 𝛿t−1v∗ t−1 ) = 𝛿t−1v∗2 t−1 �̄�(1, 1) = Kv̄2(𝛿R2)t−1 , proving Part (iii). We also see that these formulas indeed satisfy the threshold policy and the individual rationality. ◻ Proof (Theorem 4 (ii)) Note first that Sd is monotone increasing in � . Also, note that which completes the proof. ◻ References Bakos Y, Brynjolfsson E (1999) Bundling information goods: pricing, profits, and efficiency. Manag Sci 45(12):1613–1630 Besanko D, Winston WL (1990) Optimal price skimming by a monopolist facing rational consumers. Manag Sci 36(5):555–567 Board S, Skrzypacz A (2016) Revenue management with forward-looking buyers. J Polit Econ 124(4):1046–1087 Bulow JI (1982) Durable-goods monopolists. J Polit Econ 90(2):314–332 Coase RH (1972) Durability and monopoly. J Law Econ 15(1):143–149 Cramton PC (1984) Bargaining with incomplete information: an infinite-horizon model with two-sided uncertainty. Rev Econ Stud 51(4):579–593 Cunningham T (2015) Most moviegoers would pay 10–20 to watch new releases at home.https ://www. thewr ap.com/most-movie goers -would -pay-10-20-to-watch -new-relea ses-at-home/. Accessed 12 Nov 2019 Deforge A (2018) Art and photography within the blockchain. https ://mediu m.com/block stree thq/digit al- art-and-photo graph y-withi n-the-block chain -bb744 c9342 60. Accessed 12 Nov 2019 Goldberg AV, Hartline JD, Wright A (2001) Competitive auctions and digital goods. In: Proceedings of the twelfth annual ACM-SIAM symposium on discrete algorithms, society for industrial and applied mathematics, pp 735–744 Goldfarb A, Tucker C (2019) Digital economics. J Econ Lit 57(1):3–43 Gul F, Sonnenschein H, Wilson R (1986) Foundations of dynamic monopoly and the coase conjecture. J Econ Theory 39(1):155–190 Hörner J, Samuelson L (2011) Managing strategic buyers. J Polit Econ 119(3):379–425 Huang KW, Sundararajan A (2011) Pricing digital goods: discontinuous costs and shared infrastructure. Inf Syst Res 22(4):721–738 Mas-Colell A, Whinston MD, Green JR (1995) Microeconomic theory. Oxford University Press, New York lim 𝛿→0 S d = lim 𝛿→0 v̄2(1 + 𝛿 − √ 1 − 𝛿) 4𝛿 = lim 𝛿→0 v̄2(1 + 𝛿 − √ 1 − 𝛿)(1 + 𝛿 + √ 1 − 𝛿) (4𝛿)(1 + 𝛿 + √ 1 − 𝛿) = lim 𝛿→0 v̄2(3 + 𝛿) 4(1 + 𝛿 + √ 1 − 𝛿) = 3v̄2∕8 ≥ 3(v̄ − c)2∕8 = Sp, https://www.thewrap.com/most-moviegoers-would-pay-10-20-to-watch-new-releases-at-home/ https://www.thewrap.com/most-moviegoers-would-pay-10-20-to-watch-new-releases-at-home/ https://medium.com/blockstreethq/digital-art-and-photography-within-the-blockchain-bb744c934260 https://medium.com/blockstreethq/digital-art-and-photography-within-the-blockchain-bb744c934260 1 3 Digitization and profitability McAfee RP (2007) Lecture on pricing. https ://vita.mcafe e.cc/Bin/Prici ng/Prici ngLec tures .pdf. Accessed 12 Nov 2019 McAfee RP, Te Velde V (2006) Dynamic pricing in the airline industry. In: Hendershott TJ (ed) Hand- book on economics and information systems. Elsevier, Amsterdam McAfee RP, Wiseman T (2008) Capacity choice counters the coase conjecture. Rev Econ Stud 75(1):317–331 Orbach BY (2004) The durapolist puzzle: monopoly power in durable-goods markets. Yale J Reg 21:67 Sobel J, Takahashi I (1983) A multistage model of bargaining. Rev Econ Stud 50(3):411–426 Stokey NL (1981) Rational expectations and durable goods pricing. Bell J Econ 12(1):112–128 Swan M (2015) Blockchain: blueprint for a new economy. O’Reilly Media, Inc., Newton Zheng C (2018) Can blockchain impact the future of art collection? https ://cultu retra ck.com/ideas /can- block chain -impac t-the-futur e-of-art-colle ction /. Accessed 12 Nov 2019 Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. https://vita.mcafee.cc/Bin/Pricing/PricingLectures.pdf https://culturetrack.com/ideas/can-blockchain-impact-the-future-of-art-collection/ https://culturetrack.com/ideas/can-blockchain-impact-the-future-of-art-collection/ Digitization and profitability Abstract 1 Introduction 2 The model 3 Physical and digital goods 3.1 Physical goods 3.2 Digital goods 3.3 The coase conjecture 4 Social welfare 5 Concluding remarks References