> -o PR RTY Oº % A/i/iº 1 & 1 *-i- A R T E S S C I E N T i a V as 1 TA9 | THE FOREIGN POLICY RESEARCH INSTITUTE SERIES The Foreign Policy Research Institute University of Pennsylvania Number 6 THE FOREIGN POLICY RESEARCH INSTITUTE UNIVERSITY OF PEN NSYLVANIA THE RECONSTRUCTION OF |RAQ: 1950 - 1957 by Fahim I. Qubain with a foreword by RoberT strausz-Hupé FREDER ICK A. PRAE GER . Publisher NEW YORK . N. Y. HC, £ BOOKS THAT MATTER Q.5 First published in the United States of America in 1958 by Frederick A. Praeger, Inc., Publishers 15 West 47th Street, New York 36, N. Y. C 1958 in the United States of America by The Foreign Policy Research Institute All rights reserved Library of Congress catalog card number 58-10098 Printed in the United States of America This is the sixth in a series of studies to be published by Frederick A. Praeger, Publishers, under the auspices of the Foreign Policy Research Institute at the University of Penn- sylvania, established under a grant of the Richardson Founda- tion, Greensboro, North Carolina. This study was subjected to the extensive and critical discussion of the Associates of the Foreign Policy Research Institute. However, the views expressed in THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ are the author’s own. . . . . . .” º -, - ? ºr 22 - A ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The publication of this study was made possible by a grant from the Foreign Policy Research Institute of the University of Pennsylvania. This grant permitted me to revise and bring up to date a manuscript which had its origins in a Ph.D. dissertation written at the University of Wisconsin under the direction of Professor Llewellyn Pfankuchen of the De- partment of Political Science. - The Staff Conference of the Associates of the Foreign Policy Research Institute reviewed the manuscript and offered many helpful comments on my work. The Institute arranged for the editing of the entire manuscript and its preparation for publication by Mr. William Sands, Editor of the Middle East journal. Many people helped me during both my research and writing. I especially want to express my heartfelt gratitude to my friend and teacher Professor Pfankuchen, who never failed to give me his support and counsel. He supervised my early research and criticized the original manuscript. Thanks are also due to Professors James McCamy, Richard Hart- shorne and Theodore Morgan, all of the University of Wis- consin, for their helpful advice and encouragement. The financial aid of the Social Science Research Council enabled me to do field work in Iraq and neighboring countries. Special thanks are due to Professor Robert Strausz-Hupé and Mr. Erasmus H. Kloman, Jr., both of the Foreign Policy Research Institute. They offered many valuable criticisms and suggestions concerning content and manner of presenta- tion. Needless to say, I am alone responsible for all statements— whether of fact or opinion—made in this book. FAHIM I. QUBAIN Washington, D.C. March 31, 1958 FOREW ORD In July, 1958 the pro-Western government of Iraq was abruptly and violently overthrown by a military coup. The revolution in Iraq raised grave questions for American foreign- policy makers. Since Iraq was the one Arab state which ad- hered to the Baghdad Pact concluded in 1955, the tremors of the upheaval in Iraq were bound to affect fundamentally the West’s strategic position in the Middle East. But even more importantly, the fall of the Hashemite Kingdom raised a question of vital concern to the entire range of America’s foreign economic policies. No country of the Middle East had progressed farther along the path of economic progress than had Iraq under the direc- tion of King Faisal and Nuri as-Sa'id. The program of the Iraqi Development Board represented a well-considered and systematic utilization of 70 per cent of Iraq’s oil resources for the development of the national economy. But economic development did not assure political stability. The obvious question raised by events in Iraq is whether efforts to promote economic growth have any significant effect on political align- ments and ideological orientation. Regardless of the political complexion of the future regimes, Iraq’s basic problems of development will remain the same. In all probability the Development Board or a device similar to it will continue to be the principal instrument for promot- ing economic growth. This study by Dr. Fahim Qubain pro- vides an objective and detached view of the basic problems involved in the transformation of a rural and static society in- to an urban and dynamic one. Dr. Qubain's study, although enlivened by a deep awareness of the social and economic changes which are taking place throughout the Middle East, avoids political controversy. It focuses on the underlying economic problems which must be understood before judg- ment can be passed on Iraq’s politics and role in regional affairs. Among the Ottoman Empire’s outlying Arab possessions, the vilayets of Mosul, Baghdad and Basrah, comprising most of ancient Mesopotamia, were among the most neglected and the poorest. The ministrations of the Sultan’s govern- ment were largely confined to the collection of taxes. The population was sparse and, especially in the river valleys, ridden by endemic diseases. From these three provinces was formed, upon the breakup of the Ottoman Empire in 1918, the state of Iraq. Its first king, Amir Faisal, was crowned in 1921. Yet, only in 1932, when Great Britain relinquished her League of Nations mandate, did Iraq acquire full sovereignty. Thus, independent Iraq has existed for less than three de- cades. The achievements of Iraq in the field of economic and social development must be measured by the burden of neglect, inherited from Turkish rule, and the short span of national experience. Unlike most of the states carved from the territory of the Ottoman Empire, Iraq had to start virtually from scratch in laying the foundations of a modern state. Ever since the beginning of the nineteenth century, Syria, Lebanon and Egypt had been open to Western influences. In these Arab- speaking countries of the Levant, long before they won national independence, Western education and trade had fostered the growth of a middle class composed of Western- trained physicians, engineers, teachers, public servants and businessmen. The newly created state of Iraq, situated at the eastern periphery of the Middle East and isolated by distance and desert from the lively, prosperous Levant, could boast of but a small cadre of Western-trained army officers and a handful of graduates from Ottoman Western academic institutions. That Iraq has been able, amidst the trouble of the turbulent Arab world and great power conflicts con- verging upon the Middle East, to assemble a corps of civil servants and technical experts capable of administering so complex and so sophisticated an undertaking as the program of the Iraq Development Board bespeaks the tenacity and inborn intelligence of the Iraqi people. Although foreign administrative and technical advisers assisted in the task of modernization—and where in the Middle East have they been absent?—native talent now operates Iraq’s departments of government, including the economic services. Iraq has put its own resources to work in developing an ix “infrastructure”—the basic public services—as well as agricultural productivity and light industries. The Iraqi performance compares favorably with that of other Afro- Asian nations who are now launched on various programs of accelerated economic development. True enough, relatively few among the latter enjoy the economic potential of Iraq. Not every “underdeveloped” country can rival Iraq’s econom- ic endowment and hence hope to equal Iraq’s economic progress. The unequal distribution of natural resources among countries is one, although not the only, reason that invalidates a global, albeit superficial, approach to the problem of in- ternational economic development. A country that can call freely upon all the capital it can use for social, agricultural and industrial investment enjoys an obvious advantage over those nations which cannot wring sizeable savings from their subsistence economies. Iraq has benefited from a steadily and rapidly growing international demand for oil. In a sense, oil revenues provided the artificial stimulant of an economy which, but for this fortuitous boon, could not hope to break the vicious circle of oppressive penury and a rapidly increasing population. But the problems facing Iraq in the present stage of its development are by no means devoid of meaning for other underdeveloped countries. In the first place, Iraq is far from the richest of the oil-producing countries of the Middle East. Many of the presently “underdeveloped’ countries in Africa and Asia are discovering resources which, once their rational exploitation has been undertaken, will find ready markets. Secondly, Iraq’s central problem is one which, to a greater or lesser degree, confronts all backward economies—the inadequate supply of technically trained personnel capable of meeting the demands of an expanding economy. Despite the remarkable increase of native talent, Iraq has not been able to dispense with the assistance of foreign technicians and advisers. The very rate of Iraq’s economic progress and the increase of trained personnel are racing one another. Iraq, just as many other countries, appears to have labored under the illusion that plenty of capital, a pile of imported industrial equipment and a battalion of foreign experts and X technicians somehow add up to national economic develop- ment. These factors, necessary and desirable as they are, cannot work lasting results within a society that is indifferent or hostile to the exacting disciplines of Western technology. This lesson Iraq had to learn the hard way. There has been waste; there have been failures. Current planning places more emphasis, than in the past, upon the development of human resources as the first and indispensable step towards the exploitation of the country’s natural wealth. The successes and failures of the Iraq government in joining native skills to the nation’s physical assets provide significant lessons to other nations. Iraq’s unusually favorable position is based on a combina- tion of several factors: a low density of population; an abun- dant supply of water; large tracts of fallow land that can be brought under cultivation by irrigation; a vast potential supply of hydroelectric energy; and, most importantly, the revenue from proven and producing oil deposits sufficient to meet all of Iraq’s capital requirements for the foreseeable future. The low population density suggests, in fact, that Iraq might be able to relieve the serious overcrowding in other Middle Eastern areas. Although the prospects for large-scale immigration to Iraq are barred at present by international political controversies, Iraq could furnish a safety valve of Middle Eastern population pressure. The unity of Arab- Islamic culture and the evident trend towards union among the Arab states will no doubt operate to diminish the obstacles which mass migration encounters in less homogeneous areas. The plans of the Development Board are comprehensive and ambitious; they must be both, for the forces of social change are all-pervasive—and the Middle East is not one of those few remaining tranquil regions where comparative remoteness insulates domestic affairs from world politics. The Iraqi model of economic progress is being scrutinized by all the peoples of the Middle East, and not all critics are friendly. The men of the Development Board are in a hurry, for not only must they prove the worth of their scheme to their own people, but they also know that the eyes of all Arabs are upon them. It is all the more to their credit that, notwithstanding xii tracting firms have submitted their bids on a competitive basis. Sometimes, this competition has been rugged, and the Board as well as the Iraqi people have been the principal beneficiaries of this wholesome international rivalry. The economic development of each country is a unique experience, and its lessons are not easily transferable to another one. There is no model of economic growth; there are some preconceived notions about what economic growth, its cause and rate, might be, provided all other things were equal—which they never are. Thus the Iraqi experience should not be compared without stringent qualifications with that of, let us say, Egypt or Syria or Iran. Yet the Iraqi record will be scanned closely by many peoples in the throes of transition from a static to a dynamic economy and, espe- cially, by the peoples of the Middle East. Not so long ago, Mesopotamia could look to little else but the sunken ruins of the past and their enigmatic message of futility. Today’s Mesopotamia, Iraq, is a new country. Its people are swept along in a universal tide: the “revolution of rising expectations.” Not all the new in Iraq has been built well; not all the expectations aroused by the popular slogans of progress can be fulfilled. This is not surprising; even in the richest and most advanced countries, the benefits of progress are contested by the pains of dislocation; and performance hardly ever lives up to expectation. ROBERT STRAUSz-HUPá Philadelphia July, 1958 CONTENTS Foreword vii Introduction xvii Part 1 The Background 1: The Population Structure of Iraq 1 2: The Background of Development 17 3: The Development Board 30 Part 2 The Development of Agriculture 4: Control over the Water Resources 54 5: The Problem of Land Tenure and Agrarian Reform 80 6: Agricultural Techniques, Facilities, and Services 105 7: Beneficiaries of Reform—Landlord or Peasant? 120 Part 3 The Development of Industry 8: The Oil Industry 129 9: Industrialization, Communications, and Electrification 162 Part 4 The Development of Human Resources 10: The Challenge of Education 205 11: Public Health 226 12: Community Development and Welfare 241 Part 5 13: Conclusions 254 Appendixes 263 Index 265 LIST OF MAPS AND CHARTS The Development Board 33 Flood Control and Irrigation 36 Wadi Tharthar Project 66 State Land Reclamation and Distribution Program 97 Oil Fields, Refineries, and Pipelines 134 Suggested Chemical Industry for Iraq 179 General Population Census Appendix I Population of Chief Cities Appendix II GLOSSARY OF TERMS FALLAH FALLAHEEN IRAQI FILs IRAQI DINAR (ID.) IRAQI DUNUM LIWA MESHARA MUTASSARIF NAHIYA QADA SHAIKH VILAYET OR WILAYET A peasant, a farmer. The word can also refer to the whole class of peasants or farmers. Plural of fallah. 1,000 fils equal one dinar (see below). A currency unit equal to one pound sterling or $2.80. A land unit measurement equal to 0.62 acres. A province. division. An administrative An Iraqi dunum (see above). A governor of a liva, or province. A sub-district, a county. An ad- ministrative division. A district. An administrative divi- sion. The head of a tribe. Can also mean a Muslim religious leader, or a teacher of the Quran. A political and/or administrative division. The Reconstruction of Iraq: I950-1957 INTRODUCTION Today a silent social and economic revolution is taking place in Iraq. Its inspirational roots go back to a glorious past when, during the Abbassid Caliphate (754 A. D.-1258 A. D.), the country is said to have supported a population of some twenty million people. During this era, Baghdad became the cultural center of the civilized world. The arts, philosophy, science, and medicine, as well as commerce and navigation, flourished and prospered. An intricate irrigation system was constructed, and Iraq was the granary of a great empire. The canal system being developed today follows, to an amaz- ing degree, the ruins of its ancient counterpart. In 1258, following a period of political decline, Iraq was invaded by Mongol hordes who reduced its splendor into dust. The canal system was virtually destroyed; the desert gradually encroached on the farmland; security was absent; the population decreased rapidly and nomadism spread. This era is regarded as the darkest period in Iraq’s history. Only in recent years has the country begun to recover from the ravages wrought by the Mongol invasions. In 1534 the Ottoman Turks under Sulaiman the Magnifi- cent invaded Iraq. With the exception of a brief period (1621-38), the country remained an insignificant Ottoman province until World War I. Generally speaking, Ottoman rule was characterized by weakness and corruption. Governors were virtually independent from the central authorities; tribal chieftains ravaged the countryside, warred against each other, and were a constant menace to the cities. In the nineteenth century some measures of reform were effected. The country was reorganized into three administra- tive provinces. The bureaucracy and the financial arrange- ments were improved. During the governorship of Midhat Pasha (1869-72), an enlightened reformer, land tenure reform was initiated, a more effective police system introduced, and an attempt at town-planning and at enforcement of modern laws was made. In addition, a few secular schools were established, and the tribes were brought under much closer discipline. The genesis of the modern irrigation system dates xix - back to the last years of Turkish rule, just before the outbreak of World War I, when Sir W. Willcocks made his famous report on the control and utilization of the waters of the Tigris-Euphrates river system. When the war broke out, the Arabs, under the leadership of Sherif Husayn of Mecca, joined the Allies with the under- standing that their independence would be recognized. For various reasons not within the scope of this book, their ex- pectations did not materialize. At the San Remo Conference on April 25, 1920, Iraq was awarded to Britain as a mandated territory. The announcement of the mandate was immediately followed by a general uprising which lasted from July to October (1920). Some 133,000 troops, including huge re- inforcements from India, were employed to suppress the rebellion. The losses in human life, money and property were staggering. When the end came, the toll had risen to some 10,000 casualties. The number of Iraqis killed has never been accurately ascertained, but is estimated at about 4,000 in addition to those injured. Over 400 British lost their lives in addition to over 1,880 wounded or missing. The cost to the British treasury was over forty million pounds. The damage to property was immense. The rebellion demonstrated to the British the need for some concessions to national sentiment. In October (1920), Sir Percy Cox, an able statesman, arrived in Baghdad as British High Commissioner. He immediately organized a provisional Arab government with limited powers, composed of ten leading Iraqi personalities. On August 23, 1921, Amir Faisal, son of Sherif Husayn, was proclaimed king. An Anglo-Iraqi treaty was signed on October 10, 1922, and the drafting of a constitution completed in the fall of 1923. Both were approved by the Constituent Assembly which was convoked for the first time in March, 1924. The treaty, and not the constitution, was in fact the basic instrument. It established the foundation and framework of the new state, as well as defining its relations with Britain and the League of Nations. Iraq was nominally recognized as a sovereign state, yet the conditions imposed left it in a mandate .xx status. This anomalous position became popularly known in Iraq as al-Wad’ al-shadh (the abnormal position). On June 30, 1930, a new Anglo-Iraqi treaty was signed which recog- nized the full independence of Iraq but, at the same time, protected British interests. The treaty remained in force until 1955, when all special ties with Britain were terminated. On October 3, 1932, upon the recommendation of the British government, Iraq was admitted as a full-fledged member of the League of Nations. Iraq is a constitutional monarchy with a king, a Parliament composed of two chambers, a cabinet theoretically responsible to Parliament, and an independent judiciary. The govern- ment, however, is highly centralized and is characterized by the subordination of Parliament—and sometimes even the judiciary—to executive power. The cabinet, modeled after the British system, functions in actual practice after the French. This is due to the absence of an organized party system and the lack of party solidarity. The exploitation of the oil wealth of Iraq has a long political history. Rivalry between British and German interests began in the opening years of the twentieth century. In 1914 the two parties joined forces when the Foreign Office Agreement was signed. The Agreement stipulated that the Anglo-Persian Oil Company receive a 50 per cent interest in the newly created Turkish Petroleum Company (T. P. C.), and that Deutsche Bank and Anglo-Saxon Company (a subsidiary of Royal Dutch Shell) receive 25 per cent each. Following the agreement, T.P.C., supported by the British and German governments, pressed the Turkish government for a con- cession. On June 28, 1914, the Grand Vizier agreed to lease the company the oil rights in the provinces of Mosul and Baghdad. Further negotiations were suspended by the out- break of the war. After the war, following several years of negotiations among British, French, and American interests on both the business and diplomatic levels, T.P.C. (renamed in 1931 Iraq Petrol- eum Company) was reconstituted by the famous Red Line Agreement of 1928 providing for the present division of ownership. In the meantime, T.P.C. received its first con- xxi cession from the Iraqi Government on March 14, 1925. Oil was struck in commercial quantities at Baba Gurgur near Kirkuk on June 27, 1927. Oil is Iraq’s Third River. The Tigris and Euphrates, properly harnessed, supply life-giving water to the vast but hitherto idle lands of the country. Oil, in addition to its in- dustrial potentialities, supplies the funds to finance the development of its natural and human resources. Oil revenue began to assume some significance in the late twenties. After 1950 a new fifty-fifty profit-sharing agreement was signed, and a Development Board was established to utilize the vastly increased revenue. What the Iraqis have done and are doing with these great resources will be the subject matter of this book. PART I The Background CHAPTER l THE POPULATION STRUCTURE OF IRAQ In 1934, the population of Iraq was estimated to be around 3.8 million persons. In 1947, when the first census in the history of the country was taken, it was found to be 4,816,185. In 1955, it was put at about 5,113,000." Iraq is not a nation in the Western sense of the term. It is rather a conglomeration of ethnic, religious, linguistic, and ecological groups. Primary loyalties in many cases still belong to immediate social units rather than to the nation-state. Strong forces are at work, however, gradually welding the various groups into a whole and effectuating a transference of primary loyalty to the state. In the first place, the culture, traditions and socio-economic institutions of the country have an Arab-Muslim base. This, in itself, is a strong unifying force which has proved its effectiveness in times of external danger. Others which appeared recently are: nationalism, the spread of education, secularization and a rational view of the universe; patriotic indoctrination of the young in the educational system; vast expansion in the social and economic activity of the state; urbanization; and, finally, increased population mobility. 2 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ The Muslim Arabs Over four million or about 93 per cent of the population of Iraq are Muslims divided into two main sects: Shi’a and Sunni. - Since the 1947 census ignored sectarian divisions among the Muslim population, no accurate statistical data exist as to the number of the Shi'a. They do constitute the largest single community in the country, and it is generally believed that they form between 50 and 60 per cent of the total population, concentrated mostly in the central and southern part of the country. With the exception of a small number of Kurds, Lurs, Shabaks, and some Iranians, the Shi’a are Arabs. Despite their numerical majority, the Shi'a have tradition- ally played the role of a minority group in the country. This is because, despised as heretics, they have suffered almost continuous persecution at the hands of Sunni rulers from the Abbassid Caliphate (est. 750 A.D.) to the end of the Ottoman Empire after World War I. The exact number of the Sunni Arabs is not known. It is, however, believed that with the Kurds, the majority of whom are also Sunni, they are numerically almost equal to the Shi’a. The Sunni Arabs are not as geographically concentrated as the Shi'a. They engage in a wide variety of occupations including a majority in agriculture. In economic status, they range over the whole spectrum from the wealthiest to the poorest. However, they are heavily represented in govern- ment, and most of the members of the economic, political, and intellectual élite are drawn from among them. They play an influential role in the country. The Kurds and Other Muslims Second in numbers after the Arab Muslims are the Kurds. They are Sunni by religion and speak several Kurdish dia- lects, although they are gradually adopting the Arabic language. The latest considered estimate, that of Hourani in 1947, placed their number at about 800,000 persons, or about 16 per cent of the total population of Iraq. THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 3 In the 1920’s, there was a fairly strong movement for the formation of a Kurdish state, including also the Kurds of Iran and Turkey. The state did not materialize, and, after the failure of their movement, the Kurds began to play an important role in the life of Iraq. This is in part because they share the Sunni faith with the Arab political majority and in part because their leading families identified them- selves with Arab-Iraqi nationalism. Several Kurds have occupied cabinet and other high posts in the government and particularly in the army. The Kurds are concentrated in the mountain border regions of the North and Northeast. The Sulaimaniya prov- ince is almost exclusively Kurdish, and the provinces of Mosul, Arbil, Kirkuk, and Diyala contain large majorities. In many respects they still maintain a tribal form of social organization and are characterized by extreme clannishness. In addition to the Kurds, there are some 75,000 Turkomans who are Sunni by religion; about 60,000 Lurs who are Shi’a; and about 12,000 Shabak who practice another variant of the Shi'a faith. All these groups, however, are being gradually Arabicized. The Tezidis The Yezidi minority, according to the 1947 census, number- ed 32,434 persons. It is one of the two most interesting mi- norities in Iraq, the other being the Mandaean community. Inbreeding will probably result in extinction of the Yezidis before long. The religious beliefs of the Yezidis are held in strict secrecy. They have been erroneously called devil worshipers. Basically, their religion is dualistic and recognizes two forces in the universe: good and evil. These two are in perpetual struggle, but Shaitan (Satan) is most powerful on earth and therefore must be appeased. To escape his attention, the Yezidis avoid the use of words beginning with the sound sh. During the Ottoman regime they were regarded as a heretical Muslim sect. As such they were not allowed, like the Christians and the Jews, the status of millet (sect) and were consequently deprived of all the attendant legal bene- 4 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ fits. They were subjected instead to constant persecution and periodic raids from their Turkish rulers and Kurdish neighbors. This struggle for survival has made them the most tightly- knit and most regimented community in Iraq. Their social organization is both semi-political and religious. This brings them occasionally into conflict with the central authorities. In addition, some of their religious beliefs inhibit the educa- tion of children, which makes the task of government difficult. The Yezidis speak a Kurdish dialect but many of them speak Arabic also. Almost all of them live in the province of Mosul. Because of their religious beliefs and their social isolation, they stand apart from the main stream of Iraqi life. They fall into the lowest economic brackets in the country. The Mandaeans The Mandaeans are another picturesque religious minority. In 1947 they constituted an urban community of 6,597 per- sons scattered in various towns south of Baghdad. Their main town is Suq al-Shuyukh in the southern province of Muntafiq. Assimilation may soon lead to the extinction of the Man- daeans, whose number is rapidly diminishing even now. Mandaean women are highly in demand by other groups as wives, since they are renowned for their beauty. The Mandaeans do not object to marrying off their women to outsiders. Their religion appears to be of gnostic origin. They are sometimes called the “Followers of St. John” or the “Christians of St. John,” and they themselves claim descent from the ancient Sabaeans. Two outward manifestations of their religion are pacifism and baptism. The latter is observed not only once, as in the Christian faith, but after the commission of any sin. They are reputed for their honesty, gentleness, and industry. The Jews In 1947, according to the census, the Jewish community numbered some 118,000 persons. Estimates, however, ran THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 5 as high as 150,000. In 1950-51 the bulk of the Jewish com- munity left the country for Israel, India, Europe, and the United States. It is estimated that some 10,000 are still left in Iraq. Before their exodus, the Jews were an urban community holding a very important position in the economic life of the country. They were prominent in business and banking and had almost exclusive monopoly of the money-changing trade. T he Christians. In 1947 there were some 150,000 Christians of all de- nominations. Half live in Mosul—the traditional Christian center in Iraq. The other half are scattered throughout the country, but particularly in urban centers such as Baghdad, Basrah, Kirkuk, and Ramadi. As in all Arab countries, the Christians in Iraq were the first to avail themselves of the advantages, such as education, offered by the West and to adopt Western techniques and attitudes. At the same time, however, they generally identified themselves with the Arab nationalists and took over the outlook and aspirations of the Sunni political majority. On the whole, they live in harmony with their fellow nationals and cannot be distinguished from the rest of the populat- ion. An exception are the Nestorians, who claim descent from the ancient Assyrians. Until recent years they have been in constant conflict with both the government and the majority. Although no reliable data are available, it is believed that they number around 25,000 in Iraq. There are two main sources of conflict. The Nestorians claim to be a nation and in the twenties attempted to es- tablish a state in the north of Iraq along the Turkish border. Their patriarch, who now resides in the United States, still claims political as well as religious authority over them. This fact, along with the tendency of many constantly to petition foreign governments and international bodies for redress of real or imaginary wrongs, has created considerable resent- ment against them among other Iraqis. THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 7 Geographic Distribution of the Population The total population in 1947 was 4,816,185 persons, divided into 2,257,345 males or 46.6 per cent, and 2,558,840 females or 53.4 per cent. There is reason to believe that there was considerable under-reporting of both males and females— the former to escape military conscription and the latter because of Islamic tradition. The country is divided into fourteen administrative prov- inces with an average density for the whole country (ex- cluding desert areas) of twenty-one persons per square kilometer. The provinces of Baghdad and Dulaim have the highest and lowest densities with sixty-seven and five persons per square kilometer respectively. The urban population comprises about 34 per cent of the population. In fact, this figure is not a precise one, for urban population is defined by the census as all persons living within municipalities. TABLE 1. PoPULATION of IRAQ: 1947 Density Per Cent Per Urban Square Popula- Liwa Total Male Female JNomads Km. tion. Baghdad 817,205 408,404 408,801 64 67 Mosul 595,190 288,199 306,991 70,000 20 35 Diwaniya 378,118 159,875 218,243 25 21 Muntafiq 371,867 148,034 223,833 30,000 25 15 Basrah 368,799 183,723 185,076 30 40 Amara 307,021 138,207 168,814 17 20 Kirkuk 286,005 129,365 156,640 14 33 Karbala 274,264 132,116 142,148 125,000 45 42 Diyala 272,413 133,749 138,664 17 19 Hilla 261,206 124,897 136,309 48 28 Arbil 239,776 108,488 131,288 13 21 Sulaimaniya 226,400 101,767 124,633 24 24 Kut 224,938 103,987 120,951 14 22 Dulaim 192,983 96,534 96,449 25,000 5 20 4,816,185° 2,257,345 2,558,840 250,000 21 34 *In 1957 a new census was completed. The preliminary results, which have just been published, are incorporated as Appendixes I and II at the end of the book. (Table continued on following page) 8 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Cities Total Male Female Greater Baghdad 523,870 270,685 253,185 Greater Basrah 101,535 53,762 47,773 Mosul 133,625 67,392 66,233 Kirkuk 68,308 36,852 31,456 Najaf 56,261 25,683 30,578 Amara 48,110 23,719 24,391 Kazimain 48,676 24,390 24,286 Karbala 44,150 20,964 23, 186 Source: 1947 Census, I, 3. Percentage figures tabulated. Close to 550,000 live in the city of Baghdad and its suburbs, 300,000 in the three cities of Basrah, Mosul, and Kirkuk, and about 350,000 in towns with a population of 15,000 and over. This brings the total urban population to about 1.25 million, or about 25 per cent of the total population. About half a million people live in a hundred or so towns of less than 15,000 population. These are usually the ad- ministrative and market centers of minor political subdivisions. Most of them are no more than large villages. They con- stitute a semi-rural category intermediate between the village and the town. The population can then be divided as follows: 250,000 or 5 per cent are nomadic (it is believed that the number is larger); 1,250,000 or 25 per cent are urban; 500,000 or 10 per cent are semi-rural; and 3 million or 60 per cent are rural. The city of Baghdad accounts for 11 per cent of the total population and for 44 per cent of the urban population. Age-Sex Distribution Iraq is a very young nation. 34.5 per cent of the total population—excluding nomads—was, in 1947, between the ages of one and nine; and 16 per cent fifty years and over. In other words, the economically productive population ranging between the ages of ten and forty-nine constituted, in 1947, 51.5 per cent of the total population (see Table 2). This is a picture fairly representative of underdeveloped countries, where both fertility and mortality rates are very high. THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 9 TABLE 2 PopULATION of IRAQ. BY AGE AND SEx: 1947 (Nomads Excluded) Percentage Age Male Female Total Male Female Total Under 5 409,039 430,101 839,140 9.0 9.4 18.4 5-9 337,433 399,231 736,664 7.4 8.7 16.1 10-19 317,967 415,448 733,415 7.0 9.1 16.1 20-29 201,224 285,468 486,692 4.4 6.3 10.7 30–39 250,650 301,695 552,345 5.5 6.6 12.1 40-49 252,224 232,262 484,486 5.5 5.1 10.6 50-59 148,176 144,576 292,752 3.2 3.2 6.4 60 & Over 209,561 228,980 438,541 4.6 5.0 9.6 2,126,274 2,437,761 4,564,035 46.6 53.4 100.0 Source: 1955 Statistical Abstract, p. 16. Data based on 1947 census. Percentage figures tabulated by the writer from the data. Marital Status In 1947, 56 per cent of those aged ten and over (2,958,231) among the settled population were married. An additional ten per cent were widowed, divorced, or separated. Of those married, 92.3 per cent had one wife, 7 per cent had two wives, and a little over one-half per cent, three wives or more (see Table 3). The figures indicate that marriage and the family are an established institution in Iraq. They also show that polygamy has to all practical purposes ceased to be an acceptable social institution among the Muslims. The factors operating to limit polygamy are the gradual conversion from subsistence to money economy with concomitant economic pressures on the poorer classes; education and westernization, especially among the upper strata of society; and, finally, the appearance of new prestige values. Death and Birth Rates According to government sources in 1950, the crude birth rate in Iraq is twenty-seven per thousand; the crude death rate, twelve per thousand, and the infant mortality rate ninety-seven per thousand babies born.” Estimates of medical authorities and other writers, how- ever, indicate that the above figures are way off the mark. 10 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ TABLE 3 , MARITAL STATUS: 1947 (Nomads Excluded) Male Female Total Single 542,502 494,511 1,02- old Divorced, separated, or widowed” 37,137 253,673 299.310 v. Married: ise.: One wife or married 738,515 860,846 * - Two wives 56,283 * -, Three wives 5,304 92- Four wives 1,131 1,1: Total Married 801,233 860,846 l, --,- Source: 1955 Statistical Abstract, p. 18. Data based on 1947 census. *This category is composed mostly of “widowed.” There were 34,271 widpwed men and 243,197 widowed women. Adams, writing in 1956, estimated the crude birth ral about fifty per thousand, the crude death rate at thirty thousand, and the infant mortality rate for the whole coul at 300-350 per thousand with regional variations going tº high as 500 per 1,000 babies born in malarial areas.” - Prima facie evidence indicates that mortality is on ti decline, and that the rate of decline will accelerate quickr, over the next few years. The effects of the new public healti. program are not as yet recorded, but drastic measures are, being taken to eradicate malaria and other endemic diseases. Sanitation, pure water, and medical facilities are being in- creasingly introduced to towns as well as to rural areas. Education is being provided to a much larger segment of the population, and real income is rising. On the other hand, evidence also indicates that the birth rate is extremely high, and the traditional beliefs of the population favor high fertility. It has been stated that govern- ment activity will soon reduce mortality considerably. No such measures can be imposed to limit fertility. Social mores and traditions have a way of hanging on for years and cannot be changed by legislation. The conclusion is obvious: the THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 11 rate of net natural increase will steadily climb higher for some years to come. Fortunately for Iraq, no Malthusian docin need be predicted. The country at present is under- populated. It has large resources which, if properly developed, as jº.now being done, can support a much larger population at a higher standard of living. However, the high rate of gro. 7th does place a considerable burden on the state in n iding adequate social services such as educational and ...th facilities. 138.9ec. º Migration *Irecent years there has been very heavy migration from gºu god reas to urban centers. The main recipients have been Baghdad and Basrah, where literally thousands of immigrants save created sarifa camps and barely exist in makeshift reed and mud huts under the most unhygienic conditions. As can be expected, most of these rural immigrants are ºng adults or adolescents, mostly male. An index of the **bf the movement to the city is that the 1947 census *wed a high proportion of the very young (under ten) and **ery old (over fifty) living in rural areas, as well as a iáºil proportion of females. The flight to the city has not subsided since 1947, but has, 2d the contrary, increased. Recently, the director of the *icultural machinery administration stated that “recent official agricultural statistics show that less than 15 per cent of the manpower on the farm remain to work in the field, while 85 per cent migrated to the main cities.”4 The “pull factor” in this migration follows the same pattern as that of other areas where the process of urbanization and industrialization takes place: the expectation of better wages and advancement, the lure of city pleasures, com- parative freedom from traditional ties and from the tyranny of the family are the usual incentives. The “push factor” is the depressed condition of the fallah in rural areas. This latter is probably the predominant factor. The heavy migration to urban centers has in recent years created rather serious problems in the cities. In the first place, the immigrants have aggravated the housing shortage; 12 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ secondly, the makeshift hut camps which they build create slums which become breeding places for disease and epi- demics; finally, being willing to accept low wages, they compete with city labor and tend to depress wage rates. Literacy Of the five million people in Iraq only 369,864 persons, or 8 per cent, could read and write in 1947. Of these, 312,319 persons, or 79 per cent, were men and 85,545 persons, or 21 per cent, were women. The literate males were 14 per cent of the total male population, while the literate women con- stituted 3 per cent of all females. The provinces of Baghdad and Muntafiq had the highest and the lowest percentages, respectively, of literates in the country with 18 and 3 per cent. Baghdad Province had 34.5 per cent of all literate men and 48 per cent of all literate women. Literacy in 1947 was still a city luxury. The prov- inces of Baghdad, Basrah, Mosul, and Kirkuk, with large urban centers, accounted for about 50 per cent of the total literate male population and 76 per cent of literate women.5 Distribution of the Labor Force Statistics on occupational distribution in Iraq hardly exist. Data gathered by the 1947 census can serve only as a general guide since they contain wide margins of error. Ac- cording to the census, there were in 1947, 1.3 million people economically active in the following occupations: Percentages of Employed Agriculture 56 Service; government and private 12 Commerce 10 Manufacture 7 Workers (not specified) 9 Miscellaneous 1 Apprentices (under ten) 1 100 THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 13 The above percentage figures for agriculture (fifty-six) and industry (seven) do not coincide with other data. It would seem, from what is generally known, that a much higher percentage of the labor force is engaged in agriculture. This contention is supported by the Agricultural Census of 1952-53 which gave the number of those actually employed on farms as 1,400,152 persons." Similarly, the percentage allotted to industry seems high for 1947, although it may not be far off the mark today after ten years of further industrializa- tion. The Industrial Census of 1954 gave the number of those employed in industry (of all categories) as 90,291 persons.” In any case, there is no dispute as to the order of importance. The majority of the labor force is engaged in agriculture, followed in descending order by government and private services, commerce, and industry. JNational and Per Capita Income In 1949 the Statistical Office of the United Nations es- timated the national and per capita incomes of Iraq at 424 million dollars and eighty-five dollars a year respectively.* Two years later, the International Bank Mission to Iraq attempted to make a rough estimate, but the reports were so conflicting and important data either so unreliable or un- available that the attempt was abandoned. It did, however, reach the conclusion that the estimate of the Statistical Office was roughly correct.” In fact, the above estimate is at best an informed guess. Since 1951 two developments have taken place: a sharp increase in oil revenues, coupled with a consistent policy of plowing back the major part of these revenues into the development of the idle resources of the country. Oil revenue rose from 5.35 million dinars in 1950 to 73.74 million ($206.5 million) in 1955, an increase of over fourteen times. If we assume that the oil revenue today averages about 200 million dollars a year (it is actually more) and if we also assume that, as a result of capital investment in flood control, land, agriculture, industry, roads, health, etc., the national 14 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ income from all sources other than oil rose to 500 million dollars a year, then, roughly speaking, the total national income of Iraq in 1957 was about 700 million dollars. If we divide by five million, the number of the population, then the annual per capita income would now be around 140 dollars. It should be noted that the per capita income figures are national averages which, in fact, do not reflect enough such income frequencies to make them representative. They are only broad estimates that can only show general orders of magnitude. In a certain sense they are almost meaningless, for it is only too well known that, with the exception of a small middle income group, there is a large majority whose income falls much below the national average and a small wealthy minority whose income is much above. Disposition of Family Income There is hardly any information on this subject. It is reasonable to assume that a fairly large part of the income of wealthy families goes to luxury items. On the other end of the scale, among laborers and fallaheen, most, if not all, of the income goes to the maintenance of a minimum level of existence. In January and February, 1954, a sample survey of house- holds with monthly incomes of twenty dinars or less was conducted in Baghdad to determine the expenditure habits of various economic groups. The households were selected so as to provide a representative cross-section. Two hundred ninety-one households covering 2,025 persons were selected in the built-up area. The mean family size among this group was found to be 6.96 persons. Fifty-nine more households covering 335 persons in a sarifa camp were also selected. The mean family size of this group was 5.68 persons. The results of the survey were as follows: THE POPULATION STRUCTURE 15 Built-Up Area Sarifa Camp Item Dinar Per Cent Dinar Per Cent Food Cereals 4.674 23.65 4.042 33.17 Meat 2.092 10.59 1.252 10.28 Fats 1.307 6.61 .463 3.80 Vegetables .887 4.49 .536 4.40 Fruits .291 1.47 .000 0.00 Sugar .664 3.36 .836 6.86 Tea .523 2.65 .549 4.51 Eggs .252 1.28 .051 - 0.42 Other .557 2.82 .257 2.11 Total Foods 11.247 56.92 7.986 65.55 Clothing 1.408 7.13 .935 7.67 Fuel & Light Electricity ..198 1.00 .000 0.00 Other Fuels 1.236 6.26 1.240 10.18 Total Fuel & Light 1.434 7.26 1.240 10.18 Cleaning Material .686 3.48 .358 2.94 Furniture & Utensils .309 1.56 .137 1.12 Rent 1.786 9.03 .000 0.00 Misc. (cigarettes, movies, cafes, buses, etc.) 2.889 14.62 1.528 12.54 Grand Total 19.759 100.00 12.184 100.00 Source: Statistical Abstract for 1955, pp. 132-33. The survey shows that in the case of both the dwellers in the built-up area and the sarifa camp, over 80 per cent of the family income goes to the absolute necessities of life: food, clothing, rent, and fuel. It is also to be noted that the sarifa dwellers do not use electricity and do not pay rent. This is because the sarifas are huts made up of reeds and mud which the occupants, mostly immigrant laborers from rural areas, built themselves. Under the food category, cereals (mainly wheat and rice), meat, and fats receive the major share of expenditures. Vegetables are consumed in small quantities, and fruits only 16 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ in the built-up area. Expenditures on sugar and tea are particularly high among the sarifa dwellers. Very sweet hot tea is the national drink of Iraq. Cigarettes are evidently regarded as a necessity. They account for 5.43 per cent of expenditures in the built-up area and for 6.72 per cent in the sarifa camp. Coffee houses are still the chief entertainment and account for 3.23 and 2.27 per cent respectively. Movies have become popular in the built-up area (1.17 per cent), but sarifa dwellers probably cannot afford them (0.38 per cent). To be noted also is the comparatively high percentage spent on fuel, and the very small percentage spent on house furniture—an index of the low level of existence of these people. 1. Iraq Government, Ministry of Economics, Statistical Abstract, 1955 (Baghdad: 1956), p. 8. Henceforth referred to as Statistical Abstract followed by year. A second census was completed in 1957. See preliminary results in Appendix I at end of book. 2. Iraq Government, Directorate General of Health, Annual Bulletin of Health and Vital Statistics for 1950 (Baghhad: 1952), pp. 1-4. 3. Doris Adams, “Current Population Trends in Iraq,” The Middle East Journal, Vol. 10 (Spring, 1956, pp. 159, 161.) 4. Iraq Times, May 2, 1956. 5. Data based on 1947 census. 6. Iraq Government, Ministry of Economics, Report on the Agricultural and Live- stock Census of Iraq, 1952-53 (Baghdad: 1954), Vol. I, p. 18). Henceforth re- ferred to as the Agricultural Census. 7. Iraq, Ministry of Economics, Report on the Industrial Census of Iraq, 1954 (Bagh- dad: 1956), p. 9. Henceforth referred to as the Industrial Census. 8. U. N. Dept. of Economic Affairs, Statistical Office, National and Per Capita Income of Seventy Countries (New York: 1951), pp. 14, 22. 9. International Bank for Reconstruction & Development, The Economic De- velopment of Iraq (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1952), pp. 131-32 Henceforth referred to as IBRD. CHAPTER 2 THE BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT Conditions in 1920-21 Iraq has a comparatively vast natural wealth in land, water, and minerals, in addition to its human resources. When the state came into being, however, conditions in the country were, in the words of an early Iraqi Health Director, “like those described in the Book of Genesis.” The native provisional government took over from the British in the midst of widespread unrest and tension; the government administrative machinery itself had to be organiz- ed; the form of government had to be decided upon; out of the heterogeneous religious, linguistic, racial, and tribal blocs a nation had to be created; the traditional schism be- tween government and people so characteristic of Middle East society, with its resultant fears and suspicions, had to be overcome. There were no statistical data and no surveys! upon which to establish criteria. Health and Education. Over 98 per cent of the population were illiterate. In 1920, the country had eighty-four primary schools, all for boys, with 363 teachers and 6,743 students. There were also three trade schools, one secondary school, and one small law college.” 18 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Medical facilities were equally lacking. During the same year, there were one or two hospitals worthy of the name, although twenty-eight so-called hospitals were listed, as well as fifty-one dispensaries and a few specialist institutions. There were twenty-five Iraqi doctors and forty British medical officers.” Agriculture. Of the country’s vast land wealth, less than 5 per cent was under cultivation. Control and utilization of the water resources were to all practical purposes non-existent. The country was subject to disastrous floods in the spring and to severe droughts in the summer. There was always the danger of frequent drastic shifts in the courses of the twin rivers and their tributaries. Age-old methods of production were used in agriculture and yields were very low. Few landholders were certain of their claims to the land. In addition to floods, a variety of insects, including locusts, and diseases plagued the main industry of the country. Livestock production was primarily an occupation of the nomads. Industry, Trade, and Transport. Aside from handicrafts and some cottage industry, there was no other industry worth mentioning. Factories were virtually unknown. Commerce and trade were the main occupations of the people after agriculture. The communications system was still in an embryonic stage. In 1920 there were some 3,500 miles of dirt roads, the majority of which were impassable in the winter.4. Before 1914, there had been no mechanized vehicles.5 Postal and telegraph services were in the process of organization.6 The total length of the railroad system was 1,139 miles, consisting of “a number of unconnected sections built, for the most part, of secondhand rails. . . and the rolling stock was a heterogeneous collection of such secondhand or worse vehicles as could be spared from the Indian Railways.” The port of Basrah, which was brought by the military into fairly good working condition during the war, was able to handle 428 ships in 1920-21.8 An inefficient installation pumped crude river water into BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT 19 Baghdad, but no other town in the country had either electric- ity or piped water.” Experiments in Progress It is against the above background that the progress of Iraq must be considered. There was an early awareness of the potentialities of the resources of the country and the need to develop them. The three decades between 1920 and 1950 witnessed faltering attempts by the government to translate the dreams of a better future for Iraq and its people into reality. For illustrative purposes, some of the laws regarding de- velopment which were enacted year after year and sum- maries of their contents, are cited below. The general prin- ciple followed throughout this period, was to have one bud- get, an “ordinary budget,” to take care of current expenses of government, and another, an “extraordinary budget,” the accounts of which would be exclusively devoted to “productive capital works.” The sources of income for the extraordinary budget were to come from oil royalties, profits of the Iraqi Currency Board, sales of government land and loans. The difference between the two budgets, however, remained more theoretical than real. Some of the laws enacted are as follows: 1. Law No. 79 (1931). This law provided for the expenditure of 2,210,000 dinars” from oil revenue to be spent on “capital works” from 1931-35 inclusive. 2. Law JNo. 39. (1934). This revoked the above law. Instead, it allotted 3,237,000 dinars to be spent from 1934-38 inclusive. The revenue was to be provided from the government reserve account. 3. Ordinance JNo. 26 (1935) and Law JNo. 26 (1936). These created the Three-Year Plan. They provided for the ex- penditure of 761,180 dinars from 1935-37 inclusive. The money was to be provided from the excess funds of the ordi- nary budget. 4. Ordinance No. 28 (1935) and Law JNo. 33 (1936). These revoked Law No. 39 (1934). Instead, they allotted *For value of the dinar see Glossary of terms for Arabic words used in the text. 20 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 4,120,000 dinars to be spent during 1936-40. The program was to be financed from oil revenues. 5. Law JNo. 45 (1938). This law revoked Law No. 33 (1936). It provided, however, for the expenditure of 8,230,000 dinars between 1938-42 inclusive. The program was to be financed from oil revenue, profits of the Currency Board, revenue from repatriated loans to municipalities, the railways, the Port Authority, and from sales of state land. 6. Law No. 37 (1939). This replaced the above law. It allotted 11,135,000 dinars to be spent on capital works during 1939–42. The sources of income were to be oil royalties, revenue from the Currency Board, the I.P.C. loan to the Government, sale of state land, and from repatriated loans to municipalities and the railways. Each of these laws had a schedule attached, specifying how and on what the funds were to be spent. The contem- plated projects covered the whole spectrum of social and economic life: the construction of government buildings, schools, hospitals, clinics, special schools for mothers, mu- seums, cultural and athletic clubs, low-cost housing, resort hostels, and a refinery. They also included the building of roads, bridges, dams, reservoirs, canals, grain stores and silos, quarantine stations, wireless, telephone and telegraph lines, as well as the establishment of an agricultural-industrial bank, land settlement schemes, loans and grants to local industries, loans to farmers in times of crop failure and, finally, price support for agricultural products. In actual fact, however, “capital productive works” within the extraordinary budget consisted mainly of irrigation and flood control projects, such as the Kut Barrage on the Tigris, construction of roads, bridges and other means of communications and public buildings, including schools and hospitals. These works excluded development projects of the Basrah Port Authority, the Fao Dredging Scheme, the Railways Administration, the Tobacco Monopoly, and similar other public undertakings. Each of these has been a semi-autonomous organization, has its own budget separate from the government budget, and carries out its own develop- ment programs. They also excluded other development BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT 21 undertakings carried out by the various government minis- tries and credited to the ordinary budget. Therefore, ex- penditures under the “extraordinary” budget do not in actual fact reflect the full attempt of the government to develop the resources of the country. Table 4 below gives a statistical summary of expenditures on “capital works” from 1933 to 1950, and their percentile relationship to total government expenditures. It will be noted that during the thirties expenditures were constantly rising in absolute terms. In relative terms they rose from 18 per cent of the budget in 1935 to an all-time high of 30 per cent in 1936. During the war years and in the immediate post-war era, they dropped considerably. The drop was much more severe than indicated in the table because the the real purchasing power of the dinar had dropped to about half its prewar level. Expenditures on capital works did not TABLE 4 ExPENDITUREs on CAPITAL Works IN MILLIONS of IRAQI DINARs AND ExPENDITUREs As PER CENT of Total GovernmENT ExPENDITURES Million Tear Dinars Per Cent 1933 .43 10.3 1934 .42 9.8 1935 1.03 18.2 1936 2.18 30.5 1937 2.37 27.6 1938 2.46 27.2 1939 2.23 24.6 1940 2.71 27.5 1941 .96 11.0 1942 .98 8.4 1943 1.65 10.7 1944 0.00 00.0 1945 1.54 7.2 1946 3.05 11.9 1947 3.57 13.4 1948 3.93 12.3 1949 3.38 11.3 1950 3.60 12.3 Source: Statistical Abstracts for 1947; 1950, p. 292; 1952, p. 258. U. N. Dept. of Economic Affairs, Public Finance Information Papers: Iraq, N. Y., 1951, pp. 34- 35; Muzaffar H. Jamil, Trade Policy of Iraq, Cairo, 1949, p. 216 (in Arabic). 22 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ recover their prewar magnitude until 1951 when, with a new arrangement for the sharing of oil profits, Iraq entered a new era of development programs. Problems of Development Between 1920 and 1950 the country registered appreciable progress, especially in its physical plant. On the whole, however, development was painfully slow, and the major part of the natural resources of the country remained idle. There were many reasons for this. Some of them were peculiar to Iraq, and others characteristic of most, if not all, under- developed countries. 1. Political Problems. A consistent policy of develop- ment requires a measure of public tranquility and national cohesion, both of which were absent. The period was one of turmoil during which the attention of both the public and the government was focused on political problems. Internally, the central government was almost continually preoccupied with maintaining and consolidating its own position and in dealing with secessionist movements and dissident groups. For example, it had to deal with the Kurdish problem, the Assyrian problem, the Yezidi problem and, finally, the volatile Bedouin tribes, who regarded all organ- ized government as a nuisance and were ever ready to flout its authority at the least sign of weakness. They were particu- larly inclined to do so since the central authorities put a stop to their ancient sport of raiding, both of defenseless villages and among themselves. Externally, there was always the ever-present question of relations with Britain and the Palestine question. Then came World War II, and soon after that the Arab-Israeli conflict. 2. Frequency of Cabinets. In theory, the Iraqi cabinet system is modeled after the British. In practice, it functions after the French system. Since 1921 there have been more than fifty cabinets, an average of one cabinet for each seven to eight months. This has affected the progress of the country considerably, since a continuing policy of development was not possible. BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT 23 There is no responsible party system in Iraq. As in several Arab countries, there are, instead, political groupings which revolve around personal leadership. As a result, generally speaking, each cabinet that came into power either materially changed or discarded the program of its predecessor and instituted its own, which in turn was discarded or changed by the succeeding cabinet. This situation continued until the establishment of the Development Board, which is by law fairly insulated against political pressures and unaffected by cabinet changes. 3. Administration. Another factor which affected devel- opment was the absence of a career civil service corps trained in the efficient administration of government and the execu- tion of policy. For centuries the Turks had ruled the country with the aid of a few Arab officials. When they left, there were only a few Iraqis adequately trained to replace them. This problem is not peculiar to Iraq, but applies to many other underdeveloped countries which have become independent in recent years. The organization and operation of the civil service in Iraq was until recent years subject to patronage. The system generally attracted the incompetent and discouraged the able and resourceful. Many civil servants regarded govern- ment employment as a “business” and lacked the sense of devotion to duty so necessary for an efficient administration. As late as 1955, Lord Salter, in his report to the Development Board, was moved to state: The chief limiting factor to the success of development in Iraq may prove to be neither the amount of money for invest- ment, nor even the limits of skilled labor and materials available, but the efficiency of the administrative machine.” The corruption and inefficiency in the government ma- chinery were officially recognized through a speech from the Throne to Parliament on December 1, 1955. The King stated in part: The Government is aware of the weak machinery of govern- ment due to the presence of inefficient individuals and persons 24 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ of ill-repute in the government service. It has therefore resolved to reform this machinery, making it reliable and effective, so that it can care for the interests of the country and fulfill its duty in the best possible manner. The Government, therefore, is seeking enactment of legislation which will guarantee the public interest and a full measure of justice. ... ** In recent years the reform of the civil service has been the subject of several reports, the last of which was made in July, 1954 by Mr. William Brownrigg, an American public administration specialist. He recommended the establishment of a central personnel administration incorporating both the merit system and career service principles, the adjustment of and increase in salaries, and training in administrative methods. In June of the same year a committee was set up to draft a new Unified Civil Service Law. Upon the recommendations of the committee which incorporated Mr. Brownrigg’s suggestions, a new Civil Service Law was passed in May, 1956, providing for a considerable increase in salaries.” 4. Conservatism. The cabinets which have been in power so far are generally composed of members who belong to the “old generation.” They have a paternalistic concept of government, tend to be quite conservative and wary of bold programs of development or radical economic re- forms. With the exception of King Faisal I (1921–33), no dynamic personality has so far appeared in Iraq able to capture the public imagination and galvanize the energies of the nation behind him. In addition, big landowners are the strongest social and political group. With but few exceptions they are reactionary in both orientation and outlook. They have resisted, and for the most part successfully so, any program of economic re- form that might threaten their privileged position. Their effective opposition has been a serious limiting factor in the progress of the country, for, in the words of Lord Salter, the government’s guiding principle in this respect has generally been not “what is most desirable” but rather “what is politically feasible.” BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT 25 5. Shortage of Skilled Labor and Technicians. The num- ber of skilled workers even today is very small, and the number of those who could be imported was also restricted by a variety of considerations. Moreover, the educational system instituted in the twenties followed the European tradition of emphasizing “classical” subjects at the cost of technical education. Consequently, today there is an oversupply of university and college men trained in the humanities and social sciences, as compared with the meager number of those trained in the natural sciences. 6. Shortage of State Revenues. Until 1951, the revenue of the state could not finance integrated large-scale development programs. Income from oil royalties was very small. Alternatively, it was not possible for the state to use taxation as a means of financing development. As in all underdeveloped countries, indirect taxes are the largest source of regular revenue. A graduated income tax was introduced in 1939 and amend- ed in 1943, but it excluded agricultural income. The law established rates ranging from 6 per cent to a high of 15 per cent on income over 1,200 dinars; in addition there was a surtax ranging from 5 per cent (after exempting the first 1,500 dinars which are actually already taxed) to a high of 45 per cent on income over 9,500 dinars a year. The major burden of the tax fell on the urban class, of whom a large number are employes of government and private establishments. In any case, revenue from this source has been comparatively small (Table 5 below). Since 1952 there has been a decline in the number of individuals subject to the tax because exemption limits were raised to 350 dinars for single persons and to 450 dinars for married persons, plus 30 dinars for each child. In the agricultural sector, the fallaheen are too poor to be heavily taxed and it has not been politically possible to im- pose a tax on large landowners commensurate with their income. Consequently, revenue from taxes on agriculture has generally been very small (Table 6 below), especially 26 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ when the fact that agriculture is the main source of national income is taken into consideration. TABLE 5 INCOME TAx IN MILLIONS OF IRAQI DINARs Individuals Companies Tear JNumber Tax & Surtax Number Tax & Surtax Total 1948/49 33,361 2.0 165 .8 2.8 1949/50 30,405 1.6 463 .7 2.3 1950/51 28,123 1.3 163 .6 1.9 1951/52 27,307 1.3 154 .6 1.9 1952/53 26,282 1.4 134 1.0 2.4 1953/54 24,319 1.2 195 1.0 2.2 1954/55 25,914 1.2 729 1.0 2.2 1955/56 23,735 2.5* 332 1.1 * 3.6 Source: Statistical Abstracts for 1950, p. 284; 1952, p. 255; 1954, p. 124; 1955, p. 127; 1956, p. 203. Figures have been rounded. *No surtax in 1956 figures. State revenue from agriculture comes from two main taxes: (a) the istihlaq (consumption tax) which is collected when the produce is sold. At present the rate is 10 per cent of the value on such main products as cereals, dates, etc. In 1953 the tax was abolished on local consumption of several commodities such as meat, fats, vegetables, fruits, hides, wool, cotton, etc., but was raised to 20 per cent on the same products when exported. Probably the object is to encourage local consumption of such commodities and to combat inflation. (b) The Land Tax. This was originally conceived as a rental for the use of state land. The rate varies between 2.5 per cent and 10 per cent of the value of the produce. In operation the tax discriminates against those who regularly lease land from the state (usually small land- holders) and favors holders of lazma grants, usually big landlords (see Chapter V). Many of the latter, on the basis of tenuous claims, escaped the tax completely. Revenue from the land tax is meager, especially so since a large part of the land under cultivation is state land. BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT 27 TABLE 6 STATE REvenue FROM TAxes on AGRICULTURE IN MILLIONS OF IRAQI DINARs Tear Tax 1946/47 4.4 1947/48 3.6 1948/49 3.9 1949/50 4.0 1950/51 5.0 1951/52 4.7 1952/53 3.9 1953/54 3.6 1954/55 3.4 1955/56 2.7 Source: Statistical Abstracts for 1950, p. 291; 1952, p. 261; and 1955, p. 321; 1956, p. 241. Revenue is composed mostly of tax on produce, land tax, tax on livestock products, etc. Figures have been rounded. 7. Lack of Private Capital. Most, if not all, of the above- mentioned factors relate to state action. The past three decades, however, have also been characterized by lack of progress on the private level. No significant industrial development or basic change in the method of agricultural production took place until the late forties. One of the obvious reasons is lack of capital. The Middle East economy has for many centuries been a hand-to-mouth one, with little or no savings for capital investment. In addi- tion, the savings that were made were traditionally either hoarded in the form of jewelry (mostly gold and silver) or invested in real estate or trade where, it was believed, the capital would be safe and the returns high. In the agricultural sector, those who had the means, the big landlords, lacked the initiative to improve their lands. With few exceptions, they were generally content to live in urban centers on the substantial income from their holdings. 8. Religion and Tradition. Religion (whether Islam or Christianity) in the Middle East is an all-embracing force which for many centuries has not only satisfied the spiritual yearnings of its adherents but also regulated their everyday 28 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ conduct and social life. Even today, it still remains the major medium of personal identification. Institutional religion (both Christian and Muslim) in the Middle East has been, on the whole, detrimental to economic progress. It glorified as an ideal a life of contem- plation and repose, de-emphasized the importance of time (“hurry is the devil’s work” is a common proverb in the Middle East), and placed a very heavy emphasis on respect for tradition and authority. In such a tradition-bound society, initiative, innovation, enterprise, experimentation, and new creative ideas—all cornerstones of progress—are usually not only suspect, but reviled as dangerous to the public good and to time-honored institutions. In addition, the emergence and development of modern banking and credit, insurance and the stock exchange, all necessary vehicles of economic expansion, were handicapped by the theories of Islam on “risk” and its ban on interest. It is only in recent years that these institutions have begun to make headway in Iraq. On the whole, the three decades were a period during which the foundations were laid for future development. The end of World War II heralded a new era. 1. The attitude of the local population towards statistics in earlier years, which still finds an echo today, is illustrated by a letter of the Qadi (judge) of Mosul. In reply to an inquiry from an English traveler as to the size of Mosul, the number of its inhabitants, commerce, history, etc., he wrote: “My Illustrious Friend, and Joy of My Liver! The thing you ask of me is both difficult and useless. Although I have passed all my days in this place, I have neither counted the houses nor have I inquired into the number of the inhabitants; and as to what one person loads on his mules and the other stows away in the bottom of his ship, that is no business of mine. But, above all, as to the previous history of this city, God only knows the amount of dirt and confusion that the inhabitants may have eaten before the coming of the sword of Islam. It were unprofitable for us to inquire into it.” Austen H. Layard, Discoveries among the Ruins of JNineveh and Babylon (New York: G. P. Putnam & Co., 1853, p. 663.) 2. Great Britain, Colonial Office, Special Report . . . to the Council of The League of Nations on the Progress of Iraq. During the Period 1920-31 (London: H. M. S. O., 1931), p. 224. Henceforth cited as Special Report, 1931. 3. Ibid., pp. 65-67. 4. Ibid., pp. 137-39, passim. 5. Ibid., p. 137. 6. Ibid., p. 142. BACKGROUND OF DEVELOPMENT 29 7. Ibid., p. 157. 8. Ibid., p. 171. 9. Ibid., p. 141. 0. Lord Salter, The Development of Iraq: A Plan of Action. A Report submitted to the Iraq Development Board (London: The Caxton Press, 1955), p. 96. 11. Iraqi Embassy, Washington, D.C., Bulletin, January 1956, p. 3. Henceforth referred to as Bulletin. 12. Iraq Times, May 28, 1956. 1 CHAPTER 3 THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD With the end of World War II, and particularly after 1951, Iraq entered an era of accelerated economic and social development which has had no parallel in the history of the country since the golden age of the Abbassid Caliphate some twelve centuries ago. The primary factor which has brought about this change is the vast increase in oil revenues. Prior to 1951, the amount of oil revenue was comparatively small, though it averaged about 13 per cent of the total income of the state between 1934 and 1950. From 1951 on, however, it began to increase very rapidly, until by 1955 it accounted for over 30 and perhaps up to 40 per cent of the total national income (see Table 7). These funds, almost all in foreign exchange, made it possible for the state to initiate programs of development without the necessity of going through an austerity period or one of heavy taxation, either of which would probably have created considerable political unrest. Another principal factor is that of a social awakening. Existing economic and social conditions are no longer ac- ceptable to the masses. This is even more true of the urban middle class and the intelligentsia. This discontent resulted, in the years after the war, in almost universal social unrest and in widespread radical and extremist movements in the THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 31 cities. Most observers of a few years ago, if not all, believed that Iraq was on the brink of a revolutionary upheaval which would fundamentally change its political and social order. As one writer recently put it, “The parallel with Czarist Russia is uncomfortably obvious.” In short, the issue re- solved itself into a race between reform and revolution. TABLE 7 ToTAL Government REVENUE, Government OIL REVENUE, AND OIL REvenue As PER CENT OF ToTAL GovernmENT REVENUE IN MILLIONS OF IRAQI DINARs 1927-1955 Total Oil Tear Govt. Revenue Revenue Per Cent 1927-33 .64a 1934 5.02 1.02 20.3% 1935 5.36 .59 11.0 1936 6.03 .60 9.9 1937 6.94 .73 10.5 1938 7.84 1.98 25.2 1939 9.21 2.02 21.9 1940 9.72 1.58 16.2 1941 10.16 1.46 14.3 1942 13.83 1.56 11.4 1943 18.10 1.88 10.4 1944 18.89 2.22 11.4 1945 20.22 2.32 11.4 1946 25.10 2.33 9.3 1947 26.02 2.35 9.0 1948 26.72 2.01 7.5 1949 28.63 3.24. 14.3 1950 33.49 5.28 15.8 1951 37.53b 13.93 1952 50.54 37.630 1953 47.72 51.34 1954 52.17 68.37d 1955 65.28 73.74. Source: Jamil, op. cit., p. 211; Public Finance Papers: Iraq, op. cit., pp. 40–41; Statistical Abstracts for 1947, 1950, 1952, 1955, 1956; Industrial Census, op. cit., p. 207. *Annual average for 1927-33 inclusive. b From 1951 on, only 30 per cent of the oil revenue was included in the government budget. Seventy per cent was allotted to the Development Board. • Including 5 million dinars for settlement of previous claims. d Including readjustment for the retroactive 1954 settlement in conformity with the March, 1955 agreement. 32 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Thirdly, over the past three decades, Iraq was able to build a small skilled and semi-skilled labor force. In addition, a fairly large number of Iraqis, either on their own or through state support, received advanced training and education in the universities of the West. These persons are now making a valuable contribution to the development of their country. Finally, a factor which began to play a positive role in recent years is technical assistance and the importation of personnel from abroad. These come from three main sources: a) The United States through its Point Four program. At present there are about 100 U.S. technicians and specialists assisting in the development of the country. b) United Nations agencies, such as WHO, UNESCO, UNICEF, the International Bank, etc., either conduct pilot projects or provide technical personnel or do both. c) Western business, at the expense of the Iraqi govern- ment, provides technicians and carries out most of the techni- cal construction now taking place. Unlike assistance in the past, the various technical assist- ance programs of today are also designed to train Iraqis to undertake the work themselves. This, for example, is one of the main objectives of the U. S. Point Four program and the programs of the U. N. agencies. In addition, all business concerns undertaking technical construction for the Iraqi government are required to train their Iraqi workers. Organization of the Development Board It became clear to the government after the war that a much more energetic and consistent policy must be followed in developing the resources of the country. The two main questions in this respect were: (1) what was the most efficient method of administration, and (2) how was this development to be financed? The pre-war experience of Iraq had clearly demonstrated that development programs suffered gravely from partisan politics and from frequent cabinet changes. Moreover, allocations for capital works were often raided to meet the ordinary expenses of government. The answer was clear. If development was to have a fair chance of success, then an ; -unist ER THE P. R. E. s. I d E N T DEVELOPMENT O BOARD PRIME M I NISTER DE PUTY PRESIDENT ministER ExEcutive Executive Executive of ºf ||º ºf ºuts ||º II ºf DEVELOPMENT - - Specialist specialist designated in Director Generol. Administration Director Generol, accounts Director General. Controcºs ond legal Affairs chairman of Committee for Development of Miri Sir lands Economic Advisor Technicol section irrigation and Droinage Technical section Roods, Bridges ond Buildings Technical Section Industries, Mining ond Electrification Technicol section Lond reclamation, forests ond Underground water Technical Section Housing Council of Minister- secret a R1 at by irrigation directorate of advice and Publicity Economic Research Dept. Supervisor of administration ond Personnel student Missions Bureau 34 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ autonomous agency, protected from cabinet changes and partisan politics, must be created. Such an agency would have a budget completely separate from that of the govern- ment and would be run primarily by experts rather than by political appointees. As to the second question, it soon became evident that development could be entirely financed from oil revenues which were expected to increase very rapidly, as in fact they did. At first it was thought that all the oil income should be diverted to development. Later, however, due to the increasing functions of government and the needs of the regular de- partments, the oil revenue was divided: 70 per cent to de- velopment and 30 per cent to the government budget. In 1950, with the above objectives in mind, the govern- ment established, under Law No. 23 (1950), a Development Board and diverted to it 100 per cent of the oil revenues. Two years later, the above law was amended to restrict the income of the Board to 70 per cent. Under Law No. 6 (1952) the Board was constituted in the following manner: The president of the Board is the Prime Minister. The members are: the Finance Minister and six other executive members, three of whom must be experts, one in finance and economics, another in irrigation, and the third in a field to be specified by the Council of Ministers. One of the expert members is to be the Secretary-General of the Board. The executive members are to be appointed by the Council of Ministers and are to hold office for a term of five years each, which terms may be extended. No executive member may hold any other governmental, legislative, or judicial office, nor may he have private interests, during his member- ship, which may benefit from the activities and program of the Board. Two of the executive members are, by practice, foreigners—one British and one American. So far, two Ameri- cans and two British experts have been executive members. Powers and Duties 1. The Board shall have a juristic personality. 2. It is empowered to “contract loans, issue bonds, mortgage its assets or borrow funds. . . etc., in its own right.” THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 35 3. The Board shall present. . . a general economic and financial plan for the development of the resources of Iraq and the raising of the standard of living of her people.” 4. “After the general programme has been approved by Parliament, the Board shall proceed to carry out the proj- ects mentioned in the programme.” 5. The Board shall make “a report on its operations for the preceding year indicating the extent to which the general program previously approved has been completed and the expenditures made in connection thereof.” Finance The Board shall have its own budget. Its revenues shall derive from “70 percent of the net revenues received from... the oil companies. . . and from such other sums as may from time to time be allotted to it by Parliament. . . and from the proceeds of any income domestic or foreign contracted by the Board under this law.” Voting Each member of the Board shall have one vote. Decisions are by majority vote, and in case of a tie, the president or vice-president may cast the deciding vote.” Administration To assist the Board in formulating and executing policy, technicians and specialists were recruited and technical departments, called “sections,” were created. Since the Board was not a regular government agency, its employees did not come under the Civil Service Law. In this manner, it was able to offer fairly high salaries and attract personnel of high caliber–Iraqis, other Arabs, and Europeans. The salaries of Americans working in the various sections, how- ever, are usually paid by the U. S. government under its Point Four program. The 1953 Reorganization As constituted in 1950, the Board was an autonomous agency, fairly protected from political pressures and pro- 1 RAQ FLOOD CONTROL AND IRRIGATION * * * International boundary * Proposed dam site - Dam and barrage under construction - Existing barrage ~ Existing eansl •--- Proposed canal New IRRIGation Projects ! Mussyab -7 Makhmut 2 Hille 6 Hawise 3. Babº 9 Adheim * Shamiya No Lower Nahrawee 5 tikra tº Dujah 6 tshaq, 12 Ghats! o so so 90 tºo tºo tººk - ~e? . arºs ./ Basra" suwart 2. THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 37 vided with a continuity of policy. Liaison with the Govern- ment and Parliament was provided through its President, the Prime Minister, and the Finance Minister, a member. Soon after its establishment, the Board began to run into difficulty. In the first place, its budget, under the control of only a few men, exceeded the total regular governmental budget. This caused resentment and even consternation in some political circles. It was also argued that the Council of Ministers had hardly any authority over the Board and received too little information from it with which to answer intelligently ques- tions and criticisms in Parliament. The Board made the fatal mistake of failing to establish an adequate public relations program to inform and guide public opinion. Finally, it made the further mistake of formulating a program which, as shall be explained later, could not but lead to disappointment. It promised a development-starved population what it could not possibly deliver within the time limits it had set for itself. This caused the Board to become, temporarily, very unpopular with the public, a situation which was exploited by some politicians to bring about its reorganization. In 1953 the cabinet in power secured from Parliament the passage of a law (No. 27 of 1953) which in effect subverted the original intent for which the Board was created, restricted its powers, and made fundamental changes in its organiza- tional structure. The new law created a Ministry of Development and transferred all the staff (except the secretariat) and the technical sections of the Board to it. The Minister of Develop- ment became the ninth voting member of the Board. Lord Salter describes the significance of the change in the following manner: This change fundamentally altered the character and authority of the Board. The new Minister, unlike the other ex-officio members, had no duties outside the same problems of develop- ment with which the Board is concerned and could therefore devote his whole time to their study. He alone had the technical 38 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ staff to advise on policy; he alone had the staff to implement it. The Board could only obtain the necessary technical advice and information on which to base their decisions from staff responsible to him, not to the Board itself, and could not execute them through him. The original purpose of the Act of 1950 was thus frustrated and the Board made dependent for positive action upon agree- ment with Ministers changing with governments. All it could do otherwise was, by a majority, to veto the allocation of funds. There are limits even to this negative power, as has been shown more than once, both before and since the new law.” The new law also created anomalies in the structure of the Board itself, which Salter pointed out. For example, the Minister of Development may be opposed to a certain policy or program but may be outvoted by the Board. On the one hand, being the representative of the Board on the Council of Ministers and its link with Parliament, he is required under the law to defend the policy to which he is opposed in Parlia- ment; on the other hand, since he alone is vested with the power of execution, he can frustrate it and render it ineffective. The new law also made important changes in the manner of execution of development plans and restricted the maneuver- ability of the Board. Article 3(a) of the 1950 law, as amended, left a fairly wide margin of freedom for the Board. Moreover, when Parlia- ment approved the Six-Year Plan in 1951, it allowed the Board to add unspent sums to the following year or years and to shift expenditures within major allocations.” Article 12 of the 1953 law restricts this freedom. First, it requires that each program be executed in a period of not more than seven years. Secondly, it requires the Board to carry out the works of each year during the year to which they relate. Thirdly, it requires that the program set forth in detail the forms of development it is designed to cover. “The Minister,” Article 12 states, “shall present to the Council of Ministers the general programme of the Board accompanied by de- tailed studies showing its justification, its economic con- sequences, its effect on raising the standard of national income, method of execution for each year, total cost of the THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 39 projects approved for each year, total cost of the programme, and actual or approximate cost of each project.” Article 13, however, allows the Minister of Development to “present to the Council of Ministers any recommendations and pro- posals by the Board for such amendments to be made in the general programme as may appear to the latter necessary. . . provided that such amendments shall be within the policy laid down in Article 12.” Article 15 of the same law, probably with a view to de- centralization, introduced another important change. It divided the Board’s projects into two main categories: One, “capital development projects,” which will continue to be executed by the Board; two, “small development projects” which, although conceived and financed by the Board, shall be entrusted by it to the appropriate government department for execution. Results of Reorganization The immediate repercussions of the 1953 reorganization were the down-grading of the salaries of Iraqi employes as they were incorporated in the civil service and the con- sequent resignation of several members of the staff, resulting, it is reported, in some lowering of efficiency. The long-term results cannot as yet be determined. The Board was created in 1950 by the Nuri as-Sa'id cabinet, which remained in power until 1952, thus becoming the longest in power since the establishment of the state. His resignation in 1952 was followed by a period of agitation, disorder, and violence, during which four cabinets rapidly succeeded each other. It was during this period, in 1953, that the Board was reorganized. In 1954, Nuri as-Sa'id re- turned to power and remained in control until July, 1957 when he was succeded by a political ally. Thus from 1954 to 1957 there was only one Minister of Development, a fact which lent stability to the operations of the Board. Now that a new Prime Minister and a new Minister of Development are in power, it is not certain how the Board will function. These men may or may not support the policies of their predecessors.” *Nuri as-Sa'id returned to power in March, 1958. 40 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ In any case, the Board has, to all practical purposes, lost its independence. The only effective power it has left is a negative one: that of the veto by a majority vote. The smooth functioning of its operations has become dependent on the ability, goodwill, and cooperation of the Minister of Develop- ment, a politician who may change with each cabinet. Since cabinets have changed frequently, and since there is no responsible party system in Iraq but, rather, factional groupings, it is probable that the work of the Board will suffer from the revision of its structure described above. On the other hand, it may be possible that the Board will become so entrenched and so popular with the public, be- cause of its evident contributions, that no politician would dare to subject it to serious pressure, or seriously obstruct its work. This possibility is in the realm of political dynamics which are beyond organizational charts, legal authority, or an author’s prescience. In the final analysis, Board mem- bers do have a minimum tenure of five years, while the life expectancy of a cabinet—if previous patterns will begin to operate again—is between seven and nine months. This fact, in itself, is one of the intangibles which can be a source of considerable strength to the Board. The Operations of the Board Since its organization, the Board has presented to Parlia- ment three programs: one in 1951, another in 1955, and a third in 1956. It will be noted that the second program was presented two years after the reorganization of the Board. The Six-Year Plan In accordance with its terms of reference, the Development Board prepared a six-year program (1951-56) in May, 1951, which was approved by Parliament the following month. The program was presented in the form of six major alloca- tions (votes), within which there were fifty-one subheadings, with financial provisions under these latter for specific projects for each of the six years (see Table 8.) THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 41 TABLE 8 DevelopMENT BoARD PROGRAM for 1951-56 Iraqi Dinars Administration, Studies and Organization Expenses 3,180,000 Irrigation Projects 53,374,000 Main Roads and Bridges 26,766,000 Buildings 18,018,000 Reclamation of Land and Other Schemes 22,986,000 Industrial and Mining Schemes 31,050,000 TOTAL 155,374,000 Source: Compilation of Laws Concerning the Development Board, op. cit., p. 8, Schedule “A”. The proceeds of the Board during the same period were estimated at 168.74 million dinars—ID. 164.64 million to come from oil revenue, ID. 3.965 million from the Inter- national Bank loan,” and ID. 135 thousands from other Sources. The Board, in addition to its own operations, granted several loans to municipalities and other governmental and semi-governmental agencies, which amounted (up to the end of financial year 1953/54) to 14,113,000 dinars. As can be readily seen from Table 9, the Board, during its first years of operation, failed to come anywhere near its projected targets. Planned expenditures from 1951 to 1954 were 58.2 million dinars. Actual expenditures, however, came only to 26.8 million, leaving a surplus of almost 32 million dinars. This result demonstrates in a spectacular manner that capital by itself is only one among many in- terlocking factors necessary for the success of a development program. It is not surprising that expenditures lagged behind sanc- tioned amounts. Such a possibility was anticipated by the International Bank Mission to Iraq before the program was launched.” It is not easy to spend money in such magnitude, rapidly and efficiently, on a well-conceived development program. This has been the experience not only of Iraq, but of almost every country, including India, which embarked on a consistent policy of development. The International Bank, for example, “has noted that disbursements on its loans to 42 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ underdeveloped countries seldom conform to original sched- ules.” The fact is that the government machinery was not geared to such large-scale spending. Such a program, involving comparatively large expenditures, requires a high level of administrative efficiency and careful planning and coordina- tion. It requires a large number of technicians and an enor- mous amount of technical study. It is interesting to note in this respect that the building program, which does not re- quire a great deal of technical work, was the most advanced; while the industrial and irrigation programs, which do, lagged far behind. Above all, perhaps, the program requires that the whole government administrative machinery be galvanized into action and imbued with a sense of mission and participation. All these factors were either absent or partly lacking when the program was launched. When the International Bank Mission visited Iraq in 1951, almost a year after the Board was organized, it noted that some govern- ment officials were not even aware of its existence, and where there was awareness, the tendency was to be cynical and to disparage possible results.” The Development Board itself gave the following reasons for its failure to reach its targets during 1951/52: (a) “Delay in sanctioning the budget.” (b) “The inability of the different ministries to execute the projects and works entrusted to them by the Board.” (c) “The necessity of providing adequate time for the preparation of estimates of costs and detailed specifica- tions for inviting tenders for the various works. Sufficient time was also to be given to prospective tenderers to enable them to inspect the sites of the proposed works and to study the specifications prior to the submission of their tenders.” The first two or three years of the program have to be regarded as essentially a period of preparation. It would have been folly to proceed with the program otherwise. It was one during which the government machinery was gradually geared to heavy spending, technicians and special- ists recruited, technical studies of specific projects prepared, relations established with qualified foreign engineering THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 43 firms, and technical assistance from abroad utilized. It is to be noted that, from 1953 on, the work began to proceed much more rapidly. For example, in 1955 actual expenditures came to 46,607,327 dinars—thus exceeding original planned expenditures for that year (32,335,000) by more than 14 million dinars. TABLE 9 ALLOTMENTs (A) & ACTUAL ExPENDITUREs (E) of THE DEVELOPMENT BoARD, 1951/52 To 1953/54 (In Thousands of Iraqi Dinars) 1951/52 1952/53 1953/54 Total A E A E A E Surplus Administration 170 110 460 260 600 300 560 Irrigation 3,024 1,733 7,100 1,064 10,840 4,000 14,167 Roads & Bridges 2,066 836 3,800 2,933 4,700 2,500 4,297 Buildings 2,368 1,368 2,650 2,650 3,100 2,900 1,200 Reclamation, etc. 1,736 953 3,450 2,076 4,150 2,150 A,157 Industry, etc. 6 3,000 5 5,000 500 7,489 9,364 5,006 20,460 8,988 28,390 12,350 31,870 Source: Iraq Government, Development Board, Annual Reports for the Fi- nancial Tears, 1951, p. 11; 1952/53, p. 23; 1953/54, pp. 5, 9, 49. The Five-Year Plan: 1955–59 No new program was presented to Parliament until 1955. In April of that year, the Minister of Development presented and Parliament approved a new Five-Year Plan to supersede the first one. In the view of the Board, the new plan had become necessary for several reasons. In the first place, expected oil revenues far exceeded original estimates. The cost estimates of the first plan were also no longer realistic and the 1953 law had changed the basis of financing proj- ects of other departments and agencies. The plan called for the expenditure of 304,306,100 dinars ($852,057,000) from 1955 to 1959 inclusive. The revenue for the period was estimated at about 252,685,000 dinars, including 37 million dinars of unobligated balances from 44 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ the previous program. The deficit, some 50 million dinars, was to be covered from expected increases in oil revenue and from anticipated savings on the estimated total cost of the program. TABLE 10 THE FIVE-YEAR PLAN: 1955–59 Iraqi Dinars Chapter I: Main Projects Administration Expenses 5,450,000 Irrigation, Drainage & Flood Control 107,935,000 Roads & Bridges 53,700,000 Airfields 5,000,000 Railways 15,500,000 Main Buildings 28,550,000 Industry, Mining & Electrification 43,571,000 Development of Animal, Plant, and Underground Water Resources 6,475,000 TOTAL–Chapter I 266,181,000 Chapter II: Small Projects Buildings & Institutes 32,250,000 Miscellaneous Projects 5,875,000 TOTAL–Chapter II 38,125,000 GRAND TOTAL 304,306,100 Source: Law No. 43 (1955), Schedule (A). The Six-Year Plan: 1955-60 In May, 1956 the Minister of Development proposed a new supplementary Six-Year Program (1955-60) to Parlia- ment to replace the one submitted the previous year. The new program was approved in June. Three main reasons prompted the Board to propose the new program: a sharp increase in oil revenues, the completion of several studies and surveys which now needed implementation, and, finally, the recommendations of Lord Salter, the economic adviser, in favor of a more flexible and inclusive program. The new plan contemplates the expenditure of 500 million dinars ($1,400,000,000) between 1955 and 1960, including some ID. 46 million which had already been spent in 1955. The revenue for the same period is estimated at about ID. 400 million. The deficit, about ID. 100 million, is expected THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 45 to be covered from unobligated balances of previous years amounting to more than ID. 50 million, and savings on the 1955-60 expenditures estimates—totaling about 15 per cent. The new plan differs from previous ones in many respects. First, it is of much greater financial magnitude. It contem- plates a rate of expenditure averaging about 85 million dinars a year, as against ID. 31 million for the first plan and ID. 61 million for the 1955 plan. Then, unlike the first plan, execution is much more de- centralized. The program is divided into “main” and “small” projects; the latter are to be executed by the appropriate government departments. This is a step in the right direction, since on the one hand it gives some relief to the administrative machinery of the Board and, on the other, it gives the regular government departments a sense of participation in the development of the country. Finally, and also unlike the first plan, the program was presented to Parliament as a tentative proposal. Contem- plated new projects may or may not be executed depending on whether, after careful study, they are found to be econom- ical. Moreover, the Board may propose to Parliament, if necessary, a supplementary program either in the light of new studies or if oil revenues increase or decrease sharply. In other words, the program is much more flexible than its two predecessors. The new plan differs also in content. Flood control, irriga- tion, and drainage in all three plans receive first priority in allocations. But where emphasis in the first plan was on the flood control aspect, the emphasis in the present one is on irrigation, drainage, and reclamation. This is because the flood menace has been brought under a reasonable measure of control through the completion of the major control projects. Attention can now be properly diverted to the constructive aspect of agriculture, i.e., improvement of existing areas and bringing new land under cultivation. In both the 1955-59 and the present program, far more emphasis is placed on the transportation system, particularly roads and bridges. This new direction is probably due to two main factors: the greater realization that it would be THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 47 Plants under Construction 16,424,217 Mining Survey 126,000 Electrification 12,669,000 Improvement of Existing Industries and New Industries 37,900,000 67,119,217 8. Development of Animal, Plant & Underground Water Resources Research & Laboratories 1,500,000 Plant Resources Development 2,500,000 Animal Resources Development 2,000,000 Forests 1,000,000 1955 Allocations for All Above 1,036,818 State Land Reclamation 1,125,000 Artesian Wells 3,000,000 Main Water Projects 1,125,000 Agricultural Machinery 250,000 Agricultural Schools & Centers 750,000 14,286,818 TOTAL-Chapter I 430,732,327 Chapter II: Small Projects 9. Buildings & Institutes Health Institutions 5,750,000 Elementary & Other Schools 8,000,000 Housing for Labor 1,800,000 Buildings for Government Departments 28,825,000 Secondary Roads & Bridges 8,500,000 Telephone, Telegraph & Wireless 4,500,000 Eradication of Malaria 2,000,000 59,375,000 10. Miscellaneous Projects Minor Irrigation Works 6,500,000 Improvement of Drinking Water 1,500,000 Filling of Swamps 300,000 Aerial & General Surveys 850,000 Other 750,000 9,900,000 TOTAL-Chapter II 69,275,000 GRAND TOTAL 500,007,327 Source: Law No. 54 (1956), Schedule (A). The new program is by far more balanced and inclusive than the two preceding it. Unlike the others, it strikes a reasonable balance between long-term “brick and mortar” development projects and short-term projects geared to meet immediate human needs. Housing, which was almost com- pletely ignored in previous plans, moved to fourth place and 48 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ receives more than ID. 24 million. Expenditures on hospitals, clinics, drinking water, and other direct and indirect health measures receive a sharp boost. Allocations for education, including colleges, secondary, elementary, technical and agricultural schools and training centers are vastly increased. Similarly, there is a much greater balance between ex- penditures on new projects and expenditures on the im- provement of existing plant. The tendency in earlier plans, particularly the first one, was to allocate most of the avail- able funds for launching new projects: new dams, new land, new roads, new factories, new schools, new hospitals, etc., with few allocations for improving those facilities already in existence. This was particularly true of irrigation proj- ects. In the present program proper attention is paid to this aspect. The main question concerning such a mammoth plan, involving the expenditure of an average of ID. 85 million a year in addition to some ID. 20 million spent annually by other departments, is whether the Board and the minis- tries are administratively capable of implementing it. The evidence indicates that they may be, or at least that the new plan will have a far greater success than the first one. Both the Board and the ministries have now had over five years of practical experience in intensive development prob- lems and are probably far more administratively efficient than in 1950. Very heavy reliance in the execution of proj- ects is now placed on competent foreign firms which have had wide experience in their respective fields. Too, many of the technical studies, the lack of which caused considerable delay in the past, are now completed and ready for implemen- tation. Finally, Iraq has also drawn heavily upon the technical resources of the United Nations, the United States, European countries, particularly Britain, and those of neighboring countries. The Objectives of the Board The Board was entrusted by Parliament to carry out programs for the “development of the resources of Iraq and the raising of the standard of living of her people.” THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 49 As for the first part, “the development of the resources of Iraq,” the Board in its first and second plans imposed a narrow construction on its mandate and concerned itself mainly with the physical type of development. By and large, its conception did not seem to include the “development of human resources.” A glance at the first two plans shows clearly the heavy concentration on long-range projects such as dams, irrigation works, roads, bridges, industrial plants and so forth. Few projects related to the immediate human problem. According to Lord Salter, the primary reasons why the Board was reluctant to enter heavily into the social welfare field was the question of departmental jurisdiction. It is wary of slipping into the habit of subsidizing current govern- ment operations under the umbrella of development. In some cases the lines of demarcation fade out and it be- comes difficult to determine where “development” ends and an ordinary departmental operation begins. For example, is combatting malaria a development function or an ordinary government operation? Good arguments can be made for both views. In any case, after the program gained momentum it became clear that an efficient plan of development has to be balanced and integrated. A new industrial plant needs skilled workers to run and maintain it, and efficient pro- duction requires a labor force free from debilitating diseases such as malaria and hookworm. Moreover, the Board’s policy of emphasizing—almost exclusively—long-range proj- ects soon made it unpopular with the public and was one of the main factors exploited to bring about its reorganization in 1953. The present plan reflects the shift which has taken place in the development philosophy of the Board. This was brought about by the realization mentioned above, through popular discontent, and finally by the wise advice of Lord Salter in his report to the Board. The pattern of the Board’s expenditures leaves little doubt that one of its chief aims is the development of agriculture: to increase vastly the land under cultivation, increase pro- | 50 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ ductivity per unit, diversify agricultural production, intro- duce intensive farming, and gradually to mechanize. Ex- penditures on agriculture (i.e., flood control, irrigation, drainage, etc.) average, in all three plans, about 35 per cent of total planned expenditures. This emphasis is understand- able, since land and water are the country’s most valuable natural resources. The second objective of the Board is to move Iraq from its present stage, in which agricultural production dominates the economy, into a second stage where agriculture, industry, and other economic activities such as trade and services are more or less on an equal footing. Among other things, this will mean considerable investment in industry, siphoning off part of the agricultural labor force from the land and a geographical and occupational redistribution of the popula- tion. Quantitatively, what do the programs of the Board mean in terms of raising the standard of living—the second part of the Board’s mandate? The rise or decline in the standard of living is governed by one basic factor: the relation between the rate of population growth and the rate of increase in the national income. Increase in the national income, however, is also governed by two basic factors: the rate of productivity and the rate of capital investment. Net annual population growth has been estimated at about 2.3 per cent. It may be that, as a result of the various health measures now being undertaken by the government, this rate may soon go up to 3 per cent. The capital income ratio in Iraq has been recently estimated at 6:1 (i.e., six units of invested capital produce one unit of income). Thus, according to an Iraqi economist, taking into consideration population growth, Iraq must, in order to maintain the standard of living existing around 1950, make an annual capital investment at the rate of 13.8 per cent of the total national income (2.3 x 6 = 13.8).9 l In 1951 the IBRD Mission to Iraq estimated the national income at about 150 million dinars ($424 million). Between 1951/52 and 1955/56, a five-year period, excluding other THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 51 government departments and the private sector, the Board alone made a total capital investment of over 150 million dinars (or 30 million dinars a year) equal to 20 per cent of the national income in 1951. This exceeds by 6.2 per cent the amount of investment necessary (13.8 per cent) to main- tain the standard of living. We have already stated that in Iraq each unit of capital investment produces one unit of product or income (capital productivity coefficient equals one-sixth). Hence the annual investments of the Board (20 per cent of the national income) increase the national income by 3.3 per cent annually (20 x 1 = 3.3). But the population increases at the rate of 6 2.3 per cent a year, thus leaving a surplus of 1 per cent. In other words, the Board’s rate of investment between 1951/52 and 1955/56 should have raised the standard of living by 1 per cent each year. Under the present program, the Board plans to spend an average of 85 million dinars a year. Assuming, for theoretical purposes, that all other factors have remained constant (not a correct assumption), then this rate of investment equals about 56 per cent of the national income in 1951. Such a rate should theoretically produce 9.3 per cent increase in the national income annually (56 x + = 9.3). If 2.3 per cent, the annual growth of population, is deducted, then this leaves a 7 per cent increase in the standard of living a year. All the above data are, of course, based on theoretical formulations which, because of other variables, may not coincide with actual results. Despite probable wide margins of error, however, they do show rough approximations of trends. It is quite obvious that the activities of the Board have on the one hand placed great quantities of money in circulation in the form of wages, and expenditures on services and materials. On the other hand, these activities were apt to cause shortages in certain materials, particularly in con- struction. Unless adequate measures are taken, this trend will tend to cause inflation and nullify an apparent rise in income. * 52 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ The government wisely took various measures to forestall such an eventuality. It undertook the sale of some foods, particularly bread. It removed the istihlaq (consumption) tax on the local consumption of some commodities and raised it on the same if exported. It reduced import taxes on some consumer products and, finally, floated internal loans to siphon off some of the money in circulation. As a result of these and other measures, there has been no appreciable increase in prices, as table 12 indicates. TABLE 12 WHOLESALE PRICE INDEx (Monthly Average) Base Year 1939 = 100 1945 1950 1951 1954 1955 1956 Grain & Dates 592.9 530.0 557.2 462.1 452.5 543.5 Meat & Milk Products 665.2 627.7 597.1 584.9 595.9 637.3 Other Foods 309.6 346.0 365.3 329.5 336.0 335.0 Other Animal & Vegetable Products 412.9 615.3 708.3 514.1 510.1 502.9 Building Materials 634.5 488.8 653.6 517.7 590.8 602.4 Textiles 944.0 792.5 890.5 620.7 597.8 597.7 Fuels 138.7 149.0 162.5 153.7 154.2 154.8 Other Goods 535.0 428.6 509.7 355.1 335.5 327.3 General Price Index 494.4 475.1 520.8 427.9 432.1 463.1 Source: Statistical Abstract for 1955, p. 137; 1956, p. 159. Other Government Agencies Development work is by no means restricted to the Board and the Ministry of Development. Other state agencies carry out important major works which have averaged in recent years some 20 per cent of the total expenditures of the ordinary government budget. 1. There are “capital works” and “economic projects” in the general budget of the government. These have averaged more than four million dinars a year since 1951. THE DEVELOPMENT BOARD 53 2. There are also expenditures for “administrative local councils and expenses of elementary education” and other projects carried out by the councils. These have also averaged over four million dinars a year (1953/54, ID. 4.5 million; 1954/55, ID. 6.1 million). 3. Various government banks such as the Industrial Bank, the Agricultural Bank, the Mortgage Bank, etc., carry out their own important projects. 4. Semi-governmental agencies such as the State Rail- ways, the Port of Basrah, the Tobacco Monopoly, the Date Association, etc., finance many of their own projects in addition to any assistance they may receive from the Board. 5. There are also programs of the U. S. Point Four and United Nations agencies. The chapters that follow will discuss in detail the trans- formation taking place in all sectors of Iraqi life, principally as a result of the activities of the Development Board and the Ministry of Development, but also of other government agencies and of private investment, both native and foreign. 1. Walter Z. Laqueur, Communism and JNationalism in the Middle East (New York: Praeger, 1956), p. 202. 2. Iraq Government, Development Board, Compilation of Laws Concerning the Development Board, (revised) (Baghdad: Government Press, 1952). 3. Salter, op. cit., p. 97. 4. Articles 4 and 5 of Law No. 35 (1951). 5. In 1950 the Government of Iraq contracted a loan from the International Bank for 12.8 million dinars for the Tharthar project. Actually only a little over six million dollars of the loan were used. The loan was paid back in full by 1956. 6. IBRD, p. 76. 7. Ibid., p. 79. 8. Annual Report for the Financial Year 1953-54, op. cit., p. 5. 9. Abdul Sahib Alwan, “Population Increase and Economic Development in Iraq,” Majallat al-Zira’a al-Iraqiya, (Special Issue), Vol. 12, No. 1, January- February-March, 1957, pp. 77-84. Published by the Ministry of Agriculture at Baghdad, in Arabic. PART II The Development of Agriculture CHAPTER 4 CONTROL OVER THE WATER RESOURCES Control and utilization of its water resources have been for generations—and indeed for centuries—the principal prob- lem of Iraq. Although nature has endowed the country with abundant supplies sufficient to irrigate all the arable land, the desired amounts are not delivered when and where they are needed. Droughts scorch a thirsty land during the sowing season, and spring floods lay waste the crops when they are almost ready for the harvest, and devastate villages and even urban centers such as Baghdad. Iraq is divided into two zones: a rainfall zone and an irrigation zone. Since the amount of rain is not controllable, agricultural expansion in the Mesopotamian valley must therefore depend on harnessing the waters of the Tigris- Euphrates river system. Regional Aspects of the System Both the Tigris and Euphrates originate in Turkey. The Euphrates flows through Syria for some considerable distance before entering Iraq. Headwaters of the Lesser Zab and the Diyala, tributaries of the Tigris, are in the Iranian mountains and the east bank of the Shatt al-Arab forms one of the WATER RESOURCES 55 frontiers with Iran. Clearly then, both the Tigris and Eu- phrates are international rivers. Iraq being a lower riparian country is in a very vulner- able position vis-a-vis Turkey, Syria, and Iran. Theoretically, there is very little that Iraq can do if any or all of these states embark on schemes for extensive exploitation and diver- sion of the waters of the two rivers and their tributaries. Moreover, anti-erosion measures, such as afforestation of the watershed areas of the system to protect the water storage works being built in Iraq from silting up, can be effective only with the cooperation of Turkey and Iran. A stable river development in Iraq is therefore contingent upon the execution of bilateral or multilateral agreements with the other riparian states concerned. The ideal would be one agreement to which Turkey, Iran, Syria, and Iraq would all be parties. In the case of Iran, because of the mountainous terrain in which the watersheds of the Tigris tributaries are located, there is little likelihood that this country will divert any significant quantities of water. Its only objection could be concerning the possible deterioration of the Shatt al-Arab river for navigation. This eventuality seems remote. Syria poses a different problem. Large areas there, ad- jacent to the Euphrates, are suitable for agricultural develop- ment. Actual large-scale projects, such as the proposed Yusuf Pasha dam, have been under consideration for some time. This would seriously reduce the amounts of water flow into Iraq from the Euphrates. Similarly, a proposed dam at Ana on the Euphrates in Iraq would back up the water into Syria over a distance of some sixty kilometers. There is no agreement between Syria and Iraq concerning river control and allocation of water supply. A convention was signed in Paris on December 23, 1920, between France and Britain, as mandatory powers for Syria and Iraq, which called for the formation of a commission which would examine all proposed irrigation schemes in Syria which may seriously diminish “the waters of the Tigris and the Euphrates at the points where they enter the area of the British mandate in Mesopotamia.” No such commission was set up. In any 56 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ case, the convention is probably no longer binding. Iraq, upon the termination of the British mandate in 1932, de- clared herself bound by all the agreements made on its be- half by the Mandatory Administration. No such declaration was made by Syria when the French mandate was terminated in 1945. The principle of cooperation (even though limited) be- tween Iraq and Turkey over river control was established in the Treaty of Friendship and Neighborly Relations signed by the two governments on March 29, 1946. In Protocol I of the treaty Turkey allowed Iraq to establish meteorological stations in its territory, to conduct geological surveys for possible flood-control dam sites, and consented in principle, subject to confirmation in each case, to the construction by Iraq, in Turkey, of water works found to be necessary. Turkey also obligated itself to inform Iraq of any contem- plated projects on the two rivers. Under the treaty, Iraq has so far established three meteorological stations in Turkish territory but no river works have been constructed there. More recently, closer cooperation between Turkey, Iraq, and Iran over river control is being effected through the “Baghdad Pact.” A Joint Irrigation Projects Committee has been established as a subdivision of the Pact's Economic Committee. There is also a subcommittee on cooperation in agricultural planning. At a meeting of the Joint Irrigation Projects Committee held at Ankara in July, 1956, the Iranian and Turkish Govern- ments undertook to establish meteorological and hydrological stations at the headwaters of the Euphrates, the Tigris, and their tributaries in their territories. The Committee also undertook to make a survey of joint irrigation projects which had been recommended by the Economic Committee at its meeting in Teheran earlier in the summer. Features of the Tigris-Euphrates System Sir William Willcocks, the great Anglo-Indian engineer, described the Nile as a “gentleman.” In contrast, the Tigris and Euphrates can perhaps be described as two tempera- mental ladies who need considerable persuasion and control. WATER RESOURCES 57 Unlike the Nile, the seasonal distribution of the water supplies of the system does not coincide with crop needs. Winter crops in Iraq need water from May onwards. The low-water season, however, lasts from July to December. During this period the mean water discharges of the Tigris and the Euphrates are 559 and 421 cubic meters per second (cumecs), respectively. The two rivers reach their lowest levels in September and October when water is badly needed. When the crops are either half-grown or almost ready for the harvest and water is no longer badly needed, they are subject to the danger of inundation. Spring is the flood season. During this period the mean water discharges of the two rivers are 2,572 and 1,765 cumecs respectively. In the case of summer crops which need water from April to September, the situation is reversed. At first they receive abundant supplies, then the supply declines gradually until it reaches a low point in September. Again, unlike the Nile which flows gently, the Euphrates and the Tigris, particularly the latter, have very steep gra- dients in the upper and central parts of the valley, but very slight in the lower part. The bed of the Tigris slopes down at a ratio of 5.7:10,000 between the Turkish frontier and Baghdad, but from there on the ratio falls down to one in 20,000. The Euphrates, though not as steep (3.3:10,000), also flattens out from Ramadi on. This feature has several important consequences. Erosive action in the upper reaches is extremely strong. Sediments are carried during all parts of the year. The effectiveness of water-storage and flood-control works and irrigation canals is therefore constantly endangered by silting. Moreover, the rivers during the flood season tend to be very violent (es- pecially the Tigris). They thunder down the mountain slopes, sometimes sweeping away irrigation works, causing con- siderable damage to crops and carving themselves new COurSeS. On the other hand, the silt-laden waters have, during the past 5,000 years, built the southern part of the valley. At present, the delta on the shoreline of the gulf is being built entirely by the Karun river which flows from Iran, while 58 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ the Tigris and Euphrates deposit their silt in the central marshes. The waters of both the Tigris and Euphrates are some- what saline. The proportion of salt in both rivers near Baghdad is thirty to thirty-three parts in 100,000. In the lower reaches of the Euphrates, however, salinity goes up to ninety per 100,000. This has resulted in progressive salination of the soil and declining crop yields. The Haigh Commission Re- port (see below) estimated that some 60 per cent of the irriga- ted areas have been affected by salination and that about 20–30 per cent of the cultivated land in the irrigation zone has been abandoned in recent decades because it was no longer suitable for cultivation. Another feature of the system, which has had a favorable effect on agriculture, is that the bed of the Euphrates from north of Falluja southwards until the two rivers meet at Qurna, is slightly higher than that of the Tigris. In modern times, as in the past, this difference of elevation had been utilized to build a network of gravity flow canals from west to east to irrigate large areas of land. Of the two rivers, the Euphrates is the more gentle and easier to control. During its course after leaving Turkey, only one main tributary, the Khabur in Syria, flows into it. Otherwise, in Iraq, it only receives the discharges of main wadis and seepages from the North Desert. Consequently, its water discharge fluctuates less widely than the Tigris. In contrast, the Tigris is to a high degree unruly and difficult. It has a vast catchment area. As it flows from Turkey towards the Persian Gulf, it receives several tributaries: in Iraq, four: the Greater Zab, the Lesser Zab, the Udhaim and the Diyala. Both the Udhaim and the Diyala are difficult rivers. The floods of the former occur as a result of rain storms rather than melting snow, and, therefore, they fluctu- ate widely in volume and intensity. On the Diyala, floods occur suddenly with little warning. Hence, the Tigris is subject to periodic violent floods and is feared much more than the Euphrates. WATER RESOURCES 59 Reports on Water Control To appreciate the scope and significance of the vast water control program taking place now in Iraq, it is important to summarize here, in a few paragraphs, two global reports made on the subject in recent years. In fact, the present program is a modified version of their recommendations. They are the Haigh Commission Report* made in 1949 after some three years of field investigation, and the report of Knappen-Tippets-Abbett-McCarthy (KTAM), a New York engineering firm, made in 1952.” The Haigh Report The report estimated the total gross area in the valley “available and suitable for cultivation” to be 27 million dunums (see Table 13). Only 12.7 million of this total are under cultivation, and only 5.2 million dunums are actually planted annually in winter crops, while most of the rest is left fallow. With the installation of flood control works, water storage, drainage, land reclamation, new irrigation canals, improve- ment of existing canals, etc., the report states that 13 million dunums more can be irrigated, bringing the possible total to 25.7 million dunums. The mean water supply of the Euphrates is 280 cumecs, of which 228 cumecs are used to irrigate inadequately some 4.7 million dunums. Of this area only 1.9 million dunums are planted in winter crops annually. The report shows that by perennial live storage of some 17.2 billion cubic meters of water in Lake Habbaniya and the Abu Dibbis depression, it is possible to raise the water supply of the Euphrates to 510 cumecs, an amount sufficient both to irrigate four million dunums of new land and to im- prove the supplies of existing areas. As for the Tigris and its tributaries, they have a mean water supply of 351 cumecs, which is used to irrigate a gross area of eight million dunums. Of this, only 3.3 million dunums, the report estimates, are annually planted in winter crops. WATER RESOURCES 61 TABLE 14 KTAM REPORT ESTIMATEs: 1952 Land Under Cultivation, New Land (Arable and Irrigable), Plans of Development, and Water Requirements Existing Areas JNew Land in Annual Water Requirements Million Dunums Million Dunums in Billion Cubic Meters Fallow Intensive Intensive Grand System System System Total Total Euphrates Tigris Total Euphrates - Basin 4.9 - - 2.8 7.7 6.1 a - 6.1 a Tigris Basin 8.1 - - 6.2 14.3 - 11.3a 11.3a Total 13.0 - - 9.0 22.0 6.1 a 11.3a 17.4a Plan “A” 13.0 - 9.0 9.0 22.0 12.1 26.1 38.2 Plan “B” 4.0 9.0 9.0 9.0 22.0 14.7 32.0 47.1 Source: KTAM Report, op. cit. * Excluding new lands. Under Plan “A”, the 13 million dunums of existing land would continue to be cultivated under the fallow system with improved drainage. However, the nine million dunums of new land would be cultivated on the “basis of modern in- tensive methods including crop rotation, improved methods of cultivation and irrigation, livestock management, and other related modern practices.” The annual water require- ments under this plan would be 38.2 billion cubic meters of Water. Under Plan “B”, four million dunums would continue to be cultivated under the fallow system (because of water supply limitations), and 18 million under the intensive system. The annual water requirements in this case would be 47.1 billion cubic meters. The report argues that the water requirements of either plan “A” or “B” can be met from the available water supplies of the two rivers. In the case of the Tigris, measurements taken at Baghdad since 1906 show that its average annual discharge for the period has been 38.8 billion cubic meters. During 1930-34, a succession of dry years, the annual average discharge for the period was 32.5 billion cubic meters. 62 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Similarly, measurements taken of the Euphrates since 1924 at Hit show an average annual flow for the period of 26.4 billion cubic meters. During the dry five-year period (1930– 34), the average annual flow was 17.2 billion cubic meters. The above figures show that the water supply is assured in both cases. The problem reduces itself to one of perennial storage. “If storage reservoirs are built, it will be possible to store water during a wet year and use it during a succeed- ing dry year; therefore, the flow during a single dry year is not necessarily critical.” The report estimates the total population of the valley as 3.3 million persons (against 5.1 for the whole country) of whom 1.2 million are urban and 2.1 million are rural. On the basis of these population estimates, the farm income of the inhabitants of the valley would rise in the following Inanner: Present (13 mil. dunums Fallow System) Plan “A” Plan “B” Dinars Dinars Dinars Gross Farm Income (Includes Produc- tion Cost, Labor Cost & Surplus) 118,000,000 542,000,000 764,000,000 Net Farm Income, (Includes Labor Cost & Surplus) 62,000,000 295,000,000 416,000,000 Average Net Farm Income Per Head of Inhabitants (3.3 million) 19 89 126 This vast increase in farm income, which would make the farm population of Iraq the most prosperous in the Middle East, is made contingent by the report on meeting certain basic requirements: (a) Construction of new facilities 1. Drainage 2. Water storage facilities WATER RESOURCES 63 3. Irrigation canals and control works 4. Flood control facilities (b) Management 1. Improved farm practices 2. Organization and training 3. Maintenance of completed works The program of development would depend primarily on flow irrigation. Lift irrigation by comparison is very costly. The total cost of the program, excluding cost of flood and storage reservoirs, would be 198 million dinars ($555.4 million) with expenditures spaced over a period of twenty-five years. At present, the target of the Development Board is—and correctly so—more modest than the KTAM proposals. Dur- ing the past five years the Board has concentrated mainly on building basic facilities such as flood control and water storage works. In the recent program the emphasis has begun to shift to drainage and irrigation. The rest of this chapter will be devoted to the accomplishments of the Board in the fields of flood control, storage, irrigation, and drainage. Flood Control and Water Storage Until 1952 very little was done to control the flood menace. Minor works, mostly embankments called “bunds,” were constructed, and Lake Habbaniya was utilized to some extent for overflow from the Euphrates. These measures could cope with the danger of moderate floods only. No wonder, then, that the Development Board gave first priority in its pro- gram to flood control projects. In 1956, the two major flood control works were com- pleted, bringing a good measure of safety to Iraq for the first time in its long history. Others which are now under construction will bring the flood menace under full control, making it a memory of a dreaded past. The Euphrates The worst recorded flood on the Euphrates, that of May 5, 1929, had a maximum discharge of 5,200 cubic meters 64 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ per second at Hit. Flood control and storage on the Euphrates centers around the Lake Habbaniya water complex reduce the maximum possible flood danger from 5,200 to 2,000 cumecs. With the use of the Abu Dibbis depression, it can be reduced still further to 1,500 cumecs, thus giving full protection against flood from the Euphrates. The complex is composed of six major components: 1. Lake Habbaniya itself, which serves the dual purpose of a flood escape and a storage reservoir. Until 1956, its storage capacity was 1.3 billion cubic meters. In that year, however, work on raising its dykes from 49.5 to 51 meters above sea level was completed, giving it a storage capacity of 2.3 billion cubic meters. This has now reduced the flood danger from 5,200 to 4,000 cumecs. 2. The Ramadi Barrage. Work on this barrage started in 1953. Its total cost came to 1.4 million dinars. It is located across the Euphrates and is 209 meters long and fourteen meters high. It has a fish ladder and a navigation lock to allow the passage of river craft. The barrage arrests the upstream waters of the river and thus reduces the flood danger further to 2,000 cumecs, and makes it possible to fill the lake to a higher level. The excess flood water is diverted to the lake through the Warrar regulator. 3. Warrar Inlet Canal and regulator. Both the canal and the regulator were completed in 1952. The canal is 8.5 kilometers long and connects the river with the lake. Dur- ing floods, its regulator can divert water through the canal at the rate of 2,800 cumecs. 4. The Dhibban Outlet Canal and regulator. Both were completed in 1951. The canal is thirteen kilometers long and connects the lake with the Euphrates. Its purpose is to feed the river from water stored in Lake Habbaniya during the dry season. Its regulator has a discharge capacity of 250 CuIIleCS. 5. The Majjara Escape Canal. This was completed in 1945. It is 8.2 kms. long and connects the lake with the Abu Dibbis depression. Should floods exceed the storage WATER RESOURCES 65 capacity of the lake, the regulator on the canal can discharge water to the depression at the rate of 850 cumecs. At present another escape canal to the depression, with a discharge capacity of 2,800 cumecs, is under study. 6. The Abu Dibbis Depression. This is a natural de- pression with no outlet canal. At present it is used only for flood control purposes: that is, to receive the water over- flow from Lake Habbaniya through the Majjara Escape Canal. The new storage provided by the Habbaniya complex has now raised the available water supplies of the Euphrates from 280 to 440 cumecs. This amount can now provide sufficient water supplies to existing cultivated areas and in addition bring under cultivation some 2.4 million dunums gross of new land. It is possible to increase the water supplies of the Euphrates and provide for additional flood protection by using the Abu Dibbis for storage (see preceding summary of Haigh Report). The depression would have a storage capacity of 21 billion cubic meters gross or 14.5 billion net. This would reduce the flood danger still further to 1,500 cumecs and increase the water supply of the Euphrates to a total of 510 cumecs. The IBRD Mission, however, had very serious reservations about the usefulness of the depression for irrigation storage because of its high salt content, which would render water stored there useless for irrigation purposes.” The above question is now under study. If it is proved that the water stored in the depression is usable for irriga- tion, then the full potential development of the Euphrates basin, insofar as water supplies are concerned, has already been achieved. Otherwise, an alternative storage site will have to be found. The Tigris and Its Tributaries Many studies have been made to determine the best sites for flood control and storage works on the Tigris and its tributaries. Several proposed sites are now under investiga- tion by engineers; some are under construction and one has been completed. -•—• №::= ==) -a ; p:= - ) != -= —~~'+ →± - №; ,==- - ±±, ±,±, ± Ē ē ě Ē Ē *|- na NNwyo manumo wwwwwtww caeozou0wouvnnaeae, uanino *9www.vryw •w•w•ınx yº •mo•şN •ąon ~qoae woqqoh S03.NNwho manni wwwww.aw wołanouwou wºnnº, maennu nºnnuwwo manuno naerº,J№wwwww.aw f(EN)(~) ovowntw… • • • • • ovou - qnaen veqovųows; · Nvid Ivº 3N39) ICĒTONG RIVHIRI VH1 |C|V|WAL ou owes • aowwwww w.wwwww.ws •wen wews umºwę, wºw 09 •wewpxomdøv voisseudºo woquoque WATER RESOURCES 67 The Wadi Tharthar Project. The major flood control work on the Tigris and, for that matter, in the whole of Iraq is the Tharthar project. It was officially inaugurated by the king on April 2, 1956 in an imposing ceremony attended by foreign diplomats, government leaders, and most of the prominent personalities in the country. Work on the project started in 1952 with an average labor force, until completion, of about 3,000 workers and 140 engineers. The earthwork removal came to about 60 per cent of that carried out for the construction of the Suez Canal. The cost, up to March 1956, amounted to 12.1 million dinars ($33.88 million); 4.5 million dinars more are expected to be spent before completion. The maximum recorded flood discharge of the Tigris at Samarra where the barrage of the project is located, was 12,000 cumecs (in February 1941). The project reduces this maximum danger to 3,500 cumecs, thus giving Baghdad and downstream areas a considerable margin of safety. The project consists of three main parts.: 1. The Wadi Tharthar. This is a vast natural depression which lies between the Tigris and Euphrates about forty miles northwest of Baghdad. Its lowest point is three meters below sea level, but its edges rise to a height of 60 meters above. The wadi is 100 kilometers long and some forty kilometers wide with an area of 2,025 square kilometers. When filled to a height of sixty meters, it forms a lake with a gross capacity of sixty-eight billion cubic meters, comparable in size to the Dead Sea in Palestine. Its live (net) storage, however, de- pends on how high the depression is filled and on how low an outlet irrigation canal is drawn. For instance, if the de- pression is filled to a height of fifty-eight meters, and the outlet canal is drawn at a height of thirty-eight meters, then the dead storage would be 33 billion cubic meters, and the live storage, thirty billion cubic-meters. 2. The Inlet Canal and regulator. The canal is sixty- five kilometers long and connects the Tigris with the de- pression. Its regulator can discharge water at the rate of 9,000 cumecs. Consideration is now being given to enlarging the canal and the discharge capacity of the regulator. 68 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 3. The Barrage. This lies across the Tigris near the town of Samarra. It backs up the upstream waters of the Tigris and diverts the excess flow to the depression through the canal. The barrage has an estimated potential capacity of generating 112,000 kilowatts of electric power. As in the case of the Abu Dibbis depression, there are doubts that the Wadi Tharthar depression is sufficiently water-tight for irrigation storage. The Haigh Commission was certain that it is. Other experts and consulting engineers who have studied the project since are not so certain. In the view of Lord Salter, its usefulness, according to the criteria of salinity and seepage, cannot be determined before 1961 and, in any case, it will take ten years for the depression to fill to the level at which water can be used. Should the depression be found suitable for irrigation storage, there will be very little need for any further storage works, for, along with the dams under construction, it will be able to meet all the water requirements of existing and new lands in the Tigris Basin. An interesting project, which is under study now, is a canal connecting the Habbaniya com- plex with the depression. The Dokan Dam. This project is located on the Lesser Zab river at the Dokan gorge some 60 kilometers northwest of the town of Sulaimaniya near the Iranian border in the northeast of Iraq. Work on the dam started in 1954 and is scheduled to be completed in 1958. The budgeted cost of the dam proper is 13 million dinars ($36.4 million). The dam, when completed, will be the largest of its kind in the Middle East. It consists of a massive concrete arch- shaped wall across the gorge, 325 meters long and 108 meters high. The thickness of the wall at the bottom will be fifty meters and at the top nine meters. It will create a mountain lake fifty square kilometers in area with a storage capacity of 6.8 billion cubic meters. The structure will also have two diversion tunnels, 12.5 and 11 meters in diameter respectively, to be used as spill- ways for flood water. In addition, it will have five outlets, each 3.65 meters in diameter, for future generation of electric power. 70 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ the water of the river itself and that conveyed by the feeder canal from the Batma dam. The structure is expected to irrigate an estimated area of 214,000 dunums on its right bank, and 662,000 dunums on the left bank. Other Proposed Dams. Two more dams have been under study and investigation for some time: The Bekhme on the Greater Zab river, and Eski Mosul on the Tigris north of Mosul. Their suitability as dam sites has been established. Studies indicate that if a dam is erected on the Bekhme gorge to a height of 165 meters, it would have a storage capacity of 8.3 billion cubic meters of water in addition to generating 600,000 kilowatts of electric power. It is estimated that the Eski Mosul dam would have a storage capacity of eight billion cubic meters. Funds have been allocated for these two dams in the 1955-60 program. However, construc- tion will take place only when and if it is determined that there is need for further water storage. Such a decision may be reached towards the end of 1959. Irrigation Canal building in Iraq was brought to the level of a fine art by the ancient Babylonians and was further developed by the peoples that followed them. Historical evidence indicates that, up to the thirteenth century A. D., there was a much larger area of land under cultivation than at present. The canals of today follow to a surprising degree the ruins of those built centuries ago. When the Development Board was organized, there was already in existence an intricate system of canals, a large number of which were built during the past three decades. The Board’s task in this respect is twofold: first, to improve the efficiency of the existing system by the installation of barrages, regulators, pumping plants, and desilting works; by reclamation of canals which had silted up; and by re- modeling, expanding and extending others; second, to build new canals where needed. Through such measures, water supplies to areas under cultivation can be improved, large areas of land can be reclaimed, and finally, the danger from WATER RESOURCES 71 floods can be reduced further by diverting excess waters to where they can do no harm. As pointed out above, the emphasis during the past six years has been more on building dams and less on improving existing facilities. In recent programs far more emphasis is being placed on irrigation and drainage than before. For instance, in the first Six-Year Plan (1951-56), the amount allotted to irrigation was ten million dinars, most of which was not spent. In the second Six-Year Plan (1955-56), irrigation was allotted more than 30 million dinars under various expenditure categories. What is more important is that the allotments are actually being spent. In the following few pages some of the main irrigation projects either under study or construction will be discussed. The Euphrates 1. The Hilla Canal System. This canal is commanded by the Hindiyah barrage built in 1913. It is the largest canal in Iraq served by a single in- take. With its four main branches, it serves some 2.7 million dunums of land in the Euphrates basin. One of its branches, the Dagharra, has deteriorated to the point of becoming useless. Investigations by the engineering firm KTAM show that if the Hilla system is expanded, remodeled, and desilting works installed, it can be made to serve 1.8 million dunums more of government land. This land can be divided into small holdings and cultivated under the intensive system. The estimated total cost of improving the canal is 25 million dinars. Ten million have been allocated for it during the 1956-60 program. As a first step the Board has already approved the ex- pansion of the Hilla Canal from its head down to its first branch, the Babil Canal, together with the expansion of the Babil Canal itself, to provide water for 400,000 dunums of government land. Aside from enlargement, the work also includes earth embankments, one cross regulator on the Hilla Canal, two cross and one inlet regulator on the Babil Canal. 72 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 2. The Greater Musayyib Project. Work on this project began in 1953 and was completed in the fall of 1956. It brought under irrigation 250,000 dunums of new land, the distribution of which began in November 1956 (and brought reassured supplies of water to 85,000 dunums which were already under irrigation and privately owned). The work consisted of two parts. First, enlarging, re- modeling, and extending the old canal. It is now 50 kilo- meters long, has twelve lateral canals, and a 500-kilometer network of small canals. Second, providing full drainage facilities to the areas to be irrigated. In addition to excava- tion, the work also involved installing cross, main, and small regulators, pumping stations, etc. 3. Euphrates Tail Regulators. In the rice-growing area just above Lake Hammar in the south, constant erosion has made the bed of the Euphrates there so low in relation to the silted land that water distribu- tion in the dry season has become almost impossible. To control erosive action, and to raise the water level in the river when needed, work on the installation of five regulators on the tails of the Euphrates before Lake Hammar, began in 1954 and is due to be completed in the early part of 1957. Expenditures on this project amounted to some 700,000 dinars. 4. The Shamiyah Canal Project. The Shamiyah is actually a branch of the Euphrates which has been canalized. It needs extensive improvements, including remodeling and expansion. This, however, is still under study. In the meantime, erosive action, a phe- nomenon known in Iraq as naggarat, lowers the bed of the canal and its subsidiaries in the dry season, making the distribution of water in this rice land very difficult. As partial measures, a main regulator was installed at the tail of the canal (250,000 dinars), and the Directorate of Irrigation on behalf of the Board is at present installing eleven small regulators (total cost 37,000 dinars) on both sides of Mish- Khab, in addition to constructing bunds, a cross regulator, a side regulator, and a navigation lock (total cost 33,000 dinars). WATER RESOURCES 73 The Tigris 1. The Gharraf Canal Project. The Gharraf is the main canal system on the Tigris. It is commanded by the Kut barrage built in 1939. With its two branches, the Shatrah and the Bad'a, the Gharraf serves an area roughly estimated at about 2.3 million dunums. Studies show that with remodeling, enlargement, and ex- tension, water supplies to existing areas can be improved and 600,000 dunums of new government land can be brought under irrigation. The consulting engineers, KTAM, rec- ommended the construction of the following works: a. Drainage: The Western and Eastern outfalls, also the Dujailah outfall. b. Four regulators on the Gharraf with bunds and lateral gates. c. Seven regulators on the Badºa canal. d. A new canal extension to irrigate new government land in the Jazirat area. Some eight million dinars have been allocated for this project. Construction of the regulators is scheduled for com- pletion in 1958, and construction of the new canal is expected to begin in 1957 with the hope that by 1960 some 10 per cent of the new land will be served with water. The Lesser Zab and Udhaim Basin The construction of the two dams on the Lesser Zab and the Udhaim to utilize the waters of the Dokan dam will necessitate the enlargement of one canal, and the construction of one feeder canal to irrigate some 1.3 million dunums of land. The areas that will benefit are as follows: Makhmur 162,000 dunums Hawija 253,000 “ Udhaim right bank 214,000 “ Udhaim left bank (Ghurfa) 663,000 “ 1,291,000 The Hawija canal is at present being enlarged. Con- struction of canals and related works was scheduled to begin 74 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ in 1957 and to be completed in 1958. Construction of other structures and canals was also to begin in 1957. It is expected that 15 per cent of the area will be served by 1960. Other Projects 1. Reclamation of Nahrawan Lands These lands are located on the eastern bank of the Tigris south of the Diyala river. They constitute about 1.2 million dunums. Study of their reclamation is under way and con- struction of canals and related works is scheduled to begin in 1958. Very little land, if any, however, will be ready to be served with water by 1960 when the present program terminates. 2. The Ishaqi Area Irrigation of the Ishaqi area on the Tigris south of the Tharthar barrage is now under study. Construction of canals and drainage is expected to begin in 1958 and it is hoped that about 15 per cent of the area will be served with water by 1960. 3. Basrah Lands Improvement of irrigation, flood control on the Shatt al-Arab and Lake Hammar, and land reclamation in the Basrah area have been under study for some time. Four million dinars have been allocated to this project between 1955-60 and construction is expected to begin in 1957. 4. Northern Districts Project Studies of small irrigation projects in Mosul, Arbil, and Kirkuk and Sulaimaniya livas for relocation of persons displaced by the Dokan and Darband-i-Khan reservoirs are now under way. Construction in each case will commence when plans are ready. Eleven million dinars have been allocated for these and other irrigation projects in the north. 5. Diyala Basin Project The Diyala barrage built in 1939 commands six canals which irrigate an area of some 1.3 million dunums. Water from the Darband-i-Khan Dam is expected to irrigate 1.5 million more dunums of new land. Studies are now under way to enlarge and remodel some of the existing canals and build new ones to irrigate the new land to be brought under WATER RESOURCES 75 cultivation. Five million dinars have been allocated for the Diyala lands project. Drainage Salination of the soil is a deadly enemy of the Iraqi fallah. The Haigh Commission estimated that 60 per cent of the flow-irrigated area has been affected and 20 to 30 per cent abandoned in the past three decades because it became either not profitable or impossible to cultivate it. Crop yield, it was also estimated, declined by 20 to 50 per cent. The high concentration of salt in the soil, especially in the flow-irrigated areas, is due primarily to continuous irrigation and flooding combined with the high rate of evaporation that obtains in these climatic conditions. Irriga- tion keeps the sub-soil water table high, just below the ground surface, exposed to the hot summer sun. When evaporation takes place, it leaves salt deposits in the plant root zone. As the years go by, the salt accumulation be- comes toxic in quantity, gradually causes a decline in crop yield, and finally makes further cultivation impossible. Fortunately, the chemical composition of the salt in most of Iraq is such that it can be “washed out” of the land by drainage. With deep drains, the sub-soil water table is lowered; accumulated salts are flushed and further accumula- tion prevented. Moreover, in this manner, as the KTAM Report states, “The root zone of the plant will be deepened, more minerals that are available in the soil will become avail- able to the plants, stagnant waters will be removed, the growing season will be lengthened... crop rotation. . . will become possible; in general, the health and yields of crops will be greatly improved.” Hardly any measures were taken to combat salination during the past thirty years. Even new settlement projects such as Dujailah (1945), in which the government invested considerable amounts of money, were not provided with drainage facilities, so that after ten years of cultivation salt began to appear and the land began to deteriorate. The “drainage movement” began in earnest when the Development Board was organized. Since its creation, the 76 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Board has become more and more drainage-conscious. In its first program, the total allocation for drainage amounted to 4.1 million dinars. In its second program, it rose to 13.9 million, and in the last program, the allocation jumped to 28.3 million dinars. Drainage of cultivated areas is now taking place on a fairly large scale. Excavation of new canals and reclamation of new land go hand in hand with in- stallation of drainage facilities. In the following few pages, the main drainage schemes that have been completed or are under construction or study will be discussed. The drainage program consists of three main parts. First is the excavation of drainage outfalls. These are very large channels. Because of the vast areas they serve, they will be almost small rivers when completed. To protect them from silt- and sand-laden winds, especially in undeveloped areas, windbreaks consisting of trees and other vegetation are also planned as part of the program. Secondly, deep main drains and their subsidiaries are being excavated. These are de- signed to lower the underground water table. They will empty into rivers and natural depressions or into outfalls. Finally, some of the drains will flow by gravity. In the case of a large number, pumping will be required. The KTAM Report mentioned previously estimated the total cost of a full drainage program at 79 million dinars ($221 million), divided as follows: a) 7 drainage outfalls — 26,700,000 dinars b) main drains 21 in Euphrates Basin— 19,648,000 “ 12 in Tigris Basin — 32,508,000 “ 78,856,000 “ Some 30 million dinars have been allocated for the period up to 1960. Assuming this sum is fully spent, then at the termination of the present program in 1960, only 38 per cent of the drainage work needed will have been completed. 1. The Musayyib Project Drains. This is the first project to be fully completed providing drainage for some 335,000 WATER RESOURCES 77 dunums of land. Work on excavating both the Musayyib- Babil outfall and the main drains began in 1954 and was brought to completion in the closing days of 1956. TABLE 15 DEvelopMENT BoARD ALLOCATIONS FOR DRAINAGE (in 1,000 Iraqi Dinars) Actually spent up to March 31, 1956 56 57 58 59 60 Total Left Bank of Euphrates & Hilla Canal including Rumeitha 825 1,100 1,000 650 500 750 4,825 Right Bank of Euphrates & Hilla Canal 245 300 700 1,350 1,300 1,350 5,245 Land on the Gharraf Canal Project 200 500 1,600 4,000 5,700 12,000 Diyala Land Project 180 200 500 1,000 1,700 1,600 5,180 Others 450 500 300 400 500 600 2,750 Total 1,700 2,300 3,000 4,980 8,000 10,000 30,100 Source: Law No. 54 (1956), p. 19. 2. The Dujailah Project. As a pilot project, 25,000 dunums of the Dujailah settlement were provided with drainage facilities. Work began in 1954 and was completed the follow- ing year. Work on drainage for the whole area continues. The excavation of the Dujailah outfall was scheduled to start in 1956 with the expectation that the greater part of it will be completed by 1960. 3. The Saqlawiyah Drain. Through this project some 166,000 dunums of land on the Saqlawiyah and Abu Ghraib canals will be provided with drainage facilities. Work began in 1954 and is due to be completed in 1957. 78 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 4. The Tuwairij Drain. Work on providing drainage for some 31,000 dunums in the Hindiyah area began in 1954, and will be completed in 1957. 5. The Ba‘quba Drain. This provides drainage for 11,800 dunums of land on the Khoraisan canal on the Diyala river. The work has now been completed. 6. The Hawija Settlement. Work on providing drainage for the Hawija settlement on the Lesser Zab began in 1955 and still continues. 7. The Shamiya Drain. Work on the eastern drain of the Shamiya canal area began in 1954 and still continues. 8. Construction of Outfalls. Construction of the Euphrates- Tigris outfall began in 1950. Only a small part of it however will be completed by 1960. Work on the Shamiya and Gharraf outfalls was scheduled to begin in 1956. 9. Scheduled Projects. Work will begin soon in earnest to provide drainage to the areas served by the following canals: left and right banks of the Euphrates and Hilla canal; the Gharraf, Abu Ghraib, Yusafiyah, Bani Hasan, and Husseini- yah. All these, with the exception of the Gharraf, are on the Euphrates. Conclusion Iraq is well under way in its agricultural development program. Within the short span of six years, it has forged ahead of every country in the Middle East. By 1960, most if not all the water reservoirs and flood-control structures will have been built. The effort will then shift almost ex- clusively to the improvement of the irrigation system, drain- age and land reclamation. The total cost of the agricultural development program was estimated by the Minister of Development in 1955 at 282 million dinars. By 1960, if the program keeps on schedule, some 180 million will have been invested. This means that over 60 per cent of the program will have been completed. About a million and a half dunums of new land will also have been reclaimed and developed by then. Tangible effects of the agricultural development program have just begun to be felt. The floods of 1956 were completely WATER RESOURCES 79 averted; crop yields are beginning to improve in both quality and quantity; landless peasants are being settled on new lands in increasing numbers and lands which remained desert wastes for centuries are beginning to bloom again. Agricultural development in Iraq is of significance not only for the country itself, but also for the Middle East. Iraq can become the main supplier of agricultural products, particularly of cereals, to the area. This would be far less costly to the Middle East than importing these commodities from distant areas such as Canada and Australia. In times of war, the Middle East would not have to suffer food shortages be- cause of lack of transportation facilities on the high seas. Dur- ing World War II, such shortages did occur and it was neces- sary for the British and American Governments, which con- trolled the shipping in the area, to organize the Middle East Supply Center to control distribution of basic commodities. Moreover, this new development would encourage intra- regional trade, the lack of which has been one of the chief economic problems of the area during the past three decades. 1. Iraq Government, Directorate General of Irrigation, Report on the Control of the Rivers of Iraq and the Utilization of Their Waters. Submitted by the Irriga- tion Development Commission, F. F. Haigh, president. (Baghdad: The Baghdad Press, 1951.) Hereafter referred to as Haigh Report. 2. Knappen-Tippetts-Abbett-McCarthy, Engineers, Report on the Development of the Tigris and Euphrates River Systems. A report submitted to the Iraq De- velopment Board, (mimeographed) (New York: 1952.) Hereafter referred to as KTAM Report. 3. IBRD, p. 186. CHAPTER 5 THE PROBLEM OF LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM Forms of Land Tenure For all practical purposes, a class of independent farmers who own the lands they farm does not exist in Iraq. The land is owned, largely, under various forms of land tenure by a very small group of tribal shaikhs, aghas, and city landlords. The great majority of the farming population is composed of what would be called in the United States sharecroppers. Since over 70 per cent of the population is employed in agri- culture or allied industries, land tenure is the human prob- lem par excellence in Iraq. In one way or another, it lies be- hind most, if not all, of the social, economic, and political problems of the country. In theory, the state has ultimate ownership of almost all lands and the underground water and mineral resources pertaining to them. Within this framework, four main forms of tenure are recognized: 1. Mulk. Land held in absolute private ownership. In most cases, this is restricted to urban property. 2. Matruka (literally, “What is left”). Land reserved for public purposes. In actual practice this is treated as state land. LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 81 3. Waqf. Property or land in trust. There are two types of waqf. (a) True waqf. Property or land administered for the benefit of religious institutions by the government Awqaf Administration, or for the benefit of private persons by individuals appointed by religious COUrtS. (b) “Untrue” waqf. Property or land from which taxes or revenues were assigned in the past to religious institutions. 4. Miri land. State land, of which there are three kinds: (a) Miri Tapu. Land held in permanent tenure from the state amounting to absolute private owner- ship. Documentary proof of registration is required for such tenure. Otherwise, factual evidence that the land has been productively used by the holder or his predecessors for at least ten years during which no rent was paid, or that it was planted with trees. Tapu land can be mortgaged, sold, or in- herited. (b) Miri Lazma. Land held under the same general conditions as tapu lands. The holder must prove that he has made productive use of the land during the preceding fifteen years. In contrast to tapu, however, the government may veto the transfer of lazma. (c) Miri Sirf. Land which definitely and exclusively belongs to the state. Although tapu and lazma lands are still officially regarded as state or miri lands, in actual practice they can hardly be distinguished from full private ownership. Tapu land, as mentioned above, may be mortgaged, sold, or inherit- ed. The same applies to lazma with certain reservations which are now very seldom employed. Legally, ownership of both lazma and tapu lands may lapse if they are not pro- ductively used for three and four successive years respectively but this rarely, if ever, happens. Before 1939, holders of both lazma and tapu lands were assessed an annual payment for 82 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ “rent” and water rights, which was a little higher for lazma than for tapu. In that year these assessments were abolished. With this furtherance, very little distinction remained be- tween tapu and lazma lands and between tapu and lazma and full ownership. History of Land Tenure The land tenure system is the result of historical forces, legal concepts, and tribal traditions which go back to ancient times. When the Arabs first occupied Iraq (641 A.D.), land was classified into two kinds: kharaj (tax-land) and ‘ushr (tithe-land). During the Abbassid Caliphate (750–1257) these two were expanded into five classifications: the King’s lands, feudal lands, mulk (private property), masha'a (common land) and wafq (religious trust land). The period between 1258, when the Mongol hordes in- vaded Iraq, and 1534, when the Ottomans established their rule, was one of general retrogression. The great irrigation canals were destroyed, the blooming gardens and green fields gradually became wasteland, the desert encroached on the farmland, the population decreased rapidly, and no- madism spread. Internecine tribal warfare became the order of the day. Only in the twentieth century did Iraq begin to recover from the havoc and devastation wrought by the Mongols and subsequent war lords. : From this period until the nineteenth century laws were loosely enforced. Both individuals and tribes, in most cases, claimed title to the land by the simple expedient of occupying it without making any special effort to seek or obtain legal sanction. Tribal land was regarded as the common property of the tribe. As the tribes changed their nomadic mode of existence and began a settled life, their shaikhs, being powerful, were able to assert their claim to tribal land as their personal property. Their free warrior tribesmen gradually became their subservient sharecroppers. In addition, large land grants were made by the state to tribal chieftains either to bribe them into good behavior or to reward them for ser- vices rendered. LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 83 In 1858 the Ottoman government attempted to bring some order into the chaos. Through the Land Code which it promulgated in that year and the Land Registration Law of the year after, it sought to establish one system of tenure, the tapu. The attempt was not only a failure but also added to the general confusion. For one thing, because of the existing system of shifting agriculture, it was difficult in many cases to determine what land belonged to whom. Grants were made in most cases without examination of conflicting claims and were used as a means of rewarding some and punishing others. Influential notables and tribal chiefs with the help of corrupt officials were also able to register huge tracts of lands in their names. In the northern districts whole villages and their lands were registered as the personal property of local notables and aghas. These had previously served as intermediaries between the state and the cultivators, collecting taxes and performing other functions. Land-grabbing by the powerful few was assisted to some extent by the cultivators themselves. Many of them were apprehensive that registration might mean more taxes and/or military service (not a farfetched assumption). Moreover, they were powerless against the periodic raids of nomadic tribes, or against the ubiquitous money-lender. With prom- ise of protection against all these dangers, many of them were willing to register their lands in the names of neighbor- ing influential notables and tribal chieftains. Later, as was to be expected, these latter claimed the lands as their own and the original owners became their tenants. During the British mandate (1920-32) the Ottoman Land Code continued to operate. The administration’s policy tended to use the land for political purposes, to win supporters and punish troublemakers. By special decrees some large holdings were given to shaikhs, some land sold and the owner- ship of some transferred to others. A new complication appeared during this period with the introduction of fuel-pump irrigation. Many financially able city merchants entered into agreements with holders of miri land whereby they supplied the pumps and in return 84 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ received a specified share of the crop. This added one more claim to the many unresolved existing claims. By the time the national government assumed full power, the land problem had become extremely serious. When the Turks left the country, they either took with them or destroyed all the land registry records so that there was very little documentary proof of ownership left. Almost invariably, ownership was contested among various parties, which many times led to tribal warfare. Very few, if any, felt legally secure in their claims to the land which they held. In his report to the government on the subject, Sir Ernest Dawson, a British land expert, wrote: No man engaged in the management and cultivation of a landholding, large or small, can be expected to sink his capital in the land and devote his energies unreservedly to its develop- ment, if he is uncertain whether he and his heirs will benefit by his husbandry. ... The injurious effect of the existing welter of uncertainty and dispute upon both the agricultural prosperity of the country and public order, can hardly be exaggerated. . . . Indeed the most diligent enquiry would be unlikely to reveal anywhere any appreciable number of holdings, large or small, held in undisputed possession and free from hampering and conflicting claims. It needs no great effort of the imagination to appreciate the blighting effect of these unhappy conditions prevailing throughout the country, upon the prosperity of the main na- tional industry and the welfare and contentment of the people as a whole.” In line with the recommendations of Sir Ernest Dawson, the government took concrete steps. In 1932 it passed the Land Settlement Law (replaced in 1938), which recognized the four forms of tenure discussed at the beginning of this chapter and inaugurated a cadastral survey to be conducted by settlement committees. The task of these committees was to survey the whole country, to investigate conflicting claims and to adjudicate ownership under the forms of tenure recognized by the law. The survey has been going on since 1933 and is at present almost complete in most of the prov- InCCS. 86 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ fied, only 15.7 per cent belongs to small peasant proprietors. Over 67 per cent is owned in holdings of over 1,000 dunums. These are national averages and do not reflect the full pic- ture. For instance, of the private land classified in six prov- inces, up to 1951, holdings of 10,000-100,000 dunums ac- counted for the following percentages: Amara, 75.8; Kut, 47.5; Karbala, 31.3; Mosul, 27.2; Baghdad, 20.9; Diwaniya, 20.6. TABLE 16 TYPE of LAND Ownership CLASSIFIED BY THE CADASTRAL SURVEY 1933-1956 In Thousand Dunums Per Cent Mulk 239 0.3 Matruka 5,136 6.5 Waqf 840 1.1 Tapu 12,348 15.6 Lazma 11,649 14.8 Miri Siri wºol * 61.7 Total 78,913 100.0 Source: Statistical Abstract for 1956, p. 70. It is true that some of these holdings are owned by more than one person. This is more than counterbalanced by the fact that many persons own a number of holdings in several administrative areas. These have been registered as separate units. For instance, the survey lists only one holding over 100,000 dunums in the Kut province. It is a well-known fact, however, that there are several holdings there, each of which is over 300,000 dunums. These figures illustrate the central point, namely, that the country to all practical pur- poses is devoid of small peasant proprietors and that the land is mostly owned by large landholders, most of whom are tribal shaikhs and city notables. Data available since 1951 support the above picture. Table 17 shows the number of LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 87 lazma grants in holdings of over 10,000 dunums and their total areas, made between 1933 and 1954 in nine of the pro- vinces. Sixty-six of these holdings are owned by single in- dividuals. It should be noted that several of these holdings may be owned by one person. Condition of the Fallah As has been shown, the greater part of the private agri- cultural holdings are owned by a very small landed aristoc- racy. Conversely, the large majority of the fallaheen are tenant sharecroppers. Until recent years, the lot of the fallah in Iraq has been a very sad one. His income barely served to keep body and soul together. In 1948, Doreen Warriner reported the follow- ing distribution of the crop as being typical in southern Iraq: Per Cent of Crop Government 10.0 Landowner (shaikh or notable) 40.0 First tenant (shaikh) 7.5 Shaikh’s bailiff 2.5 Fallah (sharecropper who works the land) 40.0 Total 100.0 In 1945 an Iraqi writer estimated the income of the fallah including his family of five or six dependents to be, in prewar prices, ten to twelve dinars in the south and fifteen to twenty dinars in the north.3 In the same year, Alfred Bonné estimated income on the same basis as six to ten dinars in the northern provinces and in the order of nine to fifteen dinars in the south.4 In 1951, the Bank Mission after noting that “conditions [were] extremely varied and information virtually non- existent,” suggested that “a hypothetical example of the condition of a fallah in the irrigation zone, where barley is the principal crop, may serve as a rough guide.” It calculated his share of the crop (two-fifths) as three tons which he could 88 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ sell at the prevailing 1951 local prices of ten dinars a ton. His share of the summer crops was estimated at about ten dinars." TABLE 17 LAzMA GRANTS IN Holdings of Over 10,000 DUNUMS 1933-54 JNo. of Lazma Grants Total Area of Lazma Grants Liwa Over 10,000 dunums Over 10,000 dunums Kut 37 755,964 Mosul 28 521,252 Diwaniya 14 240,244 Hilla 6 143,930 Amara 3 86,483 Baghdad 2 38,627 Diyala 2 37,275 Erbil 2 21,331 Kirkuk 1 15,442 Total 95 1,860,578 Source: Agricultural Reform and Land Development, op. cit., pp. 146–50. Now let us add up the gross income in 1951 of this “hy- pothetical” fallah with five or six dependents in the irrigation zone. His income from winter and summer crops is forty dinars. If we add a maximum of thirty dinars to cover casual work during the off season, home consumption, and in- come from other sources, then his total annual income would be at maximum, about seventy dinars a year. If we divide this by five, the number in the family, this would bring the income per head of a fallah’s family to a maximum of fourteen dinars a year. Until recently, the government provided the fallaheen with extremely limited economic or social services. Negatively, the legal and social system reduced them into a state of virtual servitude. The law “Governing the Rights and Duties of Cultivators,” enacted in 1933 and still operative though apparently in- effective, prescribes in one of its debt clauses that when a sharecropper is dismissed or moves from a plantation, he must pay his agricultural debt to the landlord immediately, LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 89 and that pending such payment, unless he receives a certifi- cate of release from the landlord, he is prohibited employ- ment on any other plantation, in any government office, or in any private business establishment of any kind including domestic service in private homes. Since the fallah is per- petually in debt to his landlord or to the money-lender, the law, at least theoretically, makes him and his children virtually serfs attached to the land. Aside from the human problem involved, the economic effects of the depressed condition of the fallah and the pres- ent sharecropping system are obvious. The fallah has no incentive to improve the land beyond the year in which he is cultivating it. He has no assurance that the same plot will be leased to him the following year, or for that matter, that he will be given a lease at all. If he manages to save some money beyond his needs and the needs of his family, he may buy a cow, a donkey, or a mule, but he is hardly likely to invest in the land. Nor is he interested in improving his methods of production such as terracing, crop rotation, drainage, etc., for all these relate to “results” after the year’s harvest. As for the landlords, some of them have proved surprisingly progressive and have introduced many improvements to their benefit and the benefit of their tenants. The large ma- jority of them, however, have had little interest in the land beyond receiving huge incomes from it and spending them in the city. In the case of some, there is hardly any link be- tween them and the land. Many huge estates belong to a family or a number of families, with each member usually living in the city, receiving his pro rata share of the estate’s revenue. Neither the sharecropping system nor large land-holdings as such are necessarily bad. Both of them, with an enlightened approach on the part of the owners, can be of benefit to all the individuals concerned and to the country as a whole. The topography of Iraq is ideally suited to large-scale agri- culture. There are holdings of comparable size, or even larger, in progressive countries such as the United States, Canada, and Australia. It is the anachronistic economic and LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 91 per cent of the land in Iraq still belongs to the state. This is a vast reserve upon which the government can draw to resettle all the landless peasants, without in the meantime disturbing the status quo. In the long run, resettlement of a large number of fallaheen would reduce the power and the hold of big landowners. Then too, the big landowners are the most politically powerful social unit in the country. Any reform legislation that might infringe on their privileged status or interests can be blocked. Lord Salter, in his report to the Develop- ment Board, expressed the problem very graphically when he wrote: “It may be that some among the great landowners will accept or welcome some changes on the principle of ‘reform that you may preserve.’ In the meantime, however, successive Governments have usually felt that new legislation on land tenancy must be kept within the bounds of what will not be actively resisted by landowners.”6 Although the government is making some progress in its resettlement program, as shall be pointed out later, its ap- proach to the problem of land reform has its dangers. Re- settlement, by its nature, is slow of results. Land has to be reclaimed and developed, irrigation and drainage works have to be installed and so forth. In the meantime, the time element has become very important. As in all Arab areas, there is considerable social discontent in Iraq which may express itself as violently as has been the case in neighbor- ing countries. Although the masses have little power in legislative halls, they command, as Salter correctly stated, “an ultimate power which is altogether out of proportion to their present representation in Parliament and their ability to influence legislation by constitutional means.” The Land Settlement Law In Law No.23 (1945), entitled “The Dujailah Land Develop- ment Law,” the first planned scheme of resettlement was initiated. In 1951 it was replaced by Law No. 43 (1951), entitled “The Land Development and Settlement Law.” This was further supplemented by Ordinance No. 52 (1952) and amended by Ordinance No. 4 (1952). LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 93 c. Graduates of agricultural schools, retired army and police officers; and servicemen and policemen who have been in active service not less than four years, shall be allowed not more than a total of 20 per cent of any one settlement project, provided the authorities are satisfied with the individual’s agricultural abilities. d. Government employees who served not less than eight years or are retired; persons with not less than elementary education; and graduates of recognized religious institutions, who are unemployed, shall be allowed a total of not more than 25 per cent of any one settlement project, provided the authorities concerned are satisfied with the individual’s agricultural abilities and with his sincere intent to work the land. 5. Benefits. a. The land is to be given free. b. The settler receives full tapu title to his plot after ten years of continued occupation and development. c. Upon the death of the settler before the ex- piration of the ten-year period, his rights and obligations are inherited in common by his successors. If death occurs after the ten-year period, the land may be divided among the successors provided that each share is not less than one- fourth of the area of the plot. Otherwise, the plot must re- main in common ownership. d. Upon allocation of the plot to him, the settler may borrow, on a supervised basis, from the appropriate government authorities up to 100 dinars at 3 per cent in- terest to be paid back in yearly installments over a period of five years. In the event of flood or crop failure, payment may be deferred for one year. 6. Obligations. a. During the ten-year period, the settler may not alienate, rent, or allow anyone else the right to cultivate part or all of his plot, nor may he enter into any contractual arrangements whatsoever concerning the plot or the crop 94 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ without the knowledge and approval of government author- ities. b. For ten years after receiving full title, the farmer may not alienate his land in any way, or mortgage it except to the State Agricultural Bank. c. During the ten-year period, the settler must follow the instructions of the authorities regarding the meth- ods of production, the types and quantities of crops to be planted, and the size of the areas to be planted of each kind. d. The settler undertakes to follow the cooperative system in the sale of his crops and in his consumption, and to belong to and abide by the regulations of the cooperative society established in his settlement for this purpose. (This provision is part of the contract and not the law.) e. The settler must build a house according to the plans and specifications of government authorities. Government authorities will plan the whole settlement including houses and public buildings. f. The settler must plant an orchard on a plot of land specified by the authorities. The trees must be issued by the authorities, and planted under their supervision and the guidance of the officer concerned. (The latter part of this provision is an administrative regulation.) g. The settler undertakes to devote all his time and the time of men in his family to the land (part of the contract). Nor may he leave his land for more than five days without the knowledge of the government officer in charge (administrative regulation). 7. Water Distribution. a. Distribution of water shall be restricted to lands of the settlement project at no cost to the settlers. However, it may also be distributed to tapu, lazma, and mulk lands by a decision of the Council of Ministers, provided the owner of such lands either (1) transfers to the govern- ment, in one bloc to be selected by the authorities, the owner- ship of one-fourth of the land to be irrigated, or (2) pays the state treasury his pro rata share of the moneys spent by LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 95 the government on the construction of irrigation works from which he desires his land to benefit. b. In pump-irrigation projects, the settler shall pay over a number of years his pro rata share of the money the government spent on the installation of pumps and other related works. He shall also pay his share of the annual costs of maintaining and operating these pumps. 8. Administration. When the law was first enacted in 1945, a special Miri Sirf Department managed by a Central Committee was created to administer the law. It was first attached to the Ministry of Economics, then transferred to the Ministry of Agriculture when the latter was established. In 1954 it was transferred to the Ministry of Development as a technical section. The Committee, apart from its administrative and ex- ecutive staff, is composed of an irrigation engineer, an agricultural specialist, a doctor, and an agricultural econo- mist. These are assisted by experts in various fields from Iraq, U. S. Point Four, and the various United Nations Agencies. Among foreigners, however, particular mention should be made of Point Four specialists, of whom there were ten attached to the Committee in 1956. Criticisms Several criticisms have been made of the law and its operations. A government committee which was recently organized to study the questions of land distribution and water rights made the following recommendations: 1. The settlers should pay for the land they receive over a long period of time. It was argued that it is morally wrong to give away the land and that the settlers would be more appreciative of its value if they paid for it. 2. The costs of irrigation works, drainage, and other related structures are very great. New settlers and others who benefit should at least pay part, if not all, of the cost. The settler’s share can be incorporated in the cost of the land and paid in a similar manner over a long number of years. 96. THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 3. Ownership of ground and surface waters should re- main vested in the state but water rights should be pred- icated on continued usage. Non-settlers may use any excess water supply under a special agreement with the govern- ment, provided the latter reserves its right to the use of this oversupply in its future projects when they are established. 4. Another question, which was not touched upon by the committee, is the provision of the law which allows up to 45 per cent of settlement projects to go to army personnel, civil servants, and school graduates. This provision has been severely criticized from various quarters. First, it cuts down the amount of land available to the fallaheen, whom the law is supposed to help. Secondly, with the Arab social back- ground in mind, it is doubtful that army officers, civil ser- vants, and school graduates would be sincerely interested in tilling the soil themselves. They are more likely to hire others to do the work for them. This would frustrate the whole intent of the law. Distribution of State Land According to official sources, between 1945, when the first law was enacted, and 1955, over 2.7 million dunums (1.7 million acres) of state land were distributed (see Table 18). Of this, about half a million were developed in settlements under close government supervision and planning. Most of the rest was distributed without reclamation or assisted development. Some of the settlements that have been es- tablished are discussed below. The Dujailah Settlement Dujailah, established in 1945, was the first and is still the largest government experiment in planned and supervised settlement of peasants. It has proven itself conspicuously successful. The income of the farmers has risen to three and four times its former level. When the scheme was first inaugurated it met with strong opposition from the shaikhs, and the government had con- siderable difficulty in inducing the fallaheen to accept land grants. Since then the idea has caught on like wildfire 1 RAQ stateuana-ti-ation - distribution Program H Projects Completed Projects to be completed soon E. Projects to be completed by 1960 98 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ TABLE 18 DISTRIBUTION OF MIRI SIRF LAND Number of Persons on Settlement; Number of Holdings; Total Area of Holdings in Dunums up to the End of 1955 JNo. of JNo. of Total Area of Settlement Persons Holdings Holdings Dujailah 14,320 2,864 373,990s Shahrzoor 2,545 509 33,830 Hawija 1,595 319 23,300 Latifiya 2,325 765 23,250 Musayyib 875 175 10,500 Makhmur 930 186 17,700 Sub-total 22,590 4,818 482,570 Karma 3,590 718 70,671 Saddah 325 65 5,200 Sanjar 39,350 7,870 1,568,750 Lands in other areas 14,680 2,936 169,870 Sub-total 57,945 11,589 1,814,491 Total 80,535 16,407 2,297,061 Land Distributed but Unidentified Il.a. Il-3. 424,210 Grand Total 2,721,271b Source: Agricultural Reform and Land Development, op. cit., pp. 7, 141. See, however, conflicting date in Statistical Abstract for 1956, p. 98; also Salter, op. cit., p. 204. *This figure seems suspect. Up to the end of 1953 only 131,700 dunums had been distributed. Other data indicate that land distributed and actually irri- gated in the project amounts to 165,650 dunums. The explanation may be that the 373,990 figure shows the land actually distributed, not all of which however is yet settled or under cultivation. Also the number of holdings seems suspect (i.e., 2,864). Other data indicate that they numbered 1,523 in 1955. *This total seems suspect. The Minister of Development stated that up to March 1956, 2,416,254 dunums had been distributed. (Iraq Times, March 29, 1956). and the authorities are unable to keep up with the thousands of requests they receive. By 1955, the Dujailah settlement had grown into a prosperous community of 2,820 families com- prising 14,320 persons. 100 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ on the farms and distant from each other. This proved to be a mistake. First, with the lack of good transportation facilities, it made movement within the settlement difficult. It also made the provision of drinking water and other facilities and services both expensive and cumbersome. Furthermore, it does not fit the traditional pattern of gregarious Arab village life, in which housing is concentrated in one village area from which agricultural land radiates outwards in widening seg- ImentS. Health services include two clinics, a mobile clinic, and a doctor who makes regular weekly visits from the nearby town of Kut. A bilharzia center was also established to com- bat that disease in the settlement. In 1955 the various clinics treated 16,514 outpatient cases. Primary education facilities, though not adequate, are larger in number and far superior to other farming areas. By 1954-55 six schools for boys were operating, with 605 students and seventeen teachers, and one school for girls with forty-eight students and three teachers. One of the boys’ schools and the girls’ school were established and are run by UNESCO under its program for “Fundamental Education.” UNESCO’s program of fundamental education in Iraq is centered in the Dujailah settlement. It is composed of a health center and the two schools mentioned above. The health center, in addition to treating patients, serves as a demonstration unit to teach peasant women sewing, weaving, child care, sterilization of drinking water, habits of cleanliness, etC. In the two UNESCO schools, advanced educational techniques and concepts are used. The emphasis is more on creating human beings fitted to live in their environment than on classroom work where students are taught by rote subjects that have little relation to their daily life. In the boys’ school, students’ time is divided between classroom work and practical application. They plant vege- table gardens, crops of wheat and barley, and raise chickens. They have built their own football and basketball fields. In 1954-55 they established a cooperative shop. In the girls’ school the same advanced methods are em- LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM IOI ployed. Girls are taught not only the “three R's,” but also sewing, ironing, needlework, cooking, hygiene, and sports, in addition to practical training in agriculture. Several modern light industries were established by the government on the project. They consist of a small spinning and weaving plant, a carpentry shop, a machine shop, and two brick kilns. There are several objectives in establishing these industries: to absorb concealed unemployment; to train farmers and their children in complementary industries; to provide them with supplementary income and to supply them with essential, cheap, locally-produced articles and services. Settlement farmers are also employed in the con- struction of houses and public buildings, repair shops, and in the construction of irrigation and drainage works in the project. From the preceding description, it can be seen that the government has spent considerable time, effort, and money to insure the beginning of a good life to the settlers and the scheme has been, without question, very successful. An index of the scheme is that in Iraq it is said, “You can tell a Dujailah man from the way he walks.” And yet, several serious mistakes were made. First and perhaps the most serious, no drainage facilities were in- stalled, so that within a relatively short time the land began to deteriorate on account of salt accumulation. The authori- ties are now installing the necessary drainage facilities at considerably higher cost than if they had been installed when irrigation works were excavated. Secondly, locating the houses at such distances from each other in a sparsely populated area created many hardships. Encouraged by the success and popularity of the Dujailah scheme and armed with the practical experience gained from it, the government has since established several other settlements. However, Dujailah still remains “the pet” of the authorities. - The Latifiya Settlement Some of the experience gained in the Dujailah project was applied in the Latifiya settlement, which was established LAND TENURE AND AGRARIAN REFORM 103 The Greater Musayyib Settlement This is the greatest reclamation and land settlement proj- ect of its kind in the Middle East. It combines both irriga- tion and drainage. The project will certainly revolutionize agricultural concepts in Iraq since, for the first time, in- tensive cultivation has been introduced into a large area of land. The settlement is located on the Greater Musayyib Canal (see Chapter IV), and covers 335,000 dunums of land, of which 250,000 dunums are reclaimed state land and 85,000 dunums are privately owned and presently cultivated. Construction of irrigation and drainage works for the whole area was completed in 1956 after four years of intensive work. Official sources estimate that 15,000 persons will be settled directly on the project in addition to some 35,000 persons who will indirectly benefit from it. Two modern towns are planned on the settlement, one to be located about thirty- three kilometers east of the town of Musayyib, and another at the end of the project area some fifty kilometers east of Musayyib. In addition, fifty villages will be built on the settlement, with fifty to ninety families each. The land will be distributed in plots of sixty-seven dunums, of which fifty dunums are to be devoted to winter and summer crops, five for an orchard and twelve for a pasture, a house plot, roads, irrigation, and drainage canals. Actual distribution of land was officially begun on Novem- ber 17, 18, 19, and 24, 1956, in the Biblical town of Cutha. Press dispatches tell an interesting and human story. It is reported that thousands of landless peasants poured into the town to attend the four-day lottery. They came on foot, on horseback, on donkeys, in truck loads, and in hired taxis. They watched as the names of the winners were drawn by government officials from a cardboard box containing the names of approved applicants (some 30,000 had applied for 2,000 plots). As the public drawing came to an end, 431 landless peasants were selected to settle on sixty-six dunum plots comprising the land that was then ready. 104 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Other Projects There are several other settlement projects, both super- vised and unsupervised (see Table 18). They include Hawija, Makhmur, and Shahrzoor. These are supervised in a similar fashion as the ones discussed. Others include the vast Sanjar area, lands in the provinces of Hilla, Dulaim, Diyala, Diwan- iya, and others. Conclusion The government has made a good start in its land dis- tribution program. It is hoped that, by 1960, 500,000 more dunums will have been reclaimed and distributed in super- vised settlements. With the completion of several flood con- trol and storage works a major obstacle has been overcome. The land distribution program can now proceed at an accelerated rate. Through land distribution the government is helping solve the major social and human problem of the country. This should lead to both political stability and economic prosperity. 1. Sir Ernest Dawson, An Inquiry into Land Tenure and Related Questions. Printed for the Iraqi Government by the Garden City Press. (Letchworth, England: 1931), pp. 32-33. 2. IBRD, op. cit., p. 142. 3. Hashim Jawad, The Social Structure of Iraq, Baghdad, New Publishers Press, 1945, p. 21. 4. Alfred Bonné, The Economic Development of the Middle East. (London: Kegan Paul, etc., 1945), p. 36. 5. IRBD, op. cit., pp. 132-133. 6. Salter, op. cit., p. 54. 7. Ibid., p. 55. 8. Iraq Government, Ministry of Development, Miri Sirf Central Committee, Agricultural Reform and Land Development, Baghdad, 1956, p. 34 (in Arabic). CHAPTER 6 AGRICULTURAL TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES, AND SERVICES Prior to World War II, the government was not vitally interested in agriculture, the mainstay of the majority of the population. This is reflected in the fact that a Ministry of Agriculture was created only after a recommendation by a mission of the International Bank to Iraq in 1951. Until then only a small directorate had existed. The creation of a Ministry of Agriculture is symbolic of the conceptual change which has taken place concerning the function of government in public life. Gradually at first, but then more rapidly, the government began to play a positive role by providing services and creating institutions and facilities which hitherto had been absent. The preceding chapters discussed the efforts being made to develop the agricultural sector through harnessing the forces of nature and converting them into constructive use. This chapter will deal with the introduction of new techniques and the development of new services and institutions de- signed to increase the quantity and quality of agricultural production and to lift the peasant from his present impecun- ious state. Many of these innovations are taken for granted in the United States and other technologically advanced countries, but in Iraq they are new. Despite their elementary 106 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ character, they represent a significant step forward on the path of progress. Administratively, unlike the building of dams, land rec- lamation, bridges, etc., these new services do not come under the jurisdiction of the Development Board, but are regarded as routine government operations. Moreover, they arose, not as a result of a coordinated plan, but gradually in the different departments, with the expansion of govern- ment functions. All these “innovations” are still in an em- bryonic stage. Their significance lies not so much in their immediate contribution, but rather in their cumulative effect and in the role they will play in changing the socio- economic base of agriculture in Iraq. Farm Mechanization It is perhaps of historical interest to note that the drive for farm mechanization in Iraq was given its first impetus by the United States Lend-Lease Program during the war. Until then hardly any modern agricultural implements were used. The wooden plow of ancient form reigned supreme. With the war experience behind it, the government em- barked on a policy of introducing and generating demand for farm equipment among farmers. Several devices have been used to put government policy into effect: 1. The Agricultural Machinery Administration was cre- ated. It became a Directorate in 1956. This agency per- forms several functions. At present it controls the importation and licensing of all agricultural machinery. Originally, the agency also held a complete monopoly on the sale of such equipment. Following the recommendation of the Interna- tional Bank mission, however, it now licenses private im- porters with the stipulation that they also must import ade- quate stocks of spare parts and erect service stations. The agency itself owns a fairly large number of tractors, combines, and other farm equipment which it rents out to farmers. Until 1952, the rental rates were so low that the agency operated at a considerable annual loss. Finally, the agency provided technical help and service stations in var- ious parts of the country. TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES 107 2. Settlers on state land are implicitly required to use modern machinery. 3. Loans are advanced to independent farmers by the State Agricultural Bank for the purchase of farm equipment. Such loans may amount to as much as fifty per cent of the purchase price. Table 19 illustrates the results of government policy. From 1945 to 1956 inclusive, 2,097 tractors and 1,368 com- bines were sold. The Agricultural Census mentioned pre- viously reported that, in 1953, there were 2,091 tractors on agricultural holdings with a total of 88,000 horsepower. If the number of tractors sold in 1954, 1955, and 1956 is added, then at the end of 1956 there were some 3,061 tractors in the country. The flatlands of Iraq are ideally suited for the use of heavy machinery. The main obstacle to their use is the numerous irrigation canals. While there is little question about the advisability of universal mechanization in the future, there are arguments both for and against its speedy adoption. First, there is the question of relative costs. It is a known principle that where labor is cheap and abundant, it is, generally speaking, more economical in certain sectors to use human labor. A reasonable argument can be made that this is the case in Iraq. In addition, experience over the past ten years has shown that the life expectancy of agricultural machinery in Iraq is about half what it is in the United States and other advanced countries. This is because of the lack both of adequate training and main- tenance facilities. Hence, in many cases, the use of heavy equipment is not economical, especially when the com- paratively large initial investment is taken into consideration. Secondly, mechanization may create a social problem. There has been a growing concern in Iraq that while speedy mechanization may be economically desirable, it may also aggravate further the rural problem through wholesale displacement of tenant peasants and their consequent emi- gration to the cities. There are two arguments in favor of controlled mechaniza- 108 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ tion. At present mechanization is not of such proportions as to constitute a serious problem. In fact, the contrary may be true. Mechanization by landlords and as a government policy is, at least in part, the result of considerable migration of peasants to urban centers and the need for their replace- ment. This was the main argument advanced in 1956 by the director of the Agricultural Machinery Administration." Mechanization as a state policy can be used to serve three interrelated functions: to increase and improve the quality of production; to distribute and exploit the labor potential more efficiently. It is widely known, for instance, that there is considerable concealed unemployment in agriculture. Mechanization would force surplus labor out and transfer it to other sectors of the economy where it is needed. Then, too, it can indirectly aid in the breakdown of the present land tenure system and other archaic traditions and social in- stitutions in rural areas. The government realized that mechanization, for some time to come, will remain beyond the financial reach of the majority of farmers. For the time being, the path of improvement lies in the direction of introducing, on a uni- versal basis, simple modern implements which farmers can afford, which need little servicing, and the use of which can be taught in a short time. With the advice of American specialists, the government has been increasingly active in this field. The most significant development in this respect is the recent introduction of the steel moldboard plow. Agricultural Credit The establishment and development of the state Agri- cultural Bank is another illustration of the expansion of government activity in the agricultural sector. In Iraq, as in most underdeveloped countries, one of the chief impedi- ments to economic expansion is the lack of modern credit institutions. Until recently, the few banks that operated in Iraq were all foreign, and were primarily concerned with commercial transactions. Moreover, to this day, banks continue to be urban institutions of which the majority of the Iraqi population are only vaguely aware. Credit, TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES 109 therefore, could only be obtained from the traditional money- lender at rates of interest varying between 30 and 300 per cent. Both landlord and peasant were perpetually in debt. A story quoted by an Iraqi writer and alleged to be true is illustrative: “A farmer borrowed the price of three chickens which he served to a visiting guest. Interest compounded at such a rate that the farmer was forced to sell two cows to liquidate his debt.” *Sº tº co cro co lo co cN co try S 35 tº 3 & $ 3 3 S $3 #3 S c. cº, Co - to, co º- bº ºf -- Sc º, - ** Tº Go cº - uro S. o So S: 3 : S g – g – is 3 o o (o c ur, on tº- SS Qo F, d, * tºº. cN ~ CN - NH co ury § 3 ; Ś is o g on 3 * Co - w * º co o cN Go tº co co tº. o, & 3 S 3 T & CO * - tº < ~ co ºr ºt, -- c º: -- * § to p to c. ° S, or ; $ 6 z o; c. on ºf tº- co ſº - * - - co 8 § 3; 3 g : go co - ºn 3 O OS Co ºr “ tº- cN co -. va *~ vº oo # 3 is CO -4 cry co co - ºr co co S; Go on ºf *} -4 - : ; to $3 + - ſºlº * 33 s. - lo co tº. ury cry on to urb § 3 ; ; ; 3 & --- 2 tº st § £ 4 × wº- -- < Sº sh Qo co try cºw & º: § ury co CN on 3 * g & S. E * CN H - 3 § 3; 3 co cy CN C - tº ſºlº S on co = cºf 3 * lo o < $ 2 Sº 2 to * Co - S Co co o 3 * * : 3 * J lo CO ur) ** 3 $ 3, § 2, tº S 3 § s: - -4 $ *c. ~ "S # .S. : § $- $ *5 ºa ; ă ă = % § 5 º' ‘E f : ; ; # # 3 3 3 & C * 8 § 3 ; ; ; ; ; ; ; ; ; ; § 3 ; ; ; 8 3 : 3 +4 3 § 5 # 3 # 5 § 3 ; ; ; H C C H tº C Q ſº C.) Q ſº 108 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ tion. At present mechanization is not of such proportions as to constitute a serious problem. In fact, the contrary may be true. Mechanization by landlords and as a government policy is, at least in part, the result of considerable migration of peasants to urban centers and the need for their replace- ment. This was the main argument advanced in 1956 by the director of the Agricultural Machinery Administration.1 Mechanization as a state policy can be used to serve three interrelated functions: to increase and improve the quality of production; to distribute and exploit the labor potential more efficiently. It is widely known, for instance, that there is considerable concealed unemployment in agriculture. Mechanization would force surplus labor out and transfer it to other sectors of the economy where it is needed. Then, too, it can indirectly aid in the breakdown of the present land tenure system and other archaic traditions and social in- stitutions in rural areas. The government realized that mechanization, for some time to come, will remain beyond the financial reach of the majority of farmers. For the time being, the path of improvement lies in the direction of introducing, on a uni- versal basis, simple modern implements which farmers can afford, which need little servicing, and the use of which can be taught in a short time. With the advice of American specialists, the government has been increasingly active in this field. The most significant development in this respect is the recent introduction of the steel moldboard plow. Agricultural Credit The establishment and development of the state Agri- cultural Bank is another illustration of the expansion of government activity in the agricultural sector. In Iraq, as in most underdeveloped countries, one of the chief impedi- ments to economic expansion is the lack of modern credit institutions. Until recently, the few banks that operated in Iraq were all foreign, and were primarily concerned with commercial transactions. Moreover, to this day, banks continue to be urban institutions of which the majority of the Iraqi population are only vaguely aware. Credit, TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES 109 therefore, could only be obtained from the traditional money- lender at rates of interest varying between 30 and 300 per cent. Both landlord and peasant were perpetually in debt. A story quoted by an Iraqi writer and alleged to be true is illustrative: “A farmer borrowed the price of three chickens which he served to a visiting guest. Interest compounded at such a rate that the farmer was forced to sell two cows to liquidate his debt.” S S 3 g :: * $ $3 3 S 3 #3 -S on Go c * ury on tº ur, S cº, cº, Co * to, co º- bº ºf lº -- tº. ur) § 2 + s e i = 2 & 2 & ^ cº, CN - F. cN so tº- § 3 S 3 § 2 gº cN ~ CN wº $ to ºr st tº co ur) on o, co ur, co tº- o ur) * cry *4 * º § cº - 2 - C - to S Co cº C . § 3 ; S. & cN 2 * - g 5 s -- ur, ur) cr) - § 3 ; ; * S: o g; $ 5. 2. * - - 3 * co co º • * – c. § O § 3; 3 & S. tº- & & 2 ta * 3 So co tº- cr) cry co 2 É § {s 3, § - $ 5; S: - -- ur) - - - ſºlº # 33 & 2 s ufo -4 cry ob ur “hº trº < S ºr co ury cºn &f p. § 3; 3 g º ºs • 3 * g & 8 B * CN N. d. 5 § 3; 3 * * es e - tº - g = wº- § o co ur) * $ 2 & 3 ° 3 * 2 T # * Jº lo > $ $ S ; * tº 3 3 S Sº H -- S -S ~ "S É .S. ** *H .3 $- TS --º ºa H a a . $- O - P. . . § 3 ; *E 5 § 3 ; ; : ; ; 3 : C © tº § 3 ; ; ; ; ; ;I. Tº B t; # 3 # 3 ; # 5 3 & § E 3 3 Q +4 E § 5 # 3 # 5 # 8 ºf 3 ; tº H C C H ºd 3 Q Ad C) Q & I 10 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ The Agricultural Bank began operating after the war with a moderate capital of one million dinars. In 1952 its paid-up capital was raised to two million and, in 1957, to three. The experiences of the bank illustrate the problems of a new experiment. Despite many pitfalls, the bank steadily expanded in size and in the scope of its operations. Initially its loans went mostly to farmers of substantial means since they could provide the necessary securities required. This meant that the majority of small farmers were automatically excluded from its services. Moreover, most of its loans were of short duration. Gradually the Bank began to enter new, less orthodox fields. For instance, it now makes loans at five per cent for the purchase of agricultural machinery. During 1953 and 1954, it made 581 such loans with a total value of 444,853 dinars. The loans made possible the purchase of 673 agri- cultural machines including tractors, harvesters, and water pumps. It now also makes loans to agricultural cooperatives at 3 per cent interest. In 1955 the Bank launched a pilot project to provide credit to small farmers under expert supervision and guid- ance. The scheme was initiated for the Bank by a Point Four specialist in Hilla province where, during 1955-56, some thirty farmers in three villages received supervised loans totalling about 800 dinars ($2,240) at 3 per cent interest. In December, 1956, after the limited experiment proved successful and popular, the scheme was expanded to cover the whole country and its administration was transferred from the Bank to the directorate of agricultural economy in the Ministry of Agriculture. Table 20 shows the loans made by the Bank from 1948 to 1954. It indicates two trends. First, an increase in the role of the Bank in the agricultural development of Iraq and, secondly, a growing awareness on the part of the farmers of the facilities with which such an institution can provide them. There is a growing awareness that the Bank also has an educational function in addition to its regular duties. As indicated previously, banking is a new phenomenon in TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES III Iraqi economic life. Hence, by going out to the people, by opening branches in rural areas, the Bank can also function as an educational institution, in addition to providing badly needed services. Its lack of initiative in this respect has been one of the chief criticisms leveled against it. It is quite obvious that the Bank still falls far short of meeting the vast needs of the farmer for credit facilities. It has taken initial steps on a long road that has yet to be travel- ed. Its primary function is to lead the way, to act as a pioneer, but it cannot in itself be the final solution. In the first place, no matter how active the Bank can be, its facilities will still remain inadequate in relation to the need. Secondly, as business organizations, state agencies of this type everywhere suffer from a crusading spirit and are apt to be comparatively inefficient since their primary function is to serve rather than to make money. The solution lies rather in the develop- ment of private banking and private credit institutions. A beginning in this respect has already been made, but until such time as these are more numerous the state will continue to play the major role in this field. TABLE 20 LoANs of THE AGRICULTURAL BANK: 1948-54 JNo. of - Total Value Tear Loans in Dinars 1948 264 121,247 1949 Il. a. Il. a. 1950 524. 144,621 1951 789 263,693 1952 1,256 660,010 1953 2,186 1,353,639 1954 1,894 882,952 Source: Agricultural Bank, 17th, 18th, and 19th Annual Reports for 1952-53, 1953–54 and 1954-55. (All in Arabic.) The Agricultural Cooperative Movement In 1944, with the passage of Law No. 27 (1944), the co- operative movement reached Iraq, nearly a century after it was first introduced in Europe. Unlike its European coun- terparts, however, the movement is not doctrinaire and has no TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES 113 but in its great potential as a means of social change and as a powerful instrument through which farmers can band together for self-help. It is the antithesis of the growing de- pendence on the state. Agricultural Extension The concept of extension work is very new in Iraq. The counterpart of the American county agent was conspicuous by his absence. An extension service worthy of the name was organized only some four years ago. At the end of 1956 it had fifty-nine agents, six supervisors and five American Point Four specialists. Although the service is very limited in its scope, it has shown quite healthy signs of growth. Perhaps what is most significant at this stage is that it has taken roots, that it is popular among the farmers, and that at this initial period in its development, it has the guidance and advice of special- ists from the United States, a country where this field is most highly developed. In addition to its direct functions, the extension service, if and when it is fairly developed, may indirectly serve as an important link of confidence between the government and the peasant farmer. The schism between the two is centuries old, and the latter almost instinctively distrusts the government. The two main points of contact between them have traditionally been the ubiquitous tax-collector and military conscription. The extension agent, by working with the farmers as their trusted friend, may provide part of the link missing for many centuries. Research and Training Another facet of agriculture which has registered con- siderable progress in recent years is research and training. Whereas in the past only token attention was paid to this field, it has now become a regular governmental function. Agricultural research is carried out primarily by the var- ious departments of the Ministry of Agriculture. Other ministries also participate in areas of their particular in- terest. The Ministry has five experimental stations. Here, TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES I 15 the Extension Service has a program for training agents; the Agricultural Machinery Administration (which became a Directorate in 1956) has a program in the use and main- tenance of machinery; the Soils Laboratory, recently es- tablished jointly by the Irrigation Department, the College of Engineering, and Point Four, has a training program in soil classification and analysis. Finally, the rural school syllabus is being revamped in favor of far greater emphasis on practical training in vo- cational agriculture. This includes teaching children to raise vegetables in garden plots, planting, taking care of and harvesting field crops such as wheat and barley, and organizing the counterpart of 4-H clubs. An Arbor Day has also been set. Crop Diversification Agricultural production in Iraq is restricted to five princi- pal products: two winter crops, wheat and barley; two sum- mer crops, cotton and rice; one fruit, dates. These constitute the bulk of Iraq’s exports in addition to animals (on the hoof), raw wool and hides. Other fruits and crops are grown only in limited quantities. Poultry and dairy farming are almost non-existent. Animal husbandry is an adjunct to, but not a part of, agriculture. A number of economic and social factors must have brought about this traditional pattern of production. Some of them may only be guessed at. The salinity of the soil in the Mes- opotamian Valley dictated the choice of hardy crops which have a comparatively high resistance to salt. Hence the choice of wheat and barley. Then the economy of Iraq was, and still is, basically a subsistence rather than a money econ- omy. Production was primarily geared to meeting consump- tion needs. There was, therefore, not sufficient incentive to raise cash crops. Too, dietary habits and lack of good communications and storage facilities operate in favor of the production of some foods and against others. For in- stance, the staple foods of the Iraqi farmer are wheat and barley (for bread). He eats very few vegetables and fruits with the exception of onions and dates. Production of fruits I 16 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ and vegetables is, therefore, necessary only for supply to urban markets and for export. But this supply is hindered by lack of good transportation and storage facilities, since fruits and vegetables spoil quickly and require either immediate delivery or refrigeration. Finally, the fallow system which requires the land to “rest” in alternate years probably operated to limit crop variation. For generations this system was treated as sacred. All plans for agricultural expansion were based on the assumption that it would continue to be followed. Only in recent years has it begun to occur to planners that there is nothing particularly sacrosanct about the system and that, surely, after the advantages of other systems have been demonstrated to the farmer he will not be too reluctant to adopt them. In recent years the state has begun to take an active in- terest in the diversification of agricultural products. The drive has several objectives: first, to increase the number and variety of fruit trees. For instance, certain parts of central-southern Iraq are suitable for the development of a citrus industry, and others, to the north, for growing a variety of fruits and nuts. Second, to increase the variety of crops. In the 1920's cotton was introduced by the British as a cash crop, and later tobacco was introduced for local consumption. After several years of experimentation with sugar-producing crops, the state has, in the last few years, introduced sugar beet cultivation to provide raw material for the emergent refining industry. More recently, jute cultivation began on an experimental basis. Several other crops and legumes have also been introduced. Third, to encourage vegetable cultiva- tion on a much larger scale. Finally, to improve animal husbandry and gradually to integrate it with agriculture. Conclusions The period beginning after World War II may be de- scribed as a formative one in the history of agricultural development in Iraq. Agricultural expansion (including flood control, irrigation, reclamation, and drainage) became almost overnight the most important activity of the govern- ment. This stems from the recognition that agriculture is TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES 117 the most important sector of the economy and that it is the springboard to economic expansion in all other sectors. Initially the program of agricultural development suffered from lack of adequate detailed planning and technical studies. Consequently, the pace at which it moved was slow indeed and the program was unable to meet its targets. The first five-year program emphasized the construction of flood-control and water-storage structures for protection and for bringing more land under cultivation. Basically, this objective has been achieved. The dams and reservoirs that have been completed or are under construction are more than adequate for Iraq’s immediate needs. In recent programs the emphasis has shifted to irrigation, drainage, and improvement of areas already under culti- vation. This is a field which requires vast expenditures and years of coordinated intensive efforts. Only a beginning has so far been made. Almost all the institutions and services necessary for a modern agricultural system have either been created or are in the process of being organized. They are all, however, still in their formative stages. Their value is not so much in the magnitude of their present contribution, for this is limited, but in their potential, if and when they are fully developed. No studies have been made to measure and quantify the impact of the program. Prima facie evidence indicates that it is beginning to have its effects. In all probability its im- pact will not be greatly felt before 1960. By then, a large number of the works under construction will have been completed and their cumulative effects should become visible. Also, the agricultural institutions which have been recently created will have had time to grow into somewhat more effective instruments. The agricultural expansion program in Iraq is the only one of this magnitude in the Middle East. Despite many criticisms that may be made of its details, all the evidence shows that, on the whole, it is well planned and effective. If uninterrupted, it will probably be able to lift the standard of living in Iraq to three and four times its present level by 1970. 118 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ The program has several characteristics: 1. It has some of the attributes of socialism in the sense that it is being undertaken almost exclusively by state agencies, principally by the Development Board, with hardly any participation by private capital. Its benefits are designed to go primarily to the small farmer. For instance, state land, after being reclaimed and developed, is given away, but only to landless persons, principally farmers. Irrigation and drain- age works are in many cases planned in such a manner as to avoid having big landowners derive any benefits from them, sometimes even at the cost of greater efficiency. In effect this amounts to a redistribution of public wealth in favor of the masses. This is of great significance since more than 61 per cent of the land in Iraq is owned by the state. Side by side with this pronounced orientation of the pro- gram, the government has avoided introducing any agri- cultural reform, particularly in the land tenure system, which might antagonize or be resisted by the big landlords. These latter are very heavily represented in Parliament and are able to block any reform legislation which might seriously threaten their privileged position and interests. Thus the tendency of the program is to outflank the problem rather than to attack it directly. The big landlords are left in peace, but the peasant, through land distribution and other benefits, is given the opportunity to shed his economic and social shackles, and to begin a new life. 2. Generally speaking, the program is fairly isolated from politics and protected from the vicissitudes of changing cabinets and the raids of party politicians. It has continuity and is controlled and directed to a considerable degree by experts. This arrangement is unique in the history of Iraq and the other countries of the Middle East. 3. Due to personnel shortages in Iraq, the program depends very heavily on the services of qualified foreign technicians, consulting firms and construction companies, in addition to technical aid from the United States and United Nations agencies. For instance, nearly all heavy construction (dams, drainage, etc.) is carried out under contract by British, German, French, American, and Italian TECHNIQUES, FACILITIES AND SERVICES 119 firms. American technicians and specialists are particularly active as advisers in setting up new government agricultural services and institutions, and in improving others. 1. Iraq Times, May 2, 1956. 2. Jafar Khayyat, The Iraqi Village. (Beirut: 1950), f, n., p. 66. (in Arabic). CHAPTER 7 BENEFICIARIES OF REFORM-LANDLORD OR PEASANTº Since the majority of the population in Iraq is engaged in agriculture or associated enterprises, landlordism may be said to be at the root of almost all the ills that have plagued the country for several centuries. There is hardly any prob- lem, whether political, social, or economic, which in one way or another is not related to this central fact. It follows, therefore, that no development program in agriculture can be really effective if it is not accompanied by a program of agrarian reform. Large land holdings, as such, are not necessarily bad. In the United States, Canada, and Australia there are holdings comparable in size to those of Iraq. In Iraq, however, land- lordism is a way of life with rigid lines of demarcation de- noting economic, social, and political status with little or no mobility. Such a system means that the peasant leads a marginal existence with no hope for a better life, while the landlord receives most of the income from agricultural pro- duction and retains effective control of the political institu- tions of the country. The devastating effects of such a system are obvious. Economically, it results in very low productivity. While most of the landlords take little interest in the land beyond en- BENEFICIARIES OF REFORM 121 joying its income, the peasants have no special concern for improving it since they have little or no stake in it. Socially, the system leaves the peasant in virtual economic bondage, deprives him of his dignity as a human being, and limits his capacity to develop his potentialities or to contribute to the community. Politically, such a system in a twentieth-century world can only lead to instability and to the emergence of subversive movements. There is increasing realization that such a system is not an immutable law of nature, and that each individual has a right to a more equitable share of the goods of this earth and to a voice in the determination of his own destiny. Iraq today stands at the threshold of a new era. If there is to be economic and social progress, if the transition is to be effected peacefully without revolutions, then ways and means must be found to solve this problem effectively and with dis- patch. What are the possible basic objectives of a program of agrarian reform in Iraq” First, to increase the productivity of the agricultural sector of the economy; secondly, to provide the peasant with economic security and a higher standard of living; and thirdly, to restore to him his dignity as a hu- man being by liberating him from ignorance and disease, and at the same time allowing him to develop his potentialities. There are two alternatives open to the Iraqi government in dealing with the matter of land distribution. One approach would be to expropriate, in one way or another, large land holdings and redistribute them among landless peasants. Such a move, even if politically feasible, would be unsound. The land is ideally suited for large-scale agricultural tech- niques, including the use of heavy machinery. If the land- lords can be induced to use modern techniques, this would result in far greater increase in productivity than if the land were to be broken into small units. The second approach, the one which has been taken by the Government of Iraq thus far, is to leave the big landlords alone and to distribute the vast state-owned land reserve among the landless peasants. In addition to the land grant, the government extends to the new owner various types of BENEFICIARIES OF REFORM 123 destroy the foundations of landlordism as practiced in Iraq, leaving the landlord in virtually the same position as that of his counterparts in more advanced economies. One important question remains to be answered: how persistent and how speedy has the government been in im- plementing this program? It is in this area that criticism can justly be made. Although the plan was initiated in 1945, the number of landless peasants who have actually been settled is still comparatively small. Successive conservative ad- ministrations have been charged with failure to give ade- quate attention to the program. But these charges, although largely true, should be examined in the light of certain con- siderations. The program, in its initial stages, was a new venture for which the existing administrative machinery was not prepared. The natural tendency was to proceed slowly. Secondly, it was only after 1951 that funds became available on a sufficiently large scale to finance the program on more than a skeleton basis. Finally, preparatory work had to be carried out before distribution; plans had to be drawn, land surveyed, classified, and reclaimed and irrigation and drain- age works had to be constructed. In the last few years the program has picked up considerable momentum and is proceeding at a more rapid rate. The efforts of the government during the last few years to give the peasant a measure of economic security and in- dependence have not been insignificant, especially if judged in the light of the millions of dollars that have been invested in improving land and water resources. The legislation au- thorizing this investment provides that only landless peasants shall benefit from such improvements. Landlords are pro- hibited from participating in benefits. The Development Board has gone to considerable lengths to insure that no landlord will benefit from its activities. In some irrigation and drainage projects efficiency has been sacrificed in order to live up to the letter of the law. Now let us turn to the human aspects of agrarian reform, namely the activities of the government in the fields of education, health, rural welfare, and community development. So much needs to be done in each of these fields that, 124 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ no matter how extensive the efforts of the government, they can never be considered adequate. Over 95 per cent of the peasant population is illiterate. Almost every peasant is the victim of one endemic disease or another. As of 1956, 80 per cent of all houses in the country were either mud or reed huts, or tents; 79 per cent had no piped water supplies; 83 per cent had no electricity; 67 per cent had no toilets; and 90 per cent had no baths. The national average of occupancy per room was 2.73. Conditions in rural areas are generally much worse than in urban districts. Each year in the postwar period the government of Iraq has intensified its efforts to improve the basic conditions of the masses. Expenditures of the Ministry of Education rose from 1.6 million to 10.5 million dinars a year in the period from 1946 to 1957. This excludes expenditures of the Development Board and of other ministries and the costs of most college education. The number of elementary, in- termediate, and secondary schools during the same period rose from 1,003 to 2,070; the number of students from 130,000 to 430,000; the number of teachers, from 5,371 to 14,679. In recent years the number of elementary schools has been increasing at the rate of about 150 schools per year. College facilities have been considerably expanded, and a number of new colleges and technical schools have been opened. In 1956/57, over 3,000 Iraqis were studying at universities abroad—about a thousand of them at state expense. Elementary school facilities in the rural areas are being expanded quite rapidly. Whereas the children of peasants a few years ago had few or no opportunities for education, to- day it is possible for a peasant’s son to go all the way through a university at state expense. Thus, the benefits which used to be restricted to a privileged few are now being more widely extended. The gap which separates the peasant from the upper class is being gradually closed, and the possibility that his children may move up the social ladder, although still limited, has nevertheless become a reality. Such basic changes constitute a state-sponsored socio-economic revolution more significant than the political developments usually headlined in the press. These changes herald the gradual BENEFICIARIES OF REFORM 125 destruction of class lines, the rejection and replacement of existing social and economic institutions and traditions, and the adoption of a rational view of the universe and of man’s place and functions in Society. In the wake of such a revolution, a readjustment, either peaceful or violent, in the distribution of political power is sooner or later in- evitable. Similar progress has taken place in public health. Rural hospital and clinic facilities are being increased rapidly. The shortage of trained personnel is the main problem in this program. Perhaps the most encouraging progress has been made in the recent extensive campaigns to wipe out the endemic diseases which have long ravaged Iraq, particularly the countryside. Malaria, which used to kill some 50,000 persons each year, most of them peasants, has now been brought under reasonable control. In 1946, over 742,000 malaria cases were treated. Ten years later, in 1956, the figure was brought down to 217,000 cases. The facilities and functions of the Endemic Diseases Institute have under- gone considerable expansion in the last few years, and a Malaria Board was established in 1957. Until the past three years the government has not been active in rural community development in the fields of housing, water purification, and sanitation. In 1956, how- ever, a Rural Community Development Council on the ministerial level was under consideration. During the same year a housing census was completed. At the same time, the Development Board in its 1955-60 plan allocated some 25 million dinars to housing throughout the country. Ultimately, it plans to construct some 125,000 housing units in rural areas. Work on providing clean water supplies in rural communities has been intensified. The activities of the government designed to improve the living conditions of the poorest classes of the population reveal a basic interest in the general welfare. The government is, in effect, sponsoring changes which in the Western world required a long time to take hold. It should be pointed out that most of these state activities represent new concepts which, in contrast with the conservative environment of the 126 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ country, are revolutionary in character. In view of the fact that state responsibility for safeguarding human welfare was virtually unrecognized until after World War II, progress in this respect may be considered significant. The question of whether the state effort is “adequate” involves a difficult value judgment. The human needs in Iraq are virtually limitless, and vastly greater sums could be absorbed in programs attempting to meet them. A scale of priorities must be established, however, which will provide for the most judicious expenditure of the considerable, but limited, capital for investment. When both are badly needed, which should take preced- ence, a dam or a hospital? Should priority be given to the physical plant or to human resources? Or should there be some balance in expenditures? The expenditures of the De- velopment Board provide the best index as to policy. During the first years of operations the Board gave a de- cisive priority to the physical plant. This policy was based on the theory that to raise the standard of living there must be an increase in production which, in turn, required im- provement and expansion of the physical plant. A study of the 1950-55 plan, however, reveals that over 45 per cent of all planned expenditures went to the construction of flood control works, water storage schemes, irrigation, drainage, and land reclamation. As noted previously, the main bene- ficiary of these works is the peasant and not the big landlord. In other words, although the peasant was not receiving any immediate benefits from the activities of the Board, the land distribution program assured that, when the government’s investment began to pay dividends, the peasant was to be the main recipient. The 1955-60 plan reflects a decisive shift in the policy of the Board. The physical plant still receives the major share of expenditures. However, comparatively large sums, a total of about 70 million dinars, are also allotted to educa- tion, health, housing, and water purification. Agricultural works, from which the peasant is the principal beneficiary, constitute the largest single allocation. It is sometimes said that the development of the physical BENEFICIARIES OF REFORM 127 plant has not been accompanied by a “concurrent program of social and agrarian reform,” that the government is not “doing enough quickly enough” to win the support of the people, and that, despite painstaking precautions against profiteering, the vast expenditures of the Development Board are “benefiting the contractors and entrepreneurs far more than the great sharecropping mass of the populace.” As to the first point, the previous discussion demonstrates that this is not the case and that a program of social and agrarian reform does exist. It is true that, in its initial stages, it was slow in taking hold. But in the last few years reform has gathered considerable momentum. The second point raises a completely different issue. Should the Development Board, originally organized so as to be isolated from political pressures, become the handmaiden of political expediency? Should the Development Program, planned and executed by capable and presumably honest specialists, be oriented toward winning popular appeal at the expense of the welfare of the country? If this is to be the case, would the capital made available from oil revenues not be wasted on elaborate social welfare schemes? Would the country not eventually find itself economically more or less in the same position in which it started in 1950? Would it not be the better part of wisdom and political strategy to withstand pressures for immediate benefits in order to assure greater benefits later? This is not to say that the develop- ment program is perfect or that more funds should not be allocated to meet immediate human needs. It does mean that, if the program is to be effective, it cannot be sub- ordinated to political expediency or oriented to satisfying the whims of popular fancy. As to the third point, it is true that contractors absorb a considerable part of the expenditures of the Board. Un- fortunately, this is a necessary evil. The government admin- istrative machinery is not capable (nor should it be) of carrying out the construction work itself. Part of the reason for the failure of the 1950-55 plan to reach its objectives was the inability of the various government departments to carry out the work entrusted to them by the Board. Experience PART III The Development of Industry CHAPTER 8 THE OIL INDUSTRY Ownership There are two oil industries in Iraq: one extractive, pro- ducing only crude oil, essentially a foreign enterprise financed and developed by foreign capital and skill; the other, very recent, principally engaged in refining, financed and owned by the state. The state industry will be treated in the next chapter along with other new industries. This will be de- voted to the extractive industry. The development of the oil reserves of Iraq represents the largest industrial enterprise in the country. The complex political history of its evolution and its political significance will not be discussed except where necessary to make clearer the economic design. There are four international companies exploiting the oil resources of Iraq: the Khanaqin Oil Company, a subsidiary of the British Petroleum Company (previously Anglo-Iranian Oil Co.); the Iraq Petroleum Company (I.P.C.), the Mosul Petroleum Company (M.P.C.), and the Basrah Petroleum Company (B.P.C.). The last three are actually one, and are owned by the same interests. Stock participation in each of them is as follows: 130 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Percent Near East Development Co. (American)" 23.75 Cie. Française des Pétroles (French) 23.75 Royal Dutch Shell Group (British-Dutch) 23.75 Anglo-Iranian Oil Co. (British) 23.75 Estate of C.S. Gulbenkian (Armenian, British national) 5.00 The Khanaqin Oil Company is the smallest. Its production is small, and its concession covers only the “transferred territories,” a small area of about 648 square miles on the Iraqi-Iranian frontier. The company’s first concession was signed on August 30, 1925, and was revised in 1926. In accordance with the agree- ment, the company produces oil from the Naft Khaneh field and operates a small refinery at Alawand for the supply of refined products to Iraq. In 1932 it organized a marketing subsidiary, the Rafidain Oil Company, for the distribution of oil and oil products in the country. In 1927, a twenty-five- mile pipeline was completed, connecting the refinery with the oil field. On December 25, 1951, the government reached an agree- ment with the company and its subsidiary, whereby the government took over, as of January 1, 1952, the Alawand refinery and the distributing facilities of the two companies. However, it was agreed that the Rafidain Oil Company will continue to operate the refinery for the account of the government until otherwise requested and, for the ten years from 1952, will continue to be the distributor of oil products in Iraq on behalf and for the account of the government. It was agreed further, that the Khanaqin Oil Company shall, within seven years from date of agreement, commence regular exports of crude oil at a rate of not less than two million tons a year, or will surrender its concession. Profits from exports shall be shared equally between the company and the government.” In 1954 the crude oil production of the company amounted to a little more than half a million long tonS. The Iraq Petroleum Company operates in north central Iraq. Its first concession agreement with the Iraqi government was signed on March 14, 1925. It was revised on March 24, THE OIL INDUSTRY 131 1931, giving the company exclusive rights to exploit all lands situated east of the Tigris river, covering an area of about 32,000 square miles. The Mosul Petroleum Company has exclusive rights to exploit all lands in the Mosul and Baghdad provinces west of the Tigris river and north of the thirty-third parallel, an area of about 46,000 square miles. The company now operates only in the north around Ain Zala. Actually, the company inherited this concession. The first concession agreement was signed on April 20, 1932 with the British Development Co. During the same year, the Mosul Oil Fields, Ltd., with British, German, Italian, Dutch, French-Swiss, and Iraqi participation, was organized to buy up the share capital of the British Oil Development Company. By 1935, the Italians were the majority shareholders with 52 percent stock interest. In 1936, the Iraq Petroleum Company organized a sub- sidiary, Mosul Holdings, Ltd., for the purpose of acquiring the stock shares of the Mosul Oil Fields, Ltd. By 1937, the I.P.C. was in effective control. In 1941, the British Oil De- velopment Company assigned its 1932 concession to Mosul Holdings, renamed Mosul Petroleum Company. Both B.O.D. and Mosul Oil Fields, Ltd., retired from the scene. The Basrah Petroleum Company, which operates in the south near Basrah, obtained its concession on December 4, 1938. The concession covers all areas not included under previous concessions, including the Iraqi part of the Iraqi- Saudi Neutral Zone—a total area of about 93,000 square miles. Thus, by 1938, the Iraq Petroleum Company and its affili- ates had exclusive control on the production of oil in all Iraq with the exception of the small “transferred territories” con- cession. This final settlement was achieved after over thirty years of struggle, beginning in 1904, among many interests for the control of Mesopotamian oil. The “Fifty-Fifty” Formula The agreements signed with the oil companies were basic- ally identical. The principal provision, so far as we are here concerned, was that the companies were to pay the govern- THE OIL INDUSTRY 133 7. The I.P.C. is to supply the government refineries all the necessary crude oil for local consumption at 5.5 shillings (current sterling) per ton. [First Schedule, Point 5 (2).] 8. If production is halted, due to force majeure or an act of God, the companies are to loan the government a minimum of five million pounds a year, provided the amount loaned and unpaid does not exceed ten million pounds at any one time. (Article 8.) 9. If, in the future, higher royalty levels obtain in neigh- boring countries, the government has the right to ask for similar increases, and the company shall be willing to discuss the matter with the government." 10. Each of the companies is to appoint two Iraqis on its Board of Directors. (Schedules 1, 2, and 3.) 11. Payments of the companies to the government are to be in pounds sterling. Discovery Exploratory drilling by the I.P.C. began on April 5, 1927. Two months later, on June 27, 1927, oil was struck at Baba Gurgur on the Kirkuk structure. By the end of 1930, twenty- eight producing wells had been completed, and in 1934 pro- duction began on a commercial basis. In the Mosul concession farther north, drilling began in 1933 and continued with heavy expenditures until 1939 without success. A few days before the outbreak of the war (1939) deposits of light oil were discovered at a depth of five to six thousand feet at Ain Zala. In the Basrah concession actual drilling did not begin until after the war. In 1948 oil was discovered in commercial quantities at Zubair at depths of ten to eleven thousand feet. The Pipeline System Due to the inland location of most of the oil fields, the production of oil in Iraq is governed to a considerable extent by the availability of transport. Hence, the industry depends on an intricate pipeline system which carries its crude oil to sea terminals for export to the world markets. -...". ae © `--> &^ Refineries, -* *~. e -> ,” * , Oil Fields f Qasab º \ i. Kirkuk *~ cand A Naimah Baba Gurgur ~~2 f Qaiyarah - f © e { •Jambur \ Pipelines J government li j\ }. *raditha Yººs-s - Kermanshah *\ aft Khaneh. Naft-i-Shah womediterranean 12 and & \. ** 15 inch **, ºver * -: p" Factoaº *Y. iRAN cºunal. 2. t- 1. frefinery - Pipeline - Marine Ter-inst state ºf Miles *r-r-r-r-, © to 20 30 40 50 C fad A S. * - z / KUWAIT Q a "-- - - - PERSIAN … w GULF Sºlº ºf Riº THE OIL INDUSTRY 135 The first international pipelines to be constructed were two twelve-inch lines, with an annual capacity of two million metric tons each, from Kirkuk to Haditha, a distance of 150 miles. From there they branched off; one taking a southern route and terminating at Haifa, a distance of 470 miles, and the other taking a northern route and terminating in Tripoli, Lebanon, a distance of 380 miles. They were completed in the last weeks of 1934 and officially inaugurated in January, 1935. Due to the Arab-Israeli hostilities, the pumping of oil to Haifa ceased on April 17, 1948, and has not been resumed Since. In October, 1946, the construction of a sixteen-inch parallel pipeline, to follow the same route of the twelve-inch pipeline and to have an annual capacity of eight million tons (four million each) was begun. Again due to the Arab-Israeli hostilities, the work on the Haifa branch was suspended in 1948 after the completion of 575 miles of line—then only forty-two miles short of its destination. The Tripoli branch, 531 miles in length, was completed in the latter part of 1949. Work on a thirty- to thirty-two-inch single pipeline linking the Kirkuk and Mosul fields with Banyas on the Mediterra- nean in Syria, a distance of 556 miles, began in April, 1950, and was completed in April, 1952, at a cost of forty-one million pounds. The line has a capacity of 13.5 million tons a year. In July of the same year (1952), a single 135-mile, twelve-inch pipeline connecting Ain Zala (Mosul oil fields) with Baiji (K-2 station) on the main Kirkuk pipeline system was com- pleted. After the development of the oil industry in southern Iraq, a new pipeline system was begun, connecting the southern oil fields with the Persian Gulf at the Fao sea terminal on the Shatt al-Arab. In 1948 work began on a single seventy-five mile, twelve-inch pipeline to connect the Zubair oil fields with Fao. It was completed in October 1951. Due to the expansion in production, another seventy-five-mile, twenty-four-inch par- allel pipeline was found necessary and completed on Jan- uary 1, 1954. After the discovery of a new oil field at Ru- maila, southeast of Zubair, a twenty-mile, twelve-inch 136 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ pipeline was constructed connecting Rumaila with Zubair and the B.P.C. pipeline system. An interesting development is the entry of the Iraqi Govern- ment into the refining business, and it will be discussed in greater detail later. For this purpose a government 135-mile, twelve-inch pipeline was completed in 1954, connecting Baiji on the I.P.C. pipeline system with its newly-built re- finery at Dawrah near Baghdad. At present there are various plans for expanding the pipe- line system. Putting these into effect is complicated by political factors. A new twenty-four-inch pipeline from Kirkuk to Banyas on the Mediterranean in Syria will soon, it is hoped, be completed. The pipeline has an annual capacity of nine million tons. It was originally scheduled to terminate at Tripoli in Lebanon, but a recent decision switched the terminal point to Banyas. The line has been completed as far as Homs in northern Syria. Another plan calls for the diversion of the idle Kirkuk-Haifa pipelines (annual capacity 7.5 million tons) from Mafraq in Jordan to Sidon in Lebanon, across Syrian territory. In 1956 extensive discussions took place in this connection, and in late September 1956 final agreement was reached with the Lebanese government.” Similar negotiations between Iraq and Kuwait were con- ducted for the construction of a pipeline from the Basrah oil fields to Mina al-Ahmadi oil terminal on the Persian Gulf in Kuwait. The pipeline would have an annual capacity of four million tons. Its purpose is to make possible the shipment of oil on larger tankers which are unable to enter the shallow waters of the Shatt al-Arab. Agreement in principle is said to have been reached.” A plan which has received considerable publicity in the world press calls for the construction of a forty- to forty-two- inch pipeline system commencing at Kuwait, going through Iraq, and terminating in Alexandretta on the Mediterranean in Turkey, just north of Syria. Several international oil companies would underwrite its cost, and it would serve Kuwait, Iraq, and Iran.* The plan is still in the speculative stage. A more recent plan was sponsored by the Saudi-Arab- ian government in late 1957. The plan calls for the formation THE OIL INDUSTRY 137 of a corporation which would own and construct all future pipelines. The Arab governments in the area would be the stockholders. Reserves and Production The estimated proved oil reserves of the Middle East at the end of 1956 were some 144.4 billion barrels. Iraq held a little over fifteen per cent of this total (see table 21). TABLE 21 EstimateD PRoved OIL RESERVES IN THE MIDDLE EAST (End of 1956) Million U. S. Barrels Kuwait 50,000 Saudi Arabia 40,000 Iran 30,000 Iraq 22,000 Qatar 1,500 Neutral Zone (Kuwait-S. Arabia) 650 Bahrain 205 Israel 50 144,405 Source: U. S. Senate, Hearings Before the Committee on Foreign Relations and the Committee on Armed Services, 85th Cong., 1st Sess. on S. J. Res. 19 and H. J. Res. 117. (Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1957), Part I, p. 32. Iraq’s production remained comparatively low until after World War II. This was due to several factors. First, in the initial stages, the I. P. C. was reluctant to begin production until a settlement had been reached on concessions and its position was secure. Secondly, because of the location of the Kirkuk oil fields, the only producers at that time, production depended on the availability of transport facilities. Until pipelines had been constructed, production had to remain low. Thirdly, oil production in Iraq is extremely sensitive to inter- national political tensions. For instance, during the war a good number of the producing wells of the Kirkuk and Ain Zala areas were destroyed by the British military command in Iraq in anticipation of a possible southward advance by Ger- man forces. Similarly, two pipelines with a total annual capacity of over six million tons have been idle since 1948. 138 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ The Suez conflict of 1956 caused a temporary suspension of pumping to the Mediterranean with an estimated revenue loss to Iraq of some seventy million dollars. - Table 22 shows crude oil production in Iraq. From 1927 to 1933 production was insignificant. In 1934, with the com- missioning of the Kirkuk-Haifa-Tripoli pipelines, it jumped to over a million tons, and in each of the years 1937 and 1938, it was over four million. With the outbreak of the war in 1939 production began to decline, reaching a low of over 1.5 million tons in 1941. In 1942 it began to pick up, rising in 1944 to its pre-war levels. In 1949, with the completion of the sixteen-inch pipeline to Tripoli, it made an uninterrupted rise. In 1951, production jumped to 8.5 million, and since then, with the completion of a variety of pipelines, the temporary shutdown of the Iranian oil industry, and the demands in the world markets, the rise has been in leaps and bounds. In 1952 it rose to over eighteen million and by 1955 reached over thirty-three million. TABLE 22 CRUDE OLL PRODUCTION IN IRAQ (in thousand long tons) Thousand Thousand Tear Tons Tear Tons 1927 110 1942 3,555 1928 120 1943 3,804 1929 120 1944 4,300 1930 120 1945 4,621 1931 110 1946 4,698 1932 100 1947 4,746 1933 100 1948 3,470 1934 1,060 1949 4,168 1935 3,677 1950 6,545 1936 4,013 1951 8,561 1937 4,257 1952 18,549 1938 4,288 1953 27,740 1939 3,954 1954 30,141 1940 2,621 1955 32,188 1941 1,609 1956 29,469 Source: Iraq Government, Principal Bureau of Statistics, Report on the In- dustrial Census of Iraq, 1954. (Baghdad: al-Noor Press, 1956), p. 203; Statistical Abstracts for 1956, p. 192. 140 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ and where both Iraqi and foreigner alike work on equal terms for the common good. The outward manifestations of this change are many. Among others, they are reflected in the profit-sharing formula. Westerners in top positions are being replaced at an increasing rate by Iraqi nationals. Workers receive much higher wages than before. Working conditions, health, housing, and recrea- tion benefits have been vastly improved. The industry takes an active part in public life and community affairs. These include fairs, fire-fighting, charities, city and village cam- paigns, athletic contests, and so forth. The Role of the Industry The petroleum industry has now become the central factor affecting the economic and, indirectly, the political stability of the country. Its influence, directly or indirectly, permeates every aspect of economic and social development. An idea of its strategic position may be gained from the fact that it alone accounts for over one-third of the total national income. Any extended interruption of the flow of oil would bring in its wake chaos, poverty, and political unrest. Oil Revenue Between 1934 and 1950, revenue from the industry averaged about 14 per cent of the total revenue of the state. From there on it began to rise steadily until in 1955 it reached 73.74 million dinars (see Table 8), thus exceeding government receipts from all other sources by some forty-five million dinars. Oil revenue has been directly significant in three respects: a. It exclusively underwrites the program of the Develop- ment Board. Not only that, but such a program would otherwise have been impossible, since no alternative sources of income of the same magnitude are available. b. Between 1927 and 1950, oil revenue paid a minor part of the costs of government. From 1950 on, in addition to supporting the development program, it has been partly re- sponsible for the expansion that has taken place in govern- ment services in the fields of health, education, credit, agri- THE OIL INDUSTRY 141 culture, social welfare, etc. Thirty per cent of the oil revenue goes to the regular government budget to defray the cost of ordinary operations. c. It supplies Iraq with the necessary foreign exchange for her international trade. Iraq’s perennial problem in her trade relations with other countries has been the great gap between the value of imports and the value of exports. The foreign exchange deficit over the years has usually been covered by income from the transit trade; expenditures by pilgrims and tourists; expenditures by foreign vessels and recently airlines; expenditures by British forces for goods and services prior to, during, and after the war; oil royalties which represent income from the export of petroleum, and foreign exchange disbursements by the oil companies and expendi- tures of their foreign employes in the country. It is important to note that the oil industry after 1927 be- came an important factor influencing Iraq’s balance of trade. On the one hand, the heavy imports of the oil industry be- came one of the factors contributing to the import surplus, and on the other, foreign exchange payments by the oil indus- try in royalties, local disbursements, and expenditures of its foreign employes, have been the major source from which Iraq covered its trade deficit. From 1947 to 1949, payments of the oil industry failed to cover the trade deficit and Iraq drew heavily on its sterling balances and other assets which had accumulated during the war. Since 1940, owing primarily to income from the oil in- dustry, there has been an increase in Iraq’s foreign assets. The foreign assets of the National Bank of Iraq (which acts as a central bank), almost all in sterling, stood at 77.6 million dinars in September 1954.9 Labor The oil industry is the largest industrial enterprise in the country and the largest employer after the government. Its character and location are the two main determinants of the size of the labor force and the role employment plays in the national economy. The industry produces only crude oil. Unlike the case in 142 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Iran, it does not engage in any refining operations for com- mercial purposes. Once a well is drilled and connected, it needs little attention. The labor force is therefore comparative- ly small compared to the size of the industry, and is mainly concerned with drilling, maintenance, and pumping opera- tions. For instance, the labor force in the Iranian oil industry was about 60,000 in 1948; the industry’s labor force in Iraq during the same year was only 14,200. The second feature of the industry in Iraq is the dispersion of its operations in various parts of the country. Therefore, he recruitment of the labor force is not concentrated in one area. Because of the size of the labor force and its dispersion the oil industry in terms of employment occupies no com- manding position, as is the case in Iran, Bahrain, and Saudi Arabia. Nor does the industry have an exclusive monopoly on labor but—especially today—has to compete for it under pro- gressively adverse conditions because of competition from the Development Board and industrial expansion. While the industry is required to employ only Iraqi labor, unless other- wise absolutely necessary, Iraqi labor is free to move to other areas, such as Kuwait, in search of better opportunities. Dur- ing the last few years there has been an acute shortage of in- dustrial labor in Iraq. Table 23 shows the number of workers in the oil industry in 1938 and from 1943 to 1956 and local disbursements of the industry during the same period. From 1927 to 1938 (not indicated in the table) the number of workers ranged between three and four thousand. During the early years of the war the number dropped considerably, but in 1943 it returned to its pre-war level. In 1946, the year in which expansion began in earnest, the number jumped to 11,000 and in 1956 it reached close to 16,000. As shown by the table, the labor force is composed mostly of Iraqis, with a sprinkling of Jordanians, Syrians, Lebanese, and Palestinian refugees. Hardly any other nationality, with the exception of Europeans, is represented. The difficult question of employment of foreigners does not, therefore, arise as it does in Bahrain and Kuwait. THE OIL INDUSTRY 143 In terms of rank, position, privileges, facilities, and salaries, the labor force is divided into three main groups. 1. The Covenanted Staff. This group constitutes the executive, administrative, and higher technical labor force. The salaries of this group are calculated on an annual basis. The “staff” is divided into two categories. “London covenanted” are mostly Europeans—and primarily British– who sign a contract with the London office. Their salaries and allowances are geared to the European wage scale. TABLE 23 NUMBER of IRAQI AND Foreign WoRKERs; AND Local DISBURSEMENTS OF OIL CoMPANIES IN MILLIONs of IRAQI DINARs Local Dis- 1 car Iraqis Foreigners Total bursements 1938 Im.a. Im.a. 3,600 0.58 1943 3,804 158 3,962 Il.a. 1944 4,311 232 4,543 Il.a. 1945 5,486 256 5,742 Im.a. 1946 10,756 504 11,260 2.14 1947 13,900 656 14,556 5.60 1948 13,463 778 14,241 7.03 1949 12,069 814 12,883 6.49 1950 10,578 796 11,374 4.39 1951 10,385 659 11,044 5.69 1952 12,317 997 13,314 7.18 1953 12,279 906 13,185 8.76 1954 11,949 821 12,770 8.91 1955 14,468 860 15,328 11.a. 1956 14,914 918 15,832 Im.a. Source: Statistical Abstracts for 1950, p. 170, 1952, p. 235, 1955, p. 236, and 1956, p. 193; EDME, 45-54, p. 97; Iraqi Embassy, Washington, D.C., Bulletin, March, 1956. The second group is called “local covenanted staff.” These sign a contract with the Baghdad office and their salaries are geared to wage levels in the Middle East. The great majority of this group are Iraqi nationals, many of whom are paid at higher rates than those prevailing in the area as a whole. Other than differences in salary scale, the two groups enjoy the same privileges and facilities (clubs, cinemas, mess halls, housing, etc.) The local staff comprises only a small percent- age of the total staff. Since 1950, however, a drastic change in 144 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ policy has taken place. Local staff, increasingly and wherever possible, is replacing foreigners. 2. The Monthly Rate. The salaries of this group are cal- culated on a monthly basis. It consists mostly of clerical and skilled workers. Usually the members of this group are high school and local college graduates, skilled artisans, foremen, and the like. It comprises about 15-20 per cent of the total labor force and probably represents its more stable elements. This group is second in importance to the first mentioned, although the gulf between them is very wide. It has many privileges not enjoyed by others. 3. The Daily Rate. The salaries of this group are calculated on a daily basis. It represents the lowest rung in the employ- ment ladder. It consists of unskilled, semi-skilled, and skilled workers. On the whole the workers are either new with the industry, or do not have sufficient skill to be placed on the monthly payroll. A large majority of this group is illiterate. The above three groups constitute the regular labor force. In addition, during heavy construction periods the industry makes arrangements with contractors to supply labor at specified rates for definite periods of time. From the preceding discussion, it is evident that the im- portance of the industry as an employer in the industrial sector of the economy is steadily increasing. Between 1945 and 1955, the number of workers increased nearly three times. It is also significant in another respect. There is an increasing trend among workers to regard their employment as a life- time Occupation rather than a temporary measure. For in- stance, at Kirkuk (I.P.C.) in January, 1953, the total monthly and daily labor force was divided in length of service as follows:10 Daily Monthly Total Percent 1 year and above 2,254 304 2,558 47.4 5 years and above 1,664 362 2,026 10 years and above 339 80 419 45.6 15 years and above 171 91 262 20 years and above 34 38 72 25 years and above 6 13 19 7.0 4,468 888 5,356 100.00 THE OIL INDUSTRY 145 Wages The legal minimum wage rate for unskilled workers in Iraq is 250 fils (seventy cents) per day. The oil industry generally tries to stay close to the legal minimum. Its wages are therefore divided into two parts—basic wage geared to legal minimum requirement, and a high cost of living allow- ance. The basic wage does not change frequently, but fre- quent increases are made in the allowance. Since the daily and monthly rate payrolls constitute over 90 per cent of the total labor force of the industry, the dis- cussion will be restricted to these two groups. Table 24 shows the wage structure of the Iraq Petroleum Company and its affiliates as of January 1953. In April 1954 there was a general boost in allowances bringing about an increase of 10 to 15 percent in total wages. There are seven grades (one to seven) in the monthly rate payroll. Within each grade there are four basic wage incre- ments. The allowance remains constant within each grade. Similarly, there are seven grades (zero to six) in the daily rate payroll, with identical arrangements with the exception of grades zero and six. - TABLE 24 WAGE STRUCTURE OF THE I.P.C., B.P.C., M.P.C. In IRAQ. As of JANUARY, 1953. IRAQI DINARs. Monthly Payroll Daily Payroll Grade Basic/M HCLA/M. Total/M Grade Basic/D HCLA/D Total/D 1 11. 10. 21. 0 .17 .24 .41 12. 22. .18 .42 13 23. 14 24. 15 25. 2 15.5 11 26.5 1 20 26 46 16.5 27.5 22 48 17.5 28.5 24 50 18.5 29.5 26 52 19.5 30.5 28 54 3 20.0 12 32. 2 .30 28 58 21 33. .32 60 22 34. 34 62 146 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Manthly Payroll Daily Payroll Grade Basic/M HCLA/M. Total/M Grade Basic/D HCLA/D Total/D 4. 25.50 12. 37.50 3 .40 .30 .70 26.75 38.75 .43 .73 28.00 40.00 .46 .76 29.25 41.25 .49 .79 30.50 42.50 .52 .82 5 32.00 12. 44.00 4 .55 .35 .90 33.25 45.25 .58 .93 34.50 46.50 .61 .96 35.75 47.50 .64 .99 37.00 49.00 .67 1.02 6 39.00 12.5 51.50 5 .70 .40 1.10 40.75 53.25 .73 1.13 42.50 55.00 .76 1.16 44.25 56.75 .79 1.19 46.00 58.50 .82 1.22 7 49.00 12.5 61.50 6 .87 .40 1.27 51.00 63.50 53.00 65.50 55.00 67.50 57.00 69.50 Source: I.P.C., Kirkuk, Personal Communication, January 21, 1953. Basic/M. means basic wage per month. HCLA/M. means high cost of living allowance per month. The same applies to D., meaning Daily. There is little doubt that the oil industry is the wage leader in the country. Its wage policy apparently attempts to stay just a little ahead of the going market rate. For instance, the lowest wage paid by the I.P.C. and its affiliates in 1953 was 410 fils per day for a newly-hired unskilled worker. Actually very few workers remain at this wage level for long. Prevailing wages for such workers at Baghdad and Basrah in 1953 were 250 fils and 280 fils per day respectively (see Table 25). The great majority of the labor force falls within grades one to six in both the monthly and daily rate payrolls. These range from semi-skilled workers with few months of training to skilled mechanics, electricians, fitters, turners, wireless operators, painters, carpenters, clerks, draftsmen, store- clerks, accounts clerks, etc. The wage for this group (one to six) begins with a low of nearly 500 fils (half a dinar) per day for a new semi-skilled worker and proceeds to a high of nearly two dinars a day for a grade six monthly worker. As can be seen from Table 25, these rates are higher than prevail- ing rates in both 1953 and 1955. THE OIL INDUSTRY 147 TABLE 25 DAILY WAGEs for CoNTRActors’ LABOR IN BAGHDAD Liwa AND THE Port of BASRAH IN 1953 AND 1955 (in Iraqi Fils) Contractors (Baghdad Liwa) Basrah Port End 1953 jan. 1955 End 1953 Jan. 1955 Carpenter 900 900-1,200 4.25- 555 465- 595 Tractor Driver 800 750 425- 525 465- 565 Electrician 700 1,200 425- 525 465- 565 Turner 1,000 1,300 600- 700 640- -740 Mechanic 700 700- 900 525- 660 565- 700 Blacksmith 700 800 425- 525 465- 565 Crane Driver 1,000 1,000 515- 595 545- 635 Fireman 600 600 355- 395 395- 435 Greaser 450 400- 600 335- 375 375- 415 Laborer 250 250- 350 280- 335 320- 375 Storekeeper 1,330 1,500 1,930-2,130 1,970-2,530 Clerk 1,330 1,500 615- 860 655- 900 Source: Lord Salter, Development of Iraq, A Report Submitted to the Iraq Development Board (London: Caxton Press, 1955, p. 153.) An idea of the wage position of the oil industry in the indus- trial sector of the economy can be gained from comparing annual wage bills. In 1954 the annual wage bill of the four oil companies which then employed 15,249 (including re- fineries and distribution, otherwise 12,770) was 6,200,349 dinars. This amount exceeded by some 444,000 dinars the total wages paid by all other manufacturing industries in the country (total wage bill: 5,756,024 dinars) which then numbered 22,460 establishments and employed 90,291 work- ers.11 It should be pointed out that approximately 37 per cent of the workers in these industries are small owners, partners, or unpaid family workers and do not therefore receive wages. Wages in the final analysis are not the only criteria for T48 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ comparison. Workers in the oil industry receive many other tangible and intangible benefits which in most cases are not available outside the industry: fairly speedy advancement; assurance of a steady job; good working conditions; sub- sidized meals, housing, medical treatment and so forth. Table 23 shows the disbursements of the oil companies in Iraq for both wages and services. It is assumed that the major part of the expenditures went to the payroll. On the whole they indicate a steady increase in wages per worker even though the number of workers also increased considerably. Expenditures rose from about 600,000 dinars in 1938 to nearly nine million in 1954. The increase in real wages, how- ever, is not as great as might be surmised from the table. This is because the purchasing power of the dinar has declined to more than half its pre-war level. Hours and Conditions of Work Conditions and hours of work in the industry are governed by the Iraqi Labor Law No. 72 (1936) as amended by Law No. 36 (1942). A new labor law recommended by the Inter- national Labor Organization was approved by the Cabinet in June, 1956 for presentation to parliament, but was not, at the time of writing, passed.” The existing law covers daily workers only and, until recently, it applied in practice only to the oil industry and a few other enterprises, since there was hardly any other industry in Iraq. In accordance with the law, the work day in the industry is eight hours and the work week forty-eight hours, for which the worker receives seven days’ pay. Since 1945 the work day during the month of Ramadhan (the Muslim fast) has been only seven hours. Friday, the Muslim Sabbath, is the weekly holiday. The law requires that workers receive leave with full pay at the rate of one day for each month employed and sick leave at the rate of four days for every three months. In case the sick leave has been utilized and the worker still requires treat- ment, he may use his ordinary leave. Workers receive a week’s notice before being discharged. 150 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ with accumulated interest on them, are called “A” account. The company contributes a similar 10 per cent plus a yearly bonus of 5 to 7.5 per cent of the total annual earnings of the worker. These contributions, together with accumulated interest on them, are called “B” account. Upon leaving the service of the company, the monthly worker receives the whole of “A” account in addition to: 50 per cent of “B” account after five years of service. p y - 75 per cent of “B” account after ten years of service. p y - 100 per cent of “B” account after fifteen years of service. 2. The Employees Saving Scheme. This plan is open to both the monthly and daily rate workers. It is designed to help the workers save part of their earnings. Membership and amount of saving are voluntary. Upon joining, the employe decides on the amount he desires to save, and it is then checked off by the paymaster and sent to the thrift office. The money is deposited in banks at rates of interest between 2.5 and 3 per cent. The company’s contribution lies in its encouragement of workers to join, and in providing the clerical and administra- tive staff, office space, and equipment free of cost. The scheme was initiated around 1950 in Kirkuk and subsequently in- troduced at Ain Zala and Basrah. It has been fairly successful, although some of the employes use it as a checking account. The year 1956 may be regarded as a turning point in the history of labor in Iraq. It has already been stated that a new comprehensive labor law was approved by the Cabinet in June, 1956. According to press accounts, the proposed law extends the definition of workers to include white-collar employes, expands the indemnity clauses of the 1942 labor law and provides for more adequate compensation for indus- trial injury. It further provides for compulsory unionization in industries which employ over a certain number of workers. During the same year the first Social Security Law in the history of the country was passed. On December 1, 1956 it was put into effect in five of Iraq’s fourteen provinces. These five— Baghdad, Basrah, Mosul, Kirkuk, and Hilla—were chosen because of the heavy concentration of workers in them. The THE OIL INDUSTRY 151 law gave initial coverage to some 65,000 workers in private enterprises, oil companies, and government establishments. The main provisions of the law are as follows: 1. Coverage. It brings under coverage every employe who is working for an employer—whether for wages, or as an apprentice or as a probationer. The coverage is not restricted to industry but extends to every occupation. 2. Contributions. The employer is required to pay the Social Security Fund fifteen fils for every day of service of the employe excluding rest days, provided that such rest days are not more than one day a week. The state pays fifteen fils, and the worker ten fils. In other words, the employer pays 37.5 per cent, the state 37.5 per cent and the worker 25 per cent of the fund. 3. Benefits. The law provides for the following benefits which the worker covered can receive from the fund at one time or another: (1) old age benefit, (2) permanent invalidity benefit, (3) survivor’s benefit, (4) marriage benefit, (5) maternity benefit, (6) funeral benefit, (7) unemployment benefit, and (8) sickness benefit. 4. Administration. Responsibility for the program is lodged in a Social Security Commission of three members appointed by the Council of Ministers. The Commission has a juristic personality and is authorized to buy property and otherwise invest the funds. The operation of the program is administered by a directorate in the Ministry of Social Affairs. Before its passage, the law had been under discussion since 1951. Representatives from both industry and commerce were consulted concerning its various provisions. The knowl- edge that such a law would be passed may have been the reason why the oil companies took no action on their own in recent years to give their workers more adequate protec- tion. It should be remembered that the policy of the industry is one of integration. Such a concept implies not being too far ahead, and not too far behind general trends and develop- ments in the country. Labor Unions and Relations The labor law provides for the formation of labor unions. 152 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ In actual practice, there is a mass of cumulative evidence from impartial observers indicating that, on the whole, the government does not look with favor on the union movement. Moreover, union leaders seem to have no clear concept of union work, and it is believed the union membership (total in the country about 500) is infiltrated with state security agents. According to a report of the United States Embassy in Baghdad, the government activity in the labor field is mainly confined to suppressing elements of potential threat to internal stability.” For instance, the union of cigarette workers which organized an effective strike in 1953 was disbanded by the government in 1954. In September, 1954, a new ordinance authorized the Council of Ministers, upon the recommenda- tion of the Minister of Interior, to suspend or close down permanently any association, including labor unions, for actions endangering public security and order. The following month (October, 1954) the government issued regulations and set up machinery for conciliation and arbitration of labor disputes. One provision requires strikers to give a minimum of fourteen days’ notice to the Ministry of Social Affairs before stopping work. Whatever may be the attitude of the government, as of this writing no labor union exists in the oil industry. The only organizational channel through which the workers have some way of presenting their views or grievances to management is the Joint Consultation Committee System. This system was found effective in England during the war. It was in- troduced in one department in Kirkuk in 1950 and has since then been installed in all departments at Kirkuk, Ain Zala and Basrah. a. Objective. The objective of the Joint Consultation Com- mittee, according to the charter of the oldest committee at Kirkuk, is “to provide regular meetings between management and employes' elected representatives to discuss matters of mutual interest, to secure cooperation through explanation of measures proposed or taken on behalf of the interest of both parties.” b. Functions. The functions of the committee are complete- ly advisory. They are limited to discussion of such subjects THE OIL INDUSTRY 153 as promotion of physical welfare, improvement of working conditions and general work discipline. No subject covered by the labor law may be discussed. c. Composition. Each department elects three sub-com- mittees (each sub-committee has between six and eight mem- bers), one for each group of workers—the daily paid, the monthly paid, and the staff. Each sub-committee then elects two members to represent it on the Joint Consultation Com- mittee of the whole department. In addition, management appoints two members to represent it. Thus the Committee is made up of eight members; two each, to represent manage- ment, staff, daily paid and monthly paid workers. Housing Up to 1950 the oil companies in Iraq to all practical pur- poses provided no housing for their employes. Very adequate housing was provided for the “staff,” composed mostly of Europeans, and also housing for everyone on the pipeline stations in the desert. Other than that, there was hardly any housing scheme worthy of mention. Since 1950, however, housing has been provided for a larger and larger number of employes and workers. At Kirkuk, a modern housing development was begun which by the end of 1952 had some 500 houses. The develop- ment has a shopping center, schools, a modern sewage system, and all the other necessary amenities. The houses are of current design and are of two sizes. The larger size has three bedrooms and the smaller two. Both have a living room, a kitchen, a store-room, a bathroom, and a toilet. They are provided with electricity and running water, in addition to electric ceiling fans and radiators. Heat is supplied from a central plant. Rent is very low. Priority is based on a point system. Each year of service is given two points, and each grade two points. But in any case, before becoming eligible, a worker must have served two years with the company. In effect, the point sys- tem leaves most of the daily workers out, until the needs of the monthly rate employees and those who have been long with the company are satisfied. 156 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ mentary education are selected by the company for a five- year course of apprenticeship training. During this period the students receive from the company about ten dinars a month each month the first year. The pay is then annually in- creased until by the last year it reaches twenty dinars a month. Part of the pay is withheld, either as savings for the student or payments to the parents. Kirkuk students live at home but they are charged for books and sports gear. The others are housed and fed by the company, for which seven dinars a month are deducted from their pay. The training is divided into two parts: during the first two years all students go through a broad program of study with concentration on English, mathematics, physics, chemistry, engineering drawing, laboratory work, and workshop training in wood and metals. After the first two years the students are divided into three groups according to aptitude and ability. One group receives artisan training, the second, training in advanced engineering and science, and the third, training in commercial practice. The Center opened at Kirkuk in late 1951. It has a modern classroom building, and an imposing array of training work- shops. By the end of 1952 the Center had 100 students and it was expected that enrollment by 1956 would be around 300 students. In addition, the Center carries out an adult education pro- gram in the evening. Workers between the ages of twenty- five and thirty-five are given instruction in English, commer- cial subjects, and office methods. It should be noted that day students under the regular program are not under obligation to work for the company when they complete their five-year COUIrSe. c. Training in the United Kingdom. Company artisans who show ability and promise are sent to the United Kingdom for one or two years of practical industrial training with part- time attendance at technical colleges. The scheme was initiated around 1951. d. Trainees’ Schemes. There is a complex variety of “learner” and “trainee” schemes at the Training Workshops in Kirkuk, THE OIL INDUSTRY 157 to which the associated companies send the men they select. The training varies in length from a six-months basic course to a two-year program. e. The company pays the tuition fees and other incidental expenses of approved correspondence courses with schools in the United Kingdom. Payment, however, is conditional upon the worker’s successful completion of the course. f. On the job Training. Workers receive training while on the job under the direction of skilled artisans. g. “Sandwich.” Training. The companies accept a limited number of students from technical schools in the country for training at company workshops during their summer vacations. h. Evening Classes. Evening classes at various installa- tions of the companies and under a variety of arrangements are given in either English or Arabic or both. An increasing number of workers, especially from the lower grades, are taking advantage of this opportunity. These various training programs are probably one of the more valuable and permanent contributions of the industry to the development of the country. There is an acute shortage of skilled labor in Iraq which is expected to become progressive- ly more severe. The industry’s efforts in this field are part of a countrywide drive to produce as many skilled workers as possible within the shortest period of time. This will be discussed later in another connection. Medical Facilities and Services In all, the oil companies have six hospitals with a total capacity in 1955 of 200 beds. The central hospital of the industry is located at Kirkuk. It serves the Kirkuk area and takes care of the major operations of the Mosul area and the pump stations. The hospital is fully equipped and com- petently staffed. It carries out an average of 1,200 operations a year. The total number of outpatient attendances at the hospital in 1952 were 72,005 of which 13,668 were non- employees. Both Ain Zala and Basrah have smaller hospitals. In addi- 158 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ tion all areas have several clinics. Every pump station has its own medical arrangements including a doctor, a clinic, a detention ward, etc., to handle minor cases. The services of the medical departments extend over a wide area: a. Every employe prior to his engagement is examined and vaccinated against smallpox and inoculated against typhoid and paratyphoid. b. All employes receive free medical treatment including hospitalization. This service in many cases extends to the employe's immediate family. c. The company hospitals and clinics, especially in isolated areas, serve not only company personnel but also neighboring villages. d. The medical departments are responsible for the general sanitation of the camps including supervision of water, food in the canteens, sanitation in houses on company estates, and other such functions. e. They carry out, in cooperation with the local authorities, various campaigns to control disease in the areas in which they operate. The most extensive are the malaria campaigns which include larval control (spraying of water, etc.) and adult control (spraying of buildings). Welfare The welfare movement in the companies started around 1950. There are now welfare committees elected by workers in all areas. Their functions are purely advisory. 1. Food. In all areas the cost of food is subsidized. It is provided to monthly and daily rate personnel in most areas by contractors. The company usually supplies the contractor, free of cost, room space, equipment, part of the fuel, electricity and water, in addition to a straight monthly subsidy, or a per person subsidy or per plate subsidy, In return, it specifies the meal prices which the contractor may charge, specifies the kind of food he may serve and supervises the cleanliness of the mess hall. In addition there are tea and coffee rooms which are also subsidized. 2. Recreation. The extent of recreation facilities depends on 160 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ felt. Production was low, the labor force was small, royalties comparatively meager, and local disbursements not too significant. With the conclusion of the 1952 agreement, however, the oil industry became suddenly the central factor affecting the stability and development of the country. Negatively, there is little doubt that, if the industry were to close down sudden- ly, the government machinery would collapse and economic and social chaos would follow. Positively, it is the one im- portant single force responsible directly or indirectly for economic progress and social reform and for pushing Iraq by forced march into the twentieth century. The industry is the largest enterprise in the country. From its inception it set the pace for wages, industrial social wel- fare, and liberal treatment of labor. Since 1950 labor benefits such as housing, training, recreation, food, medical treat- ment, and so forth have been vastly expanded. Periodic in- creases are also made in wages, and the wage scale is higher than prevailing rates in the country. The industry’s attitude towards the labor force is, however, paternalistic and there is reason to believe that the formation of labor unions is dis- couraged. In any case, no labor unions exist in the industry. About 1950 the industry initiated a policy of integration with the country and its people. In one sense, such a concept implies not being distinctly recognizable as “different” or “foreign,” not creating an élite labor force physically and spiritually segregated from the community and in general not being too far ahead nor too far behind developments in the country. In another, it implies identification with local interests and local life, increasing the number of Iraqis in responsible positions, better and more humane treatment of labor, participation in community affairs, rising along with local interests to meet emergencies, constructive sensitivity to public opinion and, in general, overt concern for the wel- fare of the country. THE OIL INDUSTRY 16] i . Owned equally by Standard of New Jersey and Socony Mobil. . Iraq, Agreement Between the Government of Iraq and Khanaqin Oil Co., Ltd., and Rafidain Oil Co., Ltd., 25th December, 1951 (London: Cooper and Sons, Ltd., 1952.) . The formula has several variations, but is generally known as the “Fifty- Fifty” agreement. . I.P.C., M.P.C., B.P.C., Agreement with the Government of Iraq Made on the 3rd Day of February, 1952, Together with Law No. 4 of 1952, (Hertford, Herts, England: Stephen Austin and Sons, n.d. In English and Arabic.) . This was not actually part of the agreement. The promise was made by an exchange of letters between the Minister of Economics, dated September 28, 1951, and a reply from the General Manager of the three companies, G. S. Gibson, also dated September 28, 1951. . USIA, Baghdad, Press Dispatch, October 4, 1956. . USIA, Baghdad, Press Dispatch, December 13, 1956. . See, for instance, Time Magazine, May 27, 1957, pp. 29-30. . United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Economic De- 10. . Industrial Census, 1954, op. cit., pp. 9, 211, 213. 12. 13. 14. 15. welopments in the Middle East, 1945-1954 (New York: 1955, p. 102.) Hereafter referred to as EDME, 45-54. I.P.C., Kirkuk, personal communication, January 23, 1953. Iraq Times, June 12, 1956. U. S. Embassy, Baghdad, Annual Labor Report, Iraq 1954 (Dispatch No. 562 of May 21, 1955). Quoted by Iraq Handbook, New Haven, H.R.A.F., 1955. I.P.C., Kirkuk, Home Ownership Scheme Handbook, an unpublished typescript. This obligation is actually not part of the 1952 agreement. It is more in the nature of a gentleman's understanding—probably based on article 29 of the 1925 concession agreement. INDUSTRIALIZATION packing, tailoring, brick-making, metal products, bakeries, construction, motor vehicle repair, cigarette and tobacco and grain-milling. In terms of annual wage bills, spinning and weaving were also the most important, followed by construc- tion, brick-making, railway workshops, bakeries, grain- milling, cigarettes and tobacco, electricity and water, motor vehicle repair, and cement. The wage bill of each of these industries was over 200,000 dinars. TABLE 26 INDUSTRIAL SUMMARY OF IRAQ: (Excluding Oil) Number of Establishments JNumber of Workers: Men 67,373 Boys 10,611 Women 10,270 Girls 2,037 Literate 22,813 Illiterate 67,478 Total Value of Machinery, etc., in Dinars Annual Expenditures in Dinars: Costs of raw materials Costs of oil and electricity Annual Wage Bill Total Annual Receipts (Gross) in Dinars Motive Power Used: JNo. Electric Motors 6,157 Oil Engines 1,561 Steam Engines 26 7,744 Water Wheels 216 7,960 22,460 90,291 90,291 15,658,000 15,024,000 995,000 5,756,000 21,775,000 39,198,000 Horsepower 37,403 98,052 59,256 194,711 1,110 195,821 Source: Iraq, Industrial Census of Iraq, 1954. (Baghdad: 1956), pp. 9-19. 164 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ TABLE 27 MAIN INDUSTRIEs of IRAQ: 1954 Annual JNumber of Wage Establish- JNumber of Workers Bill in Industry ments Men Women Total Dinars Spinning, Weaving, etc. 2,248 7,871 1,187 9,058 695,881 Construction 39 4,644 35 4,679 546,848 Brick-Making 203 6,770 70 6,840 485,802 Railway Workshops 8 2,506 2,506 434,690 Bakeries 1,563 3,754 1,445 5,199 311,566 Grain-Milling 954 3,648 135 3,783 273,373 Cigarettes & Tobacco 1,057 3,417 571 3,988 267,173 Electricity Generating 49 1,338 21 1,359 250,008 Electricity & Water 22 1,383 1 1,384 249,603 Motor Vehicle Repair 1,239 4,044 2 4,046 219,999 Cement, Juss, Gypsum, etc. 266 2,552 6 2,558 215,759 Fruit-Preserving, Date- Packing, etc. 98 3,166 5,051 8,217 175,883 Metal Products 2,346 5,370 5 5,375 169,770 Shoemaking 1,239 3,103 83 3,186 166,452 Tailoring 4,236 6,072 1,313 7,385 166,300 Printing 132 955 4. 959 118,155 Soap & Misc. Chemicals 53 1,020 80 1,100 112,884 Water Supply 34 815 815 79,900 Shipbuilding & Repair 5 442 442 74,124 Carpentry 1,914 3,318 19 3,337 70,868 Soft Drinks & Soda Water 56 567 567 68,758 Canneries 96 641 5 646 68,608 Furniture-Making 184 696 2 698 65,682 Pottery- and Tile-Making 140 718 12 730 63,922 Sweets-Making 176 732 77 809 51,602 Spirits, Brewing, etc. 7 303 1 304 50,864 Source: Industrial Census, 1954, op. cit., pp. 10-13. TABLE 28 INDUSTRIEs of IRAQ. AND BAGHDAD CITY: 1954 Iraq Baghdad City Size of Firm— Mo. of T Total No. JNo. of Total JWo. JNo. of Workers Firms of Workers Firms of Workers 1- 4 19,896 35,406 3,874 7,420 5- 9 1,837 10,475 456 2,750 10- 19 433 5,718 119 1,556 20- 99 199 8,185 75 3,041 100-249 59 9,527 32 4,886 250-499 24 7,835 7 2,628 500-999 8 5,336 7 4,499 1,000-Over 4. 7,809 3 6,587 TOTAL 22,460 90,291 4,573 33,367 Source: Computed from Industrial Census, 1954, op. cit. INDUSTRIALIZATION 1.65 The three preceding tables show statistically the basic characteristics of the industrial establishment in Iraq. It is still in an embryonic stage, using for the large part human labor and simple machinery. It consists mostly of hundreds of small shops and family enterprises, a very large number of which cannot be classified as “modern industries” but are more in the nature of handicraft and cottage industries. For instance, most of the spinning and weaving, tailoring and shoemaking establishments fall into this category. It consists entirely of light industries, including some service industries such as vehicle repair shops. It produces entirely for the domestic market and, finally, it is very highly concentrated in the city of Baghdad. In the whole country there were 22,460 firms employing 90,291 workers. Baghdad City ac- counted for 4,573 firms or 20 per cent of the total and 33,367 workers or 36 per cent of the total. Included in these totals are ninety-five firms employing over 100 workers each, with a total labor force of 30,507 persons. Of these, Baghdad City had forty-nine firms or 51.5 per cent, and 18,600 workers or sixty-one per cent. Another index of the concentration of industry in Baghdad City is its share of the annual wage bill and the value of in- dustrial machinery, plant, and equipment. The annual wage bill for the 22,460 establishments mentioned was estimated in 1954 at 5,756,000 dinars of which the industries of Baghdad City paid 3,359,000 dinars or 58 per cent. The value of machinery and other installations in factories employing twenty persons and over in the whole country (excluding oil) was found to be about 12.1 million dinars. Of this, Baghdad’s share was eight million or 66 per cent. Industrial Policy Although the economic structure of the country precludes the immediate creation of substantial large-scale industry, Iraq has either entirely neglected or inadequately exploited some very valuable industrial raw materials. Industrial ex- pansion based on these resources can produce new wealth, raise the standard of living, and, perhaps most important of all, develop human skills. In particular, Iraq possesses an 166 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ abundance of potential thermal and hydroelectric power, mineral deposits and chemicals, and agricultural lands. A fairly sizeable industrial complex can be built on the basis of these resources. Since 1950 several reports have been submitted by special- ists to the Iraqi Government concerning industrialization. Basically, they all subscribe to the same thesis: that industrial- ization should not be forced through tariff protection and government subsidies and that primary attention should be given to agriculture in preference to industry. The International Bank Mission, after recommending certain specified industries, warned that “Particular care should be taken that government assistance does not foster inefficient industries at the expense of the country’s standard of living.” Professor Iversen in his report to the National Bank of Iraq came to the conclusion that:” Since fertile land is undoubtedly the most valuable asset of Iraq (even counting oil) it seems to be most appropriate to choose the first alternative [i.e., agriculture]. This does not mean, of course, that industry should not be allowed to develop; on the contrary, it is to be expected that in the very long run Iraq will have to follow the path of other countries towards an increasingly industrialized stage of de- velopment. But in a world in which the problem of providing food for an evergrowing population is one of the most serious, it seems in the best interest of Iraq not to force this develop- ment, but to concentrate on raising the efficiency of agricultural production. Iversen, in discussing the “diversification of exports,” adds: “Iraq has large comparative advantages in agricultural production, whereas the possibilities of creating new indus- tries able to compete on equal terms with producers abroad are more limited and more remote.” He further states that, from this, it is not to be inferred that industrialization should be neglected, but that “to force this development, e.g., through strong protective measures . . . would probably in most cases be unwise . . . .” | º ; INDUSTRIALIZATION 167 Lord Salter, in his report to the Development Board, sub- scribed to both the reasons and conclusions of Iversen and added a few of his own. He points out that “There is every prospect that, in spite of short-term variations, there will be a chronic and increasing tendency for the terms of trade to be adverse to those industrialist countries which do not include large primary-producing areas.” Salter further pointed out that the self-sufficiency argument does not hold in the case of Iraq since “Her rich oil supplies require foreign markets and provide the resources which enable her to import advantageously all the manufactured goods she needs as an addition to those which she can produce economically.” A case for industrialization can be made for countries whose population is already too great for the limited land available. “Here,” he argues, “under penalty of starva- tion or semi-starvation, industrial production is a necessity.” In the case of Iraq, he states, this does not apply, and “will not do so for many years to come. On the contrary, the poten- tial increase in cultivable land largely exceeds the labor re- quired for it.” In short, the basic argument of the Bank Mission, Iversen, and Salter is that forced industrialization should be avoided. The Arthur D. Little Report (1956), which proposed a com- prehensive plan for immediate industrial development, was generally in sympathy with the above view. In recommending specified industries the report applied the following criteria: 1. The proposed industry must be able to produce at a cost below the landed price of comparable imported goods or materials before import duty is levied. “If an industry can produce goods in Iraq at a price equal to or lower than the landed price without import duty, its establishment is truly economic. In the future it may be desirable to apply a less stringent test, but at the moment a number of industrial opportunities promise a profitability that does not need ad- ditional assistance. It is clearly desirable that they should be established first.” 2. The technical processes of the proposed industries must have been in successful use elsewhere for a reasonable period of time. 168 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 3. Because of the present limitations of the domestic market, several industries were recommended which will produce mainly for the export market. “Improved levels of national income can be obtained only by fuller utilization of domestic economic resources. As Iraq’s two great resources are agri- cultural and chemical, development cannot proceed on the basis of the internal domestic market alone.” Some of the principal factors contributing to lack of in- dustrial development in Iraq follow the familiar pattern in underdeveloped countries. Lack of technical knowledge and industrial labor; inadequate markets and marketing facilities; lack of stock market and banking institutions and the inability or unwillingness to invest in industrial enterprises. Savings in the past were either hoarded (in the form of gold, silver, or jewelry) or invested in land, urban property, or commerce where the capital was believed to be more secure and the returns much higher. For the above reasons, industrial expansion in recent years is almost exclusively sponsored by the state. Expansion has taken three forms: (1) State enterprises mainly financed by the Development Board. The major part of industrial invest- ment in Iraq goes to these industries. (2) Enterprises initiated and financed by both private capital and the government mainly through the government Industrial Bank. (3) Private enterprises which, however, do receive extensive aid in the form of loans, tax exemptions, and tariff protection. Each of these will be discussed separately. State Enterprises Major industrial projects in Iraq are usually undertaken by the Development Board. The allocations of this agency for industrial development have increased each year since its establishment. In the first Six-Year Plan (1951-56) alloca- tions amounted to 31 million dinars. In the second program (1955–59) they rose to 43 million and in the third plan (1955- 60) they rose further to 67 million. It should be noted that in the previous two plans the budgeted targets were never reached, mainly because technical studies were not complete. Most of the Board’s enterprises are still either under con- INDUSTRIALIZATION 169 struction or in the planning stage. However, the first results began to appear in 1955 with the emergence of the state oil- refining industry. The State Refining Industry The creation of a refining industry in Iraq has been the subject of government and public concern since the genesis of the oil industry. Up to 1951 the production of the Alawand refinery did not exceed 375,000 tons a year and considerable quantities of refined products were imported from Abadan in Iran. After the Abadan refinery was closed down in 1951, pro- duction at Alawand was stepped up to 492,000 tons in 1952, and in order to close the gap between domestic'supplies and requirements a new refinery was hastily constructed by the government at Muftiyah near Basrah. It was built largely from improvised materials and was put into operation in September, 1952. In 1952 the government took the first steps to create a state refining industry capable of meeting the country’s require- ments. In that year it organized the Government Oil Re- fineries Administration (GORA) to be responsible for the administration of all government refineries. It also con- structed the Muftiyah refinery and purchased from the Khanaqin Oil Company its marketing facilities in Iraq and the Alawand Refinery. Since then three more plants have been constructed by the government. 1. The Dawrah Refinery. This refinery, located near Bagh- dad, was completed in 1955 at a total cost of 10.5 million dinars. It was designed to have a capacity of 24,000 barrels of crude per day, but has proved capable of handling 27,000 b/d, and if necessary its capacity can be stepped up to 30,000 b/d. It produces gasoline, kerosene, gas oil, diesel oil, fuel oil, and Bunker “C” oil. The refinery commenced operations in June, 1955 with a staff of about 1,000 workers. Plans are already in progress to expand its capacity to 40,000 barrels per day. Crude oil for the refinery is supplied by a new government twelve-inch 135-mile pipeline extending between the main 170 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ I.P.C. pipeline system at Baiji (K2) and Dawrah. The refinery was sited at Dawrah because of its proximity to Baghdad City, which consumes about 40 per cent of the country’s total demand for refined products. The refinery is largely self- sufficient. It has adequate storage facilities for both refined and crude oil, a tin-can factory, filling stations, maintenance workshops, power plant, and electricity generating station. The Dawrah Lubricant and Asphalt Plant. This plant is an ex- tension of the Dawrah refinery. It is financed by the Develop- ment Board and was scheduled for completion in April, 1957 at a total cost of 3.6 million dinars. The plant is designed to produce annually 25,000 tons of various grades of lubricants in addition to 18,000 tons of road asphalt.” The Qayarah Asphalt Refinery. This refinery located at Qayarah, south of Mosul, was financed by the Development Board and completed in early 1956 at an estimated total cost of 2.2 million dinars. It now employs some 250 workers and has an annual production capacity of 60,000 tons of asphalt and 29,000 tons of various gas oils. A drum manufacturing plant with a capacity of 600 drums daily was recently erected near the refinery. It is said to be able to produce asphalt at eight dinars a ton as against thirty dinars per ton which Iraq had to pay for imported asphalt. The Muftiyah Asphalt Refinery. This is a small plant located at the refinery near Basrah. It was completed in 1955 and has a production capacity of 6,000 tons of asphalt a year.” By the end of 1957 Iraq was to have attained a large meas- ure of, if not full, self-sufficiency in refined products. Since 1955 it has not imported for local consumption any motor spirit, kerosene, gas oil, or fuel oil. Aviation oil continues to be imported, although plans are in progress for its domestic production. Iraq will also produce all its needs of asphalt and most lubricating oils. Between 1952 and 1957 state investment in the refining industry reached some 16.3 million dinars, excluding the costs of the Muftiyah refinery and the purchase price of the Alawand refinery and the marketing facilities of the Khanaqin Oil Co. This investment is justified for many reasons. Pro- duction costs are lower than the costs of similar imported INDUSTRIALIZATION 171 products. The state will not only be able to make a profit, but may be able to sell at lower prices. This is particularly true of lubricants and asphalt. Local consumption of refined products is expected to rise steadily. For instance, imports of lubricating oils rose in value from 0.6 million dinars in 1949 to 1. 1 million in 1955. Between 1951 and 1955 local consumption of kerosene rose from 31.6 million gallons in 1951 to 61.6 million in 1956; fuel oil from 895 million to 135.7 million; motor spirit from 26.6 million to 53.7 million; gas oil from 9. 1 million to 32.3 million gallons. When the industry is operating at full capacity it will probably be able to provide employment for some 5,000 workers. Finally, it will help increase the skilled labor force in the country. Mosul Textile Factory The consumption of cotton fabrics has declined consider- ably in recent years in Iraq. For instance, in 1949 Iraq im- ported 51.5 million square meters of cotton yard goods. By 1956 imports declined to 27.9 million square meters. Part of the decline is due to local production, but part of it is also due to lack of demand and the shift in tastes. This is evidenced by the rise in the imports of rayon fabrics. Such imports rose from 4.2 million square meters in 1949 to sixty-six million in 1955. Although the domestic market for cotton fabrics was not expanding, the Development Board properly concluded that the market was large enough to justify the establishment of a factory using local cotton for raw material. Consequently, construction of such a plant, located near Mosul in the north, began in 1954 and was completed in late 1956 at an estimated total cost of 4.9 million dinars. This figure included costs of housing for workers (894,000 dinars) and the cost of a training program (62,000 dinars). The housing is not yet complete. The factory has a production capacity of twenty million square meters of cotton fabric a year. It is believed that its production, together with the production of other private factories, will meet the major part of Iraq’s present needs for cheap cotton yard goods. The factory will commence opera- INDUSTRIALIZATION 173 The Sugar Industry Up to 1956 Iraq produced no sugar. Its consumption of this commodity has been steadily increasing in recent years. The volume of sugar imports rose from 52,000 tons in 1949 to 140,500 tons in 1956. The establishment of a local industry would indeed be attractive, if it were feasible, since there is an expanding domestic market. The establishment of such an industry has been under study since 1951, when the International Bank Mission recommended that the project be held in abeyance until there was a reasonable certainty that the necessary raw mater- ials would be available locally. Since then the government has been experimenting with growing a variety of sugar raw materials in Iraq. Sugar beets were found to be suitable for cultivation in the north and the government encouraged the development of sugar beet culture there. In 1956 the Development Board felt justified in proceeding with the project. On May 9, 1956, it awarded a contract for two million dinars to a German firm for the construction of a plant near Mosul to be completed in November, 1957. The estimated total costs of the plant, including workers’ housing, is three million dinars. The plant will produce 10,000 tons of sugar a year from locally-grown beets and, until such time as beet production in Iraq is sufficient to keep it operating the whole year, it will also refine 25,000 tons of imported raw sugar annually.19 In 1956 a new law was in the process of being drafted to make the manufacture of sugar a state monopoly. Its stated purpose is the encouragement of local sugar beet agriculture, since, it is suggested, private sugar manufacturers may turn to imported raw materials, and in this way destroy the infant sugar beet culture.11 Plans for the possible expansion of the sugar industry are already in progress. The Development Board is considering establishing another factory at Sulaimaniya”. It was also suggested by consultants that a sugar plant might eventually be established in Basrah, since soil and climatic conditions INDUSTRIALIZATION I75 Industrial Planning From the previous discussion it can be seen that between 1952 and 1956 investment in state industries exclusive of the refining industry came to some fifteen million dinars. In each case the industry depends on local raw materials, caters to the domestic market only, and was selected after years of study and planning. The state industrial program fell behind its scheduled targets, but in the long run it seems much more advisable to fall behind schedules than to be hurried by various pressures into establishing, without ade- quate study, industries which might later prove inefficient and uneconomical—provided, of course, that “adequate study” is not taken as a blanket excuse for laxity and in- effectiveness. Many new industries are either being planned or are ready to be launched by the Development Board or some other government agency. The Little Report, mentioned previous- ly, proposed a phased program for implementation in a period of some six years (see Table 29). The program con- templates creating a chemical industry with a variety of by- products, establishing date industries, a steel-rolling mill and a steel furnace, and expansion and improvement of the agricultural products, metal products, and building materials industries. TABLE 29 SUGGESTED PHASING of INDUSTRIALIZATION PROGRAM (The Little Report:1956) PHASE I PHASE II PHASE III PHASE IV Rayon Textile Rayon Textile Rayon Plant Steel Furnace Mill Mill Plastic Ma- Plastic Ma- Sulfur Extrac- Steel-rolling terials Plants: terials Plant: tion Plant Mill Ethylene Polyvinyl Paper Plant Fertilizer Poly- Chloride Date Industries: Plant ethylene Caustic Soda Syrup Plant Plant Animal Feed Date Industries: Plant Syrup Plant Animal Feed Plant 176 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ PHASE I PHASE II PHASE III PHASE IV Extension & Extension & Extension & Extension & Improvement of: Improvement of: Improvement of: Improvement of: Agricultural (Same as (Same as (Same as Products First Phase) Previous Previous Industry Phase) Phase) Metal Products Industry Building Materials Industry Approximate Total Investment in Million Dinars: 14 13.5 8 Source: The Little Report, p. 6. The Six-Year Plan (1955-60) of the Development Board seems to follow fairly closely the program suggested above. In addition to electrification (to be discussed below) the Board’s program contemplates the following breakdown: Estimated Expenditures: Industry 1956–60 In Millions of Dinars 1. Extension and Improvement of: Agricultural Products Industry Metal Products Industry Building Materials Industry 2. JNew Industries: Sulfur Extraction Plant Paper Mill Date Syrup Plant Date Animal Feed Plant Rayon Textile Mill Steel-Rolling Mill Steel Furnace 12. 3 3. New Plants (Under Study): Fertilizer Plant Plastic Materials Plant Caustic Soda Plant Mining Projects 11. 5 Natural Gas Pipeline 10. 7 4. Development of Other Industries, including Atomic Energy. 4.67 Total: 39.17 178 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ countries and the obstacle of tariff barriers; her geographical position places her in a favorable position to supply the ex- panding Near and Far Eastern markets.” The Report then proceeds to suggest the possible lines along which a chemical industry might be developed in Iraq. It states: The nature of the chemical industry is such that joint prod- ucts or by-products often result from the productive process. The economics are generally such that, unless markets can be found for these extra products, it is not profitable to produce the main product. As a result, the chemical industry consists of a series of complex, interdependent plants; despite the large sales of products to other industries, the chemical industry has now become its own best customer. Products of one plant are used by another in manufacturing a product required by an external industry; the second plant in turn produces joint or by-products that are used by a third plant; and so on. The possible line of development of a chemical industry in Iraq illustrates this interdependence. Investigation has disclosed that the establishment in Iraq of plants to produce rayon and paper and to recover sulfur from natural gas is economically justified. A rayon plant and a paper mill of the recommended size would between them require 5,600 tons annually of caustic soda. This, coupled with the demand of existing industries, would by 1960 result in a probable total demand of 8,000 tons of caustic soda, which would justify its production in Iraq. The only method of producing this chemical that would be economical on this scale, the electrolytic method, would result in the production of about 0.9 ton of chlorine for each ton of caustic soda produced. Unless markets can be found for this it would be cheaper to import the caustic soda. The proposed plastic-material industry offers a potential market for chlorine, as it is required as a raw material for polyvinyl chloride. Natural gas can be used to produce ethylene, a raw material for both polyvinyl chloride and polyethylene, which are widely used plastics with growing world markets. The sulfur in the Kirkuk natural gas could supply, in addition to export markets, the rayon plant with the sulfur and sulfuric acid it would need. At the same time it would make it possible to produce fertilizer in Iraq, as sulfur would be required in substantial quantities to produce ammonium sulfate. Ammonium sulfate, or the other nitrogenous fertilizers, ammonium nitrate a N3 nak 13 Anod 30 180m hº ^ A N 1 AA10 d. 1. Nyºnd a N3 na H13 --ATOd 1. Nynae 20 180THO na N I A AT 04 1. Nynd 3 NB in AH13 wws.wg ºwo nwu mu w M 0 180 wae N0 Aww. sinn i w 3 T 11x31 Mae N $3$ n 83 H10 w00s º 118 nwº w00S O 11 s nwº 1. Nyºnd 3 M I won ho w00s. O 11 s nwo |(9961 w0438 3ıurfaſſu) Ôw w I w0w sinn i w 3 T 11x31 Q no Awusmºwi Twº Ing M0 03ısı bºms 1. Nw nº w I NOWww. · · · · ·… 31 wae nºms Wml | MO www. $3$ n w 3 H1 0 0 10 w O 18 na n ms 1. Nyºnd 31 wae nºns wºn I NOwww. u Nwºnd Q. 10 w o 1 w mae'n ns A83 A 0038 w mae n ns × m × 1 × GWO Tww.mlw'N --★ → ← → ← → ← → ← → 180 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ and urea, would require ammonia, which could also be manu- factured from natural gas. Between these two extremes—a chemical industry (which is fairly large, interdependent, and for which domestic and foreign markets have to be created or found), and a build- ing materials industry (consisting of medium or small in- dependent production units, with domestic market demand far ahead of supply)—lie the agricultural and animal products industries. In this case, both domestic and foreign markets exist with considerable potential for growth. An industry also exists but requires some expansion and vast improve- ment. The leather products industry is a good example. Iraq produces its own leather in addition to some imports. Local tanneries are protected by high import tariffs. Yet local leather is generally of poor quality, has a limited range of colors, and is expensive compared with foreign products. At the same time, the annual per capita consumption of shoes is 0.2 pair.” It is quite obvious that, with the rising standard of living, a substantial increase in the consumption of shoes is most likely. If the consumption rises to no more than one pair a year per person, this would entail a fivefold increase. Measures for improvement would have to begin at the source and proceed all along the line, such as improvement in live- stock nutrition, protection from diseases, etc., forcing tanner- ies to improve their processes, possibly through removing tariffs on imports of leather, and so on. Another illustration is the dairy products industry. The consumption of dairy products is extremely low in Iraq, but with the rise in the levels of income, a substantial increase is to be expected. Hence, there is a potentially expanding market for products of modern dairy industries. Similarly, there is a potential domestic market for vege- table oils and fats. The per capita consumption of these products in Iraq is 4.3 kilograms annually, as against a world average of ten kilograms and a United States average of 30 kilo- grams.” There are two modern factories at Baghdad more than capable of meeting the present local market demands, 182 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ in the city of Baghdad, where the standard of living is gener- ally higher than the rest of the country, showed that people spent only a little over 1.5 per cent of their incomes on household furniture and utensils.” In other words, they bought only absolute minimum necessities. Since the houses are al- most bare, it is therefore reasonable to assume that people, with the rise in their real income, would want to spend more on furnishing their homes, an important prestige factor. The estimated rate of some 22,000 housing units to be con- structed annually by 1960 will, in effect, lead to a substantial increase in the demand for household goods, since new houses need furnishings. The demand will not be only for more, but also better furniture. The houses being built or planned are much better in design and quality than those the public, especially in the lower income groups, has been used to. There would be little inclination to furnish a hut nicely, but there would be much incentive to do so in a nice house, signi- fying a change in social status. In any case, the potential local market demand would probably justify establishment or expansion in the near future of modern light industries manufacturing such articles as kitchen utensils (in oversupply at the time of the report), metal furniture, kerosene stoves, and heaters (widely used in Iraq), air coolers (now being manufactured there), small low-cost refrigerators with imported motors, and similar articles. 3. Service Industries. There is an urgent need for service industries to supply other industries, such as those of agri- cultural machinery and motor transport, with spare parts and components and to provide servicing and maintenance facilities. The lack of spare parts and service facilities usually results in long delays, considerable expense to owners, and waste to the country. The Little Report suggests the estab- lishment of central machine shops and foundries in Baghdad, Basrah, Mosul, and Kirkuk (the four main cities), and a central garage in Baghdad. The machine shops could organ- ize mobile repair units to service agricultural equipment in the various provinces. In Turkey this procedure has proved fairly successful. INDUSTRIALIZATION 183 The discussion on industrial planning above serves to illus- trate two main points. First, the wide range of opportunities for industrialization to meet the demands of the present and future local market. Second, the type of policy questions the Development Board will be seized with for the next five years. For example: which industries should receive priority? Which industries should be undertaken by the Board and which by private capital? Which private industries should re- ceive assistance from the Board? What are the best ways of providing assistance? What organizational structures should be established to administer state industries and to super- vise private industry? What are the best ways of insuring efficiency, high standards, and high quality? What are the best ways to increase the skilled labor force at such a short notice? The list could go on. State Participation in Private Enterprise The chief instrumentality of state assistance to private in- dustry is the Industrial Bank. The concept of direct state aid to industry was put into practice in 1936, when the State Agricultural-Industrial Bank was organized. The assistance which the bank afforded industry was insignificant. The total value of its industrial loans—its only contribution—from 1936 to 1945 came to some 64,000 dinars.22 In 1946 it was replaced by the Industrial Bank and the Agricultural Bank. In 1946/47 the government created the Industrial Bank with a capital of half a million dinars. In 1952, its nominal capital was raised to three million. According to its charter, its functions are: (1) to grant loans for the establishment of new industries or the expansion or improvement of ex- isting industries, (2) to participate in stock industrial enter- prises, (3) to start new industries on its own initiative if necessary, and (4) to offer various services connected with the import of machinery and materials and the export of prod- ucts. 23 In many ways the Bank has been very successful. It has contributed materially to the development of private industry through capital participation, and has shown substantial profits. Table 30 shows twelve companies in which the Bank INDUSTRIALIZATION 185 Bank was created is to assist in the industrial development of the country and not to involve government in business. Con- sequently, once a company is established as a going concern and its success is assured, the bank tries to dispose of its stock to the public. This has two objectives: (1) to release the Bank’s funds for investment in new industries, and (2) to help create a very badly needed capital market and to educate the public in the use of stocks. TABLE 31 LOANs of THE INDUSTRIAL BANK Total Value of Tear JNo. of Loans Loans in Dinars 1948/49 35 50,298 1949/50 81 132,110 1950/51 87 281,225 1951/52 151 655,380 1952/53 Il-3. Il.a. 1953/54 172 734,140 1954/55 242 1,367,602 Source: Industrial Bank, 2nd and 3rd Annual Reports for the years 1948–49, 1949–50; National Bank of Iraq, Annual Report for 1952; Statistical Abstract for 1955, p. 181. On the other hand, the Bank has been criticized on two counts. It seems to set a high value on profits and has a ten- dency to measure its success in that context. Although the Bank should make some profit in order to create public con- fidence in its operations, it was not created to make money but to assist and develop industry. Therefore, it should partic- ipate not only in ventures that show considerable profits but also in industries which benefit the country as a whole, even though their profit margin may be low. The Bank has a tendency to participate only in fairly large enterprises. It should in addition help in the establishment and improvement of handicraft industries and small repair 186 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ shops. This would contribute to social stability since it helps to create a class of independent artisans in the cities. The second main function of the Bank is to assist in the im- provement and expansion of industry through loans. The Bank has become increasingly active in this field as a glance at Table 31 will show. In 1948/49—the second year of its operation—it made thirty-five loans totaling in value 50,- 298 dinars. Six years later, in 1954/55, the number of its loans rose to 242 with a total value of 1,367,602 dinars. They vary in amount from 150 to 150,000 dinars and more, and are extended to small and large establishments, although the latter seem to receive the lion’s share. It is apparent that the Bank is playing an increasingly vital role in the industrialization of Iraq. It will be recalled that among the major allocations of the Development Board for the 1955-60 industrial program were included unspecified amounts for the Industrial Bank and the Ministry of Eco- nomics. Apparently, insofar as private industry is concerned, the Bank is to become the executive arm of the Board. Lord Salter recommended that where industrialization was concerned the Board should separate policy function from administrative functions and should delegate administrative functions to a separate body. This was endorsed by the Little Report. The report specifically recommended that the Indus- trial Bank be reorganized and transferred to the Ministry of Development, with additional loan and capital funds above those now at its disposal. It further recommended that the Board facilitate the establishment of an Industrial Develop- ment Finance Corporation owned by private and state banks. Such a corporation should have a line of credit from the Board. Its function would be to provide capital and loan funds to private industry. Once it is formed it should take over the functions of the Industrial Bank with regard to private in- dustry. The Development Board would, however, remain the policy-making body determining the scope and direction of industrialization. The report cites the Industrial Bank of Turkey as a successful example of an industrial bank in the Middle East. INDUSTRIALIZATION 187 Private Industry Basically, the rise of modern private industry dates back to the war years. From 1936 to 1943 total capital investment in industry came to a little over one million dinars.” During the war, shortages of manufactured goods and expectations of high profits resulted in some industrial expansion. From 1943 to 1948 private industrial investment totaled 3.1 million dinars.” Some of the factories that were established were in- efficient and could survive only as long as there was no com- petition from foreign goods. Consequently, in the years im- mediately following the war, these industries experienced considerable distress.26 In any case, by the end of 1952, in addition to other indus- tries, there were ten large-scale industries totaling in number twenty-two establishments.” Their total capital was nearly five million dinars (4,835,755), and the value of their annual output was 4.4 million dinars (4,424,339). They employed 4,553 workers with an annual wage bill of close to 600,000 dinars (599,366).28 Since 1952 there has been substantial development. In 1954, according to the census, there were ninety-five firms employ- ing 100 workers and over each, with a total labor force of 18,600 workers.” Four of these employed 1,000 workers and over each, with a total of 7,800 workers (see Table 28). These figures exclude the oil industry. It can be stated—probably without much exaggeration— that since 1950 private industry has come into being almost exclusively as a result of state effort. The activities of the In- dustrial Bank have already been discussed at some length. But in addition to direct financial aid, new industries receive extensive privileges. In 1950 a new law (No. 43 of 1950), called the Encouragement of Industry Law, replaced an old one passed in 1929. The new law awards new industries the following benefits: (1) exemption from income and surtaxes for four years, (2) exemption from import duty on machinery, material, equipment, and spare parts, (3) exemption from property tax for ten years, and (4) use of government land not in excess of 25,000 square meters, free of rent for ten years. 188 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Also, industry is afforded varying degrees of protection. For instance, heavy import duties are imposed on leather, while the importation of cotton yarn and beer is entirely pro- hibited. Other goods are subject to a quota system. The main obstacles which have so far stood in the way of the development of private industry are being gradually removed. The foremost is probably lack of capital, with a concomitant hesitancy or reluctance to invest in industry. Through state financial aid and various other inducements the volume of private capital invested in industry is increasing year by year. As knowledge of the “mysteries” of industry in- creases and the benefits from it become clear, it is reasonable to expect that the rate of investment will increase and that private capital will become more venturesome in spirit. The second main obstacle is lack of technical knowledge and shortage of skilled labor. This, again, is being rectified by the state. The third main obstacle is market limitation. As has been demonstrated, the market in Iraq for many commodities is no longer static. It is either expanding or expandable. On the whole, however, state investment in industry for some years to come will far exceed private investment. If the present trend continues, the state may eventually own most— if not all—the most important industrial enterprises in the country. This raises the question of the desirability of state ownership of industry versus private ownership. It is argued that state investment in industry is only a tem- porary measure, necessitated by the lack of private capital and the immediate need and/or desire for a measure of in- dustrialization to utilize valuable natural and human re- sources now completely idle or only partially exploited. The wisdom and the need for the present state action are beyond question. There is little doubt that, if there is to be any significant industrialization, major investment will have to be by the state since it alone has the necessary capital. How- ever, there is a real possibility that what began as a temporary measure, until a capital market could be developed, may become permanent. Three main arguments support this conclusion: 1. Experience in other countries has shown that once an INDUSTRIALIZATION 189 organization is created, it becomes extremely difficult to dis- lodge it, for it generally entrenches itself and develops vested interests. Particularly in government, temporary measures and organizations have a way of becoming permanent. 2. Ownership of industry by the state may become more and more attractive as a revenue-raising instrument. As the volume of profits from state industries increases, there will probably be considerable reluctance to give up this lucrative source of revenue. On the contrary, this may provide further temptation to increase state industrial holdings. 3. Although there is no conclusive evidence based on actual study, there is reason to believe that, generally speaking, the vocal segments of the Iraqi public and particularly the in- telligentsia, would prefer state ownership of the important industries to private ownership. This statement would probab- ly hold true in all countries of the Middle East. Conceptually, state ownership has the advantage of appealing to the public in terms of “public property” to be used for the general good rather than to enrich the few. Conversely, private ownership of industry brings with it mental association with “capitalism,” a term which in the Middle East carries unpleasant and some- times even sinister connotations. The ultimate outcome will probably depend on state policy. At present the tendency, whether by choice or necessity, seems to be toward more state ownership. It remains to be seen whether this trend will continue. Electrification The consumption of electricity in Iraq is still almost entirely restricted to the four main cities of Baghdad, Kirkuk, Basrah, and Mosul. Among them, they account for about 90 per cent of the consumption of electricity in the country. The other ten per cent is distributed among the other smaller towns. No electricity is consumed in rural areas. Between 1947 and 1955 consumption increased over eight times (see Table 32). However, as can be seen from the table, the greatest part of the increase took place in the two cities of Baghdad and Kirkuk. Over 90 per cent of the electricity in Kirkuk is consumed by the oil company. INDUSTRIALIZATION 191 in the city of Baghdad (other than oil). Finally, it shows an increasing use of electricity for other purposes than lighting. This indicates that electrical appliances are in much greater use in the country. Iraq possesses plentiful supplies of low-cost thermal and potential hydroelectric energy resources. Nevertheless, until 1956 these resources were not utilized, although electric supply is inadequate and comparatively expensive. The question of increasing the supply of electricity has been under discussion and study for several years. Lately it has become more urgent, since the demand for domestic use has been increasing steadily and the development of in- dustry depends to a large measure on the availability of low- cost electric power. An electrification program was included in the first Six-Year Plan, but no concrete steps were taken until 1956. The program contemplates the gradual electrification of the whole country. Present plans are based on the use of natural gas and oil as sources of energy. This is because under present conditions of low demand (i.e., in relation to potential production capacity) and low-cost thermal fuels, the com- paratively high cost of constructing hydroelectric plants would be unjustified. Thirdly, intensive cost studies have shown that electric power can be sold to industry and other consumers at two fils (0.28 cents) per unit. The program also calls for the construction of a power plant at Dibbis near Kirkuk to serve northern Iraq, with an initial generating capacity of 60,000 kilowatts, another at Baghdad to serve central Iraq with a capacity of 60,000 kilo- watts” and a third at Basrah to serve southern Iraq, with a capacity of 45,000 kilowatts.31 The Development Board allo- cated 12,669,000 dinars for electrification in its 1955-60 plan. In July 1956 the Board awarded contracts to two German firms to supply and install turbogenerators, boilers, and other equipment for the Dibbis and Baghdad power plants. The Dibbis station will use Kirkuk natural gas and the Baghdad station crude oil, but the Baghdad plant will revert to natural gas at a later date. According to the contract one generator (15,000 k.w.) in each station should be installed and handed 192 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ over to the Board not later than twenty-one months after the signing of the contract. The due date will then be in the spring of 1958. The latest information available indicates that the Board was ready in October 1956 to award contracts for the Basrah station to be completed in 1959.3% Communications Administration, Nature, and Problems of the Transport System. Control over the transportation system in Iraq is vested in several government agencies. The railways are state- owned and are operated by the Railway Administration, an autonomous agency which has its own budget independent of the ordinary government budget. The Railway Administra- tion is also responsible for operating the Iraqi Airways. Control over and maintenance of the road system is vested in the Public Works Department under the Minister of Com- munications and Public Works. Roads within municipal boundaries are the responsibility of municipal authorities. The construction of major roads and bridges is carried out by the Development Board. The Port of Basrah is operated by the Basrah Port Directorate which, like the Railway Adminis- tration, is an autonomous body with its own separate budget. Geography and demography have bequeathed two distinct features to Iraq’s transportation system. First, the major part of the traffic in Iraq moves along a north-south axis from Mosul to Basrah. This is the backbone of the transportation system. Southwards must move the great quantities of grain and other produce for the domestic and export markets; northwards go all goods entering Basrah, the country’s only port and its southern extremity. Second, the system is con- centrated mainly in the populated and cultivated eastern part of the country. It converges on two main points: Bagh- dad, the capital and trade center, and Basrah. A good transportation system is essential to economic growth. Expansion in agricultural production, for instance, is meaningless unless there are adequate facilities to carry the produce to market centers. Industrial development is also dependent in a similar manner. | 194 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ standard gauge, connects Baghdad with Mosul and continues to Syria and up to Turkey and from there to Europe. It is the only railroad link which Iraq has with its neighbors. The railway system consists entirely of single track lines. Up to 1950 the system was more than adequate for the country’s needs and was estimated to be able to carry about 15 per cent more than its 1950 average. Expansion was never- theless deemed necessary because a sharp increase in the movement of goods resulting from the development program was anticipated. Moreover, a large part of the rolling stock and engines was very old and needed immediate replacement. In 1951 the International Bank Mission made the following recommendations: 1. Extension of the railroad system to meet expected rise in the movement of goods and passengers. 2. Gradual conversion from steam to diesel traction. It was argued that diesel traction is much more efficient, es- pecially since diesel fuel is available locally at favorable prices. 3. Conversion from narrow gauge to standard gauge throughout the system. It was suggested that large segments of the narrow-gauge lines were old and would need replace- ment in any case. In this way, too, the system would be unified and facilitate the movement of goods and passengers. As things stood, goods transported from Basrah to Mosul, for instance, would have to go up to Baghdad on the narrow- gauge line and there be moved to the standard-gauge line and then transported to Mosul. In the words of the Mission, “the operation is costly, inefficient, and time-consuming.”84 The Iraqi Railways administration, supported by Lord Salter, did not agree with the last recommendation of the Mission. It is in favor of building a new standard-gauge line from Baghdad to Basrah and, at the same time, retaining the old meter-gauge line. In this way the country would have two complete systems: standard gauge from the Syrian border- Mosul-Baghdad-Basrah and meter gauge from Erbil-Kirkuk- Baghdad-Basrah. Transhipment of goods at Baghdad would thus become unnecessary. The Administration and Lord Salter argue that converting 196 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ The road system in 1950-51 was limited, and road condi- tions were (and still are) very bad. Road traffic was very light and the number of vehicles in the country even now continues to be comparatively small (see Table 34). TABLE 34 REGISTERED VEHICLES IN IRAQ 1945 1950 1955 1956 Passenger cars 3,771 11,438 20,603 23,815 Buses Im.a. 3,007- 3,311 3,451 Trucks 2,017 5,907 9,043 10,543 Motorcycles 127 1,626 2,091 2,420 Source: Statistical Abstracts, 1950, p. 249; 1955, p. 213; 1956, p. 135. • Source: IBRD, p. 330. The broad objectives of the road-building program were laid down in 1950 by an Interdepartmental Committee of Government Officials, assisted by a foreign expert. The Com- mittee devised a ten-year program with the following order of priorities: (1) trunk roads connecting Baghdad with Basrah and Kirkuk, (2) roads in areas which do not and are not likely to have railroad connections, (3) roads between centers which are served or are likely to be served by rail, and (4) strengthen- ing the existing paved roads. There has been no basic change in policy since the Develop- ment Board took over. Roads, in the words of Lord Salter, are to serve as “ribs in the transport anatomy with the railroad system as the backbone.” Emphasis is on trunk roads connect- ing main centers and on feeder roads connecting rural areas with main centers to facilitate the movement of agricultural products. Whenever possible, roads will not follow the rail- road routes, in order to avoid duplication and prevent waste- ful competition. The basic difference between the Board’s program and that of the Committee is one of timing and speed. The former is much more extensive and geared to be completed in a 198 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ TABLE 35 RoAD AND BRIDGE CONSTRUCTION IN IRAQ (1952—January 1, 1956) Road Design: a. Location Surveys: Completed 75% completed Under 75% completed b. Construction Plans: Completed 50% completed Under 50% completed Road Construction: a. Completed: By P. W. D." By Contract b. Under Construction: By P. W. D. By Contract c. Contracted but not started Bridge Construction: a. Completed: By P. W. D. By Contract b. Under Construction: By P. W. D. By Contract 101 42 60 329 Kilometers 765 116 685 227 143 389 85 JNumber 18 25 Source: U.S.A., I.C.A., Baghdad, Iraq Progresses, Baghdad, August, 1956, n.p. * Public Works Department. | INDUSTRIALIZATION 199 º Navigation In recent years river navigation has ceased to be a significant factor in the country’s transportation system. This is because river conditions have deteriorated steadily by heavy silting, shifts of the channels, and a rising of the river bed. Emphasis is now on using the river system for irrigation rather than navigation. Consequently, the plans of the Development Board do not include improvement of river transportation. Basrah, Iraq’s only port for general cargo, was first devel- oped as a modern port by the British during World War I. Since then it has experienced considerable expansion and improvement. It now handles very efficiently an ever-increas- ing volume of passenger and cargo traffic (see Table 36). Its varied activities extend along the Shatt al-Arab from the main wharves at Magil (Basrah) to Fao, the oil terminal. TABLE 36 MovemENT of OCEAN-GoING VESSELS AT THE PORT OF BASRAH 1945 1950 1953 1955 1956 Vessels: Arrived 128 372 430 434 453 Departed 128 363 424 434 457 Cargo Tonnage: Imported 147,769 238,725 478,145 727,446 659,086 Exported 316,958 687,497 719,417 561,194 475,613 Passengers: Arrived 2,344 16,415 14,466 20,753 15,670 Departed 428 16,075 12,830 16,224 11,808 Source: Statistical Abstract, for 1950, p. 257, and 1955, p. 118; 1956, p. 128. At various times the Iraqi government has considered the construction of a new port at Umm Qasr, on an inlet of the Persian Gulf south of Basrah. The project has a certain appeal in case of war and in view of the present congestion at Basrah. Both the Bank Mission and Lord Salter recommended that the project be abandoned, at least for the present. There INDUSTRIALIZATION 201 TABLE 37 AIR TRAFFIC IN IRAQ 1947 1950 1953 1955 1956 JNo. of Planes: Arrived 5,394 5,443 5,995 6,716 7,813 Departed 5,394 5,443 5,995 6,716 7,813 Passengers: Arrived 12,376 21,453 31,412 45,818 57,744 Departed 12,882 44,448 30,962 42,976 57,204 In Transit 31,672 44,456 43,921 47,646 40,500 Source: Statistical Abstract, 1950, pp. 263-270; 1955, p. 123; and 1956, p. 133. It has become fairly apparent that the facilities of the Baghdad Airport are no longer adequate to meet the in- crease in air traffic. In its 1955-60 program, the Develop- ment Board allocated 8.85 million dinars for the expansion of the existing Baghdad airport, the construction of a new modern airport (at Baghdad) and other airports throughout the country. Apparently, when the allocation was made no final policy decision had been taken whether to enlarge the present airport or to build a new one. This is indicated by the recommendation of the Council of Ministers to the Develop- ment Board in October, 1956 that it take immediate steps either to build a new modern international airport or to en- large and improve the existing Baghdad airport to meet the proposed standards.” Summary and Conclusions The present industrialization program in Iraq represents the first major step which the country has taken toward in- dustrialization. No doubt it is also the first phase. The pro- gram has certain distinct features: 1. For all practical purposes it is sponsored, planned, financed, and executed by the state. Even private industrial enterprises receive, in one way or the other, state financial aid in addition to other benefits. 2. It is organic in the sense that it is primarily designed to put into use idle national resources which have been either completely neglected or only partially exploited. PART IV. The Department of Human Resources “IO THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION No more serious challenge confronts Iraq today than that of education, both as a means of building a new social structure and as an instrument of technological progress. The problem is one of vast dimensions, In 1947 when the first census was taken, only eight per cent of the population (excluding nomads) could read and write. Of the total male popula- tion about 14 per cent were literate, while the corresponding figure for females was three per cent. The problem is not only vast, but its solution has assumed critical urgency in view of Iraq’s development program. There has to be some balance, a proportional relationship, between material and intellectual progress. In order to run efficiently, the new physical plant abuilding in agriculture, industry, etc., has to be manned and maintained by a fairly skilled and literate labor force. However, the time gap be- tween physical production and personnel training is wide. It takes two to four years to build a factory or a dam, but it takes a larger number of years to build up a skilled and intelligent labor force. The terms “skilled” and “intelligent” are used here in a broad sense. They include not only the ability to read and to manipulate machines, but also the ac- quisition and/or adaptation of philosophies, attitudes, be- 206 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ havior, and other intangible components necessary for a society which aspires to a higher standard of living. The tables that follow in this chapter serve to illustrate two central points: (1) the almost pathetic inadequacy of the educational establishment and (2) the desperate efforts that are being made (since 1950) to improve it and enlarge it. In Iraq, education is a state function. Authority, however, is divided among various government departments. The Ministry of Education has full administrative and financial responsibility for intermediate, secondary, vocational, and technical schools, teachers’ training schools, six colleges, and most of the students studying abroad at government expense. Until 1951 it also had similar authority over elementary schools, but in that year, with a view to decentralization, the government transferred responsibility for them to the Provincial Administrative Councils. The Ministry, however, retained supervisory powers and set the curriculum. Seven other colleges come under the jurisdiction of various other ministries, depending on the subject of specialization. Finally, the Development Board is responsible for the con- struction of schools and other educational institutions. In TABLE 38 ACTUAL ExPENDITUREs of THE MINISTRY OF EDUCATION, AND THEIR PERCENTILE RELATIONSHIP To Total Government ExPENDITURES Tear Thousand Dinars Percent 1920/21 130a 2.3 1925/26 171 4.2 1930/31 294 7.3 1935/36 431 9.6 1940/41 848 11.8 1945/46 1,612 9.0 1950/51 3,5998 14.0 1953/54 6,787 13.5 1956/57 10,560 16.3 1957/58 12,887° 18.3 Source: For 1920/21 to 1953/54, Ministry of Education, Annual Report for 1953/54; for 1956/57 and 1957/58, Education in Iraq, op. cit., p. 2. * All figures include costs of elementary education. * All figures exclude high cost of living allowances. * Estimated. THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 2O7 addition, the Board supports either directly or indirectly educational enterprises that come within the purview of the development concept as such. Table 38 shows actual expenditures of the Ministry of Education in selected years and their percentile relation- ship to total government expenditures. These include the costs of elementary education but exclude high cost of living allowances and the expenditures of colleges and other in- stitutions not attached to the Ministry. They also exclude expenditures of the Development Board. In the 1920’s expenditures began to rise slowly, and they registered appreciable increases during the 1930's. During the war years there was a considerable decline both in real terms and in percentage of the total budgetary figure. The increase in expenditures in 1945-46, for instance, was actually offset by the decline in the purchasing power of the dinar and a corresponding rise in the cost of materials and services. After the war, expenditures on education began to re- cover. In 1950/51, they reached a high of 14 per cent. Since then they have risen sharply year after year. In fact, the table does not show the full extent of the rise since, in the past, part of the expenditures used to go to school construction. The apparent percentage decline in 1953/54 is not real, for in that year the Development Board assumed full responsi- bility for the costs of school construction. The role of the Development Board in the field of education has increased considerably since it was organized in 1950. In the first program (1951-56) its projected activities were restricted to the building of schools, sending students abroad to study technical subjects—mainly to meet part of its own needs for skilled personnel—and to developing and improving research facilities. The conception of its role became broader in each succeed- ing program. In the 1955-60 plan there were included the establishment of technical schools, schools to develop agri- cultural education, a public library, swimming pools, and sports fields. In other words, in addition to increasing and improving the physical plant, the Board also became con- cerned with the development of human resources and skills. 208 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ TABLE 39 ALLocations of THE DEveLopMENT BoARD FoR EDUCATION: 1955-60 Dinars 1. Student Missions 1,650,000 2. Research and Laboratories 1,550,000 3. Scientific Institutes and Primary Schools 8,000,000 4. Other Scientific Institutes 750,000 5. Technical Schools 1,250,000 6. Schools and short courses to develop agricultural education 750,000 7. Iraqi University 2,000,000 8. Public Library 350,000 9. Students’ House 250,000 10. Swimming pools and sports fields 2,000,000 TOTAL 18,500,000 Elementary Education Iraq is committed to the ideal of universal literacy. The task is so formidable that only little progress has been made. The achievements between 1920 and 1950 are impressive in absolute terms, but are only “a drop in the bucket” in terms of ultimate goals. In 1920/21 there were eighty-eight primary schools with some 8,000 students. Thirty years later, in 1950/51, their number had increased to 1,101. In other words, they in- creased at the rate of some thirty-three schools a year. From 1950/51 on there was a radical departure from previous patterns. This was due to the establishment of the Development Board, which had become financially respon- sible for the construction of schools, and to considerable in- creases in the budget of the Ministry of Education. The Board began building “schools by the hundreds” so that between 1950/51 and 1956/57, a period of six years, 760 new elementary schools were added, amounting to 70 per cent of the number of all elementary schools opened during the previous thirty years. Perhaps as significant is the fact that even the annual rate of increase is not static. In 1951/52, 108 new schools were added. In 1953/54, the number rose to 128 schools. Between 1954/55 and 1956/57, it increased rther to 141 new schools per year. It would not be sur- THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 2T1 TABLE 40 Government ELEMENTARY AND Secondary Schools” 1945/46 1950/51 1951/52 1952/53 1953/54 1954/55 1955/56 1956/57 Elementary Schools Schools Boys 723 819 901 984 1,094 1,154 1,062 Im.a. Girls 169 190 204 228 256 270 261 Il.a. Co-Ed. 52 92 104. 117 101 155 425 Il.a. Total 944 1,101 1,209 1,329 1,451 1,579 1,748 1,861 Teachers Men 3,361 4,376 5,051 5,544 6,070 6,679 7,274 Il.a. Women 1,418 1,991 2,237 2,491 2,749 2,948 3,196 Il.a. Total 4,779 6,367 7,288 8,035 8,819 9,627 10,470 11,607 Students Boys 90,419 138,530 153,653 173,341 195,803 224,253 252,732 Il.a. Girls 28,068 42,249 45,600 52,487 62,530 70,744 79,949 Il.a. Total 118,487 180,779 199,253 225,828 258,333 294,997 332,681 378,384 Intermediate and Secondary Schools Schools Boys 36 64 73 86 92 109 107 Il.a. Girls 23 31 31 39 42 50 45 Il.a. Total 59 95 104 125 134 159 152 210 Teachers Men 451 698 814 1,027 1,185 1,350 1,439 Il.a. Women 141 301 356 430 535 662 699 Il.a. Total 592 999 1,170 1,457 1,720 2,012 2,138 3,072 Students Boys 9,480 17,594 18,553 23,015 26,666 32,036 34,040 Il.a. Girls 2,693 5,112 5,525 6,926 8,144 9,448 10,558 Im.a. Total 12,173 22,706 24,078 29,941 34,810 41,484 44,598 60,389 TOTALS Schools 1,003 1,196 1,313 1,454 1,585 1,738 1,900 2,071 Teachers 5,371 7,366 8,458 9,492 10,539 11,639 12,608 14,679 Students 130,660 203,485 223,331 255,769 293,143 336,481 377,279 438,773 Sources: For 1945/46 through 1953/54, Iraq, Ministry of Education, Annual Report for 1953/54; for 1954/55, Iraq, Statistical Abstract, 1955, pp. 109-111; for 1955/56, Statistical Abstract, 1956, pp. 74-76; for 1956/57, Iraqi Embassy, Office of the Cultural Attaché, Education in Iraq (Washington, D.C.: n.d.), pp. 7 and 12. THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 213 better than a central bureaucracy. It is also more democratic and, by giving local authorities responsibility (with assistance), expansion of school facilities will probably proceed at a faster rate. Some have expressed fear that the move may in- crease divisive tendencies. This fear seems unjustified, since the central authorities still retain supervisory powers and still prescribe the curriculum and the rules and regula- tions. In addition to a few minor ones, elementary education in Iraq confronts two special problems: (1) the problem of the Yezidi minority, and (2) the problem of Bedouin education. The Yezidis are a closely-knit, semi-political religious minority comprising some 32,000 persons. Some of their religious beliefs and taboos prohibit the education of children, and the pronunciation of certain sounds and words. Even if schooling were allowed, the second prohibition makes in- struction nearly impossible. The problem of Bedouin education has been the subject of serious thought for many years. Since tribes migrate from one area to another, the usual school organization does not apply. A few mobile schools have been organized and move with the nomads; and some of the tribes, such as the Shammar in the north, are anxious to have their children receive instruction. By and large, no serious effort has been made to solve the problem. Probably, as the nomads become sedentarized— and they are gradually becoming so—the educational system will be expanded to include their children. In the meantime, Bedouin children continue with little or no schooling. Secondary Education In order to qualify for secondary school, the student must have completed a six-year elementary course and passed a general examination set up by the Ministry of Education. The secondary school system itself is divided into two stages: an intermediate stage consisting of three years of study; and a preparatory stage consisting of two years. The preparatory stage has three divisions: science, literature, and commerce. After completion of the intermediate stage, the student must pass another general examination before proceeding to the 214 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ preparatory stage. Similarly a third examination must be passed at the end of the two-year preparatory course before receiving the secondary school certificate. Both inadequate economic resources and conscious govern- ment policy have tended to reduce substantially the number of students who may continue their education from the ele- mentary to the secondary stage. Each examination hurdle eliminates between 40 and 50 per cent of the candidates. Those who fail cannot proceed further. For instance, in 1955, out of 21,045 students who took the general examination after the six-year elementary course, only 12,531 or 60 per cent passed. Out of 7,256 participants in the intermediate examination, only 3,715 or 51 per cent passed. Out of 3,406 students who took the secondary school examination, 1,644 or 48 per cent passed. In all the three examinations, out of 31,707 participants, 17,890 or 56 per cent passed. Despite these limiting factors, the number of schools and students rose sharply, particularly in recent years (see Table 40). In 1920 there was only one school in the whole country, located at Baghdad. By 1951 the number had risen to ninety- five, including thirty-one schools for girls. As in the case of elementary schools, 1951 was a year of departure from pre- vious patterns. In a period of six years between 1951 and 1957, 115 new schools were added, bringing the total to 210. Until 1956 secondary education in Iraq followed the European tradition. Heavy emphasis was placed on classical and literary subjects with a marked tendency toward pre- paring students for the universities and the professions. The repeated examinations tend to have a stultifying effect on the students. In particular, the general examination after the six-year elementary course categorizes students too sharply and usually affects the candidate for the rest of his life. Similarily the “science” examination, held at the end of the two-year preparatory period, is so difficult as compared with the “arts” examination that few students elect to take a science major, thus creating another impediment to technical education, so very badly needed at this stage in the develop- ment of Iraq.4 The whole conception of what intermediate and secondary 216 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ into separate and optional programs: science, literature, in- dustry, agriculture, commerce, and home economics. Since 1952 secondary education has been completely free. In addition, boarding school facilities are to be established for students from small villages not likely to have secondary schools of their own. Progress—to the extent that money can achieve it—has been impressive in recent years. Iraq has still to solve the curriculum problem and the related problem of availability of qualified teachers to meet the requirements of the new curriculum proposed. Technical and Vocational Training Because of the development program and the growth of industry, services, and mechanized agriculture in recent years, the question of technical education has now assumed a special significance. The level of technical knowledge in the country is very low, even by Middle Eastern standards, and both the number of technicians and of training facilities are entirely inadequate to meet the present needs of the country. Various theories have been offered from time to time to explain the present dilemma. “The Arab mind,” it is said, “has a flair for literature but none for natural science”; young men prefer “white collar” jobs; working with one’s hands is not considered dignified,” and so on. Some of these generalizations are no doubt true, but they fail to provide an adequate explanation, for—time and again—actual experience has seemed to disprove them. The numerous oil companies with specific objectives have found the Arab receptive and capable, once given the incentive and oppor- tunity, of acquiring quickly a relatively high level of technical skill.” The oil companies have been able to train large bodies of men in a bewildering variety of skills and trades. It seems to this writer that the explanation is a simple one. On the one hand, until recent years there has been no particular demand in Iraq for artisans. The wages of skilled workers were generally lower than those of office workers. Therefore, no strong enough incentive existed for acquiring technical skills. On the other hand, “white collar” jobs, in addition to THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 217 being better paid, carried with them social prestige, so that it was only natural for young men to seek them in preference to skilled work. In any case, the technical training movement has gathered considerable momentum in recent years. This was inevitable since the success of the development plans rests to a large degree on the availability of an adequate labor force. In 1955 there were three technical schools (at Baghdad, Kirkuk, and Basrah), and a fourth was opened the same year at Sulaimaniya. In 1955/56 they had a total of some 808 students and were able to graduate 92 students. So far, following the recommendations of the Committee mentioned previously, the Ministry of Education opened, in addition to the above, three commercial secondary schools, three agri- cultural secondary schools, and two technical secondary schools. The Development Board has allocated large sums of money for the establishment of technical and agricultural schools and other “scientific” institutes. The next few years will probably see considerable expansion in technical train- ing facilities although, for some years, the expansion will not keep up with the demand. Some progress has also been made in vocational education. Courses in agriculture (since 1950) have been set up in rural primary schools; in gardening for boys in the cities; in home arts for girls. In addition, there is a school for nursing and midwifery attached to the College of Medicine, which in 1954/55 had 134 women students; a Home Arts School for girls (799 students in 1955/56), and an Institute of Fine Arts (361 students in 1955/56). Teachers’ Training In spite of the increased and heavy demands on the supply of teachers, training facilities have generally kept abreast of the needs of the country, so that only occasional shortages occur. Between 1950 and 1957 the number of elementary school teachers increased by 82 per cent; that of secondary school teachers by more than 207 percent (see Table 40). In 1953/54 there were three schools for the training of elementary school teachers: two for boys and one for girls. THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 219 Higher Education In 1921 there was one institution of higher learning in the whole country—the Baghdad Law College. In 1956/57, the system of higher education consisted of thirteen colleges with a total enrollment of over 5,000 students (see Table 41). Four of these colleges have been established only since 1950: The College of Agriculture (1950), the College of Dentistry (1952), the College of Physical Education (1954), and the Veterinary College (1956). Financial responsibility and jurisdiction over the thirteen colleges are divided among various government depart- ments. The Ministry of Education has jurisdiction over seven colleges; the Ministry of Health over three, the Ministry of Agriculture over two; and the Directorate of Waqf over one. All the colleges with the exception of Queen Aliya College (for women), and the College of Religious Juris- prudence (for men) are coeducational. The College of Medicine admits only “science” majors from secondary schools for a six-year course of study, includ- ing one year of internship. After the successful completion of the six-year course it grants the degree of Licencié in Medicine. The same regulations apply to the College of Pharmacy and Chemistry, except that it offers only a five-year course which includes one year of internship for pharmacists and a four- year course for a B.S. degree in chemistry. All the other colleges admit only graduates of secondary schools for a four- year course. All of them grant the degree of Licencié to students who pass the prescribed examinations in the final year of study. In addition to the above colleges, there is a school of nursing and midwifery and a school for health officials. Both are attached to the College of Medicine. A police college under the jurisdiction of the Ministry of Interior completes the list. Some of the colleges, such as the College of Arts and Sciences, have attained a fairly high academic standing. However, they all suffer from the fact that they are not 222 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Foreign study has not been an unmixed blessing, although it must be stated that, on balance, it has proved not only a very valuable but also a necessary experience. On the positive side, it has provided Iraq with a large body of experts which otherwise it would have been unable to obtain in such a short time. Since Iraq has no facilities for such training, it is hard to see how the needs of the Development Board, the other government departments, agriculture, industry, etc., can otherwise be met. Certainly, in the long run, Iraq cannot depend on the services of foreign experts. Secondly, it offers the intelligent among the new generation a far greater margin of social and economic mobility, and in the process it creates a new élite based not only on family heritage but on intelligence and on achievement. Thirdly, it helps in the breakdown of narrow provincialism. The students bring back a wide variety of personal experience and a broader realization of the world which cannot but have an impact on Iraqi society. On the negative side, it is claimed that some students choose inferior universities and do not receive enough reward for their time and money; that many often choose subjects of little value to themselves and to their country;” that social conditions in the foreign countries they go to are so radically different from their own background that considerable damage is done to their personalities; and that some become so acculturated to the West that when they return they are un- able to readjust themselves to the traditional environment of their country. Some of the above statements are probably true, although perhaps somewhat exaggerated. On the whole, however, the benefits far outweigh the harm. Some of the misuses can be corrected. Universities and disciplines can be more carefully selected. In any case, until such time as Iraq has adequate facilities there is no alternative to advanced foreign study. Perhaps the most potent argument that can be made against it is that it is comparatively very expensive. Iraq, therefore, should begin to establish such facilities. This would have the advantage of being less expensive and leaving the student in his own environment. THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 223 Illiteracy Centers The campaign against illiteracy began in the late twenties. However, statistical data indicate that no consistent policy was followed until 1950, so that the number of centers and students used to fluctuate radically from year to year. In 1927/28 there were thirty-one centers, all for men, with 2,074 students. In the thirties the movement gained consider- able momentum, reaching in 1938/39 a high of 205 centers for men, with 16,415 students, and seven centers for women, with 218 students. During the war it declined sharply reach- ing in 1948/49 a low of eighteen centers, all for men, with a total of 1,498 students. From then on, however, the number of centers and students began to climb steadily, with no set- backs, until in 1954/55 there were 309 centers for men, with 26,178 students, and thirty-seven centers for women, with 3,693 students. In 1955/56 the number rose to 506 centers with a total enrollment of 34,695 men and women. Students attend two consecutive courses of four months duration each, six nights a week, two classes each night. In the first course, they study reading, writing, and arithmetic. In the second, reading, writing, arithmetic, hygiene and civics are studied. In addition to the above centers, illiteracy classes are conducted in jails, in the army and in the police. Also many government departments, such as the Railways and the Port Directorate, private companies, such as the oil companies, and private philanthropic and volunteer organizations con- duct similar classes. Conclusions Officially, the system of education in Iraq is described as “democratic, progressive, and nationalist.” It is democratic in the sense that available facilities are open to all without discrimination for reasons of race, color, or creed. It is pro- gressive in the sense that it is basically secular and has followed Western methodologies of education. It is nationalist in a dual sense. It attempts to inculcate in the Iraqi child love and devotion to Iraq as a country and a political entity, and 224 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ similar sentimental loyalty to the “Arab Nation” of which Iraq is only a part. The country still faces a formidable task. Over two-thirds of the children (at least) of primary school age receive no instruction. The administrative structure is cumbersome, the curriculum needs a radical reform, and considerable ex- pansion in technical education is required. Perhaps the most hopeful thought lies in the fact that the government is con- scious of these problems, and that it is bending every effort to meet the challenge and forge ahead in creating an enlighten- ed society. 1. A law passed in 1945 provided for the creation of an administrative council in each of the fourteen provinces. It is to be composed of representatives of the province and presided over by the provincial governor representing the central government. The purpose of the council is to assume some of the responsibilities of the central government with regard to local affairs. Among these is education. The Council receives grants-in-aid from the central govern- ment for specific purposes. In a certain sense, these councils—very limited in their powers as they are—represcrit an interesting experiment in real democ- racy. Although the law was passed in 1945, the first council was not or- ganized until 1954—some ten years later—in the province of Baghdad. 2. For details of the history of the movement see R. D. Matthews and M. Akrawi, Education in the Arab Countries of the JNear East. (Washington, D. C.: American Council on Education, 1949), p. 146. 3. Ministry of Education, Annual Report for 1953/54, op. cit., p. 23. 4. In 1953/54, 52.5 per cent of those who took the science examination passed, as compared with 61.4 per cent for the “arts” examination, and 57 per cent for the “commerce” examination. 5. Office of the Cultural Attaché, Embassy of Iraq. Education in Iraq. (Wash- ington, D.C.: 1957, pp. 10-11.) 6. This writer has seen Arab students in the United States (who had never done any manual work in their lives in their home countries) work as manual laborers, waiters, and in factories. This goes to show that attitudes are not in- flexible and that under given incentives and circumstances they change quickly. 7. For instance, British labor supervisors at the I. P. C. in Kirkuk told this writer that members of the Jabbur tribe have an amazing knack for handling machinery. 8. The number of students who were sent by the Ministry or the Board (fully supported) are as follows: 1950/51, 133 students; 1951/52, 234 students; 1952/53, 125 students; 1953/54, none (because of disturbances); 1954/55, 114 students; 1955/56, 120 students. Of these, the Development Board sent a total of 317 students, of whom 102 have already returned. 9. In the case of bursary students, I have been unable to find evidence to sup- port this allegation. In the first place, the subject of specialization is selected by the Ministry of Education on the basis of the demands of government de- partments. Secondly, I went through the subjects of specialization of all THE CHALLENGE OF EDUCATION 225 bursary students sent between 1950/51 and 1953/54. The subjects are mostly in the natural sciences, followed in a far smaller number by the social sciences. This is in line with what Iraq needs today. The allegation may, however, be true of students studying on their own. “Il PUBLIC HEALTH The concept that the state is responsible for the health of its citizens is accepted in Iraq without challenge. This is a natural development, since Iraq began its national life almost completely devoid of medical facilities, and the full burden of responsibility fell upon the state. Therefore, almost the entire medical profession itself as well as the physical plant existing today are the creation of and in the service of the state. Responsibility for public health is vested in the Ministry of Health, which was created only in 1952. Prior to that, re- sponsibility lay in a directorate attached to the Ministry of Social Affairs. In line with the general development of the country, expenditures of this department have increased steadily. Between 1947/48 and 1954/56, they rose from 450,- 000 dinars to 4.3 million dinars, a ninefold increase in seven years (see Table 42). Expenditures in 1955/56 represented 7.8 percent of the total ordinary expenditures of the govern- ment. Since 1950 almost all the expenditures of the Ministry have been for operational activities. Since that time the Develop- ment Board has assumed the major responsibility for financing the construction of hospitals, clinics, and other health es- tablishments. As in the case of education, the Board’s con- PUBLIC HEALTH 227 ception of the role it should play became broader in each successive plan and the magnitude of planned expenditures increased. Between 1952 and 1956, it built fifteen hospitals, forty-nine clinics, and a considerable number of houses for medical staff. TABLE 42 BUDGET OF THE MINISTRY of HEALTH AND THE MEDICAL College (Selected Years) Per cent of Total Budget in Dinars Government Budget 1947/48 448,332 7.8 1949/50 1,339,239 6.5 1950/51 1,829,198 6.2 1951/52 2,341,863 7.6 1952/53 Im.a. Il.a. 1953/54 2,973,849 5.9 1954/55 3,794,658 7.0 1955/56 4,327,158 7.8 Source: Statistical Abstracts for 1950, p. 287; 1952, p. 258; 1955, p. 318; and 1956, p. 238. In addition to its direct contributions, the Development Board plays an indirect role in improving health conditions: through loans to municipalities and other agencies for drink- ing water and sewage disposal schemes; through the drainage or filling in of swamps; construction of low-cost housing; extension and improvement of drinking water supplies; es- tablishment of community centers and construction of sanitary slaughter houses and other establishments which have a direct bearing on raising the health standards in the country. The direct allocations of the Board for health in its 1955-60 plan are 18.2 million dinars. Direct and indirect expenditures during the same period are estimated, however, to reach the neighborhood of one hundred million dollars. Since 1952 several international agencies have also been active in improving health conditions in Iraq. These include the United States Point Four Program, UNICEF, UNESCO, and WHO. These organizations either conduct independent programs of their own, collaborate in government programs, or train Iraqis to undertake specific tasks. 228 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ TABLE 43 DevelopMENT Board ALLOCATIONS FoR HEALTH: 1956-60 Estimated Beds Cost in Dinars Baghdad Medical Centerx 1,000 4,000,000 Karkh Hospital (Baghdad)* 550 2,000,000 Kazimain Hospital (Baghdad suburb)* 300 700,000 Basrah Hospital” 400 900,000 Amara Hospital” 200 500,000 Other Hospitals and Clinics” 5,750,000 Eradication of Malaria Campaign” 2,000,000 15,850,000 Improvement of Drinking Water* 1,500,000 Filling of Swamps* 300,000 Milk Pasteurization Plant (at Abu Ghraib)f 550,000 Grand Total 18,200,000 x Planning completed. * Construction in progress. f Completed. Attitudes Toward Medicine To all practical purposes, no native practice of medicine— as distinguished from modern practice—exists any longer in Iraq, except perhaps in isolated villages where no other facilities are available. On the contrary, people demand medical facilities and in recent years a village which has a clinic acquires prestige. There are two exceptions to the above general rule: mid- wives are still preferred to obstetricians. This may be due to the traditional segregation of the sexes in Middle Eastern society and because it is felt that such an intimate life process as giving birth should be witnessed only by persons of the same sex. Midwives are regarded with considerable respect and affection, and homes are generally open to them at all times. In many respects, especially in the villages, they occupy a position similar to that of the priest. The government has recognized their importance and influence, and in recent years it has begun to establish training centers for them. In contrast to midwifery, nursing, especially among the Muslims, is not regarded as quite a respectable profession. PUBLIC HEALTH 229 . : This is particularly true for a girl of good family. This attitude prevails throughout the Middle East, but increases in intensity as one moves towards the Persian Gulf and farther east. A very serious problem of recruitment thus exists. The second exception to the general lack of native medi- cine, although far less significant, is the bone-setter. In some isolated communities local bone-setters may still be found, who are generally surprisingly efficient and knowledgeable in their vocation. An attitude which creates considerable difficulty is that which has developed throughout the Middle East, including Iraq, concerning tuberculosis. It is regarded as a “shameful” disease. Consequently every effort is usually made to conceal the fact from the neighbors, and there is great reluctance to report cases to hospitals. In many instances, only when the disease reaches a latent stage are the patient and his family willing to take this step. In contrast to the attitude toward tuberculosis, no stigma seems to attach to bejel, a mild form of syphilis fairly common among the Bedouins of Iraq. In recent years a new difficulty has begun to appear in the attitude of villagers toward mobile clinics. It seems that mobile clinics which make it possible to serve a number of villages (where a clinic for each would not be justified) are not regarded by the villagers with the same degree of con- fidence as permanent clinical installations. It may be that this is a transitory attitude which will disappear with more experience. Medical Facilities As in the case of education, in absolute terms the progress achieved has been remarkable. In 1918 there were one or two hospitals in the entire country. In 1950 there were eighty- two hospitals (seventy-one government, eleven private), 4,901 beds (4,483 government, 418 private), and 448 dis- pensaries. Assuming a population of five million in 1950, there was about one hospital bed for each 1,000 population. Between 1950 and 1955 the number of hospitals rose to 115 (ninety-eight government, seventeen private), and beds 230 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ to 7,745 (7,269 government, 476 private)—an increase of 40 per cent and 58 per cent respectively. The ratio of beds to population rose to one per 650 persons. No exact data are available as to the number of clinics that have been constructed since 1950. A figure of sixty would probably not be far off the mark, so that it can be estimated that in 1955 there was a total of some 550 clinics. Although statistically less impressive, similar increases took place in the medical staff. In 1951 there were 762 registered doctors (sixty-one of them foreigners), of whom 582 were government officials. There were 274 pharmacists, 557 nurses, 938 male dressers, and 682 midwives. The figures for 1955 were 1,014 doctors (ninety-four foreigners), 305 pharmacists, 781 nurses, 1,309 male dressers, and 767 midwives. These data do not include dentists, dental practitioners, vaccinators, health officers, laboratory analysts, etc. Iraq is still confronted with serious problems in regard to both facilities and staff. Most of the hospitals are located in urban centers such as Baghdad, Basrah, Mosul, and Kirkuk. Some rural areas have no facilities whatsoever. The most serious problem, however, is not the construction of hospitals and clinics (for this can proceed fairly rapidly) but the acute shortage of trained personnel. One new hospital in the south, it is reported, remained unopened for two years after completion because no personnel could be found to man it. Doctors are usually extremely reluctant to work outside Baghdad. Of the 1,014 doctors in all of Iraq in 1955, 560 were located in the province of Baghdad alone. In essence, this means the city of Baghdad and its suburbs. Young doc- tors, after living in a foreign country or in Baghdad, find life in rural areas drab and uninteresting. There is usually no adequate housing, life is monotonous, and there is nothing to do besides one’s job. The shortage is not only in doctors but also in medical aides. The Jewish girls who used to be the main source of supply for nurses have gone with the general exodus of Jews in 1950. Male “dressers” are recruited in order to fill part of the need. PUBLIC HEALTH 231 Some efforts are now being made to meet the problem of personnel. Doctors trained at state expense are required to serve a certain number of years outside the big cities (this has always been the case). As an inducement to serve in the provinces, adequate housing in rural areas is now being con- structed for the medical staff. Training programs for doctors, nurses, and male dressers have been stepped up, but they still fall far short of meeting the requirements. Preventive Medicine Progress in preventive medicine has not been as evident as in curative medicine. In fact, the preventive medicine campaign can be said to have begun in earnest only since 1950. Between 1920 and 1950 epidemics which used to deci- mate the area, such as cholera, the plague, smallpox, and louse-borne typhus were either completely eradicated or brought under substantive control. However, the principal endemic diseases—such as malaria, trachoma, bilharzia, hookworm, and other intestinal diseases—remained wide- spread. The incidence of some of them, as will be pointed out later, actually increased. The reasons why progress in this field has not been as marked are the complexity of the problem and the very heavy expenditures involved. Amelioration requires a large trained staff scattered throughout the country. It also re- quires considerable expenditures on sewage disposal, latrines in villages, pure drinking water, drainage works, and so forth. Awareness on the part of government officials and the public is needed; planning and coordination among the various government departments are required. An example cited by Salter gives a graphic illustration of this point. He WriteS: An old abandoned canal system was partly re-opened in 1941. By the summer of 1943 some 7,000 people were beginning to farm about 130,000 mesharas of newly irrigated land. Malaria from which the district had, before the new irrigation, been entirely free, at once appeared in a virulent form. Almost the entire population was stricken. Many of the villages were deserted. A review of the situation then showed that impervious PUBLIC HEALTH 233 Carrier. Malaria threatens about three-fourths of Iraq’s population. persons a year.” Irrigation canals and stagnant pools are now the main breeding grounds of the malaria mosquito The worst areas are the north and northeast, and the foot- hills and uplands of the northern Zagros mountains. It is also serious in the low-lying coastal areas of Shatt al-Arab, Hammar Lake, and the alluvial plains of central and south doctors estimate that this disease alone kills some 50,000 ºoroueqo Jos pue ‘eoquouoº ºsȚIȚqđÁs sapnpouſ! ºsuu joj IIV, ·●‘Çé-OZZ ºdd ‘996 I pue ‘919-*19 ºdd ‘GG6I ‘Z6-18 ºdd ‘zÇ61 ‘’LG-№g ‘çg ºdd ‘OÇ6I joj slovaqsqy poſsippis :oornos Z00% lºgº 869‘I I GZ6% 919'8I Z68‘ZZ 009'99 Lºgº/ſ, ļsoseasIGI [eorouoA G0º0l 696°9 #glº9 ILI ‘9 990‘II GZ6‘6 ç06‘6 099'8„sȚsoſno 19qn L ZOZ‘Iý 91./'99 Z80‘GZ 10*'ZZ #8I“9% 69ç‘9Ý Z09'98 9#0%„ Á 19ļuºsÁGI 998%, G90% Z OZI% I 19I‘61 989% z 881'91 81ç‘6 Z66‘ÇIuJowąooH 699%g g6#‘ZW #81°19' 6ºz‘6Z ZĽ9‘Zg Z8Zºçº ZZººgz 6ZO‘IZeſz-reqiſq #88‘LIZ 9Z6‘0ZG GZ9'099 99 I“IGW GŁO‘60ſ, 66Z‘9ç# 98Z$Zºg Iz6‘ZŁ)eſueſe W. GVZ“IĢſ *Ig'90ý ZLZ“18ý ĽZg‘68$ 80%819 66ç‘ZZ9 GZ9%8Ł CZgº8ççeuuoqoe II, 99,619:961#96189618961196109619Þ6I qalva (JL sasvasIGI Snoiloa.aNI woľvyw ## aTavL 234 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ Iraq.8 Statistical data gathered over the years indicate that malarial incidence is much greater during flood years. Little was done to combat the disease until after the war, | due to the prohibitive costs of wide-scale larvicide and drainage projects, “the world’s main recourse until the ad- vent of DDT.” Due to preventive measures taken since 1947, malaria has completely disappeared in the cities of Baghdad, Basrah, Mosul, and Kirkuk. In 1950 the Endemic Diseases Institute (created in 1946) | began concerting efforts to attack the malaria problem. Soon thereafter, the World Health Organization began cooperating by sending experts to train local specialists and to help develop a “national malaria strategy.” In 1952 UNICEF entered the scene. In addition to govern- ment effort, UNICEF began sending trucks, jeeps, sprayers, DDT, and field research supplies. Its efforts concentrated on the Tanjero Valley in northern Iraq. In 1954, U. N. and government operations were consolidated, giving protection to some 1.7 million persons.4 In late 1955, with continued U. N. and United States aid, 2,000 malaria workers launched an eight-year campaign which will protect two million persons during the epidemic season and achieve total protection for all the threatened population (three million) by 1963. The UNICEF release cited previously states, “UNICEF aid will cease in 1956 when the Iraq government, which all along matched UNICEF’s investment, plans to take over ! full responsibility. For the task, Iraq is enlarging the Endemic Diseases Institute at Baghdad; establishing five regional malaria centers . . . .” The Development Board allocated two million dinars to the Endemic Diseases Institute to be spent between 1956 and 1960 on the eradication of malaria.” The results of the work that has been accomplished since 1950 are reflected in the number of malaria cases treated at health institutions (see Table 44). In 1950 there were over 537,000 cases. In 1956, only 218,000, a decline of sixty per cent. The decline took place year after year (except in 1953), and has been too steady to be simply a statistical accident. * In 1957 a Malaria Board was established. PUBLIC HEALTH 235 The social and economic significance of the decline in the incidence of malaria is far-reaching. For one thing, malaria has been one of the major causes of the high rate of infant mortality—estimated to reach up to 500 per 1,000 babies born in malarial areas, with an average of 300-350 per 1,000 for the country as a whole. Once the malaria menace is removed, a considerable drop in the infant mortality rate should follow. This was, of course, the justification for UNICEF’s joining the campaign against malaria in Iraq. In addition to some 50,000 deaths it is said to cause each year, malaria also causes much disability and saps energy and vitality. It thus affects adversely the general level of productivity in the country, and limits the prospects of economic betterment for the individual. 2. Trachoma. With the decline in the incidence of malaria, trachoma has now moved to statistical first place among the problem diseases of the country. It is an eye disease, social in origin, and arises from unhygienic practices and general un- cleanliness. It is carried from one person to the other by the common housefly. Although the disease yields to curative treatment in its early stages, unlike malaria (for which comparatively in- expensive means of attack at the source has been found through insecticides), its eradication can only be accom- plished through a general rise in the level of sanitation which would reduce fly-breeding areas and eventually eliminate the carrier. People come to health institutions to be treated in an ever larger number, while the source of the disease itself re- mains untouched year after year. No data are available as to the incidence of the disease in the country as a whole. Illustrative examples only can be cited. Out of 140,451 students examined in 1950/51, 23 per cent were found to be afflicted with trachoma. In 1952/53, the rate was also 23 per cent out of 199,359 students. In the following year (1953/54), the percentage rose to 24.6 of 154,397 students examined." A UNESCO worker recently estimated that trachoma incidence in the Dujailah settlement is as high as 80 per cent. A guess that some 60 per cent of the 236 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ population in the entire country is afflicted with it would probably not be too far wrong. There is reason to believe that incidence may be on the decline in Iraq. For instance, trachoma cases treated have been decreasing since 1951 (see Table 44). It must be admitted that this is not necessarily a reliable index, since many of those afflicted either have no access to, or do not take the time to visit, clinical facilities. Perhaps the best index is the province of Baghdad which has superior facilities, accessible to everyone, and where the population is more aware of the problem than in other areas. It would therefore be reasonable to assume that the majority of those afflicted would visit health institutions for treatment. This is statistically indicated, since about one-third of the cases treated in the entire coun- try are located in this province." The number of cases treated in Baghdad (province) dropped steadily year after year from 331,479 in 1951 to 102,789 in 1955, a decline of about 69 per cent. The pattern of decline followed that of the country as a whole. 3. Bilharzia. Bilharzia (schistosomiasis) is a parasitic ail- ment caused by a fluke which has a life cycle of human, vector snail, human. The fluke is picked up through the skin of the foot, develops in the human liver, reproduces, passes out through the urine into water, goes through a stage of develop- ment in the snail, and lives in stagnant and polluted waters until it finds a human host. The disease is debilitating. The main components of its effects are lassitude, low vitality, and blood in the urine. It is therefore of profound economic significance. It lowers both the individual’s capacity for work and his ability to resist and overcome other diseases. As in Egypt—where the disease was first identified—it predominates in the flow-irrigated areas of the Iraqi country- side. A survey carried out by the Endemic Diseases In- stitute (around 1950) showed that the disease does not occur south of the town of Basrah; that it reaches its peak of in- cidence in the Lake Region, but from there northward, it declines steadily up to the Kurdish mountains, where it does not occur at all. The same survey showed that its highest in- 238 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ 4. Hookworm. Hookworm (ankylostomiasis) is another para- sitic disease. Among its effects are anemia and very low vitality. Like bilharzia, the parasite is picked up through the skin of the foot (and through infected drinking water) and lives in the intestinal tract. The disease thrives in areas where there are inadequate sewage disposal and open drains. The disease seems to predominate in the south, although some Iraqi writers believe that some two-thirds of the entire population are afflicted with it.” In 1954, over 50 per cent of the pregnant women examined in one month at the Samawah Health Center were found to have one or more types of intestinal parasites.” As is clearly evident, effective eradication of the disease is dependent, like that of bilharzia, on a rise in the level of sanitation, installation of sewage disposal facilities, stricter enforcement of sanitary laws, and economic betterment. In the meantime, of course, it can be treated clinically. The number of cases treated during the last six years give no conclusive indication whether the disease is increasing or decreasing in the country (see Table 44). Cases which came to clinical attention rose from over 9,000 in 1950 to over 23,000 in 1953. Then they dropped to something over 14,000 in 1954, but rose to an all time high of over 24,866 cases in 1956. It is probable that there has been some decline since then, for improvement has occurred in sanitation and eco- nomic conditions. In any case, a decline is clearly indicated in the province of Baghdad. The number of cases treated there fell steadily year after year, from 13,794 in 1952 to 3,023 in 1955. 5. Tuberculosis. The number of tuberculosis cases brought to medical attention indicates that the disease does not represent a serious danger. There is reason to believe, how- ever, that its incidence is much higher, owing to the social implications mentioned before. In 1952 a national campaign, with the help of WHO and UNICEF, was launched to combat the disease, by attempting to discover its actual extent, by B.C.G. vaccination, and by public education. It is reported that by the early part of 1955 PUBLIC HEALTH - 239 some 550,000 persons were X-rayed, and 220,000 were given B.C.G. vaccinations. 6. Venereal Diseases. The principal causes of venereal diseases in Iraq are prostitution, legal and illegal, and bejel, a mild form of syphilis common among the Bedouins and apparently passed on by parents to their children. In recent years venereal diseases seem to have been brought under reasonable control. This may have been due to the widespread use of antibiotics and a much closer super- vision of prostitution. In 1950, over 47,500 cases were brought for medical attention. Six years later in 1956, their number dropped to 4,000. In 1950 the Directorate of Health estimated that some half a million persons were afflicted with bejel, mainly among the tribes in the provinces of Amara, Dulaim, Mosul, and Kirkuk.9 No data are available on the progress achieved with this disease since 1950, although it is known that the Endemic Diseases Institute assisted by the World Health Organization is investing considerable time and effort in combatting it. The fact that the Bedouins attach no stigma to this disease should be of considerable help in eradicating it, once its exact nature is determined. Conclusions Considerable amounts of money have been invested and remarkable progress has been achieved since 1950 in the im- provement and expansion of the medical facilities of the country. Despite this progress, Iraq, as in the case with educa- tion, is still a long way from solving its health problems. Health facilities, particularly clinics and health centers, are still extremely inadequate; severe shortages in medical personnel exist; and the death rate is still very high. There is, however, the desire to improve health conditions, and the funds to do it. Generally speaking, no aspect of the development program has met with more enthusiastic response from the public than the measures taken to raise the health standards in the country. 240 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ : : . Salter, op. cit., p. 86. . A Committee of Officials, Kingdom of Iraq. (Baltimore: The Lord Baltimore Press, 1946), p. 91. . Iraqi Embassy, Washington, D. C., Bulletin, August, 1955, quoting a UNICEF press release of July, 1955. . Ibid., p. 8. . Iraq, Ministry of Education, Annual Reports for 1950–51 and 1953-54. . Of course, it is possible that this is so because the incidence of the disease in : Baghdad is higher than the rest of the country. Such reasoning, however, would be rather far-fetched and illogical since the level of sanitation is higher in Baghdad than anywhere else. In the absence of definite data, it would be more reasonable to accept the first assumption. . Khayyat, op. cit., p. 33. . Adams, op. cit., p. 160. . Iraq. Directorate General of Health, Annual Bulletin of Health and Vital Statis- tics for 1950. (Baghdad: Government Press, 1950), p. 20. “12 COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT AND WELFARE After World War I the cities and towns of Iraq grew haphazardly with little planning or coordination. The old sections, medieval in many of their features, are characterized by narrow, winding streets and alleys, unsavory odors, open drains, and generally unhygienic living conditions. Not in- frequently, livestock are kept within municipal limits of some of the main cities. To this day, not even Baghdad can boast an adequate sewage disposal system. In contrast, the new sections look impressive with broad tree-lined, dual-carriage boulevards and modern apartment buildings and villas for the rich. According to the Inter- national Bank Mission, even the new sections were not properly planned. It stated in part:* Streets and traffic circles have been laid out according to pre- scribed geometrical patterns without paying much attention to their functions or to the need for creating integrated residential areas with appropriate housing for different income groups and provision for schools, shops and hospitals or clinics . . . Growth has been, in fact, piecemeal and spasmodic rather than coordinated and regular, and emphasis has been placed more on the ornament- al than on the useful. Some traffic circles, for example, are un- necessary; others are even safety hazards . . . . Sometimes streets have been ruthlessly cut or widened through built-up 244 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ It is against this background that a conscious community development movement began in earnest only recently. Its general objectives are to make life more pleasant and bearable. Among other things, its program includes better and more coordinated planning of the physical layout of cities, towns, and villages; the provision of schools, clinics, health and community centers; better and more housing; gardens and playgrounds; clean water; better sewage disposal in the cities and latrines in the villages, etc. Some aspects of the community development movement are discussed below. Housing The present housing program is carried out by three main government agencies: the Development Board, the State Mortgage Bank, and the Ministry of Social Affairs. In addition, of course, should be mentioned private, municipal, and industrial housing. 1. The Development Board. Initially, the Board’s housing program was very limited in scope and conception. It was designed primarily to help government employes and workers of the Board. Between 1951 and 1956, however, thinking developed considerably on this subject. This is reflected in the fact that—against a small sum allotted for housing in the first Five-Year Plan—the new program calls for the ex- penditure of more than twenty-four million dinars between 1956 and 1960. In 1956 serious consideration was being given to the formation of a Ministry of Housing, Villages, and Munic- ipalities to be financed by the Board. The Board’s ultimate objective is the construction of some 245,000 housing units; 125,000 in rural areas, and 120,000 in cities and towns. Of the latter, 47,000 are to be located in Baghdad and 13,000 in Basrah. For all practical purposes, the Board’s immediate program was launched only in 1955. A Greek consultant recommended by the International Bank acts now as the housing advisor to the Board. He has recommended a two-fold program: (a) a general program for the construction of 25,000 houses in five years and (b) a short-term program whereby several housing developments, each not to exceed 1,000 houses, COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT AND WELFARE 245 would be constructed: four in Baghdad, two in Basrah, two in Mosul, one in Kirkuk, and one in Sarchinar (cement factory). The houses are to be built in complete groups. Each development will have its requirements of public services, i.e., roads, water supply, sewage system, electricity, and public buildings such as schools, mosques, clinics, social and rec- reational centers, markets, playgrounds, and parks. The short-term program is now in operation. Some 2,000 houses are now under construction in Mosul, 600 in Kirkuk, 160 in Dibbis, 400 in Sarchinar, 5,000 in Baghdad, and about 1,800 at Basrah—a total of some 10,000 houses. Commission- ing of new houses by the Board will probably reach some 10,000 a year by 1960. The houses under construction seem to be designed pri- marily to meet part of the needs of government employes, workers of the Board’s industrial plants, and sarifa dwellers at Baghdad and Basrah. Some of the houses are to be sold on a long-term installment basis, while others are to be rented at low rates. 2. The Ministry of Social Affairs. This department is primarily concerned with the construction of low-cost housing for government employes and workers. So far, it has con- structed some 2,000 houses for that purpose. In addition, it is now building a new township, Topchi, near Baghdad. The township will include electricity, piped water, sewage disposal, a shopping center, streets, a mosque, a hospital, a school, a post office, a police station, and a park. As planned, the Topchi development consists of 1,950 houses, some already completed, some near completion, and some under construction in late 1956. Twelve hundred and fifty of the houses will be allotted to government officials, em- ployees and workers, and 700 to some of the 1954 flood victims. The main housing projects of the Ministry are financed through grants from the Development Board. 3. The Mortgage Bank This state bank was founded in 1948 with a nominal capital of half a million dinars, and began actually operating in 1949. In 1952 its capital was raised to two million dinars but the amount was not fully 246 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ paid up by the government until 1954. In 1954/55, the bank had at its disposal a total of 3.2 million dinars in capital, deposits and loans. The purpose for which the bank was created is to facilitate the construction of housing. It is authorized by law to perform two main functions: (1) to build houses on its own account and sell them at cost or at nominal profit on an installment basis and (2) to make loans to individuals and organizations to help them (a) construct new buildings or houses, (b) re- pair or purchase buildings and houses, and (c) pay off existing house mortgages which are usually at high rates of interest. So far the bank has built 168 houses in Kirkuk, Baghdad, and Sulaimaniya, as well as eighty-two houses for teachers in Baghdad. In addition, eighty houses were under con- struction in Mosul in 1956. Under construction, also by the Bank, are two Baghdad suburbs. Faisal City is primarily for army and police officers and will consist of 4,450 houses. The second suburb, al- Mamun Town—named after a famous caliph of Iraq–in- cludes all the modern amenities such as electricity, piped water, and sewage disposal, as well as schools, a shopping center, a clinic, a park, and a police station. This suburb is due to be completed in 1957 and will consist of 500 houses, each fifty being in a different style. Each house will include four rooms, a hall, a bath, and a kitchen. Evidently the suburb is designed for the middle-class income group. Loans by the bank are limited to a minimum of 100 dinars and a maximum of 2,000 at five per cent interest and re- payable over a maximum period of twelve years. Between 1949/50 and 1954/55 the bank made the following loans:” JNo. of Total Value Per Cent Loans in Dinars of Total Conversion of Existing Mortgages 3,008 1,727,343 32.4 New Houses 1,651 1,650,540 31.0 Repairs and Purchase 4,126 1,939.423 36.6 8,785 5,317,306 100.0 248 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ | in Baghdad. Rural areas received hardly any benefits of the program up until 1957. It must be said, however, that the | plan has only been launched. The 1955-60 program is ex- pected to spread the benefits over a much larger geographical area, including rural sections, and over a larger segment of the population. As in the case of almost every development activity, the program confronts two main difficulties: scarcity of skilled labor and shortages of materials. The first problem is being met, at least in part, in three ways: (a) by employing foreign workers, (b) by requiring all contractors to give unskilled Iraqi workers on-the-job training, and (c) by establishing training schools. For instance, one such school has now been established, and has about 1,200 trainees. Most of the teachers are foreign specialists. | The second problem is being met through (a) the en- couragement of new building materials industries, and (b) the use of new materials. For example, a new factory, prob- ably the largest of its kind in the Middle East, was recently built to mass-produce construction materials such as tiles, bricks, etc. Pure Water Supply In 1951, out of a total of 131 municipalities of all four classes in the country, about forty of them, including most towns with a population of over 6,000, had modern piped water supply systems.” In 1955, water purification systems were in operation or under construction in ninety towns and cities.4 The increase is reflected in the figures on consumption of pure water in the towns. In 1951, more than 44 million cubic meters were consumed. By 1955, the consumption reached to more than 77 million, an increase of 75 per cent (see Table 46). This indicates two trends—an increase in per capita consumption, and extension of the system to new toWnS. The water systems are managed by municipal Boards under the direction of the Department of Municipalities in the Ministry of Interior. The Development Board administers | COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT AND WELFARE 251 Education, and Agriculture as members, and a secretary- general with cabinet rank to administer the program. The council will have a separate and autonomous Central Board with full executive, financial, and administrative powers. It is to be attached to the Council of Ministers, but directly responsible to Parliament. The secretary-general of the Council will be the board chairman. He will be assisted by an advisory committee of top-level specialists from the Ministries of Education, Health, Agriculture, Social Affairs, Interior, Finance, Economics, and Development, as well as heads of any other relevant government department. The object of the program is to improve the standard of living of Iraq’s rural population, reduce the migration of farmers to larger cities and towns, step up farm production and provide solutions for such basic problems as ignorance, disease, and unemployment. The program calls for a total expenditure of six million dinars over a ten-year period. Expenditures during the first year are to be 1.5 million dinars, and, thereafter, half a million each year for the duration.6 Several features of the plan are of special interest. First, unlike any previous attempt, it is integrated and coordinated, with all the appropriate departments participating. The rural problem is also placed on the highest executive level, i.e., the ministerial level. Too, the “autonomous board” idea, under the control of specialists isolated from politics, seems to have taken root. From the meager information available and the relatively small amounts involved, it seems that the scheme is not intended to replace other projects but rather to supplement them. It is probable, however, that after some experience and confidence have been gained, the plan will undergo considerable expansion. Sanitation The extent of improvement in this field cannot be statistically determined. Prima facie evidence indicates, however, that progress has been more or less in line with the general develop- PART V Conclusions “13 CONCLUSIONS Among the principal causes of political and social in- stability in the Middle East are the abject poverty of the majority of its peoples and their desire for a better life. The area contains sources of potential wealth which, if properly developed, can support a much higher standard of living. All specialists agree that the best approach to development in the area would be through a coordinated regional pro- gram. For reasons which lie outside the scope of this book, such an approach has not been possible so far. Development, therefore, has taken place on a country basis, and, in most countries, it has been rather sporadic, lacking in coordi- nation and clearly defined objectives, and ineffectual in terms of changing the basic pattern of the socio-economic structure. Some countries have the capital for investment, but no resources; others have the resources but no capital; some have both, but lack an imaginative and wise leadership. Iraq is considered to be among the less advanced countries in the region. It is, however, blessed with the main com- ponents necessary for development: capital for investment, extensive resources in land, water, oil, undetermined quan- tities of minerals, and a low population density in relation to these resources. CONCLUSIONS 255 The program initiated in 1950 is designed to employ these favorable factors in the development of the country. The program is by no means perfect. Justifiable criticisms may be made—and have been made— of the individual components of some of its schemes, of policies, of administration, and of the slowness with which the work is sometimes executed. Yet, as a whole, it remains a bold and imaginative program representing a refreshing and radical departure from the inefficient methods of previous years. For the first time in the modern history of Iraq and, in- deed, of all the Arab countries, development, through the creation of an organizational structure (the Development Board), is relatively insulated from politics and is left basic- ally in the hands of competent specialists; large amounts of capital are being continuously invested; comprehensive and coordinated plans covering all sectors of the economy and aiming at fairly well-defined objectives have been drawn and are being implemented; and a large number of specialists, technicians, and engineering firms have been employed, not only to help in the execution of the program, but also to train Iraqis to help themselves. Some of the more immediate benefits of the program are already visible. Unemployment has, for all practical pur- poses, disappeared, and the real wage income has risen. In 1956 the country, for the first time in its long history, achieved reasonable protection against the menace of floods, and, in the summer of the same year, produced bumper crops— almost double those of 1955. The number of children going to school in 1956/57 was more than double that of 1950. Malaria, which used to kill some 50,000 persons a year, is being brought under a substantial measure of control. The program should affect, either directly or indirectly, the very foundations of the economic, social, and political institutions of the country. It should be remembered that Iraq’s intensive planned development began only in 1950. The various plans of the Board and other government agencies and depart- ments represent only initial steps in a grand design which may take twenty to thirty years to reach fulfillment. It is also assumed here that intensive development as a state 256 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ policy will not be interrupted except by circumstances over which the government has no control, such as war. What then is the significance of the program? Basically, it is a means of speeding up the process of economic and social change taking place, not only in Iraq, but throughout the Middle East and most underdeveloped countries. The essential difference between Iraq and some of her neighbors is that she is forging ahead at a much faster pace and that the country, because of its resources, holds the promise of a more prosperous future for its people than some of her less fortunate neighbors. There are limits to what heavy government spending and “crash programs” can do in bringing about change. Some- times they create economic stresses, social dislocation, and cultural chaos. It may be desirable at times to slow down elements of a program so that its main components can develop proportionately. This is particularly true in the field of human relations. Habits, customs, and traditions do not change or disappear overnight and new ones cannot be imposed without explanation if they are to be effective. The most healthy change is that which springs from the “grass roots” with guidance and assistance from above. There is also the ever-present danger that designs for change may be borrowed from other societies without due regard to whether they are adaptable to the Iraqi environment or congenial to its people. This is probably the main criticism against the program in Iraq. It is for the people, but not from them. There is a considerable lack of communication between the bureaucracy which administers the program and the com- mon people whom it is designed to benefit. The bureaucrat is contemptuous of the fallah and his customs, and believes him to be an unintelligent dolt who has little to contribute to progress, if anything; and the fallah has a deep-seated suspicion of the bureaucrat and his designs, gained from centuries of unpleasant contact with government which was usually restricted to military conscription and the collection of taxes. As one writer on Middle Eastern economic matters has observed, “Government is alien.” 260 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ in Iraq is numerically small. The program, through in- dustrialization, new economic opportunities, increased popu- lation mobility and education, should cause a considerable increase in its ranks. This means a greater rate of social urbanization, the spread of middle class attitudes and way of life, a geographical redistribution of the population, the growth of urban areas, and an occupational redistribution of the labor force resulting in a relative decline of the number of those engaged in agriculture and a corresponding increase of those in industry, trade and services. 3. As mentioned previously, many aspects of society in Iraq, as in other Middle Eastern countries, have been under- going change for many years. The program should soon be- come the main force speeding up this process. Secularization should reduce the differences among the various linguistic, ethnic, and religious segments of the population, and weld these blocs into a more cohesive unit with common beliefs, aspirations, and loyalties. The above changes should also bring about a much greater degree of social mobility, both horizontal and vertical. For instance, to take an extreme case, a short time ago the chances of the son of a fallah receiving a university education and moving out of his class and up the social ladder were rather remote. Although still limited, such cases are now not in- frequent. On the horizontal plane, social intercourse and intermixture between the various population groups is becoming more prevalent and should increase. Iraqi society is also undergoing a cultural reorientation. Until recent years the aspirations of Iraqis, as well as those of most Arabs, were anchored in the past. Today, pre- occupation with the glories of the past among the vocal public is restricted mainly to religious divines, historians, and antiquarians. Most educated young Iraqis are concerned with the future and are groping for solutions to immediate problems. Generally, they are interested in establishing a new kind of society that will equip them to live the good life in a twentieth century world. CONCLUSIONS 26. Political Impact The political effects of development in Iraq are of a two- fold nature: internal and external. Internally, the short-term result of the program has been the maintenance of a measure of public peace. Many com- petent observers a few years ago believed that Iraq was on the eve of a revolutionary upheaval. This is a very real possibility. In almost all countries of the Arab world, including Iraq, internal political issues have been reduced to one of two alternatives: immediate reform or revolution. In Iraq, in addition, there is considerable dis- content in relation to foreign policy. Barring outside inter- vention or a revolution, the development program may give Iraq a “breathing spell” during which reform may be effected in an orderly manner. The long-term results of the program are also obvious. It should bring about a redistribution of political power in favor of the masses and particularly the middle class, which includes the intelligentsia. This class today has considerable influence over the masses and is far more powerful than its representation in Parliament would indicate. The program will increase its membership and strengthen its economic position. As to the fallaheen, the landlords and the shaikhs will no longer be able to exert over them the same degree of political control which they do at present. It is, therefore, hard to escape the conclusion that the traditional ruling class will no longer have a monopoly on political power. Finally, the social, economic, and cultural changes taking place should effectuate the transference of loyalties from the tribe, the religious group, etc., to the ideal of a nation. Externally, the program requires that Iraq (at least for the time being) dedicate itself to the cause of peace and stability in the Middle East. An extended armed conflict in the region would result in the suspension of the flow of oil and oil revenue. The suspension of the program would cause chaos in the governmental machinery and bring in its wake hunger and poverty and severe public unrest. 262 THE RECONSTRUCTION OF IRAQ On the other hand, Iraq, on the basis of its economic potential and barring international disturbances, should soon emerge as one of the major powers in the region. Significance for the Middle East Middle Eastern countries which may later initiate similar programs can benefit from Iraq’s experience with intensive development. Successful experiments can be imitated, and mistakes avoided. The development of Iraq, assuming political considerations permit, can provide a partial solution—through emigration— to the population problem of some Middle Eastern countries. Finally, if at a later date a development plan for the Middle East is formulated and agreed upon, the program in Iraq will have laid some of the groundwork for the execution of the regional scheme. Appendix Il POPULATION OF CHIEF CITIES, 1957 * Greater Baghdad Greater Mosul Greater Basrah Kirkuk Karbala Amara Sulaimaniya Nasiriyah Arbil 1,085,232 444,883 164,623 120,593 60,804 53,311 48,450 39,060 34,751 ic .On- ntrie r t *Source: Embassy of Iraq, Press Attaché, Washington, D. C. INDEX Abadan, 169 Abbassid Caliphate, 2, 30, 82 Abu Dibbis depression, 59, 64, 65, 68 Abu Ghraib canal, 77, 78, 228 Adams, Doris, 10, 16 afforestation, 55, 115 Afghans, 6 aghas, 80, 83 agriculture: Agricultural Machinery Adminis- tration (Directorate), 11, 106, 108, 115 Agricultural Services, 105, 119 capital invested in, 14, 89, 126, 140-141 credit, 108-111 - development program, 78, 117, 120, 165-167, 173-175, 192, 203, 258-259 experimental stations, 113-114 extension service, 99, 102, 113, 114, 115, 122 facilities for, 105-106, 114 farm management, 63 farming, dairy, 115 farms, demonstration, 99, 102 grain stores and silos, 20 large-scale, 89, 121 machinery, use and maintenance of, 106, 115, 183 mechanization of 11, 47, 60, 90, 106-110, 121-122, 166, 216, 222, 242 percentage of population in, 12, 13, 18 percentage of land cultivated, 18 production, 18, 27, 78, 91, 177, 197, 251, 257–258 reporting service, 114 research and training, 113-114 revenue from taxes on, 25-26 Soils Laboratory, 115 technical studies on, 117 techniques of, 105, 106, 122 see also: crops Agriculture, Ministry of 53, 95, 105, 110, 112, 114, 219, 250, 251 Ain Zala, 131, 133, 135, 137, 150, 152, 154 air transport, 44, 192, 200–201, 203- 204 Alawand, 130, 169, 170 Alexandretta, 136 al-Mamun Town, 246 Alwan, Abdul Sahib, 53 Amara, 7, 8, 86, 88,90, 197, 228, 237, 239 Ana, 55 Anglo-Iranian Oil Co.; see British Petroleum Co. Ankara, 56 ankylostomiasis; see hookworm Aramco, 132 Arbil, 3, 7, 74 Arizona, University of, 114 army personnel, 93, 96 Asia, 139 Asia, Southeast, 200 asphalt, 170 Assyrians, 5, 6, 7, 22 atomic energy development, 176 Australia, 79, 89, 120, 257 Awqaf Administration, 81 Baba Gurgur, 133 Babil canal and outfall, 71, 77 Babylonians, 70 Badºa canal, 73 Baghdad, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 11, 12, 19, 54, 57, 58, 67, 86, 88, 104, 131, 136, 143, 146, 147, 150, 152, 161, 164, 165, 169, 170, 178, 181, 183, 189, 190, 191, 192, 193, 194, 195, 196, 197, 200, 201, 203, 204, 214, 217, 218, 219, 220, 224, 228, 230, 234, 236, 237, 238, 240, 241, 245, 246, 247, 248,252 Baghdad Pact, 56 Bahrain, 137, 142, 200 Baiji, 135, 136, 170 Bani Hasan, 78 banking, 108, 110-111 banks: Agricultural, 53, 94, 107, 108, 110, 111, 247 Agricultural-Industrial, 20, 184-185 banking institutions, 168 foreign, 108 266 INDEX Industrial, 53, 168, 177, 178, 184, 185, 186, 187, 202, 204 Mortgage, 53, 178, 244, 245-247, 253 National, 166, 185 private, 111, 168, 186 Rafidain, 178 Banyas, 135, 136 Ba‘quba, 197 Ba‘quba drain, 78 barley, 87, 99, 100, 102, 115 Basrah, 5, 6, 7, 8, 11, 18, 20, 74, 131, 133, 136, 146, 147, 149, 150, 152, 154, 155, 159, 169, 170, 173-174, 183, 189, 191, 192, 193, 194, 195, 196, 197, 199, 202, 204, 217, 228, 230, 234, 236, 245, 247, 252 Port, 53, 199, 200, 203 Port Directorate, 192, 247 Basrah Petroleum Co. (BPC), 129 Batma dam, 69, 70 Bedouins, 22, 213, 229, 239 bejel, 229, 239 Bekhme dam, 70 bilharzia, 100, 231, 233,236-237 Bonné, Alfred, 87, 104 bridges, 20, 41, 43, 44, 45, 46-47, 49, 106, 172, 192, 197, 198,203 Britain: see Great Britain British Development Co., 131 British nationals, 6, 34 British Oil Development Co., 131 British Petroleum Co., 129, 131, 132, 161 Brownrigg, William, 24 bunds, 63, 72 Cabinet: changes in, 22, 32, 34, 38, 39, 40, 118, 148, 150 conservatism in, 24 effect on development programs of, 23, 32, 34, 37 of Nuri as-Sa'id, 39 system, 22-23 Cairo, 200 Canada, 79, 89, 120, 257 canals, 20, 57, 59, 62, 67, 70-74, 76, 82, 107, 232, 233,237, 242, 249 see also: Abu Ghraib; Babil; Ba‘quba; Dagharra; Dhibban; Dujailah; Euphrates; Gharraf; Hawija; Hilla; Husseiniyah; Khoraisan; Majjara; Saqlawiyah; Shamiyah; Shatrah; Ruwairij; Wadi Tharthar; Warrar; Yusa- fiyah capital, 27, 50, 51, 118, 177, 183, 188, 202, 254-255, 259 increase in reserves of, 27, 50, 51, 118, 177, 183, 188,202, 254, 255, 259 lack of, for investment in private industry, 188 private, 27, 53, 118, 177, 183, 188, 202 rate of investment of, 50-51 capitalism, 189 caustic soda plant, 176, 179 cement, 172 censuses: agricultural, 13, 16, 107 housing, 8, 125 industrial, 13, 16, 161, 163 population, 1, 2, 3, 7, 8, 10, 11, 12, 16, 205 cereals, 26, 79, 257 cholera, 231 Christians, 3, 4, 5-6 Christianity, 27-28 citrus industry, 116 civil service, 23-24, 25, 39, 93, 96, 245, 247 classes: intelligentsia, 2, 30, 189, 222, 261 masses, 2, 4, 9, 14, 91,261 middle class, 14, 30, 247, 257, 259- 260 peasants, 79, 91, 92, 103, 105, 107, 108, 109, 113, 118, 120, 121, 122, 123, 124, 126, 127, 210 upper, 2, 9, 14, 257 clover, 102 colleges, 48, 114, 124, 144, 206-207, 221-222 Baghdad Law, 17, 219 Higher Teachers’ Training, 218 Institute of Fine Arts, 217-218 Iraqi University, 208, 220 law, 17 of Agriculture, 114, 219 of Arts and Sciences, 219 of Dentistry, 219 of Engineering, 115 INDEX 267 of Medicine, 217, 219 of Pharmacy and Chemistry ,219 of Physical Education, 218-219 of Religious Jurisprudence, 219 police, 219 Queen Aliya, 218-219 school for health officials, 219 University of Baghdad, 220 Veterinary, 219 colonialism, 139 Communications and Public Works, Ministry of, 192 communications and transportation, 18, 45, 79, 100, 115, 133, 137, 172, 183, 192-203 see also: air transport; bridges; postal system; railways; river transport; roads; telegraph system community development and welfare, 123, 241-252 community enters, 244, 250 impact of, 257-262 loans to municipalities, 249 rural community development, 125, 250-252 Rural Community Development Council, 125, 250 Compagnie Française des Pétroles, 130 conscription, military, 7, 113, 256 cooperation, international, 56 cooperative system: agricultural, 110, 111, 112, 122 credit, 99, 112 housing, 112 sale and consumption, 94, 99, 100, 112 cotton, 26, 99, 102, 115, 116, 171, 188 councils, local administrative, 53, 232 crops: diversification of, 50, 99, 115, 116 new, 114 rotation of, 61, 75, 89 see also; barley; cereals; clover, cot- ton; dates; fruits; jute; onions; rice; sugar beets; vegetables; weed control; wheat culture, 1, 256, 258, 260 Cutha, 103 \ Dagharra branch (Hilla Canal), 71 Damascus, 200 dams, 20, 48, 49, 56, 60, 68, 71, 106, 118, 126, 172, 197, 205 see also: Batma; Bekhme; Darband- i-Khan; Diyala; Dokan; Eski Mosul; Hindiyah; Kut; Ramadi; Udhaim; Wadi Tharthar; Yusuf Pasha Darband-i-Khan dam, 69, 74 Date Association, 53 dates, 26, 115, 174, 175-176, 200 Dawrah, 126, 170, 195 refinery, 169 lubricant and asphalt plant, 170 Dawson, Sir Ernest, 84, 104 Dead Sea, 67 Development Board, 23, 28, 31, 32, 34-53, 63, 70, 71, 72, 75-76, 91, 106, 114, 118, 123-127, 142, 167, 169, 170, 172-173, 175-176, 183, 191, 192, 195, 196, 197, 200-201, 203, 206-208, 217, 220-222, 226-228, 232, 234, 237, 244-245, 249-250, 252, 254, 259,262 from establishment to reorganiza- tion in 1953, 23, 34–37, 39-40, 43-45, 49 predecessors of, 19–20, 34, 38, 40, 17] Development Board Plans: First Six-Year Plan (1951-56), 38, 40-43, 71, 168 Five-Year Plan (1955-59), 43-44, 168, 244, 252 Second Six-Year Plan (1955-60), 44-48, 71, 125, 126, 168, 176, 186, 195, 197, 200, 201, 203, 207, 220, 227, 244, 248,252 development projects of other state agencies: government banks, 53 long-range, 47-49 semi-governmental agencies, 53 short-term, 49 Development, Ministry of, 38-39, 40, 43, 44, 53, 78, 95, 98, 104, 186, 251 devil worship; see Yezidi Dhibban outlet canal and regulator, 64 Dibbis, 191, 245 diet and nutrition, 15, 16, 115, 158, 160, 209, 210, 232, 257 diseases: degenerative, 232 270 husbandry, animal, 18, 61, 99, 102, 115, 116 Husseiniyah canal, 78 hydrological stations, 56 illiteracy, 17, 121, 124, 144, 163, 205, 209, 223, 251 sex distribution of, 12, 205 imperialism, 139 imports, 52, 106, 141, 167, 170, 171, 172, 173, 181, 182, 184, 188, 202, 203, 257, 258 income: family, 14, 15 farm, 62, 96, 102, 122 level of, 181, 255 national, 13, 14, 25-27, 31, 38, 50, 51, 168,474, 257 of fallaheen, 18, 87, 88 per capita, 13, 14, 257 rate of increase of, 50, 232, 257 supplementary, 101 India, 5, 41 industrial development: Directorate General of Industry, 204 Industrial Development Finance Corporation, 186-189, 202 mechanization in, 165, 184 plant construction for, 47, 48, 49, 172-174,205 private industry plans for, 183-184, 186-189, 202 program for, 122, 142, 151, 162-163, 165-167, 175-176, 183, 186-189, 192, 197, 201-203, 205, 216, 222, 258, 259, 260 state investments in, 41, 185, 188- 189, 200-201, 246-247 state loans to municipalities for, 249 state loans for private, 168, 184, 188, 201 state ownership vs. private, 188 see also: state industrial enterprises industry, private: agricultural products, 175-176, 179 animal products, 179, 181 building materials and construc- tion, 172, 175-176, 177, 179, 248 chemical, 175-180, 202 dairy, 181 fertilizer plant, 175-176, 179 INDEX handicrafts and cottage, 18, 46, 50, 165 household products, 182-183 large-scale, 165, 187,202 light, 101-102, 165, 202, 258 metal products, 175-177, 182 paper manufacture, 175-176, 179 service, 12, 13, 165, 183, 216, 259, 260 small-scale, 165, 202 steel, 175-176, 182 textile, 178 vegetable oils and fats, 181 inflation, 51-52 instability: political, 121, 254 social, 254, 256 Interior, Ministry of, 152, 219, 248, 250, 251 International Cooperation Adminis- tration (ICA), 114 Iran, 3, 54, 55, 56, 57, 68, 69, 130, 131, 136, 137, 139, 142, 159, 169 Iranians, 2, 6 Iraq Petroleum Co. (IPC), 20, 130- 131, 132, 133, 136, 137, 145, 149, 150, 161, 170, 190, 224 Iraqi Currency Board, 19, 20 “Iraqi Levies,” 6 irrigation: Committee, Joint Irrigation Proj- ects, 56 Directorate of Irrigation, 72 projects, 20, 41, 42, 44, 45, 48, 49, 50, 55, 56, 60, 63, 65, 69-71, 74, 75, 78, 83, 91, 92, 98, 101, 102, 103, 116, 117, 118, 123, 126, 193, 249 use of rivers for, 199 Ishaki area, 73 Islam, 27-8 heretics: see Mandaeans Israel, 5, 22, 135, 137,257 Istanbul, 200 istihlaq; see taxes, consumption Iversen, Professor Carl, 166 Report to National Bank of Iraq, 166-167 Jabbur tribe, 224 Jadriyah, 220 Jamil, Muzaffar H., 22, 31, 204 272 INDEX Latifiya settlement, 98, 101-102 laws: Civil Service (May, 1956), 24, 35 General Education (1940), 218 “Governing Rights and Duties of Cultivators,” (1933), 88-89 Labor, Comprehensive (June, 1956), 150 Land Code, Ottoman, 83 Land Registration, 83 Land Settlement (1932-38), 84 Social Security (May, 1956), 24 No. 6, (1952), 34 No. 23 (1945) (Dujailah Land De- velopment), 91-92 No. 23 (1950), 34, 38 No. 26 (1936), 19 No. 27 (1953), 37, 38 No. 27 (1944), 111 No. 29 (1947), 247 No. 33 (1936), 19-20 No. 35 (1951), 53 No. 36 (1942), 148 No. 37 (1939), 20 No. 39 (1934), 19 No. 43 (1950) (Encouragement of Industry), 44, 187 No. 43 (1951) (Land Development and Settlement Law), 91 No. 45 (1938), 20 No. 54 (1956), 47 No. 60 (1956) (University Bill), 220 No. 72 (1936) (Iraqi Labor), 148- 149 No. 79 (1931), 19 Ordinance No. 4 (1952), 91 Ordinance No. 26 (1935), 19-20 Ordinance No. 28 (1935), 19-20 Ordinance No. 52 (1952), 91 lazma (land grants), 26, 81, 85, 86, 87, 88, 92, 94 leather goods, 188 Lebanese, 6 Lebanon, 135, 136, 159, 221 literacy, 12, 163 Little, Inc., Arthur D.; see Little Re- port Little Report, 46, 167, 175, 177, 178, 181, 183, 186, 202, 203, 204 livestock, 18, 61 London, 200 Lurs, 2, 3 Mafraq, 136 Magil, 199 Majjara escape canal, 64-65 Makhmur land, 69, 73, 98, 104 malaria, 10, 47,49, 125, 158, 228, 231- 235, 255 Mandaeans, 3, 4 mandate, British, 6, 55, 56, 83 mandate, French, 55, 56 markets and marketing facilities, 168, 188 masha'a (common) land, 82 materials, plastic, 175-176, 179 materials, raw, 165, 166, 167, 173, 175, 181-182, 258 matruka, 80, 86 meat, 16, 26, 52 medicine: attitude of public toward, 228-231 native, 228-229 preventive, 231-232, 234, 237-239, 251, 259 Mediterranean, 135, 136, 137 Mesopotamia, 54, 55, 115, 131 meteorological stations, 56 Middle East, 17, 27, 28, 62,78, 79,90, 103, 117, 118, 132, 137, 139, 143, 186, 189, 216, 229, 254, 256, 257, 260, 261 population problem of, 262 Supply Center, 79 Mina al-Ahmadi, 136 Mines, Department of, 249 mining, 41, 44, 47, 176 mineral deposits, 166 Ministers, Council of, 34, 37, 38, 39, 94, 151, 152, 174, 201,251 minorities, 2-6 miri land, 81-83, 85-86, 98 lazma, 81, 82 sirf, 81, 85, 86, 98 tapu, 81, 82 Miri Sirf Department, 95 Central Committee of, 95, 104 Mish-Khab, 72 Mongol invasion, 82 Mosul, 3, 4, 5, 7, 8, 12, 28, 70, 74, 86, 88, 130, 135, 150, 170, 171, 172, 173, 183, 189, 192, 194, 197, 230, 239, 245, 246, 252 Mosul Holdings, Ltd., 131 Mosul Oil Fields Company, 131 INDEX 273 Mosul Oil Fields, Ltd., 131 Mosul Petroleum Company (MPC), 129, 130, 131, 132, 161 Mosul Textile Factory, 171 Muftiyah Asphalt Refinery, 169, 170 mulk, 80, 82, 85, 86, 94 Municipalities, Department of, 248, 249 Muntafiq, province of, 4, 7, 12,90, 237 Muslims, 1, 2, 3, 9 see also: Sh’ia and Sunni sects Musayyib Project, the Greater, 72, 76-77, 98, 103, 197 Naft Khaneh oil field, 130 naggarat, 72 Nahrawan Lands, 74 Najaf, 6, 7, 8, 197 Nasiriyah, 195, 197 nationalism, 1, 3, 5, 22, 139, 223 nationalization, 132 Near East; see Middle East Near East Development Company, 130 Nestorians, 5-6 Neutral Zone (Kuwait-Saudi Arabia), 131 Nile river, 56, 57 nomads, 8, 18, 82, 83,92, 205, 213, 250 North Desert, the, 58 Northern Districts project, 74 Nuri as-Sa'id, 39 nurseries, experimental, 99, 102 occupational distribution, 12-13, 162 oil companies, international: American, 130, 159 Armenian, 130 British, 129, 130, 159 British-Dutch, 130 Dutch, 131 French, 130, 159 French-Swiss, 131 German, 131 Italian, 131 oil industry: extractive, 129, 130, 159, 187, 262 “fifty-fifty” formula, 131-132 hours, 148 housing, workers’, 247 labor, 141-142, 148, 160, 171 marketing and distribution, 132, 191 130, medical facilities and services, 157- 158, 160 recreation facilities, 158-159, 160 refining, 20, 129, 130, 135, 136 revenues from, 13-14, 19–20, 25, 30- 31, 34-35, 43-45, 127, 130-133, 137, 140-141, 160, 259, 261 schools, 159, 223 training programs, l 14, 155-157, 160, 216, 222 wages, 145-149, 160 welfare program, 158, 160 see also: oil companies, international onions, 115 orchards, planting of, 94, 99, 102, 103 Ottoman empire, 2, 3, 82, 83 Pakistanis, 6 Palestine, 22, 67 Paris Convention, 55-56 Parliament, 23, 35, 37, 38, 40, 43, 44, 45, 48, 91, 118, 148, 174, 250, 251, 261 pasture, 99, 102, 103 pensions: industrial, 148 Persian Gulf, 57, 58, 135, 136, 199,229 pest control, 114 pests, insect, 18 plague, 231 plow, steel moldboard, 102, 108 Point Four program; see United States politics: partisan, 23, 32, 34, 118 party system, 23, 40 polygamy, 9 population: age-sex distribution of, 7, 8-9 death and birth rates, 9, 10-11, 235, 239 decline of, under Ottomans, 82 density, 7, 254 distribution, geographic, 2, 7-8, 260 increase of, 50, 51 internal migration of 11-12, 15, 89, 107, 108, 242, 251 marital status of, 9 mobility of, 1, 260 redistribution of, 50 rural, 62 semirural, 8 274 INDEX structure of 8 urban, 7, 8, 25, 62 postal system, 18 poultry, 115 power, electric: consumption of, 15, 190-191 electrification, 44, 46, 102, 124, 153, 176, 189-192, 202-203, 242, 245, 246, 252 hydraulic generation of 19, 68, 69, 70, 166, 191, 202, 204 plant construction, 191-192 thermal generation of, 191 prestige values, 9, 182, 217, 258 prices, wholesale, 52 Prime Minister, 34, 37, 39, 250 productivity, 49-50, 120, 121-122, 126, 235, 259 prostitution, 239 Provident Fund, 149-150 Public Works, Department of, 192, 198 Qara Dagh, 197 Qatar, 137 Qayarh Asphalt Refinery, 170 Qurna, 58 Rafidain Oil Company, 130, 161 railways: capital investment in, 44 conversion from steam to Diesel traction, 194 meter gauge, 193-195, 203 Railway Administration, 192, 194, 195, 247 Railways and Port Directorate, 223 railway system, 18, 193-196, 204 standard gauge, 192-195, 203 Ramadi, 5, 57, 197 Ramadi barrage, 64 Raniyan, 197 rayon, 171, 179 reclamation, 41, 43, 45, 59, 70, 74, 76, 78, 79, 91, 92, 96, 99, 103, 106, 116, 118, 123, 126 see also: land, new recreation, 140, 158-159 reform: agrarian, 80, 85, 90, 91, 104, 118, 120-121, 123, 126 economic, 24 effect of, on intellectuals, 90 objectives of, 121 of civil service, 24 political, 261 social, 126, 160, 205 refugees: Palestinian, 6 religion, 4, 17, 27–28, 261 see also: sects, religious resources: animal, 13, 44, 47, 258 chemical, 13, 166, 168, 177 human, 13, 17, 32,49, 126, 165, 203, 207,254 land, 13, 17, 18, 50, 254 mineral, 13, 17, 80, 254 oil, 13, 254 plant, 13, 44, 47, 258 underground water, 13, 17, 18, 44, 47, 54-79, 47,258 rice, 16, 72, 115, 232 river transport, 193 Iraq Shipping Company, Ltd., 200 navigation, 199-200 ports, 46 river development, 55 rivers, shifting of 18, 199 roads: capital investment in, 14, 20, 41, 43, 44 construction program, 41, 45, 46-47, 172, 196-197, 203, 245 system of, 192-193, 195-196 traffic on, 195-196 under provisional government, 18 Royal Dutch Shell Group, 130, 159 Rumaila, 135, 136 Rumeitha, 77 rural areas, 10, 11, 12, 15, 124, 189, 203, 230, 244, 247, 250-252, 259 Russia, 31 Rutba, 197 Sabaeans, 4 Saddah settlement, 98 salination, 65, 68, 75, 101, 242 salinity, 58, 65, 68, 115 salt, 177 Salter Report, 23, 24, 29, 37-38, 44, 49, 53, 68, 91, 98, 104,147, 167, 172, 186, 194, 195, 196, 199, 203, 204, 231, 240 Samarra, 67, 68 Samawah Health Center, 238 276 INDEX Suq al-Shuyukh, 4 surveys: cadastral, 84, 85, 86, 92, 123 of expenditures by economic groups, 14-15, 182 of road location, 198 technical, 42, 44, 47, 48, 123, 168 syphilis; see bejel Syria, 54, 55, 56,58, 135, 136, 159, 194 Syrians, 6 Tanjero Valley, 234 tapu land, 81-82, 83, 85, 86, 93, 94 tariffs, 166, 167, 168, 178, 181, 187, 188,202 taxes: collectors of 113, 256 consumption, 26, 52 exemption from, 30, 168, 187 export, 52 import, 52 income, 25-26 indirect, 25 Land Tax, 25, 27 on agriculture, 25, 26 technical assistance: from United Nations; see United Nations from United States; States from Western business firms, 32, 43, 118-119 Teheran, 56, 200 telegraph system, 18, 20, 47 telephone system, 20, 47 tension, international, 139, 261 Tigris, 20, 54, 55, 56, 57, 58, 59, 60, 61, 65, 67,68, 69, 70, 73, 74, 76, 78, 99, 131, 193 textile mills: cotton, 171 rayon, 175, 176, 179 tobacco, 15, 16, 20, 116, 174 Topchi township, 245 trachoma, 231, 235-236 trade, 18, 27, 50, 79, 141, 151, 167, 168, 260 proportion of population engaged in, 12, 13 unfavorable balance of, 258-259 traditions, 7, 11, 12, 25, 27, 28, 82, 108, 112,214, 222, 256 see United Treaty of Friendship and Neighborly Relations (Turkey and Iraq), 56 Tripoli (Lebanon), 135, 136, 138, 159 tuberculosis, 229, 233,239 Turkey, 3, 5, 54, 55, 56, 57, 58, 136, 159, 183, 186, 194, 257 see also: Industrial Bank of Turkey; Treaty of Friendship and Neigh- borly Relations Turkomans, 3 Turks, 4, 6, 23, 84 Tuwairij drain, 77 typhus, 231 Udhaim Basin, 73 Udhaim dam, 69, 73 Udhaim river, 58, 69 Umm Qasr, 199, 200 underdeveloped countries, 9, 22, 23, 25, 42, 108, 168, 254, 256, 258 unemployment, 101, 108, 251, 255 unions, labor, 151-152, 160 United Nations, 48, 53, 95, 118, 234 Department of Economic and Social Affairs, 16, 22, 161 International Bank for Reconstruc- tion and Development (IBRD), Mission of, 13, 16, 32, 41-42, 50, 53,65, 87, 103,105,106, 166, 167, 173, 174, 194, 199, 200, 204, 241, 244, 253 International Labor Organization, 148 Statistical Office, 13, 16 UNESCO, 32, 100, 227, 235, 250 UNICEF, 32, 209-210, 227, 234, 235, 238 WHO, 32, 227, 234, 238,239 United States, 5, 32, 48, 79, 89, 105, 112, 113, 114, 118, 120, 152, 181, 221, 224, 234 Lend-Lease Program, 106 Point Four Program, 32, 35, 53, 95, 110, 113, 114, 115, 159, 161, 227 unity, national, 1, 22 unrest, social, 30-31, 91 “ political, 17, 31 urban areas, 10, 11, 12, 27, 124, 189, 242, 247, 252,260 urbanization, 1, 11, 90, 107, 260 ushr (tithe-land), 82 INDEX vegetables, 16, 26, 99, 100, 102, 115, 116 vehicles, motor, 18, 196 Vienna, 200 Wadi Tharthar depression, 60, 68 Wadi Tharthar: barrage, 67-68, 74 project, 53, 67 wages, 11, 12, 143, 144, 145, 147, 165, 216 waqf (religious trust land), 81-82, 86 Waqf, Directorate of, 219 Warrar Inlet canal and regulator, 64 Warriner, Doreen, 87 Water resources: development of, 17, 18-19, 47, 48, 50, 54, 59, 78, 122, 123, 153, 204, 242-246, 254 distribution of 94, 95; see laws (No. 23) Hammar Lake Project, 72, 74, 233 in Syria, 55 potable, 10, 47, 48, 100, 124-126, 158, 227–228, 231-232, 237-238, 248-250, 252 reports on; see Haigh and KTAM Reports rights to, 95, 96 storage of, 55, 57, 59, 60, 62,63, 64, 65, 67,68, 69-70, 104, 117, 126 277 underground, 75, 76, 80 see also: canals; dams; drainage; floods; irrigation; wells wealth: redistribution of, 118 weed control, 114 welfare, social, 49, 88, 123, 125, 141, 149, 158-159, 232, 250 wells, 249-250 Westernization, 5, 9 wheat, 16, 99, 100, 102, 115 Willcocks, Sir William, 56 windbreaks, 76 wool, 26, 115 World War I, 2, 199, 241 World War II, 21, 22, 28, 30, 79, 90, 105, 106, 116, 125, 187, 207, 223, 241 Yezidi, 3–4, 22, 213 educational problems among, 4, 213 Yusafiyah canal, 78 Yusuf Pasha dam (Syria), 55 Zab River, the Lesser, 54, 58, 68, 69, 73, 78 Zab River, the Greater, 58, 70 Zagros mountains, 233 Zubair, 133, 135, 136 186 , 69 539 AA A 30 . * & ------ ----- ~~= = = = ==)=):=)…). …