Murray Rothbard - Wikipedia Murray Rothbard From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Jump to navigation Jump to search American economist "Rothbard" redirects here. For other uses, see Rothbard (disambiguation). Murray Rothbard Murray Rothbard in the early 1990s Born Murray Newton Rothbard (1926-03-02)March 2, 1926 Bronx, New York City, New York, U.S. Died January 7, 1995(1995-01-07) (aged 68) New York City, New York, U.S. Resting place Oakwood Cemetery, Unionville, Virginia, U.S. Nationality American Spouse(s) JoAnn Rothbard ​ (m. 1953)​ Institution Brooklyn Polytechnic Institute University of Nevada, Las Vegas School or tradition Austrian School Alma mater Columbia University Influences Aristotle · Aquinas · Bastiat · Chodorov · Locke · Mises · Spooner · Tucker Contributions Anarcho-capitalism, historical revisionism, libertarianism, paleolibertarianism, title-transfer theory of contract Part of a series on Libertarianism in the United States Origins Age of Enlightenment Classical liberalism Individualist anarchism in the United States Concepts Anti-imperialism Argumentation ethics Civil libertarianism Counter-economics Decentralization Departurism Economic freedom Evictionism Free market Free-market environmentalism Free migration Free trade Free will Freedom of association Freedom of contract Homestead principle Individuality Individualism Libertarianism Liberty Limited government Localism Marriage privatization Natural and legal rights Non-aggression principle Non-interventionism Non-politics Non-voting Polycentric law Private defense agency Private property Public choice theory Restorative justice Self-ownership Single tax Small government Spontaneous order Stateless society Tax resistance Title-transfer theory of contract Voluntary association Voluntary society Schools Austro-libertarianism Bleeding-heart libertarianism Christian libertarianism Consequentialist libertarianism Geolibertarianism Green libertarianism Natural-rights libertarianism Neo-libertarianism Paleolibertarianism Technolibertarianism Theory Agorism Anarcho-capitalism Autarchism Constitutionalism Fusionism Libertarian feminism Left-wing market anarchism Libertarian conservatism Libertarian paternalism Minarchism Libertarian transhumanism Panarchism Propertarianism Voluntaryism Economics Austrian School Economic liberalism Fiscal conservatism Georgism Laissez-faire Neoliberalism Supply-side economics People Amash Barnett Block Brennan Caplan Carson Chartier Chodorov Chomsky Epstein Friedman (David) Friedman (Milton) Gillespie Goldwater Hazlitt Heinlein Hess Hoppe Hospers Huemer Johnson Jorgensen Kinsella Konkin III Long Machan McElroy Mencken Mises Napolitano Nock Nolan Nozick Paterson Paul Postrel Rand Read Rockwell Rothbard Schulman Sciabarra Sowell Spooner Stossel Thiel Thoreau Tucker Wilder Wilder Lane Williams Woods History New Left Old Right Issues Abortion Capital punishment Criticism Foreign affairs Immigration Inheritance Intellectual property Internal debates LGBT rights Objectivism Political parties Politics State Theories of law Culture Libertarian science fiction Organizations Alliance of the Libertarian Left Cato Institute Free State Project Foundation for Economic Education International Alliance of Libertarian Parties Libertarian Party Liberty International Mises Institute Reason Foundation Students for a Democratic Society Students for Liberty Works Anarchy, State, and Utopia The Ethics of Liberty For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto Free to Choose Law, Legislation and Liberty The Market for Liberty Related topics Conservatism in the United States Left-libertarianism Liberalism in the United States Libertarian Democrat Libertarian Republican Libertarianism in Hong Kong Libertarianism in South Africa Libertarianism in the United Kingdom New Right Outline of libertarianism Right-libertarianism  Liberalism portal  Libertarianism portal v t e Part of a series on Capitalism Concepts Business Business cycle Businessperson Capital Capital accumulation Capital markets Capitalist mode of production Company Corporation Competitive markets Economic interventionism Economic liberalism Economic surplus Entrepreneurship Fictitious capital Financial market Free price system Free market Goods and services Investor Invisible hand Liberalization Marginalism Money Private property Privatization Profit Rent seeking Supply and demand Surplus value Value Wage labour Economic systems Anglo-Saxon Authoritarian Corporate Dirigist Free-market Humanistic Laissez-faire Liberal Libertarian Market Mercantilist Mixed Monopoly National Neoliberal Nordic Private Raw Regulated market Regulatory Rhine Social State State-sponsored Welfare Economic theories American Austrian Chartalism MMT Chicago Classical Institutional Keynesian Neo- New Post- Marxian Monetarist Neoclassical New institutional Supply-side Origins Age of Enlightenment Capitalism and Islam Commercial Revolution Feudalism Industrial Revolution Mercantilism Primitive accumulation Physiocracy Simple commodity production Development Advanced Consumer Community Corporate Crony Finance Global Illiberal Late Marxist Merchant Progressive Rentier State monopoly Techno People Adam Smith John Stuart Mill David Ricardo Thomas Robert Malthus Jean-Baptiste Say Karl Marx Milton Friedman Friedrich Hayek John Maynard Keynes Alfred Marshall Ludwig von Mises Ayn Rand Murray Rothbard Joseph Schumpeter Thorstein Veblen Max Weber Ronald Coase Related topics Anti-capitalism Capitalist state Consumerism Crisis theory Criticism of capitalism Cronyism Culture of capitalism Evergreening Exploitation Globalization History History of theory Market economy Periodizations of capitalism Perspectives on capitalism Post-capitalism Speculation Spontaneous order Venture philanthropy Wage slavery Ideologies Anarcho-capitalism Authoritarian capitalism Democratic capitalism Dirigism Eco-capitalism Humanistic capitalism Inclusive capitalism Liberal capitalism Liberalism Libertarian capitalism Neo-capitalism Neoliberalism Objectivism Ordoliberalism Right-libertarianism Third Way  Capitalism portal  Business portal  Philosophy portal  Politics portal  Money portal v t e Murray Newton Rothbard (/ˈrɒθbɑːrd/; March 2, 1926 – January 7, 1995) was an American heterodox economist of the Austrian School,[1][2][3][4] economic historian[5][6] and political theorist.[7] Rothbard was the founder and leading theoretician of anarcho-capitalism, a staunch advocate of historical revisionism and a central figure in the 20th-century American libertarian movement. He wrote over twenty books on political theory, revisionist history, economics, and other subjects.[8] Rothbard argued that all services provided by the "monopoly system of the corporate state" could be provided more efficiently by the private sector and wrote that the state is "the organization of robbery systematized and writ large".[9][10][11][12][13][14] He called fractional-reserve banking a form of fraud and opposed central banking.[15] He categorically opposed all military, political, and economic interventionism in the affairs of other nations.[16][17] According to his protégé Hans-Hermann Hoppe, "[t]here would be no anarcho-capitalist movement to speak of without Rothbard".[18] Libertarian economist Jeffrey Herbener, who calls Rothbard his friend and "intellectual mentor", wrote that Rothbard received "only ostracism" from mainstream academia.[19] Rothbard rejected mainstream economic methodologies and instead embraced the praxeology of his most important intellectual precursor, Ludwig von Mises. To promote his economic and political ideas, Rothbard joined Lew Rockwell and Burton Blumert in 1982 to establish the Mises Institute in Alabama. Contents 1 Life and work 1.1 Education 1.2 Marriage, employment, and activism 1.3 Conflict with Ayn Rand 1.4 Death 2 Ethical and philosophical views 2.1 Austrian economics 2.1.1 Polemics against mainstream economics 2.1.2 Reception of Rothbard's work 2.2 Ethics 2.3 Anarcho-capitalism 2.4 Race, gender, and civil rights 2.5 Opposition to war 2.6 Middle East conflict 2.7 Historical revisionism 2.8 Children's rights and parental obligations 2.9 Civil liberties 2.10 Retributive theory of criminal justice 2.10.1 Torture of criminal suspects 2.11 Science and scientism 3 Political activism 3.1 Paleolibertarianism 4 Works 5 Interviews 6 See also 7 Notes 8 Further reading 9 External links Life and work[edit] Education[edit] Rothbard's parents were David and Rae Rothbard, Jewish immigrants to the United States from Poland and Russia, respectively. David was a chemist.[20] Murray attended Birch Wathen Lenox School, a private school in New York City.[21] He later said he much preferred Birch Wathen to the "debasing and egalitarian public school system" he had attended in the Bronx.[22] Rothbard wrote of having grown up as a "right-winger" (adherent of the "Old Right") among friends and neighbors who were "communists or fellow-travelers". He was a member of The New York Young Republican Club in his youth.[23] Rothbard characterized his immigrant father as an individualist who embraced the American values of minimal government, free enterprise, private property and "a determination to rise by one's own merits ... "[A]ll socialism seemed to me monstrously coercive and abhorrent".[22] Rothbard in the mid-1950s Rothbard attended Columbia University, where he received a Bachelor of Arts degree in mathematics in 1945 and a Ph.D. in economics in 1956. The delay in receiving his Ph.D. was due in part to conflict with his advisor, Joseph Dorfman, and in part to Arthur Burns’s rejecting his dissertation. Burns was a longtime friend of the Rothbards and their neighbor at their Manhattan apartment building. It was only after Burns went on leave from the Columbia faculty to head President Eisenhower's Council of Economic Advisors that Rothbard's thesis was accepted and he received his doctorate.[7](pp43–44)[24] Rothbard later said that all his fellow students were extreme leftists and that he was one of only two Republicans at Columbia at the time.[7](p4) During the 1940s, Rothbard became acquainted with Frank Chodorov and read widely in libertarian-oriented works by Albert Jay Nock, Garet Garrett, Isabel Paterson, H. L. Mencken, and Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises.[7](p46) In the early 1950s, when Mises was teaching in the Wall Street division of the New York University Stern School of Business, Rothbard attended his unofficial seminar. Rothbard was greatly influenced by Mises's book Human Action. He attracted the attention of the William Volker Fund, a group that provided financial backing to promote right-wing ideologies in the 1950s and early 1960s.[25] The Volker Fund paid Rothbard to write a textbook to explain Human Action in a form that could be used to introduce college undergraduates to Mises's views; a sample chapter he wrote on money and credit won Mises's approval. For ten years, the Volker Fund paid him a retainer as a "senior analyst".[7](p54) As Rothbard continued his work, he enlarged the project. The result was his book Man, Economy, and State, published in 1962. Upon its publication, Mises praised Rothbard's work effusively.[26](p14) Marriage, employment, and activism[edit] In 1953, Rothbard married JoAnn Beatrice Schumacher (September 17, 1928 – October 29, 1999),[27] whom he called Joey, in New York City.[26](p124) JoAnn was a historian and was Rothbard's personal editor and a close adviser as well as hostess of his Rothbard Salon. They enjoyed a loving marriage and Rothbard often called her "the indispensable framework" of his life and achievements. According to Joey, the Volker Fund's patronage allowed Rothbard to work from home as a freelance theorist and pundit for the first 15 years of their marriage.[28] The Volker Fund collapsed in 1962, leading Rothbard to seek employment from various New York academic institutions. He was offered a part-time position teaching economics to engineering students at Brooklyn Polytechnic Institute in 1966 at age 40. The institution had no economics department or economics majors and Rothbard derided its social science department as "Marxist", but Justin Raimondo writes that Rothbard liked teaching at Brooklyn Polytechnic because working only two days a week gave him freedom to contribute to developments in libertarian politics.[7] Rothbard continued in this role until 1986.[29][30] Then 60 years old, Rothbard left Brooklyn Polytechnic Institute for the Lee Business School at the University of Nevada, Las Vegas (UNLV), where he held the title of S.J. Hall Distinguished Professor of Economics, a chair endowed by a libertarian businessman.[31][32] According to Rothbard's friend, colleague and fellow Misesian economist Hans-Hermann Hoppe, Rothbard led a "fringe existence" in academia, but he was able to attract a large number of "students and disciples" through his writings, thereby becoming "the creator and one of the principal agents of the contemporary libertarian movement".[33] He kept his position at UNLV from 1986 until his death.[29] Rothbard founded the Center for Libertarian Studies in 1976 and the Journal of Libertarian Studies in 1977. In 1982, he co-founded the Ludwig von Mises Institute in Auburn, Alabama, and was vice president of academic affairs until 1995.[29] Rothbard also founded the Institute's Review of Austrian Economics, a heterodox economics[34] journal later renamed the Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, in 1987.[35] Rothbard with his wife Joey After Rothbard's death, Joey reflected on his happiness and bright spirit, saying, "he managed to make a living for 40 years without having to get up before noon. This was important to him". She recalled how Rothbard would begin every day with a phone conversation with his colleague Lew Rockwell: "Gales of laughter would shake the house or apartment, as they checked in with each other. Murray thought it was the best possible way to start a day".[36] Rothbard was irreligious and agnostic about God,[37][38] describing himself as a "mixture of an agnostic and a Reform Jew".[39] Despite identifying as an agnostic and an atheist, he was critical of the "left-libertarian hostility to religion".[40] In Rothbard's later years, many of his friends anticipated that he would convert to Catholicism, but he never did.[41] The New York Times obituary called Rothbard "an economist and social philosopher who fiercely defended individual freedom against government intervention".[29] Conflict with Ayn Rand[edit] In 1954, Rothbard, along with several other attendees of Mises's seminar, joined the circle of novelist Ayn Rand, the founder of Objectivism. He soon parted from her, writing among other things that her ideas were not as original as she proclaimed, but similar to those of Aristotle, Thomas Aquinas and Herbert Spencer.[7](pp109–14) In 1958, after the publication of Rand's novel Atlas Shrugged, Rothbard wrote her a "fan letter", calling the book "an infinite treasure house" and "not merely the greatest novel ever written, [but] one of the very greatest books ever written, fiction or nonfiction". He also wrote: "[Y]ou introduced me to the whole field of natural rights and natural law philosophy", prompting him to learn "the glorious natural rights tradition".[7](pp121, 132–34)[42](pp145, 182)[43] Rothbard rejoined Rand's circle for a few months, but soon broke with Rand again over various differences, including his defense of what he described as "anarchism". Rothbard later satirized Rand's acolytes in his unpublished one-act farce Mozart Was a Red[44] and his essay "The Sociology of the Ayn Rand Cult".[42](p184)[45][46] He characterized Rand's circle as a "dogmatic, personality cult". His play parodies Rand (through the character Carson Sand) and her friends and is set during a visit from Keith Hackley, a fan of Sand's novel The Brow of Zeus (a play on Atlas Shrugged).[47] Death[edit] Rothbard died of a heart attack on January 7, 1995, at the age of 68. He was buried in Oakwood Cemetery, Unionville, Virginia. Ethical and philosophical views[edit] Austrian economics[edit] Part of a series on the Austrian School Principal works Capital and Interest Human Action Individualism and Economic Order Man, Economy, and State Principles of Economics Theory Austrian business cycle Catallactics Creative destruction Economic calculation problem View of inflation Malinvestment Marginalism Methodological individualism Praxeology Roundaboutness Spontaneous order Subjective theory of value Theory of interest Organizations Cato Institute Foundation for Economic Education George Mason University The Independent Institute Liberty Fund Mises Institute Property and Freedom Society Reason Foundation People Eugen Böhm von Bawerk Walter Block Peter Boettke Thomas DiLorenzo Frank Fetter Roger Garrison Friedrich Hayek Henry Hazlitt Robert Higgs Hans-Hermann Hoppe Steven Horwitz Jörg Guido Hülsmann Jesús Huerta de Soto Israel Kirzner Ludwig Lachmann Don Lavoie Peter Leeson Roderick T. Long Fritz Machlup Carl Menger Ludwig von Mises Robert Murphy William H. Peterson Murray Rothbard Joseph Salerno Mark Skousen Friedrich von Wieser Richard Ritter von Strigl Gottfried Haberler Oskar Morgenstern Related topics Austrian School economists Economic freedom Perspectives on capitalism  Business and economics portal v t e Rothbard was an advocate and practitioner of the Austrian School tradition of his teacher Ludwig von Mises. Like Mises, Rothbard rejected the application of the scientific method to economics and dismissed econometrics, empirical and statistical analysis and other tools of mainstream social science as useless for the study of economics.[48] He instead embraced praxeology, the strictly a priori methodology of Mises. Praxeology conceives of economic laws as akin to geometric or mathematical axioms: fixed, unchanging, objective and discernible through logical reasoning without the use of any uncontrolled observation.[48] According to Misesian economist Hans-Hermann Hoppe, eschewing the scientific method and uncontrolled observation distinguishes the Misesian approach "from all other current economic schools". Mark Skousen of Chapman University and the Foundation for Economic Education, a critic of mainstream economics,[49] praises Rothbard as brilliant, his writing style persuasive, his economic arguments nuanced and logically rigorous and his Misesian methodology sound.[50] But Skousen concedes that Rothbard was effectively "outside the discipline" of mainstream economics and that his work "fell on deaf ears" outside his ideological circles. Paralleling Skousen's remarks, Hoppe laments that non-Misesian economists dismiss as "dogmatic and unscientific" the Misesian approach, which both he and Rothbard embraced. Rothbard wrote extensively on Austrian business cycle theory and as part of this approach strongly opposed central banking, fiat money and fractional-reserve banking, advocating a gold standard and a 100% reserve requirement for banks.[15](pp89–94, 96–97)[35][51][52] Polemics against mainstream economics[edit] Rothbard wrote a series of scathing polemics against modern mainstream economics. He was critical of Adam Smith, calling him a "shameless plagiarist" who set economics off track, ultimately leading to the rise of Marxism. Rothbard praised Smith's contemporaries, including Richard Cantillon, Anne Robert Jacques Turgot and Étienne Bonnot de Condillac, for developing the subjective theory of value. In response to Rothbard's charge that Smith's The Wealth of Nations was largely plagiarized, David D. Friedman castigated Rothbard's scholarship and character, saying that he "was [either] deliberately dishonest or never really read the book he was criticizing".[53] Tony Endres called Rothbard's treatment of Smith a "travesty".[54] Rothbard was equally scathing in his criticism of John Maynard Keynes,[55] calling him weak on economic theory and a shallow political opportunist. Rothbard also wrote more generally that Keynesian-style governmental regulation of money and credit created a "dismal monetary and banking situation". He called John Stuart Mill a "wooly man of mush" and speculated that Mill's "soft" personality led his economic thought astray.[56] Rothbard was critical of monetarist economist Milton Friedman. In his polemic "Milton Friedman Unraveled", he called Friedman a "statist", a "favorite of the establishment", a friend of and "apologist" for Richard Nixon and a "pernicious influence" on public policy.[57][58] Rothbard said that libertarians should scorn rather than celebrate Friedman's academic prestige and political influence. Noting that Rothbard has "been nasty to me and my work", Friedman responded to Rothbard's criticism by calling him a "cult builder and a dogmatist".[59] In a memorial volume published by the Mises Institute, Rothbard's protégé and libertarian theorist Hans-Hermann Hoppe wrote that Man, Economy, and State "presented a blistering refutation of all variants of mathematical economics" and included it among Rothbard's "almost mind-boggling achievements". Hoppe lamented that, like Mises, Rothbard died without winning the Nobel Prize that Hoppe says Rothbard deserved "twice over". Although Hoppe acknowledged that Rothbard and his work were largely ignored by academia, he called Rothbard an "intellectual giant" comparable to Aristotle, John Locke, and Immanuel Kant.[60] Reception of Rothbard's work[edit] Although he self-identified as an Austrian economist, Rothbard's methodology was at odds with that of many other Austrians. In 1956, Rothbard deprecated the views of Austrian economist Fritz Machlup, stating that Machlup was no praxeologist and calling him instead a "positivist" who failed to represent the views of Ludwig von Mises. Rothbard stated that in fact Machlup shared the opposing positivist view associated with economist Milton Friedman.[61] Mises and Machlup had been colleagues in 1920s Vienna before each relocated to the United States and Mises later urged his American protege Israel Kirzner to pursue his PhD studies with Machlup at Johns Hopkins University.[62] According to libertarian economists Tyler Cowen and Richard Fink,[63] Rothbard wrote that the term evenly rotating economy (ERE) can be used to analyze complexity in a world of change. The words ERE had been introduced by Mises as an alternative nomenclature for the mainstream economic method of static equilibrium and general equilibrium analysis. Cowen and Fink found "serious inconsistencies in both the nature of the ERE and its suggested uses". With the sole exception of Rothbard, no other economist adopted Mises' term and the concept continued to be called "equilibrium analysis".[64] In a 2011 article critical of Rothbard's "reflexive opposition" to inflation, The Economist noted that his views are increasingly gaining influence among politicians and laypeople on the right. The article contrasted Rothbard's categorical rejection of inflationary policies with the monetary views of "sophisticated Austrian-school monetary economists such as George Selgin and Larry White", [who] follow Hayek in treating stability of nominal spending as a monetary ideal—a position "not all that different from Mr [Scott] Sumner's".[65] According to economist Peter Boettke, Rothbard is better described as a property rights economist than as an Austrian economist. In 1988, Boettke noted that Rothbard "vehemently attacked all of the books of the younger Austrians".[66] Ethics[edit] Ludwig von Mises Although Rothbard adopted Ludwig von Mises' deductive methodology for his social theory and economics,[67] he parted with Mises on the question of ethics. Specifically, he rejected Mises conviction that ethical values remain subjective and opposed utilitarianism in favor of principle-based, natural law reasoning. In defense of his free market views, Mises employed utilitarian economic arguments aimed at demonstrating that interventionist policies made all of society worse off. On the other hand, Rothbard concluded that interventionist policies do in fact benefit some people, including certain government employees and beneficiaries of social programs. Therefore, unlike Mises, Rothbard argued for an objective, natural law basis for the free market.[26](pp87–89) He called this principle "self-ownership", loosely basing the idea on the writings of John Locke[68] and also borrowing concepts from classical liberalism and the anti-imperialism of the Old Right.[7](p134) Rothbard accepted the labor theory of property, but rejected the Lockean proviso, arguing that if an individual mixes his labor with unowned land then he becomes the proper owner eternally and that after that time it is private property which may change hands only by trade or gift.[69] Rothbard was a strong critic of egalitarianism. The title essay of Rothbard's 1974 book Egalitarianism as a Revolt Against Nature and Other Essays held: "Equality is not in the natural order of things, and the crusade to make everyone equal in every respect (except before the law) is certain to have disastrous consequences".[70] In it, Rothbard wrote: "At the heart of the egalitarian left is the pathological belief that there is no structure of reality; that all the world is a tabula rasa that can be changed at any moment in any desired direction by the mere exercise of human will".[71] Noam Chomsky critiqued Rothbard's ideal society as "a world so full of hate that no human being would want to live in it ... First of all, it couldn't function for a second—and if it could, all you'd want to do is get out, or commit suicide or something."[72] Anarcho-capitalism[edit] Part of a series on Anarcho-capitalism Origins Age of Enlightenment Aristotelianism Austrian School Marginalism School of Salamanca Subjective theory of value Classical liberalism French Liberal School Homestead principle Labor theory of property Physiocracy Individualist anarchism Concepts Anti-statism Civil rights Counter-economics Decentralization Deregulation Economic liberalism Free market Free-market anarchism Free-market roads Free trade Freedom of contract Individualism Jurisdictional arbitrage Laissez-faire Land ownership Natural Law Non-aggression principle Polycentric law Private defense agency Private governance Private military company Private police Private property Privatization Propertarianism Property rights Right to own property Self-ownership Spontaneous order Title-transfer theory of contract Voluntaryism People Bruce L. Benson Walter Block Bryan Caplan Gerard Casey Anthony de Jasay David D. Friedman Hans-Hermann Hoppe Michael Huemer Stephan Kinsella Michael Malice Wendy McElroy Lew Rockwell Murray Rothbard Joseph Salerno Jeffrey Tucker Thomas Woods Works Defending the Undefendable Democracy: The God That Failed The Ethics of Liberty For a New Liberty The Machinery of Freedom The Market for Liberty The Problem of Political Authority To Serve and Protect The Voluntary City Issues Abortion Anarchism Capital punishment Criticism Foreign affairs Immigration Inheritance Intellectual property Internal debates LGBT rights Minarchism Objectivism Political parties Politics Theories of law Related topics Agorism Right-libertarianism Libertarianism in the United States Left-libertarianism  Capitalism portal  Politics portal v t e According to anarcho-capitalists, various theorists have espoused legal philosophies similar to anarcho-capitalism. However, Rothbard was the first person to use the term as in the mid-20th century he synthesized elements from the Austrian School of economics, classical liberalism and 19th-century American individualist anarchists.[73] According to Lew Rockwell, Rothbard was the "conscience" of all the various strains of what he described as "libertarian anarchism", because their advocates (described as Rothbard’s former "colleagues"), had often been personally inspired by his example.[74] During his years at graduate school in the late 1940s, Rothbard considered whether a strict laissez-faire policy would require that private police agencies replace government protective services. He visited Baldy Harper, a founder of the Foundation for Economic Education,[75] who doubted the need for any government whatsoever. Rothbard said that during this period, he was influenced by 19th-century American individualist anarchists like Lysander Spooner and Benjamin Tucker and the Belgian economist Gustave de Molinari who wrote about how such a system could work.[26](pp12–13) Thus, he "combined the laissez-faire economics of Mises with the absolutist views of human rights and rejection of the state" from individualist anarchists.[76] Rothbard began to consider himself a "private property anarchist" in 1950 and later began to use "anarcho-capitalist" to describe his political ideology.[77][78] In his anarcho-capitalist model, the system of private property is enforced by protection agencies, which compete in a free market and are voluntarily supported by consumers who choose to use their protective and judicial services. Anarcho-capitalists describe this as "the end of the state monopoly on force".[77] He later came to terms that anarchism identified with socialism, and wrote that individualist anarchism is different from anarcho-capitalism and other capitalist theories due to the individualist anarchists retaining the labor theory of value and socialist doctrines, suggesting a new term to identify himself: nonarchist.[79] In Man, Economy, and State, Rothbard divides the various kinds of state intervention in three categories: "autistic intervention", which is interference with private non-economic activities; "binary intervention", which is forced exchange between individuals and the state; and "triangular intervention", which is state-mandated exchange between individuals. According to Sanford Ikeda, Rothbard's typology "eliminates the gaps and inconsistencies that appear in Mises's original formulation".[80][81] Rothbard writes in Power and Market that the role of the economist in a free market is limited, but it is much larger in a government that solicits economic policy recommendations. Rothbard argues that self-interest therefore prejudices the views of many economists in favor of increased government intervention.[82][83] Race, gender, and civil rights[edit] Michael O'Malley, associate professor of history at George Mason University, characterizes Rothbard's "overall tone regard[ing]" the civil rights movement and the women's suffrage movement to be "contemptuous and hostile".[84] Rothbard criticized women's rights activists, attributing the growth of the welfare state to politically active spinsters "whose busybody inclinations were not fettered by the responsibilities of health and heart". Rothbard argued that the progressive movement, which he regarded as a noxious influence on the United States, was spearheaded by a coalition of Yankee Protestants, Jewish women and "lesbian spinsters".[85] Rothbard called for the elimination of "the entire 'civil rights' structure" stating that it "tramples on the property rights of every American". He consistently favored repeal of the 1964 Civil Rights Act, including Title VII regarding employment discrimination,[86] and called for overturning the Brown v. Board of Education decision on the grounds that forced integration of schools was aggressive.[87] In an essay called "Right-wing Populism", Rothbard proposed a set of measures to "reach out" to the "middle and working classes", which included urging the police to crack down on "street criminals", writing that "cops must be unleashed" and "allowed to administer instant punishment, subject of course to liability when they are in error". He also advocated that the police "clear the streets of bums and vagrants. Where will they go? Who cares? Hopefully, they will disappear, that is, move from the ranks of the petted and cosseted bum class to the ranks of the productive members of society."[88] Rothbard held strong opinions about many leaders of the civil rights movement. He considered black separatist Malcolm X to be a "great black leader" and integrationist Martin Luther King Jr. to be favored by whites because he "was the major restraining force on the developing Negro revolution".[7](p167) Rothbard rejected the idea of "compulsory integration" and felt that "self-help, pride, thrift, Negro businesses, etc... cannot hope to flourish within the context of the black reality in America: permanent oppression by the white 'power structure.' None of these good and libertarian things can be achieved without first and foremost, getting the white-run U. S. and local and state governments off the backs of the Negro people."[89] In 1993 he rejected the vision of a "separate black nation", asking "does anyone really believe that ... New Africa would be content to strike out on its own, with no massive "foreign aid" from the U.S.A.?".[90] Rothbard also suggested that opposition to King, whom he demeaned as a "coercive integrationist", should be a litmus test for members of his "paleolibertarian" political movement.[91] Opposition to war[edit] Like Randolph Bourne, Rothbard believed that "war is the health of the state". According to David Gordon, this was the reason for Rothbard's opposition to aggressive foreign policy.[35] Rothbard believed that stopping new wars was necessary and that knowledge of how government had led citizens into earlier wars was important. Two essays expanded on these views "War, Peace, and the State" and "Anatomy of the State". Rothbard used insights of Vilfredo Pareto, Gaetano Mosca and Robert Michels to build a model of state personnel, goals and ideology.[92][93] In an obituary for his friend historical revisionist Harry Elmer Barnes, Rothbard wrote: Our entry into World War II was the crucial act in foisting a permanent militarization upon the economy and society, in bringing to the country a permanent garrison state, an overweening military-industrial complex, a permanent system of conscription. It was the crucial act in creating a mixed economy run by Big Government, a system of state monopoly capitalism run by the central government in collaboration with Big Business and Big Unionism.[94] Rothbard's colleague Joseph Stromberg notes that Rothbard made two exceptions to his general condemnation of war: "the American Revolution and the War for Southern Independence, as viewed from the Confederate side".[95] Rothbard condemned the "Northern war against slavery", saying it was inspired by "fanatical" religious faith and characterized by "a cheerful willingness to uproot institutions, to commit mayhem and mass murder, to plunder and loot and destroy, all in the name of high moral principle".[96][97][98] He celebrated Jefferson Davis, Robert E. Lee and other prominent Confederates as heroes while denouncing Abraham Lincoln, Ulysses S. Grant and other Union leaders for "open[ing] the Pandora's Box of genocide and the extermination of civilians" in their war against the South.[99][100] Middle East conflict[edit] Rothbard's The Libertarian Forum blamed the Middle East conflict on Israeli aggression "fueled by American arms and money". Rothbard warned that the Middle East conflict would draw the United States into a world war. He was anti-Zionist and opposed United States involvement in the Middle East. Rothbard criticized the Camp David Accords for having betrayed Palestinian aspirations and opposed Israel's 1982 invasion of Lebanon.[101] In his essay, "War Guilt in the Middle East", Rothbard states that Israel refused "to let these refugees return and reclaim the property taken from them".[102] He took negative views of the two state solution for the Israeli–Palestinian conflict, saying: On the one hand there are the Palestinian Arabs, who have tilled the soil or otherwise used the land of Palestine for centuries; and on the other, there are a group of external fanatics, who come from all over the world, and who claim the entire land area as "given" to them as a collective religion or tribe at some remote or legendary time in the past. There is no way the two claims can be resolved to the satisfaction of both parties. There can be no genuine settlement, no "peace" in the face of this irrepressible conflict; there can only be either a war to the death, or an uneasy practical compromise which can satisfy no one. That is the harsh reality of the Middle East.[103] Historical revisionism[edit] Rothbard embraced "historical revisionism" as an antidote to what he perceived to be the dominant influence exerted by corrupt "court intellectuals" over mainstream historical narratives.[7](pp15, 62, 141)[104] Rothbard wrote that these mainstream intellectuals distorted the historical record in favor of "the state" in exchange for "wealth, power, and prestige" from the state.[7](p15) Rothbard characterized the revisionist task as "penetrating the fog of lies and deception of the State and its Court Intellectuals, and to present to the public the true history".[104] He was influenced by and called a champion of the historian Harry Elmer Barnes, a Holocaust denier.[104][105][106] Rothbard endorsed Barnes's revisionism on World War II, favorably citing his view that "the murder of Germans and Japanese was the overriding aim of World War II". In addition to broadly supporting his historical views, Rothbard promoted Barnes as an influence for future revisionists.[107] Rothbard's endorsing of World War II revisionism and his association with Barnes and other Holocaust deniers have drawn criticism from within the political right. Kevin D. Williamson wrote an opinion piece published by National Review which condemned Rothbard for "making common cause with the 'revisionist' historians of the Third Reich", a term he used to describe American Holocaust deniers associated with Rothbard, such as James J. Martin of the Institute for Historical Review. The piece also characterized "Rothbard and his faction" as being "culpably indulgent" of Holocaust denial, the view which "specifically denies that the Holocaust actually happened or holds that it was in some way exaggerated".[108] In an article for Rothbard's 50th birthday, Rothbard's friend and Buffalo State College historian Ralph Raico stated that Rothbard "is the main reason that revisionism has become a crucial part of the whole libertarian position".[109] Children's rights and parental obligations[edit] In the Ethics of Liberty, Rothbard explores issues regarding children's rights in terms of self-ownership and contract.[110] These include support for a woman's right to abortion, condemnation of parents showing aggression towards children and opposition to the state forcing parents to care for children. He also holds children have the right to run away from parents and seek new guardians as soon as they are able to choose to do so. He argued that parents have the right to put a child out for adoption or sell the rights to the child in a voluntary contract in what Rothbard suggests will be a "flourishing free market in children". He believes that selling children as consumer goods in accord with market forces—while "superficially monstrous"—will benefit "everyone" involved in the market: "the natural parents, the children, and the foster parents purchasing".[111][112] In Rothbard's view of parenthood, "the parent should not have a legal obligation to feed, clothe, or educate his children, since such obligations would entail positive acts coerced upon the parent and depriving the parent of his rights".[111] Thus, Rothbard stated that parents should have the legal right to let any infant die by starvation and should be free to engage in other forms of child neglect. However, according to Rothbard, "the purely free society will have a flourishing free market in children". In a fully libertarian society, he wrote, "the existence of a free baby market will bring such 'neglect' down to a minimum".[111] Economist Gene Callahan of Cardiff University, formerly a scholar at the Rothbard-affiliated Mises Institute, observes that Rothbard allows "the logical elegance of his legal theory" to "trump any arguments based on the moral reprehensibility of a parent idly watching her six-month-old child slowly starve to death in its crib".[113] Civil liberties[edit] Rothbard consistently advocated for abolition of the subpoena power, court attendance, contempt of court powers, coerced testimony of witnesses, compulsory jury duty, and the bail system, arguing that all these functions of the judiciary were violations of natural rights and American common law. He instead advocated that until a defendant is convicted, he or she should not be held in prison or jails, writing that "except in those cases where the criminal has been caught red-handed and where a certain presumption of guilt therefore exists, it is impossible to justify any imprisonment before conviction, let alone before trial. And even when someone is caught red-handed, there is an important reform that needs to be instituted to keep the system honest: subjecting the police and the other authorities to the same law as everyone else. If everyone is supposed to be subject to the same criminal law, then exempting the authorities from that law gives them a legal license to commit continual aggression. The policeman who apprehends a criminal and arrests him, and the judicial and penal authorities who incarcerate him before trial and conviction—all should be subject to the universal law". Rothbard argued that police who make wrongful arrests or indictments should be charged with kidnapping.[114] Retributive theory of criminal justice[edit] In The Ethics of Liberty, Rothbard advocates for a "frankly retributive theory of punishment" or a system of "a tooth (or two teeth) for a tooth".[115] Rothbard emphasizes that all punishment must be proportional, stating that "the criminal, or invader, loses his rights to the extent that he deprived another man of his".[116] Applying his retributive theory, Rothbard states that a thief "must pay double the extent of theft". Rothbard gives the example of a thief who stole $15,000 and says he not only would have to return the stolen money, but also provide the victim an additional $15,000, money to which the thief has forfeited his right. The thief would be "put in a [temporary] state of enslavement to his victim" if he is unable to pay him immediately. Rothbard also applies his theory to justify beating and torturing violent criminals, although the beatings are required to be proportional to the crimes for which they are being punished. Torture of criminal suspects[edit] In chapter twelve of Ethics,[117] Rothbard turns his attention to suspects arrested by the police.[113] He argues that police should be able to torture certain types of criminal suspects, including accused murderers, for information related to their alleged crime. Writes Rothbard: "Suppose ... police beat and torture a suspected murderer to find information (not to wring a confession, since obviously a coerced confession could never be considered valid). If the suspect turns out to be guilty, then the police should be exonerated, for then they have only ladled out to the murderer a parcel of what he deserves in return; his rights had already been forfeited by more than that extent. But if the suspect is not convicted, then that means that the police have beaten and tortured an innocent man, and that they in turn must be put into the dock for criminal assault".[117] Gene Callahan examines this position and concludes that Rothbard rejects the widely held belief that torture is inherently wrong, no matter who the victim. Callahan goes on to state that Rothbard's scheme gives the police a strong motive to frame the suspect after having tortured him or her.[113] Science and scientism[edit] In an essay condemning "scientism in the study of man", Rothbard rejected the application of causal determinism to human beings, arguing that the actions of human beings—as opposed to those of everything else in nature—are not determined by prior causes, but by "free will".[118] He argued that "determinism as applied to man, is a self-contradictory thesis, since the man who employs it relies implicitly on the existence of free will". Rothbard opposed what he considered the overspecialization of the academy and sought to fuse the disciplines of economics, history, ethics and political science to create a "science of liberty". Rothbard described the moral basis for his anarcho-capitalist position in two of his books: For a New Liberty, published in 1973; and The Ethics of Liberty, published in 1982. In his Power and Market (1970), Rothbard describes how a stateless economy might function. Political activism[edit] As a young man, Rothbard considered himself part of the Old Right, an anti-statist and anti-interventionist branch of the Republican Party. In the 1948 presidential election, Rothbard, "as a Jewish student at Columbia, horrified his peers by organizing a Students for Strom Thurmond chapter, so staunchly did he believe in states' rights".[119] He was a member of The New York Young Republican Club.[23] By the late 1960s, Rothbard's "long and winding yet somehow consistent road had taken him from anti-New Deal and anti-interventionist Robert A. Taft supporter into friendship with the quasi-pacifist Nebraska Republican Congressman Howard Buffett (father of Warren Buffett) then over to the League of (Adlai) Stevensonian Democrats and, by 1968, into tentative comradeship with the anarchist factions of the New Left".[120] Rothbard advocated an alliance with the New Left anti-war movement on the grounds that the conservative movement had been completely subsumed by the statist establishment. However, Rothbard later criticized the New Left for supporting a "People's Republic" style draft. It was during this phase that he associated with Karl Hess and founded Left and Right: A Journal of Libertarian Thought with Leonard Liggio and George Resch, which existed from 1965 to 1968. From 1969 to 1984, he edited The Libertarian Forum, also initially with Hess (although Hess's involvement ended in 1971).[121] The Libertarian Forum provided a platform for Rothbard's writing. Despite its small readership, it engaged conservatives associated with the National Review in nationwide debate. Rothbard rejected the view that Ronald Reagan's 1980 election as President was a victory for libertarian principles and he attacked Reagan's economic program in a series of Libertarian Forum articles. In 1982, Rothbard called Reagan's claims of spending cuts a "fraud" and a "hoax" and accused Reaganites of doctoring the economic statistics in order to give the false impression that their policies were successfully reducing inflation and unemployment.[122] He further criticized the "myths of Reaganomics" in 1987.[123] Rothbard criticized the "frenzied nihilism" of left-wing libertarians, but also criticized right-wing libertarians who were content to rely only on education to bring down the state; he believed that libertarians should adopt any moral tactic available to them in order to bring about liberty.[124] Imbibing Randolph Bourne's idea that "war is the health of the state", Rothbard opposed all wars in his lifetime and engaged in anti-war activism.[35] During the 1970s and 1980s, Rothbard was active in the Libertarian Party. He was frequently involved in the party's internal politics. He was one of the founders of the Cato Institute and "came up with the idea of naming this libertarian think tank after Cato's Letters, a powerful series of British newspaper essays by John Trenchard and Thomas Gordon which played a decisive influence upon America's Founding Fathers in fomenting the Revolution".[125][126] From 1978 to 1983, he was associated with the Libertarian Party Radical Caucus, allying himself with Justin Raimondo, Eric Garris and Williamson Evers. He opposed the "low-tax liberalism" espoused by 1980 Libertarian Party presidential candidate Ed Clark and Cato Institute president Edward H Crane III. According to Charles Burris, "Rothbard and Crane became bitter rivals after disputes emerging from the 1980 LP presidential campaign of Ed Clark carried over to strategic direction and management of Cato".[125] Rothbard split with the Radical Caucus at the 1983 national convention over cultural issues and aligned himself with what he called the "right-wing populist" wing of the party, notably Lew Rockwell and Ron Paul, who ran for President on the Libertarian Party ticket in 1988. Rothbard "worked closely with Lew Rockwell (joined later by his long-time friend Burton Blumert) in nurturing the Ludwig von Mises Institute, and the publication, The Rothbard-Rockwell Report; which after Rothbard's 1995 death evolved into the website, LewRockwell.com".[125] Paleolibertarianism[edit] Lew Rockwell In 1989, Rothbard left the Libertarian Party and began building bridges to the post-Cold War anti-interventionist right, calling himself a paleolibertarian, a conservative reaction against the cultural liberalism of mainstream libertarianism.[127][128] Paleolibertarianism sought to appeal to disaffected working class whites through a synthesis of cultural conservatism and libertarian economics. According to Reason, Rothbard advocated right-wing populism in part because he was frustrated that mainstream thinkers were not adopting the libertarian view and suggested that former KKK Grand Wizard David Duke and Wisconsin Senator Joseph McCarthy[129] were models for an "Outreach to the Rednecks" effort that could be used by a broad libertarian/paleoconservative coalition. Working together, the coalition would expose the "unholy alliance of 'corporate liberal' Big Business and media elites, who, through big government, have privileged and caused to rise up a parasitic Underclass". Rothbard blamed this "Underclass" for "looting and oppressing the bulk of the middle and working classes in America".[127] Rothbard noted that Duke's substantive political program in a Louisiana governor's race had "nothing" in it that "could not also be embraced by paleoconservatives or paleolibertarians; lower taxes, dismantling the bureaucracy, slashing the welfare system, attacking affirmative action and racial set-asides, calling for equal rights for all Americans, including whites".[130] Rothbard supported the presidential campaign of Pat Buchanan in 1992 and wrote that "with Pat Buchanan as our leader, we shall break the clock of social democracy".[131] When Buchanan dropped out of the Republican primary race, Rothbard then shifted his interest and support to Ross Perot,[132] who Rothbard wrote had "brought an excitement, a verve, a sense of dynamics and of open possibilities to what had threatened to be a dreary race".[133] Rothbard ultimately supported George H. W. Bush over Bill Clinton in the 1992 election.[134][135] Like Buchanan, Rothbard opposed the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA).[136] However, he had become disillusioned with Buchanan by 1995, believing that the latter's "commitment to protectionism was mutating into an all-round faith in economic planning and the nation state".[137] After Rothbard's death in 1995, Lew Rockwell, president of the Mises Institute, told The New York Times that Rothbard was "the founder of right-wing anarchism".[29] William F. Buckley Jr. wrote a critical obituary in the National Review, criticizing Rothbard's "defective judgment" and views on the Cold War.[16](pp3–4) The Mises Institute published Murray N. Rothbard, In Memoriam which included memorials from 31 individuals, including libertarians and academics.[138] Journalist Brian Doherty has summarized Buckley's obituary as follows: "[W]hen Rothbard died in 1995, his old pal William Buckley took pen in hand to piss on his grave".[139] Hoppe, Rockwell, and Rothbard's colleagues at the Mises Institute took a different view, arguing that he was one of the most important philosophers in history.[138] Works[edit] Articles “His Only Crime Was Against the Old Guard: Milken: In the best tradition of free enterprise, he made money by serving the public.”. Los Angeles Times, March 3, 1992. “Saint Hillary and the Religious Left”. December 1994. “The Other Side of the Coin: Free Banking in Chile”. Austrian Economics Newsletter, Vol. 10, No. 2. Books Man, Economy, and State, D. Van Nostrand, 1962; full text reprint of second edition (Scholar's Edition), Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2004, ISBN 0-945466-30-7. The Panic of 1819: Reactions and Policies, Columbia University Press, 1962; full text reprint, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2004, ISBN 1-933550-08-2. America's Great Depression, D. Van Nostrand, 1973; full text reprint, fifth edition, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2005, ISBN 0-945466-05-6. Power and Market: Government and the Economy, Sheed Andrews and McMeel, 1970; full text reprint, reattached to Man, Economy, and State, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2004, ISBN 0-945466-30-7. For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto, Collier Books, 1973, 1978; full text reprint/Audio book, Ludwig von Mises Institute, ISBN 0-945466-47-1). The Essential von Mises, "Bramble Minibook", 1973; full text reprint, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988. Egalitarianism as a Revolt Against Nature and Other Essays, Libertarian Review Press, 1974; full text reprint, Second edition, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2000, ISBN 0-945466-23-4. Conceived in Liberty, (4 vol.), Arlington House Publishers 1975–1979; full text collected in single volume, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2012, ISBN 0-945466-26-9. The Logic of Action (2 vol.), Edward Elgar Publications, 1997, ISBN 1-85898-015-1 and ISBN 1-85898-570-6; full text reprint as Economic Controversies, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2011. The Ethics of Liberty, Humanities Press, 1982; New York University Press, 1998; full text reprint/Audio Book, Ludwig von Mises Institute, ISBN 0-8147-7506-3. The Mystery of Banking, Richardson and Snyder, Dutton, 1983; full text reprint, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2007, ISBN 978-1105528781. The Case Against the Fed, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1994; full text reprint, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2007, ISBN 0-945466-17-X. An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, (2 vol.), Edward Elgar Publishers, 1995, ISBN 0-945466-48-X; full text reprints Vol. 1: Economic Thought Before Adam Smith and Vol. 2: Classical Economics, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2009. Making Economic Sense, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2007, ISBN 0-945466-18-8; full text reprint updated 7/15/2011 version. The Betrayal of the American Right, Ludwig von Mises Institute publication of 1970s unpublished work, 2007, ISBN 978-1-933550-13-8; full text reprint. Book contributions “Introduction”. Capital, Interest, and Rent: Essays in the Theory of Distribution, by Frank A. Fetter. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel, 1977. “Foreword”. The Theory of Money and Credit, by Ludwig von Mises. Liberty Fund edition, 1981. Full text available. Monographs Wall Street, Banks, and American Foreign Policy. World Market Perspective, 1984. Center for Libertarian Studies, 1995. Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2005; 2nd 2011. Full text and a Spanish translation are available. Interviews[edit] “Interview with Murray Rothbard on Man, Economy, and State, Mises, and the Future of the Austrian School”. Austrian Economics Newsletter, Summer 1990. See also[edit] Libertarianism portal American philosophy Anarcho-capitalism Criticism of the Federal Reserve Libertarianism in the United States List of American philosophers Notes[edit] ^ Lewis, David Charles (2006). "Rothbard, Murray Newton (1926–1995)". In Ross Emmett (ed.). Biographical Dictionary of American Economists. Thoemmes. ISBN 978-1-84371112-4. ^ David Boaz, April 25, 2007, Libertarianism – The Struggle Ahead, Encyclopædia Britannica blog; reprinted at the Cato Institute: "a professional economist and also a movement builder". ^ F. Eugene Heathe, 2007. Encyclopedia of Business Ethics and Society, SAGE, 89: "an economist of the Austrian school". ^ Ronald Hamowy, ed., 2008, The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, Cato Institute, SAGE, ISBN 1-41296580-2, p. 62: "a leading economist of the Austrian school"; pp. 11, 365, 458: "Austrian economist". ^ Bessner, Daniel (December 8, 2014). "Murray Rothbard, political strategy, and the making of modern libertarianism". Intellectual History Review. 24 (4): 441–456. doi:10.1080/17496977.2014.970371. S2CID 143391240. ^ Matthews, Peter Hans; Ortmann, Andreas (July 2002). "An Austrian (Mis)Reads Adam Smith: A critique of Rothbard as intellectual historian". Review of Political Economy. 14 (3): 379–392. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.535.510. doi:10.1080/09538250220147895. S2CID 39872371. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l Raimondo, Justin (2000). An Enemy of the State: The Life of Murray N. Rothbard. Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books. ISBN 978-1-61592-239-0. OCLC 43541222. ^ Doherty, Brian (2008). "Rothbard, Murray (1926–1995)". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. pp. 441–43. ISBN 978-1-4129-6580-4. OCLC 233969448. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1997). "The Myth of Neutral Taxation". The Logic of Action Two: Applications and Criticism from the Austrian School. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. p. 67. ISBN 978-1-85898-570-1. First published in The Cato Journal, Fall 1981. ^ Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (1998). "Introduction". The Ethics of Liberty. Ludwig von Mises Institute. ^ Rothbard, Murray (2002) [1982]. "The Nature of the State". The Ethics of Liberty. New York: New York University Press. pp. 167–68. ISBN 978-0-8147-7506-6. ^ Rothbard, Murray. The Great Society: A Libertarian Critique, Lew Rockwell. ^ Rothbard, Murray. The Noble Task of Revisionism Archived June 18, 2015, at the Wayback Machine, Lew Rockwell. ^ Rothbard, Murray. The Fallacy of the 'Public Sector' ^ a b Rothbard, Murray (2008) [1983]. The Mystery of Banking (2nd ed.). Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute. pp. 111–13. ISBN 978-1-933550-28-2. ^ a b Casey, Gerard (2010). Meadowcroft, John (ed.). Murray Rothbard. Major Conservative and Libertarian Thinkers. 15. London: Continuum. pp. 4–5, 129. ISBN 978-1-4411-4209-2. ^ Klausner, Manuel S. "The New Isolationism: An Interview with Murray Rothbard and Leonard Liggio". Reason. ^ Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (December 31, 2001). "Anarcho-Capitalism: An Annotated Bibliography". Retrieved June 2, 2013. ^ Herbener, J. (1995). L. Rockwell (ed.), Murray Rothbard, In Memoriam Archived December 20, 2014, at the Wayback Machine. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute. p. 87 ^ Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (1999). "Murray N. Rothbard: Economics, Science, and Liberty". The Ludwig von Mises Institute. Reprinted from 15 Great Austrian Economists, edited by Randall G. Holcombe. ^ Raimondo, Justin (2000). An Enemy of the State: The Life of Murray N. Rothbard. Prometheus Books, Publishers. p. 34. ISBN 978-1-61592-239-0. ^ a b Rothbard, Murray. "Life in the Old Right". Lewrockwell.com. Retrieved March 16, 2015. ^ a b "History". ^ French, Doug (December 27, 2010) Burns Diary Exposes the Myth of Fed Independence, Ludwig von Mises Institute ^ David Gordon, (editor), Strictly Confidential: The Private Volker Fund Memos of Murray N. Rothbard, 2010; Full text reprint Quote from Rothbard: "The Volker Fund concept was to find and grant research funds to hosts of libertarian and right-wing scholars and to draw these scholars together via seminars, conferences, etc." ^ a b c d Gordon, David (2007). The Essential Rothbard (PDF). Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-1-933550-10-7. OCLC 123960448.[permanent dead link] ^ https://mises.org/library/joann-beatrice-schumacher-rothbard-1928-1999 ^ Scott Sublett, "Libertarians' Storied Guru," Washington Times, July 30, 1987 ^ a b c d e David Stout, Obituary: Murray N. Rothbard, Economist And Free-Market Exponent, 68, The New York Times, January 11, 1995. ^ Peter G. Klein, Editor, F. A. Hayek, The Fortunes of Liberalism: Essays on Austrian Economics and the Ideal of Freedom, University of Chicago Press, 2012, p. 54, ISBN 0-22632116-9 ^ Rockwell, Llewellyn H (May 31, 2007). "Three National Treasures." Mises.org ^ Frohnen, Bruce; Beer, Jeremy; Nelson, Jeffrey O., eds. (2006). "Rothbard, Murray (1926–95)". American Conservatism: An Encyclopedia. Wilmington, DE: ISI Books. p. 750. ISBN 978-1-932236-43-9. Only after several decades of teaching at the Polytechnic Institute of New York did Rothbard obtain an endowed chair, and like that of Mises at NYU, his own at the University of Nevada at Las Vegas was established by an admiring benefactor. ^ Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (1999). "Murray N. Rothbard: Economics, Science, and Liberty." Mises.org ^ Lee, Frederic S., and Cronin, Bruce C. (2010). "Research Quality Rankings of Heterodox Economic Journals in a Contested Discipline." American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 69(5): 1428 ^ a b c d Gordon, David. "Biography of Murray N. Rothbard (1926–1995)". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Rothbard, JoAnn. Murray Rothbard, In Memoriam (PDF). Auburn, AL: von Mises Institute. p. vii–ix. Archived from the original (PDF) on December 20, 2014. Retrieved December 16, 2014. ^ Sciabarra, Chris (2000). Total Freedom: Toward a Dialectical Libertarianism, Penn State Press, 2000. p. 358, ISBN 0-27102049-0 ^ Vance, Laurence M (March 15, 2011). "Is Libertarianism Compatible with Religion?" LewRockwell.com ^ Raimondo, Justin (2000). An Enemy of the State: The Life of Murray N. Rothbard. Prometheus Books. p. 67. ISBN 978-1-61592-239-0. ^ Raimondo, Justin (2000). An Enemy of the State: the Life of Murray N. Rothbard. Prometheus Books. p. 326. ISBN 978-1-57392809-0. In the same letter, he reiterates his atheism: "On the religion question, we paleolibertarians are not theocrats," he writes. "Obviously, I could not be myself, both as a libertarian and as an atheist." However, he continued, "the left-libertarian hostility to religion, based as it is on ignorance and the bitterness of "aging adolescent rebels against bourgeois America", is "monstrous." ^ Casey, Gerard (2010). Meadowcroft, John (ed.). Murray Rothbard. Major Conservative and Libertarian Thinkers. 15. London: Continuum. p. 15. ISBN 978-1-4411-4209-2. ^ a b Burns, Jennifer (2009). Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right. Oxford Univ. Press. ISBN 978-0-19-532487-7. ^ "Mises and Rothbard Letters to Ayn Rand", Journal of Libertarian Studies, Volume 21, No. 4 (Winter 2007): 11–16. ^ Chris Matthew Sciabarra, Total Freedom: Toward a Dialectical Libertarianism, Penn State Press, 2000. p. 165, ISBN 0271020490 ^ Murray Rothbard play Mozart was a Red, early 1960s, at LewRockwell.com. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1972). "The Sociology of the Ayn Rand Cult." ^ Mozart Was a Red: A Morality Play in One Act by Murray N. Rothbard, with an introduction by Justin Raimondo ^ a b Rothbard, Murray (1976). Praxeology: The Methodology of Austrian Economics. Mises.org ^ "Where Modern Economics Went Wrong". mises.org. Archived from the original on September 16, 2014. Retrieved August 28, 2017. ^ Mark Skousen. The Making of Modern Economics (M. E. Sharpe, 2009, p. 390). Skousen writes that Rothbard "refused to write for the academic journals." ^ Rothbard, Murray (1991) [1962]. "The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ North, Gary (October 10, 2009). "What Is Money? Part 5: Fractional Reserve Banking". LewRockwell.com. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Casey, Gerard (2010). Murray Rothbard. New York, NY: The Continuum International Publishing Group. p. 112. ISBN 978-1-4411-4209-2. ^ Tony Endres, review of Classical Economics: An Austrian Perspective, History of Economics Review, http://www.hetsa.org.au/pdf-back/23-RA-7.pdf ^ Keynes the Man, originally published in Dissent on Keynes: A Critical Appraisal of Keynesian Economics, Edited by Mark Skousen. New York: Praeger, 1992, pp. 171–98; Online edition at The Ludwig von Mises Institute ^ Gordon, David (1999). "John Stuart Mill on Liberty and Control." Archived September 14, 2014, at the Wayback Machine The Mises Review ^ Ruger, William (2013). Meadowcroft, John, ed. Milton Friedman. Major Conservative and Libertarian Thinkers. New York, NY: Bloomsbury. p. 174 ^ Rothbard, Murray (1971). "Milton Friedman Unraveled." LewRockwell.com ^ Doherty, Brian (1995). "Best of Both Worlds." Archived April 5, 2019, at the Wayback Machine Reason ^ Rockwell, Llewellyn (1995). Murray N. Rothbard In Memoriam (PDF). Auburn, Alabama: Mises Institute. pp. 33–37. Archived from the original (PDF) on December 20, 2014. Retrieved December 16, 2014. ^ In Defense of "Extreme Apriorism" Murray N. Rothbard Southern Economic Journal, January 1957, pp. 314–20 ^ Kirzner, Israel. "Interview of Israel Kirzner". Mises Institute. Retrieved June 17, 2013. ^ Tyler Cowen and Richard Fink (1985). "Inconsistent Equilibrium Constructs: The Evenly Rotating Equilibrium Economy of Mises and Rothbard". American Economic Review. 75 (4): 866–869. JSTOR 1821365. ^ Gunning, Patrick (November 23, 2014). "Mises on the Evenly Rotating Economy". Journal of Austrian Economics. 3 (3). ^ "free marketeers and inflation." The Economist ^ Boettke, Peter (1988). "Economists and Liberty: Murray N. Rothbard". Nomos: 29ff. Retrieved November 17, 2013. ^ Grimm, Curtis M.; Hunn, Lee; Smith, Ken G. Strategy as Action: Competitive Dynamics and Competitive Advantage. New York: Oxford University Press. 2006. p. 43 ^ Olsaretti, Serena. 2004. Liberty, Desert and the Market. Cambridge University Press. p. 91 ^ Kyriazi, Harold (2004). "31 Reckoning with Rothbard". American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 63 (2): 451–84. doi:10.1111/j.1536-7150.2004.00298.x. ^ George C. Leef, "Book Review of Egalitarianism as a Revolt Against Nature and Other Essays by Murray Rothbard", edited by David Gordon (2000 edition), The Freeman, July 2001. ^ Rothbard, Murray (2003). "Egalitarianism as a Revolt Against Nature and Other Essays", essay published in full at Lewrockwell.com. See also Rothbard's essay "The Struggle Over Egalitarianism Continues", the 1991 introduction to republication of Freedom, Inequality, Primitivism, and the Division of Labor, Ludwig Von Mises Institute, 2008. ^ Schoeffel, John; Chomsky, Noam (2011). Understanding Power: The Indispensable Chomsky. ReadHowYouWant.com. ISBN 978-1-4587-8817-7. ^ Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Thought, 1987, ISBN 978-0-631-17944-3, p. 290; quote: "A student and disciple of the Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises, Rothbard combined the laissez-faire economics of his teacher with the absolutist views of human rights and rejection of the state he had absorbed from studying the individualist American anarchists of the 19th century such as Lysander Spooner and Benjamin Tucker." ^ Rockwell, Llewellyn (1995). "Murray N. Rothbard: In Memoriam." Archived December 20, 2014, at the Wayback Machine p. 117 ^ Ronald Hamowy, ed. (August 15, 2008). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, California: SAGE. p. 623. ISBN 978-1-4129-6580-4. Rothbard, Murray N (August 17, 2007). "Floyd Arthur 'Baldy' Harper, RIP". Mises Daily. ^ Miller, David, ed. (1991). Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Thought. Blackwell Publishing. p. 290. ISBN 978-0-631-17944-3. ^ a b Roberta Modugno Crocetta, Murray Rothbard's anarcho-capitalism in the contemporary debate. A critical defense, Ludwig Von Mises Institute. ^ Oliver, Michael (February 25, 1972). "Exclusive Interview With Murray Rothbard". The New Banner: A Fortnightly Libertarian Journal. Capitalism is the fullest expression of anarchism, and anarchism is the fullest expression of capitalism. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1950s). "Are Libertarians 'Anarchists'?" Lew Rockwell.com. Retrieved 4 September 2020. ^ Ikeda, Sanford, Dynamics of the Mixed Economy: Toward a Theory of Interventionism, Routledge UK, 1997, p. 245. ^ Rothbard, Murray. Chapter 2 "Fundamentals of Intervention" from Man, Economy and State, Ludwig von Mises Institute. ^ Peter G. Klein, "Why Intellectuals Still Support Socialism", Ludwig von Mises Institute, November 15, 2006 ^ Man, Economy, and State, Chapter 7 – Conclusion: Economics and Public Policy, Ludwig Von Mises Institute. ^ O'Malley, Michael (2012). Face Value: The Entwined Histories of Money and Race in America. Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press. pp. 205–07 ^ Murray N. Rothbard (August 11, 2006). "Origins of the Welfare State in America". mises.org. ^ "The Great Thomas & Hill Show: Stopping the Monstrous Regiment". archive.lewrockwell.com. Archived from the original on April 18, 2017. Retrieved July 31, 2016. ^ "Open Borders Are an Assault on Private Property – LewRockwell LewRockwell.com". Retrieved July 31, 2016. ^ "Right-Wing Populism". archive.lewrockwell.com. Archived from the original on May 24, 2016. Retrieved July 31, 2016. ^ Rothbard, Murray (Spring–Autumn 1967). "The Black Revolution". Left and Right. 3: 7–17. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. (February 1993). "Their Malcolm ... and Mine." LewRockwell.com ^ Rothbard, Murray (November 1994). "Big-Government Libertarians." LewRockwell.com ^ Stromberg, Joseph R. (January 10, 2005) [first published June 12, 2000]. "Murray Rothbard on States, War, and Peace: Part I". Antiwar.com. Also see Part II, originally published June 20, 2000. ^ See both essays: Rothbard, Murray. "War, Peace, and the State" Archived May 15, 2013, at the Wayback Machine, first published 1963; "Anatomy of the State" Archived September 8, 2012, at the Wayback Machine, first published 1974. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. (2007) [1968]. "Harry Elmer Barnes, RIP". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Archived from the original on October 17, 2012. Retrieved April 3, 2009. Article originally appeared in Left and Right: A Journal of Libertarian Thought. ^ Stromberg, Joseph (June 12, 2000). "Murray N. Rothbard on States, War, and Peace: Part I." Antiwar.com ^ Rothbard, Murray (1991). "Just War." LewRockwell.com ^ Denson, J. (1997). Costs of War: America's Pyrrhic Victories. (pp. 119–33). New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers. ^ Dilorenzo, Thomas (January 28, 2006). "More from Rothbard on War, Religion, and the State." LewRockwell.com ^ Denson, John V. (1999). The Costs of War: America's Pyrrhic Victories. Transaction Publishers. p. 133. ISBN 978-0-7658-0487-7. ^ Barr, John McKee (April 7, 2014). Loathing Lincoln: An American Tradition from the Civil War to the Present. LSU Press. p. 265. ISBN 978-0-8071-5384-0. ^ Perry, Marvin (1999). "Libertarian Forum 1969–1986". In Lora, Ronald; Longton, William Henry (eds.). The Conservative Press in Twentieth-Century America. Greenwood Publishing Group. p. 372. ISBN 978-0-313-21390-8. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. (Autumn 1967). "War Guilt in the Middle East" (PDF). Left and Right. 3 (3): 20–30. Reprinted in Rothbard, Murray N. (2007). Left and Right: A Journal of Libertarian Thought (The Complete Edition, 1965–1968). Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-1-61016-040-7. OCLC 741754456. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. (April 1994). "The Vital Importance of Separation". The Rothbard-Rockwell Report. Retrieved November 5, 2018. ^ a b c Rothbard, Murray (February 1976). "The Case for Revisionism." Mises.org ^ Bertrand Badie, Dirk Berg-Schlosser, Leonardo Morlino, Editors, International Encyclopedia of Political Science, Volume 1, "Revisionism" entry, SAGE, 2011 p. 2310, ISBN 1412959632 ^ Raimondo, Justin (2000). An Enemy of the State: The Life of Murray N. Rothbard. Amherst, New York: Prometheus Books. pp. 15, 62, 141. ISBN 978-1-61592-239-0. OCLC 43541222. Raimondo describes Rothbard as a "champion of Henry Elmer Barnes, the dean of world-war revisionism". ^ Rothbard, Murray (1968). "Harry Elmer Barnes as Revisionist of the Cold War." ^ Williamson, Kevin D. (January 23, 2012). "Courting the Cranks."National Review, January 2013 edition. p. 4 (subscription required) Archived October 20, 2017, at the Wayback Machine ^ Raico, Ralph (May 23, 2010). "Rothbard at his Semi-Centennial". Mises Institute. Retrieved November 15, 2013. ^ Walker, John (1991). "Children's Rights versus Murray Rothbard's The Ethics of Liberty". Libertarians for Life. Archived from the original on September 10, 2012. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ a b c Murray N Rothbard (1982). "14 "Children and Rights"". The Ethics of Liberty. LvMI. ISBN 9780814775592. ^ See also: Hamowy, Ronald (editor) (2008). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, Cato Institute, SAGE, pp. 59–61, ISBN 1-4129-6580-2, ISBN 978-1-4129-6580-4 OCLC 233969448 ^ a b c Callahan, Gene (February 2013). "Liberty versus Libertarianism". Politics, Philosophy & Economics. 12 (1): 48–67. doi:10.1177/1470594X11433739. ISSN 1470-594X. OCLC 828009007. S2CID 144062406. ^ "The Tyranny of Government Courts and Prisons | Mises Institute". mises.org. April 10, 2011. Retrieved August 28, 2017. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1998). "Punishment and Proportionality". The Ethics of Liberty. New York University Press. pp. 85–97. ISBN 978-0-8147-7506-6. ^ Morimura, Susumu (1999). "Libertarian theories of punishment." In P. Smith & P. Comanducci (Eds.), Legal Philosophy: General Aspects: Theoretical Examinations and Practical Application (pp. 135–38). New York, NY: Franz Steiner Verlag. ^ a b Rothbard, Murray (1998). "Self-Defense". The Ethics of Liberty. New York University Press. pp. 77–84. ISBN 978-0-8147-7506-6. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1960). "The Mantle of Science." Reprinted from Scientism and Values, Helmut Schoeck and James W. Wiggins, eds. (Princeton, N.J.: D. Van Nostrand), 1960, pp. 159–80, ISBN 978-0405004360 ; The Logic of Action One: Method, Money, and the Austrian School (Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar, 1997), pp. 3–23. ISBN 978-1858980157 ^ McCarthy, Daniel (March 12, 2007). "Enemies of the State". The American Conservative. Archived from the original on June 5, 2011. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Kauffman, Bill (May 19, 2008). "When the Left Was Right". The American Conservative. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Riggenbach, Jeff (May 13, 2010). "Karl Hess and the Death of Politics". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Ronald Lora, William Henry Longton, editors, The Conservative Press in Twentieth-Century America, Chapter "The Libertarian Forum", Greenwood Publishing Group, 1999, p. 372, ISBN 0313213909, ^ "The Myths of Reaganomics | Mises Institute". mises.org. June 9, 2004. Retrieved August 28, 2017. ^ Perry, Marvin (1999). "Libertarian Forum 1969–1986". In Lora, Ronald; Henry, William Longton (eds.). The Conservative Press in Twentieth-Century America. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Publishing Group. p. 369. ISBN 978-0-313-21390-8. OCLC 40481045. ^ a b c Burris, Charles (February 4, 2011). "Kochs v. Soros: A Partial Backstory". LewRockwell.com. Retrieved August 14, 2013. ^ "25 years at the Cato Institute: The 2001 Annual Report" (PDF). pp. 11, 12. Retrieved August 18, 2013. ^ a b Sanchez, Julian; Weigel, David (January 16, 2008). "Who Wrote Ron Paul's Newsletters?". Reason. Retrieved August 14, 2013. ^ Rothbard, Murray (November 1994). "Big Government Libertarianism", LewRockwell.com ^ Rothbard, Murray (2010). "A Strategy for the Right". mises.org. ^ Rothbard, Murray (January 1992). "Right-wing Populism". LewRockwell.com. Archived from the original on May 24, 2016. Retrieved August 14, 2013. Originally published in the January 1992 Rothbard-Rockwell Report. ^ Rothbard, Murray. "Strategy for the Right". LewRockwell.com. Retrieved August 14, 2013. First published in The Rothbard-Rockwell Report, January 1992. ^ Rockwell, Jr., Llewellyn H. (April 8, 2005). "Still the State's Greatest Living Enemy". Mises Daily. Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Rothbard, Murray (June 1, 1992) "Little Texan Connects Big With Masses: Perot is a populist in the content of his views and in the manner of his candidacy", Los Angeles Times ^ Rothbard, Murray (July 30, 1992). "Hold Back the Hordes for 4 More Years: Any sensible American has one real choice – George Bush". Los Angeles Times. ^ Raimondo, Justin (October 1, 2012). "Race for the White House, 2012: Whom to Root For?". Antiwar.com. Retrieved August 13, 2013. ^ Reese, Charley (October 14, 1993) "The U.S. Standard Of Living Will Decline If Nafta Is Approved", Orlando Sentinel ^ Lew Rockwell, "What I Learned From Paleoism", LewRockwell.com, 2002. ^ a b Murray N. Rothbard, In Memoriam Archived December 20, 2014, at the Wayback Machine, Preface by JoAnn Rothbard, edited by Llewellyn H. Rockwell, Jr, published by Ludwig von Mises Institute,1995. ^ Goldberg, Jonah (July 2, 2005). "Idealists vs. Empiricists". New Republic. Retrieved September 4, 2013. Further reading[edit] Block, Walter E. (Spring 2003). "Toward a Libertarian Theory of Inalienability: A Critique of Rothbard, Barnett, Gordon, Smith, Kinsella and Epstein" (PDF). Journal of Libertarian Studies. 17 (2). SSRN 1889456. Archived from the original (PDF) on July 2, 2014. Retrieved September 13, 2014. Boettke, Peter (Fall–Winter 1988). "Economists and Liberty: Murray N. Rothbard" (PDF). Nomos: 29–34, 49–50. ISSN 0078-0979. OCLC 1760419. Archived from the original (PDF) on September 25, 2013. Retrieved September 21, 2013. Doherty, Brian (2007). Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement. PublicAffairs. ISBN 1-58648-350-1 Frech, H. E. (1973). "The public choice theory of Murray N. Rothbard, a modern anarchist". Public Choice. 14: 143–53. doi:10.1007/BF01718450. JSTOR 30022711. S2CID 154133800. Hudík, Marek (2011). "Rothbardian demand: A critique". The Review of Austrian Economics. 24 (3): 311–18. doi:10.1007/s11138-011-0147-3. S2CID 153559003. Klein, Daniel B. (Fall 2004). "Mere Libertarianism: Blending Hayek and Rothbard". Reason Papers. 27: 7–43. SSRN 473601. Pack, Spencer J. (1998). "Murray Rothbard's Adam Smith" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 1 (1): 73–79. doi:10.1007/s12113-998-1004-5. S2CID 153815373. Archived from the original (PDF) on April 2, 2013. Retrieved September 13, 2014. Touchstone, Kathleen (2010). "Rand, Rothbard, and Rights Reconsidered" (PDF). Libertarian Papers. 2 (18): 28. OCLC 820597333. Archived from the original (PDF) on October 20, 2017. Retrieved August 16, 2013. External links[edit] Murray Rothbardat Wikipedia's sister projects Media from Wikimedia Commons Quotations from Wikiquote Texts from Wikisource Data from Wikidata Murray Rothbard full bibliography at Mises.org Rothbard videos at YouTube channel of the Ludwig von Mises Institute Murray N. Rothbard Library and Resources from LewRockwell.com Murray Rothbard Institute, Belgium Murray Newton Rothbard at Find a Grave Murray Rothbard publications indexed by Google Scholar v t e Books by Murray Rothbard Man, Economy, and State (1962) The Panic of 1819 (1962) America's Great Depression (1963) What Has Government Done to Our Money? (1963) Power and Market (1970) For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto (1973) Egalitarianism as a Revolt Against Nature and Other Essays (1974) Conceived in Liberty (1975–79) The Ethics of Liberty (1982) The Mystery of Banking (1983) The Case Against the Fed (1994) An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought (1995) A History of Money and Banking in the United States (2002) The Complete Libertarian Forum (2006) Left and Right: A Journal of Libertarian Thought (Complete, 1965–1968) (2007) The Betrayal of the American Right (2007) v t e Anarcho-capitalism Origins Aristotelianism Austrian School Marginalism School of Salamanca Subjective theory of value Classical liberalism French Liberal School Homestead principle Labor theory of property Physiocracy Individualist anarchism Concepts Anti-statism Civil rights Counter-economics Decentralization Departurism Deregulation Economic liberalism Evictionism Free market Free-market anarchism Free-market roads Free trade Freedom of contract Individualism Jurisdictional arbitrage Laissez-faire Land ownership Natural Law Non-aggression principle Polycentric law Private defense agency Private governance Private military company Private police Private property Privatization Propertarianism Property rights Right to own property Self-ownership Spontaneous order Title-transfer theory of contract Voluntaryism People Bruce L. Benson Walter Block Bryan Caplan Gerard Casey Anthony de Jasay David D. Friedman Hans-Hermann Hoppe Michael Huemer Stephan Kinsella Michael Malice Robert P. Murphy Wendy McElroy Lew Rockwell Murray Rothbard Joseph Salerno Jeffrey Tucker Thomas Woods Works Defending the Undefendable Democracy: The God That Failed The Ethics of Liberty For a New Liberty The Machinery of Freedom The Market for Liberty The Problem of Political Authority To Serve and Protect The Voluntary City Issues Abortion Anarchism Capital punishment Criticism Foreign affairs Immigration Inheritance Intellectual property Internal debates LGBT rights Minarchism Objectivism Political parties Politics Theories of law Related topics Agorism Right-libertarianism Libertarianism in the United States Left-libertarianism Category v t e Austrian School economists Influences Frédéric Bastiat French Liberal School Jean-Baptiste Say Gustave de Molinari School of Salamanca Founders Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk Friedrich Hayek Carl Menger Ludwig von Mises Friedrich von Wieser Other contributors Walter Block Peter Boettke Thomas DiLorenzo Frank Fetter Roger Garrison Gottfried Haberler Henry Hazlitt Robert Higgs Hans-Hermann Hoppe Steven Horwitz Jesús Huerta de Soto Israel Kirzner Ludwig Lachmann Roderick T. Long Fritz Machlup Robert Murphy David Prychitko Larry Reed Murray Rothbard Joseph Salerno Mark Skousen Gerhard Tintner See also List of Austrian School economists v t e Libertarianism Origins Age of Enlightenment Anarchism Aristotelianism Liberalism Schools Libertarian capitalism (Right-libertarianism) Anarcho-capitalism Autarchism Christian libertarianism Conservative libertarianism Consequentialist libertarianism Fusionism Libertarian transhumanism Minarchism Natural-rights libertarianism Neo-classical liberalism Paleolibertarianism Propertarianism Voluntaryism Libertarian socialism (Left-libertarianism) Anarchism Collectivist Free-market Agorism Left-wing laissez-faire Left-wing market Green Individualist Insurrectionary Libertarian communism Mutualism Pan- Philosophical Social Autonomism Bleeding-heart libertarianism Communalism Geolibertarianism Georgism Green libertarianism Guild socialism Liberalism Classical Radical Libertarian Marxism Participism Revolutionary syndicalism Concepts Anti-authoritarianism Anti-capitalism Antimilitarism Anti-statism Argumentation ethics Class struggle Communes Counter-economics Crypto-anarchism Decentralization Departurism Direct action Economic democracy Economic freedom Egalitarianism Evictionism Expropriative anarchism Federalism (anarchist) Free association (Marxism and anarchism) Free love Free market Free-market environmentalism Free migration Free trade Freedom of association Freedom of contract Global Justice Movement Gift economy Homestead principle Illegalism Individualism Individual reclamation Liberty Localism Natural and legal rights Night-watchman state Non-aggression principle Non-voting Participatory economics Polycentric law Private defense agency Propaganda of the deed Property is theft Really Really Free Market Refusal of work Restorative justice Self-governance Self-ownership Single tax Social ecology Spontaneous order Squatting Stateless society Tax resistance Title-transfer theory of contract Voluntary society Workers' councils Workers' self-management People Stephen Pearl Andrews Mikhail Bakunin Frédéric Bastiat Walter Block Murray Bookchin Jason Brennan Bryan Caplan Kevin Carson Frank Chodorov Noam Chomsky Grover Cleveland Calvin Coolidge Voltairine de Cleyre Joseph Déjacque Ralph Waldo Emerson David D. Friedman Milton Friedman Mahatma Gandhi Henry George William Godwin Emma Goldman Barry Goldwater David Graeber William Batchelder Greene Daniel Hannan Friedrich Hayek Auberon Herbert Karl Hess Thomas Hodgskin Hans-Hermann Hoppe Michael Huemer Penn Jillette Gary Johnson Stephan Kinsella Samuel Edward Konkin III Janusz Korwin-Mikke Étienne de La Boétie Rose Wilder Lane David Leyonhjelm Roderick T. Long Lord Acton Tibor Machan Wendy McElroy Ludwig von Mises Gustave de Molinari Albert Jay Nock Robert Nozick Isabel Paterson Ron Paul Pierre-Joseph Proudhon Ralph Raico Ayn Rand Leonard Read Murray Rothbard Joseph Schumpeter Chris Matthew Sciabarra Julian Simon Herbert Spencer Lysander Spooner Max Stirner John Stossel Thomas Szasz Henry David Thoreau Leo Tolstoy Benjamin Tucker Josiah Warren Issues Anarcho-capitalism and minarchism Criticism Intellectual property Internal debates LGBT rights Objectivism Political parties Theories of law Books Anarchy, State, and Utopia Atlas Shrugged For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto Free to Choose Law, Legislation and Liberty The Market for Liberty Related Anti-collectivism Anti-communism Anti-fascism Anti-socialism Austro-libertarianism Center for Libertarian Studies Civil libertarianism Classical liberalism Constitutionalism Economic liberalism Fusionism Green libertarianism Libertarian conservatism Libertarian socialism Libertarian Democrat Libertarian Republican Libertarian science fiction Libertarianism in South Africa Libertarianism in the United Kingdom Libertarianism in the United States Objectivism Public choice theory Small government Technolibertarianism Libertarianism portal Outline of libertarianism v t e Social and political philosophy Ancient philosophers Aristotle Chanakya Cicero Confucius Han Fei Lactantius Laozi Mencius Mozi Origen Plato Polybius Shang Socrates Sun Tzu Tertullian Thucydides Valluvar Xenophon Xunzi Medieval philosophers Alpharabius Augustine Averroes Baldus Bartolus Bruni Dante Gelasius al-Ghazali Giles Hostiensis Ibn Khaldun John of Paris John of Salisbury Latini Maimonides Marsilius Nizam al-Mulk Photios Thomas Aquinas Wang William of Ockham Early modern philosophers Beza Bodin Bossuet Botero Buchanan Calvin Cumberland Duplessis-Mornay Erasmus Filmer Grotius Guicciardini Harrington Hayashi Hobbes Hotman Huang Leibniz Locke Luther Machiavelli Malebranche Mariana Milton Montaigne More Müntzer Naudé Pufendorf Rohan Sansovino Sidney Spinoza Suárez 18th–19th-century philosophers Bakunin Bentham Bonald Bosanquet Burke Comte Constant Emerson Engels Fichte Fourier Franklin Godwin Hamann Hegel Herder Hume Jefferson Justi Kant political philosophy Kierkegaard Le Bon Le Play Madison Maistre Marx Mazzini Mill Montesquieu Möser Nietzsche Novalis Paine Renan Rousseau Royce Sade Schiller Smith Spencer Stirner Taine Thoreau Tocqueville Vico Vivekananda Voltaire 20th–21st-century philosophers Adorno Ambedkar Arendt Aurobindo Aron Azurmendi Badiou Baudrillard Bauman Benoist Berlin Bernstein Butler Camus Chomsky De Beauvoir Debord Du Bois Durkheim Dworkin Foucault Gandhi Gauthier Gehlen Gentile Gramsci Habermas Hayek Heidegger Irigaray Kautsky Kirk Kropotkin Laclau Lenin Luxemburg Mao Mansfield Marcuse Maritain Michels Mises Mou Mouffe Negri Niebuhr Nozick Nursî Oakeshott Ortega Pareto Pettit Plamenatz Polanyi Popper Qutb Radhakrishnan Rand Rawls Rothbard Russell Santayana Sartre Scanlon Schmitt Searle Shariati Simmel Simonović Skinner Sombart Sorel Spann Spirito Strauss Sun Taylor Walzer Weber Žižek Social theories Anarchism Authoritarianism Collectivism Communism Communitarianism Conflict theories Confucianism Consensus theory Conservatism Contractualism Cosmopolitanism Culturalism Fascism Feminist political theory Gandhism Individualism Islam Islamism Legalism Liberalism Libertarianism Mohism National liberalism Republicanism Social constructionism Social constructivism Social Darwinism Social determinism Socialism Utilitarianism Concepts Civil disobedience Democracy Four occupations Justice Law Mandate of Heaven Peace Property Revolution Rights Social contract Society War more... Related articles Jurisprudence Philosophy and economics Philosophy of education Philosophy of history Philosophy of love Philosophy of sex Philosophy of social science Political ethics Social epistemology Category Authority control BNE: XX874732 BNF: cb13769929d (data) CANTIC: a10360311 GND: 118951769 ISNI: 0000 0001 2146 4806 LCCN: n79059349 NDL: 00806494 NKC: jn20011018422 NLI: 000420039 NLK: KAC200609923 NTA: 070176140 PLWABN: 9810628418305606 SNAC: w6dv2k0z SUDOC: 077039297 VIAF: 107013507 WorldCat Identities: lccn-n79059349 Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Murray_Rothbard&oldid=998157585" Categories: 1926 births 1995 deaths 20th-century American economists 20th-century American essayists 20th-century American historians 20th-century American journalists 20th-century American male writers 20th-century American non-fiction writers 20th-century American philosophers American agnostics American anarcho-capitalists American anti-communists American anti–Vietnam War activists American atheists American book editors American economics writers American foreign policy writers American libertarians American male essayists American male journalists American male non-fiction writers American people of Polish-Jewish descent American people of Russian-Jewish descent American political journalists American political philosophers American political writers Austrian School economists Birch Wathen Lenox School alumni Burials in Virginia Cato Institute people Columbia College (New York) alumni Critics of neoconservatism Critics of Objectivism (Ayn Rand) Economists from New York (state) Historians of economic thought Historians of the United States Historical revisionism Jewish agnostics Jewish American historians Jewish American social scientists Jewish American writers Jewish anti-communists Jewish atheists Jewish philosophers Journalists from New York (state) Libertarian historians Libertarian theorists Mises Institute people New York (state) Libertarians New York (state) Republicans Non-interventionism Old Right (United States) Opinion journalists Paleolibertarianism Philosophers from Nevada Philosophers from New York (state) Polytechnic Institute of New York University faculty Right-wing populism in the United States University of Nevada, Las Vegas faculty Writers from New York City Hidden categories: Webarchive template wayback links All articles with dead external links Articles with dead external links from April 2020 Articles with permanently dead external links Pages containing links to subscription-only content Articles with short description Short description is different from Wikidata Use mdy dates from December 2018 Articles with hCards Pages using Sister project links with wikidata namespace mismatch Pages using Sister project links with hidden wikidata Wikipedia articles with BNE identifiers Wikipedia articles with BNF identifiers Wikipedia articles with CANTIC identifiers Wikipedia articles with GND identifiers Wikipedia articles with ISNI identifiers Wikipedia articles with LCCN identifiers Wikipedia articles with NDL identifiers Wikipedia articles with NKC identifiers Wikipedia articles with NLI identifiers Wikipedia articles with NLK identifiers Wikipedia articles with NTA identifiers Wikipedia articles with PLWABN identifiers Wikipedia articles with SNAC-ID identifiers Wikipedia articles with SUDOC identifiers Wikipedia articles with VIAF identifiers Wikipedia articles with WORLDCATID identifiers Good articles Navigation menu Personal tools Not logged in Talk Contributions Create account Log in Namespaces Article Talk Variants Views Read Edit View history More Search Navigation Main page Contents Current events Random article About Wikipedia Contact us Donate Contribute Help Learn to edit Community portal Recent changes Upload file Tools What links here Related changes Upload file Special pages Permanent link Page information Cite this page Wikidata item Print/export Download as PDF Printable version In other projects Wikimedia Commons Wikiquote Wikisource Languages Afrikaans العربية Azərbaycanca تۆرکجه Български Català Čeština Dansk Deutsch Ελληνικά Español Esperanto فارسی Français 한국어 Հայերեն Bahasa Indonesia Italiano עברית Lumbaart مصرى Nederlands 日本語 Norsk bokmål Polski Português Română Русский Shqip Simple English Slovenčina Suomi Svenska தமிழ் Türkçe Українська Vèneto 中文 Edit links This page was last edited on 4 January 2021, at 02:39 (UTC). Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization. Privacy policy About Wikipedia Disclaimers Contact Wikipedia Mobile view Developers Statistics Cookie statement