key: cord-021105-6z619phm authors: Sandler, Todd title: Regional public goods and international organizations date: 2006-03-09 journal: nan DOI: 10.1007/s11558-006-6604-2 sha: doc_id: 21105 cord_uid: 6z619phm This article focuses on the provision prognosis for regional public goods (RPGs) and the role of international organizations in fostering supply in developing countries. All three properties of publicness—i.e., nonrivalry of benefits, nonexcludability of nonpayers, and the aggregation technology—play a role in this prognosis. The paper highlights many provision impediments, not faced by national or global public goods. When intervention is necessary, the analysis distinguishes the role of global, regional, and other institutional arrangements (e.g., networks and public-private partnerships). The pros and cons of subsidiarity are addressed. able benefits to people in two or more countries. 1 Some TPGs provide benefit or cost spillovers globally-e.g., efforts to reduce ozone-shield-depleting chlorine and bromide substances improve the well-being of people worldwide. When spillovers are global, the associated good is a global public good (GPG). If, instead, the public good's benefits are confined to two or more countries in a given location, then the good is a regional public good (RPG), whose spillovers may be more confined than TPGs. In recent years, there is a growing interest in the study of GPGs and TPGs beginning with Global Challenges (Sandler, 1997) and followed by other contributions (see, e.g., Ferroni and Mody, 2002; Kanbur, Sandler and Morrison, 1999; Kaul, Grunberg and Stern, 1999; Kaul, Conceiçã o, Le Goulven, and Mendoza, 2003; Sandler, 1998 Sandler, , 2004 . Some studies focus on RPGs and their associated collective action problems (Arce and Sandler, 2002; Cook and Sachs, 1999; Estevadeordal, Frantz and Nguyen, 2004; Sandler, 1998 Sandler, , 2002 Stå lgren, 2000) , while others analyze GPGs and their provision efforts to date. A primary concern is to distinguish TPGs for which nations have the proper incentives to contribute from those where incentives are perverse. Another concern is to identify the role of diverse agents and international organizations-i.e., global (e.g., World Bank, United Nations) institutions, regional institutions, networks, public-private partnerships, and charitable foundations-in bolstering TPG provision in developing countries. In recent years, increased foreign assistance has been channeled in a bilateral and multilateral fashion to finance TPGs in developing countries. Based on data from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), te Velde, Morrissey and Hewitt (2002: 128) show that aid-funded public good support more than doubled from 16.22% of assistance in 1980-82 to 38.19% in 1996-98. 2 Much of this increase was in terms of NPGs: in 1996-98, 29 .40% of official assistance funded NPGs compared with 8.79% for TPGs (te Velde et al., 2002: 126-127) . The current study has two essential purposes: to survey the current knowledge of RPGs and to push this knowledge frontier outward. In accomplishing the first goal, the modern study of public goods and collective action (Olson, 1965; Sandler, 1992 Sandler, , 2004 is applied to assess the effectiveness of the support for RPGs in developing countries. All three properties of publicness-nonrivalry of benefits, nonexcludability of nonpayers, and the aggregation technology (i.e., how individual contributions add to the overall level for consumption)-indicate where to direct efforts in providing RPGs. Blanket statements about RPGs must be resisted since these goods display a wide range of publicness properties and prognoses. Once the prognosis is understood, the role of national and international institutions in promoting the supply of RPGs and GPGs in developing countries will be known. 1 Benefits are nonrival when a unit of the good can be consumed by one agent without detracting, in the least, from the consumption possibilities still available for other agents from the same unit. Benefits are nonexcludable when they are available to all would-be consumers once the good is supplied. 2 Estimates by Raffer (1999) indicate that support for public goods varied from 20% to 40% of official development assistance in the 1990s, depending on the classification of public goods used. The growth of aid-supported public goods is further documented in a recent study by Mascarenhas and Sandler (2005) . Also see the World Bank (2001) study, which distinguishes between complementary and core activities. Complementary activities lay the infrastructure for developing countries to consume TPGs-the so-called core activity. The former require NPGs that prepare the country to benefit from TPGs. For the second goal, we highlight the importance of the aggregation technology. The unique position of RPGs vis-á -vis NPGs and GPGs is clarified for the first time. Moreover, the article identifies the role of global and regional institutions in fostering the provision of RPGs in developing countries. The article also highlights the pros and cons of applying the principle of subsidiarity to the choice of jurisdiction and international organizations. Finally, the article explores new institutional arrangements and participants-i.e., networks, public-private partnerships, regional trade pacts, and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs)-to augment RPG provision where needed. This section explores the properties and classes of RPGs in regards to developing countries in order to identify the need for international organizations to bolster the provision of RPGs. In many instances, intervention may not be needed, but, when required, the form of intervention and the requisite institutional arrangement hinge on the publicness properties of the RPGs. Hence, this taking stock of RPGs is essential. An RPG provides benefits to two or more nations in a well-defined region. A region is a territorial subsystem of the global system, whose basis may be geological (based on earth formations such as a plain or coastline), geographical, political, cultural, or geoclimatic. Regional characteristics can influence the extent of spillovers from a public good-e.g., language can facilitate or limit spillovers, while natural barriers, such as mountain ranges, may also affect the range of spillovers. Because agricultural research findings are specific to soil and climatic conditions, geoclimatic factors can be the prime determinant of the range of the resulting spillovers. Thus, knowledge public goods can be regional in nature. Diseases and pests may be indigenous to some regions so that defensive measures may yield RPGs. The two classic properties of a pure public good give rise to market failures that may require either government provision or some form of cooperation among the benefit recipients. Nonexclusion results in a market failure because a provider cannot keep noncontributors from consuming the good's benefit. Once the public good is provided, consumers have no incentive to contribute because their money can purchase other goods whose benefits are not freely available. Thus, the public good will be either undersupplied or not supplied. Benefit nonrivalry means that extending consumption to additional users results in a zero marginal cost. Exclusionbased fees are inefficient because some potential users, who derive a positive gain, are denied access even though it costs society nothing to include them. Purely public RPGs include cleansing a local ecosystem, curbing the spread of an infectious disease, curing a region-specific disease, and instituting regional flood control. For purely public RPGs, intervention by a global institution, regional organization, or other collective is required for provision. Impurely public RPGs may, at times, have a more favorable prognosis. Impurity can stem from partial rivalry or partial excludability. Suppose that impurity is due to partial rivalry alone. An example is a common property resource, such as a regional fishing ground, where access is open to all nations in the region. Rivalry applies because increased fishing effort by one nation limits the catch of other nations through crowding. To haul in the same catch, each nation's fleet must exert more effort as that of other nations increases. This problem can be addressed if a regional body restricts fishing efforts to account for the crowding externality. Nations are not anticipated to reduce overexploitation on their own unless there is a nation with a sufficiently large stake in the fishery and/or the ability to impose restrictions on others. Next, suppose that an RPG is impure owing to partial rivalry and partial excludability. Partial rivalry means that extending consumption has a nonzero marginal cost owing to crowding (e.g., treating diseased patients, monitoring a disease outbreak, or cleaning up an oil spill), so that a crowding toll can be levied without necessarily implying inefficiency. The partial exclusion indicates that some of the users can be denied entry unless they pay the toll. The lack of complete excludability means that there will still be some free riders who will use the good, crowd others, and escape payment. Thus, the good will be undersupplied and overutilized, which worsens as the degree of exclusion decreases. Club goods are impure public goods whose benefits are fully excludable and partially rival. Club RPGs include regional parks, power networks (e.g., Central American Electricity Interconnection System (SIEPAC)), 3 transportation infrastructure, crisis-management teams, satellite-launch facility, and biohazard facility. Members can efficiently provide these club RPGs, financed through tolls. If exclusion is complete, then there will be no free riders and only members benefit. The toll charges each user the same fee, which equals the crowding costs associated with a standardized unit of use or visit. Taste differences among members can be taken into account: members with a stronger preference for the club good will use it more frequently and will thus pay more in aggregate tolls. Under a wide range of scenarios, the tolls collected will finance the efficient level of provision (Cornes and Sandler, 1996) . Suppose that nations in a region jointly utilize a satellite-launch facility (e.g., Alcâ ntara in Brazil for Latin America). Each launch is charged the same fee, but countries that launch more satellites will pay more in total charges. Such a club arrangement means that resources will gravitate to their most-valued use without the need for outside intervention. Regional clubs can seek loans from global institutions, donor nations, or regional development banks to initially finance the club good. Toll proceeds can subsequently repay the loan. Members can be quite heterogeneous and include nations, private firms, and other organizations. INTELSAT is a global club that is a private consortium with diverse members that share a satellite-based communication network that carries most intercontinental phone calls and television transmissions. Clubs represent a low-cost institutional arrangement for collective provision that can be member owned and operated or government provided. Joint products arise when an activity yields two or more outputs that may vary in their degree of publicness. Jointly produced outputs may be purely public, private, a club good, or something else. Actions to preserve a rain forest not only yield local public goods (e.g., a watershed, ecotourism, and localized climate influences) but also GPGs (e.g., biodiversity and sequestration of carbon). Eliminating a local insurgency not only provides RPGs in the form of fewer refugees and a reduced spread of diseases, but also a TPG from a smaller likelihood of a contagious conflict. Regional peacekeeping may offer similar joint products. Foreign aid is also associated with joint products. Conditionality may provide donor-specific private benefits, while poverty reduction in the recipient country can create an altruistic GPG as the global community benefits from welfare improvements in poor countries. For joint products, the prognosis for effective collective action depends on the ratio of excludable benefits-e.g., contributor