key: cord-0222027-16ueper7 authors: Fiaschi, Davide; Tealdi, Cristina title: A general methodology to measure labour market dynamics date: 2021-04-02 journal: nan DOI: nan sha: 6b55b4822101e1d45b665079a60795c9930a8368 doc_id: 222027 cord_uid: 16ueper7 We propose a general methodology to measure labour market dynamics, inspired by the search and matching framework, based on the estimate of the transition rates between labour market states. We show how to estimate instantaneous transition rates starting from discrete time observations provided in longitudinal datasets, allowing for any number of states. We illustrate the potential of such methodology using Italian labour market data. First, we decompose the unemployment rate fluctuations into inflow and outflow driven components; then, we evaluate the impact of the implementation of a labour market reform, which substantially changed the regulations of temporary contracts. The unemployment rate represents a static and partially informative variable, and yet is the single most important measure considered when evaluating labour market performance and designing optimal welfare policy (Layard et al., 2005; Barnichon et al., 2012) . While considerable progress has been made in the theory of modelling labour market dynamics towards understanding the deep functioning of labour markets (Pissarides, 2000; Mortensen and Pissarides, 1994) , the methodological empirical counterpart, although emerging (Shimer, 2012; Elsby et al., 2009) , is still lacking a systematic approach. To this end, we propose a methodology to estimate instantaneous time transition rates across labour market states, on which the search and matching framework is built (Phelps, 1968) , starting from discrete time observations and allowing for any number of states. This methodology, which is a generalization of the method proposed by Shimer (2012) , and it is also based on the work of Israel et al. (2001) , allows for an easy implementation of inference on transition rates via bootstrap methods, the decomposition of the contribution of inflows and outflows to the change in labour market shares, and the evaluation of labour market policies via forecast. For a number of different (historical) reasons most of the economic literature considers unemployment indicators as the main proxies of labour market performance (Perugini and Signorelli, 2007) . While classical economists, such as Adam Smith, focused on employment, subsequent theoretical evolution led to a clear-cut tendency towards the use of unemployment rates. However, while the unemployment rate is a useful indicator of particularly low labour market performance, its exclusive use is questionable. In fact the view of the labour market it offers is partial, incomplete and at odd with dynamic approaches typical of macroeconomic frameworks, such as search and matching models, which focus on flows of individuals across different labour market states. Moreover, in countries/regions with significant labour market segmentation and important local labour markets, the role of aggregate unemployment rates in affecting wage bargaining and dynamics towards labour market equilibria is significantly reduced. This raises the issue of considering additional variables, e.g., inflows and outflows, as complementary indicators of labour market performance (Valli, 1970; Garibaldi and Mauro, 2002) . Two countries might in fact have similar unemployment rates, while hiding very different labour markets, specifically in terms of workers turnover and flows (Blanchard and Portugal, 2001) . There is, therefore, a need to first, identify relevant workers' states in high frequency panel datasets, in which the longitudinal feature is essential to follow the individuals' career paths. Second, it is crucial to adopt an appropriate and empirically implementable methodological approach to analyse such dynamics and interpret them to properly evaluate the performance of the labour markets. This paper proposes a general approach to estimate instantaneous transition rates starting from discrete time transitions between different labour market states based on the work of Israel et al. (2001) . Our approach has two main advantages: it is flexible to include any number of labour market states; and inference via bootstrap and forecasting are easily implementable. Our methodology advances the knowledge on how to measure the cyclicality of transition rates and on the decomposition of the unemployment fluctuations over the business cycle into inflow and outflow driven components (Shimer, 2012; Silva and Vázquez-Grenno, 2013) . In addition, we discuss how the estimates of the transition rates and their forecast could be used to assess the changes of the labour market dynamics for guiding policy evaluation. We apply this methodology to the Italian labour market by using longitudinal quarterly labour force data for the period 2013-2020. First, we illustrate how the decomposition of the unemployment rate fluctuations points to a major role played by the transitions from and to inactivity. We then report transition rates between five labour market states and the corresponding shares before and after the implementation of a labour market reform, which significantly modified the regulations of temporary contracts. Overall, we find strong support for the utilisation of labour market flows as well as labour market stocks for the assessment of labour market dynamics. This paper directly relates to the search and matching literature, which is the theoretical framework at the basis of the flow approach to the labour market (Mortensen et al., 1970; Phelps, 1968) . From a methodological point of view, approaches to measure flows in and out of unemployment, using publicly available data have been proposed by Elsby et al. (2009); Darby et al. (1986) ; Fujita and Ramey (2009) . These studies differ along two main dimensions: (i) how many labour market states are included and (ii) the "time aggregation", as flows in and out of each state are taking place in continuous time while data are collected in discrete times. Shimer (2012) uses US monthly statistics on employment, unemployment and short-term unemployment to compute the probabilities that an employed worker becomes unemployed and that an unemployed worker finds a job, i.e, the job finding and the job exit rates. His approach is based on two key assumptions: (i) individuals only move between employment and unemployment and (ii) individuals are homogeneous. 1 This methodology however is implementable when the number of labour market states is small. As Shimer (2012, p.133) claims, when expanding the number of labour market states, 'the theory here is more cumbersome, the data limitations are more serious, and the data analysis is more involved'. Using the same methodology, Elsby et al. (2015) discusses the importance of including inactivity, while Silva and Vázquez-Grenno (2013) ; Fontaine et al. (2020) and Borowczyk-Martins and Lalé (2020) expand the number of labour market states by including temporary employment, public employment and part-time employment, respectively. Elsby et al. (2009) account for the time aggregation bias using a discrete-time variant of the Shimer (2012) pro-cedure, based on the fact that the US Current Population Survey (CPS) uses the week as its reference period. Finally, some papers have followed applying such methodologies in different countries (Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2008; Smith, 2011; Hertweck and Sigrist, 2015; Baussola and Mussida, 2014; Gomes, 2012) , while Gomes (2015) discusses the importance of the data frequency. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains in detail the proposed methodology, which is based on a view of the labour market in terms of flows, as in the search and matching framework. Section 3 applies the methodology using Italian data to illustrate its main advantages and Section 4 concludes the paper. The appendices collect the technical material. As discussed in the introduction, we propose a dynamic approach to the labour market, based on observed transitions of working age individuals between different labour market states (e.g. unemployed, employed, inactive, etc.), compared to the traditional static approach, based on stock variables, such as unemployment rates and labour market participation. Specifically, we take a microeconomic perspective by tracking movements of individuals across labour market states and discuss under which conditions these transition rates can summarize the whole dynamics of the labour market. The theoretical (economic) basis of the proposed methodology is the search and matching model, which supplies a meaningful economic interpretation to estimated (instantaneous) transition rates. We discuss how this methodology is sufficiently flexible to deal with 'realistic and empirically implementable' scenarios in the labour market (Pissarides, 2000, p. 3). We first illustrate a simplified version of labour market dynamics with three labour market states (employed, unemployed and inactive) and map the corresponding transition rates into a standard continuous time search and matching framework (Section 2.1). Next, we discuss the general framework and characterize the short-run dynamics, the equilibrium distribution, how to deal with the presence of seasonality, and the decomposition of the the contribution of individual transition rates to labour market dynamics (Section 2.2). Finally, we describe the methodology to estimate the instantaneous transition rates starting from discrete time observations (Section 2.3). The seminal papers that proposed the search and matching framework (Mortensen et al., 1970; Phelps, 1968 ) introduced a flow approach to the labour market. The core idea on which the search and matching model is built is that trade in the labour market is a decentralized economic activity, in which the process for both individuals and firms to find each other, agree on the wage and start producing is costly and time consuming (Pissarides, 2000) . While similar to other macroeconomic models, the search and matching framework features optimizing agents, rational expectations, and equilibrium outcomes, the real emphasis in the model is placed on the flows between labour market states. Consider a simple model in which a mass of employees L can belong to one of the three labour market states available in the economy: employed (e), unemployed (u) or inactive (n); hence: (1) Assume that individuals can freely move across the labour market states at some instantaneous transition rates. Specifically, unemployed individuals become employed at rate α, while employed worker become unemployed at rate λ. Inactive individuals join the unemployment pool at rate ϕ u and find a job at rate ϕ e . Finally, employed and unemployed individuals become inactive at rate µ and γ, respectively. On the basis of these rates, assuming no entry and exit from the working age population, the number of employees who are employed, unemployed and inactive evolve according to the following system of differential equations: The observed dynamics are the outcome of inflows and outflows of individuals between the three labour market states and are fully described by the set of transition rates. The economic theory has provided several explanations for these transitions (see, e.g., Pissarides, 2000; Garibaldi and Wasmer, 2005; Mortensen and Pissarides, 1994) . For example, α is directly related to job creation, i.e. the process by which a firm and a worker meet and agree to form a match, which results in the worker's flow from unemployment to employment; while λ is directly related to job destruction, which takes place in case of a separation between a firm and a worker, which results in the worker's flow from employment into unemployment. Consider the dynamics of the shares of individuals on the working age population. In particular, the system of differential equations (2), assuming L to be constant, can be written as: π u = −(α + γ)π u + λπ e + ϕ u π n ; anḋ π n = −(ϕ u + ϕ e )π u + µπ e + γπ u . ( where π e ≡ e/L, π u ≡ u/L, and π n ≡ n/L, while Equation (1) becomes: π e + π u + π n = 1. From Equations (3)-(4), by settingπ e =π u =π n = 0, we can then calculate the steady-state equilibrium values of the labour market shares of the working age population as: ; and where π EQ e , π EQ u and π EQ n are the equilibrium share of employed individuals, of unemployed individuals, and of inactive individuals respectively. The system of equations (5) highlights that different combinations of transition rates can lead to the same equilibrium shares of employed, unemployed and inactive individuals. In particular, the same equilibrium unemployment share can be the result of either high job finding and job destruction rates or of the opposite scenario, of low job finding and job destruction rates. Blanchard and Portugal (2001) report, for instance, that similar average unemployment rates for Portugal and the USA for the period 1983-1995 are the result of low (Portugal) versus high (USA) job finding and job destruction rates. 2 Moreover, a comparison between observed employment and unemployment shares of the working age population and their equilibrium values is particularly appealing as it is suggestive of the direction the labour market is moving to. In this respect, it is also possible to compute the expected speed of convergence to the long-run equilibrium Cox and Miller, 1972, p. 184. In a more general setting with K labour market states, the system of equations (3) can be expressed where π is a 1 × K vector collecting the shares of individuals in the working age population in different K states, and Q is a K × K matrix, whose elements are the instantaneous transition 2 The unemployment rate is defined as the ratio between the number of individuals who are unemployed and the number of individuals in the labour force, which according to our definition would read as π EQ u π EQ u + π EQ e = ϕ u (λ + µ) + ϕ e λ ϕ u (λ + µ) + ϕ e λ + ϕ e (ϕ u + α) + αϕ u . rates between different states, with the constraint that: where 1 is a 1 × K vector of ones; Equation (7) simply states that the shares of working age individuals in the K labour market states sum to one. The matrix of (instantaneous) transition rates Q is assumed to satisfy the following conditions: which amounts to assume that the process governing the labour market dynamics is conservative (Cox and Miller, 1972, p. 180) , i.e., there are no entries and exits from/to the working age population and, hence, the working age population is constant. Under general conditions (i.e., finite K), the matrix Q represents a continuous time honest Markov process with discrete states (Cox and Miller, 1972, p. 182) , i.e.: 3 where P(t) is the matrix collecting the transition probabilities from period 0 to period t, with Q 0 = I. When Q is constant over time, the general solution to Equation (6) is (Hirsch et al., 2012, p. 129) : where π(0) is the 1 × K vector which collects the shares at time 0. A non-trivial equilibrium is characterized byπ = 0, i.e., πQ = 0. Solving Equation (10), using Equation (7), we get that the equilibrium distribution of π, π EQ , reads as: 4 where π EQ is a 1 × K row-vector whose elements are non-negative and sum to 1. Finally, the convergence to equilibrium is exponential and the speed of convergence is measured by the eigenvalues 3 The definition of the exponential matrix is the following: where I is the K × K identity matrix. 4 The proof uses π1 T 1 = 1. of the Q matrix (Hirsch et al., 2012, p. 110 ). Pissarides (1986) and Shimer (2012) propose a methodology for decomposing the contribution of inflows and outflows to the changes in the labour market shares over time. This approach is based on the construction of counterfactual shares computed by setting all but one transition rates to their average/trends/long-run/reference values and allowing only the element (s, r) of the matrix Q, denoted as q sr , to vary over time. The counterfactual matrix of transition rates Q CF is therefore constructed as: whereq ij (t) can be set to its initial value (Pissarides, 1986) or to its average value over the observed period (Shimer, 2012) , or to the trend component of the q ij (t) series (Silva and Vázquez-Grenno, 2013 ). The counterfactual matrix Q CF is then used to compute the counterfactual matrix of shares π CF per each period to be compared with the observed matrix of shares π. To effectively compute π CF , Shimer (2012) takes as reference the equilibrium shares, i.e.: as equilibrium and observed shares are highly correlated in his sample (ρ = 0.98). This high correlation however is not always guaranteed. An alternative way, which does not rely on this hypothesis but on the milder conjecture that one-period ahead forecasts are very close to the observed shares, computes the counterfactual matrix of shares period by period as follows: Counterfactual and observed shares are then compared in different ways depending on the objective of the analysis. Since Pissarides (1986)'s goal is to explain the continuous increase in unemployment in Britain between the late 60s and early 80s, he makes a direct comparison between π and π CF . Shimer (2012), instead, being interested in the determinants of the unemployment volatility, extracts the cyclical component of both shares, denoted byπ andπ CF , and computes the contribution of the (s, r) element of the Q matrix to the fluctuation of the k element of π as: where Cov π k ,π CF k is the covariance between the k element ofπ andπ CF and Var (π k ) is the variance ofπ. So far we have assumed the matrix Q to be constant, however it might not always be the case. We could in fact observe seasonality in transition rates (Shimer, 2012) , for instance directly related to seasonal fluctuations of employment in specific sectors, such as tourism and agriculture. In this scenario, from Equation (10) we can define an "annual" Q a based on a set of τ "seasonal" Qs, i.e.: where Q a is the sum of the seasonal Qs and τ is chosen according to the seasonality, e.g., monthly (τ = 12) or quarterly (τ = 4). Since observations on the labour market states of individuals are available at discrete time, a direct estimation of Q is not feasible. To circumvent this issue, we first estimate P in discrete time and then estimate Q using Equation (9). Anderson and Goodman (1957, p. 92) show that each element p ij of the matrix P can be estimated by maximum likelihood as follows: where m ij (t) is the number of individuals in period t in state i moving in period t + 1 in state j and m i (t) is the total number of individuals in period t in state i. From the estimate of P, we then get an estimate of Q using Equation (9), under the conditions discussed by Israel et al. (2001) . In particular, they argue that under mild conditions, the matrixQ, which is defined by the following geometric infinite series: is such that exp Q = P and its rows sum to zero (Theorem 2 in Israel et al., 2001) . A potential drawback of using Equation (18) is that it does not ensure thatQ is a "valid" Q, i.e.,Q satisfies all Conditions (8). Specifically, there is no guarantee that all off-diagonal entries of matrixQ are non-negative. 5 Finally, Zahl (1955, p. 97) shows that the properties of the maximum likelihood estimate of P are inherited by Q. In Section 3 we will use bootstrap as an alternative robust approach to inference (see Appendix A). In this section we discuss two applications of our methodology using data from Italy. The first application aims at identifying the determinants of the labour market shares' volatility, specifically of unemployment rate (Section 3.4), while the second focuses on the implications of labour market policies. Before moving into the applications, we first provide a short overview of the features of the Italian labour market (Section 3.1), then we describe the data used in the analysis (Section 3.2) and finally we provide evidence of the goodness of our estimates (Section 3.3). Following important labour market reforms in the 1990s and early 2000s, labor market outcomes have improved substantially in Italy: employment and labor force participation rates have increased, and the unemployment rate dropped. But despite these improvements, the Italian labour market is still under-performing compared to those in most other European countries (OECD, 2019). Specifically, the participation rate is still substantially below that in most other European countries, the unemployment rate is higher, and the shares of temporary employment and selfemployment are significantly higher compared to the EU average (Table 1 ). The fast growing share of temporary employment led to the implementation of several reforms over the years with the goal to facilitate the transitions of individuals from temporary to permanent employment, while reducing the unemployment (and inactivity) rate and the growing share of self-employment 6 (Boeri and Garibaldi, 2019; Di Porto and Tealdi, 2019) . 7 This evidence provides support for considering five labour market states when applying our methodology: inactive, unemployed, tempo-5 In Section 3, Israel et al. (2001) propose two methods to circumvent this issue. The first is to set q ij = max (q ij , 0) for i = j and q ii = (q ii + j =i min (q ij , 0), i.e. to set to zero all negative off-diagonal elements and change the diagonal elements to make sure the sum of each row is equal to zero. The second method sets the negative off-diagonal values to zero and spans the difference on all positive entries to assure that the sum of each row is equal to zero. 6 The category of para-subordinate workers in Italy, i.e. individuals who are legally self-employed but who are often "economically dependent" on a single employer, is relatively large. These workers are disadvantaged relative to employees in terms of the welfare provisions that they are entitled to receive (Raitano, 2018) . rary employed, permanent employed and self-employed. 8 We use Italian quarterly longitudinal labour force data as provided by the Italian Institute of Statistics (ISTAT) for the period 2013 (quarter I) to 2020 (quarter III). 9 The Italian Labour Force Survey (LFS) follows a simple rotating sample design where households participate for two consecutive quarters, exit for the following two quarters, and come back in the sample for other two consecutive quarters. As a result, 50% of the households, interviewed in a quarter, are reinterviewed after three months, 50% after twelve months, 25% after nine and fifteen months. This rotation scheme allows to obtain 3 months longitudinal data, which include almost 50% of the original sample. The longitudinal feature of these data is essential for achieving a complete picture of significant economic phenomena of labour market mobility. Per each individual who has been interviewed we observe a large number of individual and labour market characteristics at the time of the interview and three months before. Taking into account the structure of this database, we compute the labour market flows by calculating the quarter-on-quarter transitions made by individuals between different labour market states. Specifically, we estimate the gross flows using a five-state model (permanent employed, temporary employed, self-employed, unemployed, and inactive). The drawback of these data is the point-in-time measurement of the worker's labour market state, which fails to capture transitions within the period (quarter). For instance, if an employed worker becomes unemployed and finds a new job within a quarter, we do not observe those transitions in our data. However, from Section 2.3 we know that, assuming constant (instantaneous) transition rates within the quarter, the latter (Q) can be estimated using the transitions at quarterly frequency (P). On average approximately 70.000 individuals are interviewed each quarter, of which 45.000 are part of the working age population. The average quarterly inflow of younger individuals in the working age population is 0.3%, while the average quarterly outflow of older individuals from the working age population is 0.4%, backing our hypothesis of a (almost) constant working age population within quarters. In order to assess how well our methodology works, we compare the observed labour market shares with the fitted ones, i.e., the ones computed using Equation (10) in each quarter. 10 Specifically, starting from the observed shares at quarter t − 1 we use the estimated Q to compute the fitted shares at quarter t. Figure 1 reports the observed and fitted shares for all the five labour market shares. A visual inspection suggests that both shares follow fairly similar paths throughout the period; the high correlation between the observed and the fitted shares for all labour market shares confirms this impression. 11 This evidence therefore supports the validity of our methodology in estimating the instantaneous transition rates, i.e., matrix Q. The aim of this section is to illustrate an application of the methodology discussed in Section 3.4. Given that, as shown in Section 3.3, the fitted shares are a very good approximation of the observed shares, we use this strong relationship to distinguish between the contribution of the fluctuations in the inflows and outflows from each labour market state to the fluctuations in the fitted shares. We compute the hypothetical (counterfactual) shares using the methodology explained in Section 2.2.1 (Equation (12)). Specifically, we allow movements over time in just one transition rate and assume that the remaining rates are fixed at their trend values calculated via a Hodrick-Prescott filter as in Silva and Vázquez-Grenno (2013) . We report in Figure 2 the resulting time series for the unemployment rate 12 , with the observed unemployment rate for comparison. In Table 2 Note: The entries are computed as the covariance of the fitted unemployment share and the counterfactual unemployment share for different time periods. All series are detrended using an HP filter with smoothing parameter equal to 1600. We now apply the methodology discussed above to analyse labour market changes due to the implementation of a new policy. In particular, we estimate transitions rates and labour market shares in the period 2013-2020 and discuss their patterns in light of an important labour market reform approved in 2018 (Decreto Dignità), 13 which significantly changed the regulations of temporary contracts. Although we do not claim any causal relationship between the reform and the changes in the transition rates and the labour market shares, we believe this to be an interesting setting on which to test our methodology and prove the importance of considering both stock and flow variables when evaluating the performance of the labour market. Note: the black line reports the observed share of unemployed in the working age population, while the blue line reports the counterfactual share, computed using the methodology described in Section 2.2.1 (Equation (12)). The Decreto Dignità, which was approved in July 2018, significantly increased the rigidity of the temporary contract legislation with the goal of reducing job instability, defined by the time spent by individuals in temporary employment. Specifically, the reform reduced the maximum length of temporary contracts from 36 to 24 months. It also introduced the restriction that any temporary contract longer than 12 months could be utilized only in three circumstances: (i) to replace a worker, (ii) for temporary reasons, outside the regular business and (iii) in case of a temporary and unforeseeable increase in business. If the contract was not justified by any of these reasons, the contract would be transformed into a permanent one. The number of extensions within the 24 months were reduced from 5 to 4 and any renewal of the contract would need to be justified by any of the three reasons listed above. The reform also increased the contributions payable by employers on each renewal of a temporary contract. 14 Clearly, the reform made the utilization of the temporary contract more difficult, more costly, it restricted the circumstances in which it could be utilized and it reduced the possibility of renewals/extensions. As a result, some economists debated on the possible consequences of such reform, fearing that the increase in labour costs would lead to a decrease in labour demand and therefore an increase in unemployment, as predicted by the economic theory. 15 We take quarter III of 2018, which includes the date of the approval of the Decreto Dignità (July 12, 2018), as the time when the dynamics of the Italian labour market is expected to change. We will test whether the reform has affected the transitions rates between labour market states and the equilibrium shares in two ways. First, we consider two quarters, one immediately before the reform, i.e. quarter II of 2018, and one at the end of the observation period, just before the onset of the Covid-19 pandemic, i.e., quarter IV of 2019. For both quarters considered, we compute estimates based on the average of four quarters (the actual quarter and the three quarters before) and make inference using a "pairwise" comparison between the elements of the Q matrix and the equilibrium shares, using bootstrapping methods. Then, in Section 3.5.2, we compare the estimated transition rates with counterfactual transition rates, i.e., transition rates that we would have observed if the reform would have not been implemented. We look at the five annual labour market shares, i.e., permanent and temporary employed, self-employed, unemployed and inactive in quarter II of 2018, immediately 14 Prior to the reform coming into force, this contribution was set at 1.4% of taxable salary for social security purposes and applied to all temporary contracts. With the reform it increased by 0.5%. Moreover, the reform increased the firing costs associated with permanent contracts in case of unfair dismissals. 15 https://www.lastampa.it/politica/2018/07/19/news/decreto-dignita-l-audizione-di-tito-boeri-la-stima-di-8mila-posti-persi-e-ottimistica-1.34032792. before the implementation of the reform and in quarter IV of 2019, at the end of our observation period. 16 We find no change in the share of self-employed, permanent employed and inactive (Table 3) . We instead find an increase in the share of temporary employed (from 7.1% to 7.8%) and a decrease in the share of unemployed (from 7.4% to 6.8%). Looking at the shares of individuals in the five different states before and after the reform, we identify some important changes, but we are not able to understand why these changes are happening, i.e., how the individuals move across states. Is the share of unemployment lower after the reform because more unemployed individuals move to employment or because they move to inactivity? This information is rather important to evaluate the impact of the reform on individuals and firms' choices. Transition rates We then compute the estimates of the annual matrix Q in quarter II of 2018, and in quarter IV of 2019 (see Equation (16)) and we perform a pairwise comparison of each element of the two matrices (Table 4 ). We find that the transition rates from self-employed to unemployed have declined significantly between the two quarters (from 0.05 to 0.037), 17 while the transition rates from self-employed to self-employed have increased. We also find that the transition rates from temporary employed to temporary employed have significantly decreased, while from temporary employed to permanent employed have significantly increased (from 0.257 to 0.390). We also observe significant increases in the transition rates from permanent employed to inactive (from 0.046 to 0.051), but a decline in the transition rates from permanent employed to unemployed (from 0.034 to 0.027). Transition rate from unemployed to inactive have increased (from 2.371 to 2.561), while transition rates from unemployed to unemployed have decreased. Finally, we find that the transition rates from inactive to unemployed have decreased (from 0.471 to 0.440), while transition rates from inactive to inactive have significantly increased. We then compute the equilibrium labour market shares in the two quarters considered (Table 5) . We find that the shares of temporary employed and unemployed are significantly lower after the reform (from 9.1% to 7.8% and from 7% to 6%, 16 The annual shares are computed according to Equation (16). 17 Remember that the diagonal elements of the Q matrix are negative and the elements on the same row sum up to zero. A diagonal element which becomes less negative is interpreted as a reduced outflow from that state, and therefore as an increase in the persistence in that state. respectively), as observed when we analysed the dynamics of actual labour market shares, but in addition we also observe that in equilibrium the share of permanent employed is significantly higher (from 35.7% to 38.1%). Note: The equilibrium shares are calculated on the basis of the annual Q matrices (Equation (16)). The shares are computed as the ratio of the number of individuals in each state and the working age population. Standard errors are reported in parenthesis. Differences in the coefficients in the two quarters which are statistically significant at 5% level are reported in bold (the corresponding p-values are reported in the Appendix B). SE refers to self-employment, FT to temporary employment, PE to permanent employment, U to unemployment and IN to inactivity. In this section, we use data from before the reform to forecast labour market shares and transition rates after the reform was implemented, which we interpret as counterfactual, and compare these forecasts to the observed ones (Blanchard and Leigh, 2013; Pathak and Shi, 2020) . We compute the forecasts using the methodology described in the Appendix C. 18 Labour market shares We look at the evolution of the five labour market shares in each quarter from 2013 (quarter I) to 2020 (quarter I) and we compare them with the counterfactual shares. 19 These values are reported in Figure 3 . The observed share of individuals hired on a temporary contract has been stable after the reform, compared to a growing trend before the reform. Compared to the counterfactual share, the observed one is significantly lower: the share of individuals who are temporary employed would have reached approximately 8.5% of the working age population if no reform would have been implemented against the observed average of 7.8%. Similarly, the share of unemployed individuals is significantly lower after the reform: the difference between the estimated and the counterfactual unemployment share is approximately 1 percentage point. Finally, the share of inactive individuals is significantly higher after the implementation of the reform, compared to the counterfactual estimate. While if there was no reform, the decreasing trend of the share of inactive individuals would have continued to reach 33.5% of the working age 18 This forecasting methodology has also been used by Barnichon et al. (2012) and Barnichon and Garda (2016) . In the counterfactual evaluation we ignore the constraints listed in the system of equations 8 and the fact that the elements of the matrix Q are estimated variables. 19 It is interesting to notice how the forecasts replicate the seasonal fluctuations of labour market shares which are more affected by the seasonality, such as temporary employed, unemployed and self-employed, while showing smoother patterns for shares such as inactive and permanent employed, which are less subject to seasonal fluctuations. population, with the reform the share is approximately equal to 34.5%. We do not pick up instead any relevant difference between the observed and the counterfactual estimates of the shares of permanent and self-employed individuals. Transition rates To dig deeper into the underlying dynamics, we document how the transition rates across the five labour market states considered have evolved in each quarter from 2013 (quarter I) to 2020 (quarter I). Specifically, the transition rates from self-employed, temporary employed, and permanent employed towards all other states are reported in Figure 4 , while the transition rates from unemployed and inactive towards all other states are reported in Figure 5 . The black line reports the observed transition rates, the red line reports the annual observed transition rates, while the blue line reports the forecasted transition rates, i.e., the counterfactuals without reform, together with their standard errors. We notice that the transition rates from self-employed to temporary employed and from selfemployed to unemployed have significantly decreased compare to the counterfactual scenario of no reform. We also observe that the transition rates from temporary to temporary contract have declined significantly after the reform. The counterfactual transition rates instead show that in the absence of the reform we would have observed an increase in those transitions. We also observe that the transition rates from temporary to permanent employed have significantly increased after the reform, while the counterfactual transition rates show that in the absence of the reform we would have observed a flat trajectory. We do not detect additional significant changes in transition rates from temporary employed to unemployed or inactive, although there are signs of increased transitions from temporary employed to self-employed. When we focus on transition rates from permanent employed, we observe increased transitions toward temporary employed, self-employed and inactive, although with some lags compared to the implementation of the reform. We also observe decreased transitions from permanent to permanent employed. Quite interesting are the dynamics of the transition rates from unemployed to other states. We notice decreased transition rates from unemployed to temporary employed, permanent employed and unemployed, while we observe increased rates towards inactive. Finally, we detect a decrease in the outflow from inactive towards towards unemployed, while a significant increase in the transition rates towards selfemployed (with some lags) and inactive. In summary, although we do not claim any causal relationship between the reform and the transition rates, we can state that after the reform we observe a reduced flow of individuals transiting from temporary to temporary employed (which was the aim of the reform), an increased flow of individuals upgrading from temporary to permanent employed, but also a higher flow of individuals moving from unemployed to inactive and a higher persistence in the inactive state. In this paper, we propose a general methodology to estimate transition rates between labour market states, which represent the core on which the search and matching theoretical framework is built. Specifically, our approach suggests a new method for the estimation of transition rates in continuous time when the data observed are in discrete time, without restrictions on the number of labour market states considered. Moreover, with this methodology we are able to perform inference using bootstrap and to forecast labour market dynamics. We explore two applications of our methodology useful to learn about labour market dynamics using longitudinal labour force data for Italy. Specifically, first we compute the contribution of inflows and outflows in the labour market shares' volatility and second, we evaluate how the transition rates between five labour market states and the equilibrium shares have changed after the implementation of a reform, which significantly modified the temporary contract regulation. We find that the transitions from and to inactivity are the two most important factor contributing to the volatility of the unemployment rate, suggesting a week attachment of individuals to the labour force. In terms of policy evaluation, although we find that after the reform, the shares of individuals in the five labour market states considered have changed, it is the analysis of the evolution of the transition rates which really informs about the dynamics of the labour market and its trajectory. Specifically, when looking at the transition rates we can identify movements of individuals across states, which are not picked up by the changes in the shares. For instance, by simply looking at the changes in the shares, we observe an increase in temporary employment and a decrease in unemployment, however, we cannot infer anything about the underlying dynamics, as this outcome can be the result of many different alternative combinations of transition rates (Blanchard and Portugal, 2001) . By analysing the transition rates, instead, we observe that there are many underlying movements of workers, such as an increase in the transitions from temporary to permanent employment, a decrease in the transition from temporary employment to unemployment, but also for instance an increase in the transitions from unemployment to inactivity. While the former two effects were set as goals of the reform, the latter may be an important unintended consequence. The analysis of these transition rates are therefore paramount when designing labour market policies, as they provide important information about the direction the labour market is heading to. Moreover, the equilibrium shares are informative about the expected evolution of the labour market shares, as a consequence of the changed transition rates. Although we do not intend to establish causality, as a theoretical framework would be needed, our suggested methodology should provide a different approach to the estimation of instantaneous transition rates for policy evaluation. Our strategy for the estimation of the counterfactual transition rates is inspired by Blanchard and Leigh (2013) and based on forecasting. The f -quarter ahead forecast of transition rate q ij in quarter t can be expressed as: where q ij,t+f −1:t+f is the observed transition rate (i, j) in quarter (t + f ), q ij,t+f |t is the forecasted transition rate for the quarter (t + f ) calculated in quarter t and ǫ ij:t+f is the forecasting error. If the forecasting is computed exploiting any information available in period t, then the expected value of ǫ ij:t+f is zero and ǫ ij:t+f and q ij,t+f |t are orthogonal, i.e.: Hence, any significant divergence between q ij,t+f and q ij,t+f |t signals a novelty with respect to the information set available in period t or, alternatively, q ij,t+f |t can be interpreted as a counterfactual. The novelty in the labour market in quarter t should appear as a significant gap between q ij,t+f and q ij,t+f |t . In estimating the forecast, we follow Clemen (1989) and Hyndman and Athanasopoulos (2021) , and consider the combination of three different models of forecasting, i.e. AutoRegressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA), exponential smoothing (ETS) and linear regression (TSLR), allowing in all models for the presence of a trend and seasonality and using the modified AIC for model selection (Hyndman and Athanasopoulos, 2021, Chapters 8, 9 and 13) ). Statistical inference about markov chains Forecasting unemployment across countries: The ins and outs The ins and outs of forecasting unemployment: Using labor force flows to forecast the labor market Transitions in the labour market: discouragement effect and individual characteristics What hides behind an unemployment rate: Comparing portuguese and u.s. labor markets Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers A tale of comprehensive labor market reforms: Evidence from the italian jobs act The ins and outs of involuntary part-time employment Combining forecasts: A review and annotated bibliography The theory of stochastic processes The ins and outs of unemployment: The ins win Heterogeneous paths to stability An introduction to the bootstrap On the importance of the participation margin for labor market fluctuations The ins and outs of cyclical unemployment Labour market flows: Accounting for the public sector The cyclicality of separation and job finding rates Anatomy of employment growth Equilibrium search unemployment, endogenous participation, and labor market flows Labour market flows: Facts from the United Kingdom The importance of frequency in estimating labour market transition rates The ins and outs of german unemployment: a transatlantic perspective Differential equations, dynamical systems, and an introduction to chaos Forecasting: principles and practice. OTexts: Melbourne, Australia. OTexts.com/fpp3 Finding generators for markov chains via empirical transition matrices, with applications to credit ratings Unemployment: macroeconomic performance and the labour market A theory of wage and employment dynamics. Microeconomic foundations of employment and inflation theory 219 Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. The review of economic studies Recent trends in the Italian Labour Market How well do structural demand models work? Counterfactual predictions in school choice Labour market performance differentials and dynamics in EU-15 countries and regions The ins and outs of european unemployment Money-wage dynamics and labor-market equilibrium Unemployment and vacancies in Britain Equilibrium unemployment theory Italy: Para-subordinate workers and their social protection Reassessing the ins and outs of unemployment The ins and outs of unemployment in a two-tier labor market The ins and outs of UK unemployment Programmazione e sindacati in italia A markov process model for follow-up studies Given a sample of transitions X of cardinality N, the bootstrap procedure is composed of three steps (Efron and Tibshirani, 1994 , Chapter 6):1. Draw B samples of cardinality N by sampling with replacement from X; 2. For every bootstrapped sample b estimate matrix P b and the correspondingQ b ;3. Compute the standard errors of the transition ratesq ij , σ q ij as:The test of zero difference between two transition rates and/or between two equilibrium labour market shares is based on the bootstrap procedure suggested in Efron and Tibshirani (1994, Chap- ter 16). In this section we report the p-values of the pairwise comparisons of the elements of estimated Q matrices (Table 6 ) and the p-values of the pairwise comparisons of the estimated equilibrium labour market shares in quarter II of 2018 and quarter IV of 2019 (Table 7) . These p-values are calculated by the bootstrap procedure suggested in Efron and Tibshirani (1994, Chapter 16) .