key: cord-0457242-2d9aq09m authors: Rudkin, Simon; Qiu, Wanling; Dlotko, Pawel title: Uncertainty, volatility and the persistence norms of financial time series date: 2021-09-30 journal: nan DOI: nan sha: 3520e8c59bda17cc2811d601066e62cc32622f82 doc_id: 457242 cord_uid: 2d9aq09m Norms of Persistent Homology introduced in topological data analysis are seen as indicators of system instability, analogous to the changing predictability that is captured in financial market uncertainty indexes. This paper demonstrates norms from the financial markets are significant in explaining financial uncertainty, whilst macroeconomic uncertainty is only explainable by market volatility. Meanwhile, volatility is insignificant in the determination of norms when uncertainty enters the regression. Persistence norms therefore have potential as a further tool in asset pricing, and also as a means of capturing signals from financial time series beyond volatility. Since Gidea and Katz (2018) identified the power of topological data analysis (TDA) persistence norms to warn about financial crashes, there has been strong interest in how the tools of TDA can be brought to finance and economics (Goel et al., 2020; Bakas and Triantafyllou, 2020; Gidea et al., 2020; Majumdar and Laha, 2020) . TDA is introduced in the seminal work of Carlsson (2009) , and is widely developed for, the natural sciences (Bubenik and D lotko, 2017; Bubenik, 2020) . Initial potential for financial market dynamics of the type described by Hsieh (1991) comes from the applications in the detection of phase transitions and system instability (Stolz et al., 2017; Smith et al., 2021) . Promising advancements on correlation and volatility show how each alter the topology of the time series, but that neither correlation or volatility alone can explain persistence norms (Aromi et al., 2021; Leaverton et al., 2020; Katz and Biem, 2021) . Focus in this literature has been on the strength of the volatility-norm relationship. We expand that focus to consider financial market dynamics, asking how persistence norms link to forward looking measures of uncertainty Jurado et al. (2015) constructs uncertainty indexes for financial (FIN), macroeconomic (MAC) and real activity (REA) based upon the predictability of relevant series under each heading 1 . Of these, the MAC index sees most adoption in asset pricing (Bali et al., 2017 (Bali et al., , 2021 . FIN has a natural association with the topological norms we derive from the financial markets, as our measure stems from the returns on four major US stock indices. This paper therefore focuses primarily on FIN and MAC. Regression of persistence norms on FIN yields an insignificant constant term, suggesting that FIN can span persistence norms. Further, adding volatility does not remove statistical significance from FIN. MAC is only significantly linked to volatility. Conversely, neither norms nor volatility span uncertainty 2 . This paper focuses on contemporaneous relationships between volatility, uncertainty and persistence norms in recognition of the way these series are used in the asset pricing literature (Ang et al., 2006; Bali et al., 2017 Bali et al., , 2021 . Our empirical contribution is the demonstration that norms are better explained by FIN than volatility, but that norms and volatility alone do not directly explain uncertainty. In evaluating the links between Jurado et al. (2015) and persistence norms for the first time, this paper furthers the understanding of how TDA can enhance financial modelling 3 . Consider a point cloud X = {x 1 , . . . , x n } where each point {x i } k i=1 have k coordinates. Given X, an abstract simplicial complex K, being a family of subsets of X, will be constructed. Each subset consisting of points x l0 , . . . , x l k will constitute a k−dimensional simplex. Such a simplex is equipped with a filtration value being equal to maximal distance between each pair of points among {x l0 , . . . , x l k }. This distance will be referred to as a filtration of the simplex. Clearly, when each subsets of X constitute a simplex, the size of the obtained data structure is 2 n and therefore not tractable computationally. Consequently, in what follows, only the simplices of a filtration value bounded by a predefined constant r (and often of a bounded cardinality) will be considered in a restricted simplicial complex K r . Note that when a simplex constituted in points {x l0 , . . . , x l k } belongs to K r , each simplex supported in a subset of {x l0 , . . . , x l k } will also belong to K r . An obtained simplicial complex K r is called a Rips complex of X. Let us consider the simplices of K r in order of their filtration. Concentrating on connected components, we can observe creation of new connected components, and merging of existing ones as the simplices of higher and higher filtration values are considered. The filtration value on which the components connect will be called birth, while the filtration value at which the connected components connect to another component is the death of the original connected component. However, the multi-scale approach presented here is not restricted to connected components. When considering higher dimensional topological features like holes and voids, analogously each feature can be equipped with a birth and a death filtration value. Note that some of the features will not die in K r , in which case, they are said to have an infinite length. This assignment is a basis of persistent homology. For more formal, yet intuitive introduction to the subject please consider Carlsson (2009) The life-time of a feature is calculated as the death minus the birth value. Note that in what follows, we only consider features of a finite lifetime. Life information can be combined into L 1 being the sum of the lives of the features, whilst the L 2 norm is the square root of the sum of the squared lives of the features. That is: where feature f is born at radius b f and dies at radius d f . For dimension as z, z = 0, 1, F z is the total number of features identified. Note that so called 1-persistent landscape norms used in Gidea and Katz (2018) are simply L 11 up to a constant re-scaling, hence we will focus on them in the further work. Influences on the norm are the distances between points within the cloud and the number of points in the cloud. For comparability all of the clouds in this paper contain the similar numbers of points meaning any difference may be attributed to the distance between points. Distances are impacted by the correlation between axes and the variance within the underlying distributions that generate the cloud. Volatility and the correlation between market index returns capture those distributional features in this paper. Monthly uncertainty data is obtained from the website of Sydney Ludvigsson 4 . Daily index data is downloaded through Yahoo! Finance with daily log returns for day t, R t , constructed from adjusted closing prices, p t , using R t = ln p t − ln p t−1 . Monthly returns may then be aggregated across all days in the month. Using the daily data we construct point clouds of length 1 month, 3 months, 6 months and 12 months and compute the persistence norms there upon. Following Gidea and Katz (2018) a cloud is produced using log returns on the S&P 500, Dow Jones Industrial Average, NASDAQ and Russell 2000. The geometric mean of the standard deviation of returns on the four indices provides the measure of volatility 5 . Allowing for availability of stock index returns and uncertainty measures, our sample runs from 1st January 1993 to 28th June 2021. Correlations between the Jurado et al. (2015) uncertainty indexes and volatility are high, being approximately 0.7 for F IN 1, around 0.6 for M AC1 and approximately 0.6 for REAL. Correlations between volatility and the uncertainty indexes are always higher than the corresponding correlations between uncertainty and the persistence norms. Table 1 shows correlations between L 1 norms and F IN 1 to be below 0.6 in the 3-month and 6-month clouds, rising to near 1 for the 12-month cloud 6 . L 2 norms have a correlation of just above 0.6 with F IN 1. With M AC1 we see correlations below 0.4, and with REA1 the correlations are lower at 0.3 or less. Whilst the evidence suggests uncertainty is picking up much of the volatility in the cloud, the norms are providing different information about the data. A note of caution is raised by the strong correlation between volatility and F IN 1 when using these two metrics to model persistence norms. When M AC1 is used the correlations with volatility are lower meaning fewer modelling concerns. Plotting the uncertainty, volatility and L 1 persistence norms series, Figure 1 shows that whilst using more lags, or considering longer time periods produces more consistency, these are still volatile series. Choice of 4 Downloaded 12th September 2021 from https://www.sydneyludvigson.com/data-and-appendixes. 5 The shape of the point cloud is dependent on the variance-covariance matrix of the input series but is not order dependent. Further each index is weighted equally in the construction of the persistence norms. Therefore the average volatility is seen as a parsimonious measure to apply in this paper. See Aromi et al. (2021) for a discussion of the role of the variance-covariance matrix and empirical examples using the four index cloud considered here. 6 We present a discussion of the correlation between measures of volatility and the persistence norms across the cloud lengths in the supplementary material. L 1 follows Gidea and Katz (2018) , but the plots with L 2 included in the supplementary material are very similar as the high correlation between L 1 and L 2 would suggest. Across the full sample it is difficult to conclude which series can be used to explain the others 7 . Panels (a) and (b) show the persistence norms being high during the "dot-com" bubble bursting in the early part of this century, a time where uncertainty is high but volatility is not. Meanwhile for both the Covid-19 pandemic and the global financial crisis we see volatility and uncertainty go to high standardised values whilst norms remain comparatively low. Panels (c) and (d) show closer alignment between M AC1 and volatility since M AC1 does not peak in the "dot-com" bubble like F IN 1. These observations are important for evaluating the use of uncertainty, and particularly M AC1 in the asset pricing literature (Bali et al., 2017 (Bali et al., , 2021 . Consequently the time series plots show potential for L 1 norms in financial uncertainty. Our results are presented for the dimension one L 1 norm to keep this work in line with Gidea and Katz (2018) . Results for the corresponding dimension 1 L 2 norms are provided in the supplementary material. Regression of persistence norms on the uncertainty indices of Jurado et al. (2015) and the average volatility index returns tests whether these financial market variables are able to span the persistence norms. Formally we estimate a total of 216 models which are based upon three base regressions 8 : Where L 11 is the dimension one L 1 persistence norm, σ is the standard deviation of S&P 500 returns and F IN 1 is the one month ahead financial uncertainty index of Jurado et al. (2015) . In all cases is the error term. In all estimations Newey and West (1987) adjusted standard errors are employed to account for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity inherent in financial time series. An immediate inference from Table 3 is that regressions involving the uncertainty indexes do not have significant constant terms. Further, coefficients on FIN1 are significant in all but model 3 on the 12-month cloud. Meanwhile, volatility is not significant when uncertainty is added. The significant constants in Model 2 confirm that the norm of the four index cloud is picking up additional information beyond the volatility in the cloud. When MAC1 is used as the uncertainty measure, there is some significance in model 1 for the 3-month and 6-month clouds, but model 3 has no significant coefficients. Reversing the question we regress the uncertainty indexes on the persistence norms and volatility. Model4 Notation follows models 1 to 3. Table 3 demonstrates the significance of volatility to the uncertainty index. F IN 1 has significant terms on the L 11 norms in both Model 4 and Model 6. Persistence norms are also picking up an element of 7 Developing lead-lag relationships within this data is left to future work, with greater focus needed on TDA measures from the same series as the uncertainty measures. 8 For each measure of uncertainty there are 4 point clouds to consider. Three uncertainty indices at three different lags, and with both a standard and economic version for each of the 9, this all means 72 combinations arise from Model 1. Note that there can only be one of the 18 possible uncertainty indexes and one of the four cloud lengths used in any one regression. Likewise we can only use one of the two norms, either L 1 or L 2 in a regression. Each model therefore comprises one uncertainty index, one norm and/or one volatility. In each caseσ is the average standard deviation of the four index returns in the window and is the error term. Estimation employs Newey and West (1987) robust standard errors to control for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity inherent in these time series. Sample from 1st January 1993 to 28th June 2021. n = 342 6 A feature of the uncertainty indexes of Jurado et al. (2015) is that they have very clear peaks. In the case of F IN 1, Figure 1 showed that there were three peaks within our sample. M AC1 has peaks in the global financial crisis and now in the Covid-19 period. Therefore much of the variation in these indexes can be explained by factors that are effective at explaining the peaks. To explore this further we split the sample into those months where each uncertainty index is above, or below, its respective median. The 342 months of our sample therefore move into two sets of 171. Results in Table 4 derive from the estimation of models 4 to 6 on high, and low, uncertainty subsamples. In all cases the constant is highly significant for both FIN and MAC. Persistence norms are significant in high F IN 1 periods when the 3-month and 6-month clouds, but this disappears after the addition of volatility into the model. Volatility is significant in the regressions of both F IN 1 and M AC1, the significance robust to the addition of persistence norms to the model. Hence, whilst there is evidence of norms adding power in explaining uncertainty for the full sample, the split at the median shows the power to be insufficient in either high or low uncertainty periods. Taking financial markets as complex dynamical systems (Hsieh, 1991) , persistence norms provide a means to evaluate phase transitions and forewarn of crashes (Gidea and Katz, 2018 ). An intuitive link to uncertainty in the spirit of Jurado et al. (2015) is made in this paper. Through contemporaneous regressions amongst the norms, volatility and uncertainty it has been shown that FIN, not volatility, has the strongest association with persistence norms. That persistence norms have explanatory power for FIN, but cannot span uncertainty, positions norms as a potentially useful further metric to add to the asset pricing arsenal. Although links between MAC and volatility shown in our results lend interpretation to the observed mispricing of MAC in Bali et al. (2017) , there is only limited significance for persistence norms. Further development of the norms and volatility from the same dataset as the uncertainty indexes is a natural next step. Given the demonstrated roles of uncertainty and volatility in asset pricing, and the fact that volatility cannot explain the persistence norms, there is strong potential to also explore TDA signals in asset pricing. A Measures of Uncertainty Jurado et al. (2015) provide three categories of uncertainty index, financial (FIN), macroeconomic (MAC) and real (REA), each based upon the predictability of a different set of time series. On an individual series uncertainty may be understood as the forecast error at a h-month horizon given information available at time t. Recognising that the information set I t available to investors is far wider than a single series it is necessary to use a large set of series to fully measure uncertainty. Jurado et al. (2015) 's approach seeks a common component of uncertainty to model from the observed data, rather than being based upon gathering large volumes of internet or newspaper data like the economic policy uncertainty index of Baker et al. (2016). From the perspective of the main paper, the uncertainty indexes are taken as givens but it remains helpful to recognise the debate that informs their construction. Details of the series and processes can be accessed via the paper and via the website of Sydney Ludvigson. In most asset pricing applications it is the MAC that is used, with the one-month ahead index (MAC1) being the choice for Bali et al. (2017 Bali et al. ( , 2021 . However all three sets include a one-month, three-month and twelvemonth ahead index. There are also versions of these indices computed for the subset of series which excludes any health related outcomes. This is referred to in the data descriptions as "economic". In the main paper we focus on MAC1 in line with the asset pricing literature, but also use FIN1 as the indicator derived from the financial markets directly. Here we demonstrate the tight relationships between the indexes, expanding the demonstration in Bali et al. (2017) and the exposition in Lee et al. (2021) . Figure A1 presents comparisons between the three one-month ahead uncertainty measures in panel (a), and then the three different time spans for each uncertainty measure in panels (b) to (g). Immediately it may be seen that the financial uncertainty measure remains the most volatile, as observed in Jurado et al. (2015) . We see that there are three spikes in the FIN series, 2 in the MAC and just one in the REA. In every case the one-month ahead is the most volatile, the 12-month ahead measure being far more persistent through the time periods. However, in the Covid-19 period we see that all three uncertainty measures have very similar behaviour 9 . To restrict the effect of health related variables, the "Economic" series were created. Contrasting the right hand plot on each row with the total uncertainty we see that there is very little difference in the series. Following the literature we continue therefore to use total uncertainty in the main paper. Results using the economic measure are qualitatively similar and are available on request. Formalising the message from Figure A1 , Table A1 presents a full 18x18 correlation matrix for the uncertainty indexes. We denote the economic series with an E prefix. We see a very clear blocking of both the Pearson correlations in the lower left triangle, and the Spearman's ranked correlation ceofficients above the diagonal. Of the three sets of measure the within variation for MAC is the highest. Correlation between M AC1 and F IN 1 is 0.666, whilst the rank correlation of the series is little over 0.5. This difference explains the potential for the persistence norms to provide additional information to financial uncertainty without necessarily giving extra explanatory power in regressions with M AC1 as the dependent variable. This is what we find in the main paper. The brief exposition here is consistent with the discussion in Jurado et al. (2015) and the interested reader is referred to the original paper for further discussion of the relationships between the uncertainty indexes. Whilst Covid-19 has seen different behaviour from REA, MAC1 shows only a short spike and FIN is already looking to be beyond its spike at all horizons. There is undoubtedly an interesting research agenda to understand the rationales for the observed responses. However, such an exploration of Covid-19 responses is beyond the focus of this paper. In the regressions we treat each of our four cloud lengths independently. This follows since interpretation requires that the volatility and norms be computed on the same data. However, the results are naturally compared across the 1-month, 3-month, 6-month and 12-month clouds. In this short appendix we therefore present the correlation between the three cloud based measures in Table . Each code includes a number to indicate the number of months ahead, being either 1, 3 or 12. Finally for those using the "economic" series a prefix "E" is added. Sample from 1st January 1993 to 28th June 2021. Within the three measures taken from our clouds we can see that the between lengths correlations are much higher for volatility than they are for the persistence norms. The correlation between the 1-month cloud volatility and the 12-month cloud volatility is 0.601, but the corresponding figure for the L 11 norms is 0.272 and for the L 12 norms is 0.254. Between the 1-month and 3-month clouds the correlations are 0.858 for the volatility, but just 0.322 for L 11 and 0.362 for L 12 . When we see the differences in the regression results it is understandable because of these low correlations. From the construction of persistence norms described in Section 2 of the main paper, it follows that more points produces a denser cloud and will lead to features being born, and dying, at lower filtration radii than is the case for the sparse 1-month cloud. In the main paper we follow Gidea and Katz (2018) to use the L 1 norms from the point cloud of index returns. Table 1 shows that the correlation between the L 1 and L 2 norms is high and so we may expect that the regression results are also similar. Through this appendix we demonstrate that there is consistency to the inference if using the L 2 norms. Figure A2 can be directly compared with Figure 1 of the main paper. To highlight the similarity below each plot of the L 2 norm we place the corresponding L 1 plot. Thus panels (a), (b), (e) and (f) are the L 2 plots and (c), (d), (g) and (h) replicate those from the main paper in showing L 1 norms. The main contrasts appear in the "dot-com" bubble period towards the left of the plot. Panels (e) and (g) show this well in the tall spike in the L 2 contrasting with a shorter spike in the L 1 . In Panels (b) and (d) we can see a small first spike in the early part of the global financial crisis for the L 2 norm, but this is absent in the L 1 . Both the L 1 and L 2 norms then have a taller spike at the same time that the volatility reaches its maximum. Through the rest of the panels behaviour is as similar, as the high correlation between the series would suggest. Exploring the rationale for these differences would be an interesting task for further research. Regression of persistence norms on the uncertainty indices of Jurado et al. (2015) and the average volatility index returns tests whether these financial market variables are able to span the persistence norms. Formally we estimate a total of 288 models which are based upon three base regressions: Model22 :L 12 = α 2 + β 21σ + (10) Where L 12 is the dimension one L 2 persistence norm, σ is the standard deviation of S&P 500 returns and F IN 1 is the one month ahead financial uncertainty index of Jurado et al. (2015) . In all cases is the error term. In all estimations Newey and West (1987) adjusted standard errors are employed to account for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity inherent in financial time series. This set up is identical to that in the main paper, but here we are reporting L 2 norms instead of L 1 . The addition of the 2 to the model allows distinguishing with models 1 and 2 in the main paper. We do not add any additional subscripts to the coefficients for ease of reading. As in the main paper Models 12, 22 and 32 are just the building blocks for a series of estimations that must be performed. Again, for each measure of uncertainty there are 4 point clouds to consider. Three uncertainty indices at three different lags, and with both a standard and economic version for each of the 9, this all means 72 combinations arise from Model 12. Across the three models the total number of combinations is thus 216. This exposition focuses on FIN and MAC at the 1 month ahead horizon, but as noted results for other uncertainty indexes and time horizons are available on request from the authors. Table A3 reports estimates from the regressions with Newey and West (1987) robust standard errors. Panel (a) shows that F IN 1 is significant in both models 12 and 32. Volatility is significant in model 22 and here in model 32. Herein we see the main difference between L 1 and L 2 comes in the insignificance of F IN 1 when volatility is included. Caution is urged because of the high correlation between volatility and F IN 1, but it may also be noted that L 12 has a stronger correlation toσ than L 11 in Table 1 of the main paper. Further when using only volatility as the explanatory variable for the L 12 norm, the constant term is highly significant, but this is not the case when uncertainty appears in the specification. Recalling that the same observation was found for the L 1 norm we have the consistency between the results of Table A3 and Table 2 of the main paper. Further consistency is found in the results of the 1-month cloud, with the adjusted r-squared being much lower than the longer clouds. As a month only has 22 trading days on average it follows that the cloud being used is quite small. At a smaller size the impact of an extreme value is much larger, the distance between the extremes and the next nearest point in the cloud will then influence the feature construction in the rips complex. Although the measures from the 1-month cloud are consistent with those from longer clouds on average, we are directed to use longer clouds if we wish to explain the behaviour of the persistence norms. Reversing the question we regress the uncertainty indexes on the persistence norms and volatility. Model42 Model52 :F IN 1 = α 5 + β 52σ + (13) Model62 :F IN 1 = α 6 + β 61 L 12 + β 62σ + Here again F IN 1 is the one month ahead financial uncertainty from Jurado et al. (2015) , L 11 is the dimension 1 L 1 persistence norm andσ is the mean standard deviation from the four return series in the cloud. is the error term. Models are estimated with Newey and West (1987) robust standard errors. Once more we add a 2 to the name of the model to ensure correct referencing against models 4, 5 and 6 of the main paper. It must be noted at this point that results from model 52 will be identical to model 5 in the main paper as uncertainty and volatility are not affected by the choice of persistence norms. Panel (a) of Table A4 shows again that the persistence norm is significant as an explanatory variable for F IN 1. However, the constant terms in Model 42 are also highly significant and the adjusted r-squared values are around 0.40. Volatility has a higher significance and, when combining volatility and norms in Model 62, it is volatility that has the most significant coefficients. Almost two-thirds of the variation in FIN1 may be explained by volatility and persistence norms, a large increase from the just under half that is explained by volatility alone. Model fits using the L 2 norm are slightly better than those obtained the L 1 norm in the main paper. Importantly the qualitative messages emerging from panel (a) are very similar. Panel (b) of Table A4 considers MAC and specifically the one-month ahead macroeconomic uncertainty index (M AC1). Here, as in the main paper, we see no significance of the persistence norms from clouds of any-length. Because the volatility is not affected by the choice of norms in the model, results for model 52 match those from model 5 exactly. Drawing parallels with the L 1 norms in the main paper, we may again see that the results are qualitatively similar. Hence whilst persistence norms add to the fit of FIN they do not provide additional information in the fit of MAC. In each caseσ is the average standard deviation of the four index returns in the window and is the error term. Estimation employs Newey and West (1987) robust standard errors to control for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity inherent in these time series. Sample from 1st January 1993 to 28th June 2021. Newey and West (1987) robust standard errors to control for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity inherent in these time series. Sample from 1st January 1993 to 28th June 2021. As with the main paper, the strong correlation between volatility and uncertainty means that we do not consider high and low norm periods. Here we ask whether there is a different role for norms and volatility in periods of high, or low, uncertainty. To achieve this we split the sample at the median of the respective uncertainty indexes. As neither the uncertainty index, nor the volatility, are affected by the choice of norm the results from model 52 are again identical to those from model 5 in the main paper. Panel (a) of Table A5 shows again that persistence norms from the 3-month and 6-month clouds are significant in explaining high periods of FIN. Compared to the results in the main paper the adjusted rsquared is higher, but the inference on the role of norms is qualitatively similar. We also see strong similarity in the significance of the persistence norms after the inclusion of volatility in the model. Here the change to the r-squared value is negligible. It remains the case that the constant terms are highly significant in all models. Panel (b) shows that L 2 norms give significance in the 6-month and 12-month clouds but that this does not survive the introduction of volatility into the model. Recognising the links between volatility and norms, attributes this result to volatility. Primarily the inference on FIN is that the results are qualitatively similar. Turning to M AC1 in panel (c) we again see that persistence norms from the financial markets do not explain contemporaneous uncertainty. The only coefficient identified with statistical significance for the L 2 norm is in the 1-month point cloud and this is a very volatile signal. With typically 22 points in the cloud caution should be extended about interpreting the significance of the L 2 norm in model 62 versus the insignificance of the L 1 in model 6 of the main paper. Panel (d) shows again that in low periods of M AC1 the persistence norm does pick up a significant coefficient in longer length clouds. However, this significance in model 42 disappears when moving to model 62. Again it is volatility that is the main explanatory variable for M AC1. This appendix has repeated the analysis from the main paper using the L 2 persistence norm in place of the L 1 . We have shown that the results are qualitatively similar as would have been expected from the strong correlations in Table 1 of the main paper. Some small differences in the series were observed around the "dot-com" bubble and understanding the reasons for these may help evaluate the best choice between L 1 and L 2 norms in practical applications. It remains the case that the use of L 1 after Gidea and Katz (2018) is sufficient to provide inference on the links between persistence norms, volatility and the uncertainty indices of Jurado et al. (2015) . Is economic uncertainty priced in the cross-section of stock returns The macroeconomic uncertainty premium in the corporate bond market The persistence landscape and some of its properties A persistence landscapes toolbox for topological statistics Topology and data Topological recognition of critical transitions in time series of cryptocurrencies Topological data analysis of financial time series: Landscapes of crashes Topological data analysis in investment decisions Chaos and nonlinear dynamics: application to financial markets. The journal of finance Measuring uncertainty Time-resolved topological data analysis of market instabilities Some statistical properties of functional norms of persistence topological landscapes Which uncertainty measures matter for the cross-section of stock returns? Finance Research Letters Clustering and classification of time series using topological data analysis with applications to finance A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation Topological data analysis: concepts, computation, and applications in chemical engineering Persistent homology of time-dependent functional networks constructed from coupled time series