key: cord-0526498-97eyqugl authors: Heinrich, Torsten title: Epidemics in modern economies date: 2021-05-06 journal: nan DOI: nan sha: dd555c5f1ea0e2273f5acbb2c512a8b4c6843e59 doc_id: 526498 cord_uid: 97eyqugl How are economies in a modern age impacted by epidemics? In what ways is economic life disrupted? How can pandemics be modeled? What can be done to mitigate and manage the danger? Does the threat of pandemics increase or decrease in the modern world? The Covid-19 pandemic has demonstrated the importance of these questions and the potential of complex systems science to provide answers. This article offers a broad overview of the history of pandemics, of established facts, and of models of infection diffusion, mitigation strategies, and economic impact. The example of the Covid-19 pandemic is used to illustrate the theoretical aspects, but the article also includes considerations concerning other historic epidemics and the danger of more infectious and less controllable outbreaks in the future. 1 With outbreaks of unknown origin it is difficult to determine the prident way of action. Much of what Chinese authorities did was prudent; they did immediately investigate the seafood market, they quarantined the known patients, they sequenced the virus within three weeks (Zhou et al., 2020) . 2 Note that while there are scholars who doubt this explanation of the origins of COVID-19, these are considered fringe opinions and unreliable (Cohen, 2020; Deslandes et al., 2020; Michael-Kordatou, Karaolia, & Fatta-Kassinos, 2020; Platto, Xue, & Carafoli, 2020) . For a summary of the current state of research, see the official WHO report (Embarek et al., 2021) . Pathogens are older than humanity itself and so are, in all likelihood, pandemics. Throughout recorded history, they have repeatedly swept entire continents or, in the last few centuries, the entire world. Starting with reports of outbreaks some 3350 years ago (Trevisanato, 2007) and early medieval records of what may or may not have been the bubonic plague, examples reach to the black death and modern pandemics of smallpox, cholera and influenza right to the present Covid-19 pandemic. Data for earlier times is sketchy, the record is incomplete until modern times, but the body of evidence is nevertheless substantial. It yields some clear and general facts: (1) We know what devastating pandemics can do to human society. The black death killed between a third and two thirds of the European population (Alfani & Murphy, 2017) . The diseases introduced in the Americas by conquistadores may have killed up to 92% of the population -which disrupted the cohesion of societies and the pre-contact civilizations were easily conquered or simply collapsed (Koch, Brierley, Maslin, & Lewis, 2019; Livi-Bacci, 2006) . In Europe, the black death in the 14th century may have forced deep social changes, e.g. through better wages because of labor shortages, and may this have inadvertendly contributed to the rise of Europe. However, it is alco clear that the immediate effects were negative by all accounts -collapse of the irrigation system that had been the core of agriculture in Egypt, decline of income in Spain such that pre-black-death levels were probably only exceeded in the 1800s, in Eastern Europe it may have contributed to the establishment of serfdom (Alfani & Murphy, 2017) . (2) Advances sanitation and in medical technology, including vaccines, antibiotics and antiviral drugs, and other treatments have been highly effective in containing epidemics (Madhav et al., 2017; Morabia, 2020; Morens, Folkers, & Fauci, 2008) . Smallpox has been eradicated, cholera, bubonic plague and many other diseases that caused devastating pandemics at some point in history are now treatable and could probably be eradicated given sufficient funding for such an effort. New pandemics have continued to arise, however. Not all of them are under control and new ones continue to emerge. Many scholars have warned of the dangers new pandemics pose to growth, stability, peace, and human society as such (Cincotti et al., 2012; Goldin & Mariathasan, 2014; Morens et al., 2008; Pastore y Piontti, Perra, Rossi, Samay, & Vespignani, 2019) . (3) The behavior of pandemics depends crucially on the transmission network, that is population density, social practices, and mobility (Clemens & Ginn, 2020; Li, Richmond, & Roehner, 2018; Morens et al., 2008; Piret & Boivin, 2021; Saunders-Hastings & Krewski, 2016) . 3 Interaction networks have highly asymmetric, sometimes heavy-tailed, degree distributions. That is, the number of contacts is not even; some people have substantially more than most others and are thus both more likely to catch and to spread a given disease. With modern means of transportation, social networks in modern societies also have and the small-world property 4 , meaning the epidemics will not be contained in local populations. Thus the properties of the interaction network will dominate that of outbreaks the size distribution of which will be equally asymmetric (Newman, 2002) . There are indications that the outbreak size may in some cases be heavy-tailed; Fukui and Furukawa (2020) find this for Covid-19 for instance. (4) While increased mobility may have contributed to the spread and endemicity (continued presence in a host population) of pandemic diseases (Morens et al., 2008; Piret & Boivin, 2021) , there were only a handful of pandemics in the last century that health systems could not efficiently and quickly contain, most notably the H1N1 virus (Spanish influenza) of 1918-1921 (≥ 50 million deaths Morens et al. (2008) ), HIV/AIDS (≈ 30 million deaths, 75 million infections so far), and COVID-19 (≈ 3 million deaths, 150 million infections so far). (5) There are other potential determinants of the emergence of pandemics such as sanitation, the state of public health, and environmental disruption (Morens et al., 2008; Piret & Boivin, 2021) . (6) Unchecked, any epidemic will spread such that the number of cases grows exponentially until it reaches the capacity of the susceptible population (D'Arienzo & Coniglio, 2020). The doubling peropd may be quite short; less than a week in unchecked Covid-19 for instance (La Maestra, Abbondandolo, & De Flora, 2020; Muniz-Rodriguez et al., 2020) . As a result, the timing of public health measures is crucial. A week may make the difference between an insignificant local outbreak and the near-collapse of the health care system with tens of thousands of deaths. In the case of Covid-19, the slow pace of the reaction in many countries (cf. (Arrowsmith et al., 2020) ) made the crisis much worse. There is often a latency period during which subjects may be contagious without realizing they are infected, thus exacerbating the spread of the disease. Symptomless but contagious cases -a hallmark of Covid-19 outbreaks -have the same effect. It has been known for a very long time that epidemics somehow spread between people and that modifying the transmission network with measures like quarantines is effective in curbing the spread of the diseases. El Amarna letter EA 96, written about 3350 years ago describes this: "I will not permit the entrance of the men of Simyra [int]o my city; there is a pestilence in Simyra." 5 (Youngblood, 1962) . Quarantine became standard procedure in pre-modern times and long before it was understood how pandemics are caused (Morabia, 2020) . However, it was often difficult to enforce and extensive lockdowns remained prohibitively expensive even for the richest countries until a few decades ago. The COVID-19 pandemic constitutes the first opportunity for us to deploy modern technology and stop a global pandemic in its tracks, although we have not succeeded so far. Thanks to epidemiology, network science, and also complex systems science, we have detailed models of the development of the present pandemic -comprehensive studies with constructive policy recommendations on every aspect of the crisis emerged fairly quickly after the start of the pandemic (del Rio Chanona, Mealy, Ferguson et al., 2020; Pichler, Pangallo, del Rio-Chanona, Lafond, & Doyne Farmer, 2020) . It is possible to send large sections of the labor force to work from home -especially in developed economies far more than half of the labor force works jobs in the tertiary (service) sector, some of which can be done remotely. Global travel networks can be scaled down while maintaining communications via modern communications technologies and enabling logistics and global supply chains to continue, many tasks have been automated anyway. Other important aspects of society such as education and leisure activities are also shifting online. What is more, today's economies are not at the brink of collapse in spite of many months of lockdowns. Strategies to contain epidemics -not only Covid-19 -usually include the following (Colizza, Barrat, Barthelemy, Valleron, & Vespignani, 2007; Ferguson et al., 2006) : • Reduce the network density via lockdowns or closure of businesses, the hospitality sector etc. • Compartmentalize the network to prevent it from spreading to other countries or communities. • Remove transmission channels, e.g. animal vectors, unsafe water supply, droplets in the air in indoor venues. • Reduce susceptibility by vaccination. • Increase the capacity of the health care sector. • Contain the spread of the epidemic to as few individuals as possible in order to limit the expected number of mutations. All of these measures have been deployed at one point of the other against the Covid-19 pandemic. They all follow the same epidemiological strategy: increase the selection pressure on the virus beyond it's capacity to adapt. A different strategy is possible: increase the mutation rate enough for the replication process to falter causing the loss of functional adaptations and making the virus population less potent (error catastrophe (Eigen, McCaskill, & Schuster, 1988) ). It has been suggested that this might play a role in drugs used to manage active Covid-19 infections (Jena, 2020) , although SARS-Cov-2 (the virus causing Covid-19) is a positive-stranded RNA-virus. These viruses have a comparatively low mutation rate, especially compared to retroviruses like HIV. The COVID-19 pandemic has changed society and the economy substantially -and even so, in spite of our best efforts, the pandemic is not defeated and may yet lead to further and perhaps devastating consequences. Beyond the immediate effects like the devastating jump in the death rate (Figure 1) , the pandemic had effects on all parts of socio-economic life. The GDP collapsed around the globe (Figure 2 ), transport logistics ground to a halt (Figures 3 and 4) , there were shortages because of bottlenecks in storage and transportation and later because production of microchips, bicycles and other commodities could not keep up. Meanwhile the price of oil collapsed to practically zero ( Figure 5 ), and to negative values for futures. Consumers are saving huge quantities of money. Significant numbers of employees have been laid off or furloughed and parts of the economy, especially in the hospitality sector, are only maintained with government subsidies. The adjustment that will follow when the subsidy schemes will finally end may be as turbulent as the beginning of the pandemic. While the considerations would apply similarly to other pandemics, it is convenient to use the current Covid-19 pandemic as an example. Virtually all other recent pandemics have been brought under control relatively quickly with the exception of the 1918-1921 influenza and the HIV pandemic. The 1918-21 influenza occured in a very different environment (much less sophisticated medical technology, war, social hardship, widespread poverty, different demographic structure) (Morens & Fauci, 2007) ; HIV on the other hand progresses and spreads slowly and has thus completely different properties. 6 Fairly quickly after the start of the 2020 Covid-19 lockdowns, the question about re-opening safely and mitigating the economic efects emerged. DSGE modelers combined epidemiological SIR models (see below) with standard DSGE models and concluded that the rebound was going to be swift -a V-shaped recovery (Acemoglu, Chernozhukov, Werning, & Whinston, 2020; Eichenbaum, Rebelo, & Trabandt, 2020) . Complexity economics on the other hand used data-driven approaches to build models that took -among other things -the sectoral level into account Pichler et al., 2020; Sharma, Bouchaud, Gualdi, Tarzia, & Zamponi, 2020) . Starting from the finding that the impact on different sectors differs widely Richiardi et al., 2020) , Pichler et al. (2020) for instance suggested a partial reopening with consumer-facing sectors remaining closed at first. They use a sectoral agent-based model combined with SIR-model and other aspects and calibrated with the sectoral shocks found by (del Rio Chanona et al., 2020). 7 Many dynamic or ABM approaches agreed that a V-shaped recovery was unlikely and variously suggesting W-shaped or L-shaped developments of macroeconomic indicators (Gómez-Pineda, 2020; Sharma et al., 2020) . Combined with the earliest findings by Ferguson et al. (2020) that suggested that multiple lockdowns may be necessary to quell repeated outbreaks, and considering the subsequent second and third waves of the pandemic (Figure 1) , this finding has been vindicated -there has been no V-shaped recovery so far except the worst-hit countries are also catastrophing and do not leave the economy unscathed (Canning, 2006) . 7 There are many other studies that follow similar, but less sophisticated, approaches, e.g. Barrot, Grassi, and Sauvagnat (2020) ; Inoue and Todo (2020) or equilibrium models with sectoral levels and input-output matrices but with the pandemic modeled as a simple shock (Baqaee & Farhi, 2020) . Beyond the development of economic growth, substantial changes can be expected at the microlevel: • With layoffs and uneven impact in different sectors, there are effects on inequality: (Casarico & Lattanzio, 2020; Finck & Tillmann, 2020; Mattana, Smeets, & Warzynski, 2020) agree that moinortities, women, and employees in low-skilled jobs are are disproportionally affected by layoffs. Some authors suggested that stimulus packages may reduce inequality in the short term , although it is doubtful that this effect will last. • Haldane (2020) pointed out that central bank balances are increasingly inflated, more so than at any other point in recent times. It is not clear what the effect of this will be in the mid-to long term. • Substantial skills have been developed in working and collaborating remotely; communication technologies (video conferencing tools in particular) are more sophisticated. However, contrary to popular belief, being forced to work from home still seems less productive than the regular pre-pandemic work-schedule, although this effect was less strong for highly skilled jobs and those who had experience with work from home (Morikawa, 2020) . • At the same time, a lock-in effect as analyzed in the 1980s by David (1985) and Arthur (1989) had taken place. Zoom Inc. has emerged as the clear industry leader, followed by Microsoft • With production interruptions occurring because of outbreaks and lockdowns anyway, it is possible that in some industries the re-investment (upgrade, modernization) cycle will be brought forward. Driven by technological developments that were under way long before the crisis (Brynjolfsson & McAfee, 2015; Brynjolfsson, Rock, & Syverson, 2017) , this may lead to an earlier replacement of human employees by AI and higher unemployment and vanishing of entire categories of jobs in the wake of the crisis (Pissarides, 2020) . These effects would be expected to occur in a simular way in other pandemics to come, unless the economy, governments, or corporations take steps to prevent undesirable outcomes from this list. (1) β is the rate of infection for each pairing of a susceptible and an immune infividual; γ is the rate at which infected persons recover. The model makes the simplification that all persons are identical except for their infected status and that interactions between all individuals are equally likely. As a result, the development of the outbreak can easily be computed. Figure 6 visualizes the intuition behind this model. Compartmental SIR models can easily be extended. They could include deaths (SIRD models) include limited immunity, i.e. reversion from immune to susceptible (SIRS models), and many other aspects. They can also be included in other, more comprehensive models (as in (Eichenbaum et al., 2020; Pichler et al., 2020) ) or extended to allow for non-trivial interaction networks (see below). Like in real-life epidemics, the outbreak will show an close-to-exponential growth until it approaches the capacity boundary -i.e., as long as S remains high. Many public health efforts, including many of those in response to the Covid-19 pandemic, are designed to react to the R 0 number. This number is the exponential growth rate While it is easy to work with the R 0 number in a model environment such as this one, where everything is known, the number is more difficult to measure in real outbreaks. Instead of operating at the aggregated level the transition rates βI and γ can be interpreted as transition probabilities β i , γ i at the level of the individual agent. Equation 1 becomes . ( and p(S i ), p(I i ), and p(R i ) are now probabilities that agent i is in the respective state. Computationally, this can be simulated by shifting each agent from state to state with probabilities β i and γ i in each time period. Even with modest computation power, huge models of this type can be simulated (Bagni, Berchi, & Cariello, 2002) . The advantage is that agents can now be heterogeneous and there is no need to assume a complete network (where agery agent could infect every other agent) -any network structure can be studied. Further, adding additional states such as latent infections, co-morbidities, etc. no not make the simulation substantially more complex. Of course, in this case a simulation approach is used -with all advantages and drawbacks of that approach (for an overview, see, e.g., Gräbner et al. (2019) ). Another way to allow for heterogeneity and non-trivial network structures is to solve the agent-based version of the compartmental model (Equation 3) as a mean-field model (Sharkey, 2008) . As above, all transmission risks for agent i are folded into β i : where T is the matrix of the transmission rates, N is the number of agents, p(S i ) is the probability that i is susceptible and p((I j , S i )) is the joint probabilities that i is susceptible and j is infectious. With statistical independence p(I j , S i ) = p(I j )p(S i ), we obtain (after substituting 4 into 3) . The expected numbers of agents in each state are Expectations for p(S i ), p(I i ), and p(R i ) are At this point, we can drop R and dR i dt , because the system is closed and S + I + R = N must hold at every time step. We obtain development equations Comparing Equation 8 to 1 shows that the equivalent of β here is Hence, we also have Note that these expressions can be simplified if we assume homogeneous recovery rates γ i = γ and homogeneous transmission probabilities. If we have homogeneous transmission probabilities β on all existing connections in the network T = βA (where A is the simple adjacency matrix and A N is the average degree; the average number of neighbors), we get which reduces back to Equation 1 for the case of a complete network, where everyone is everyone else's neighbor, because then n = N . Compartmental models or their extensions can be used to model the development of a pandemic, especially its scale. This has been used as an input in economic models either in the form of a shock (Baqaee & Farhi, 2020) or by including the SIR-model as such (Acemoglu et al., 2020; Eichenbaum et al., 2020; Pichler et al., 2020) . The latter approach has the advantage that the impact of policy decisions and economic activity on the course of the pandemic can be incorporated in the SIR-based ABM or mean field. The economic part of the model will often concentrate on the sectoral level (Baqaee & Farhi, 2020; Pichler et al., 2020) conveniently modeled using input-output-tables. The impact of the pandemic on the labor force -possible labor shortages in particular sectors or possible layoffs is also often included (Acemoglu et al., 2020; del Rio Chanona et al., 2020) . ABMs are particularly versatile in this context. Compared to simpler models which separate the two aspects -the epidemiological and the economic model -integrated ABMs can offer important insights into feedback effects, differences between sectors, and possible systemic risks for both the expected future development and hypothetical scenarios (for alternative policy measures for instance). Complex systems science and complexity economics have helped enormously in understanding the present Covid-19 pandemic (Ferguson et al., 2020) and its socio-economic consequences Pichler et al., 2020; Sharma et al., 2020) . Effects on economic growth and the labor market have been modeled in detail. Effects on inequality, productivity, and financial stability are suspected. Many other effects of the Covid-19 crisis on, e.g., innovation, insurance, financial stability, health care economy, etc. are likely, but few findings have been clearly established. With vaccinations there is hope that the pandemic will be brought under control soon, i.e. within months, in most countries. This is in line with initial estimates (Byambasuren et al., 2020; Fontanet & Cauchemez, 2020) . However, it is also clear that Covid-19 will not be the last pandemic and SARS-Cov-2 not the last emerging pathogen. Integrated trade networks, improved mobility and higher population densities all contribute to this. In spite of some cautioning voices in recent years (e.g., Goldin and Mariathasan (2014) ) and good theoretical understanding of how pandemics spread and how they can be stopped, society, policy makers and economic systems have been largely unprepared for what happened. It is crucial that this should not happen again. There are many pathogens that cause periodic localized outbreaks or have the potential to do so -and some of them (Ebola, Marburg-virus, new strains of influenza, multiresistant bacteria?, more virulent HIV?) could be much more devastating than Covid-19. It is important that modern society and public officials learn to trust scientists and researchers -including complex systems scientists and complexity economists -more than political strongmen, who were very vocal in the early stages of the Covid-19 pandemic, and who have agendas and strong opinions, but no expertise. Optimal targeted lockdowns in a multi-group SIR model (Working Paper No. 27102). National Bureau of Economic Research Plague and lethal epidemics in the pre-industrial world Public request to take stronger measures of social distancing across the UK with immediate effect Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events A comparison of simulation models applied to epidemics Nonlinear production networks with an application to the Covid-19 crisis (Working Paper No. 27281) Sectoral effects of social distancing The Covid-19 crisis response helps the poor: The distributional and budgetary consequences of the UK lock-down Artificial intelligence and the modern productivity paradox: A clash of expectations and statistics. (NBER working paper No. 24001 Comparison of seroprevalence of SARS-CoV-2 infections with cumulative and imputed COVID-19 cases: systematic review. medRxiv The economics of HIV/AIDS in low-income countries: the case for prevention The heterogeneous effects of COVID-19 on labor market flows: Evidence from administrative data An economic and financial exploratory Global mobility and the threat of pandemics: Evidence from three centuries Wuhan coronavirus hunter Shi Zhengli speaks out Modeling the worldwide spread of pandemic influenza: Baseline case and containment interventions Assessment of the SARS-CoV-2 basic reproduction number, R0, based on the early phase of COVID-19 outbreak in Italy Clio and the economics of QWERTY Supply and demand shocks in the COVID-19 pandemic: An industry and occupation perspective SARS-CoV-2 was already spreading in France in late The macroeconomics of epidemics (Working Paper No. 26882) Molecular quasi-species WHO-convened global study of origins of SARS-CoV-2: China part A complex systems approach to constructing better models for managing financial markets and the economy Strategies for mitigating an influenza pandemic Impact of non-pharmaceutical interventions (NPIs) to reduce COVID-19 mortality and healthcare demand Pandemic shocks and household spending COVID-19 herd immunity: where are we? Power laws in superspreading events: Evidence from coronavirus outbreaks and implications for SIR models. medRxiv The butterfly defect Growth forecasts and the Covid-19 recession they convey Getting the best of both worlds? developing complementary equationbased and agent-based models Li Wenliang. The Lancet The second quarter. (Speech, given during an online webinar The propagation of economic impacts through supply chains: The case of a mega-city lockdown to prevent the spread of COVID-19 Role of different tautomers in the base-pairing abilities of some of the vital antiviral drugs used against COVID-19 A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics Earth system impacts of the European arrival and Great Dying in the Americas after 1492 Epidemiological trends of COVID-19 epidemic in Italy over March 2020: From 1000 to 100 000 cases Effect of population density on epidemics The depopulation of Hispanic America after the conquest The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank Changing skill structure and COVID-19. Covid Economics, 45 , 1-30 Sewage analysis as a tool for the COVID-19 pandemic response and management: the urgent need for optimised protocols for SARS-CoV-2 detection and quantification Pandemics and methodological developments in epidemiology history The 1918 Influenza Pandemic: Insights for the 21st Century Emerging infections: a perpetual challenge. The Lancet infectious diseases Productivity of working from home during the COVID-19 pandemic: Evidence from an employee survey Doubling time of the COVID-19 epidemic by province Spread of epidemic disease on networks Charting the next pandemic: Modeling infectious disease spreading in the data science age Production networks and epidemic spreading: How to restart the UK economy? Covid Economics Pandemics throughout history As Covid-19 accelerates automation, how do we stop the drift into long-term unemployment? LSE Business Review COVID19: an announced pandemic The economic consequences of COVID-19 lockdown in the UK. an input-output analysis using consensus scenarios An application of the theory of probabilities to the study of a priori pathometry. -Part I Reviewing the history of pandemic influenza: Understanding patterns of emergence and transmission Deterministic epidemiological models at the individual level Economic recovery after COVID-19? insights from an agent-based model1 The 'Hittite plague', an epidemic of tularemia and the first record of biological warfare Amorite influence in a Canaanite Amarna letter (EA 96) Modelling the effects of Wuhan's lockdown during COVID-19 others (2020). A pneumonia outbreak associated with a new coronavirus of probable bat origin