key: cord-0541360-klu6obxt authors: Bodnar, Taras; Parolya, Nestor; Thors'en, Erik title: Is the empirical out-of-sample variance an informative risk measure for the high-dimensional portfolios? date: 2021-11-24 journal: nan DOI: nan sha: 9085b92dbf9d0c3b2884aa255690972a7b8ec018 doc_id: 541360 cord_uid: klu6obxt The main contribution of this paper is the derivation of the asymptotic behaviour of the out-of-sample variance, the out-of-sample relative loss, and of their empirical counterparts in the high-dimensional setting, i.e., when both ratios $p/n$ and $p/m$ tend to some positive constants as $mtoinfty$ and $ntoinfty$, where $p$ is the portfolio dimension, while $n$ and $m$ are the sample sizes from the in-sample and out-of-sample periods, respectively. The results are obtained for the traditional estimator of the global minimum variance (GMV) portfolio, for the two shrinkage estimators introduced by cite{frahm2010} and cite{bodnar2018estimation}, and for the equally-weighted portfolio, which is used as a target portfolio in the specification of the two considered shrinkage estimators. We show that the behaviour of the empirical out-of-sample variance may be misleading is many practical situations. On the other hand, this will never happen with the empirical out-of-sample relative loss, which seems to provide a natural normalization of the out-of-sample variance in the high-dimensional setup. As a result, an important question arises if this risk measure can safely be used in practice for portfolios constructed from a large asset universe. Mean-variance analysis of Markowitz is a well established tool for optimal portfolio selection which is one of the most popular approaches today in financial literature (see, e.g., Markowitz (1952) , Markowitz (1959) , Britten-Jones (1999) , Ao et al. (2019) , Bodnar et al. (2021d) , Ding et al. (2021) ). The idea behind the approach is to invest in the portfolio which has the smallest variance for a given level of the expected return. In the limiting case of the fully risk-averse investor, the so-called global minimum variance (GMV) portfolio is selected. The latter portfolio possesses the smallest variance among all mean-variance optimal portfolios and lies on the vertex of the efficient frontier which is a parabola in the mean-variance space (see, Merton (1972) , Kan and Smith (2008) , Bodnar and Schmid (2009) ). One of the important challenges, which arise when the Markowitz theory is implemented in practice, is related to the estimation error which appears when unknown parameters of the data-generating process are replaced by their sample counterparts in the expressions of the optimal portfolio weights (see, Okhrin and Schmid (2006) , El Karoui (2010), Cai et al. (2020) , Bodnar et al. (2021e) , Bodnar et al. (2021a) ). The impact of the parameter uncertainty on the performance of optimal portfolios is usually comparable to or even larger than the one described by the model uncertainty which is determined by using the covariance matrix in Markowitz optimization problem. Moreover, the estimation error present in an estimator of the mean vector has even a larger influence on the performance of optimal portfolios than the error related to the estimation of the covariance matrix (see, e.g., Merton (1980) , Best and Grauer (1991) , Chopra and Ziemba (1993) ). This is usually used in financial literature as an argument to hold the GMV portfolio whose weights only depends on the covariance matrix (Chan et al. (1999) , Jagannathan and Ma (2003) , Frahm and Memmel (2010) , Bodnar et al. (2021b) ). Let y denote the k-dimensional vector of the asset returns and let µ = E(y) and Σ = Var(y) be its mean vector and covariance matrix. Then the expected return and the variance of the portfolio with the weights w are given by R p = w µ and V p = w Σw, respectively. The weights of the GMV portfolio are found by minimizing V p given that the whole investor wealth is invested in the selected assets, i.e., under the constraint w 1 = 1 where 1 denotes the p-dimensional vector of ones. They are given by while the variance of the GMV portfolio is expressed as We refer to w GM V and V GM V as the population weights and the population variance of the GMV portfolio, since they both depend on the unknown parameter Σ of the data-generating model. It has to be noted that V GM V is also called the in-sample variance in financial literature (see, Frahm and Memmel (2010) ). In practical applications, the population GMV portfolio cannot be constructed since its weights w GM V depend on the unobservable quantity Σ. Given historical realizations of the asset returns, y 1 , ..., y n , the population covariance matrix is estimated by its sample counterpart expressed as Then, the traditional GMV portfolio is determined as the sample estimator of w GM V where the unknown Σ is replaced by S n , i.e., w n;S = S −1 n 1 1 S −1 n 1 . (1.4) If the portfolio dimension p is considerably smaller than the sample size n, then S n consistently estimates Σ under weak conditions imposed on the data-generating model of the asset returns and, consequently, the traditional GMV portfolio provides a good approximation of the population GMV portfolio. The situation is completely different in the high-dimensional setting when the portfolio dimension is comparable to the sample size such that p/n → c ∈ [0, 1) as n → ∞ where the constant c is called the concentration ratio (see, Bai and Silverstein (2010) , Bodnar et al. (2019a) ). In this case the sample covariance matrix S n is not longer a consistent estimator for Σ. As a result, the traditional GMV portfolio might deviate considerably from the population GMV portfolio. In order to ensure a good performance of the holding portfolio, the weights of the traditional GMV portfolio have to be adjusted by taking the parameter uncertainty into account (see, e.g., Jagannathan and Ma (2003) , Bodnar et al. (2019b) , Ao et al. (2019) , Cai et al. (2020) , Ding et al. (2021) ). In order to define an improved estimator of the high-dimensional GMV portfolio, i.e., when p is comparable to n, the optimization problem has to be formulated. As a performance measure, the out-of-sample variance is usually used which is given by whereŵ n is an estimator of w GM V based on the asset returns y 1 , ..., y n . Alternatively, one can use the out-of-sample relative loss as a performance measure. By definitions of Vŵ n and Lŵ n , one directly gets that the portfolio which minimizes the out-of-sample variance also minimizes the out-of-sample relative loss and vice versa. Unfortunately, due to the presence of Σ in (1.5) and in (1.6), both the performance measures can only be used in theoretical derivations or in the comparison study based on the simulated data where the covariance matrix Σ is known. In practice, Σ is usually replaced by its estimator S n+1,m constructed by using the asset returns y n+1 , ..., y n+m from time n+1 to n+m and defined by (1.7) Consequently, the out-of-sample variance and the out-of-sample relative loss are replaced by the sample counterparts, the so-called empirical out-of-sample variance and the empirical out-ofsample relative loss expressed aŝ Vŵ n;m =ŵ n S n+1:m+1ŵn , (1 −c) −1V n+1:n+m;GM V = (1 −c)1 S −1 n+1:m+1 1ŵ n S n+1:m+1ŵn − 1, (1.9) respectively, with p/m →c as m → ∞. In (1.9), (1 −c)V n+1:n+m;GM V is a consistent estimator for V GM V in the high-dimensional setting (see, Lemma 1.3 in Bodnar et al. (2021e) ). We contribute in this paper by deriving the asymptotic behaviour of the out-of-sample variance, of the out-of-sample relative loss, and of their empirical counterparts in the highdimensional setting, i.e., when p/n → c as n → ∞ and p/m →c as m → ∞. The results are obtained for the sample estimator (1.4) of the GMV portfolio (1.1), for two shrinkage estimators introduced by Frahm and Memmel (2010) and Bodnar et al. (2018) , and for the equally-weighted portfolio, which is used as a target portfolio in the specification of the considered two shrinkage estimators. We show that the empirical out-of-sample variance might tend to zero independently of chosen estimator of the GMV portfolio, which make hard to distinguish between the estimators in practice. In contrast, the empirical out-of-sample losses of the considered estimators of the GMV portfolio tend to deterministic finite quantities. As such, a decision about the ranking of the estimators can be drawn. Moreover, one needs milder conditions for the derivation of the asymptotic properties of the empirical out-of-sample relative loss in comparison to the empirical out-of-sample variance, which is an additional advantage for the application of the former in practice. Statistical methods used in the derivation of improved estimators of optimal portfolio weights and of the performance measures are closely related to the approaches applied in statistical signal processing. In particular, the GMV portfolio is linked to the Capon or minimum variance spatial filter in signal processing literature (see, e.g., Verdú (1998) , Van Trees (2002)). Rubio et al. (2012) , Yang et al. (2018) , Li et al. (2004) studied the estimation risk in the case of the high-dimensional minimum variance beamformer, while Mestre and Lagunas (2006) investigate the finite-sample size effect on minimum variance filter. Zhang et al. (2013) discuss the improved estimation of the inverse covariance matrix from signal processing perspectives. Finally, applications of random matrix theory to signal processing and portfolio optimization are provided in Feng and Palomar (2016) , among others. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, the asymptotic behaviour of the out-of-sample variance and of the out-of-sample relative loss is established for the traditional sample estimator and for the two shrinkage approaches. Section 3 presents the corresponding results in the case of the empirical performance measures. The results of a comprehensive simulation study are provided in Section 4, while the theoretical findings are implemented to real data in Section 5. Concluding remarks are drawn in Section 6. The proofs of the theoretical results are postponed to the appendix (Section 7). 2 Out-of-sample variance and relative loss Let the vector of asset returns, y 1 , ..., y n , y n+1 , ..., y n+m be independent and identically distributed with the following stochastic representation where the components of x t are independent and identically distributed with zero mean, unit variance, and finite 4 + moments for some > 0. No specific distributional assumptions are imposed on the components of x t . The symbol Σ 1/2 denotes the square root of a positive definite matrix Σ, i.e., Σ = Σ 1/2 (Σ 1/2 ) . Finally, we note that only y t , t = 1, ..., n + m, are observable, while µ, Σ, and x t , t = 1, ..., n + m, are all unknown. Depending on the performance measure different assumptions on the covariance matrix Σ and on the weights b of the target portfolio are imposed. They are summarized as follows: (A1) The variance of the GMV portfolio V GM V as given in (1.2) is uniformly bounded in p. (A2) The variance of the target portfolio V b = b Σb is uniformly bounded in p. (A3) The relative loss of the target portfolio is uniformly bounded in p. The considered assumptions are very general and are fulfilled in many applications. For instance, all three assumptions are fulfilled when the eigenvalues of Σ are uniformly bounded in p and the Euclidean norm of the target vector b is uniformly bounded in p. Assumptions (A1) and (A2) will be needed when the out-of-sample variance (1.5) and its empirical counterpart (1.8) are analyzed, while Assumption (A3) is required only in the case of the out-of-sample relative loos (1.6) and of the empirical out-of-sample relative loss (1.9). This is not surprising, since the relative loss functions are already normalized and for that reason less restrictive assumptions are needed to study their asymptotic behaviour. Furthermore, the normalization constant does not depend on an estimator of the GMV portfolio weights and thus, the normalization has no impact on the selected estimator. Two shrinkage estimators for the GMV portfolio weights were derived in Frahm and Memmel (2010) and Bodnar et al. (2018) , and they are given bŷ respectively. Next, we present the asymptotic behaviour of the out-of-sample variance (Theorem 2.1) and of the out-of-sample relative loss (Theorem 2.2) calculated for the sample estimatorŵ n;S of the GMV portfolio weights and for two shrinkage estimatorsŵ n;F M andŵ n;BP S in the highdimensional setting. The proofs of the theorems are given in the appendix. To this end, we note that the out-of-sample variance and the out-of-sample loss of the target portfolio b are, by definition, expressed as respectively. Theorem 2.1. Let y t , t = 1, ..., n follow model (2.1). Then, (i) under Assumption (A1), for the out-of-sample variance of the sample GMV portfolioŵ n;S it holds that (A2), for the out-of-sample variance of the shrinkage GMV portfolioŵ n;BP S it holds that (A1) and (A2), for the out-of-sample variance of the shrinkage GMV portfolioŵ n;F M it holds that for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) as n → ∞. Theorem 2.2. Let y t , t = 1, ..., n follow model (2.1). Then, (i) for the out-of-sample relative loss of the sample GMV portfolioŵ n;S it holds that (2.13) (ii) under Assumption (A3), for the out-of-sample relative loss of the shrinkage GMV portfoliô w n;BP S it holds that (2.14) (iii) under Assumption (A3), for the out-of-sample relative loss of the shrinkage GMV portfoliô w n;F M it holds that for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) as n → ∞ where α BP S and α F M are given in (2.10) and (2.12), respectively. The findings of Theorem 2.2 shows that the relative loss of shrinkage portfolios is present as a linear combination of the relative loss of the corresponding target portfolio and of the limiting relative loss of the traditional GMV portfolio. The relative loss of the traditional GMV portfoliô w n;S tends to a constant c/(1 − c) that does not depend on the covariance matrix of the asset returns. Moreover, if c tends to 1, then the relative loss of the traditional GMV portfolio tends to infinity showing that the impact of the estimation error could be drastically large in the high-dimensional setting. Furthermore, using (2.10) and (2.12) the limiting values of relative loss computed for two shrinkage estimators can be rewritten as for the shrinkage estimator of Frahm and Memmel (2010) and for the shrinkage estimator of Bodnar et al. (2018) . As a result, expressions (2.16) and (2.17) show that the out-of-sample relative loss of the shrinkage estimator (2.2) tends to infinity as c approaches one, similarly to the traditional estimatorŵ n;S , while the out-of-sample relative loss of the shrinkage estimator (2.4) tends to the relative loss of the target portfolio when c tends to one. The results of Theorem 2.2 lead also to some dominance statements presented Corollary 2.3 in terms of the out-of-sample relative loss. Due to the relationship between the out-of-sample variance and the out-of-sample loss the same statements also hold for the out-of-sample variance by using the findings of Theorem 2.1. with equality if and only if c = 0 or L b = ∞, i.e., when the sample size is considerably larger than the portfolio dimension or the target portfolio deviates too strong from the true GMV portfolio; (ii) Lŵ n;S − Lŵ n;BP S a.s. with equality if and only if c = 0 or L b = ∞, i.e., when the sample size is considerably larger than the portfolio dimension or the target portfolio deviates too strong from the true GMV portfolio; (iii) with equality if and only if c = 0 or c > 0, L b = 0 or c > 0, L b = ∞, i.e., when the target portfolio coincides with the true GMV portfolio or the target portfolio deviates too strong from the true GMV portfolio when the concentration ratio is positive. The findings of Corollary 2.3 show that the shrinkage estimator of Bodnar et al. (2018) outperforms the other two estimators, while the shrinkage estimator of Frahm and Memmel (2010) is always better than the sample estimatorŵ n;S . The exception is present when the sample size n is considerably larger than the portfolio dimension p such that the concentration ratio is equal to zero or when the target portfolio is very poorly chosen such that its relative loss is infinity. In the latter situation, the investor might consider a different target portfolio in order to get the advantage of the shrinkage approaches over the sample estimator. Interestingly, when the target portfolio coincide with the population GMV portfolio, then both shrinkage estimators perform similarly. The results of Theorems 2.1 and 2.2 cannot be used in practice, since the definitions of both the out-of-sample variance and the out-of-sample relative loss depend on the unknown population covariance matrix Σ. As a result, different portfolio strategies are compared between each other based on the empirical counterparts of the out-of-sample performance measures as presented in (1.8) and (1.9), respectively, where the sample of the asset returns y n+1 , ..., y n+m is used to construct an estimator of the covariance matrix denoted by S n+1:n+m as in (1.7). In Theorems 3.1 and 3.2 we derive the asymptotic properties of the empirical out-of-sample variance and of the empirical out-of-sample relative loss computed for the four portfolios discussed in Section 2. The proofs of the theorems are presented in the appendix. It is remarkable that the results of Theorems 3.1 and 3.2 are deduced under the same conditions as given in the statements of Theorems 2.1 and 2.2, even though additional randomness is taken into account in the derivations of the results. Moreover, both the empirical out-of-sample variances and the out-of-sample relative losses converge to the same limiting values as given in Theorems 2.1 and 2.2. with α BP S as in (2.10), (iv) under Assumptions (A1) and (A2), for the empirical out-of-sample variance of the shrinkage GMV portfolioŵ n;F M it holds that with α F M as in (2.12), for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) and p/m →c ∈ (0, ∞) as n → ∞. with α BP S as in (2.10), (iv) under Assumptions (A3), for the empirical out-of-sample relative loss of the shrinkage GMV portfolioŵ n;F M it holds that with α F M as in (2.12), for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) and p/m → c ∈ (0, 1) as n, m → ∞. Since the empirical out-of-sample lossesLŵ n;S ;m ,Lŵ n;BP S ;m , andLŵ n;F M ;m possess the same high-dimensional asymptotic behaviour as the corresponding out-of-sample losses Lŵ n;S , Lŵ n;BP S , and Lŵ n;F M in Theorem 2.2, the results of Corollary 2.3 remain also valid. Namely, we get for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1), p/m →c ∈ (0, 1) as n, m → ∞, with equality if and only if c = 0 or L b = ∞, i.e., when the sample size is considerably larger than the portfolio dimension or the target portfolio deviates too strong from the true GMV portfolio; (ii)Lŵ n;S;m −Lŵ n;BP S;m a.s. for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1), p/m →c ∈ (0, 1) as n, m → ∞, with equality if and only if c = 0 or L b = ∞, i.e., when the sample size is considerably larger than the portfolio dimension or the target portfolio deviates too strong from the true GMV portfolio; (iii)Lŵ ( for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1), p/m →c ∈ (0, 1) as n, m → ∞, with equality if and only if c = 0 or c > 0, L b = 0 or c > 0, L b = ∞, i.e., when the target portfolio coincides with the true GMV portfolio or the target portfolio deviates too strong from the true GMV portfolio when the concentration ratio is positive. Figure 1 : Asymptotic differences between the empirical out-of-sample relative losses limits from Corollary 3.3 for c ∈ (0, 1) and L b ∈ (0, 50). Corollary 3.3 provides the limiting behaviour of the differences of the empirical out-of-sample losses and, consequently, the same ranking between the three estimators of the GMV portfolio weights as previously obtained in Corollary 2.3. Furthermore, the difference between the asymptotic behaviour of the three estimator is negligible only when the concentration ratio is zero, i.e., the portfolio size is considerably smaller than the sample size, or when the target portfolio is poorly chosen such that its relative loss becomes infinity. The asymptotic differences between the relative losses of these three estimators are depicted as functions in c ∈ (0, 1) for several values of L b ∈ (0, 50) in Figure 1 . Larger differences are observed when the shrinkage estimator of Bodnar et al. (2018) is compared to the traditional estimator and the shrinkage estimator of Frahm and Memmel (2010) , especially when c is close to one. On the other side, the asymptotic difference between the empirical out-of-sample relative loss functions computed for the traditional estimator and the shrinkage estimator of Frahm and Memmel (2010) is large only when L b is close to zero, i.e., when the target portfolio b is close to the true population GMV portfolio. In this section we will investigate the finite sample behaviour of the high-dimensional asymptotic results presented in Corollary 3.3 via an extensive Monte Carlo study. The aim of the study is twofold: (i) first, we investigate how fast the difference of the empirical out-of-sample relative loss functions tend to the corresponding limiting value provided in the statement of Corollary 3.3; (ii) second, we study the impact of the presence of linear and non-linear time dependence in the data-generating model on the performance of the three considered trading strategies. For each fixed value of the portfolio size p we first simulated the elements of the mean vector µ as µ i ∼ U (−0.1, 0.1), i = 1, 2, ..., p and the elements of the covariance matrix Σ using the RandCovMtrx function from the HDShOP package (Bodnar et al. (2021c) ). Then these values were used in simulating samples of the asset returns from the following three data-generating models: Scenario 1: t-distribution The elements of x t are drawn independently from the t-distribution with 5 degrees of freedom, that is x tj ∼ t(5) for j = 1, ..., p, while y t is constructed according to (2.1). Moreover since the variance of the t-distribution with 5 degrees of freedom is equal to 5/3 we, additionally multiply the vector x t in (2.1) by 3/5. As such, all 3/5x tj have mean zero and variance one. Scenario 2: VAR model The vector of asset returns y t is simulated according to a for t = 1, ..., n + m, where Γ = diag(γ 1 , γ 2 , ..., γ p ) with γ i ∼ U (−0.9, 0.9) for i = 1, ..., p. We note that in the case of the VAR model, the covariance matrix of y t is computed as vec(Var(y)) = (I − Γ ⊗ Γ) −1 vec(Σ) where vec denotes the vec operator. This matrix is used in the computation of the limiting differences from Corollary 3.3. Scenario 3: CCC-GARCH model of Bollerslev (1990) The asset returns are simulated according to where the conditional covariance matrix is specified by with h j,t = α j,0 + α j,1 (y j,t−1 − µ j ) 2 + β j,1 h j,t−1 , for j = 1, 2, ..., p, and t = 1, 2, ..., n + m. The coefficients of the CCC-GARCH model are generated by α j,1 ∼ U (0, 0.1) and β j,1 ∼ U (0.6, 0.7) which implies that the stationarity conditions, α j,1 + β j,1 < 1, are always fulfilled. The intercepts α j,0 , j = 1, ..., p is thereafter chosen such that the unconditional covariance matrix is equal to Σ. The model under scenario 1 fulfills the assumptions imposed in Section 2 by drawing the vector x t independently each of other. In contrast, scenarios 2 and 3 possess some time dependence structure, thus violating the assumption imposed on the data-generating model in Section 2. While the VAR model from scenario 2 is used to investigate the performance of three portfolio selection strategies when the asset returns y t are assumed to be autocorrelated, a more complicated non-linear time dependence structure is assumed in scenario 3 which is accompanied with conditionally time-dependent covariance matrix Σ t . Finally, the equally weighted portfolio is used as a target portfolio in all scenarios. In Figures 2 to 4 we present the relative differences of empirical out-of-sample losses as considered in Corollary 3.3 divided by the corresponding asymptotic limit determined for each difference in the statement of the corollary in the right hand-side of each inequality. For each scenario we set n = {100, 250, 500, 750, 1000}, c = {0.5, 0.9} andc = {0.5, 0.9}. The portfolio size p and the sample size m are thereafter determined by p = nc and in turn m = p/c. If necessary we round to the closest integer. The results in the figures are based on the 1000 independent repetitions and present the corresponding average values. Figure 2 depicts the results of the simulation study obtained under scenario 1. The relative differences in the empirical out-of-sample losses converge quickly to one, indicating that the results of Corollary 3.3 may also be used when samples of asset returns of moderate size are used. As expected, the fastest convergence is observed in the case c =c = 0.5, while the largest deviations from one is present in the case of c = 0.5 andc = 0.9, when the sample size is small. Finally, we note that all computed values in the plots are positive and, as such, the shrinkage estimator of Bodnar et al. (2018) outperforms the other two trading strategies followed by the shrinkage approach of Frahm and Memmel (2010) in all of the considered cases. In Figure 3 the results of the simulation study obtained under scenario 2 are present. This scenario imposes linear time dependence structure on the vector of asset returns and, thus, it breaks the model assumption that Corollary 3.3 is derived from. This can also be seen in the computed relative differences of losses. In contrast to the values shown in Figure 2 the empirical out-of-sample relative losses do not converge to one in Figure 3 . This indicates that the presence of linear time dependencies has an impact on the limiting properties on the empirical out-ofsample loss functions. On the other hand, the relative differences depicted in Figure 3 are all positive and thus the ranking between the three estimation strategies remains unchanged. Moreover, the relative differences converge to the values which are larger than one, meaning that the derived limiting values in Corollary 3.3 can still be employed as lower bounds. Figure 4 illustrates the results of the simulation study under the last scenario. In this setting the returns are simulated from a CCC-GARCH model which captures volatility clustering and also introduces a non-linear time dependence structure in the vectors of the asset returns. Similarly to scenario 2, the relative differences do not converge to one, although the departure from one is considerably smaller as observed in the case of scenario 2. As such, a conclusion can be drawn that the presence of linear time dependence structure has larger impact on the asymptotic behaviour of the empirical out-of-sample losses than the non-linear one. Also, in scenario 3, the relative losses converge to the values which are larger one and the computed values are all positive. As such, the ranking between the three trading strategies is preserved and one can also us the expression of the limiting values of Corollary 3.3 as the corresponding lower bounds for the differences under the assumption of the CCC-GARCH model. In the empirical application we use 10 years of daily data for 100 and 190 stocks included in the S&P500 index from the first of June 2011 to the seventh of January 2021. During the considered period of time, 380 stocks were continuously included in the the S&P500 index from which we randomly choose 100 and 190 stocks to build the GMV portfolio. The first n = 200 observations were used to estimate the weights of the GMV portfolio by employing the traditional estimator and the two shrinkage estimators introduced in Section 2, while the next m = 200 observations were used to compute the values of the empirical out-of-sample variances and the empirical out-of-sample relative loses for each trading strategy. Then, using the rolling window approach the same computations are subsequently performed over the time period from the fourteenth of February, 2013 to the seventh of January 2021. As a target portfolio in the construction of the two shrinkage estimator, the equally weighted portfolio was used. Figure 5 depicts the values of the empirical out-of-sample variances and of the empirical out-of-sample relative losses computed for three estimators of the GMV portfolio considered in the paper. The result are presented for two portfolio sizes which correspond to c =c = 0.5 and c =c = 0.95. A considerable increase in both the empirical out-of sample variances and losses of each estimator is observed in March 2020 which corresponds to the crisis on international financial market caused by the beginning of COVID-19 spread over the world. The rapid increase of volatility is more pronounced in the case of the smaller dimensional portfolio, i.e., when p = 100. In the case of the portfolio which is based on p = 190 stocks the jump in the values of the two considered performance measures is smoothed due to higher variability of these two measures presented during the whole period of observation. Another rapid increase in the loss functions for p = 100 occurs in late December 2020. This date can be related to the second wave of the COVID-19 spread. Similar increases in the behaviour of the relative loss function are also present for the portfolio consisting of p = 190 stocks, although they are somehow hidden by the more volatile behavior of the loss function in the latter case. In general, the results in Figure 5 confirms the ordering of the three trading strategies which is deduced in Corollary 3.3 and confirmed in the finite-sample case in the simulation study of Section 4. Namely, the shrinkage estimator of Bodnar et al. (2018) shows the smallest values of both the empirical out-of-sample variance and the empirical out-of-sample relative loss, while the shrinkage estimator of Frahm and Memmel (2010) is ranked on the second place. On the other side, when the empirical out-of-sample variance is used as a performance measure, the distinction between the strategies become visually negligible in almost all cases presented for p = 100 and in majority of cases when the portfolio with p = 190 is constructed. This empirical finding can be explained by noting that most of the values of the empirical out-of-sample variance were computed during the stable period on the capital market and as such, the true value of the global minimum variance was very small at that time. In contrast, the usage of the empirical out-ofsample loss can lead to the obvious conclusion about the performance of each of the considered three trading strategies. Finally, the impact of portfolio dimensionality which is accompanied with a huge amount of estimation error becomes more pronounced when the empirical relative loss is used, especially during the turbulent period on the capital market. The sample variance of the GMV portfolio is known to be biased and to significantly underestimate the true population variance of this portfolio, especially when the portfolio size is comparable to the sample size. In many practical situations it is not a good measure for the portfolio performance and the out-of-sample variance is usually used instead. Figure 5 : Empirical out-of-sample variance and out-of-sample relative loss of the the traditional GMV portfolio and the two shrinkage estimators based on the rolling window approach with window size equal 200 and computed for two portfolios which consist of 100 and 190 stocks traded in the S&P 500 index. In this paper we derive the asymptotic properties of the out-of-sample variance and of the outof-sample relative loss as well as of their empirical counterparts. Under weak conditions imposed on the data-generating model it is shown that the out-of-sample variance and the empirical outof-sample variance might tend to zero independently of chosen estimator of the GMV portfolio weights, which can make the comparison between the trading strategies intractable. This is not, however, an issue when the out-of-sample relative loss and the empirical out-of-sample relative loss are used instead. In the latter case a clear ordering between the estimators of the three considered estimator can be made. As a by product of the derived theoretical findings, we also prove that the shrinkage estimator of Bodnar et al. (2018) outperforms the shrinkage estimator of Frahm and Memmel (2010) and the traditional estimator of the GMV portfolio. Moreover, we quantify the difference in the performance of the three trading strategies by deducing the asymptotic difference of their empirical out-of-sample relative loss functions. Within a comprehensive numerical study it is shown that the derive asymptotic limits can still be used when the sample of moderate size is present and when the asset returns possess both linear and non-linear time dependence structure. (iii) The result of part (iii) follows from the proofs of parts (i) and (ii). (iii) We get Vŵ n;BP S = (α n;BP Sŵn;S + (1 −α n;BP S )b) S n+1:n+m (α n;BP Sŵn;S + (1 −α n;BP S )b) =α 2 n;BP Sŵ n;S S n+1:n+mŵn;S + (1 −α n;BP S ) 2 b S n+1:n+m b + 2α n;BP S (1 −α n;BP S )ŵ n;S S n+1:n+m b =α 2 n;BP Sŵ n;S S n+1:n+mŵn;S + (1 −α n;BP S ) 2 b S n+1:n+m b + 2α n;BP S (1 −α n;BP S ) 1 Σ −1/2 V −1 n V n+1:n+m Σ 1/2 b 1 S −1 n 1 a.s. for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) and p/m →c ∈ (0, 1) as n, m → ∞ by applying Lemma 7.2, Lemma 1.3 of Bodnar et al. (2021e) , and the results from parts (i) and (ii). (iv) The result of part (iv) follows from the proofs of parts (i) and (ii). Approaching mean-variance efficiency for large portfolios Spectral Analysis of Large Dimensional Random Matrices On the sensitivity of mean-variance-efficient portfolios to changes in asset means: some analytical and computational results. The review of financial studies Recent advances in shrinkage-based highdimensional inference Testing for independence of large dimensional vectors Sampling distributions of optimal portfolio weights and characteristics in low and large dimensions HDShOP: High-Dimensional Shrinkage Optimal Portfolios Statistical inference for the expected utility portfolio in high dimensions Tests for the weights of the global minimum variance portfolio in a high-dimensional setting On the strong convergence of the optimal linear shrinkage estimator for large dimensional covariance matrix Optimal shrinkage-based portfolio selection in high dimensions Estimation of the global minimum variance portfolio in high dimensions Econometrical analysis of the sample efficient frontier Modelling the coherence in short-run nominal exchange rates: a multivariate generalized arch model The sampling error in estimates of mean-variance efficient portfolio weights High-dimensional minimum variance portfolio estimation based on high-frequency data On portfolio optimization: Forecasting covariances and choosing the risk model The effect of errors in means, variances, and covariances on optimal portfolio choice Likelihood ratio tests for many groups in high dimensions High dimensional minimum variance portfolio estimation under statistical factor models High-dimensionality effects in the markowitz problem and other quadratic programs with linear constraints: Risk underestimation A Signal Processing Perspective on Financial Engineering Dominating estimators for minimum-variance portfolios Risk reduction in large portfolios: Why imposing the wrong constraints helps The distribution of the sample minimum-variance frontier Doubly constrained robust capon beamformer Portfolio selection Portfolio selection: efficient diversification of investments An analytic derivation of the efficient portfolio frontier On estimating the expected return on the market: An exploratory investigation Finite sample size effect on MV beamformers: optimum diagonal loading factor for large arrays Distributional properties of portfolio weights Spectral convergence for a general class of random matrices Performance analysis and optimal selection of large minimum variance portfolios under estimation risk Optimum Array Processing Multiuser Detection High-dimensional MVDR beamforming: Optimized solutions based on spiked random matrix models Improved calibration of highdimensional precision matrices Proof of Theorem 2.1. (i) It holds that Vŵ n;S =ŵ n;S Σŵ n;S = 1 S −1 n ΣS −1 n 1 (1 S −1 n 1) 2 ,where (see, proof of Lemma 1.3 in Bodnar et al. (2021e) )a.s.for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) as n → ∞. Combining these two results we get the first statement of the theorem.(ii) It holds that Vŵ n;BP S = (α n;BP Sŵn;S + (1 −α n;BP S )b) Σ (α n;BP Sŵn;S + (1 −α n;BP S )b) =α 2 n;BP Sŵ n;S Σŵ n;S + 2α n;BP S (1 −α n;BP S )ŵ n;S Σb + (1 −α n;BP S ) 2 b Σb,where from part (i)Moreover, we get (see, Theorem 2.1 in Bodnar et al. (2018) )for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) as n → ∞. Putting these results together we get the statement of Theorem 2.1.(ii).Proof of Theorem 2.2. The results of Theorem 2.2 follows from Theorem 2.1 and the definition of the relative loss.In the proofs of Theorems 3.1 and 3.2 we use the results of two technical lemmas presented below. Let V 1:n = 1 n X 1:n X 1:n with X 1:n = (x 1 , ..., x n ),and define V 1:n = 1 n − 1 X 1:n X 1:n − n n − 1x 1:nx 1:n withx 1:n = 1 n X 1:n 1 n andThen, we haveLemma 7.1. Let ξ and θ be two nonrandom vectors with bounded Euclidean norms. Assume that m, n > 1. Then it holds thatfor p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) and p/m →c ∈ (0, ∞) as n → ∞.Proof of Lemma 7.1. It holds thatfor p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) as n → ∞ by applying Lemma 1.3 in Bodnar et al. (2021e) . Furthermore, using the equalityx j V −1 n θξ V −1 n x j and the fact that V −1 n θξ V −1 n possesses the bounded trace norm which is asymptotically bounded by θ V −2 n θ ξ V −2 n ξ, the application of Lemma 4 in Rubio and Mestre (2011) leads tofor p/m →c ∈ (0, ∞) as m → ∞ for any large enough n. The second statement (7.3) can similarly be proved. This completes the proof of the lemma.Lemma 7.2. Let ξ and θ be two nonrandom vectors with bounded Euclidean norms. Assume that m, n > 1. Then it holds that (7.5) for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) and p/m →c ∈ (0, ∞) as n, m → ∞.Proof of Lemma 7.2. The application of the Sherman-Morrison formula leads toBy definition √ mx n+1:n+m consists of elements with are independent and identically distributed with zero mean and variance equal one. Then, conditionally on X 1:n it holds that (see, Theorem in Dette and Dörnemann (2020) Proof of Theorem 3.1. (i) We get with (7.1) that Vŵ n;S ;m =ŵ n;S S n+1:n+mŵn;S = 1 S −1 n S n+1:n+m S −1 n 1 (1 S −1 n 1) 2 = 1 Σ −1/2 V −1 n V n+1:n+m V −1 n Σ −1/2 1 (1 Σ −1/2 V −1 n Σ −1/2 1) 2 a.s. (1 − c) −3 1 Σ −1 1 (1 − c) −2 (1 Σ −1 1) 2 = (1 − c) −1 V GM V for p/n → c ∈ (0, 1) and p/m →c ∈ (0, ∞) as n, m → ∞ by using Lemma 7.2 and Lemma 1.3 in Bodnar et al. (2021e) .(ii) The result of part (ii) follows from the proof of Theorem 3.2 of Bodnar et al. (2014) .