key: cord-0738295-er9mbu9x authors: Kollmann, Robert title: Effects of Covid-19 on Euro area GDP and inflation: demand vs. supply disturbances date: 2021-09-28 journal: Int Econ Econ Policy DOI: 10.1007/s10368-021-00516-3 sha: f17d5002f8b04fdb9e512b12ff87d1a8889626d9 doc_id: 738295 cord_uid: er9mbu9x This paper analyzes the macroeconomic effects of the Covid-19 epidemic on Euro Area (EA) GDP and inflation, using a stylized New Keynesian model. Covid is interpreted as a combination of aggregate demand and aggregate supply disturbances. Offsetting aggregate demand and supply changes are shown to account for the stability of EA inflation, in the face of Covid. The evidence presented here indicates that Covid-induced aggregate demand and supply shifts were persistent. An aggregate supply contraction is identified as the dominant force driving the sharp fall of EA GDP in 2020. The global Covid-19 health crisis that erupted in early 2020 has triggered a sharp contraction in worldwide real activity. This paper studies the response of Euro Area (EA) GDP and inflation to the Covid crisis. The Covid epidemic is a very large and truly unexpected and exogenous disturbance. This distinguishes Covid from standard macro shocks in "normal" times. Due to its huge size, the Covid shock is likely to have dominated other macroeconomic disturbances in 2020-2021. Thus it is plausible that macroeconomic developments, in 2020-2021, were mainly caused by Covid. Covid thus provides a unique laboratory for analyzing the determination of real activity and prices in the face of a large exogenous disturbance. Understanding the transmission of exogenous disturbances is, e.g., important for designing effective policy responses. A vast (and growing) literature has analyzed the economic repercussions of Covid. 1 Early studies on the macroeconomic effects of Covid include Eichenbaum et al. (2020) who incorporated an epidemiological model into a Real Business Cycle framework; and Guerrieri et al. (2020) and Pfeiffer et al. (2020) who considered New-Keynesian models. The contribution of the present paper is to provide simple analytics of the macroeconomic transmission of Covid, using a stylized New Keynesian model. An important feature of the analysis here is that it compares the adjustment to the Covid shock in a liquidity trap, i.e. a situation in which the zero lower bound (ZLB) constraint for the nominal interest rate binds, to adjustment when the ZLB constraint does not bind. The framework is used to assess the relative role of aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) shifts, during Covid. The use of a liquidity trap model is motivated by the fact that Covid hit the EA (and other advanced economies) in a situation of persistently ultra-low interest rates. With monetary policy interest rates at the zero lower bound (ZLB), the central bank cannot stimulate real activity by lowering the policy interest rate. 2 AS shifts are modeled as total factor productivity (TFP) shocks, while AD shifts are modeled as shocks to the household subjective discount rate. As documented below, Covid induced a reduction of EA GDP of about 7.8% in 2020, but Covid only had a negligible effect on inflation. The model suggests that the macroeconomic situation under Covid must be interpreted as the outcome of joint AD and AS shocks, whose offsetting effects stabilized inflation. The muted response of inflation indicates that Covid did not affect the output gap, so that the Covid-induced contraction of GDP corresponds to the contraction that would have obtained in a flex-price economy. The model suggests that Covid amounted to a 7.8% drop in EA TFP during 2020; this AS disturbance was accompanied by a fall in the subjective rate of time preference, that stabilized the natural real interest rate. The size of the concomitant model-inferred AD and AS shocks that reproduce the actual GDP contraction of 2020, at an unchanged inflation rate, is invariant to the persistence of these shocks, and to other model parameters. However, the model-inferred relative contribution of AD vs. AS shocks to the GDP contraction, in a liquidity trap, is sensitive to the assumed shock persistence. When the Covid-induced AD and AS shifts are assumed very transient, the liquidity trap model attributes the Covid GDP contraction to a fall in AD (low household demand). However, the (predicted) slow recovery of EA output in 2021 indicates that the adverse AD and AS shifts induced by Covid are persistent (annual autocorrelation: 0.6). Under realistic shock persistence, the liquidity trap model attributes the Covid output contraction in 2020 to the negative effect of Covid on AS. However, AS and AD shifts mattered equally for the observed stability of inflation. In a liquidity trap, persistent negative AS shifts lower inflation, while persistent adverse AD shifts raise inflation. If Covid had solely affected AS, the EA would thus have experienced a sharp fall in inflation and a contraction in GDP that would have been deeper than the actual contraction, according to the liquidity trap model; that model suggests that the contraction in AD had a stabilizing effect on EA GDP during the Covid crisis. Interestingly, a model version that abstracts from the ZLB constraint (and assumes that the central bank sets the policy rate according to a Taylor rule) produces the same estimates of the Covid-induced AD and AS shifts, as the liquidity trap model. In that no-liquidity-trap model version, the Covid output contraction is unambiguously interpreted as an AS shift (irrespective of shock persistence). However, a model version without ZLB constraint predicts that if Covid had solely affected AS, the EA would have experienced a sharp rise in inflation and a contraction in GDP that would have been smaller than the actual contraction. Section 2 presents empirical evidence on the EA macroeconomy during Covid. Section 3 presents the model. Section 4 interprets the EA macroeconomy during Covid through the lens of the model. Section 5 concludes. (7)) are very small, but the forecast errors for 2020 variables (Col. (8) ) are substantial, and so are the forecast revisions for 2021 variables (Col. (9)). I interpret the forecast errors for 2020 variables, and the forecast revisions for 2021 variables, as (largely) reflecting the effect of Covid. Due to its large size and unexpected nature, the Covid shock is likely to have swamped the effect of other unexpected disturbances in 2020 (as argued above). In November 2019 the European Commission predicted EA GDP (Y) and private consumption (C) growth rates (year-on-year, y-o-y) and inflation (π) for 2020 of 1.2%, 1.2% and 1.5%, respectively (see Col. (2), Table 1 ). Actual 2020 growth rates/inflation were − 6.6%, − 8.0% and 1.5%, respectively (Col. (6)). Thus the realized growth rates of EA GDP and consumption in 2020 were 7.8 and 9.2 percentage points (ppt) below predicted values (Col. (8)). By contrast, realized EA inflation in 2020 equaled predicted inflation. Between the November 2019 and May 2021 forecasts, we note a + 3.1% revision of y-o-y predicted GDP growth for 2021 (Col. (9)). That forecast revision amounts to a − 4.7% revision in the predicted level of 2021 GDP. 5 Thus, Covid is predicted to have a persistent negative effect on the level of future GDP. By contrast, we notice only a very small revision in predicted 2021 inflation: − 0.3% (Col. (9)). These are the key empirical observations that the theoretical model below will address. In summary: Covid triggered a sharp contraction of GDP that is predicted to be persistent; by contrast, Covid did not change inflation in 2020, and its effect on predicted 2021 inflation is very muted. Table 1 also reports predicted and actual growth rates of EA government consumption (G), investment (I), employment (L) and of labor productivity 5 The level of 2021 GDP predicted in the May 2021 EC forecast falls short by 4.7 ppt of the GDP level that would have obtained if the 2020 and 2021 growth rates predicted in Nov. 2010 had actually materialized: (− 6.6% + 4.3%) − (1.2% + 1.2%) = − 4.7%. (Y/L) in 2020 and 2021; also shown is the actual and predicted (merchandise) trade balance/GDP ratio (NX/Y). Covid only had a very small effect on EA government consumption in 2020 (− 0.2%), it depressed 2020 investment by 10.2%, and it led to a slight trade balance improvement, + 0.6 ppt (see Col. (8)). Thus, Covid had a combined effect on EA government consumption and the trade balance that is negligible compared to the large GDP contraction. The theoretical model discussed below will abstract from government consumption and foreign trade (a closed economy will be considered). The Covid-induced contraction of investment in 2020 was roughly of the same proportion as the change in private consumption (-9.2%); as the EA consumption/GDP ratio (about 55%) is much higher than the investment/GDP ratio (20%), the collapse in EA private consumption accounts for the bulk of the fall in EA GDP, in 2020. For analytical tractability, the theoretical model will abstract from physical capital and investment. A standard New Keynesian model is considered (e.g., Kollmann 2001a Kollmann ,b, 2002 Kollmann , 2004 Kollmann , 2005 Kollmann , 2008 . The model assumes a closed economy with: a representative household; a central bank; monopolistic competitors that produce a continuum of intermediate goods indexed by s ∈ [0,1] using labor; competitive firms that bundle intermediates into a homogeneous final good. The household consumes the final good, supplies labor and owns all firms. The central bank sets the short-term nominal interest rate. Intermediate goods prices are sticky; all other prices and the wage rate are flexible. The labor market is competitive. The intertemporal preferences of the representative household are described by where C t and L t are final consumption and aggregate hours worked at date t. 0 < < 1 is the household's steady state subjective discount factor and > 0 is the Frisch labor supply elasticity. Ψ t > 0 is a stationary exogenous preference shock that alters the household's rate of time preference. The household equates the marginal rate of substitution between leisure and consumption to the real wage rate, which implies. There is a market for a one-period riskless nominal bond (in zero net supply). The nominal interest rate on that bond is r t between periods t and t + 1. The gross nominal rate is denoted R t ≡ 1 + r t . The household's Euler equation for this bond is: where Π t+1 ≡ P t+1 ∕P t is the gross inflation rate between t and t + 1. If Ψ t follows a stationary AR(1) process, as assumed below, then a positive shock to the date t preference shifter Ψ t lowers the expected subjective discount factor E t Ψ t+1 ∕Ψ t between dates t and t + 1, and thus the shock raises the household's subjective discount rate. In what follows, I will hence refer to the preference shock Ψ t as a (subjective) discount rate shock. A rise in Ψ t can be interpreted as a positive aggregate demand shock as, for a given real interest rate, it boosts desired current consumption (by inducing the household to substitute future consumption by current consumption). The final good is produced using the technology where L t (s) is the labor input at date t, while t > 0 is an exogenous stochastic productivity parameter (identical for all intermediate good producers). t is an aggregate supply shock. Intermediate good producers face quadratic price adjustment costs. The real profit, in units of final output, of the firm that produces intermediate good s is: where W t is the nominal wage rate. The last term in this equation is the real price adjustment cost, where Π is the steady state gross inflation rate. At date t, the firm sets p t (s) to maximizes the present value of profits E t ∑ ∞ =0 t,t+ t+ (s) , where t,t+ is the household's intertemporal marginal rate of substitution in consumption between periods t and t + . All intermediate good firms face identical decision problems, and they produce identical quantities and set identical prices: p t (s) = P t ∀ s ∈ [0, 1]. The central bank sets the nominal interest rate r t , subject to the zero lower bound (ZLB) constraint r t ≥ 0, i.e. R t ≥ 1. L t = ∫ 1 s=0 L t (s)ds. Final good mar- ket clearing requires C t = Y t , where Y t = t L t is GDP. I linearize all model equations around a deterministic steady state. Let x t ≡ (x t − x)∕x denote the relative deviation of a variable x t from its steady state value x ≠ 0 (variables without time subscript denote steady state values). Using the market clearing condition C t = Y t , the linearised Euler Eq. (2) can be written as: Linearizing the first-order condition of the intermediate good firms' decision problem gives a standard 'forward-looking' Phillips equation: where mc t = (W t ∕ t )∕P t is real marginal cost (deflated by the final good price) in the intermediate good sector (e.g., Kollmann 2002) . w > 0 is a coefficient that is a decreasing function of the price adjustment cost parameter . Using the nominal wage implied by the labor supply Eq. (1), and the conditions C t = Y t and Y t = t L t , one can express real marginal costs as mc t = (Y t ∕ t ) 1+1∕ , which implies In a flex-price economy ( w = ∞), real marginal cost would be constant. Thus, denotes GDP under flexible prices. Define the output gap ẑ t as the deviation of GDP from its flex-price level: Using this definition, the Phillips curve (4) can be expressed as: while the Euler Eq. (3) can be written aŝ R nat t is the risk-free gross real interest rate between dates t and t + 1 (expressed in deviation from the steady state gross rate) that would obtain under flexible prices. I refer to R nat t as the natural real interest rate. ( The Phillips curve (7) implies that the output gap is a function of current and expected future inflation: ẑ t = 1 {Π t − E tΠt+1 }. Substituting this expression into the Euler Eq. (8) gives: I refer to (9) as the 'Euler-Phillips' equation. Assume that TFP and the discount rate shock follow stationary univariate AR(1) processes with autocorrelations 0 ≤ < 1 and 0 ≤ Ψ < 1 , respectively: where t+1 , Ψ t+1 are mean-zero innovations. Then, the natural real interest rate is given by Thus, the natural real interest rate is a decreasing function of TFP and an increasing function of the discount rate shock. Note that 0 ≤ < 1 implies that a positive shock to TFP lowers the expected future growth rate of TFP. In a flex-price economy, this entails a fall in the expected future growth rate of GDP and consumption, which lowers the natural real interest rate. Similar logic explains why a positive shock to the subjective discount rate between dates t and t + 1 raises the natural real interest rate between t and t + 1. This paper focuses on equilibria that obtain when the ZLB binds permanently, i.e. R t = 1 ∀t. A liquidity trap can, for example, arise when the central bank follows a Taylor-style interest rate rule. Then pessimistic household expectations about future inflation and GDP can push the nominal interest rate to the ZLB (Benhabib et al. 2001a,b; Kollmann 2021a,b) . The assumption of a permanent liquidity trap is solely made for analytical convenience. Kollmann (2021a,b) studies equilibria with self-fulfilling (expectations-driven) equilibria in which, in each period, the economy can escape from the liquidity trap with positive probability. When the escape probability from a liquidity trap is sufficiently small (i.e. when the liquidity trap is expected to last long), shock transmission is very similar to transmission in a permanent liquidity trap (Kollmann 2021a,b) . The motivation for analyzing the effect of Covid using a model with a liquidity trap is that Covid hit the EA (and other advanced economies) in an environment of persistently ultra-low interest rates. The European Central Bank's (ECB) policy rate has been at (or very close to) the ZLB since November 2013; a departure from this low-interest rate policy does not seem to be on the agenda of ECB decision makers, as of this writing. In normal times, the ECB would be able to counteract adverse shocks by cutting the policy interest rate. This is not possible, in a liquidity trap. 6 In a permanent liquidity trap, R t = 0 holds. 7 The Euler-Phillips Eq. (9) then becomes 0 < β < 1 and κ > 0 imply that one of the characteristics roots of this expectational difference is strictly larger than unity, while the other root is smaller than unity. This implies that Eq. (11) has multiple non-explosive solutions (Blanchard and Kahn 1980) . Following the liquidity trap models of Mertens and Ravn (2014) It can readily be seen that Γ(x) < 0 holds for 0 ≤ x < * , and Γ(x) > 0 for * < x ≤ 1, where 0 < * < 1 is a root of the polynomial Γ(x) , i.e. Γ( * ) = 0. 8 Thus, Kabaca et al. (2020) and Altavilla et al. (2021) show that unconventional ECB policies have, to some extent, acted as a substitute for conventional interest rate policy, during the period of ultra-low policy rates. Wu and Zhang (2019) show that the effect of US QE can be captured with a 'shadow' federal funds rate that is not constrained by the ZLB, and that follows a Taylor-type rule. Explicitly modeling unconventional monetary policy is beyond the scope of the simple framework used in the paper here. However, below I consider a model variant in which the nominal interest rate is not constrained by the ZLB to address the possibility that unconventional monetary policies acted as a substitute for conventional interest rate policy, during the Covid crisis. 7 In an equilibrium with a permanent liquidity trap, R = 1 holds in steady state. Linearization around the liquidity trap steady state thus implies R t = 0 t. This shows that a (sufficiently) transitory rise in TFP lowers inflation in a liquidity trap, while a persistent positive TFP shock raises inflation. A transitory positive discount rate shock raises inflation, while a transitory positive discount rate shock lowers inflation. For intuition about the role of shock persistence for the response of inflation in a liquidity trap, consider the case where the autocorrelation of shocks is close to unity. Then Π t ≈ E tΠt+1 ≈ E tΠt+2 , so that the Euler-Phillips Eq. (11) implies that Π t ≈ −R nat t , i.e. a fall in the natural real interest rate raises inflation. This explains why a persistent rise in TFP (that depresses the natural real interest rate; see (10)) triggers an increase in inflation. Similar logic explains why a persistent positive taste shock (that raises the natural rate) lowers inflation. Conversely, when shocks are i.i.d., then a date t shocks does not affect expected future inflation, and the Euler-Phillips Eq. (11) implies Π t = R nat t . Therefore, a purely transitory rise in TFP lowers inflation, while a transitory positive discount rate shock raises inflation. Expected future inflation is As the output gap is given by ẑ t = 1 {Π t − E tΠt+1 }, we find (from (12), (16)) that Therefore, a persistent positive TFP shocks raises the output gap, while a transitory TFP increase lowers the output gap. Conversely, a persistent positive discount rate shocks lowers the output gap, while a transitory positive discount rate shock raises the output gap. Note that GDP is given by Ŷ t =ẑ t +Ŷ Flex t (see (6)). Thus, (17) implies A persistent TFP increase (with > * so that > 0) always raises GDP; a transitory TFP increase (with < * ) lowers GDP if prices are sufficiently sticky, i.e. when the slope of the Phillips curve κ is small. A persistent positive discount rate shock lowers GDP, while a transitory positive discount rate shock raises GDP. 9 (15) < 0, > 0 holds for , < * ; and > 0, < 0 holds for , > * . It is interesting to compare shock transmission in the liquidity trap to transmission when the ZLB constraint does not bind, so that the central bank can adjust the policy rate, in response to disturbances. This Section abstracts from the ZLB and assumes that the central bank sets the short-term interest rate as a function of the inflation rate, according to a Taylor rule: where the parameter γ captures the response of the policy rate to inflation. The 'Taylor principle' is assumed to hold (γ > 1): a 1% rise in gross inflation triggers a rise in the gross policy rate by more than 1%. When the monetary policy rule (19) applies, the Euler-Phillips Eq. (9) becomes. The Taylor principle γ > 1 ensures that both characteristic roots of (20) are larger than unity (in absolute value), which ensures that (20) has a unique non-explosive solution of the form where and Ψ can readily be determined using the method of undetermined coefficients: γ > 1 implies that − + Γ(x) < 0 holds ∀ 0 ≤ x ≤ 1. Thus, < 0 and Ψ > 0. GDP is now given by: Away from the ZLB, a positive TFP shock lowers inflation, irrespective of the persistence of the shock; the shock raises GDP when the inflation coefficient of the Taylor rule γ is sufficiently large (which ensures that < 0 is sufficiently small in absolute value, so that the coefficient of TFP in (23) is positive). Away from the ZLB, a positive discount rate shock raises inflation and GDP irrespective of shock persistence (provided γ > 1). This Section discusses model calibration, presents simulated shock responses, and interprets the adjustment of the EA economy to Covid in 2020-2021 through the lens of the model. (23) As the data in Table 1 are annual, I use an annual model calibration. 10 Covid was an unexpected event in 2020 that triggered persistent shifts in TFP and household preferences. I label the year 2020 as t = 0. Let dx t denote the Covid-induced deviation of a variable x t from its no-Covid trajectory in period t ≥ 0. From (7), dΠ t = ⋅ dẑ t + E t dΠ t+1 for t ≥ 0. As documented above, Covid had zero effect on EA inflation in 2020, and a negligible effect on predicted inflation in 2021. Because of the muted effect of Covid on EA inflation, the model infers that the shock had (essentially) zero effect on the output gap: dẑ 0 = 0. This implies that dŶ 0 = dŶ Flex 0 = d̂ 0 . The model thus infers that, in the EA, the Covid event of 2020 amounted to a negative TFP shock: d � 0 < 0. From the model solution for inflation, in a liquidity trap (see (12), (13)), we see that dΠ 0 = E 0 dΠ 1 = 0 imply: and Clearly, (24) and (25) imply and Because of the muted effect of Covid on actual inflation in 2020 and on predicted inflation in 2021, the model infers that the aggregate supply (TFP) and aggregate demand (discount rate) shifts in 2020 induced by Covid had exactly offsetting effects on inflation, and that these shifts had the same persistence (autocorrelation). The common autocorrelation of both forcing variables will be denoted by ≡ = Ψ . The subsequent analysis will be based on (26) and (27). It is straightforward to see 10 Quarterly data show that the EA GDP contraction was strongest in 2020q1 (− 3.8% quarter on quarter, q-o-q, change) and 2020q2 (-11.6%); this was followed by a rebound in 2002q3 (+ 12.5% q-o-q), but there was a further GDP contraction in 2002q4 (− 0.7%) due to the second wave of the epidemic in the autumn-winter 2020-21. The q-o-q changes of the EA GDP deflator were 0.5%, 1.0%, − 1.1% and 0.9%, respectively in 2020q1-q4. These q-o-q inflation changes suggest that, at the quarterly frequency, aggregate demand and aggregate supply changes were not perfectly synchronized, by contrast to the perfect correlation between AD and AS shifts at the annual frequency (see below). However, the key stylized fact driving the results of the paper, namely that inflation changes were more muted than the massive GDP changes during Covid, also holds in quarterly data. For simplicity, the paper focuses on annual data and an annual model calibration. A quarterly model would need to address that the second wave of the epidemic was possibly anticipated by households-this might require specifying a richer time series model of the Covid shocks than the simple AR(1) processes assumed in the annual calibration. (from (21, 22)) that (26) and (27) are also implied by the model variant without ZLB constraint. 11 The notion that EA firms suffered "technological" regress during Covid may seem debatable. The negative effect of Covid on aggregate supply can also reflect partial or complete government-ordered firm shutdowns (to slow the spread of the virus), or a reduction in household labor supply (as workers fear infection while commuting to work or interacting in-person with co-workers and customers). The latter may be captured by replacing the household's period utility by ln(C t ) − 1 1+1∕ (L t ∕Ξ t ) 1+1∕ , where Ξ t > 0 is an exogenous shock. Note that a fall in Ξ t raises the disutility of labor. It is straightforward to see that a 1% fall in Ξ t and a 1% fall in TFP t have identical effects on inflation and GDP. The analysis of the role of TFP shocks for the EA macroeconomy during Covid can thus be rephrased in terms of labor supply shifts induced by Covid. Given the contraction of EA GDP by 7.8% in 2020, the model-inferred estimate of Covid-induced TFP and preference shifts in t = 0 is (from (18), (26), (27)): When (27) holds, then the autocorrelation of GDP is ≡ = Ψ as can be seen from (18). The autocorrelation of GDP responses to Covid thus allows to obtain an estimate of the persistence of the Covid-induced aggregate supply and demand shifts. As discussed in Sect. 2, Covid triggered a − 4.7% revision in the predicted level of 2021 GDP, i.e. Covid is predicted to have a persistent negative effect on the level of future GDP. The ratio of the predicted 2021 GDP contraction to the 2020 GDP contraction is 0.6 (= (−4.7%)∕(−7.8%)). This suggests that the annual autocorrelation of the Covid-induced shift GDP is ρ = 0.6. The baseline model calibration below thus sets ρ = 0.6. Note that the estimated GDP autocorrelation ρ = 0.6 due to Covid is in the same range, but slightly smaller, than the autocorrelation of (detrended) EA GDP in pre-Covid times. The autocorrelation of detrended log EA GDP (annual) before Covid (1999-2019) is roughly 0.65. 12 The other model parameters are set at values that are standard in annual macro models. I assume = 0.99, which implies a 1% per annum steady state riskless real interest rate. The Frisch labor supply elasticity is set at unity, = 1, a conventional value in macro models. The slope coefficient of the Phillips curve (7) is calibrated by exploiting the observational equivalence between the linearized Phillips curve d̂ 0 = dΨ 0 = −7.8%. 12 The autocorrelations of linearly detrended, quadratically detrended and HP filtered logged real annual GDP (1999-2019) are 0.67, 0.65 and 0.63, respectively. under price adjustment costs assumed here (see (4)) and the Phillips curve implied by Calvo-type (Calvo 1983 ) staggered price setting. Empirical evidence, based on quarterly data for the EA, suggests that Calvo-equivalent price stickiness is about 4 quarters, i.e. the estimated probability that a firm does not re-optimize its price in a given quarter is about 0.75 (Kollmann 2001a; Giovannini et al. 2019) . Based on this evidence, I set the Phillips curve slope at κ = 2.9674, in the present calibration to annual frequency. 13 13 Under Calvo price setting, the slope of the Phillips curve (4) is w = (1 − D)(1 − D)∕D, where D is the probability that an individual firm keeps its price unchanged in a given period. As estimates based on quarterly data suggest D = 0.75, I set the probability of non-price adjustment at (0.75) 4 , in the annual model calibration here. This implies w = 1.48373. The assumed labor supply elasticity (η= 1) then entails ≡ w (1 + )∕ = 2.9674. Table 2 Model-predicted impact responses to 1% TFP (θ) and preference ( Cols. (2, 3): less persistent shocks (ρ = 0.1) and more persistent shocks (ρ = 0.9), respectively, than in baseline (same price stickiness as in baseline). Cols. (4, 5): prices less sticky (2-quarter Calvo-equivalent) and more sticky (8-quarter Calvo-equivalent), respectively, than in baseline (same shock autocorrelation as in baseline) (19) is set at the conventional value = 1.5. Column 1 of Table 2 shows shock responses under the baseline calibration (shock persistence ρ = 0.6, 4-quarter Calvo-equivalent price stickiness). Col. (2) assumes less persistent shocks, ρ = 0.1, while Col. (3) assumes more persistent shocks, ρ = 0.9 (Cols. (2), (3) assume baseline price stickiness). Col. (4) lowers the Calvoequivalent price stickiness to two quarters, and Col. (5) sets the Calvo-equivalent price stickiness at 8 quarters (while assuming ρ = 0.6). Away from the ZLB, a Taylor-style monetary policy rule entails that the central bank cuts the policy rate, in response to a positive TFP shock, and that it raises the policy rate in response to a positive discount rate shock (see Panel (b), Table 2 ). Away from the ZLB, a positive TFP shock lowers inflation, while a positive discount rate shock raises inflation. In all 5 model variants, the Taylor-rule-based monetary policy (away from the ZLB) delivers GDP responses to TFP shocks that are positive, but smaller than the shock response under flexible prices; the GDP response to a positive discount rate shock is positive, but weak. In fact, predicted shock responses are close to the response under flexible prices, except when the shock is very transient (Col. (2)), or prices are very sticky (Col. (5)). (Nota bene: under flexible prices, a 1% TFP increase raises GDP by 1%, and a discount rate shock has zero effect on GDP.) In the liquidity trap, the interest rate cannot adjust to shocks (Panel (a), Table 2 ). Under the baseline Phillips curve slope κ, the critical value for the shock autocorrelation * (that is decisive for the sign of the inflation response to shocks) is * = 0.215 (see (14), (15)). The baseline shock autocorrelation ρ = 0.6 thus exceeds the critical persistence * . Under the baseline calibration (Col. (1)), the model predicts hence that, in the liquidity trap, a positive TFP shock raises inflation and the GDP gap, while a positive discount rate shock lowers inflation and the GDP gap. However, quantitatively, the response of GDP, in the baseline liquidity trap model variant, is relatively similar to the flex-price GDP response: GDP rises by 1.1% in response to the TFP shock, and GDP falls by 0.1% in response to the discount rate shock; these responses are close to the 1% and 0% responses under flexible prices. The intuition for this is that persistent shocks (as assumed in the baseline calibration) have a muted effect on the natural real interest rate; those shocks thus have a relatively weak effect on inflation, and hence their effect on GDP is close to the flex-price response. This logic explains why, when shocks are more persistent than in the baseline specification (see Col. (3) where ρ = 0.9 is assumed), then shock responses are even closer to the flex-price responses. As might be expected, the model variant with lower price stickiness too generates GDP responses (in the liquidity trap) that are close to the flex-price responses (see Col. (4)). By contrast, the GDP response to shocks is magnified --and it thus differs more from the flex-price response --when greater price stickiness is assumed (Col. (5)). 14 The model variant with less persistent shocks (see Col. (2) where ρ = 0.1 is assumed) is the only model variant in Table 2 that deliver qualitatively different inflation and GDP responses than the baseline calibration. This is so because < * holds in Col. (2). In the liquidity trap, a transient TFP increase (ρ = 0.1) lowers inflation and GDP, while a transient positive discount rate shock gives a big boost to inflation and GDP. Remarkably, the size of the concomitant model-inferred AD and AS shocks d̂ 0 = dΨ 0 = −7.8% that reproduce the 7.8% Covid-induced GDP contraction of 2020, at an unchanged inflation rate, is invariant to shock persistence or to other model parameters; it is furthermore common to the liquidity trap model and to the "no ZLB" model variant (in which monetary policy follows a Taylor rule). 15 However, the model-inferred relative contribution of Covid-induced TFP and discount rate changes to the GDP contraction, differs across model variants. In all model variants without ZLB constraint, the output contraction is largely attributed to the TFP shock. Away from the ZLB, the adverse Covid-induced discount factor shock contributes to the fall in GDP, but its influence on GDP is weak. The model variants without ZLB constraint predict that if Covid had solely affected aggregate supply, the EA would have experienced a sharp rise in inflation and a contraction in GDP that would have been smaller than the actual contraction. In the baseline liquidity trap model, the Covid-induced GDP change too is largely driven by the TFP shock; the simultaneous discount rate shock counterbalances the TFP-induced GDP change, but again the effect of the discount rate shock on GDP is weak. The role of the TFP shock is especially strong when prices are very sticky (Col. (5)). The only liquidity trap model variant in which the GDP change is dominated by the discount rate shock is the variant with very transitory shocks; see Col. (2) in Table 2 . The simulations in Table 2 indicate thus that, for empirically plausible persistence of the Covid-induced AD and AS shifts, the effect of the AS shifts on GDP dominates clearly, in a liquidity trap. The analysis here suggests, hence, that the Covid-induced GDP contraction was largely due to the adverse effect of Covid on aggregate supply. However, aggregate supply and demand shifts both mattered equally for the observed stability of inflation under Covid. In a liquidity trap, persistent adverse AS shifts tend to lower inflation, while adverse demand shifts raise inflation. The liquidity trap model predicts that, if Covid had solely affected aggregate supply, the EA would have experienced a sharp fall in inflation and a contraction in GDP that would have been deeper than the actual contraction; the contraction in aggregate demand thus had a partially stabilizing effect on EA GDP, during Covid. This paper has analyzed the macroeconomic effects of the Covid-19 epidemic on Euro Area (EA) GDP and inflation, using a stylized New Keynesian model. Offsetting aggregate demand and supply changes are shown to account for the stability of EA inflation, in the face of Covid. The evidence presented here indicates that Covidinduced aggregate demand and supply shifts were persistent. An aggregate supply contraction is identified as the dominant force driving the sharp fall of EA GDP in 2020. Is there a zero lower bound? The effects of negativity policy rates on banks and firms Learning to live in a liquidity trap Macroeconomic dynamics near the ZLB: a tale of two countries The perils of Taylor rules Monetary policy and multiple equilibria The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework Temporary VAT reduction during the lockdown. Working Paper, DIW Berlin de Beauffort C (2021) Government debt and expectations-driven liquidity traps European Commission (2019) European Economic Forecast-Autumn European Economic Forecast-Spring 2021 The scars of supply shocks Euro area and U.S. external adjustment: the role of commodity prices and emerging market shocks Macroeconomic implications of COVID-19: can negative supply shocks cause demand shortages? Working Paper The macroeconomic effects of quantitative easing in the euro area: evidence from an estimated DSGE model Staff Working Paper 2020-49, Bank of Canada Kollmann R (2001a) The exchange rate in a dynamic-optimizing business cycle model with nominal rigidities: a quantitative investigation Explaining international comovements of output and asset returns: the role of money and nominal rigidities Monetary policy rules in the open economy: effects on welfare and business cycles Welfare effects of a monetary union Macroeconomic effects of nominal exchange rate regimes: new insights into the role of rice dynamics Welfare maximizing operational monetary and tax policy rules Liquidity traps in a monetary union. Forthcoming Liquidity traps in a world economy Fiscal policy in an expectations-driven liquidity trap The Covid19-Pandemic in the EU: Macroeconomic Transmission and Economic Policy Response. Working Paper, European Commission Roeger W (2015) The Fiscal multiplier and the duration of the ZLB constraint. Working Paper, European Commission Wu C, Zhang J (2019) A shadow rate New Keynesian Model Publisher's note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations Acknowledgements I thank Romanos Priftis (discussant) and Werner Roeger for very helpful comments and suggestions.Author contributions I am the sole author of this paper.Funding Not Applicable (NA). Conflict of interest NA.