key: cord-0902198-bchwql9p authors: Tildesley, M.; Vassall, A.; Riley, S.; Jit, M.; Sandmann, F.; Hill, E. M.; Thompson, R.; Atkins, B.; Edmunds, J.; Dyson, L. M.; Keeling, M. J. title: Optimal health and economic impact of non-pharmaceutical intervention measures prior and post vaccination in England: a mathematical modelling study date: 2021-04-25 journal: nan DOI: 10.1101/2021.04.22.21255949 sha: f91ce3874bb3cf46eeec806effee5b6b580f9454 doc_id: 902198 cord_uid: bchwql9p Background Even with good progress on vaccination, SARS-CoV-2 infections in the UK may continue to impose a high burden of disease and therefore pose substantial challenges for health policy decision makers. Stringent government-mandated physical distancing measures (lockdown) have been demonstrated to be epidemiologically effective, but can have both positive and negative economic consequences. The duration and frequency of any intervention policy could, in theory, could be optimised to maximise economic benefits while achieving substantial reductions in disease. Methods Here we use a pre-existing SARS-CoV-2 transmission model to assess the health and economic implications of different strengths of control through time in order to identify optimal approaches to non-pharmaceutical intervention stringency in the UK, considering the role of vaccination in reducing the need for future physical distancing measures. The model is calibrated to the COVID-19 epidemic in England and we carry out retrospective analysis of the optimal timing of precautionary breaks in 2020 and the optimal relaxation policy from the January 2021 lockdown, considering the willingness to pay for health improvement. Results We find that the precise timing and intensity of interventions is highly dependent upon the objective of control. As intervention measures are relaxed, we predict a resurgence in cases, but the optimal intervention policy can be established dependent upon the willingness to pay (WTP) per QALY loss avoided. Our results show that establishing an optimal level of control can result in a reduction in net monetary loss of billions of pounds, dependent upon the precise WTP value. Conclusions It is vital, as the UK emerges from lockdown, but continues to face an on-going pandemic, to accurately establish the overall health and economic costs when making policy decisions. We demonstrate how some of these can be quantified, employing mechanistic infectious disease transmission models to establish optimal levels of control for the ongoing COVID-19 pandemic. In late 2019, the first cases of an unknown respiratory infection began to emerge in the city of Wuhan, 2 in Hubei province, China [1, 2] . In order to attempt to control the spread of the virus, countries around 3 the world introduced a range of measures, including mandatory physical distancing, wearing of face 4 coverings, restrictions on large gatherings and, in situations where case numbers were increasing in an 5 uncontrolled manner, regional or nationwide policies that have included closure of schools, restrictions 6 on travel and in extreme cases, stay at home orders [3] . 7 In the UK, the first cases of COVID-19 were reported in the city of York on 31st January 2020. Cases 8 began to rise in a concerning manner in March 2020 and on 12th March, the government policy moved 9 from "containment" to "delay", suggesting the imminent introduction of restrictions in order to flatten 10 the peak and avoid the National Health Service (NHS) potentially being overwhelmed in the following 11 weeks. On 20th March, a wave of restrictions were introduced, including the closing of all schools to 12 children other than the vulnerable and those with key worker parents, and the closing of all pubs, 13 restaurants and indoor leisure facilities. Finally, on 23rd March, the UK prime minister announced a 14 national lockdown, in which all individuals had to stay at home and were only allowed out for essential 15 shopping, healthcare, essential work if they could not work from home and one form of exercise per 16 day. 17 As cases continued to decline during April, May and June 2020, mandatory controls were gradually 18 relaxed in order to mitigate further economic harm. in England, schools opened to certain year groups 19 from early June, whilst non-essential shops re-opened on 15th June and pubs and restaurants on 4th 20 July, albeit with physical distancing measures in place in an attempt to control the spread of the virus. 21 As society gradually opened up, cases began to rise again, slowly at first, but increasingly rapidly in 22 September and October. Given the potential for a significant second wave of infection, there was a call 23 from many stakeholders for a short "circuit breaker" lockdown in England, in order to stem the rise 24 in cases and protect the NHS during the winter months. The UK government finally introduced a 4-25 week lockdown on 5th November in England, whilst Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland introduced 26 similar, short-term mandatory control policies during October and November in an attempt to keep 27 the virus under control. 28 Much of the existing modelling literature on the pandemic has focused explicitly on the impacts of 29 interventions that minimise the direct health impact of the COVID-19 pandemic, such as the number 30 of individuals being admitted to hospital and/or dying from the disease [4] [5] [6] . However, it is important 31 to note that there are non-health benefits and harms that can arise as a result of lockdown. From 32 an economic perspective, long-term closures of the hospitality sector and non-essential shops could 33 lead to wholesale closure of businesses, which will in turn lead to increased unemployment. There 34 are additionally effects on tourism, transport and productivity. These disruptions can in turn lead to 35 indirect health harms, such as potential delays in elective hospital procedures, mental health harm and 36 reduced fiscal space for healthcare spending as a result of economic contractions. On the other hand, 37 voluntary physical distancing in response to increases in COVID-19 cases and deaths plays a role that 38 is at least as important as government-mandated controls in driving economic losses, particularly in 39 high-income countries [7, 8] . As a result, judicious use of lockdown measures may ultimately hasten 40 economic recovery [9, 10] . It is therefore important to consider the effect of any control policy on 41 the overall economic cost of an outbreak, taking into account both positive and negative health and 42 economic effects. There is significant debate around enhanced physical distancing in both the UK and around the world 44 with a focus on a perceived trade-off between averting COVID-19 cases and avoiding non-COVID 45 loss of welfare [11, 12] . However, there has only been a limited exploration of this perceived trade-off 46 in analysing the economic valuation of vaccines (REF in comment) . To date no paper has explicitly 47 explored the optimal level of physical distancing in the UK context using a mechanistic model of disease 48 transmission, that can be used to estimate the impact of interventions on cases, hospitalisations and 49 deaths, incorporating economic impact, though previous work has investigated potential health and 50 economic impacts of vaccination [12] . In this paper, we analyse the effectiveness of different control 51 scenarios (including more intensive long-term control or intermittent periods of fixed-term control) 52 taking into account the positive impact on public health and the negative impact on the economy. 53 We aim to inform optimal physical distancing policies that minimise a given mixed objective function 54 of social welfare (that combines economic and public health losses) to inform policy in the UK, and 55 provide an example of analytical approach to assessing the COVID policies more broadly. 56 We focus here on two scenarios. We first evaluate past UK policy, to illustrate the potential trade-57 offs between two physical distancing policies during the second wave in late 2020. We then extend 58 this analysis to appraise different future approaches to physical distancing as vaccination is rolled 59 out. In the first scenario, we explore the impact of introducing multiple "precautionary breaks" -60 short-term lockdowns of up to four weeks duration -would have had during 2020 and investigate the 61 predictions of the cost of such a policy, dependent upon the intensity of control both within and outside 62 these lockdown periods. We consider different lockdown period durations, intensity and timings, and 63 calculate an overall cost for each measure. In the second scenario, we investigate the optimal relaxation 64 policy to exit the 2021 lockdown, as dependent upon the pace of the vaccination campaign and the 65 acceptable level of cost of the intervention policy. To establish the COVID-related health impacts, we calculate the Quality Adjusted Life Year (QALY) 67 loss for each scenario. Additionally, we calculate the estimated Gross Domestic Product (GDP) loss 68 across this period and, by combining these measures, we determine an optimal scenario that is based 69 upon monetising QALY losses using a societal willingness to pay (WTP) conversion factor. We apply 70 the willingness-to-pay concept which can be used to evaluate direct costs incurred by health care 71 services from a demand side perspective. This provides a way to measure the overall societal valuation 72 of disease control, with an optimal policy determined based upon the policy maker's WTP for health 73 improvement. Our work provides a framework to facilitate decision making that takes into account 74 the negative impacts that mandatory controls may have to economic productivity, as well as the value 75 of positive health impacts that occur as a result of the reduction in the spread of disease. The epidemiological model 78 In this paper we used a previously developed deterministic, age-structured compartmental model, 79 stratified into five-year age bands [13] . It is important for age-structure to be incorporated into a 80 model of this type, given that the risk of hospitalisation and death is highly dependent upon age. 81 Transmission was governed through age-dependent mixing matrices based on UK social mixing pat-82 terns [14, 15] . The population was further stratified according to current disease status, following 83 a susceptible-exposed-infectious-recovered (SEIR) paradigm, as well as differentiating by symptoms, 84 quarantine and household status. We assumed therefore that susceptibles infected by SARS-CoV-2 85 would enter a latent state before becoming infectious. Given that only a proportion of individuals 86 who are infected are tested and subsequently identified, the infectious class in our model was parti-87 tioned into symptomatic (and hence potentially detectable), and asymptomatic (and likely to remain 88 undetected) infections. We assumed both susceptibility and disease detection were dependent upon 89 age. We modelled the UK population aggregated to 10 regions (Wales, Scotland, Northern Ireland, 90 East of England, London, Midlands, North East and Yorkshire, North West England, South East Eng-91 land, South West England), with each region modelled independently (i.e. we assumed no interactions 92 occurred between regions). CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; https://doi.org /10.1101 /10. /2021 A drawback of the standard SEIR ordinary differential equation (ODE) formulation in which all indi-94 viduals mix randomly in the population is that it cannot readily account for the isolation of households. 95 For example, if all transmission outside the household is set to zero in a standard ODE model, then 96 an outbreak can still occur as within-household transmission allows infection between age-groups and 97 does not account for local depletion of susceptibles within the household environment. We addressed 98 this limitation by extending the standard SEIR models such that first infections within a household 99 are treated differently from subsequent infections. To account for the depletion of susceptibles in the 100 household, we made the approximation that all within household transmission was generated by the 101 first infection within the household (see Supporting Information for further details). For our retrospective analysis, we used the transmission model to simulate the spread of SARS-CoV-2 105 infection in the UK in the presence of none, one or two precautionary breaks. We ran a suite of 106 simulations, varying the timing of the initial and the subsequent precautionary break, as well as the 107 levels of control both within the precautionary break and during the intrinsic (inter-break) period; 108 although we included a constraint that the level of control within a precautionary break must be at 109 least as severe as the level of control outside the precautionary break. The earliest date we assumed 110 the first precautionary break could occur was 1st July 2020. The minimum delay between the onset 111 date of the first and second precautionary break was set to 4 weeks, based on the practical assumption 112 that the UK government would be unlikely to implement two consecutive precautionary breaks within 113 a short time period. We assumed each precautionary break was in place for 1, 2, 3 or 4 weeks. All 114 simulations spanned February 2020 until the end of June 2021, although we calculated economic and 115 health costs from June 2020 through to January 2021 (corresponding to the time period during which 116 precautionary breaks could be enacted). Overall, we explored a wide set of potential future scenarios 117 (approximately 50,000) where the placement of precautionary breaks and strength of controls were 118 tunable parameters. In our model, we considered the following variables when determining the optimal level and type of 120 control: 121 (i) The intensity of controls both within precautionary break periods and outside these periods. We 122 measured this by a single parameter (φ, between zero and one) that combined the scale of any mea-123 sures, public adherence and reactive public behaviour, in other words both mandated and voluntary 124 distancing. When this parameter is zero, there are no restrictions or voluntary distancing, and thus 125 additional impact on the economy, but transmission is maximal. When this parameter is one, there 126 is very strong extent of physical distancing, comparable with the situation in the UK in early April 127 2020. Our constraint that the level of control within a precautionary break must be at least as severe 128 as the level of control outside the break was enforced by ensuring the intensity of controls within break 129 periods, φ P B , had a value equal to or greater than the intensity of controls outside of break periods, 130 φ O (i.e. φ P B ≥ φ O ). More details of the effect of φ upon transmission are given in the supplementary 131 material. (ii) The duration of precautionary breaks. This was modelled as a fixed time interval (1, 2, 3 or 133 4 weeks), during which more severe intervention policies were introduced, compared to the intrinsic 134 control measures. The duration of the break period(s) for a given simulation could be varied to 135 establish the optimal duration of a fixed term precautionary break. (iii) The frequency and timing of precautionary breaks. We considered the impact of single and multiple 137 breaks. We assumed that the intensity of each break was the same in a multi-phase strategy (though 138 5 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; https://doi.org /10.1101 /10. /2021 we acknowledge that, in practice, adherence could wane through time given repeated precautionary 139 breaks). (iv) Limits on hospital occupancy. Given that the choice of policy may be influenced by the current 141 number of individuals in hospital with COVID, we investigate the impact of a hospital occupancy 142 threshold upon our choice of policy. We therefore consider hospital occupancy limits of 10,000 and 143 20,000 individuals and an alternate scenario where there is no limit on hospital occupancy. For the prospective scenario, we simulate the model forward from January 2021 and investigate a range 146 of schedules of relaxation from lockdown. Prior to January 2021, the model assumes the same levels of 147 control that took place in England. In this scenario, we introduce vaccination into the population at 148 a rate of either 2 million or 4 million individuals per week. We assume a vaccine efficacy of 70% after 149 the first dose and 88% after the second dose against disease (and 48% and 60% against infection), 150 with immunity taking effect 2 weeks after vaccination. We investigate the optimal policy to emerge 151 from lockdown and how that policy is dependent upon assumptions around the acceptable cost of 152 control. Defining the counterfactual scenarios 154 In order to understand the health and economic impact of any level of control, for each scenario we 155 must outline the counterfactual against which all other strategies are judged. For analytical purposes 156 we compare all levels of control against an unmitigated outbreak (i.e. zero control, or φ = 0) without 157 vaccination as our null model for the first scenario and a scenario where we stay in full lockdown 158 (phi =) for the duration of the simulations, until the end of 2021. While this is unlikely in reality, 159 as populations are likely to change behaviours as the risk of infection changes, it provides the base 160 to assess different increasing levels of control (through either voluntary or mandatory distancing). In 161 addition, throughout our analyses for simplicity we assumed that there are no economic losses as a 162 result of reduced productivity from sickness and death. This means that any increase in the level of 163 control always leads to an economic loss but a health benefit. Calculating costs and willingness to pay 165 For each simulation of the model, we calculated the total number of deaths by age and used this 166 to establish a total QALY loss as a direct result of severe infection, taking into account mortality, 167 hospitalisation and admission into intensive care (see Supporting Information). No discount rate 168 was applied to future costs and QALYs given the limited timeframe of the analysis. We estimate 169 economic loss as a result of a given set of potential control measures by investigating the total GDP 170 loss related to the level of control. We approximated daily GDP by a polynomial function of the level 171 of control, φ (Fig. 1, red line) , derived from data on GDP from the period January to December 2020. 172 Hence, we made a pessimistic assumption about the economic impact of control measures. Given the 173 volatility in GDP in the months following the first national lockdown in March 2020, we make two 174 assumptions, one in which we fit to the whole of 2020 (Fig. 1, red line) and one in which we fit from 175 June 2020 to December 2020 (Fig. 1, blue line) . We conjecture that the model fitted from June 2020 176 may be representative of the true long term impact of the pandemic and the underlying intervention 177 measures upon GDP. We recognise using productivity as our measure of economic loss and using the 178 blunt relationship between control and GDP, excludes the economic value of non-monetary elements of 179 social welfare. Moreover, using an empirically derived relationship between control and GDP from the 180 past, limits the policy inference, as observed levels of control are likely to be driven by both voluntary 181 control (in response to levels of risk of illness) and mandatory lockdown measures. CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; To inform the temporal strength of controls, we used the temporally varying level of control inferred by 183 the SARS-CoV-2 transmission model being fit to multiple epidemiological data streams as outlined in 184 previous work [13] . Using our estimates of strength of controls, given a level of control at a particular 185 point in time, we determined the polynomial function that provided the best fit to reported monthly 186 GDP. We translated this value to total GDP loss by summing across the intervention duration and 187 comparing to the unmitigated scenario. To produce an optimal level of control from a societal perspective, we combined the value of health 189 and economic loss estimates into a single monetary quantity. We achieved this by placing a monetary 190 value (W ) on each QALY (Quality Adjusted Life Year) and minimising the net monetary loss i.e. 191 W × QALY loss + GDP loss. W represents the societal willingness to pay per QALY loss avoided. 192 We model this for different levels of W . WTP is determined by decision authorities and may reflect 193 different values. For example, the National Institute for Health and Care Excellence (NICE) currently 194 uses a cost-effectiveness threshold where W is in the range of £20,000 to £30,000 for reimbursing 195 new drugs in the National Health Service [16] ; however, this is for policy decisions that considered 196 trade-offs between new and current health sector services and in the context of the ongoing COVID-19 197 pandemic, we may expect a different value of W to be appropriate. We therefore consider a range of 198 values of W from £20,000 to £200,000 throughout this paper. 199 Fig. 1 : Graph of monthly GDP (in billions of pounds) from January to December 2020. Grey bars correspond to the GDP in the respective month. The red line shows the best (quadratic) fit to the GDP from January to December 2020, whilst the blue line shows the best (quartic) fit to the data from June 2020 to December 2020. (Shading regions show 95% credible intervals.) 7 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; https://doi.org /10.1101 /10. /2021 Analysis of the impact of precautionary breaks in 2020 201 We firstly investigated the effect that multiple precautionary break policies could have had on the 202 epidemic from June 2020. For this set of results, we do not consider the effect of vaccination and 203 we excluded simulations in which hospital occupancy across the entire country exceeded a specified 204 threshold (set at either 10,000 or 20,000 individuals at any one time and we also include a scenario 205 with no limit on hospital occupancy) to ensure that the optimal strategy did not result in the health 206 service being overwhelmed. Whilst we imposed a health service related constraint here, our model 207 framework can be extended to include other exclusionary constraints; for example, simulations that 208 result in daily economic costs exceeding a given threshold or those that exceed specific hospitalisation 209 thresholds by local area. To exemplify the dynamics, we fixed the willingness to pay per QALY (W ) at £50,000 and examined 211 the net loss across a range of scenarios ( Fig. 2) with no limit on hospital occupancy initially. As the 212 level of control increases, the total QALY loss decreases, whilst the total GDP also decreases. We 213 therefore observe that the net loss is minimised at an intermediate background level of control -a 214 value of 0.7 for the given value of W when we fit GDP to all 2020 and 0.8 when we fit from June 215 to December 2020. It is also optimal in this instance for two precautionary breaks to be introduced, 216 in July/August 2020 and September 2020. We explored sensitivity to these findings by considering 217 alternative fixed W values of £20,000, £30,000, £100,000 and £200,000. The results are summarised 218 in Figures S1-S4 . When considering £200,000 as a willingness to pay per QALY, we observe a slight 219 increase in the optimal level of control, whilst if our willingness to pay per QALY is only £20,000, 220 then the level of control that minimises loss is reduced. 221 We extended this approach across a range of W values, finding the strategy that minimised the net 222 loss. Our results are summarised in Fig. 3 when we fit GDP from June to December 2020 (results 223 when we fit to all 2020 are given in the supplementary material, ??), with particular realisations at the 224 optimal level of control shown in Figures S6-S11 . We observe that, if the willingness to pay per QALY 225 (W ) was low and our restriction on daily hospital admissions was unlimited (blue curves), the optimal 226 strategy was to have low levels of control outside the precautionary breaks and a relatively low control 227 level within a precautionary break ( Fig. 3 and ? ?, second row, right panel and third row, right panel, 228 respectively). As the willingness to pay increases, there is a preference for higher levels of control 229 both within and outside the precautionary break and a preference for a slightly delayed introduction 230 of the second precautionary break, but regardless of the willingness to pay, the tendency is for both 231 the first and second precautionary break to be introduced early. We note that for almost all scenarios 232 investigated, the optimal duration of a precautionary break was the maximum length investigated of 233 4 weeks (Fig. 3 and ? ?, third row, right hand panel), whilst multiple rather than single breaks were 234 generally preferred. This suggests that there may be a need for either longer duration or more frequent 235 breaks to be investigated. We also note that the limit on hospital occupancy only has a significant 236 effect upon the optimal policy when the willingness to pay is low -at higher values willingness to 237 pay the preferred timing and intensity of the precautionary break is found to be independent of the 238 hospital occupancy threshold. In the supplementary material, we used the same three hospitalisation thresholds and show the dy-240 namics of deaths and hospitalisations at the optimal set of controls that minimises the net monetary 241 loss for particular values of W (W =£20,000, £30,000, £50,000, £100,000 and £200,000). Across all 242 willingness to pay values, we find that the optimal policy is for two precautionary breaks to be in-243 troduced early, with a lower value of willingness to pay generally resulting in a slightly early date of 244 introduction for the precautionary breaks. As the willingness to pay increases, the optimal intensity 245 8 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; of control both within and outside the precautionary break periods increases and results in fewer daily 246 hospitalisations and deaths ( Figures S6-S11) . We also note that increasing the maximum number of 247 hospitalisations per day threshold does not significantly affect the optimal timing of precautionary 248 breaks but allows for lower background levels of control. 249 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; https://doi.org /10.1101 Outcomes at a willingness to pay per QALY (W ) of £50,000 with no limit on hospital occupancy. For various levels of control, we present (top row) Total QALY loss, (second row) total GDP, (third row) net monetary loss (W × QALY loss + GDP loss) and (fourth row) hospitalisations and deaths. In these panels, darker, larger, dots are for a constant intrinsic control level without any planned short-term breaks, whilst the smaller dots represent different timings and frequency of precautionary breaks. The red circle (left column) and blue square (right column) indicate the minimum net monetary loss for W =£100,000 when there is no limit on daily hospitalisations. The bottom panels show, for the economic optimum, daily deaths (darker colour) and hospitalisations (lighter colour) with the total number of each given in the top left hand corner of each panel. The black bars represent when the precautionary breaks take place in each instance. In this figure, the left column shows the results when GDP is fitted to the whole of 2020, whilst the right column shows the results when GDP is fitted from June to December 2020. Optimal relaxation strategies for the January 2021 national lockdown 250 We now investigate how the optimal pace of relaxation of lockdown may be dependent upon our 251 societal willingness to pay for repeated lockdowns to avoid QALY losses due to COVID. The results 252 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; Fig. 3 : Outcomes over a range of willingness to pay per QALY (W ) values. (Top Row) Net monetary loss (W × QALY loss + GDP loss) against different values of W as the daily hospitalisation threshold varies (different colours). In rows two-four, we display the following measures for the optimal control strategy as the willingness to pay per QALY increases: (second row, left panel) maximum number of hospital admissions per day. (second row, right panel) the optimal level of intrinsic control outside lockdown; (third row, left panel) the optimal level of control within a precautionary break; (third row, right panel) the optimal duration of the lock-down in days; (fourth row, left panel) the optimal date of the first precautionary break; (fourth row, right panel) the optimal date of the second precautionary break. In this figure we fit to GDP from June to December 2020. . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; are summarised in Fig. 4 . Here we can see that, if the willingness to pay is at the low end of our range 253 and 4 million individuals are vaccinated per week (dark colours in figures), our model recommends a 254 relatively rapid relaxation policy, with all interventions removed by September 2021. However, this 255 results in a significant wave of deaths occurring. As the willingness to pay increases, it is preferable 256 to ease out of lockdown much more gradually, as this results in a much lower peak in deaths as non-257 pharmaceutical interventions are relaxed. If we only have the capacity to vaccinate 2 million individuals 258 per week, we note that this results in a slightly slower easing of lockdown being optimal and as a result 259 of this, we observe a reduced peak in deaths for a given willingness to pay when compared with a 260 scenario with a higher vaccine capacity. These results highlight that the willingness to pay has a 261 significant influence upon the optimal strategy for both introducing and easing interventions. This work highlights a central tenet of disease control -that the optimal timing and level of any physical 264 distancing policy is highly dependent upon the scope of the objective that is trying to be achieved 265 [17, 18] . Combining economic and health outcomes in COVID-19 policy analysis using infectious 266 disease modelling is potentially complex. Our methods here are a starting point, but nevertheless 267 illustrate that where a multi-phase precautionary break strategy is under consideration, then the 268 exact timescale and intensity of such a policy is highly dependent upon the willingness to pay of the 269 UK population to averted health loss. For example, in our retrospective scenario, if WTP is £50,000 270 per QALY loss avoided, increasing the level of control from 0 to 0.7 would result in a reduction in net 271 monetary loss of over £150 billion. If the WTP is £100,000 then this change in control level would 272 result in a increased reduction in net monetary loss to over £400 billion. Even where the exact WTP 273 is unknown, our analysis illustrates that it is possible to develop an approach for arriving at optimal 274 control that incorporates both health and economic losses, for different levels of willingness to pay, 275 with the aim to inform the transparent assessment of the trade-offs involved. There are important caveats to the findings in this work that should be discussed, and can inform 277 those who wish to develop this approach further. First, we have examined the relationship between 278 levels of control and economic and health impact. The level of control is driven both by voluntary and 279 mandated distancing, and the former is likely to be driven at least in part by economic and health 280 risk. These feed backs may result in underestimating the optimal level of control, since strong controls 281 can reduce disease incidence and hence minimise economic damage from voluntary distancing. We 282 also note that our economic approach, utilising current GDP loss as a proxy for overall economic 283 loss, is unlikely to capture the dynamics of economic impact and wider societal welfare and long-284 term economic impacts of control, particularly given government borrowing to mitigate costs in the 285 short term. There will be a range of lagged impacts, and longer-term impacts on GDP of any set of 286 controls. We also note that GDP loss is not the only important economic indicator. Fiscal impact 287 or increases in unemployment are other important factors, and wider impacts such as educational 288 losses could be considered. It is therefore possible that the findings represented here may overestimate 289 the short-term economic impact of lockdown, whilst not capturing the social and long-term economic 290 impact. These aspects should also be considered when determining the optimal strength of control 291 implemented within lockdown periods. A more complete economic analysis would use approaches such 292 as computable general equilibrium models [19] and the need to consider which sectors of society would 293 be restricted to arrive at a particular level of control, and how this would lead to a loss in GDP. Our 294 findings do suggest, however, that governments should consider setting acceptable thresholds for a loss 295 of productivity per QALY before the next pandemic in order to establish optimal intervention policies 296 at pandemic onset. On measuring cost to health, we currently estimate health harms by calculating QALY loss from hos-298 12 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; Fig. 4 : Optimal relaxation policies from the January 2021 lockdown over a range of willingness to pay per QALY (W ) values. Daily deaths from November 2020 to September 2021 when 2 million individuals (dark colours) and 4 million individuals (light colours) are vaccinated per day. The background grey shaded region shows the relative level of control required at the optimal value whilst the dashed line shows the daily deaths when full lockdown is in place throughout. The left column shows results when we fit to GDP for the whole of 2020 whilst the right column is for when we fit from June to December 2020. Each row shows results for a different value of willingness to pay, from £10,000 to £50,000 per QALY gained. pitalisation, admission to intensive care and death as a result of COVID-19 infection. However, a more 299 complete analysis would account for a range of other factors beyond the scope of this preliminary work, 300 including: non-COVID health impacts of COVID-19 itself and of interventions to control COVID-19 301 . CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; (both positive, such as the likely decline in other infections due to social distancing, and negative, 302 such as excess all-cause mortality, cancelled elective procedures due to hospital bed pressures, and re-303 duction in hospital attendance and screening), the mental health and social impacts of COVID-19 and 304 its control [20] , long-term health impacts of economic harm [21] and the lasting health implications of 305 long-COVID [22, 23] . 306 We also note that our results are highly dependent upon the precise value of the Willingness to Pay, 307 W . When faced with the scale of the SARS-CoV-2 outbreak and associated COVID-19 disease burden, 308 trade-offs may consider a rule of rescue and the value of W could be higher than values typically used 309 by the NHS [24] . Alternative approaches, using measures of W that value health according to the 310 opportunity costs within current spending on health are likely to be lower. Finally, depending on the 311 way in which W is determined, there may be some double counting between economic loss and health 312 loss as, when valuing QALYs, the value of reduced productivity may be implicitly considered in QALY 313 valuations. Given this complexity around valuing health improvement, we present our results for a 314 range of different values of W . It is also important to note that our models assumed a fixed rate of adherence to intervention measures, 316 a fixed level of control across all lockdown periods and similarly a fixed (but lower) level of control 317 across non-lockdown periods. It is possible that such a policy of repeated lockdowns could result in 318 waning adherence over time, and this may in turn influence the overall economic and health impact of 319 any lockdown period. With this in mind, further work may be needed in order to establish the optimal 320 adaptive policy when there is uncertainty regarding future intensities of lockdown and adherence to 321 intervention measures. Finally, economic cost is proportional to the total duration and intensity of 322 a lockdown. We have not considered any additional economic cost of multiple short precautionary 323 breaks (owing to stopping and starting of businesses) or longer term lockdowns (in which businesses 324 may be more likely to become insolvent). Despite the caveats presented above, there are some important lessons that we can learn from this 326 research. During any infectious disease outbreak, policy makers must rapidly evaluate the state of the 327 system and introduce an intervention policy that is deemed most appropriate at that point in time. 328 For human diseases, the key focus is typically (and understandably) on health, with policies often 329 selected that will minimise the risk of severe disease or death over a short period of time. However, 330 a policy that focuses purely upon minimising health losses can have a very high macro-economic cost 331 and result in long-term harm. Here, we present a more nuanced approach, whereby we consider both 332 the economic costs of lockdown and the health costs of the pandemic, linked to a dynamic model of 333 infectious disease. Our results highlight the necessity for decision makers to identify their overarching 334 objective in the event of an infectious disease outbreak. We concede it may be challenging to do this 335 during a pandemic when there are multiple competing priorities facing decision makers, and population 336 preferences are unclear. However, clearly defining the objective and the trade offs that need to be 337 considered should be an essential component of the contingency planning process going forward, and 338 can help ensure that optimal policies can be defined to minimise the impact of a future epidemic 339 rapidly. Once an appropriate objective is decided upon, the research presented here provides the start 340 of a framework for decision makers to evaluate the effectiveness from a societal perspective. CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 International license It is made available under a is the author/funder, who has granted medRxiv a license to display the preprint in perpetuity. (which was not certified by peer review) The copyright holder for this preprint this version posted April 25, 2021. ; https://doi.org /10.1101 /10. /2021 Writing -original draft Writing -review & editing: Mark Jit Anna Vassall; Frank Sandmann Michael 357 MJ and WJE were sup-362 ported by the NIHR Heath Protection Research Units in Immunisation (NIHR200929) and Mod-363 elling and Health Economics (NIHR200908), as well as by the European Commission project Epipose 364 (101003688). The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis A Novel Coronavirus from Patients with Pneumonia in China World Health Organization. Novel Coronavirus (2019-nCoV) Situation Report -1 The effect of control strategies to reduce social mixing on outcomes of the COVID-19 epidemic in Wuhan, China: a modelling study Effects of nonpharmaceutical interventions on COVID-19 cases, deaths, and demand for hospital services in the UK: a modelling study Modelling the covid-19 epidemic and implementation of population-wide interventions in italy Epidemiological models are important tools for guiding COVID-19 interventions Fear, lockdown, and diversion: Comparing drivers of pandemic economic decline 2020 Social distancing laws cause only small losses of economic activity during the covid-19 pandemic in scandinavia Macroeconomic outcomes and covid-19: A progress report Protecting lives and livelihoods with early and tight lockdowns Effects of physical distancing to control covid-19 on public health, the economy, and the environment The potential health and economic value of sars-cov-2 vaccination alongside physical distancing in the uk: transmission model-based future scenario analysis and economic evaluation Fitting to the UK COVID-19 outbreak, short-term forecasts and estimating the reproductive number Social Contacts and Mixing Patterns Relevant to the Spread of Infectious Diseases Projecting social contact matrices in 152 countries using contact surveys and demographic data Guide to the methods of technology appraisal Decision-making for foot-and-mouth disease control: objectives matter Control fast or control smart: When should invading pathogens be controlled? Estimating the economic impact of pandemic influenza: An application of the computable general equilibrium model to the u.k Coronavirus: Economic impact Office for National Statistics. The prevalence of long COVID symptoms and COVID-19 complication Updated estimates of the prevalence of long COVID symptoms Using cost-effectiveness evidence to inform decisions as to which health services to provide