key: cord-0945489-cfihc8yx authors: Nizam, Ahmed Mehedi title: Some amendments to the algebraic representation and empirical estimation of the fiscal multipliers date: 2020-11-19 journal: Heliyon DOI: 10.1016/j.heliyon.2020.e05512 sha: dbabb0ed3e509a64cceb0156305da0a0899f2ec0 doc_id: 945489 cord_uid: cfihc8yx Conventional algebraic estimate of the fiscal multipliers ignores the concept of velocity of money and mistakenly assumes that money changes hands an infinite number of times during a given year while we know money only has a finite velocity. Apart from the velocity of money, fiscal multipliers tend to depend on average propensity to consume and average propensity to import of the economy as a whole and also on average tax rate among other things which are not reflected in the modern SVAR based estimation. Here, in the first place, we amend the algebraic definition of the fiscal multipliers considering the impact of velocity of money, provide a micro-foundation relating fiscal multipliers with money velocity and other macro variables and later propose a modification in the conventional SVAR set up by incorporating aforesaid macro variables arranged in a logical manner. Proposed amendments to the SVAR set up entail relatively stable estimates of the fiscal multipliers as can be seen from empirical estimation of the multiplier values for US and UK data during the period 1972-2018. History of economic multipliers can be traced back to eighteenth century when the French economist Francois Quesnay first proposed the Tableau Economique (Economic Table) [1] . However, it's the Keynes and Henderson who brought about the idea of economic multipliers to modern economic analysis and formally laid the foundation of multiplier theory during the height of the great depression [2] . Keynes and Henderson were advocates of generous government spending targeted to slash unemployment and through these they intended to reinstate the economy to its full employment level defying the rages of the great depression of the 1930s. However, the Keynesian idea of curbing unemployment through government intervention was rejected outright by the office of the Chancellor of Exchequer of the United Kingdom claiming very little additional employment could in fact be created by state funding [3] . This view of the Her Majesty's Treasury regarding the role of government spending to uplift the economy from deep down is famously known as the 'Treasury View' which suggests any increase in government spending will necessarily crowd out an equal amount of private spending or investment and thus has no net impact on economic activity [37] . However, economic ideas are often inconclusively debatable and Keynes and others downplayed the 'Treasury View' by formally introducing the concept of fiscal multipliers in the context of * Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: ahmed.mehedi@bb.org.bd, ahmed.mehedi.nizam@gmail.com. government spending. Richard Kahn in his famous paper "The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment" [4] analyzed the impact of enhanced government spending on unemployment in the presence of spare capacity, monetary accommodation and sticky prices. Kahn's idea was further refined and extended by Jens Warming [5] who introduced the concept of consumption functions in the analysis of economic multiplier. The first coherent presentation by Keynes in the context of economic multipliers was in a series of four articles published in The Times in March 1933 entitled 'The Means to Prosperity' followed by an article in the New Statesman in April entitled 'The Multiplier' [3] . Keynes further argued in favor of the multiplier effect in his famous book 'The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money' [6] . The idea of economic multiplier since its modern inception back in 1930s received mixed response from the economic community and economists around the globe are still deeply divided about how well or indeed whether such (fiscal) stimulus works [7] . Nowadays, research on economic multiplier hinges around its empirical estimation and its effectiveness to downplay recession. For example, the performance of American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 which was indeed a stimulus package enacted by the 111th U.S. Congress in response to counter great recession of 2008 following the burst of housing bubble was analyzed using the theories fiscal multipliers. White House Council of Economic Advisers (CEA) estimated that the stimulus package provided within the framework of ARRA 2009 was supposed to create between 2.5 and 3.6 million new jobs as of the second quarter of 2010 and at that point outlays and tax cuts would be totaled to $257 and $223 billion respectively (see for example, Council of Economic Advisers (2010)) [8] . The current literature on fiscal multiplier is somewhat policy oriented which helps government choose the best policy options available based upon sophisticated econometric techniques including impulse response analysis under structural VAR framework which attempts to capture the dynamic response of output to various government stimulus, tax cut and different combinations of the two. As the focus shifted to more practical side the theoretical derivation of the fiscal multiplier lacks proper attention. In the algebraic derivation of the fiscal multiplier it is assumed that one simple stimulus provided in the form of government spending triggers an infinite series of spending/consumption in the economy. The limiting value of the infinite geometric progression of spending/consumption thus created is treated as the value of fiscal multiplier. However, as we know from the concept of velocity of money, money will only change finite number of hands in a given year. So, if we do not overlook the concept of velocity of money, the infinite geometric progression used for the closed form algebraic approximation of the fiscal multiplier will only become a finite geometric series. Moreover, the real impact of fiscal stimulus will also depend (among others) upon the average propensity to consume and average propensity to import of the consumers and average tax rate as set out in the fiscal policy. The more the consumers spend on locally produced goods and services the more pronounced will be the effect of fiscal stimulus. On the other hand, if the consumers prefer savings to consumption or if they are more inclined to purchasing imported goods and services, the less will be impact of stimulus package. On the other hand, higher the tax rate, the lower will be the disposable income of the consumers which eventually entails smaller multiplier values. In the modern structural VAR based estimation of the fiscal multipliers all these facts are totally ignored. Here, we incorporate all the aforementioned facts in the algebraic and empirical estimation of the fiscal multipliers and compare our results with traditional SVAR approach using US and UK data during the period 1972-2018. The subsequent sections of this article are organized as follows. Section 2 briefly describes the vast literature relating to the fiscal multipliers and different empirical approaches to measure it. Section 3 introduces the definitions of different kinds of fiscal multipliers currently in use. Section 4 discusses the conventional algebraic calculation of the fiscal multiplier. Section 5 makes the proposed amendments to the algebraic estimation of the fiscal multipliers presented in Section 4. Section 6 provides a micro-foundation of the intuitive arguments presented in Section 5. Section 7 diffuses the modified algebraic representation of the multipliers as presented in Section 5 into structural VAR set up and elaborates the methodology followed for the empirical estimation of the government spending multipliers in this modified experimental set up. Data sources used in the analysis are also discussed in this section. Section 8 presents the results of empirical analysis and compares the performance of our proposed model to the conventional one. Section 9 discusses the policy implication and the limitation of the current study. Finally, Section 10 makes some concluding remarks. Modern approaches of estimating a reasonable size of the fiscal multipliers include impulse response analysis under structural VAR framework inspired by seminal work of Blanchard and Perotti (2002) [9] and the narrative approach popularized by Romer and Romer (2010) [10] . However, the multipliers calculated empirically using these approaches in different countries during different time frames vary considerably. For example, Blanchard and Perotti (2002) [9] estimate the multiplier values to be close to 1 for government purchases in United States under structural VAR framework. However, Perotti (2004) [11] , in a sample of 5 OECD countries has shown that the effects of fiscal policy on GDP tend to be small: government spending multipliers larger than 1 can only be estimated in the US in the pre-1980 period. Mountford and Uhlig (2009) [12] have shown that the impact multipliers corresponding to deficit financed tax cut for US data vary between 0.29 to 5.25 at different time periods. However, in long run, i.e., after period 20 it becomes negative. For deficit spending, the corresponding impact multipliers are found within the range −2.07 to 0.65 in different quarters. Based on a survey carried out by Mineshima et al. (2014) [13] , it can be noted that first year fiscal multipliers amount on average to 0.75 for government spending and 0.25 for tax revenue in advanced economies. However, these modern results have been challenged by some recent studies and it has been observed that the multipliers can exceed 1 under abnormal circumstances when the economy is facing severe downturn and the monetary policy transmission mechanism has been impaired to some extent [14] . Meanwhile, small sample size of macroeconomic data available for each individual country lures researchers towards a panel VAR approach. For example, Beetsma et al. (2008) [15] estimates the fiscal multiplier for EU countries in a Panel VAR and finds a peak multiplier value of 1.6. Another approach to measuring fiscal multipliers commonly known as the narrative approach provides a methodological improvement upon the traditional measurement of fiscal shocks. Unlike the structural VAR approach, narrative approach seeks to identify exogenous fiscal shocks directly. Some studies using narrative approach have used news about US military spending as a measure of exogenous shocks and estimate US government spending multipliers to be within the range 1.1-1.2 (Ramey, 2011 [38] ). Using US defense spending news during the period 1917-2006, Barro and Redlick (2011) [16] has found that the government spending multipliers vary within the range of 0.4-0.6 where lower multiplier values are obtained for temporary spending changes and higher values are obtained for permanent spending changes. Using US defense spending news during 1930-2008, Hall (2009) [17] has estimated the government spending multipliers to be roughly 0.6. Using narrative approaches of identifying exogenous fiscal shocks, Owyang, Ramey and Zubairy (2013) [18] estimate US government spending multipliers to be 0.8 and for Canadian data their obtained values are within the range 0.4-1.6. Higher multiplier values for Canadian data are obtained during periods of high unemployment. Numerous other studies have been conducted aiming to estimate a credible size of the fiscal multipliers and a comprehensive survey of this huge volume of literature is provided in the technical notes of IMF [14] . From the above discussion we can conclude that the estimates of the fiscal multipliers depend heavily upon the techniques used in estimation i.e., SVAR approach or narrative approach. In general SVAR approach entails relatively small multiplier values as compared to the narrative approach [19] . Differences in the estimates stem from the fact that the two approaches differ fundamentally in at least two specific dimensions [19] . In the first place, the transmission mechanism deployed by the SVAR approach comprises a multi-equation, multivariate autoregressive system in which the fiscal variables (government spending and/or tax) evolve jointly with other endogenous macroeconomic variables in the system. On the other hand, the narrative approach uses a single equation where output is represented as a linear function of current and lagged values of the exogenous fiscal shocks. The second dimension in which the two approaches differ is the identification of the fiscal shocks. While the SVAR approach imposes a number of restrictions on the variance-covariance matrix of the vector of shocks under consideration, the narrative approach analyzes historical records, presidential speeches, congressional reports etcetera to identify exogenous fiscal shocks. It has been argued that the differences in the two estimates of the fiscal multipliers are (partly) due to the failure of the two models to identify the same fiscal shock [19] . We now know that due to the misspecification of the fiscal shocks, SVAR approach and narrative approach may entail different estimates of the fiscal multipliers. However, estimation of the fiscal multipliers using single strategy i.e., SVAR or narrative approach rarely results into consistent estimates. In the SVAR context, number of endogenous and exogenous variables in the SVAR framework, choice of variables, time horizon in which the multiplier is reported and size of the sample can influence the empirical estimation of the fiscal multipliers (see Gechert (2015) [20] and Rusnak (2011) [21] for details). Moreover, data composition, data transformation and methodology used for fiscal data collection can also have a profound impact on the multiplier estimates [22] . For example, Capek and Cuaresma (2019) [22] has shown that using Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) to deflate nominal variables instead of GDP deflator and following European System of National and Regional Accounts (ESA) 95 rather than ESA 2010 result into significantly larger estimates of the fiscal multipliers. Given the wide range within which fiscal multipliers tend to oscillate, it is important to know upon which circumstances fiscal multipliers work well in stimulating the economy. Multipliers tend to vary depending upon the exchange rate regime, amount of government debt and financial crisis among other things. Corsetti et al. (2011) [23] shows that the multipliers are larger under fixed exchange rate regime, lower when public debt is higher and larger during periods of financial crisis. Gorodnichenko (2011, 2012) [24, 25] use semi-annual data of a panel of industrialized countries to compare the effectiveness of government spending during economic booms and busts. As anticipated, their study finds evidence in favor of the fiscal multipliers being more active during periods of economic downturn. Using a panel of 44 countries segregated into developing and developed ones, Ilzetzki et al. (2013) [26] shows that fiscal multipliers are larger in developed than in developing countries, larger in the countries with a predetermined exchange rates and smaller in open economies than in closed ones. On the contrary, they have found that fiscal multipliers are negative in highly indebted countries. Literatures relating to fiscal multipliers are vast and are still growing. However, that are cited above (and that are not) do not tend to consider money velocity, average propensity to consume, average propensity to import and average tax rate as some of the determinants of the fiscal multipliers. These macroeconomic variables are surprisingly missing in all of the SVAR based modern estimation of the fiscal multipliers which, we argue, limits our possibility of obtaining a reasonable estimate of the multipliers using empirical techniques. Here, we first propose a modification to the algebraic definition of the fiscal multipliers by gently dispersing the concept of finite velocity of money into the multiplier theory and then amend the conventional SVAR framework used in the estimation by adding the above-mentioned variables in an intuitive manner that complies with the amended algebraic representation of the fiscal multipliers. Fiscal multiplier is the amount of changes in real GDP or any other measures of real output brought about by a unit change in any of the fiscal variables like government consumption, government investment, government taxes etcetera. Depending upon the choice of the fiscal variables, the value and sign of the fiscal multipliers vary significantly. For example, government consumption and investment are supposed to have a positive effect on real output while government taxes may have a negative one. Here, we are more interested in the estimation of government consumption multiplier and all through the text whenever we mention the term fiscal multiplier we mean government consumption multiplier. Government consumption multipliers can be further classified into impact and cumulative multipliers which are defined as follows. • Impact multiplier: If a Δ amount of change in government consumption brings about Δ changes in output then impact multiplier for government consumption is defined as follows: • Cumulative multiplier: Impact multipliers capture the response of real output in response to shocks in government consumption for a particular period of time. However, the effect of shocks in government consumption may be pronounced over subsequent time periods after the shock is applied and hence it is reasonable to define a cumulative version of government consumption multiplier which can be defined as follows: where is the cumulative multiplier at time and the discounting rate. Before we proceed, a few preliminary definitions of some quantities along with their inter-relation with the fiscal multipliers are on the way: • Average propensity to consume: Average propensity to consume is the fraction of the total income of an entity that is spent in consumption. Another portion of the income is saved and subsequently invested. To measure average propensity to consume for a whole country we divide the total amount of consumption of that country in a year by its Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in the same year. Average propensity to consume is supposed to have a positive correlation with the effectiveness of the fiscal stimulus. If the beneficiaries of government consumption spend a significant portion of their income then the contribution of government consumption on GDP will be much more pronounced. On the other hand, if the beneficiaries choose to save a significant portion of it rather than spending then the effectiveness of government stimulus package would be much lower than what is anticipated. • Average propensity to import: Average propensity to import of an entity is the fraction of its total income that is spent on purchasing imported goods and services. For a country, average propensity to import can be calculated by dividing its yearly import by its Gross Domestic Product (GDP). As import has an adversarial relation with the GDP, a higher value of average propensity to import will result into a lower value of fiscal multiplier i.e., the stimulus package fails to boost up the economy through enhanced production. In this case, people tend to be more interested on importing goods and services rather than producing them locally. Thus a lower value of average propensity to import is desirable for the fiscal stimulus to work effectively towards boosting up the economy. • Average tax rate: Average tax rate is the fraction of total income of an entity that is paid as taxes to the government. An entity can pay taxes in many different forms e.g., housing tax, motor car tax, personal income tax, source tax on bank deposits, excise duty, corporate taxes etcetera. Then the average tax rate for that entity can be calculated by dividing its total tax payment in multifarious formats by its total income. For a country as a whole, average tax rate in a year can be calculated by dividing the total tax revenue collected by the government during the year by its GDP in the same year. A higher value of average tax rate will partly nullify the effect of fiscal stimulus as the government tends to pump in a significant portion of the money it spent as stimulus through revenue collection. To begin with, let us now assume Δ is any exogenous change in government consumption intended to work as fiscal stimuli. Then Δ will be received as wages by the workers, rents by the land owners, salaries by the employees, social security benefits by the elderly and the unemployed etcetera. If the average tax rate is given by then the increase in disposable income of the beneficiaries who receive Δ as payment is given by (1 − ) × Δ . A part of this disposable income will be spent in consumption while the rest is saved. If the average propensity to consume of the economy as whole is given by then the amount spent in consumption (both in locally produced and imported goods and services) will be given by × (1 − ) × Δ . If the average propensity to import is given by then the amount of spending in locally produced goods and services is given by ) be given by . So, the aggregate contribution on total output resulting from these two rounds of consumption initiated by the initial fiscal stimuli Δ is given by: The second round of consumption expenditure namely × Δ will be received by the producers of goods and services as sales revenue which triggers further consumption of × × Δ or 2 Δ . In the same manner, the successive consumption and savings continue inside the economy and we get an infinite geometric series as the aggregate impact of an initial fiscal stimulus of Δ on the total output: While deriving Equation (1) it is assumed that the initial fiscal stimulus Δ triggers an infinite progression of subsequent consumptions inside the economy. It may be true in the very long run. But, in short run or to be more precise within one year of time horizon its contribution will be finite. In reality, money paid as wages, rents, salaries etcetera can only change a finite number of hands during a given year. The number of times money changes hands in a particular year is known as the velocity of money. Let, the velocity of money be denoted by . If we consider a finite velocity of money then the total contribution of initial government consumption expenditure of Δ working as a stimulus to the economy will become the summation of a finite geometric series instead of an infinite one and it is given by the following: • Determination of optimal consumption sequence Each household in our simplistic endowment economy receives an annual endowment of , ∀ , 1 ≤ ≤ and transfer payment of , ∀ , 1 ≤ ≤ where is the entire life span of each household. In each period the household is supposed to determine how much to consume and how much to save with a view to maximizing its overall life time utility through consumption. Savings made up to period ( − 1) are entitled to interest payment at the rate during period . Moreover, utilities received from consumption at some future period are annually discounted at the rate of and annual consumption is taxed at the rate . Under these assumptions the optimal consumption sequence , ∀ , 1 ≤ ≤ of the household is given by the following construct: where is the coefficient of Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) factor. The detailed derivation of the optimal consumption sequence is furnished in the Appendix-A of the article. • Determining optimal savings sequence In the previous step we have calculated the optimal consumption sequence taken by the households in order to maximize their life time utility through consumption under budget constraint i.e., we have determined the optimal level of consumption made by the households at any arbitrary period , 1 ≤ ≤ . This time we are interested to determine the gross savings made by the households during period . If the accumulated savings with (simple) interest there on of the households up to period is given by then we have the following identity: where −1 is the accumulated savings with interest there on up to period ( − 1) and is the interest payment received by the households during period . In plain text the above equation simply implies that the total fund inflow for the households during any arbitrary period must equate their total outflow. That means the consumption and total accumulated savings made by the household during period must be sourced from its periodic endowment, transfer payment and interest income received at period as well as from the accumulated savings made up to period ( − 1). So the gross savings made by the households during period can be obtained by subtracting −1 from . Rearranging the above equation we get: • Determining optimal output In our representative endowment economy output produced in any given period is defined to be the summation of consumption and gross savings made during the same period. As we assume a closed economy there is no export/import. So, the total GDP of our closed endowment economy at period is given by the following: Substituting the value of from Equation (4) we get: From the above equation we can see that periodic output is significantly different from the simple summation of and as the households either receive interest on their accumulated savings up to period which adds to total output or pay interest on their accumulated debt up to period which is subtracted from total output. Now let us quantify the amount of interest income received by the households during period . At period households receive simple interest on their total gross principal savings up to period at the existing interest rate . So, Equation (5) turns out to be: • Determining the government spending multipliers Government spending multiplier is defined to be the changes in output in response to unit change in government spending. In reality, changes in government spending can be brought about by changing government consumption, investment and transfer payments. As we have previously assumed, in our simplistic economy government spending only consists of transfer payments. Including government consumption and investments as components of government spending would irrevocably break the analytical structure of the problem and would bring us to the realm of general equilibrium analysis which heavily relies upon simulation under some rather subjectively determined parameter settings. By now we prefer an analytical solution of the problem we are exposed to over a general equilibrium analysis using simulations. So in the context of our simplistic endowment economy we can define government spending multiplier as the rate of change of total output with respect to changes in government transfer payments. To do so we differentiate Equation (6) with respect to and we get the following expression: In the derivation of the above expression we have utilized the fact that the periodic endowment is exogenously determined and does not depend upon any other exogenous/endogenous variables in the system. So differentiating with respect to entails zero. Moreover, according to our initial assumption transfer payment at any period is independent of transfer payment in any other period. Hence differentiating transfer payment in any period other than with respect to transfer payment at period entails zero and differentiating with respect to entails one. Finally, as we have assumed at the beginning of our analysis , and are independent of one another and also independent of their own lagged/future terms, we can take as constant while (partially) differentiating any expression with respect to . Now we are left with determining the partial derivative of optimal consumption sequence , ∀ 1≤ ≤ with respect to transfer payment at times . Now for any , 1 ≤ ≤ we can get the optimal consumption from Equation (3): Differentiating the above expression with respect to yields: Substituting the value of for all 1 ≤ ≤ into Equation (7) we can get an algebraic expression for government spending multiplier . In each year in our simplistic endowment economy each of the following transactions takes place. -Households receive their periodic endowment . -Apart from periodic endowments households also receive their annual transfer payment . -Households receive interest income on their total gross principal savings up to year . -Households pay for their annual consumption . Apart from consumption households also pay the tax × levied upon consumption If the total money stock at year is given by then the velocity of money is given by the following construct: Now let us investigate what happens if the money velocity is simply doubled while all other things being held unchanged. Doubling the money velocity while keeping all other variables constant implies that now 02 (two) consecutive sets of the aforementioned 04(four) transactions will take place in a year. Apart from doubling the above set of transactions we have no other way to accommodate the increased velocity of money. So, there will be two sets of consumption, two sets of periodic endowment and transfer payments and also two sets of transactions regarding the receipt of interest income will occur in a year. It seems that the production cycle has simply reduced to half in time. Now everything completes with in just half of the time previously required to complete everything. We can further extend our idea for arbitrarily higher values of the velocity of money. Let us assume that the money velocity has been increased , ∈ times which means by now set of the above mentioned 04 (four) transactions will take place in a given year. So, the transfer payment made by the government during period instead of influencing only will now have a stake on all the sequential consumptions that will take place within 01 (one) year starting from . Hence, , +1 , +2 , ......, + −1 will be effected by within a one year bound. In doing so here we recall and utilize the definition of the fiscal multipliers that captures all the variations in output brought about within one year bound by unit change in government spending. As , +1 , +2 , ......, + −1 are influenced by so will be , +1 , +2 , ......, + −1 . Now, as the households' gross savings change so will be the interest income and following Equation (5) we can say that also changes. So, the total output ( ) produced during year starting at will now correspond to the summation of previous outputs of , +1 , +2 , ......., + −1 and is given by the following construct: Now differentiating the above expression with respect to we get the updated measurement of the fiscal multipliers: So for all , 0 ≤ ≤ ( −1) we need to calculate the values of + . When = 0 + turns out to be which can be calculated using Equation (7) and (8). For all other values of we rewrite Equation (6) by substituting with ( + ). Differentiating the above expression with respect to we get: For different values of , 1 ≤ ≤ ( + ) the values of can be obtained from Equation (8). So for all , 0 ≤ ≤ ( − 1) the values of + can be calculated using Equation (10) and (7). Substituting the values of + for all , 0 ≤ ≤ ( − 1) into Equation (9) we can estimate the values of the fiscal multipliers in the modified experimental set up i.e., when money velocity undergoes an -fold increase. VAR methodology has been predominantly used in the empirical estimation of the fiscal multipliers since as early as 2001, see for example, Fatas and Mihov (2001) [27] , Blanchard and Perotti (2002) where is the vector of endogenous variables, is the coefficients of the autoregressive terms of and matrix is a diagonal matrix so that is a vector of orthogonal, independent and identically distributed shocks to the endogenous variables such that [ ] = 0 and [ ′ ] is an identity matrix. To implement our proposed model and to compare its performance with the conventional estimation of the government spending multipliers the following steps are followed. • At first, we must determine which variables should comprise in our proposed approach and in the conventional estimation. To do so we take logarithms on both sides of Equation (2): , we assume changes in government consumption require at least one quarter to respond to innovations in other macroeconomic variables and hence we place government consumption before GDP. Placing government consumption before GDP implies that GDP will respond contemporaneously to any change in government spending but not the vice versa. The ordering of current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate after GDP and placing current account to GDP ratio before real effective exchange rate are inspired from Kim and Roubini (2008) [29] and Ilzetzki et al. (2013) [26] among others. Now, we are left with one more variable namely (1 − )∕(1 − ) and we place it before GDP. This is inspired from the fact that higher value of (1 − )∕(1 − ) will induce greater consumption of locally produced goods and services within a year which results into a bigger GDP but not the vice versa. • One prerequisite before we can formally proceed with our model is to check for the order of integration of our underlying time series. At the first step, we de-trend the data using Hodrick-Prescott filter and check the order of integration of the de-trended time series using Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) unit root test and Phillips-Perron test. We will use these de-trended series in our analysis. • After we are done with all the prerequisites we build a structural VAR model with appropriate number of lags of the endogenous variables. For our proposed model, endogenous variables include government consumption, (1 − )∕(1 − ), GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate appearing in the same order as mentioned. For the conventional estimation, we build a VAR with government consumption, GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate as endogenous variables appearing in the same order as mentioned. • Once the model is built we provide one standard deviation Cholesky shock in government consumption and (1 − )∕(1 − ) and note down both the impact and cumulative responses of GDP. Impact and cumulative response of government consumption to its own shock are noted as well. Moreover, the cumulative responses are appropriately discounted using the respective risk free rates. Then we divide the impact (appropriately discounted cumulative) response of GDP to shocks in government consumption by the impact (appropriately discounted cumulative) response of government consumption to its own shock to estimate the corresponding impact (cumulative) multipliers at different time periods. As we use the data in their natural logarithmic form the multipliers thus calculated also have the same unit and we need to convert them back to their original multiplier unit. To do so, we divide the multipliers thus calculated by the average value government consumption to GDP ratio in the sample used to estimate the results (see for example Gonzalez-Garcia et al. (2013) [30] ). Multipliers thus obtained are named as adjusted impact (cumulative) multipliers all through the text. • After we are done with the estimation of government spending multiplier we resort to variance decomposition of GDP with respect to other endogenous variables. We compare how much of the variance in GDP is attributed to different endogenous variables in the system and we check it for both in the long and short run. Once the methodology has been set we collect relevant data for SVAR estimation. US and UK data regarding total and private consumption, GDP, current account to GDP ratio, real effective exchange rate, tax revenue as percentage of GDP and import as percentage of GDP during the period 1972-2018 are collected from the World Bank data warehouse which are publicly available through the URL: https:// databank .worldbank .org /home .aspx (World Bank (2020) [39] ). Government consumption expenditure is calculated by subtracting private consumption from total consumption. Moreover, to discount US and UK data we use 3M treasury bill rates which are available through the economic database prepared and maintained by Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (Fed St. Louis (2020) [31] ) for US data and the web database maintained at investing .com for UK data (see, Investing (2020) [32]). We begin our analysis by performing unit root test on all the time series data. We apply both Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) test and Phillips-Perron test to test for unit roots in the underlying time series. Although not reported here all the data series are found to be integrated of order one, i.g., (1). Then we apply Hodrick-Prescott filter on the data in order to segregate them into trend and cyclical components. We again apply unit root test on the de-trended time series data and this time all the series are found to be stationary at level. The results of the unit root tests on both the original and de-trended data are available upon request. In the next step, we determine the appropriate lag length for the structural VAR models to be built and the results are presented in Appendix-B of this article. From Appendix-B, it can be seen that four out of five information criteria namely LR, FPE, AIC and HQ suggest taking 6 (six) lags for US data under proposed and conventional framework while SC suggests 2 (two) lags instead. For UK data, three out of five information criteria namely LR, FPE and AIC suggest 06 (six) lags while the other two criteria SC and HQ suggest 02 (two) lags instead for both proposed and conventional framework. As different information criteria suggest different lags for VAR models to be constructed we build a model for each of the suggested lag lengths. To begin with, we build our first structural VAR model following our proposed framework having US government consumption, (1 − )∕(1 − ), GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate as endogenous variables with 02 (two) lags for each of them. Then we apply one standard deviation Cholesky shock in government consumption and (1 − )∕(1 − ) and note down the impact and cumulative response of GDP. Response of GDP to shocks in government consumption and (1 − )∕(1 − ) are depicted in Figs. 1 and 2 respectively. From Fig. 1 , it can be seen that GDP responds positively at Fig. 3 . Impact response of US government consumption to its own shock under proposed framework using lag 2. least for the first ten periods to any change in government consumption. Moreover, from Fig. 2 , we can see that GDP also positively responds to any shocks in (1 − )∕(1 − ) and response reaches a constant steady state level even before period 10. Fig. 3 captures the response of government consumption to its own shock and it is positive as well. These responses are then used to calculate the corresponding impact and cumulative multipliers for US data and the results are presented in Table 1 . Adjusted impact and cumulative multipliers are presented in column 11 and column 12 of Table 1 . From column 11 of Table 1 , it can be seen that the impact multipliers vary between 1.75 to 3.21 in different time periods while the cumulative multipliers vary within the range 2.60 − 3.08. It is noticeable that all the impact and cumulative multipliers are positive which complies with the theoretical underpinning of it. To compare the performance of our model to the conventional one, this time we build a structural VAR model with government consumption, GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate for US data during the period 1972-2018 and provide one standard deviation Cholesky shock in government consumption. Response of GDP to shocks in government consumption and response of government consumption to its own shock are noted and they are pictorially depicted in Figs. 4 and 5 respectively. Both the responses are positive and have almost the same shape as for our proposed model. The corresponding impact and cumulative multipliers are presented in column 11 and column 12 of Table 2 . From column 11 of Table 2 , it can be seen that the impact multipliers move between 1.00-2.67 while cumulative multipliers vary between 2.02-2.60. So, multipliers in our proposed model are found to be somewhat higher than its conventional counterpart. Next, we build a VAR model with our proposed framework with 06 (six) lags for each of the endogenous variables. After the model is built we provide one standard deviation shock in government consumption and (1 − )∕(1 − ) and note down the response of GDP. The impact response of GDP to shocks in government consumption and (1 − )∕(1 − ) Table 3 . From column 11 of Table 3 , it is seen that the impact multipliers move in between 0.64 to 2.66 in different time periods while the cumulative multipliers are found within the range 1.30-2.33. Like our proposed model with 02 (two) lags, all the multipliers are found to be positive. For comparison purpose, we now build a VAR model under conventional framework with 06 (six) lags for each of the endogenous variables and note down the response of GDP to shocks in government consumption and response of government consumption to its own shock as well and the responses are pictorially depicted in Figs. 9 and 10. From Fig. 9 , it can be seen that from period 6 the response of GDP to shocks in Fig. 6 . Impact response of US GDP to shocks in government consumption under proposed framework using lag 6. Table 4 . Once we are done with the US data, we go on building VAR model with UK data during the period 1972-2018. At the first place, we build a structural VAR model under our proposed framework with government consumption, (1 − )∕(1 − ), GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate as endogenous variables with 2 lags. Fig. 11 , it can be seen that GDP responds positively to shocks in government consumption for at least 10 consecutive periods. On the other hand, from Fig. 12 it can be seen that response of GDP to shocks in (1 − )∕(1 − ) is negative for the first 10 periods. However, trend of the response curve depicts that it will eventually become positive for some period immediately after 10. Moreover, response of government consumption to its own shock is depicted in Fig. 13 . The corresponding impact and cumulative multiplier values are tabulated in column 11 and column 12 of Table 5 . From column 11 of Table 5 it can be seen that the impact multipliers start from 0.84 at period 1 and eventually reach 1.33 at period 10. In Fig. 9 . Impact response of US GDP to shocks in government consumption under conventional framework using lag 6. Fig. 10 . Impact response of US government consumption to its own shock under conventional framework using lag 6. Fig. 11 . Impact response of UK GDP to shocks in government consumption under proposed framework using lag 2. To compare the performance of our model with the conventional estimation we now build a structural VAR with government consumption, GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate each having 02 (two) lags and perform impulse response analysis by giving one standard deviation shock in government consumption. Response of GDP to shocks in government consumption and response of government consumption to its own shock are noted down in Figs. 14 and 15 respectively. Like the US data, response of GDP is found to be shifted a bit downward due to the exclusion of the term (1 − )∕(1 − ) as an endogenous variable. Hence, the multiplier values estimated in the conventional approach using the same number of lags are supposed to be lower than that of the proposed approach and it is evident from col- Fig. 13 . Impact response of UK government consumption to its own shock under proposed framework using lag 2. umn 11 and column 12 of Table 6 . From column 11, it can be seen that the impact multipliers in conventional approach vary between 0.79 to 1.14 in different time periods while the cumulative multipliers move in between 0.79 to 1.06. Next, we compare the performance of our model to conventional one by using 06 (six) lags for the endogenous variables in the structural VAR framework. We first construct structural VAR under our proposed framework and note down the response of GDP to shocks in government consumption and (1 − )∕(1 − ). These responses are graphically presented in Figs. 16 and 17 respectively. From Fig. 16 , it can be seen that GDP responds positively to shocks in government consumption and negatively to shocks in (1 − )∕(1 − ) and the patterns are comparable to the ones we have noted for model with 02 (two) lags. Moreover, the responses of government consumption to its own shock are noted in Fig. 18 . Corresponding multiplier values are noted down in column 11 Fig. 15 . Impact response of UK government consumption to its own shock under conventional framework using lag 2. Fig. 16 . Impact response of UK GDP to shocks in government consumption under proposed framework using lag 6. and column 12 of Table 7 . From column 11 and column 12 of Table 7 it can be seen that the impact multipliers vary between 0.39 to 1.70 while the cumulative multipliers move in between 0.41 to 0.80. To compare the performance of our model to the conventional one we now build a structural VAR model using government consumption, GDP, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate as endogenous variables each having 06 (six) lags. After the model is built we provide one standard deviation Cholesky shock in government consumption and note down the responses of GDP and government consumption. Responses of GDP to shocks in government consumption and responses of government consumption to its own shock are represented in Figs. 19 and 20 respectively. Corresponding multiplier values are depicted in column 11 and column 12 of Table 8 . It is evident from Table 8 that the impact multipliers vary between 0.34 to 1.12 while the cumulative multipliers vary from 0.48 to 0.62. So, also in this case, our estimated values of the fiscal multipliers are a bit larger than its conventional estimates. After we are done with the impulse response analysis we now check how much of the variance in GDP can be explained in terms of different endogenous variables included into the SVAR analysis. Results of variance decomposition of US GDP under proposed framework with 02 (two) lags are presented in Table 9 . From Table 9 , it can be seen that 6.29% variance of US GDP is attributed to government consumption while 15.81%, 0.00% and 0.00% of the variance are due to (1 − )∕(1 − ), current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate at period 1. Hence, majority of the variance of GDP is attributed to (1 − )∕(1 − ) at period 1. However, as times passes by contribution of (1 − )∕(1 − ) to the variance of US GDP declines gradually and at period 10, it becomes 5.65%. Nevertheless, the contribution of Fig. 19 . Impact response of UK GDP to shocks in government consumption under conventional framework using lag 6. Fig. 20 . Impact response of UK government consumption to its own shock under conventional framework using lag 6. (1 − )∕(1 − ) to the variance of GDP is still greater than that of real effective exchange rate which is widely included into the SVAR analysis of the fiscal multipliers. Moreover, variance decomposition of US GDP when we discard (1 − )∕(1 − ) from the SVAR model is presented in Table 10 . From Table 10 , we can see that the contribution of current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate to the variance in GDP are still 0.00 (zero) at period 1. It is not hard to notice that when we eliminate (1 − )∕(1 − ) from our model, its contribution (15.81%) to the variance in GDP is simply added back to GDP itself and at period 1, 94.93% of the variance in US GDP is attributed to GDP itself. Moreover, at period 10, 11.26%, 6.01% and 3.00% of the variance in GDP are attributed to government consumption, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate as can be seen from Table 10 . These contributions are substantially lower than the contributions they have made under our proposed model using the same number of lags. Hence, adding (1 − )∕(1 − ) into SVAR simply enhances the ability of other variables in the system to more clearly capture the variance in US GDP than ever before. Next, variance decompositions of US GDP under our proposed and conventional framework using 06 (six) lags are presented in Table 11 and 12 respectively. From Table 11 , we can see that 7.68% variance of the US GDP is attributed to (1 − )∕(1 − ) at period 1 which is greater than the contribution of any other variables in the model. At period 10, (1 − )∕(1 − ) can explain 5.73% of the variance in GDP which is still greater than the contribution of government consumption, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate. For the conventional model when we discard (1 − )∕(1 − ) as an endogenous variable we can see that the ability of government consumption and current account to GDP ratio in explaining variance in GDP are reduced substantially while the capacity of real effective exchange rate in this regard enhances a little bit (see the last row of Table 12 ). Variance decomposition of UK GDP under our proposed framework with 02 lags is presented at Table 13 . We can see from Table 13 that at period 1, 2.59% of the variance in GDP is attributed to (1 − )∕(1 − ) which is greater than the contribution of government consumption, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate. On the other hand at period 10, contribution of (1 − )∕(1 − ) to the variance of UK GDP is enhanced up to 5.57% which is greater than that of current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate. If we discard (1 − )∕(1 − ) from our SVAR model then we can see that the contributions of government consumption, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate in explaining variance in GDP have been greatly reduced (as can be seen from Table 14) . Next, the variance decomposition of UK GDP under our proposed framework with 06 (six) lags for the endogenous variables is presented in Table 15 . As we can see from Table 15 , 3.73% of the variance in UK GDP is due to (1 − )∕(1 − ) at period 1 which is greater than the contribution of any other endogenous variable in the system. For period 10, 21.28% of the variance in GDP can be explained in terms of (1 − )∕(1 − ) which is substantially greater than the contributions of government consumption, current account to GDP ratio and real effective exchange rate. On the other hand, when we discard (1 − )∕(1 − ) as an endogenous variable strengths of the remaining variables in explaining variations in GDP have been greatly reduced (as can be seen from Table 16 ). Right now, the need of a reliable estimate of the fiscal multiplier is more acute than ever before. As the COVID-19 pandemic is ravaging the global economic landscape, mass lay off and winding up become common sights at the work places across the globe [33] . While the impact of the pandemic will vary from country to country it is hurting societies and economies at their very core and is likely to increase poverty and inequalities at a daunting scale [34] . To combat this un- precedented situation of unemployment and slow (or even negative) economic growth governments around the globe have come out of their austerity with generous stimulus packages aiming to reinstate the economy at its original level. For example, in March, 2020 US government has enacted the largest economic stimulus package in history worthing $2.00 trillion in corona virus aid followed by other subsequent generous stimulus bringing the US budget deficit to record level [35] . Meanwhile, the UK government has declared $37 billion stimulus package intended to boost up the local job market now trembling at the rages of the pandemic [36] . As the government spending soars on the backdrop of COVID-19 it is important to know how well such stimulus works in reviving the economy. One tool that comes in handy in this regard is the fiscal multipliers estimated through structural VAR analysis. In fact, the theories of the fiscal multipliers have been used many times in the history to gauge the efficacy of different government sponsored stimulus packages including the famous American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 after the great recession of 2007-2009 [8] . So, to know how well the stimulus works, government expenditure, GDP and other macro-economic data can be arranged in a structural VAR set up according to our proposed methodology which, we hope, will entail a relatively more reliable estimate of the fiscal multipliers that may help the governments across the globe to take a well-informed decision regarding public spending. Apart from modeling the economy as a whole, sectoral data can be put into use to judge the potency of the government sponsored stimulus program in a particular segment of the economy in terms of output and employment in the post-pandemic economic landscape. One of the main reservations of the current study is that we only estimate the fiscal multipliers in the modified experimental set up for US and UK data only. There is a whole array of other countries for which the empirical estimation and conclusion thereon are not tested. The study can be effectively extended by including more countries in the analysis. Moreover, the dependency of the fiscal multipliers on ex-change rate regime, extent of public debt, persistent financial crisis etcetera is yet to be tested which is beyond the scope of the current study. Conventional SVAR based estimate of fiscal multiplier does not account for at least 04 (four) macroeconomic variables (if not more) namely average propensity to consume, average propensity to import, average tax rate and the velocity of money which we argue can significantly influence the estimation of the multipliers. Here, we incorporate the aforementioned variables into an SVAR set up in a logically comprehensible way and perform impulse response analysis on the modified set up. Multipliers thus obtained are then compared to their conventional peers in order to identify whether there exists a significant difference between the two. From our empirical analysis we can conclude that our estimates of the government spending multipliers are a bit higher than the one estimated under conventional SVAR framework. Moreover, in some cases, when the multipliers tend to move abruptly between positive and negative values (thus giving no clear indication regarding the implementation of stimulus packages) under conventional framework, our approach just smooths out the divergence and provides rather consistent positive estimates for the fiscal multipliers. Last but not the least, our empirical analysis also suggests that taking (1 − )∕(1 − ) as endogenous variable into the structural VAR model substantially adds to the capacity of other variables in the system to explain variance in real output. A.M. Nizam: Conceived and designed the experiments; Performed the experiments; Analyzed and interpreted the data; Wrote the paper. This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors. The author declares no conflict of interest. The views expressed in the article are of the author's and do not necessarily reflect the official view of the Central Bank of Bangladesh in this regard (the institution where the author works). Supplementary content related to this article has been published online at https://doi .org /10 .1016 /j .heliyon .2020 .e05512. The Multiplier Theory Can Lloyd George Do It? Modern Macroeconomics: Its Origins, Development and Current State The relation of home investment to unemployment International difficulties arising out of the financing of public works during a depression The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money Much ado about multipliers The Economic Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: estimates based on a new measure of fiscal shocks Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in OECD countries What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks? Fiscal multipliers Fiscal Multipliers: Size, Determinants, and Use in Macroeconomic Projections, IMF, Fiscal Affairs Division The effects of public spending shocks on trade balances and budget deficits in the European Union Macroeconomic effects from government purchases and taxes By how much does GDP rise if the government buys more output? Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater During Periods of Slack? Evidence from 20th Century Historical Data, NBER Working Paper 18769 A model-based evaluation of the debate on the size of the tax multiplier What fiscal policy is most effective? A meta-regression analysis Why Do Government Spending Multipliers Differ? A Meta-Analysis We just estimated twenty million fiscal multipliers What determines government spending multipliers? Fiscal Multipliers in Recession and Expansion, NBER Working Paper 17447 Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? The Effects of Fiscal Policy on Consumption and Employment: Theory and Evidence, Centre for Economic Policy Research Fiscal policy shocks in the euro area and the US -an empirical assessment, Institute for Fiscal Studies Twin deficit or twin divergence? Fiscal policy, current account, and real exchange rate in the U.S Fiscal Multipliers in the ECCU Federal reserve economic data (FRED) UNDP, Socio-economic impact of Covid-19 Coronavirus congress passes $484bn economic relief bill UK announces £30 billion Covid-19 stimulus package aimed at saving jobs Public expenditure and the demand for labour Identifying government spending shocks: it's all in the timing World Bank Supplementary material related to this article can be found online at https://doi .org /10 .1016 /j .heliyon .2020 .e05512.