key: cord-0951601-qcp3u20z authors: Mulligan, Casey B. title: Economic Activity and the Value of Medical Innovation during a Pandemic date: 2021-06-09 journal: Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis DOI: 10.1017/bca.2021.5 sha: 5531629fc2b6a534da6a157237d3691c07544ae4 doc_id: 951601 cord_uid: qcp3u20z The “shutdown” economy of April 2020 is compared to a normally functioning economy both in terms of market and nonmarket activities. Three novel methods and data indicate that a full shutdown of “nonessential” activities puts market production about 25 % below normal in the short run. At an annual rate, a full shutdown costs $9 trillion, or about $18,000 per household per quarter. Employment already fell 24 million by early April 2020. These costs indicate, among other things, the value of innovation in both health and general business sectors that can accelerate the time when, and the degree to which, normal activity resumes. We have been fighting a war against the COVID-19 virus. The war presents an obvious and massive tradeoff between "guns"activities whose primary purpose is war productionand "butter," which refers to the normal activities of households and businesses. Without any improvement in our techniques for fighting the war, the sacrifices by households and businesses would be staggering and historically unprecedented. This paper enumerates and quantifies the sacrifices. The lost surplus from market activity, while massive, nonetheless understates the true costs of the sacrifices that households and businesses make during a period of shutdown. I estimate that a full shutdown of nonessential activities costs almost $18,000 per household per quarter of before counting any health costs or monetizing any intrinsic costs of forgone civil liberties. These opportunity costs are why better techniques for fighting the war are incredibly valuable. Shortly before the COVID-19 pandemic, a report from the White House (Council of Economic Advisers, 2019b) concluded that medical innovation during a pandemic is better oriented for speed than for efficacy. For example, it is better to have a partially effective vaccine before the pandemic runs its course than a more effective one that is not available until after the pandemic is over. As the contemporaneous Presidential Executive Order put it, "vaccination is the most effective defense" during a pandemic (U.S. President, 2019 ). Yet federal policy threatened to be a major barrier to that innovation. Dr. Anthony Fauci, the director of the National Institute of Allergy and Infectious Diseases, told the U.S. Senate in March 2020 that "a vaccine … will take at least a year or year and a half" largely because, he said, approval by the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) necessarily requires a year or more. 1 Valuable pandemic treatments may also come from drugs in the early stages of development, drugs that have been proven safe but not yet federally approved, as well as the repurposing of drugs that were originally invented for different medical conditions. New equipment and techniques for prevention, such as the manufacture of disease-testing equipment and tools for tracing contacts of infected patients, are also possible. Medical innovation is not limited to the activities of health professionals. Business and civic organizations can also innovate how they accomplish their traditional missions while mitigating harms from COVID-19 (Mulligan, 2021b) . To name some examples, retailers such as Walmart and Whole Foods implemented special shopping hours for senior citizens, who are more vulnerable to the virus, so that they did not have to mingle with nonelderly shoppers. Schools learned to gather in-person with transmission rates one or two orders of magnitude below the rates in the surrounding communities (Falk et al., 2021; Zimmerman et al., 2021) . But organizations can hardly innovate when they are prohibited from operating. Three novel methods and data available by early April 2020 provide estimates of the effect of a full shutdown of "nonessential" businesses put market production about 25 % below normal in the short run. Those methods include (i) historical data on the relationship between annual GDP and the number of workdays in a year, (ii) historical data on the fraction of government labor that has been deemed "essential" during government shutdowns, and (iii) new data from Bick and Blandin (2020) on the amount and location of aggregate work hours circa 1 April 2020. Market production is not synonymous with welfare because factors of production can move into the nonmarket sector, which itself is economically important even in normal times. However, there are two reasons why the dollar amount of the reduction in GDP understates the welfare cost of a shutdown. The first reason is that 1 NBC News (2020). In May, FDA would change its approach with Operation WARP speed, with the result being two vaccines approved and administered to the general public as early as 14 December 2020. Operation Warp speed did not bypass safety and efficacy trials, but rather ran them in parallel with massmanufacturing investment and less bureaucratic dead time. Some may argue that the general public should have had the option to receive vaccines even earlierwhile still in trialsalthough others might warn against the reputation costs of administering an unsafe or ineffective vaccine while the world is watching. GDP measures only averages, whereas the direct effects of shutdown are unequally distributed. The inequality apparently has costs by itself, because governments attempt to mitigate those costs by implementing relief efforts that will further reduce GDP both during the shutdown and afterwards. This paper estimates a lower bound from the deadweight costs of taxationalmost $4 trillion per year that a full shutdown laststhat will someday be required to finance the relief efforts. The second reason is that shutting down nonessential businesses makes the nonmarket sector less productive too because the sector is starved of market inputs. Human capital accumulation is an important instance with more than 70 million children and young adults normally enrolled in school and tens of millions more would be accumulating skills during the early phase of their careers. I estimate that a full shutdown of nonessential businesses reduces market production by almost $6 trillion per year of shutdown. Relief efforts further reduce the current value of future economic activity by almost $4 trillion per year of full shutdown. Black markets and additional time in the nonmarket sector replace about $2 trillion of the $9 trillion of lost market production. I estimate that the value of nonmarket production falls below what it would be if the normal market inputs were available by about $1.5 trillion per year of shutdown. The sum of these puts the welfare costs at almost $9 trillion per year of full shutdown. 2 Real costs of "shutdown" Government officials around the world ordered businesses shut and families to stay in their homes except for essential activities. Using county-level data for the USA Alexander and Karger (2020) found that stay-at-home orders took effect at staggered dates between 17 March and 7 April 2020. 2 Many states closed schools effective Monday 16 March, which is the same day that the Moderna vaccine against COVID-19 was first administered to human participants in clinical trials on its path for approval on 18 December (Grady et al., 2020) . Individuals have private incentives to avoid human interactions when a dangerous and contagious disease is prevalent in the population (Philipson & Posner, 1993) . Indeed, Goolsbee and Syverson (2021) conclude that most of the reduction in economic activity in March and April was voluntary rather than an effect of public 2 ND, SD, NE, IA, and AR did not have a stay-at-home order. Only parts of UT, WY, and OK had them (Mervosh et al., 2020) . A number of social distancing regulations were relaxed between 20 April and 1 June. Many others remained much longer, for example with large urban school buildings closed for most, if not all, of the 2020-2021 school year. A number of public-school reopenings during 2020-2021 were tied to medical innovation directly, and also indirectly through community case counts. policies. 3 The degree to which a full shutdown is privately or publicly motivated is not necessarily relevant for the question addressed in this paper, which is the cost of full shutdown compared to a "normal" no-pandemic situation. This is a relevant comparison for the purposes of policy decisions affecting innovation in medicines and disease testing, as well as policies that facilitate scaling the manufacturing and distribution of protective equipment and therapies that could end shutdowns earlier, whether they be mandated or voluntary. 4 However, a voluntary partial shutdown would likely cost less than a mandatory partial shutdown because in the former case individuals and businesses would still be free to pursue the "nonessential" activities that are most valuable to them. 5 To be clear, the cost-enumeration exercise can be consistent with a conclusion that the war is worth fightingthat depends on quantifying the benefits, which are surely significant given the value that people place on health and longevity. Although this paper does not address the question of whether a shutdown is better than no policy response, it offers some of the essential ingredients for such an analysis. When it comes to projecting the welfare costs of shutting the economy, scholars have the advantage of almost a century's worth of collective experience on measuring economic activity in market economies. We have the system of national accounts, which was developed by economists based on the principles of welfare economics. 6 Gaps in the national accounts are well known and quantified in many cases. The shutdown method of fighting the war on the virus directly affects how people allocate their time. That includes what they do, where they do it, and with whom. Because normal time allocation includes elements of saving and capital accumulation, such as learning skills, the economic effects of the war are felt into the future as stocks of physical and human capital are reduced. For enumeration purposes, I distinguish market production activities from all other activities, especially because market production is counted in conventionally measured GDP whereas leisure activities are not. Although I refer to the nonmarket activities as "leisure," they include religious gatherings and forms of effort such as student effort in school and effort put toward housework. Both market production and leisure activities are significantly affected by shutdown. Shutdown reduces the amount and effectiveness with which people work. Aggregate effects of this can be measured on either the production side of the national accounts, as the value of goods and services not produced, or the income side as reductions in total incomes. Either approach yields the same result, up to measurement error. 7 However, the incidencethe distribution of impact across industries, occupations, and income groupsis different from the production and income perspectives, depending on how the production losses are shared. Momentarily putting aside costs associated with leisure activities, the shutdown can be analogized with a change in the number of holidays and weekends ("nonwork days"). A well-studied, albeit obscure, element of national income accounting is the adjustment for the fact that the number of nonwork days normally varies from year to year. 8 A normal year has about 251 working days and about 114 nonworking days. 9 The national accountants have found that adding a nonwork day to the year reduces the year's real GDP by about 0.1 % and have been applying this estimate to both the production and real income accounts. 10 Adding a nonwork day to a quarter would therefore reduce the quarter's unadjusted real GDP by about 0.4 %. Extrapolating from this finding, removing all of the working days from a quarter is 62 or 63 times this, or 25 %. In other words, if seasonally adjusted GDP 2020-Q2 would have been $5.5 trillion at a quarterly rate, then changing all of that quarter's working days to the functional equivalent of a weekend or holiday would reduce the quarter's GDP to $4.2 trillion. 11 Applying the same approach to 2020-Q1, with a shutdown occurring for one-eighth of the quarter, 2020-Q1 real GDP (in 2020-Q2 prices) would be $5.4 trillion. The quarter-over-quarter growth rate of seasonally adjusted real GDP would, expressed at annual rates, therefore be À10 % in Q1 and À63 % in Q2. 12 The Q2 growth rate would be less negative to the extent that a 7 Adding the opportunity costs of production to the reductions in incomes would be double counting. 8 Leap years also create variation in the total number of days. 9 A year has 52 weeks plus an additional one or 2 days, for a total of between 104 and 106 weekend days. There were 10 federal holidays. The second quarter always had exactly 13 weeks and one federal holiday. 10 European Central Bank (2004). Note that 0.1 % is much less than 1/251; the estimate implies that the average nonworking day has two-thirds the GDP of a working day. 11 This is the sum of Table 1 's first row with its addendum row. 12 This assumes a baseline annual growth rate of 2 % and applies it one for one. The formula for the annualized growth rate in Q2 is 1À0:004Â62:5 1À0:004Â62:5=8 4 Â 1:02 À 1 ¼ À63 %. The normal seasonal adjustment for Economic activity and the value of medical innovation 5 shutdown was in place for only part of the quarter or for part of the country, as turned out to be the case. 13 Shutdown is not exactly the functional equivalent of changing workdays to weekends or holidays. On one hand, a segment of the workforce will engage in telework during shutdown that they would not perform on a normal weekend or holiday. Other segments or regions will be exempt from shutdown, with definitions of "essential" work varying by jurisdiction. This by itself suggests that the $4.2 trillion estimate is too pessimistic. On the other hand, much of the normal weekend activity such as restaurants, entertainment, and religious activities did not occur during shutdown. This by itself suggests that the $4.2 trillion estimate is too optimistic. 14 A second method uses the production side alone and focuses on quantities of capital and labor engaged in production. Labor is reduced by the number of "nonessential" employees, which has been about 30 % during federal shutdowns. 15 In some of the industries, real capital will continue to be used, albeit by fewer employees. Other industries will not use their capital, although it may be repurposed, such as a hotel being used as a hospital ward. To be conservative, I assume that few industries increase their labor-capital ratio. 16 The reduction in capital input is therefore somewhere between 0 and 30 %; I assume 15 %. History has repeatedly shown that labor is more important in the production process than capital, so that by the second method real GDP is reduced 26 % during a full shutdown. 17 A third method takes a similar approach, but measures the labor reduction from a recent survey conducted by Bick and Blandin (2021) . They find that working hours per working age adult in April were 23 % below February. 18 Moreover, among those working in February 2020, between 58 and 60 % were absent in April from their workplaces either due to not working or working from home. 19 If half of the capital in those workplaces were idle and not replaced by capital located in home offices, then capital utilization fell by 30 % and GDP by 25 %. My estimate of the GDP effect of shutdown, shown in Table 1 and what follows, is 25.4 %, which is the average of the three methods that range from 25 to 26 %. 20 The GDP estimates do not reflect black markets. But, as seen with border patrol and the war on drugs, government regulation attempting to block valuable gains from trade will result in black market activity. Businesses will also work the gray area, lobbying and distorting their operations to have more activities declared "essential." Black-market activity is far less productive than legitimate activity, which is why it does not come close to replacing the "nonessential" sales that were banned. But it still has value, which is why the best welfare effects of shutdown may be less pessimistic than analysis assuming zero black market. 21 I assume that black markets replace 25 % of the gains from trade, based on studies of illegal drugs. 22 However, value generated in black markets is typically not measured as part of GDP. Indeed, black markets compete with legitimate markets for the factors of production and by this channel would reduce measured real GDP even more than would occur without black markets (Fleming et al., 2000) . Because the black market is entirely different in terms of measurement (albeit perhaps similar in terms of transactions), Table 1 's "nonmarket" heading shows the $513 billion annual value of black market transactions that were formerly in the legitimate economy. Section 2.3 discusses other activities, such as leisure time and the effort of students, that are more intrinsically nonmarket. Although the national income accounts were designed on the basis of the principles of welfare economics, GDP growth is not exactly a benefit and GDP reduction is not exactly a welfare cost because valuable activities and assets such as home production, elements of human capital accumulation, and environmental 18 The version of their paper available in April 2020 (Bick & Blandin, 2020) , which had less April data and different weighting methods, showed À28 %. 19 I obtain this range by assuming that (i) the share of February 2020 employment from home was 10 %, corresponding to Bick and Blandin's estimate from the 2017 and 2018 March ATUS, (ii) that those previously working at home are disproportionately likely to keep their jobs, and (iii) no jobs that were being done at home were done outside the home during shutdown. 20 Note that Table 1 contains point estimates of costs and therefore is not comparable to "worst case" estimates. 21 But government regulators can hardly defend their shutdown regulations on the grounds that they will not be obeyed! Moreover, black markets add another social cost by eroding respect for law and order. 22 The war on drugs increases the retail price (and unit cost to suppliers) by roughly a factor of four and reduces the quantity consumed by a factor of two (Jaffe et al., 2019, Figure 12 -1). Illegal drug sellers have had many years to accumulate organizational and other capital that lockdown violators did not. On the other side, drug war enforcers have had many years that lockdown enforcers have not. quality are not yet recognized in the official national accounts (Hartwick, 1990; Nordhaus & Kokkelenberg, 1999; Jorgenson, 2009; Jorgenson, 2010) . However, as discussed further below, the GDP losses cited above prove to reasonably approximate more comprehensive welfare losses. The massive costs of shutting down "nonessential" activities are not shared equally. Some workers are still able to draw a normal salary even while their industry is less active. Others work in industries that are booming as a result of the pandemic. The table shows point estimates of costs that could be netted against point estimates of health benefits such as deaths averted by shutdown. The impact on market production is taken as À25.4%, which is the average of three estimation methods. Welfare costs of market production also reflect the opportunity costs of capital out of service. Deadweight costs of relief policy are financing costs, without any distribution costs. School time is for full-time students only. The estimates do not include the entire effect of expanding social insurance, which would be to further shift inputs from the market to nonmarket sectors. The additional demand for social insurance itself reflects costs of shutdown that are not captured by the averages. Abbreviations: OJT, on-the-job training; OLF, out of the labor force. Because the aggregate reduction in the value of what is produced must equal the aggregate reduction in total income, the costs of shutdown will fall disproportionately on the remainder of the population that are not in these circumstances. Table 1 shows only averages. Public programs were created and expanded with the intention of helping some of those who were disproportionately bearing the costs. Redistribution policy may help distribute the aggregate costs more fairly, but is unlikely to reduce the aggregate cost. 23 Even while these policies assist those who are not working because of the pandemic, they do not replace the work and production that the workers would have been doing. The fact that the demand for redistribution increases in these situations suggests that the inequality itself is a cost large enough that people are willing to tolerate further increases in the average costs (i.e., further decreases in GDP, both during the shutdown and afterwards) in order to mitigate the costs for those disproportionately affected (Mulligan, 2012, Chapter 10; 2014) . In other words, the costs of inequality are reduced by replacing them with a different kind of cost: reductions in GDP during and after the shutdown. To the extent that the costs of inequality are not fully eliminated, the costs associated with the relief-induced GDP reductions (estimated in this paper) are a lower bound on the cost associated with the inequality. Four major federal relief packages were passed in the first year of the pandemic recession: the Families First Coronavirus Response Act (FFCRA, 3/18/2020), the Coronavirus Aid, Relief, and Economic Security Act (CARES, 3/27/2020), part of the Consolidated Appropriations Act (CAA, 12/27/2020), and the American Rescue Plan Act (ARPA, 3/11/2021). The Congressional Budget Office (2020a, b) estimates that the combined financing for FFCRA and CARES, which were both passed when the USA was nearest a full shutdown of nonessential activities, would require $1.95 trillion in present value of additional taxes or reduced federal spending. The latter two were passed when the economy was more than half recovered, but totaled $2.7 trillion (Congressional Budget Office, 2021a; b), not counting the normal appropriations funds that were also part of CAA. If both pairs were intended as relief for 6 months of a pandemic, that suggests that a full shutdown requires between $3.9 trillion and $10.9 trillion of redistribution funding at annual rates with a midpoint of $7.4 trillion used for the purposes of Table 1 . The collection of those taxes, or reduction in normal government spending, involves costs that I approximate as half of the 23 It has been suggested that paying people not to work might encourage enough people to stay home at the same time that disease transmission slows down enough to accelerate the end of the pandemic. However, the 2020 unemployment payments did not have that effect in the USA, where it appears that the end of the pandemic was driven instead by vaccine distribution. Mulligan (2021b) cites findings that COVID-19 transmission is particularly high at home (Grijalva et al., 2020) , as compared to at least some workplaces such as hospitals (Richterman et al., 2020) and schools (Zimmerman et al., 2021) . amount of the tax. 24 In addition to the financing costs, the distribution of the funds from the relief packages will also reduce GDP by reducing incentives to work, reducing the incentives of workers to shift into industries that need them most, and otherwise distorting the behavior of individuals and businesses (Mulligan, 2012) . I did not estimate the fund-distribution costs or include them in Table 1 . 25 The nonmarket/home sector is affected by shutdown through two basic channels, as shown in Table 1 . The first channel is discussed above: the nonmarket sector has additional labor that has been forced out of the market sector. The second channel is that the nonmarket sector becomes less productive, both for the nonmarket time that normally exists as well as the additional nonmarket time coming from the market sector, because even in their nonwork activities people are restricted in terms of where they go and how they associate with others. The percentage change in the value created in the nonmarket sector combines the two channels and is approximately the sum of the (positive) percentage change in labor input and the (negative) percentage change of nonmarket productivity. 26 An important example of the second channel is the time allocation of children and young adults who would normally be enrolled in school but during a shutdown spend their time at home. Their learning from normal face-to-face interactions with teachers and fellow students is not fully reflected in GDP, but is nonetheless valuable. In other cases, as with religious gatherings, entertainment, and tourism, shutdowns reduce the value of these activities by limiting how people can congregate and the market inputs that can be used as part of the leisure activity. Because the national accounts are based on the principles of welfare economics, GDP would ideally capture value created or destroyed in both the market and nonmarket sectors. Measurement challenges have so far limited the scope of conventional GDP measures to the market sector. Conventional GDP measures therefore miss the value of additional nonmarket time added by the shutdown (the first channel) 24 My approximation is based on the "marginal cost of public funds" (Dahlby, 2008) , as estimated for the U.S. economy by Council of Economic Advisers (2019a) by considering the various implicit and explicit taxes on income, payroll, and sales. For this purpose I assume, as Atkinson and Stern (1974) do, that the marginal cost of public funds is the same regardless of when the financing occurs and whether it occurs from less spending or more taxes. Note that the costs of relief packages would be much larger if their revenue requirements push the USA to the top of its Laffer curve. 25 Mulligan and Blase (2020) calculate enough to show that distribution of CARES funds will noticeably reduce aggregate employment. 26 The approximation is exact when the changes are measured in logarithms rather than percentages. as well as the reduced productivity of nonmarket time (the second channel). This section provides estimates of the two, which can be added to the GDP losses from Section 2.1 to arrive at a welfare loss of shutdown as compared to normal economic activity. To estimate the nonmarket value of added labor, I use the short run of the neoclassical growth model, which is essentially a labor supply and demand framework. This value is below the after-tax real wage that would normally prevail, but above the marginal value of time with a shutdown, which I estimate to be 49 % of its normal value. 27 Due to a baseline 48 % marginal tax rate (inclusive of implicit taxes on employment and labor income), the baseline marginal value of nonmarket time is itself significantly below its value in the market sector. Due to the baseline distortion and the nontrivial gap on the labor supply curve between baseline and shutdown, I estimate that the total value of the time added to the nonmarket sector is about $7 billion per day (see Table 1 ), or about 30 % of the reduction in real GDP. Simply put, about two-thirds of the $22 billion daily GDP loss is a welfare loss, even without considering any productivity change in the nonmarket sector or anything about the incidence of the GDP loss. Full-time schooling, where there are normally about 73 million children and young adults enrolled, is the part of the nonmarket sector's productivity loss that is easiest to quantify. Their time and efforts, which are known as "foregone earnings" and not counted in conventional GDP measures, are combined with direct schooling costs such as the education industry's payroll and capital expenses because the students, their parents, or their community value the results of schooling. I quantify the nonmarket component of the value of school according to two methods: one based on inputs and the other based on outputs. For the input approach, note that the direct costs of schooling (e.g., salaries for teachers and administrators) were $370 billion in 2018. Various studies, such as Breton (2013)) estimate that foregone earnings are about 102 % of the direct costs, which would be $377 billion in 2018, or about $4.3 per hour that the average student was in school. An important output of schooling is enhanced earnings during adulthood. If a yearlong shutdown resulted in today's students reaching adulthood with an average of one year less of schooling, that would reduce their earnings by what labor economists call "the rate of return to schooling" (Becker, 1964 (Becker, /1993 Mincer, 1974) . Taking that return to be 8 % per year of schooling and the present value of lifetime earnings to be $417,000 (that corresponds to a starting salary of about $25,000), losing a year of schooling costs $33,000 from the perspective of a young adult transitioning from school to the labor market. For a student 8 years before that point, the present value of that loss is about $21,000 or about $17.50 per hour spent in school. As noted above, about half of that output should be attributed to teachers and administrators, thereby putting the value of output generated by the average student's hour in school at $8.84. The average estimate from the two approaches is therefore $6.58 per hour of student time. Some schooling still occurs during shutdown, such as learning remotely. I take the loss of student output attributable to their time and effort to be half of the $6.58, or about $3.29 per hour that they would have been in school. As shown in Table 1 , the lost value of schooling is $287 billion per year of shutdown, or $72 billion per quarter. 28 Readers may also be interested in the lost schooling output during a full shutdown, including the output that is already counted in the conventional national accounts. Averaging the input and output methods, the remote-learning loss is $43 per student per school day, or $666 per teacher per school day. In aggregate, the loss is $3.2 billion per school day. 29 Learning does not stop at graduation. Postgraduation workers learn on the job, which shifts the composition of their compensation toward skill acquisition and away from the cash and other fringe benefits that are part of conventionally measured GDP (Rosen, 1972) . Although the market sector may be the physical location of this learning, I count the foregone earnings as "nonmarket" because it is usually unmeasured. I estimate the value of foregone earnings using the cross-section age-earnings profile and the average of two estimates of the age-training profile (Mulligan, 1998) . During a shutdown, this learning does not occur for 30 % of the workforce, although (as with market production) I assume that about one-third of its value is replaced with nonmarket activity. The net opportunity cost associated with on-the-job training (OJT) is therefore about $107 billion at an annual rate, as shown in Table 1 . The normal population has even more adults not in the labor force than full-time students, not to mention all of the time that workers normally spend outside of work. If a shutdown also reduced the hourly value of their time by $3.29 for 2000 h per year for those out of the labor force and for 500 h per year for those who work, that would be a loss of $1.1 trillion at an annual rate (see the final three nonmarket rows of Table 1 ). 28 Note that I estimate private values of schooling. The fact that schooling is compulsory at younger ages and subsidized at all ages suggests that the social value of schooling might be even greater. If so, the lost social value is even greater than shown in Table 1 . 29 The $1.1 billion daily amount in Table 1 's "School time" row refers only to the part of the school output that is not counted in conventional GDP. Also Table 1 's days refer to school days (180 per year) rather than work days (251 per year). Medical innovation can reduce the duration and severity of pandemics. In doing so, innovation reduces the duration and severity of the direct health costs as well as the costs of economic shutdowns intended to mitigate the health costs. As long as it remains a major barrier to medical innovation, regulation will unnecessarily add to the economic and health costs of the current pandemic (Peltzman, 1973; Philipson & Sun, 2008) . Innovation is not finished when scientists discover a new medicine, device, or technique and demonstrate its safety. Pandemic medicines and equipment need to be manufactured and distributed on a massive scale. Personnel need to be trained to administer new treatments. These processes can be slowed by regulatory barriers ranging from federal inspections of facilities manufacturing drugs and devices to state occupational licensure. Although not new, disease testing and contact tracing are essential techniques that are scalable in principle, but early in the pandemic were unavailable in the USA in more than small quantities. Regulatory barriers slow both the manufacturing of these devices and techniques as well as the development of more scalable methods for distributing them. Medical innovation has proven to be enormously valuable. Between 1970 and 1998, the average year of medical discoveries added more than a trillion dollars to national wealth (Murphy & Topel, 2003) . These include discoveries that reduced mortality from premature birth, heart disease, and cancer. All age groups benefitted from new drugs that reduce mortality, in amounts that far exceed the research and development costs for those drugs (Lichtenberg, 2003) . Vaccines and treatments for viruses are especially active areas of medical research because each year's viruses have unique genetics (Council of Economic Advisers, 2019b). Council of Economic Advisers (CEA) estimated that the value, in terms of reduced mortality, of a vaccine against a flu pandemic would be up to $4 trillion if it could be produced and distributed to millions of patients. A vaccine or treatment for COVID-19 would not only reduce mortality but would also save $34 billion for each working day that nonessential economic activities could be resumed. 30 A vaccine or treatment that allows partial resumption, or full resumption from a baseline of partial resumption, would have savings that are a corresponding fraction of the $34 billion per working day. Unlike the mortality savings, the value of resuming these activities is higher the further that the pandemic has progressed. Twenty-two COVID-19 medicines were in development as of March 2020 (PhRMA, 2020). The Moderna vaccine against COVID-19, which would ultimately be approved 18 December, is an example of how effective medical innovation is possible even early in a pandemic. Initially moving faster than the social-distancing regulators, the vaccine was formulated in January 2020 and first administered to human participants in clinical trials on 16 March (Grady et al., 2020) . 31 In addition, physicians, hospitals, and pharmaceutical companies experimented with existing drugs that were approved for other conditions but had some promise to help coronavirus patients. Employers and workers devised ways to work that are less conducive to spreading the virus (Mulligan, 2021b) . At the intersection of the medical and business communities are virus testing and treatment that would assist in the efforts to have safer workplaces. Regulatory barriers reduce both the number of patients who will directly benefit from a vaccine or treatment and the number of treatments that are available (Peltzman, 1973; Klein & Tabarrok, 2002) . Those barriers, which cost an average of $1.5 billion per approved drug, include processing time by a regulatory agency, added costs for clinical trials, and agency fees (DiMasi et al., 2016) . The average U.S. approved new pharmaceutical and biotech product spends 8 years in the approval process at the FDA, which delays patient benefits and supplier revenues by that length of time (Jørring et al., 2017) . For each approved product, there are more than four products that fail the FDA approval process. FDA new-drug approval consists of several phases. Phase I is a clinical trial to determine the safety of the drug and lasts an average of 16 months. Phase I expenses, including those for drugs that are not approved, are about a fourth of total drug development expenses (DiMasi et al., 2016) . Eight of the twenty-two COVID-19 medicines in development had already reached Phase I or beyond by March 2020. U.S. clinical trial costs are about double of what they are in middle-income countries. Clinical trials must either be conducted in the USA or for foreign trials be demonstrated to adhere to FDA standards. Only drugs shown to be safe in Phase I proceed to the next phases, which are clinical trials to demonstrate effectiveness. The later phases add expenses and postpone the date when the drug can be distributed to patients, but the FDA believes that the efficacy trials provide valuable public information that many companies would not provide if they were not required for approval (Food and Drug Administration, 2017) . Even after a drug is approved, each manufacturer of it must be FDA approved, which in many cases involves the bureaucratic delays associated with a foreign manufacturing site visit. Moreover, FDA product approval delays the beginning of manufacturing because potential manufacturers withhold their investment until they have some certainty that the product will receive FDA approval. 32 FDA new-drug approval is given only for specific indications (disease or medical condition) and dosage. An approved drug can be prescribed for unapproved ("off-label") indications and dosages. Although the FDA does not have jurisdiction over physician practice, the FDA may create malpractice and third-party payment concerns around off-label prescribing by saying that the prescribing physician must be well informed about the relevant medical evidence, which did not exist early in the pandemic for the COVID-19 indication. 33 Off-label prescriptions may be an especially fertile area for COVID-19 innovation because the drugs have already been shown to be safe and have proven manufacturing and distribution facilities. The drugs are often available as generics. Outside the USA, a large number of COVID-19 patients received a range of offlabel therapies such as hydroxychloroquine and remdesivir. 34 Even if the lack of a safe harbor for off-label prescriptions delayed the U.S. adoption of off-label COVID-19 prescriptions by a few days, the delay costs would be in the billions of dollars. Pandemics have fundamentally different regulatory costs and benefits (Council of Economic Advisers, 2019b). A pandemic involves a contagious disease, which means that a vaccine or treatment that is somewhat unsafe to the patient may nonetheless confer benefits on the general population by making the patient less contagious. More important, pandemics are also different in that most of the demand for a vaccine or treatment occurs in a span of just a few months. As acknowledged by the passage of the Right to Try Act, patients with short horizons do not benefit from waiting until regulators can ensure the efficacy of a new treatment. 35 The entire world 32 Mulligan (2021a) . Operation Warp Speed was designed to, among other things, alleviate vaccine manufacturing delays by providing manufacturers some financial certainty. 33 Food and Drug Administration (1998). Malpractice concerns may also incentivize hospitals to stockpile such drugs in anticipation of the release of medical evidence that justifies off-label prescribing. 34 Kalil (2020) . Off-label chloroquine and hydroxychloroquine were used in the USA to some extent. 35 In offering various "Fast Track" and "compassionate use" options for the later phases, especially for drugs filling an "unmet medical need," the FDA essentially acknowledges that lengthy approval processes are not necessary in every situation. has a short horizon when it comes to COVID-19 medicines. What good is a safe COVID-19 medicine that emerges only after the pandemic is over? To put it another way, the limited duration of a pandemic is an argument for allowing the entire population to enter the later-phase "trials." Although less exotic, some of the most valuable innovation can be the discovery and implementation of ways to reduce infections in the workplace and the general population. There is also a need to expand testing capacity, to consider testing in the workplace (which requires FDA approval), and to implement contact tracing on a large scale (which has other regulatory barriers). The economic shutdown itself can be a significant barrier to these kinds of progress because it closes the workplaces where many of the new practices would be administered. The presence of a disease-causing virus can be detected by gathering biological samples from a patient and sending them to a laboratory for testing. This requires clinical personnel to gather and record samples as well as testing equipment in the laboratories. Following a positive test result, contact tracing reduces disease transmission (as well as delivering treatments earlier in the disease progression) by identifying contacts and providing those contacts with follow-up monitoring and information (World Health Organization, 2017) . The FDA has removed some of the barriers to developing and implementing COVID-19 tests, although it has activated additional barriers such as those associated with a legally declared public health emergency (Boburg et al., 2020) . As shown in Table 1 , if any one of the innovations in medicine, testing, manufacturing, or workplace mitigation could accelerate the end of a nationwide shutdown by a single workday, that would be worth up to $34 billion (plus the value of health and longevity). If a combination of these innovations could accelerate the end of a nationwide shutdown by just a month, they would be worth up to $720 billion. Accelerating the end by a quarter is worth up to $2 trillion. Shutting down the economy, which was done as protection against the harms of COVID-19, has tremendous costs relative to a normally functioning economy. 36 This 36 Although this paper does not address the question of whether a shutdown is better than no policy response, it offers some of the essential ingredients for such an analysis. In also provides ingredients for estimating the dynamics of the economic burden of the pandemic, which I do at http://pandemiccosts.com. paper enumerates and attempts to quantify the costs, including opportunity costs in the nonmarket sector. At an annual rate, a full shutdown costs $9 trillion, or about $18,000 per household per quarter. By including costs accruing in the nonmarket sector, my estimates are consistent with the findings of others that the period of shutdowns were also times when drug overdoses and domestic violence spiked while student academic and social learning stalled. 37 The reward to finding alternative protections that allow more normal economic activity is therefore commensurately tremendous. Medical innovation may provide such alternatives, but is handicapped by federal and state regulations, including the shutdowns themselves as well as rules affecting innovation financial returns such as patent protections and export restrictions. Curiously, authorities administered shutdowns without proving safety or efficacy, but medical innovators were not legally allowed to sell their product to voluntary consumers without doing so. A COVID-19 vaccine, for example, would be formulated and administered to humans as part of regulated clinical trials before the first stay-at-home order in the USA, but would not reach consumers until long after social-distancing regulations were tried on a massive scale. Do Stay-at-Home Orders Cause People to Stay at Home? Effects of Stay-at-Home Orders on Consumer Behavior Pigou, Taxation and Public Goods The Coronavirus and the Great Influenza Pandemic: Lessons from the "Spanish Flu" for the Coronavirus's Potential Effects on Mortality and Economic Activity Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education Economic activity and the value of medical innovation 17 Real Time Labor Market Estimates During the 2020 Coronavirus Outbreak Real Time Labor Market Estimates During the 2020 Coronavirus Outbreak Inside the Coronavirus Testing Failure: Alarm and Dismay Among the Scientists Who Sought to Help Alarming Trends in US Domestic Violence during the COVID-19 Pandemic Were Mankiw, Romer, and Weil right? A Reconciliation of the Micro and Macro Effects of Schooling on Income Preliminary Estimate of the Effects of H.R. 6201, the Families First Coronavirus Response Act Preliminary Estimate of the Effects of H.R. 748, the CARES Act Estimated Budgetary Effects of H.R. 1319, American Rescue Plan Act of 2021 as Passed by the Senate Mitigating the Impact of Pandemic Influenza through Vaccine Innovation. Executive Office of the President The Marginal Cost of Public Funds: Theory and Applications Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry: New Estimates of R&D Costs The Macroeconomics of Epidemics The Impact of the Number of Working Days on Euro Area GDP in 2004 COVID-19 Cases and Transmission in 17 K-12 Schools-Wood County The Shadow Economy Off-Label' and Investigational Use Of Marketed Drugs, Biologics, and Medical Devices 22 Case Studies Where Phase 2 and Phase 3 Trials Had Divergent Results Shelter-in-Place Orders and Public Health: Evidence from California During the COVID-19 Fear, Lockdown, and Diversion: Comparing Drivers of Pandemic Economic Decline 2020 Authorizes Moderna Vaccine, Adding Millions of Doses to U.S. Supply Transmission of SARS-COV-2 Infections in Households-Tennessee and Wisconsin Tracking Public and Private Responses to the COVID-19 Epidemic: Evidence from State and Local Government Actions Natural Resources, National Accounting and Economic Depreciation Chicago Price Theory A New Architecture for the US National Accounts Human Capital and the National Accounts Sharing R&D Risk in Healthcare via FDA Hedges Treating COVID-19-Off-Label Drug Use, Compassionate Use, and Randomized Clinical Trials During Pandemics Agencies Paid Federal Employees $3.7 Billion Not to Work During Recent Shutdowns An extensive website sponsored by the Independent Institute (FDAreview.org) Learning During COVID-19: Initial Findings on Students' Reading and Math Achievement and Growth Measuring the Gains From Medical Research: An Economic Approach 74-109 See Which States and Cities Have Told Residents to Stay at Home Schooling, Experience, and Earnings Substitution Over Time: Another Look at Life-Cycle Labor Supply The Redistribution Recession Uncertainty, Redistribution, and the Labor Market since Deaths of Despair and the Incidence of Excess Mortality in 2020 How Chicago Economics Helped End a Pandemic The Backward Art of Slowing the Spread? Congregation Efficiencies during COVID-19 Congress Can Still Save the Recovery Some Basic Economics of COVID-19 Policy Measuring the Gains From Medical Research: An Economic Approach 74-109 Dr. Fauci Explains Possible Timeline for Coronavirus Vaccine Nature's Numbers An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments Is the Food and Drug Administration Safe and Effective? Private Choices and Public Health: An Economic Interpretation of the AIDS Epidemic The Biopharmaceutical Industry is Leading the Way in Developing New Vaccines and Treatments for COVID-19 Renaissance Learning. 2020. How Kids Are Performing: Tracking the Impact of COVID-19 on Reading and Mathematics Achievement Hospital-Acquired SARS-CoV-2 Infection: Lessons for Public Health Learning and Experience in the Labor Market Modernizing Influenza Vaccines in the United States to Promote National Security and Public Health, Executive Order Contact Tracing Incidence and Secondary Transmission of SARS-CoV-2 Infections in Schools