key: cord-1042018-7ot0utbh authors: Klug, Dana M.; Idiris, Fahima I. M.; Blaskovich, Mark A. T.; von Delft, Frank; Dowson, Christopher G.; Kirchhelle, Claas; Roberts, Adam P.; Singer, Andrew C.; Todd, Matthew H. title: There is no market for new antibiotics: this allows an open approach to research and development date: 2021-06-11 journal: Wellcome Open Res DOI: 10.12688/wellcomeopenres.16847.1 sha: 17bb01bbda2d5518721c9985576aa0558d234f71 doc_id: 1042018 cord_uid: 7ot0utbh There is an increasingly urgent need for new antibiotics, yet there is a significant and persistent economic problem when it comes to developing such medicines. The problem stems from the perceived need for a “market” to drive commercial antibiotic development. In this article, we explore abandoning the market as a prerequisite for successful antibiotic research and development. Once one stops trying to fix a market model that has stopped functioning, one is free to carry out research and development (R&D) in ways that are more openly collaborative, a mechanism that has been demonstrably effective for the R&D underpinning the response to the COVID pandemic. New “open source” research models have great potential for the development of medicines for areas of public health where the traditional profit-driven model struggles to deliver. New financial initiatives, including major push/pull incentives, aimed at fixing the broken antibiotics market provide one possible means for funding an openly collaborative approach to drug development. We argue that now is therefore the time to evaluate, at scale, whether such methods can deliver new medicines through to patients, in a timely manner. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors. Publication in Wellcome Open Research does not imply endorsement by Wellcome. Antimicrobial resistance (AMR) is a serious threat to global public health because it leads to the spread of bacteria that cannot be eliminated or controlled with existing medicines 1,2 . We have been extensively warned that we are entering a post-antibiotic era 3 as antibiotic-resistant bacteria now cause an estimated 25,000 deaths in Europe alone every year [4] [5] [6] . Nevertheless, in 2015 more people still died from lack of access to otherwise effective antibiotics than antibiotic resistance 7 . As of 2019, there were 43 antibiotics and combinations which contain a new therapeutic entity in clinical or preclinical development for the treatment of serious bacterial infections, but only 15 of these antibiotics have the potential to treat pathogens listed as priorities by the World Health Organisation (WHO) 8 and there is particular urgency regarding the lack of new treatments for gram-negative pathogens. As the success rate of the drug development pipeline remains low, there is an urgent need for novel antibiotics to circumvent the threat from AMR, and our ability to treat common infections 9 . The central problem of the empty antibiotic pipeline is not scientific but economic. Between the 1930s and 1960s, significant antibiotic innovation resulted from large-scale public and private screening programs and targeted drug development, initially driven by the lack of effective antibacterial treatments 10, 11 . By the early 1980s, private investment in antimicrobial research ebbed as a result of generational change within pharmaceutical companies and a broader reorientation of private research and development (R&D) towards more focused investment in expensive yet lucrative noncommunicable (e.g., cancer and lifestyle) medications 12, 13 as well as a change in a perception of need, arising from the effectiveness of existing antibiotics 14 . The decline in private investment was exacerbated by the parallel closure of formerly successful public R&D efforts, as a result of the contemporary political emphasis on privatization and marketplace-oriented research. The disappearance of substantial investment in functionally new antibiotic classes did not mean that scientific research on new antibiotics had reached an impasse 15, 16 . During the 1980s and 1990s, smaller biotech start-ups, publicly funded researchers, and researchers within larger companies continued to employ classic screening and new molecular approaches to find and develop promising compounds 17, 18 . The problem was that there was no longer sufficient public or private investment for these compounds to move beyond early stages of pre-clinical development or clinical trialling [19] [20] [21] [22] [23] . Already diagnosed in the mid-1990s, the described disconnect between scientific potential and lack of substantial development support from industry continues to this day. Since 2010, the United States Food and Drug Administration (FDA) has approved approximately 20 new antimicrobials 24 . However, from a classic economics perspective, antibiotics remain unable to compete with the profitability of blockbuster drugs. The profitability of the broader antibiotic market is constrained by the widespread availability of competitive cheap generic compounds ("crowding out" newer, more expensive medicines), the 'short course' treatment afforded by the rapid 'chemical surgery' antibiotics provide, and current reimbursement practices 1, 25 . Potential market size for new compounds is further constrained by stewardship concerns, and profitability is lowered further by the cost of meeting regulatory requirements and the low prices of currently marketed antibiotics. There is accordingly a significantly delayed economic return on the investment that created the drug, in many cases destroying the traditional economic incentive for drug development (this situation is commonly referred to as the "fire extinguisher problem," referring to an object that is important to have, but not to use) 26, 27 . Investing in new antibiotics is considered high risk, driving companies to decide to move away from antimicrobial research 28,29 ; high profile examples from 2016-2019 include Novartis, Sanofi, AstraZeneca, and GSK 30-33 . Small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are major contributors to preclinical development globally, accounting for 81% of antibacterial programmes 34,35 . Although a driving force in innovation, SMEs are struggling to finance their efforts 1, 28, 29 . The recent bankruptcies of Achaogen, Tetraphase Pharmaceuticals, Aradigm, and Melinta Therapeutics -all SME biotechs which recently gained FDA approval for novel antibiotics and which were actually selling them -highlights the need for new political and economic models for antimicrobial research and development 1, 23, 29, 36, 37 . One must inevitably ask: is there a viable market for new antibiotics? Are attempts to revive and use traditional systems of market lure to combat AMR going to work? If the answers are 'no', and we abandon the notion that a profit is required, then we open up different ways of conceiving the development of new medicines: ones that are not required to align with the rules designed to deliver economic return. If we also abandon the idea of a 'market' for new antibiotics, acknowledging the market failures of the current approach 38 and reframe antibiotics as public goods that keep established health-care infrastructure running and serve as a foundation for developing health-care systems, then we can develop an orthogonal development model that replaces, or at least sits alongside, the current market-led, for-profit development approach. On the one hand, public funding must play a key role in future efforts, but on the other hand new development and reimbursement mechanisms can be conceived and trialled alongside existing public stimuli programs for private initiatives. Despite an abundance of successful real-world models of public pharmaceutical development, Western state and nongovernmental funders have, since the 1980s, almost exclusively adopted neoliberal economic thinking, which demands a dominant role for the private sector in the full translation to clinical practice, and which simply dismisses the public sector as an option. However, this is a political emphasis on market-based solutions, and glosses over ample real-world evidence for successful public R&D projects that resulted in the rollout of transformative pharmaceutical interventions -including penicillin, which was famously not patented 10 . (The current COVID19 pandemic may well provide further starting points for new development and distribution models due to the major challenge of rolling out vaccines globally.) This imbalance is being addressed through the exploration of new development solutions targeting early-stage scientific initiatives (Section 4) and economic models (Section 5). There are already several initiatives outside the pharma industry aimed at facilitating the early-stage discovery of new antibiotics. Agencies such as the Directorate-General for Research and Innovation, European Commission (DG-RTD), the US National Institutes of Health (NIH) 39 , and the UK National Institute for Health Research (NIHR) have recognized the need for funding basic research grants and fellowships and have launched internal initiatives 40,41 . Public-private partnerships such as CARB-X 42-44 and the Innovative Medicines Initiative's New Drugs for Bad Bugs (ND4BB) 45,46 aim to distribute risk among public and private entities while providing platforms for collaboration and resource-sharing. Other initiatives, such as the Pew Trust's SPARK platform 47-49 , which provides an open, curated database of antibacterial research, and the Community of Open Antimicrobial Drug Discovery (CO-ADD) 50-53 , a free screening service against high-priority ESKAPE bacteria and fungal pathogens, encourage participation of new researchers, and the open sharing of information and resources 54 . The Revive initiative from The Global Antibiotic Research and Development Partnership (GARDP), a joint initiative between the World Health Organization and Drugs for Neglected Diseases initiative (DNDi), aims to ensure that knowledge gained in previous and ongoing antimicrobial campaigns is shared throughout the antibiotic drug discovery community, and that new projects can benefit from the experience of those best placed to advise 55,56 . In addition, the Access to Medicines Foundation has recently published the 2020 AMR Benchmark evaluating how 30 pharmaceutical companies, all of which voluntarily provide data for the scoring evaluation exercise, are responding to the global threat of AMR 57 . Combined, these initiatives provide a framework for funding, data sharing and information mining, and research support in service of accelerating the discovery of new antibacterial agents. Despite encouraging the community towards greater collaborative efforts, the feature behind many, perhaps all, of these initiatives is that they assume that ultimately market forces will still be needed to bring developments to the clinic. State and non-governmental actors have started to respond to the fundamental economic challenge of market-led antibiotic R&D with several proposed remedies 58,59 . The final report of the Review on Antimicrobial Resistance suggested that substantial push (direct funding, pre-approval) and pull (incentive, post-approval) mechanisms would likely be needed 5,60,61 . Regulatory agencies such as the European Medicines Agency and the US FDA have offered incentives designed to increase the market exclusivity period for new antibiotics, thereby increasing their profitability 40 . Significant push incentives are being offered through investment in early stage projects by CARB-X and the Novo REPAIR Fund 62,63 . The pharmaceutical industry has recently come together to form the AMR Action Fund 64 , an unprecedented push collaboration with the World Health Organisation (WHO), The European Investment Bank (EIB), and the Wellcome Trust to invest nearly $1bn focussing on the later stages of development and which aims to bring two to four new antibiotics to patients by 2030. These very welcome investments of resources are nevertheless just the beginning of the commitment that is likely to be needed 65 . Note added in proof: a recently-published analysis (REF) suggests that the discounted net present value of a new antibiotic is $240M, considerably below the probable development costs, and that the US market accounts for >80% of sales. Other solutions to the antibiotics market involve pull incentives that attempt to provide a guaranteed income stream for companies that successfully bring molecules to market, the so-called 'delinked market entry rewards'. These rewards attempt to fix one of the most serious of the market failures, that companies selling approved, novel antibiotics can nevertheless still go bankrupt. Recently, the UK has announced that it will trial a 'subscription model' of paying for antibiotics, in which health providers will pay for future access to antibiotics kept in reserve, regardless of the level of use (i.e., 'delinkage') [66] [67] [68] . Similarly, the Swedish government has commissioned the Public Health Agency of Sweden (PHAS) to propose and pilot new models for keeping approved antibiotics available on the Swedish market, while contending with the overuse that can lead to resistance 69 . The PASTEUR Act, currently proceeding through governmental approval in the US, aims for a similar outcome 70,71 . Such schemes rely on other governments stepping up with similar levels of (proportional) commitment 72 . Reimbursement models are challenging when considering new, breakthrough medicines, where the cost of that medicine needs to be weighed against the lower cost of one that is comparatively less effective. If the 'cost' of a drug is interpreted simply, there may be financial pressure for new, expensive medicines to be prescribed less frequently than cheaper, less effective medicines, purely to reduce the outlay on the drug itself. Of course, this ignores the very significant costs associated with ongoing patient care (e.g., non-surgical hospital admission and nosocomial infection). In late 2019, the USA Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services announced it was changing the way hospitals are reimbursed for antibiotics and treatment of antimicrobial resistance, improving the ability for resistant infections to be classified for higher payments, and boosting payments for new antibiotics 73,74 . A further suggestion has been the creation of public benefit corporations as hybrids of for-and non-profit approaches 75 . Similar to other public utilities, such corporations would combine operations for the social good with a moderate profit incentive and be able to access both public and private capital; core capital would be provided by charities and public sector entities, and shares would be sold with the expectation of moderate profits. However, substantial pull incentives like market entry rewards would still be needed to maintain long-term viability. Finally, a fully non-profit model has been proposed, where the requirements for returns are lower and any profit resulting from the sale of antibiotics could be reinvested in continuing development 76 . GARDP is an example of such a non-profit entity that aims to develop five new treatments by 2025 77,78 . All of these proposals are aimed at simultaneously incentivising the development of novel antibiotics, and enabling access for those who need them. Many of the economic solutions described above are challenging to implement because they do not address the basic paradox of section 3; namely that, despite the societal costs of untreatable resistant infections, there is currently no viable market for new antibiotics. In the absence of such a self-sustaining market, public funds are being mobilised to create and sustain a market that is artificial. While it is likely that we will need a range of public and private solutions if we are to solve a challenge of this magnitude in a way that delivers results not just for the next five years but for decades to come, it is unlikely that trying to recreate a broken marketplace will achieve this goal. However, if we acknowledge that there is no market for antibiotics, and acknowledge that there are bold new economic proposals being developed, does that open new ways for us to work together on the science? It is important to note what is shared between all the proposed economic solutions to drug development: secrecy. Though early-stage data may be shared eventually, all downstream drug development is conducted out of the public eye such that intellectual property may be protected using patents; that intellectual property (IP) is leveraged to recoup financial investment (ideally with a significant profit margin). This has three effects: 1) the preclinical R&D is less effective because it is less collaborative; 2) there is a persistent danger of unnecessary duplication of effort and therefore increased cost; and 3) the discovery and development of a new antibiotic remains thought of only as a 'private sector' problem, rather than a challenge for us as a society and a consequent public good. If there is no market for antibiotics, and if traditional protection of intellectual property is not needed, then what if we abandoned secrecy altogether? Given the significant problems caused by the requirement for return-on-investment in current thinking, we advocate removing the requirement for secrecy and IP protection. The alternative is a transparent drug development approach in which all data and ideas are shared, anyone may participate, and advances will not be protected by patents. Adopting such an 'open source' approach acknowledges its success in creating market-leading, robust software underpinning much of the world's online productivity 79 . There exist biomedical research projects benefiting from the open sharing of data and expertise in this way in the areas of chemical probe discovery 80 , the physical sharing of drug libraries 81 , and in drug discovery 82,83 . Such pilots have shown how open projects can democratize discovery and development by allowing active participation by highly qualified people (individuals through to crowds) who may not otherwise have an avenue to contribute 84 . Interestingly, there are examples of valuable data freely shared from private sector programs only once the original program has been dropped (e.g., the sharing of Novartis and Achaogen data on the SPARK platform) 54 . Naturally there is a difference in scale between such activities and what is needed for a fully-fledged drug development program that would impact the fight against AMR, but the principles involved are the same. We propose that the necessary elements of the discovery and development of new antibiotics are performed in the public domain, where everyone has access to all the same information. 'Ownership' of the project (website content and the associated data/chemical structures) may be effected clearly through an appropriate licence, similar to that which already governs other open-source projects such as Wikipedia but adapted to include aspects not well covered by such licences, such as physical samples. The general routes by which the various stages of such a project could be operated and managed have previously been outlined 85 . There exist solutions already for some of the potential hurdles and novelties involved in such an endeavour, for example possible means for production/distribution (e.g. exploiting existing infrastructure underpinning the generics industry) and stewardship (via a series sponsor or other agency that would be involved in clinical trials in the same way as for any other development project). There are many other potential challenges in establishing such a new approach, such as how to convince potential funders of the economic feasibility of the approach (see section 9), how to replace IP and patent outcomes as a mark of success in this field and how to recognise the contributions to such projects towards a researcher's career progression. An existing early-stage antibiotic discovery project has recently been initiated as an example of how the open-source approach might operate, and as a way to identify more clearly the obstacles to success 86 . A key criterion is to develop an effective medicine that is affordable and made appropriately accessible yet which would be subject to the same international best practice around responsible use and stewardship. As we write this article, there is a marked increase of similar calls for a more open culture towards coronavirus research in order to accelerate the development of an affordable cure, and many of the same issues will apply 87 . It should be noted that the development of openly-available assets is not incompatible with recent stimulus proposals such as the PASTEUR Act and the AMR Action Fund, providing strong financial incentives for investment in such projects. A further interesting aspect of open projects is of note here. There is a significant risk with the deployment of push and pull incentives that, if they are unbalanced, assets could build up and languish if they are seen as insufficiently promising for private sector capital investment, potentially wasting the original public sector investment. If all assets are openly available, they may instead be taken on by any sponsor. Objections raised to an open way of working may centre on the fear that 'people will take what you have and run with it, in secret'; this may disincentivize contributions (for fear of losing credit for those contributions) even though patient benefit could still arise. Such 'taking and running' is possible, but it is unlikely. Open projects typically self-assemble high quality teams of scientists and thereby develop both momentum and community buy-in, including from global pharma employees (as part of corporate social responsibility initiatives) who enjoy the freedom such projects offer. Since all results, and all future experiments, are in the public domain, it is a challenge for a competing group to scope out the non-intuitive space required for IP protection; this 'scorched earth' approach to public disclosure brings with it a significant responsibility for an open-source project to be completed once it has been started. More generally it is not clear why anyone would wish to invest in a traditional, closed project that is attempting to find a medicine similar to one arising from an open project that is committed to equitable pricing (particularly when the closed model has been shown to be financially unviable). For later manufacturing and distribution, competition between generics suppliers would exist for openly-derived medicines just as it does now. One might also envisage that licences to supply governments with such medicines can be auctioned, in the same way that companies supply major clients (e.g., WHO) with supplies of medicines for neglected tropical diseases. Pharmaceutical firms interested in remaining in this area would be free to compete with any open approach, or to collaborate with such projects in return for agreements on any future profits that might be required to make the collaboration commercially palatable, or in return for benefits associated with public acclaim through corporate social responsibility 88 . We have recently seen such acclaim for investment in public goods with the significant contributions from the private sector towards COVID-19 vaccines, for example in the Oxford-AstraZeneca project. Open source research is not free. Contributions arise from all sectors (from seasoned professional researchers in the pharmaceutical industry through to cohorts of students and early career researchers), yet major funding would still be required to develop a new antibiotic and a sponsor would be required to take overall ownership. Will there be innovative sustainable funding for open projects, to retain accessible technology platforms, training, and knowledge transfer to progress projects, particularly through the 'valley of death' and the more expensive later stages of development? The pursuit of a low-cost, effective new medicine will make open projects attractive to existing funding sources from governments (via grants) 89 , philanthropists (via donations), and non-governmental organizations (via honest brokership and in-kind coordination, e.g., Medicines for Malaria Venture, DNDi, GARD-P, and emerging charities). There are already existing advocates for 90 , and agencies pursuing or supporting 91,92 , a public-good development model (without necessarily opening up the research). As mentioned above, the newer push and pull incentives designed to fix a broken market for antibiotics are compatible with an open source way of working, even if they were not explicitly developed with such an approach in mind. Thus, for example, early stages of discovery are eligible for funding through CARB-X, later stages through the AMR Action Fund, and post-approval financial support through a subscription model (of which the PASTEUR Act is an example). The above mechanisms are broadly supported by all those involved in the development of new antibiotics, and it is important not to confuse such funding with "drug discovery by governments" which is not being proposed here. Yet beyond public or philanthropic funding, there is also a way to conduct the research in a company setting using existing regulatory data and/or market exclusivities specifically designed to increase innovation in drug development. A sponsor conducting open research resulting in an approved medicine can still benefit from existing, multi-year protections from generic competition in major jurisdictions (despite there being no patent protection), a strategy being tested by M4K Pharma, a for-profit company seeking a therapy for a rare, uniformly fatal paediatric brain tumour 93 . The company is fully owned by a non-profit trust, to which any profits are gifted in pursuit of an affordable medicine. One can therefore combine the mission-oriented approach of a company with the pursuit of a new medicine using an inclusive, open research model. Notably, the United States offers a significant exclusivity extension for new antimicrobials that address serious or life-threatening infections. To this end has been founded Medicines for Infectious Disease (M4ID) Pharma which is intending to trial this model for pathogenic infections including antibiotics 94 . As there is no viable market for new antibiotics, we are free to open the process of drug development. Though there have been pilots of initiatives that demonstrate the associated benefits of open research, there is a significant difference in their scale versus the usual project size that results in the development of a new medicine. A combination of approaches will be needed to make fresh progress against AMR. We are seeing bold new economic ideas involving push/pull incentives and leveraging of market exclusivities; these can now be used to fund bold, open source research practices that will accelerate the science towards new medicines. Just as there is an urgent need for new antibiotics, there is a corresponding urgency in our need to test, at scale, bold new ideas that have not yet been properly explored. No data are associated with this article. CARB-X, Boston University, Boston, MA, USA This provocative Open Letter highlights an area of significant medical concern -how to maintain a suitable pipeline of antibiotics that will continue to provide the foundation to modern medicine in an environment that is scientifically challenging and economically unrewarding. The authors explain the significant progress that has been made over the last few years around push and pull incentives in an attempt to delay what many fear will be inevitable. They appropriately cite the recent coronavirus pandemic as an example of a more open and collaborative scientific effort to develop medical interventions. However, one significant difference is the speed at which that crisis arrived which had a very large and immediate societal and economic impact making it impossible to ignore, whereas the onset of an AMR crisis is considerably more nuanced, on a different timescale, and has not received the same attention from the media or policymakers. The authors promote an open discovery platform where data and strategies can be freely shared between interested parties. Early-stage research is often funded through government funding or philanthropic organizations, and the authors cite some of the initiatives aimed at this work, with suggestions that funding for the proposed open discovery model could be made available through many of the established sources currently available. However, successful development truly means the regulatory approval of new medicines, and there are less examples of these being developed via a public model, and the authors should provide some citations to support their statement around the "abundance of successful real-world models of public pharmaceutical development". Such an open-sourced development paradigm would certainly need to deliver an innovative and sustainable solution for the time, effort, and funds that are required to successfully trial and launch a new product. Whether the open-source model drives the scientific innovation that is badly needed in this space to truly identify and develop differentiated products is certainly thought-provoking and worthy of a debate, although the finer details around concept design and execution will be critical. Some minor points for consideration are: Citation 8 from PEW tracks agents in clinical development and the statement regarding 43 ○ new therapeutic agents in clinical or preclinical development should be reworded for clarity as there are a greater number of novel entities in preclinical development. While it is true that several larger companies have exited research in the antibacterial arena, the reference citing the exit of GSK (Ref 33) actually refers to the potential sale of two marketed drugs rather than research, and GSK currently has active clinical development programs with several small molecules. Reviewer Expertise: Microbial genetics, genomics, chemical biology and antibiotic R&D I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard. Defining and combating antibiotic resistance from One Health and Global Health perspectives Potential Treatment Options in a Post-antibiotic Era The bacterial challenge: time to react Tackling drug-resistant infections globally: final report and recommendations The future of antibiotics and resistance PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Access to effective antimicrobials: a worldwide challenge PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text 8. Tracking the global pipeline of antibiotics in development Drug combinations: a strategy to extend the life of antibiotics in the 21st century Penicillin: Triumph and Tragedy The First Miracle Drugs: How the Sulfa Drugs Transformed Medicine Re-inventing infectious disease: antibiotic resistance and drug development at the Bayer Company 1945-80 PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Moonshots at Cancer: The Roche Story. Basel: Editiones Roche On the exoneration of Dr. William H. Stewart: debunking an urban legend Challenges of antibacterial discovery revisited ESKAPEing the labyrinth of antibacterial discovery British Society for Antimicrobial Chemotherapy Working Party on The Urgent Need: Regenerating Antibacterial Drug Discovery and Development: Discovery research: the scientific challenge of finding new antibiotics An analysis of antibacterial drug development trends in the United States Antibiotic Resistance: A view from the pharmaceutical industry Reviving the antibiotic miracle? Funding crunch hobbles antibiotic resistance research The economic conundrum for antibacterial drugs PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text The antibiotic paradox: why companies can't afford to create life-saving drugs Sarecycline (+ve) topical for acne 2019 4 Pretomanid (TB), Lefamulin (+ve), Lascufloxacin (+/) (Japan) Reference Source Highly potent antimalarial compounds derived from the Tres Cantos arylpyrroles PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text Crowdsourcing drug discovery for pandemics. Nat Chemistry Multi-institution research and education collaboration identifies new antimicrobial compounds PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text ): e1002276. PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full Text | Free Full Text 86. Open Source Antibiotics MurLigase. Accessed Coronavirus outbreak changes how scientists communicate Public health and corporate social responsibility: exploratory study on pharmaceutical companies in an emerging market Inter)nationalising the antibiotic research and development pipeline UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose: The people's prescription: Re-imagining health innovation to deliver public value Ideation and implementation of an open science drug discovery business model -M4K Pharma Accessed 15 We thank Henry Li (UCL) and Jack Scannell (JW Scannell Analytics Ltd) for useful comments. The reference for the note added in proof for the eNPV model is required. Are all factual statements correct, and are statements and arguments made adequately supported by citations? Partly Where applicable, are recommendations and next steps explained clearly for others to follow? Yes Competing Interests: I am currently employed by CARB-X which is a significant non-dilutive funding organization focused on agents to prevent, treat and diagnose serious bacterial infections.Reviewer Expertise: Molecular biology, microbiology, genomics, epidemiology I confirm that I have read this submission and believe that I have an appropriate level of expertise to confirm that it is of an acceptable scientific standard. this allows an open approach to research and development' outlines a provocative potential solution to the multiple and massive challenges this industry has faced historically, and which seem unrelenting going forward. The authors provide, in the cogent and well-referenced description, how the commercial market for new antibiotics has collapsed as well as emerging innovative economic "push" and "pull" solutions to this problem by public and private stakeholders. However, to confront these challenges the authors propose that an 'open-source' solution to antibiotic development, which rejects the constraints posed by the broken antibiotic commercial market, is needed to solve the conundrum. Given the problems caused by the requirement for return-on-investment in the antibiotic space, an open and collaborative approach to drug discovery is advocated -one that removes the requirement for secrecy and intellectual property protection and promotes transparency as a force multiplier for drug development. Funding to support such an initiative could be available through the same sources available to private companies. Unlike the often-cited example of opensource principles driving the success of the internet, however, skepticism of its impact on antibiotic development seems warranted. How appropriate is this analogy to the 'wet lab' setting of drug development? Even if a parallel open-source development strategy were adopted to solve market forces, how many new issues are created? Issues of program governance, management, investigator incentives, timelines, and eventual sponsors of the commercial product remain. It is also difficult to imagine how the approach would be sufficiently scalable to successfully span the decade-plus years required through discovery, preclinical and clinical stages of development. Notwithstanding such concerns, the authors suggest an innovative potential solution to the issues we face and if applied even only to the discovery/early development space, it could be impactful. Are all factual statements correct, and are statements and arguments made adequately supported by citations? Yes Where applicable, are recommendations and next steps explained clearly for others to follow? Yes Competing Interests: As Co-founder and CSO of Prokaryotics Inc., a privately owned antibiotic R&D company dedicated to the discovery and development of new therapeutics, I could be viewed as having a competing interest in the views presented by the authors.