THE NEW CAPITALISM By S. A. BALDUS BOSTON COLLEGE LIBRARY CHESTNUT HILL, MASS. CHICAGO The O’Donnell Press 621 Plymouth Court 1923 Copyright, 1923, by S. A. Baldus. All rights reserved, including that of translation into foreign languages. PART I The Established Okder Page Chapter I. The Great Unrest. 7 II. The Clash of the Classes. 14 III. The New Division . 22 IV. The Investors and the Non-Investors. 28 V. The Different Kinds of Investors. 39 VI. The Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. 48 VII. The Supreme April Fool Joke. 61 VIII. The Principle of Inflation. 72 IX. The Volume of Inflation. 83 X. The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization.... 95 XI. The Railroads: An Object Lesson in Over- capitalization . Ill XII. The Stock Market . 128 XIII. Our National Wealth. 143 XIV. The National Income . 162 XV. ‘ 1 Capital, Labor and Brains”. 179 XVI. The Shrinking Dollar . 191 XVII. The American Standard of Living. 203 XVIII. Mane-Tekel-Upharsin. 218 PART II The New Order Chapter XIX. “Where There’s a Will—”. 245 XX. “—There’s a Way”. 265 XXI. Our Principles and Policies. 283 XXII. Who is “The Public”?. 295 XXIII. The Science of Wages. 309 XXIV. The Philosophy of the Quantity Wage. 324 XXV. The Genesis of Wages and Living Costs. 341 XXVI. The Cost of Living Basis of Wages. 356 XXVII. Wages Under the New Capitalism.373 XXVIII. The Cost of Living under the New Capitalism 388 XXIX. ‘ 1 Out of the Frying Pan into the Fire ”.400 XXX. Economic Changes and Adjustments.415 ' XXXI. What About the Farmer?. 434 XXXII. Where will the Farmer Stand?.449 XXXIII. No Political Party. 460 XXXIV. The Concluding Chapter. 472 r A Postscript . 483 First Edition, April, 1923 PART I THE ESTABLISHED ORDER CHAPTER I The Great Unrest F OR nearly ten years it has been dinned into our ears that there is “industrial unrest,” not only in the United States but throughout the world. There is: but since I have not studied political, social, industrial and economic conditions in Europe at close range, and have only such knowledge of them in other parts of the world as may be obtained from a reading of books, maga¬ zines and newspapers, I shall exclude Europe and the rest of the world from the present discussion and confine myself entirely to the United States,—surely a large enough territory and with enough economic problems to enlist the best energies of an army of avowed students. “Industrial unrest” is supposed to be conspicuous in the United States. Books have been written about it, arti¬ cles without number, and countless editorials. Have there not—ever since we entered the European war and even after the armistice—been hundreds of strikes, and threats of strikes, and demands for wage increases, and protests against wage cuts? And many other manifestations of industrial disorder, such as Court orders, decisions and injunctions; Industrial conferences, boards, and commit¬ tees, to say nothing of “red plots,” most of which latter, however, I have always held, existed only in certain official minds. Even though you were to enumerate many more evidences of unrest, and cite many additional instances of tumult, I today maintain that it is not industrial unrest that is afflicting the United States, but something deeper, something more sweeping, something more portentous—a social and economic disease—contagious—fatal if not quickly checked, and likely to become epidemic and end 7 8 The New Capitalism tragically. The existence of the disease cannot be denied; its gravity must not be underestimated; its symptoms must not be ignored. Clearly if a remedy is to be applied it is important that we take a correct diagnosis, for without a proper diag¬ nosis no cure is possible. Or, having the right remedy, care must be taken lest we give the medicine to the wrong patient. Surely it is the part of wisdom to honestly en¬ deavor to discover the causes of the disorder and to eradi¬ cate them, if possible. In what street and in which house, then, does our patient live, and what is his name? What are his ailments, and are they organic, or only symptomatic of the disease from which he is suffering? Is he in danger of getting worse, or is there a likelihood of his gradual convalescence and ultimate recovery? The Spendthrift Workers It is noteworthy that all through the years 1918 and 1919, and the first half of 1920, when the industrial unrest was supposed to be at its height, industrial workers were better off than ever before; at least they were being paid better wages and were experiencing less trouble in having their demands, with or without strikes, satisfied. In fact, so well off were the industrial workers that they were accused of spending their newly acquired “ riches ” like drunken sailors. Almost daily we were treated to moral¬ izing editorials anent the wanton extravagance of the wage earners, and the orgy of reckless spending into which the industrial workers had plunged themselves. We were told, not once but a hundred times, that common laborers were buying silk shirts and automobiles; their wives sealskin coats, diamonds and pianos, proof of the hysteria of spending. The Silk Shirt Era Some writers on economic subjects spoke, and still speak, of the silk shirt era, which was supposedly at its height in The Great Unrest 9 1919. Common laborers in mines and mills, we were told, were buying silk shirts, not one or two at a time but in half dozen and dozen lots, paying ten, twelve, and fifteen dollars apiece for them, and wearing them to their work, perhaps even going to bed with them on, for many of them worked twelve hours a day and seven days a week. I have always taken these “silk shirt’’ reports with a grain of salt. I hold that they were grossly exaggerated. Most of those who wrote about the silk shirt laborers in mill and mine, never brushed shoulders with one of them. It is quite certain that they troubled themselves not at all to investi¬ gate the subject. They gave us no proof, no statistics. We had nothing but their unsupported word, based on fabricated rumor and hearsay reports. Gary, Indiana, is a typical steel mill town. The steel plants there employ, let us say, 22,000 workers, most of them foreigners. What percentage of these 22,000 steel workers bought silk shirts in the height of their economic prosperity? What percentage of them wore silk shirts to their work? Who can tell? Who has made an honest in¬ quiry? In the absence of an investigation, or any official report, let us say ten percent, or 2,200 of the workers in the Gary steel mills, adorned their grimy bodies with ten and fifteen dollar silk shirts. What does that prove? It proves, if anything, that among the 22,000 there were 2,200 fools—ten percent; which I contend is no greater percentage than can be found in any other economic group. Is it fair to include the other 19,800 non-silk-shirted Gary steel workers in your sweeping indictment of the folly and extravagance of a few—whether ten, twenty or more per¬ cent—of the total number? It would at least be decent to so word your moralizing comments—if moralize you must —that the offending few shall be set apart from the many who have not offended—the economic goats separated from the sheep. I am wondering, as I write, whether any economic writer harping on the “silk shirted” wage earner—at Gary, let us say—has ever gone to the trouble of learning 10 The New Capitalism from the merchants at Gary how many silk shirts were actually sold by them to the workers in the steel mills. But that wouldn’t be conclusive, for no doubt many of them made their purchases in Chicago. And I am won¬ dering, too, just how much of an increase or decrease in savings accounts the banks of Gary could show for the silk shirt era of prosperity during and even after the war. The Miracle of Spending and Hoarding A few months after the armistice, the same papers that published doleful comments anent the silk shirt extrava¬ gance of the mine and mill and other industrial workers, many of whom were foreigners, also complained that thou¬ sands of them were going back to their native lands, taking with them millions of American money. Precisely how they could spend millions in reckless extravagance, and also save and hoard millions, has never been satisfactorily explained. A man cannot be sick in bed, crippled with rheumatism, and run a Marathon race at the same time. Either the moralizing commentators were guilty of exag¬ gerating the reckless extravagance of the industrial work¬ ers, or the economic diagnosticians were wrong when they decided that the patient was suffering from unrest. Barking Up the Wrong Tree There would be more justification for the cry “industrial unrest ’ ’ today than there was four or five years ago! All through 1918 and 1919, and the first six months of 1920, everybody was working, and the wages of many were ad¬ mittedly above the level of former years; while in 1921 four and a half millions of industrial workers were out of work, or working only part time. Many mills and factories closed down entirely. With that singular mental obliquity, which seems to be a national characteristic, we put up the red card of danger on every door when the disease was endemic, and now that it is epidemic we take it down from all doors. The fact is that when we said there was industrial unrest The Great Unrest 11 there was less of it than the usual amount among the indus¬ trial workers. But there was—and we said little or noth ing about it— unrest —not so much among the industrial workers as among the mass of the people — men and women who cannot be called industrial workers—millions of men and women who have had little or no increase in their wages or salaries, and who are finding it increasingly difficult to make ends meet. Many of them have been com¬ pelled to abandon their accustomed mode of life, and to adopt a lower standard of living. When you speak of industrial unrest there arises the vision of discontented workmen, turbulent toilers—gener¬ ally organized—clamorously engaged in a struggle for more wages, fewer hours, better working conditions or what not; or else contending for some principle, or demanding some right or concession, or opposing some real or fancied aggression. The mind does not include in the picture the average non-industrial working man and woman, working for an inadequate wage or salary, helpless, unorganized, without leaders and without spokesmen. Yet the unorgan¬ ized, non-industrial workers outnumber the organized in¬ dustrial workers. Among those unorganized, unchampioned millions of men and women, their grievances ignored and all redress denied them, there is and has been for years, bitter unrest, and a more poignant discontent than among the organized industrial workers. Therefore I insist that “industrial unrest’’ does not fairly state the case. You must amplify it to include the whole population, or rather, that vast portion of it which has no other income than is derived from wages or salaries. Speak not of industrial unrest only. Call it national unrest—call it universal discontent —not industrial in character so much as social and eco¬ nomic. ' WTiy beat around the bush? Why predicate about a comparatively small group of industrial workers only, what is easily predicable of the majority of the people— both industrial and non-industrial workers? I have scant 12 The New Capitalism patience with these wrong economic diagnoses. I chal¬ lenge every statement that contains ten percent of truth and is ninety percent a lie; statements that are clearly misstatements based on one part fact and nine parts fabri¬ cation. The Danger Symptoms Industrial unrest? No, something deeper, something more fundamental, something more terrible, is gnawing at the vitals of our nation. Those who prate of industrial unrest when the whole country is in social foment and economic upheaval, are but “fiddling Neros” or arrant knaves.^ The industrial part of the unrest is only the rumbling of the coming disaster—a faint sound made by an exasperated group, audible only because they are partly organized; of workers whose occasional manifestation of discontent is but the feeble stirring of an outraged sense of justice that is slowly corroding the hearts and embit¬ tering the minds not only of industrial workers but a tre¬ mendous majority of our nation; of wage earners whose spasmodic turbulency is merely an echo of the pent up fury that is harrowing the very souls of millions of men and women in the United States. These periodical labor turmoils are the reverberation of fierce passions raging within bruised breasts; gestures of protest against wrongs they seem powerless to redress; a chorus cry of rage against conditions from which they seem not yet to have discovered the logical way to escape, or, to adjust. Economic Quacks cmd Nostrums No! ye exalted economic doctors in subsidized colleges, ye learned professors in endowed universities, ye silver- tongued after-dinner speakers, and mercenary apologists for the Capitalistic System; ye hired quacks of plausible speech, and self appointed analysts of the ills afflicting the body social and economic; ye deluded editors, officious writers, and obsequious scribblers;—ye who would have the world believe that the trouble is in the foot, when it The Great Unrest 13 is the heart—a heart no longer merely functionally dis¬ turbed but organically diseased and beating weak and slow—I tell you your diagnosis is false, and you are de¬ ceiving yourselves rather than the public. The industrial unrest of which you speak is only one of the symptoms of a national malady—a virulent disease—a malignant disease which cannot be cured with salves, lotions and unguents, but calls for the skilful use of the knife. The Patient Must Cure Himself The case stated in its nakedness is simply this: There is today, and there has been for more than a decade of years past, economic unrest and continuously growing social discontent among eighty percent of the population of the United States—industrial and non-industrial toilers —working men and women, organized and unorganized— and their families. These eighty million people; these sixteen million families, have neither leaders nor spokes¬ men ; no representatives of their case, no defender of their rights, no pleader of their cause. I have appointed myself their advocate and their cham¬ pion. This book is written for the purpose of arousing them to the full realization of their present condition, bound to grow worse unless they bestir themselves promptly and organize themselves into a unified group. I exhort them to combine their scattered forces into a formidable power. I urge them to constitute themselves into a mighty army—a solid phalanx; to be no longer a despairing horde but an embattled host, whose cause is just, whose might is the right, and whose strength, united, is invincible. CHAPTER II The Clash of the Classes I N the older European countries society is generally divided into classes. This division, which is both social and economic, is accepted by all concerned without question or cavil. In some of the countries, particularly England, the class system has—as is inevitable—degener¬ ated into a caste system not unlike that which has fastened its throttling death grip upon India. Kenneth L. Roberts, in an article in The Saturday Evening Post (February 19, 1921), writes: “H. G. Wells has said that there are more than two hundred classes to English society. Some of the delicate distinctions between different English classes are such as to give many persons a slow, shooting pain at the base of the brain. There is a distinction, for example, between a graduate of Oxford University and a graduate of London University. The latter belongs to a lower class than the former. There is a distinction between an Episcopalian, or Church of England clergyman, and a Baptist or Con- gregationalist or Presbyterian minister. The Episcopalian belongs to a higher class than the Nonconformist minister. Workingmen are divided by rigid class distinctions. Cer¬ tain trades are classed far higher than other trades. The barrister, who argues a case for a client, is in a much higher class than the solicitor, who approaches the bar¬ rister for the client and persuades him to accept the case. If a member of the so-called upper classes undertakes to sell stoves or cheese or canned goods, he falls from the class he originally occupied to a lower class. If, however, he chooses to sell automobiles, stocks and bonds, or land, he 14 The Clash of the Classes 15 remains in his original class and is not lowered. These three pursuits are exempt from the stigma which attaches to trading in all other commodities. . . . There is class distinction in England, and the distinction is recog¬ nized and acquiesced in by every class. The lower the classes the more rigid the distinctions.” Caste Need I emphasize that this is no longer class distinction, but that terrible curse called caste. In Italy, France, Ger¬ many, Russia, and other European countries, there are, as far as I have been able to discover, fewer divisions and less invidious distinctions than in England, especially among the humbler social or economic contingents. What¬ ever of caste is observable seems to be confined to the upper laminae, rather than to the lower strata of society. Arbitrary Class Divisions But whatever the varying divisions and sundry subdivi¬ sions in the different countries may be, broadly speaking society everywhere has for several centuries been appor¬ tioned into three great groups, or classes, namely, the upper class, the middle class, and the lower class. It is to be noted here that there is no uniform rule or standard; the class division is purely arbitrary. For example, speak¬ ing of France—the celebrated M. Quesnay, physician to the court of Louis XV, divided society into three classes: “The first, or productive class, by whose agency all wealth is produced, consists of the farmers and labourers engaged in agriculture, who subsist on a portion of the produce of the land reserved to themselves as the wages of their labour, and as a reasonable profit on their capital; the second, or proprietary class, consists of those who live on the rent of the land, or on the nett surplus produce raised by the cultivators after their necessary expenses have been deducted; and the third, or unproductive class, consists of manufacturers, merchants, menial servants, &c., who subsist entirely on the wages paid them by the other 16 The New Capitalism two classes; and whose labour, though exceedingly useful, adds nothing to the national wealth. ’ 71 Henry Parkinson, writing in 1913, divides society in England on an entirely different basis. “Roughly speak¬ ing/’ he says, “the upper class will include the aristocracy, nobility, the greater landowners, the capitalist financiers. The middle class will comprise (1) producers (small land- owners and tenant farmers, the yeoman class, and the captains of industry) ; (2) distributors, like merchants and retailers; (3) the great services (ministers of religion, teachers, doctors and nurses, lawyers and clerks, officers of army and navy, the civil service). By the lower class is understood the vast number of those who live mainly by the fruit of their labour and are without landed or other capital. ’ ’ 1 2 The important thing to remember here is that there is no uniformity as regards class divisions; each writer fol¬ lows his own particular notions, or classifies society accord¬ ing to the accepted standards of the day, or the prejudices of the country in which he lives. Certainly there is noth¬ ing scientific about such classifications. No Glasses in the United States But I am not particularly concerned at this moment with any country except the United States. Here at home I contend that there are no classes, save for the conve¬ nience of the sociologist. I say this with the full knowledge that all our writers on economics habitually, and quite erroneously, indulge in class distinctions, and prate with turgid eloquence of “class consciousness.” They have divided us, too, into the three great classes—upper, middle and lower. I do not know wiiether any have ventured to say just who is to be included in each of these three classes, but if so, it was without troubling themselves about stating the essential qualifications or distinctive charac¬ teristics of each class. 1 “The Principles of Political Economy,” by J. R. McCullough. 2 "A Primer of Social Science,” by Henry Parkinson, D.D. The Clash of the Classes 17 I do not feel disposed at this time to quarrel with these writers for their lack of definiteness when writing about their upper, middle and lower class divisions; but I take issue with them when they transcend the limits of mere classification and proceed to make distinctions which are not only arbitrary and unwarranted, but undemocratic and unscientific. Otto H. Kahn, in an article published in The Annalist (January 3, 1921) speaks of the so-called middle class as composed of “the men and women living on moderate incomes, the small shop keeper, the average professional man, the farmer, etc.” And then he continues to say that the welfare of these “is just as important to the commu¬ nity as the welfare of the wage earner.” By what right does Mr. Kahn segregate the wage earn¬ ers? By what right does Mr. Kahn differentiate between those whose maintenance is derived from wages, and those who receive a salary, or whose income, the equivalent of a wage or salary, is derived from some other pursuit, or source ? The middle class may indeed be composed of “the men and women of moderate income,” but I insist that it doesn’t make a particle of difference w T hetker their mod¬ erate income is derived from wages, salary, or a small business, or the practise of a moderately lucrative profes¬ sion. I contend that the wage earner, whose “moderate income” is, say, $1,000 or $1,500 a year, has as much right to consider himself as belonging to the middle class as has the butcher or the baker, or the lawyer, or farmer having approximately the same amount of income. Confusing Society with Economics The dictionary defines the middle class as “the class that occupies an intermediate position socially.” The middle class, therefore, is primarily a social group; but that is not the sense in which Mr. Kahn uses the term. The dictionary also says that the “trading class” is the middle class. Who constitute the trading class? Surely 18 The New Capitalism in the United States tradespeople do not constitute the middle class, for, according to the United States Census Statistics the following are listed under the designation Trade: bankers, brokers, money-lenders; clerks in stores; commercial travelers; delivery men; insurance agents and officials; laborers in coal and lumber yards, warehouses, etc.; laborers, porters, and helpers in stores; real estate agents and officials; retail dealers; salesmen and sales¬ women; wholesale dealers; importers and exporters, etc. J. P. Morgan is in the trading class; so is Barney Baruch; so is John D. Rockefeller; so is Julius Rosen- wald; so is Otto H. Kahn. But J. P. Morgan, and Barney Baruch, and John D. Rockefeller, and Julius Rosenwald, and Otto H. Kahn—traders though they be—are distinctly not of the middle class, socially speaking. Emphatically they are not of the middle class economically speaking. By the exclusion of the wage earner from the middle class Mr. Kahn arbitrarily places the men and women who work with their hands in the lowest class. That there are some—and I care not whether you make it ten or twenty percent of the total, or more or less,—working for a wage, or perhaps too lazy to work at all, and who may be put into the lowest class socially considered, I freely concede. But, on the other hand, there is a considerable number of idle and lazy rich—men and women—“who toil not, neither do they spin”—who in all their lives have never contributed aught to the sum and substance of human happiness; who have produced nothing; who have added nothing to the wealth of the nation; who render no serv¬ ice to humanity; who are, plainly speaking, social barnacles and economic parasites—where will Mr. Kahn place these? In the upper, or the middle, or in the lower class? Or will he put them in a class by themselves, lower even than his classification of the wage earners? Class Contradictions If there w r ere only two social groups, one would naturally be the upper and the other the lower group; but since we The Clash of the Classes 19 divide society into three groups or classes, then one is necessarily the uppermost or highest class, one the lowest class, and the other the middle class. Verbal accuracy, if nothing else, it seems to me, demands the abrogation of the commonly accepted upper, middle and lower class classi¬ fication of society, and dictates designating the three con¬ stituent groups, or classes, if you insist, as the highest class, the middle class, and the lowest class. According to Mr. Kahn and others, the wage earner is in the lowest class. What is it that puts a man or woman into the highest class ? It isn ’t intellect; it isn’t character; it isn’t culture; it isn’t moral perfection. It is chiefly wealth plus social position, and the purchasable concomitants, such as fash¬ ionable clothes, a magnificent residence, luxurious sur¬ roundings, a retinue of servants, leisure, etc. None will deny that one belonging to the highest class of society, may at heart be—and many of them are—reprobates. In¬ tellectually they may be nonentities, absolutely character¬ less, deficient in culture, lacking in refinement, devoid of the finer qualities, and morally below par. Yet none thus far has challenged their inclusion in the highest class. I, for one, cannot subscribe to a group arrangement that deliberately ignores the better qualities in individuals, or in groups. My intelligence refuses to accept as scientific a classification based wholly on the possession of wealth, and all that a plethora of riches implies. My sense of jus¬ tice, or shall I say, my common sense, rejects a stratifica¬ tion of society that takes no account of intellect, or of char¬ acter and the simple virtues which, none will deny, weigh heavy in the scale of human values. The Middle Group In plain English, I protest against the mass inclusion of all wage earners in the lowest class. Until those who can speak with authority—be they scientific sociologists, or just plain blunt men like Mr. Kahn—are willing to go on record as saying that probity and nobility of soul, goodness 20 The New Capitalism of heart, cleanness of mind, purity of conduct, innate honesty, a sense of justice, a decent regard for the rights of others—in brief, character and conscience—are of no social value, I shall insist on placing a considerable num¬ ber of the wage earners—most of them respectable and useful members of society, and who in the aggregate have contributed vastly more to the nation’s progress than the contingents socially higher,—into the middle class. It does not matter whether they work with their hands or their head; whether for a weekly wage or a fixed salary, or for an irregular honorarium. If the income of these workers with brain or brawn is not large, whose fault is it? If their “moderate income” does not permit them to cut much of a figure socially, who is to blame? If the meager wage or inadequate salary allowed by the Capital¬ istic System compels millions of men and women to live in humble homes and amid unpretentious and unaristocratic surroundings, not to say squalor, it is despicable of any constituent member of the Capitalistic group to turn up his nose at them. To Mr. Kahn, and whoever essays to write on this sub¬ ject, I say, with emphasis: “You shall not place the decent men and women of the United States into the lowest class simply because they work for a wage, or the equiva¬ lent of a wage. They are of the middle class! They are the middle class. Remove them and your so-called highest class will fall, socially and economically, into an abyss deeper than hell.” The Dead Past and Its Dead It is difficult for some people to understand that we are living neither in feudal times nor in the days of Louis XIV. They seem to forget that the American Revolution of 1776, once and for all, wiped out all invidious class dis¬ tinctions, at least in the United States, when politically it placed the nation on a common footing. What else does the term “democracy” signify? They seem to forget that the French Revolution of 1789, taking courage from our The Clash of the Classes 21 own example, in accents none too mild repudiated class distinctions with the words— liberte, equalite, fraternite. Indeed the French Revolution was an endeavor to equalize the classes by entirely eliminating the uppermost class— the nobility—the aristocracy, which, as we are reminded in Thiers’ “The French Revolution” had “built up a wall of demarcation between themselves and the rest of the Community, as if they were fashioned of more ‘ precious porcelain’.” And is there no lesson to be found in the more recent Revolution in Russia? The Daivn of a New Day It is difficult for some people to comprehend that within the last century vital and tremendous changes have taken place in the civilized world, and that the political upheavals observable everywhere today are but the pains of parturi¬ tion preceding the birth of a new social and economic order. At least in the United States let it be understood that in this year of our Lord 1922, we have neither feudal lords, nor barons, neither a nobility nor an aristocracy, and cer¬ tainly we who work for a wage or salary, or its equivalent, refuse to allow ourselves to be hurled back into what it would please some to designate economically, the peasant or serf class, socially the lowest group. Those who have a passion for making class distinctions, and particularly those who look upon the wage workers as our lowest class, socially and economically, might with profit ponder on these words spoken by President Harding in his Inaugural Address: “Our fundamental law recog¬ nizes no class, no group, no section. There must be none in legislation or administration. The supreme inspiration is.the common weal.” CHAPTER III The New Division B UT to sweep aside the old and generally accepted division of society into classes, places upon me the obligation to propose an entirely new classification, or rather group division, a division that has none of the objectionable features of the old classification—a division that is new and altogether more scientific. Above all it must be a division that concerns itself wholly with eco¬ nomic society—therefore an economic group arrangement that is reducable to approximate figures and easily divisible, something that is altogether impossible in what might be called a half social and half economic classification or grouping, under which the several members of the same family might belong to the three distinctive social classes. Thus, for example: the father may be a lawyer, which will place him socially in the middle class; the son may be a wage earner, which fact would thrust him into the lowest social class; and the daughter may marry a multi-million¬ aire, which would automatically determine her social status in the uppermost class. But in a statistical division that is primarily economic no social violence is implied; the transi¬ tion from the one economic group to the other group involves no medley of social contradictions. Producer and Consumer In past decades, loose economic writers, who preferred to deal with nicely sounding words and their opposites, rather than with fairly accurate terms, writers who troubled themselves not at all with definitions, have been wont to loosely divide economic society into two motley groups, namely, Producer and Consumer; and even to this day we 22 The New Division 23 hear them used by writers and speakers as if there attached to them any scientific economic significance. A moment’s reflection would establish that the classification is altogether irrelevant. Who are the producers? How many among the forty million men, women and children listed as engaged in the ‘‘gainful occupations” can be called producers in the real sense of the word ? After an analysis of the available sta¬ tistics I will say approximately one-third, certainly less than one-half, could be called producers. The producer group, as used in economic literature, therefore excludes a majority of those engaged in gainful occupations. Conse¬ quently, since no account is taken of the large number who cannot be classed as ‘ ‘ producers, ’ ’ the unscientific character of the producer and consumer division becomes at once apparent. If only those who actually produce something are called producers, some cognizance must be taken of those who, though working, are not engaged in production operations. A farmer, a miner, a steel worker, a baker, can be called a producer; but a boot-legger, a policeman, a railroad conductor, or a chauffeur, cannot be called a producer in the strict sense of the word. To call every worker, whether he produces or not, a producer, is highly inaccurate. The entanglement becomes even more obvious when we encounter the word consumer, sometimes, for the sake of emphasis perhaps, the ultimate consumer. The irrelevancy of the economic producer and consumer division is imme¬ diately apparent when we remember that the producer is at the same time a consumer—producing eight hours a day and consuming during sixteen hours of the day; in fact, he is a consumer even while he produces. But the production part of the formula is not predicable of all the consumers; whereas the consumption part is predicable of all, whether they be producers or non-producers, workers or idlers. Only a percentage of the working group are producers; but one hundred percent of the population are consumers. Clearly, then, the designations “producer” and “con- 24 The New Capitalism sumer” cannot be used appropriately, because millions of those engaged in work cannot be called producers in the literal sense of the word. All, however, are consumers. Even the retired millionaire is a consumer; he consumes as well as the wage earner. But the role of consumer makes no irksome demand on the millionaire. Consuming, to him, is no hardship, no trial, no tribulation. What he con¬ sumes does not exhaust his income; it makes no inroads on his wealth; it does not interfere with his further w T ealth accumulations; it does not disturb his capital funds. After a most liberal consumption most of his income remains to be invested by him in sundry profitable enterprises which will yield for him in the following year another uncon¬ sumable quantity of wealth, and increase of capital. Certainly he does not deserve to be mentioned in the same class with the wage earner consumer, or the small salaried consumer, who in the course of the year consumes prac¬ tically all he earns; whose wages, or salary, is his only income; who has no investments, no income from any other source than the labor of his hands or his head. All he earns, generally a limited and stipulated amount, he is compelled to spend merely in order that he and his family, or those dependent upon him, may have a roof over their heads, clothes to wear and food to eat. He lives from hand to mouth. A month of idleness, or illness; a sick wife or child; or a death in the family, will cast him down and plunge him into debt. Once and for all I’ll dismiss the "Producer-Consumer division as a sloppy, slippery economic makeshift, illuminating nothing, clarifying nothing, settling nothing, describing nothing. Bourgeoisie and Proletariat European economic literature abounds with the quasi- scientific terms Bourgeoisie and Proletariat. We have heard them frequently spoken of in connection with Social¬ ism in Germany, Syndicalism in France, Bolshevism in Russia, etc. I seriously question whether their use is scien¬ tifically justified; but since I do not mean to concern myself The New Division 25 with the economic problems of Europe, I will accept them, as, perhaps, applicable to economic conditions in Europe, but they certainly cannot be employed with any degree of appropriateness in the United States. In fact I reject the two terms peremptorily, basing my present rejection on the authority of the dictionary, which defines them as follows: Bourgeoisie —The middle class of Society; especially in France; used collectively. Proletariat —1. In earlier usage, the indigent classes, collectively of a community or a state, including day laborers and all other persons without capital or assured means of support: Kegarded in ancient Kome as con¬ tributing to the state nothing but offspring; the lower classes; peasantry; rabble. 2. In modern socialistic use, the wage workers of a state or of the world, collectively, regarded as the producers of capital and creators of wealth; the laboring classes; working men. To still further emphasize the inapplicability of the terms to the economic conditions in the United States, one has but to glance at the definition of bourgeois and prole¬ tarian. The same dictionary defines them as follows: Bourgeois —Of or pertaining to the commercial or middle class as distinguished from gentle or noble; among modern Socialistic writers often used in opposition to working class or proletariat, or to characterize a system of commercialism. Proletarian —A person of the lowest or poorest class. I shall waste no further words on this strictly European division of economic society, beyond saying that it is inad¬ missible in the United States. Drawing the Line of Demarcation What, then, is a reasonably accurate and fairly scientific economic division—one that will stand the test of analysis and at the same time be computable in figures and per¬ centages? I may be in error when I say that the only economic division that will fit the case exactly is the one I am about to make; but I am not in error when I claim that my division is better and more nearly descriptive of actual conditions than any thus far made by any economic writer. On that contention I stand pat. My division may be sus- 26 The New Capitalism ceptible of improvement, bnt as it stands I claim for it that it is distinctively economic, and not an olla podrida classi¬ fication, part social, part economic, with a strongly political flavor spoiling the broth altogether. What it pleases some to call civilized society was orig¬ inally composed of only two classes—those who ruled and those who were ruled. The economic relationship between them was that of master and slave. But in due time grad¬ ual economic changes gave rise to another group, which became known and is still spoken of by economic writers, as the middle class. The very word society is an aristo¬ cratic term, and I hesitate to use it when speaking of what the economists consider the lowest class of men and women, those who, we are told, constitute a group by themselves and who are in no sense any part of the social machine, except to serve those who are society. The, difference is that in former centuries those who served had no claim whatever on those they served; whereas today the servants have at least a right to demand pay for their services. It is this very thing, namely, that pay must be accorded those who serve, that has given to society its economic, not to say mercenary, character. It is this very thing that has enabled a number of those who, economically, were of tl\e lowest class, to lift themselves into a somewhat more favorable position and thereby improve their social status. It is not my intention to trace the economic development, interwoven with that of society, either in Europe or in the United States. For the sake of brevity, therefore, I accept the middle class as a purely social group, while maintaining that many, if not all, of those who labor for a wage, have a right to claim membership therein. But since there is, and can be, no agreement as to who might be included and who denied admission; since there are differences of opinion as to where the dividing line is to be drawn; and since no one has ever ventured to compile a set of statistics from which one might fairly approximate who and how many belong to the highest class; and who and how many to the middle class; and who and how many to the lowest class, I am The New Division 27 persuaded to make an economic classification all my own, and one which, I think, fits in more accurately with the Capitalistic character that society has acquired in the United States within recent years. Instead of dividing the population into three social classes—upper (or highest), middle, and lower (or lowest)—I will divide it into two economic groups, which I shall call the INVESTOR GROUP, and the NON-INVESTOR GROUP. This purely economic group division seems to me alto¬ gether preferable in the discussion of a subject which is wholly economic, and concerns itself chiefly with the eco¬ nomic relationship existing between the several contingents that go to make up the social amalgam. CHAPTER IV The Investors and the Non-Investors F OR the -purposes of this book, then, I shall divide the population of the United States into two distinct economic groups—the investor group and the non¬ investor group, and make an attempt at numerical classi¬ fication and apportionment. According to the latest United States Census Statistics, the population of the United States is 106,418,175. There are 24,351,676 families; an average family is composed of 4.3 persons. But in order to simplify my subject for the reader, and because practically all statisticians and economists have used five persons as constituting an average family, I am going to make my computations as if the population were one hundred mil¬ lion, and the size of the average family five persons—and therefore twenty million families. How many of this number are investors? Family Income Statistics The statistics show that in 1910 over ninety percent of the families in the United States had an income of less than $1500 a year. 1 It is a safe guess that there are not many investors to be found among them. It is likely that in 1917, 1918 and 1919 the amount of income of these families was considerably greater, but the increase in income was absorbed by the increase in living costs, and therefore did not materially alter the situation as far as investments are concerned. We must, therefore, look for our investors among the remaining ten percent of the families. 1 According 1 to the income statistics for 1910, computed by Prof. Willford Isbell King, 51.54 percent of the families had an income of less than $500 a year, 30.15 percent between $800 and $1200, and 8.62 percent between $1200 and $1500. (See table XL.IV. p. 228, “The Wealth and Income of the People of the United States.”) 28 The Investors and the Non-Investors 29 A Glance at Income Tax Statistics But he would be a reckless statistician who would con¬ clude that ten percent of the families are investor families! The “Statistics of Income’’ for 1918 2 show that only 4,425,114 individuals filed an income tax report in that year. Of this number 1,516,938, or 34.28 percent, were in the class whose income was between $1000 and $2000; and 1,496,878, or 33.83 percent in the class whose income was from $2000 to $3000. While beyond a doubt there are some investors among the three million in these two classes the statistics (Table 7) show that “dividends” and “interest and investment income” constituted a minimum of their income. The remaining 1,411,298 who reported incomes from $3000 to over a million, could more properly be said to constitute the investor group. Getting Down to Business But I am trying to put our best investor foot forward, and am desirous to make the group as large as possible. In the absence of definite statistics I will quote from the writings of a man who can be said to speak with authority. Charles M. Schwab, Chairman of the Bethlehem Steel Cor¬ poration, in an article in Collier’s Weekly (December 11, 1920), said: “Three years ago a survey of 280 leading railway and industrial corporations disclosed that their securities were owned by more than a million and a half of people. With the large purchasing of securities since the close of the war, a census taken today would, I believe, show that at least two and a half million people own, as investors, rights in - Number in 2 Income Classes Each Class $1000 to $2000. $2000 to $3000. $3000 to $5000. ' $5000 to $10,000. $10,000 to $25,000_ $25,000 to $50,000_ $50,000 to $100,000. . . $100,000 to $150,000. . $150,000 to $300,000. . $300,000 to $500,000. . $500,000 to $1,000,000 $1,000,000 and over... 1,516,938 1,496,878 932,336 319,356 116,569 28,542 9,996 2,358 1,514 382 178 67 30 The New Capitalism the profits of what is called ‘big business/ If, therefore, big business is in a conspiracy against the people, quite a number of the people seem involved in it.” When Mr. Schwab speaks of two and a half million in¬ vestors he does not take into consideration that many of the security holders he speaks of are security holders in a number of corporations; that is to say, the same names appear repeatedly in different investor lists. Which being the case I would be justified in making a considerable reduction on account of duplications. But instead of reduc¬ ing the number of investors—individuals and families—by a half million or more, as I believe could be done in all fairness, I prefer to deliberately enlarge upon Mr. Schwab’s estimate, and to settle upon a figure that will include all investors, of whatever kind. For the purposes of this book I am going to say that there are four million investors—or rather four million families, comprising twenty million of the population. Many investors are probably investors in businesses of their own. On the other hand some of the security holders may be lawyers, physicians, dentists, editors, etc.; many of them are manufacturers, merchants, tradespeople, farmers, etc. In other words, whatever dividends or interest they may derive from security holdings is additional to an income derived from other pursuits or sources. Then, too, there are men, and women, who are not actively engaged in busi¬ ness ; who have sold out their business interests for cash, or are retired, or who, through inheritance, have been enabled to invest in real-estate or securities of various kinds, and who are conspicuous in the investor group. To say that there are four million investors of all kinds in the United States, is, to my way of thinking, a very liberal estimate, particularly when we remember that from eighty to ninety percent of the families have an income just about sufficient to enable them to live; and who do not share appreciably in the national wealth. This, at least, is the conclusion one would arrive at from a correlation of the statistics pertaining to Income, Wealth, Occupations, and The Investors and the Non-Investors 31 Income Tax. Moreover, as we have seen, only four and a half million individuals filed income tax reports in 1918, three million of whom reported that a very small part of their income was derived from investment. But when we speak of four million investors in the United States we must keep in mind several things which tend to modify the claim: First, that while there may be four mil¬ lion investors on all the lists, beyond a doubt many names are duplicated, that is to say, the same names are repeated over and over. Second, that many of the “investors” in American securities are foreigners. It has been said that European investors have from eight to twelve billions invested in the United States. Third, that many citizens of the United States, whose names appear in investors’ lists, have invested in foreign securities and enterprises. A financial writer recently stated that “American invest¬ ments in Canada total two billion dollars.” It would be interesting to know exactly how much capital citizens of the United States have invested in foreign enterprises or securities. But in spite of all these things I will continue to consider the investor group as composed of four million individuals, families or estates, comprising twenty million persons. Nor will I particularly stress that of a considerable number of families it can be said that every member is an investor. I ’ll go a step further and say that these four million invest¬ ors, to all intents and purposes, own and control practically all of the valuable productive and profit-yielding prop¬ erties in the United States; all the businesses; banks, trans¬ portation systems, insurance companies, public utilities, mines, factories, stores, real estate, etc. 8 We may now state the case as follows: THE INVESTOR GROUP is composed of four million investors—let us say—four million families of five members each; therefore twenty million men, women and children * For reasons that I explain later in this chapter, I am excluding the farmer from the Investor Group. 32 The New Capitalism are included in tlie investor group. Twenty percent of the population constitute the investor group. THE NON-INVESTOR GROUP is composed of sixteen million families—a total of eighty million men, women and children; or eighty percent of the population. Liberty Bond Investors Let not some smart aleck triumphantly shout that he has me on the hip—that I have misstated facts—that there are not only four million but nearer twenty million investors, in the United States, for did not millions of men and women in the United States purchase Government bonds—Liberty or Victory bonds? Roger Babson, who is looked upon as an authority on economic matters, and as a statistical expert, said in January, 1921, that eighty percent of the original purchasers are still holding their bonds. A few weeks later George M. Reynolds, former President of the Continental and Commercial Bank, said that about fiftv percent of the original bond purchasers still hold their bonds. I do not know upon what data Messrs. Babson and Reynolds base their conflicting statements; but let us not cavil—let us compromise by saying that more than half of those who bought Liberty and Victory bonds are still holding them. But why are they holding them ? It would be fine if we could say in stentorian tones that they are holding them for patriotic reasons. But throwing dust into my own eyes is not one of my accomplishments—and I am incapable of lying to myself. If approximately one-half of the original bond purchasers are still holding the bonds they purchased —they are holding them primarily because they cannot dispose of them except at a loss. If you insist on speak¬ ing of those who bought Liberty and Victory bonds as 1 1 investors, ’ ’ I am going to insist that you consider the bonds they hold as nothing more than an investment; in which case I shall tell you that from an investing stand¬ point Liberty and Victory bonds were a poor investment. Until the latter part of 1921 the bonds they purchased at The Investors and the Non-Investors 33 $100 (many buying them on the instalment plan and paying interest thereon from date of purchase) were quoted in the market as low as $88.00. 4 Let us have done with hypocrisy and camouflage. Hard though it may he, let us at least be honest with ourselves. If the truth must be told many of those who bought either Liberty or Victory bonds were forced to buy them—they had no alternative. Charles G. Dawes, in charge of the Liberty bond sales in Chicago, said to his salesmen: “If any man refuses to buy a bond, knock him down.” The Congressional Record is full of stories of citizens who were forced to buy the quantity allotted to them by the salesmen. A queer kind of investor, who is compelled to buy, nolens volens. A queer kind of invest¬ ment that is compulsory upon many who could not afford to buy, but who would have been punished by loss of their job—or who would have been insulted and reprobated, or jailed or killed, had they refused. The less we say of the manner in which thousands of citizens were coerced into becoming 4 ‘ investors ’ ’ the better. I mention all these things for the benefit of those economic writers and analysts who might be tempted into an endeavor to show that the investor group is larger than I have declared. Professor David Friday, in his “Profits, Wages and Prices” says: “Early in 1919 the sales of liberty bonds through private channels and upon the New York Stock Exchange reached tremendous proportions. For the full year these sales on the Exchange totaled three billion dol¬ lars, and for the first four months of 1920 another billion was sold. A large part of the funds derived from this source were devoted to the purposes of ordinary consump¬ tion, rather than to capital expansion.” In June, 1922 it was reported that over three-fourths of the Liberty and Victory bonds were now in the hands of Liberty Bond Prices in New York, April 8, 1921: Liberty S^s. 90.26 Liberty 4th 4*4s.... 87.86 Liberty 2d 4s. 87.52 Liberty reg. 87.70 Liberty 1st 4s. 87.90 Victory 4%s. 97.58 Liberty 2d 4%s. 87.86 Victory reg. 97.44 Liberty reg. 87.60 Victory 3%s. 97.58 Liberty 3d 4*4s. 91.00 34 The New Capitalism the big banks and investors, who had bought them in at low figures. About the same time Liberty and Victory bond prices went up, and are now quoted at around par. Tax Evading Investors Those boastful speakers and optimistic writers who delight to swell the number of investors, might, with better grace, speak of the millions of “patriots” who since the passing of the Income Tax law have invested heavily in tax exempt securities, state, county, municipal and even foreign bonds. Secretary of the Treasury Mellon, in his annual report, recently stated that more than ten billion dollars are invested in tax exempt securities. Other estimates I have seen place the amount thus invested between twenty and thirty billions. Professor E. R. A. Seligman, before the House Ways and Means Committee on the resolution to amend the Constitution to permit the Government to tax securities which are now exempt, declared that unless the Government intervenes within a few years, from two to three billion dollars a year of state and local tax exempt securities will be issued. Investors in Homes But there are those who will insist that the man who owns his home is an investor. I do not feel disposed to quarrel with those who put forth this contention. However, let us take a glance at the statistics. According to the Census Bureau Statistics (published October, 1921) the total number of homes enumerated in 1920 was 24,351,6.76. Of this number 13,247,313 families were renters, 6,667,113 families owned their homes, while 4,271,544 families had mortgages on their homes. Reduced to simpler terms 54.4 percent of the families live in rented homes; 28.2 owned the homes they occupy free of incumbrance, and 17.5 are occupants of homes that are mortgaged. (The status of 285,243 homes was not reported.) That it is difficult to even approximate actual conditions with regard to the ownership and tenancy of houses and The Investors and the Non-Investors 35 homes may be judged from Chicago’s housing survey, according to which out of the nearly three million persons living in Chicago 125,000 own their homes, while 60,000 persons owned 145,914 apartment buildings occupied by nearly two million people. Beyond a doubt, many, if not all, of the four million investors, own their homes; many of them, besides, own buildings occupied by tenants. If a house owner occupies the building he owns himself his property represents an investment indeed, but it yields him no revenue. But if he , owns houses in addition to the one he occupies, he takes his place among the landlords, and as such derives an income from his investment. In all probability many of the four million constituting the investor group are landlords. Beyond a doubt, also, a fair percentage of those I have classed as non-investors own their homes outright. In that case the owner simply plays the double role of landlord and tenant. Instead of paying rent to a landlord he pays it to himself. The amount he pays out for taxes, insurance, upkeep, alterations and, computing interest on the amount tied up in the property he occupies, is, in every case, the equivalent of rent. On the other hand, if he has only an equity in the prop¬ erty, if the home in which he lives is mortgaged, then far from being an investor he is just the reverse—he is a debtor. The real investors are those who hold the mortgage. It is the mortgage holder who derives a revenue from the non-investor’s partial ownership. It is the equity holder who pays interest on the unpaid portion of the property of which he is the nominal, but not the actual, owner. The mortgage holders are the real investors; not the mortgagor. Probably if all data could be obtained it would be revealed that a considerable number of the four million investors hold mortgages against the properties in which many non¬ investors have only an equity. 36 The New Capitalism Is the Farmer * an Investor f Farm owners are, of course, investors, but let us remem¬ ber that the farmer derives his income from his joint invest¬ ment and labor, and that it does not much exceed, and in some years even falls below, what the Government calls a subsistence level of income. The farming industry is valued at eighty billion dollars, an amount greater than is invested in all the railroads, manufactures and mines. Yet on this investment, plus their labor, the farmers in 1912 realized only six billion dollars, or (considering that there are more than six mil¬ lion farm owners) an average of less than $1,000 per farm owner. This amount, mind you, represents interest on investment, and wages for labor performed. It is quite true that there can be added to this income a certain amount for the item of rent; and likewise an amount cov¬ ering food products consumed by the farmer and his family. But even so, surely it must be clear that the farmers’ in¬ come must cover interest on investment, wages for labor performed, and whatever allowance may be made for the items of rent, and food products consumed, so that the total amount of average income per farmer is hardly more than the equivalent of an industrial worker’s family income. The U. S. Department of Agriculture recently studied farm incomes from three groups of farms in the middle west; Dane County, Wisconsin; Washington County, Ohio; and Clinton County, Indiana. According to the Farmers’ and Drovers’ Journal, the Department of Agriculture ob¬ tained the following results: “The average annual income from Dane County farms over five years, was $1,293. Of the 185 farmers in the three areas, none made a labor income of $1000 for every year in the study, but 18 in the Indiana area and 7 in the Wis¬ consin area made labor incomes averaging over $1000 per year for the period. Four farmers (two percent of the entire number) made over $500 labor income every year. Averaging labor income and loss over the whole time, 15 The Investors and the Non-Investors 37 percent of the farmers failed to make any labor income at all. Ten percent failed even to make five percent interest on investment in any year of the study. /'The average return on investment increased from about four percent in 1913 to seven percent in 1918. But most of the farmers made less than $500 a year over the things the farm furnished toward the family living. It was ap¬ parent to department officials, therefore, that few farmers are making large profits.’’ At the hearings 5 before a subcommittee of the Com¬ mittee on Interstate Commerce, Mr. E. A. Calvin, of Hous¬ ton, Texas, Washington Representative of the Cotton State Board, stated that “the average earnings of a farmer and his family, in the Southern States, where cotton is grown, is less than $750 per annum—that is gross; not net.” Even remembering that for the period of the war, when prices of farm products were considerably higher than before the war, the aggregate income of the farmers was 18 billion dollars a year—and the average income per farmer can be said to have been $3000, plus his rent and a certain amount of living commodities—it must also be re¬ membered that the prices of all commodities which the farmer had to purchase from others had increased in the same proportion, thus practically leaving him no better off than before the war. At any rate the war period is over; and the war prosperity of the farmer has come to an abrupt end. Taking it all in all, at least for the purpose of this book, I consider it perfectly legitimate to include the far¬ mers in my non-investor group, since from all appearances they are deriving only the equivalent of wages from their joint investment and labor. The Investor Group and Non-Investor Group Divided The investor group and the non-investor group are sepa¬ rate and distinct, and hopelessly divided. There are hun¬ dreds of laws specifically protecting the rights of the inves- 5 May 20, 1920. 38 The New Capitalism tors, but no specific law protecting the rights of the non¬ investors. The courts, under the aegis of those laws, are compelled to side with the investor as against the non¬ investor. I think I am safe in saying that there are no court decisions that have been favorable to the non-inves¬ tors. Not only are there no laws on our statute books that protect the non-investor as against the investor—there are, on the contrary, a formidable number of legal enactments, state and federal, that are distinctly contrary to the inter¬ ests of certain contingents within the non-investor group —laws destructive of natural rights or depriving non¬ investors of the free exercise thereof; curtailing them, en¬ joining them, circumscribing them, compelling them. This is clearly true with regard to the laboring group. During the past few years, a number of state and federal laws have been passed, or proposed, that are restrictive, prohibitive or coercive measures, directly aimed against the Labor group. Among these may be mentioned the Lever law; the Esch-Cummins Bill; the Poindexter Anti-Strike Bill; the Calder Bill; and such by law established institutions as the Kansas Industrial Court. Then there are adverse court decisions, for example the recent decision of the Supreme Court of the United States in the Duplex Printing Press Company case, and which decision practically de¬ stroys the Clayton Act, and other decisions all taking away from those who labor the exercise of their natural rights, or depriving them of legal protection. A Postscript You may find fault with many things in this chapter; you may object that there are more investors than I claim. Very well, change the proportion as you please. But you cannot deny that dividing the population, or families, of the United States into two separate economic groups— investors and non-investors—is a step forward, and in the right direction—a better group arrangement than we have at present. CHAPTER V The Different Kinds of Investors NTIL someone having access to statistics or data not available to me, will tell ns exactly how many indi¬ vidual investors there are in the United States, I shall adhere to my estimate of fonr million investors in all forms of property, except farms. From this number I will set aside one million whose investments are probably in things other than corporate securities. This leaves three million investors in the securities of corporations. You will probably recall that Charles M. Schwab said that two and a half million persons own, as investors, rights in the profits of the big corporations. My estimate of three million is intended to cover all security holders in all corporations. Separating the Wheat from the Chaff The term investor is used in a rather loose sense in these Capitalistic times. It is applied to hundreds of thousands who are not investors in any sense of the word. Let us make an attempt at clarifying our views on this important point. There is a considerable number of persons who are pro¬ fessional speculators, not investors. They speculate in stocks; they buy on margin. Their profits are derived, not from the industry itself, not from holding the securities of corporations in order to annually derive a dividend, or interest, but from the repeated buying and selling of securi¬ ties. It is a well known fact, and my statement will hardly be .disputed, that nine-tenths of all stock transactions are of a speculative character, the speculator buying one day and selling the next. Senator Cummins, speaking on the floor of the Senate, September 1, 1913, declared that 90 39 40 The New Capitalism percent of the sales (on the New York Stock Exchange) were purely speculative. Moreover, a large percentage of the loans made by the great eastern banks is for the purpose of speculation. The following, from the Chicago Daily News (July 11, 1921) sheds an interesting light on this phase of our subject: “It is estimated that the daily call money turnover in the New York market is now only $10,000,000 to $15,000,- 000, against a normal of $40,000,000 to $50,000,000. The high level of Wall Street borrowings ran to $1,750,000,000 in July, 1919, but the belief is that it runs little beyond $600,000,000 now. Improvement in the stock exchange clearing machinery has tended to reduce the amount of money necessary to transact a day’s business.” The annual volume of purely speculative stock transac¬ tions can be gauged by this rather frank admission. Call loans are loans made for a short time to the professional speculators in stocks, not to Iona fide investors. They borrow the money to speculate with, buying on margin, never, or at least rarely, paying the full market price for the number of shares involved. By no stretch of the im¬ agination can one who borrows money for the purpose of marginal speculation be called- an investor. Half of our difficulties and misunderstandings would disappear if we would only call things by their right names. The difference between a speculator and an investor is the difference between night and day; as marked as the difference between a skunk and a robin. An Estimate of the Number of Speculative Investors It would be interesting and illuminating to know exactly how many speculative “investors”—save the mark! there are in the United States. But there are no- statistics. Neither are the professional speculators listed in the sta¬ tistics pertaining to “Occupations” compiled by the De¬ partment of Commerce, and which purport to give a com¬ plete record of everybody “ten years of age and upward The Different Kinds of Investors 41 engaged in gainful occupations,” although the Census Statistics for 1910 gives 23,600 commercial brokers and commission men; 13,522 stockbrokers; and 8,391 brokers not specified, and promoters. Beyond a doubt the specula¬ tors in securities—whether you call them speculative in¬ vestors, or professional speculators, or gamblers in securi¬ ties is to me immaterial—constitute a considerable contin¬ gent of the group it pleases financial writers to call investors. Let us, for the present, say that one-half of the three million investors are of the speculative kind—that is to say, one and a half million investors are, in reality, speculators, not investors. If you think this estimate too high, or too low, change it to suit yourself. I shall not mind it. I will even allow you to call them investors, on condition, how¬ ever, that you designate them as mala fide investors to distinguish them from the bona fide investors. The Bona Fide Investors There are left, then, a million and a half of investors in the securities of the various corporations—men and women who paid cash for their securities, and who are content with a reasonable return on their holdings. These I will call bona fide investors. Most of them are small investors; their individual holdings are not large; their collective profits, by comparison w r ith the profits made by the speculative—or mala fide investors, are negligible. As far as the industries in which they happen to have invested are concerned, they are nonentities. They take no active part in any of the industries. They know nothing about the business of which they are a part by virtue of their holdings; they have no voice in its management; and nothing at all to say about the companies’ policies. They are not consulted; an expression of their opinion isn’t solicited; their advice isn’t sought; and if it were volun¬ tarily given would be considered as an impertinence. They attend no conferences, or committee or directors’ meetings; not even the stockholders’ meetings. They do not elect 42 The New Capitalism the officers or directors. Their vote is never cast in person; always by proxy, the proxy holders being invariably an integral part of the corporation’s personnel. The Usefulness of the Small Investor There is apparent at the present time a concerted en¬ deavor on the part of ‘ ‘ Big Business ’ ’ to increase the tribe of small stockholders. Thus, for example, we read edi¬ torially in the Chicago Journal of Commerce (November 9, 1920) : “A wider distribution of the stocks among small inves¬ tors is the campaign of corporations. As one financial writer put it, speaking of the railroads, ‘They will never get public opinion behind them and supporting them until they have a great body of small stockholders among those who use their service—the farmer, the shopkeeper, the commercial traveler, the manufacturer. They have got to do what the public utilities did so successfully, entrench themselves in the good will of the people by making the public financially interested in their successful opera¬ tions.’ ” Those who constitute ‘ ‘ Big Business ’ ’ long ago discovered that the best way to control public opinion and curb ad¬ verse criticism, is to make a considerable portion of the public, at least nominally, co-partners in their sundrv Capitalistic exploitation schemes. The truth of the matter is the small investor is a conve¬ nience to the big corporations rather than a necessity. That he is frequently considered as a necessary evil may be concluded from the ruthlessness with which he is elimi¬ nated whenever his continued presence is construed as obnoxious or superfluous. One has but to examine the records pertaining to some of the wrecked railroad proper¬ ties of the United States to discover in what esteem the small investor is held. For all practical Capitalistic pur¬ poses the small investor is a supernumerary—a spear- bearer ; he adds impressiveness to the play, picturesqueness to the scene. The Different Kinds of Investors 43 Women Investors—Widows and Orphans Women are especially desirable among the small inves¬ tors, for with them in the crowd, particularly when they can be spoken of as “widows and orphans,” who is so ungallant, so unchivalrous, so bold as to throw stones at them? W. W. Atterbury, Vice President of the Pennsyl¬ vania Railroad Company, recently declared that the Penn¬ sylvania Railroad had 140,000 stockholders, over half of whom are women. I hardly know why Mr. Atterbury so insistently stressed the sex of a majority of his investors—for investor is a noun—common gender. When the Pennsylvania Railroad recently reduced its dividend rate from six to four percent, did the women stockholders, “widows and orphans,” fare better than the men stockholders? Why this sex emphasis? What difference does it make whether an investor is male or female, Jew or Gentile; his or her color black, white, red, or yellow? Yes! What difference does it make? Because an investor is a woman does that make the investment more sacred, or the property rights more inviolable? The laws of economics do not differentiate. In actual business prac¬ tice a female is grist for the economic mill as well as a male; as great a profit can be, and is, made out of a female as out of a male—out of a child as out of an adult, out of a widow as out of an orphan. Much of the profit of corpo¬ rations is derived from the labor of underpaid women and children. Sex does not protect women stockholders when a cor¬ poration decides to pay no dividends to its stockholders, sometimes for years on a stretch, as in the case of many railroads and public utilities; or when dividends are re¬ duced, as in the case of the Pennsylvania Railroad, from six to four percent. And in those cases where it can be shown that the insiders defrauded the stockholders, froze them out, robbed them of their just due by looting treas¬ uries, grafting and mismanagement and wrecking of prop¬ erties into which women had been persuaded to invest, The New Capitalism 44 one looks in vain for any special consideration extended to “widows and orphans.” The Smoke Screen Purpose The principal value of the small investor is that he or she can be used as a smoke screen, under cover of which it is possible to do many things which otherwise could not be done. “If Big Business is in a conspiracy,” said Mr. Schwab, “quite a number of people seem involved in it.” It is this smoke screen purpose that explains the small investor’s popularity. Employees as Stockholders Running parallel with the Capitalistic plan to increase the number of smoke screen investors is the Capitalistic campaign (begun ten or twelve years ago) to inveigle the employees of corporations—wage earners and salaried men and women—into becoming stockholders. During the past few years a considerable number of the leading corporations have ingeniously put forth Employees’ Stock Subscription plans. For example: On Thanksgiving Day, 1920, the daily papers announced that the directors of the Standard Oil Company of New Jersey had voted to submit to its stockholders “a plan by which about 37,000 employees in America would be assisted in acquiring stock. Increase in the common stocks by $10,000,000, accompanied by the reductions of the present $100 par value to $25, is included in the proposition. Employees who have been active in the Company’s service for a year or more will be eligible to acquire stock.” According to Mr. Gary 1 on April 30, 1919, more than 40,000 employees were stockholders in the United States Steel Corporation. “Their aggregate holdings amounted to more than 186,000 shares of stock at a par value of $18,600,000. “In January, 1920, employees of the United States Steel Corporation and the subsidiary companies, were again i The Magazine of Wall Street (November 13, 1920). The Different Kinds of Investors 45 offered the privilege of subscribing for shares of the com¬ mon stock of the corporation. . . . Subscriptions have been received from a total of 66,311 employees, for an aggregate number of 167,263 shares. This is the largest subscription received under any offer. ’ ’ 2 This endeavor on the part of ‘ ‘ Big Business ’ ’ to grapple to itself its employees “with hoops of steel,” has several notions behind it. Sir Charles Wright Macara, reputed to be “one of the foremost business men in England,” re¬ cently said: “If the workmen feel that they must earn more to face the cost of living, they should accept a monetary interest in the industries which give them employment. . . . This principle of individual co-partnership would help to solve many of the problems pending between Capital and Labor. * ’ 3 But we need not go to England for proof that there is method in the madness that is trying to make labor parti- ceps criminis in the sundry Capitalistic schemes. Here, for example, are a few excerpts from a speech made by Dr. Charles A. Eaton, before the Chicago Association of Com¬ merce : “Where are we going to find new resources and capital for working the industries of this country? We have got to find it. I tell you, gentlemen, that it is right here in the surplus, the savings of the working people of this nation. . . . “I believe that we could turn into the industries of this country about two billion dollars a year from that one source alone, and every investor so guaranteed and so looked after and cared for and educated, would become a tower of strength against all the revolutionary doctrines 1 At the end of 1921 the United States Steel Corporation reported 107,439 stockholders, over one-half of whom it would seem, are em¬ ployees. But their aggregate holdings 353,263 shares, computed at par, represent a value of $35,326,300, which is less than three percent of the authorized capital stock of the United States Steel Corporation. 8 “In Search of a Peaceful World,” by Sir. Charles Wright Macara quoted in the Chicago Daily News, December 31, 1920. 46 The New Capitalism of radicalism and stupidities that are sweeping over the world today. There is a great field there. ’ ’ 4 This is what I call killing a whole flock of birds with a stick of dynamite. Dr. Eaton is right—“There is a great field there.” If “Big Business” can succeed in tying, and keeping tied to its chariot, a considerable number of wage earners, its forward course henceforth will be a veritable triumphal procession. The Nexus of the Matter But I will not allow myself in this chapter to be carried away by the temptation to inquire into the concealed mo¬ tives inspiring and actuating “Big Business” in any of its designs. I set out to approximate the constituency and complexion of the investor group, and shall therefore re¬ sume the pursuit of my immediate purpose. I have estimated 5 the total number of investors as four million persons, one million of whom I have set aside as constituting a group whose investments are in things other than the securities of corporations. This leaves three mil¬ lion in the securities investor group, which I have divided as follows: Non-speculative, or Iona fide investors, 1,500,000. Speculative, or mala fide investors, 1,500,000. But even though we were to say that four million inves¬ tors collectively held all the securities issued by all the corporations in the United States, the one thing I desire above all others to emphasize, is that the virtual ownership and control of the important corporate properties is vested in the hands of about one percent of the investors, or about 40,000 persons. Nay! I’ll go a step farther and say that actual ownership and control is concentrated in the hands of one-tenth of one percent—-or approximately 4000 indi¬ viduals or families of the so-called investors.- Indeed it would not be difficult to show that dominant ownership and 4 Quoted from Chicago Commerce, March 12, 1921. * I shall be glad to correct my tentative estimates the moment authentic or official statistics, fully covering the points involved, are forthcoming. The Different Kinds of Investors 47 control resides in less than one-hundredth of one percent of the total number of investors—in 400 families or estates, rather than in 4000 individuals. I could easily fill a dozen pages with relevant statistics, all tending to support me in my contention; but I do not consider this necessary at the present moment, particularly since succeeding chapters will go far toward establishing the fact. These four hundred, or four thousand, or forty thousand (more or less, as you choose) circle within circle, constitute the inner Capitalistic cabal—are the center of the Capi¬ talistic System as we know it today; the chief actors in, and beneficiaries of, what it pleases some to call “the established order”—which is nothing else than Capitalistic Mam- monism. CHAPTER VI The Capitalistic Entrepreneurs IME was in the history of our industrial develop¬ ment, when we had a race of men who were pioneers in business enterprises; men who, with small capital at their command, built up the leading industries of the nation successfully and to surprising proportions. Consid¬ ering them as a group, we can say that they were men of native ability, of shrewd intelligence, of sturdy character, of robust integrity. Many of them, by hard work, laid the foundation of modest fortunes upon which they built slowly and conservatively. True, there were few millionaires among them; most of them hardly dared to dream of ever becoming more than moderately rich. Captains of Industry These men who founded, or were at the head of, the lead¬ ing industries and enterprises were called Captains of Industry, as indeed they were. The railroad president was actually a railroad man—builder or principal owner—tak¬ ing a personal interest, and feeling the pride of manage¬ ment or ownership, and the glory of achievement, in the properties over whose destinies he presided. The president of a steel mill was an iron-master; and so on, covering the entire list of industries. Captains of Finance In those times banking was a distinct business; and the banker a business man whose business it was to mass to¬ gether small amounts of idle money and wealth and bring them into use. Through his agency wealth, which would 48 The Capitalistic Entrepreneurs 49 otherwise be unproductive, became productive. The banker was, therefore, a Captain of Finance, the intermediary between those who possessed capital and those who em¬ ployed it. As such he was a part of the business machine —the main spring of the Clock of Commerce—the pen¬ dulum, if you will. “The Old Order Changeth” But towards the end of the nineteenth century a tremen¬ dous change took place in the business of banking. The banker, whose profits and success as a business man de¬ pended as much upon the continued good will and patron¬ age of men in other businesses as upon his reputation for honesty and square dealing; the banker whose sterling character, unquestioned integrity and sound business judg¬ ment were his chief assets, ceased to exist, and in his place appeared the Investment banker, as different from the old style banker as night from day. With his coming the old business and banking methods were contemptuously kicked aside. New business and banking principles were substi¬ tuted for the old; new policies were adopted; new methods introduced, new practices instituted. Thus the ‘ ‘ established order” came to an abrupt end, and a new order was estab¬ lished almost overnighty we might say, and by a few men . The Advent of the “Investment Banker” The old style banker dealt in actual capital, actual wealth, actual securities, and loaned the capital submitted to his care against actual values and actual assets. The new Investment banker took all these as a basis, and added thereto vast amounts of fictitious capital and fictitious wealth, which he himself created by a stroke of the pen; arbitrarily inflated values, vastly in, excess of existing assets; against which fictitious valuation he issued ‘ ‘ securi¬ ties ’ ’—stocks and bonds which at their inflated value could be used as credit instruments, and upon which he borrowed or loaned, or, more properly speaking, took or extended 50 The New Capitalism credit many times greater than was justified by the actual value of the physical assets. 1 Conscious of the tremendous power vested in their abso¬ lute monopoly of the nation’s finances—their unchallenged control of the nation’s money and credit; quick to see the possibilities of a still greater expansion of that power through the medium of inflated securities flotations—and by no means blind to the immense profits that could be made to accrue to them—a small group of Investment bankers, under the leadership of J. Pierpont Morgan, con¬ stituted theniselves into syndicates for the clear cut pur¬ pose bf J thkiflg"fiver the principal industries, national re¬ sources, raw materials—everything, in fact, out of which a profit could be made—with what success is now generally m -gbifj; gaoiiiaird bniiog The Ascendancy of the Captains of Finance bio 9 fit /noii Jneisnib as Thus if came to pass that Capitalists, or bankers—more accurately speaking, Investment bankers—became Entre¬ preneurs; the new Captains of Finance arrogated to them¬ selves also the role of Captains of Industry. Capital be- came the employer. And yet, only a few years before, the possibility of such a thing was scouted by eminent econom¬ ists. For example, Francis A. Walker, “a distinguished American economist” writing in 1875, vehemently main¬ tained t that the capitalist and the employer were entirely distinct; indeed he insisted on calling the employer a middle man, placing him between the capitalist and the fBjiqso 9 dt bsxLsol him ,89fthuD enalized for their continued patronage by being made to pay a bigger price for the goods they purchased. It’s D iff event N ow But since the birth of the Capitalistic System “good will” has ceased to have any meaning. Not only is it con¬ sidered as an asset on which a dividend is to be earned or paid; in most cases it is the principle asset, and is often caxntalized for more than the plants of a corporation. One of the big merchandising firms in the United States has The Principle of Inflation 83 placed a value of twenty-seven million on its plants; and a value of thirty million on “good will.” Its total capital¬ ization is $115,000,000. The Decline in “Good Will” Incidentally let me add that during the past few years the business of the firm I have in mind has decreased from twenty-five to thirty-five percent. Consequently, if logic is to prevail, it can be said that the “good will” of this particular firm has declined from one-fourth to one-third. Therefore, the capitalization of the “good will” should be reduced proportionately. But there has been no reduction in the capitalization; the shrinkage has been in the value, or market price, of the securities. The bona fide investor, as usual, must bear the brunt of the depreciation; he alone suffers a loss of dividends and in the value of the securities he purchased. “Good will,” as Capitalistically employed, is, more prop¬ erly speaking, ‘ ‘ bad will. ’ ’ At any rate when the inflated securities issued against it are offered daily, and bought and sold on the market as if “ good will ’ ’ were a commodity whose value fluctuates, quoted, perhaps, at 100 on the first of the month and worth only fifty cents on the dollar a few weeks later; paying dividends one year, and none the next —“good will” is not markedly in evidence. In plain language, “earning power” and “good will” are nothing more than Capitalistic devices invented to con¬ ceal the cardinal crime of OVERCAPITALIZATION. Just Inflation When we speak of Overcapitalization or Inflation, the mind, somehow, harps on the inflated valuation of corpo¬ rations. Yet that is only half the story. Inflation is the order of the day, and it is universally practiced. Inflation to the right of us; inflation to the left of us; inflation in front of us; inflation all around us;—inflation everywhere, based on false valuations arbitrarily raised to the uttermost limit. 82 The New Capitalism I want to make this perfectly clear, and I ask the reader to keep it in mind—viz., that when I speak of Overcapital¬ ization or Inflation I do not mean only the overcapitalized corporations, and which issue stocks and bonds against a greatly inflated valuation; I also include inflated values of properties that are not incorporated, such as real estate, land, etc. In many cases the inflation predicable of such properties is even greater than the inflation of corporate properties. I will not take a narrow view of, nor a niggardly stand on value. I can subscribe to a healthy, fair and reasonable increase in the value (price) of property, especially if the increase is computed on an absolutely fair and reasonable basis. I have nothing to say against a gradual and natural increase, but I protest against sudden and tremendous increases—in brief against artificial, excessive and arbi¬ trary inflation. This “inflation ’ 1 of valuation is now general, particularly with regard to the valuation of real estate in the big cities. It has given us excessively high rents. See for yourself how it works: If I occupy a house whose value, inclusive of the land, is $5000, and the landlord computes rental at, let us say, ten percent on the actual value or the fairly computed amount invested, I will have fairly reasonable rent. But if the landlord raises the “value” of the prop¬ erty which I occupy to $10,000, it is easy to see that he will demand an excessive rent in order to earn ten percent on the inflated valuation. But it is not only residential property whose “value” has been raised to the topmost limit. Business property of all kinds, factories, offices and stores have been included in the general scheme of inflation, with the result that the occupants pay the higher rentals and pass them along to the public. And the same process of “passing it along” applies to every line of business or form of property of which inflation can be predicated. And the non-investor is “the goat.” CHAPTER IX The Volume of Inflation 0 T HE overcapitalization of the corporate enterprises in the United States is simply fabulous. Under cor¬ porate enterprises might be included every kind of corporate property—railroads, transportation systems, pub¬ lic utilities, manufacturing industries, mining and sundry other enterprises. But the paucity of statistics pertaining to these different property classifications makes computa¬ tion of their actual value and their fictitious valuations difficult, almost impossible. Besides it is not necessary for the immediate purposes of this book. I shall, therefore, confine myself in this chapter to the one kind of corporate properties for which fragmentary, rather than approximate data are available—viz., the manufacturing industries. If I were put to the necessity of making an estimate— not a wild guess, but an estimate based upon careful com¬ putations—I should say that the overcapitalization of the manufacturing industries in the United States is four times greater than the actual value of the properties. This has been shown by actual figures, as regards the United States Steel Corporation, by which, in round numbers, $500 of se¬ curities were issued for every $100 of actual value of phys¬ ical assets. Making due allowance for the passing of twenty years of time, and taking everything into consideration, and also, above all, because I want to be conservative and fair to those concerned, I will say that the overcapitaliza¬ tion of the manufacturing industries today is approximately twice the amount of the actual value of the properties capi¬ talized. That is to say, for every dollar of actual value— 83 84 The New Capitalism value fairly and liberally computed—of the productive in¬ dustrial properties in the United States, two dollars of inflation have been added. “Where Ignorance is Bliss—’Twere Folly to be Wise” If we had complete data for all industrial properties, if we had the complete figures for all the industrial corpora¬ tions in the United States, if we had the totals pertaining to the capitalization of these properties and the amount of securities, common and preferred stock outstanding, and bonds and notes issued, we could at least approximate the total amount of inflation. But unfortunately, and for reasons that we need not inquire into at this time, this important information has never been put into concrete shape for the convenience and edification of the general public. In such works as Poor’s and Moody’s Manuals we find a wealth of information, composed of thousands of pages, with regard to the securities, industrial and others, but no tabulated statistics covering these points. Other statistical experts seem to be equally reticent. The United States Government, in all its hundreds of volumes of star tistics and data pertaining to hundreds of more or less interesting subjects, has never attempted to publish any statistics that would throw a definite light on this particu¬ lar subject. Perhaps it is well for the peace of mind of the public at large that the statistics pertaining to the amount of overcapitalization, that is, of securities, sans value, be not published. “When Doctors Disagree, Disciples Then Are Free” In the absence, therefore, of any worth-while tabulations, we are put to the necessity of approximating the situation from a correlation, or piecing together, of fragmentary (and sometimes contradictory) figures having bearing on the points involved. According to the 1920 Bureau of Census Statistics, the The Volume of Inflation 85 capital of 275,793 manufacturing establishments in 1914, aggregated $22,790,980,000. In its latest Summary of Man¬ ufactures, published October 4,1921, the United States Cen¬ sus Bureau gives the capitalization of 289,768 manufactur¬ ing establishments as $44,678,911,000—an increase of twenty-two billion in six years; which would be at the rate of about three and one-half billion a year. It is to be remembered that ordinarily capitalization re¬ fers to stock; it does not take into account the bonds and notes issued by corporations. If the figures for bond and note issues could be obtained and added to the stock issues, the total securities issued by the industrial corporations would yield a staggering figure. Unfortunately there are no detailed statistics. Wherever we encounter them they are incomplete, and unsatisfactory, or camouflaged, or so twisted and turned as to be almost irrelevant. For example: The Statistical Abstract of the United States Census (1920) gives the Journal of Com¬ merce and Commercial Bulletin of New York as the source of the following statistics pertaining to “the capital in¬ vested in new enterprises whose authorized capital equalled or exceeded $100,000. ” 1917 . 4,607,894,100 1918 . 2,599,753,600 1919 . 12,677,229,600 1920 . 13,998,944,2001 Total. 33,883,821,500 2 One may ask: precisely what is meant by “capital invested in new enterprises ’ ’ ? What about the new capital invented from 1917 to 1920 in old enterprises? And does the “capital invested” include notes and bonds as well as stock issues, or only the latter? 1 Since January, 1921, following’ the decision of the United States Supreme Court that stock dividends are non-taxable, there has been a veritable orgy of inflation of capitalization. Billions of undistributed surplus profits that had been allowed to accumulate pending the decision of the Supreme Court, were transmuted into securities. In some in¬ stances a four hundred percent stock issue was distributed. 2 According to the Summary of Manufactures for 1919, published by the United States Department of Commerce, the capital of 290,111 establishments was $44,776,000,000. 86 The New Capitalism “Confusion Worse Confounded” At any rate, according to these statistics, a total of nearly thirty-four billion dollars was added to the various enter¬ prises during four years. Yet we were told that in 1914 the capitalization of the manufacturing establishments amounted to nearly twenty-three billion dollars. Adding to this nearly twenty-three billion the nearly thirty-four billion of “capital invested” from 1917 to 1920, the total would be fifty-seven billion. Yet we were told as late as October, 1921, that the capitalization of the manufacturing establishments was approximately forty-five billion—a dif¬ ference of twelve billion. (And be it remembered we have not even touched upon the item “capital invested” from 1914 to 1917.) All of which emphasizes the untrustworthy character of the statistics upon which many financial writers base their solemn dicta and cocksure asseverations. Let me give you one more example of the utter unrelia¬ bility of securities statistics. Please note that according to the United States Census Statistics (see statistics, page 85) “the capital invested in new enterprises” in 1920 was $13,998,944,200. Then compare that with the following from the New International Year Book for 1920: “Issues of new domestic corporate securities in 1920 aggregate $3,107,000,000, of which $1,157,000,000 were stocks. Total issues exceeded those of 1919 by $86,000,000. Of the total, $416,000,000 were offered by railroads, and $2,691,000,000 by industrial concerns. The amount of new long term municipal bonds issued was $653,000,000, while loans of foreign companies and corporations placed here aggregate $345,000,000. It would thus appear that the grand total of security issues in this country in the year 1920, exceeded $4,000,000,00.” Ten Billion Dollars of Securities a Year What do you make of it? Isn’t it confusing? But let us proceed; perhaps light will break through a rift in the clouds. The Volume of Inflation 87 The Wall Street Journal, which ought to know whereof it speaks, early in 1921, in an endeavor to explain the great decline in stocks and sundry securities, gives a list of ten reasons for the decided downward movement, among which we find these three: “Flotation of companies at inflated valuations, par¬ ticularly petroleum companies without established merit. “Too many securities for the public properly to digest. As an example, over four hundred issues were recently traded in on the New York Stock Exchange in a single five-hour session. Close to one-third of the issues were stocks listed over the last year or two. In three years there has been an increase in total of public and private bonds and stocks listed on the New York Stock Exchange of something like $30,000,000,000, or at the rate of $300 per capita. Add new stocks not listed, and the total will reach a much larger figure. “Billions in new financing, including flotation of hun¬ dreds of millions of dollars of foreign securities in this market. ’ 9 From this confusion of conflicting statistics I return to my original statement made in the beginning of this chap¬ ter, viz., that for every dollar of actual value of the pro¬ ductive industrial properties in the United States, two dollars of inflation have been added. The Public Pays the Interest If we accept the statistics of the United States Census Bureau, published October 4, 1921, according to which the capitalization of 289,768 manufacturing establishments is $44,678,911,000—forty-five billion in round numbers—then the actual value of the plants would be fifteen billion dol¬ lars, and thirty billion would be sheer inflation. But the public is paying interest on this thirty billion of inflated capitalization. Computing the interest at six percent the public is being mulcted of $1,800,000,000 a year on this one item alone. In addition to capital stock there are bond and note issues against the inflated valuation of the industrial 88 The New Capitalism properties, on which the public is also paying interest. And mark you well! this is predicated only of manufactur¬ ing establishments; it does not include railroads, public utilities, mines, etc., for which I shall make no estimate for the present. You may make your own computations if you care to pursue the subject further. A “Saltus Lyricus” Now for an abrupt transition. Two lessons at least, we learn from this chapter, and they stand out clear and strong from the maze of stupendous figures and conflicting statements. They are: 1: That the aggregate corporate securities issues are simply tremendous. 2 : That the securities issues are out of all proportion to the actual value of the properties against which they are issued. Writing at a time (1883) when pools, syndicates and mergers were in their experimental stages, and consolida¬ tions, monopolies and Trusts in their infancy; when stock and bond issues were not so recklessly floated as at present, Henry Demarest Lloyd 3 said that “ Securities have become as staple an article of production with us, as wheat, cotton, oil or hogs. One million dollars worth a day of stocks and bonds is needed in prosperous years to supply the demands of the New York Stock Exchange. . . Thirty-eight years ago, according to Henry Demarest Lloyd, one million dollars worth a day of stocks and bonds was needed “to supply the demands of the New York Stock Exchange . 91 Mr. Lloyd was simply horrified; and yet one million dollars a day was only about a third of a billion of securities issues a year. How does that compare with the securities issued today? Basing my estimate on the sundry statistics and statements quoted in this chapter, I think it is exceedingly conserva¬ tive to say that during the last three years corporate secur- 3 “Making- Bread Dear,” North American Review, August, 1883. The Volume of Inflation 89 ities of all kinds (stocks, bonds, notes) were issued at the rate of five billion dollars a year; or about 416 million a month; or about 16 million a day; which is approximately two million dollars of securities every hour of every working day in the year. What pikers they must have been in the times of which William Demarest Lloyd wrote! For every dollar of secur¬ ities issued in 1883 we are today issuing sixteen dol¬ lars of securities; for every million they issued thirty-eight years ago, we are issuing sixteen million! “He Babbled o’ Green Fields”—Shakespeare Even now I hear a babble of voices, all clamoring to be heard in defense and justification of the tremendously greater securities issues of today. ‘‘We have grown tre¬ mendously in population, in size, in wealth, etc.,” they are saying in chorus. Aye, we have! That I will not even attempt to deny! But, hear me now: The volume of ~bona fide business was not sixteen times greater than in 1883; the popula¬ tion was not sixteen times greater; the production was not sixteen times greater, and consumption was not sixteen times greater; exports were not sixteen times greater, and certainly the increase in the physical assets, or in the legitimate value of the properties was not sixteen times greater; then why should the volume of corporate stocks and bond issues be sixteen times greater? Perhaps some economic Solomon will arise among us to explain; perhaps some statistical wizard will enlighten us on this important point, or some camouflage expert will set us right. 4 * Those who are disposed to contend that I have exaggerated the volume of securities issued, or that the statistics on which I base my estimate are open to criticism, or need qualification, are at liberty to substitute the correct figures (if they have them) for those I have given. Indeed I shall not mind if they cut down my claim by fully one-half. In that case we would be issuing about eight dollars of se¬ curities for every dollar issued in 1883. In that case, too, I would maintain that population, production, consumption, etc., is not eight times greater than in 1883. 90 The New Capitalism “How Long, 0 Lord, How Long—” How long is this debauch of issuing “securities” at the rate of say from four to five billion a year going to continue? Where is it going to stop? When will the bubble burst? Even though the tremendous increase were justified by growth in the volume of business, population, production, consumption, exports, etc.,—this I contend, that the end of possibilities is in sight. Certainly the enor¬ mous increase observable from 1883 to 1920 cannot be duplicated during the next thirty-eight years; nor can the same percentage of increase be maintained for any length of time. Maturing Securities But I hear a murmur among the defenders of the Capitalistic System, growing louder and louder, finally bursting into an angry shout of accusation against me for having overlooked a most important point, viz., that there are maturing securities which must be taken into account. That is a very good point, and cognizance must be taken of it in any book or article pretending to discuss the sub¬ ject of securities issues. Indeed so important is this point that I prefer to let an authority speak for me. The 1920-21 edition of “Poor’s Handbook of Investors’ Holdings,” prepared entirely from the latest published official data, and including the holdings of about three hundred and eighty companies additional to those appear¬ ing in last year’s issue, devoted seventy-five pages (six point type, double column) to a list of securities maturing from January 1, 1921, to December 31, 1923. “This com¬ pilation, ’ ’ we are told in the preface, ‘ ‘ covers all the secur¬ ities in which there is known public interest, embracing bonds, notes, etc., of Steam Railroads, Street Railways, Public Utilities and Industrial, Mining and Miscellaneous Corporations.” These maturing securities aggregate $2,664,337,634, which is less than ten percent of the new securities issued during The Volume of Inflation 91 the past three years. In other words, for every dollar of maturing securities nine dollars of new securities are issued; for every million of maturing securities, nine million new securities are issued. Or, to express it more in con¬ formity with the basis of calculation adopted in this chap¬ ter: Securities are maturing at the rate of about 880 million dollars a year; or about 74 million a month; or about $2,500,000 a day. “Maturing Securities” that Perpetuate the Debt But that is not the end of our story. The practice of issuing new stocks and bonds and selling them in order to pay off the maturing securities, is growing alarmingly. As a matter of fact, many of the maturing securities are not retired , they are merely refunded; and thus the liability or debt is perpetuated. This is called high corporate finance ■—a fine scheme for the holders of the maturing securities, and bankers and brokers, but it does not lighten the burden for the non-investors, who will continue to be taxed in order to pay the interest on the new securities issued against the old debt. A solitary example will illustrate the point. In a press clipping, dated Washington, May 21, 1921, we read of a new bond issue jointly made by the Northern Pacific Railway Company and the Great Northern Railway Company: ‘‘These corporations have bonds now due that amount to $215,227,000, bearing 4 y 2 percent. To renew this indebtedness they have been authorized by the interstate commerce commission to issue $230,000,000 at 6% percent interest. The higher interest is justified by the railroads on the ground that ‘many brokers whom they have con¬ sulted’ have advised them that this is necessary. “The new bonds are nearly $15,000,000 in excess of the amount of the indebtedness. The difference goes to bankers, brokers and investment dealers, who will receive a com¬ mission for every $100 sold. The market value of the 92 Tlie New Capitalism bonds—what the public pays—is $96.50 for every $100 bond. ‘ ‘ This bond issue means that the people are saddled with an additional tax of $15,000,000, at 6% percent interest, and because the interest rate on $230,000,000 bonds is increased from 4 y 2 percent to 6% percent, the public must also pay this increased wage for the dollar.” Hundreds of similar cases could be cited, all empha¬ sizing that in order to pay maturing bonds, corporations simply issue new bonds. In good business practice the bonded debts of a concern or corporation should be liqui¬ dated out of the earnings; that is to say, should be paid off out of a sinking fund. A business that cannot pay off its bonded indebtedness in the course of fifteen or twenty years, out of its sinking fund, is being mismanaged and deserves to be put through bankruptcy proceedings. The management of a concern or corporation that cannot con¬ duct its business so as to clear it of its burdening incum¬ brances is incompetent, and ought to be removed by the stock and bond holders. The practice, at present, almost universally employed, of meeting maturing debts by new bond issues, is immoral and reprehensible, besides offering all kinds of opportunities for inside jobbing, a phase of the subject which I shall not discuss at this time. Let it be understood that I am not against the bonding of properties; in fact I accept it as a business necessity. But what I do object to is the manner in which maturing bonds are paid—or rather perpetuated—viz., by the sale of other stocks or bonds; and most strenuously do I object to this method, because making a debt upon a property perpetual and even increasing it, and the interest charges thereon, means compelling the public to pay perpetual interest upon the original and the increased debt. Where the Non-Investor Comes In There we have the nexus of this whole subject. The non¬ investor must pay it all. Here you have the principle clearly stated. It is the chief explanation of the High Cost The Volume of Inflation 93 of Living that is afflicting the nation. Whether 20, or 50, or 100 billions of inflation has been added to the actual value of the properties in the United States, it is a burden of ponderous proportions placed upon the backs of the sixteen million families—a gigantic debt against every man, woman and child—the interest on which must be paid by the non-investor public; and it is collected through the instrumentality of higher prices. The greater the debt the greater the interest charge; the greater the interest charge the higher the prices; the higher the prices the higher the Cost of Living. That is clear! Not only is this debt perpetual, it is cumulative; it in¬ creases year after year. Whatever the exact amount of the inflation may be at this hour—whether 20, or 50, or 100 billion—or more or less—unless radical changes are made in the present corporation finance methods—it is likely that at the end of another eighteen or twenty years the debt charged up against the non-investors will have doubled itself. Let me explain what I mean, by giving you a concrete illustration. Let us assume that instead of cash, J. Pierpont Morgan received 62 y 2 million dollars of stock for organizing the United States Steel Corporation. That was the reward for his genius. He didn’t put in a single dollar, but the stock he received increased his wealth 62 1 / 2 million dollars. Now, figuring the interest he was to receive at only five percent, Mr. Morgan drew from the corporation $3,125,000 a year. Within twenty years he (or his heirs) will have drawn out from that one corporation alone, 62 y 2 million dollars, or the full amount of the face value of the stock given him. Then the same process begins over again; that is to say, every twenty years he (or his heirs) will have drawn out 62y 2 million dollars. Within a hundred years his heirs or their descendants, will have drawn out of that one corporation alone, $312,500,000. The Era of Super-Overcapitalization The pioneer period of arbitrary overcapitalization of industries has successfully demonstrated the possibilities of 94 The New Capitalism a System of exploitation. In the beginning overcapitali¬ zation was computed on the basis of a six percent * ‘ earning power ’ 9 on the amount of capital actually invested. But now the era of swper-overcapitalization has begun. Hence¬ forth the stock and bond issues will be based on the “earning power” of the inflated valuation. Through the simple device known as declaring “stock dividends” the overcapitalization will increase automatically, thus making the debt perpetual and yielding cumulative interest. This means placing a crushing weight upon the non-investors. Can they continue to carry the load? My answer is, they cannot! And I will add that once they understand what has been and is being done to them, they will not only, through their combined strength, throw off the burden, but abolish or even destroy the Capitalistic-Mammonistic Sj^stem that aims to crush them. CHAPTER X The Capital Crime of Overcapitalizatiox I T IS one thing to say that overcapitalization is the evil tree that has produced, if not all, at least most, of our economic troubles, and quite another thing to prove it. It will not do merely to make assertions; I must be able to give definite and demonstrable reasons for the opinions I hold. For years I have held that overcapitalization is fun¬ damentally wrong; that although sanctioned by law it is wicked and indefensible; economically it cannot be con¬ doned; from a business standpoint it must be condemned as a “delusion and a snare” and altogether unsound. I shall not categorically animadvert on these points in this chapter, but my collective contention will be made clear when this work is taken in its entirety. More recently I have maintained that overcapitalization is the fundamental cause for the High Cost of Living, and entirely to blame for the decrease in the purchasing power of mcney. I furthermore maintain that the system of overcapitalization is responsible for the system of inade¬ quate wages, and the determination of Capitalistic employ¬ ers to keep the wages of the mass of workers even below a mere living basis. All these, and many other things, I shall try, in the course of this book, to prove to anyone amenable to reason and disposed to be fair; to anyone whose mind is not saturated with Capitalistic toxins and whose pockets are not bulging with ill-gotten gains—thanks to the ingenious Capitalistic System. The Party of the First Part For the sake of brevity and greater lucidity let us con¬ sider the effect of overcapitalization upon the two parties 95 96 The New Capitalism concerned—the chief beneficiaries of the Capitalistic Sys¬ tem—the Capitalistic group; and the non-beneficiaries—the non-investors—the public. The beneficiaries we will call the Party of the First Part. Great and calculable benefits have accrued to the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneurs through the creation of ouercapital. Let me briefly summarize the immense benefits and mani¬ fold advantages that redounded to the Capitalistic Entre¬ preneur group: 1: Overcapitalization at least trebled (in many cases in the beginning quadrupled and quintupled) the wealth of the constituent members of the Capitalistic System. 2: Overcapitalization at least trebled the profits of the beneficiaries of the System. 3: Overcapitalization at least trebled the credit , i.e., the borrowing power, of all the persons concerned. 4: Overcapitalization conferred upon every member in the Capitalistic group a greatly increased capacity for speculating in stocks and bonds. These, in brief, are the cardinal benefits from which innumerable minor advantages have flowed, all emptying into the coffers of those chiefly concerned. Long before overcapitalization of the industrial corpora¬ tions became general the control of capital and credit was centered in a small group. Overcapitalization increased the hold and power of this small group, which automatically became the nucleus—the heart—of the greater Capitalistic System. It was overcapitalization that brought into the charmed circle of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs,' hundreds —and their number in time grew into thousands—of new men, all of whom can directly trace their rise to greater wealth and power to the date of the inclusion of their ‘ * recapitalized ’ ’ corporations into the System. The Master Mind J. Pierpont Morgan was able to organize the United States Steel Corporation primarily because he was the head of the banking house of J. P. Morgan & Co. In the finan- The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 97 cial oligarchy he was the recognized dictator; his will was law, his mere nod a command, his power greater than that of a Czar. But even a financial potentate requires some¬ thing more than autocratic power, and this something more, if I have read the records correctly, J. Pierpont Morgan possessed to an uncanny degree. No doubt others before him had vaguely sensed the possibilities of mergers, com¬ bines and consolidations, but they lacked his resourceful¬ ness, and so their visions never fructified. Although navi¬ gators before Columbus may have dreamed of an El Dorado, only Columbus translated his dream into a voyage beyond the charted seas. With all his dictatorial power Morgan could not have successfully organized the United States Steel Corporation had his genius not prompted him to perfect the machinery that enabled him to carry out his plans. The particular machinery which carried the United States Steel Corpora¬ tion, as well as every other ‘ ‘ reorganized ’ ’ corporation since, over the rocks of disaster to the haven of security, is over- capitalization. It wasn’t the amount of money in Mr. Morgan’s and the allied banks, and which the dictator could have commandeered had he deemed it necessary, that made the United States Steel Corporation a success; nor yet the credit he might have commanded in an emergency. It was the amount of money that wasn’t in Mr. Morgan’s, or allied, banks; it was the amount of money that didn’t exist —that had neither been minted, nor printed, and for which there was no gold or silver bullion in the United States Treasury vaults, nor any place on earth; it was the amount of wealth that existed only in the Morgan mind, and which the master conjurer made his audience believe actually existed; it was the amount of capital that his legerdemain persuaded the world into imagining into existence that is responsible for the financial success of the United States Steel Corporation, as well as every other so-called success¬ ful corporation organized since, according to the plans and specifications laid down by Morgan, the conjuror. Mr. Morgan’s remarkable feat of organizing the most 98 The New Capitalism gigantic corporation in the world, stamps him less a wizard of financiering than as a bold necromancer, and master of the black art of Inflation. The magician on the stage shows his audience an empty silk hat, over which he waves his wand; and lo, extracts from it a white rabbit. Mr. Morgan drew from his empty hat not only a single white, unresisting rabbit—but hundreds of millions of wealth and capital. No magician ever succeeded in deceiving his audi¬ ence as he succeeded in deluding the people into believing that there was wealth where there was no wealth; capital where there was no capital; value where there was no value; property where there were no assets; and property rights where there was neither capital, wealth, assets nor value. That his wonderful performance won the admira¬ tion, applause and approval of the men who found them¬ selves made rich over night, goes without saying. That thousands of imitators, lacking *his originality and genius, quickly learned the trick and have since duplicated his performance with a fair degree of success to themselves and others, is a matter of common knowledge. It cannot be denied that the creation of fictitious wealth by a stroke of the pen makes a powerful appeal to the imagination, par¬ ticularly since the wealth thus created can be converted into counterfeit capital and be made the basis for credit out of which further capital accumulations quickly result. Papier Mache Millionaires It is a matter of history that when the United States Steel Corporation was organized, scores of men became millionaires over night. The automatic increase in the wealth of the individuals immediately concerned is the note¬ worthy thing about this whole business of overcapitaliza¬ tion. The man in a given concern, and whose holdings therein are worth, fairly valued, let us say, $500,000, tw T enty-four hours later considers himself, and is rated, worth a million or two. His wealth is increased—doubled or trebled—by a mere resolution of a Board of Directors; his fortune augmented by a stroke of the pen. The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 99 The inherent immorality of arbitrarily inflating the wealth of individuals, or families, from the million dollars, fairly computed, to say three million dollars; or from ten million to thirty million; or from thirty million to ninety million; or from one hundred million to three hundred million; and so on without limit and without rhyme or reason, must be apparent to all w T hose sense of decency is still able to function. Thousands of men today consider themselves worth a certain amount, which, when reduced to actual facts and figures, would be considerably less. Their wealth is largely fictitious; it has no assets behind it—nothing more substan¬ tial than a mythical ‘ ‘ earning power ’ ’—which does not and cannot reside in the fictitious wealth itself, but is derived wholly from the paying power of the Party of the Second Part—the public. Thousands of so-called millionaires only imagine that they are millionaires. I would not venture to ruthlessly destroy the delusions of these papier mache millionaires were it not for the fact that they are hugging their delusions to their souls at my expense—at the expense of all non-investors—the public. The non-investors are penalized through the medium of higher prices for life's commodities. The millions of inflation taken in the aggre¬ gate now run far into the billions. It is on this enormous increase of non-existing wealth that the public must pay interest and dividends, as we shall see in the course of this book. An Objection Ansivered “What difference does it make," said a friend of mine who knows my views but who has strong leanings toward the present Capitalistic System and would defend it against all attacks, “what difference does it make whether a corporation earning, say $240,000 considers this amount as twenty-four percent on a million dollars invested, or six percent on four million invested? In other words, what difference does it make whether the capitalization in the 100 The New Capitalism case given is one million or four million? I cannot see that it makes any difference at all.” My friend is only one of thousands who take this view— they cannot see any difference! “None so blind as he who does not want to see! ’ ’ May I not ask the valiant defenders of the present Capitalistic System, and apologists for all its practices: “If it makes no difference, why do it?” Evi¬ dently, in the minds of those most concerned, there is a difference—and the difference is strongly in their favor, or they would not do it. In the case given the amount of earnings would be the same, viz., $240,000; but the trial balance sheet would read differently. Without the camou¬ flage of overcapitalization the claim that capital earns only six percent is exposed as an outrageous lie. The Capital¬ istic device of a mythical six percent “earning power” is a lie! Capital, under the segis of overcapitalization, earns many times more than six percent on every dollar actually invested, as I shall hope to establish in the course of this book. What I am trying to establish at the present moment is that it does make a difference whether a corporation earning $240,000 is capitalized for a million or for four million. Let me ask: “What is the amount actually invested?” “One million,” says my friend. Then why pretend that four million are invested? It is simply an¬ other gross lie. And these lies we find everywhere; it is upon lies that the Capitalistic System is builded; lies are its sustaining props. When a corporation overcapitalizes two, three or four times, in excess of its actual value, it is but compelling the public to pay interest on wealth that doesn’t exist, and dividends on capital that does not exist. That is an eco¬ nomic injustice, not to be tolerated much longer. But I do not want to wander from my point. Over- capitalization does make a difference. It increases the wealth of the individuals immediately concerned in that they are given securities of a mythical ‘ ‘ value ’ ’ three times as great as the actual value of the assets. The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 101 Fictitious Borrowing and Trading Power But that isn’t all. The issuance, sale, or conveyance of securities largely in excess of the existing assets, auto¬ matically increases the credit facilities or borrowing power of the persons concerned. All of which is fine for the per¬ sons immediately concerned, the borrower; and a splendid source of profit for the banks, which, as is pretty generally known, are under the dominance of the chief Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. For, the inflated securities are collateral, and are accepted as such without question by the creators of fictitious values. The borrowings are “reinvested” in other inflated securities. Beyond a doubt considerably greater sums of money can be made by the favored few than would be possible under a system not based on over- capitalization. Another great advantage to the immediate beneficiaries of the Capitalistic System lies in their ability to trade in and juggle their securities on the Stock Exchange, from which transactions probably as great, if not greater, profits are derived in the course of a year, than from their busi¬ ness enterprises. It must be clear that an increase in interest-bearing wealth and dividend-paying capital; an increase in col¬ lateral, which creates a greatly augmented borrowing power; which in turn confers the power to use a larger amount of capital to 1 i invest 9 ’ in other securities, thus multi¬ plying profits; besides the opportunity of repeatedly selling and buying their own securities, generally at a profit, con¬ stitute a combination of advantages that are of incalculable benefit to any component member of the Capitalistic group. Does overcapitalization make any difference ? It does! A most decided difference! Even under the old Capitalistic System of non-inflation—the era antedating the organiza¬ tion of the United States Steel Corporation—numerous benefits accrued to the proprietors, but at least they were content with returns on actual investments—not imaginary investments; interest on actual wealth, not fictitious wealth. 102 The New Capitalism The possibility of accumulating wealth more or less real, and certainly far in excess of any substantial wealth it would be possible to accumulate sans the device of over- capitalization; and the ability to command credit which can be converted into profit earning capital, has, naturally enough, recommended the trick of overcapitalization—it is nothing more than a trick, and a scurvy trick at that—to all hungering after greater wealth and not particularly scrupulous as to how it is acquired. No Property Rights Where There Is No Property During the past twenty years I have read a number of ponderous books dealing with Property and its Rights— books in which the authors with a great show of learning and many elaborate legal definitions ably defended their thesis. On the general thesis I am in accord with these writers. It is not to dispute or controvert aught that has been written on these subjects that I propose the question: Can there be Rights where there is no Property; or can the rights in a certain piece of property be greater than the actual fairly computed value of that piece of property? To discuss this subject even half way would require many chapters. I shall make no attempt to discuss it. However, I will briefly state the principle involved. The acquisition and possession of property is a sacred indi¬ vidual right. All laws are based on the principle that the rights of property are paramount; and their interpretation by courts proclaims the rights implied by possession in¬ violable and impregnable. I accept this status. I have the utmost respect for property, and shall always defend its rights. But I maintain that there are certain limitations with regard to property and its rights—which no man, nor group of men, has the right to transcend. Property own¬ ership may be absolute; but property rights are only relative. A property owner cannot do with his property as and what he chooses; there is a limit beyond which he cannot go, nor be permitted to go. A gun is a piece of The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 103 property, the owner of the gun a property owner; but the owner of the gun cannot, even if it pleases him, or is to his advantage, shoot his neighbor with his undoubted prop¬ erty—his gun—with impunity. A man who owns a twenty dollar gold piece, minted by the United States Government, is the absolute owner of it; it is his property. All the legislatures cannot deprive him of his property; the courts must recognize and protect his rights in it. But if the owner of that twenty dollar gold piece were to melt it in a pot that belongs to him, and mix it with cheaper metals, all of which belong to him; and with tools belonging to him, converts the twenty dollar United States gold piece into five twenty dollar counterfeit coins, he would be punished, in spite of the fact that the original twenty dollars, and all the baser metals, and all the materials and tools he employed, are his undisputed property. Surely there is none to assert that the owner’s property rights in a twenty dollar gold piece is more than coextensive with the actual value of his property, nor that his absolute ownership gives him the right to trample upon the rights of, or defraud, his neighbor. If the rights of an individual in property of which he is the sole owner and actual possessor are circumscribed, we can certainly challenge the validity of rights in property that does not exist. Thus, for example, we may ask, are the property rights of the stockholders in a corporation greater than the value of the properties themselves. If the actual value of the physical properties of a corporation fairly computed, is $100,000, but the officials of the cor¬ poration arbitrarily give it an inflated valuation of $500,000 and issue against it $500,000 of stock, does the inflation process raise the rights of the stockholders from one hun¬ dred thousand dollars to five hundred thousand? Surely a $100 stock certificate issued against $20 of actual value, confines the stockholders’ rights to the latter figure. As a general proposition I maintain that there can be no rights where there is no property; and that the property rights of stockholders can be no greater than the actual 104 The New Capitalism value of the property against which the stock is issued. I deny that corporation officials or Boards of Directors have the right to arbitrarily and fictitiously raise values. If they have this right, or authority or power, by whom was it conferred? Has the counterfeiter the right or authority or power to convert a $20 gold piece into five $20 counterfeit coins? Certainly not! Neither have cor¬ poration officials the right to convert $20 of property value into $100 of stock value. Calling Things by Their Right Name I care not by what laws sanctioned nor by what courts sustained, the whole thing is a crime against justice, a violation of every law of decency. The practice cannot be defended any more than the counterfeiter can be defended. There is not a state in the Union that has not a law on its statute books aimed against the check-raiser and check forger. In some states it is considered criminal to issue a check against a bank in which its issuer has no deposits; and within recent years attempts have been made to declare the drawing of a check for an amount greater than the drawer has on deposit a criminal offense. It is well known that the United States Government relentlessly prosecutes and severely punishes the counter¬ feiter. What happens to the man who raises a ten dollar bill to one hundred dollars? Or converts a twenty dollar gold piece into five spurious coins of a supposed value of twenty dollars each? Will the Government condone the offense ? Does the Federal Court extend clemency or mercy to a counterfeiter? Not even when the crime was committed to provide food for the criminal’s wife and children ! x I may be old fashioned and behind the times; or perhaps my training in logic was defective, but for the life of me 1 With what severity the Court punishes infractions of certain laws may be judged from the following news item : New York, July 20.— Theophilus A. Frey, 40, of Davenport, Iowa, was sentenced today by Judge McIntyre in General Sessions to from 14 months to five years in Sing Sing prison. Frey is said to have sold between $150,000 and $200,000 worth of worthless stock in a Wyoming oil company. The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 105 I can discern no material difference between issuing a check against a bank in which the issuer has no deposits and issuing ‘ ‘ securities ’ 7 against assets that do not exist. I can discern no moral difference between the counterfeiter who raises a ten dollar bill to one hundred dollars, or converts one twenty dollar gold piece into five twenty dollar pieces, and a corporation that issues one hundred dollars of secur¬ ities against twenty dollars of actual value. Through the instrumentality of overcapitalization bil¬ lions of dollars of ‘‘securities 77 (call them rather ‘‘inse¬ curities”) have been issued against inflated valuations— i.e., against a fictitious valuation many times greater than the actual value of the existing assets. We have heard a great deal within recent years about the printing presses of Russia, Germany, Austria and other European coun¬ tries turning out unlimited quantities of paper money. The principle upon which the bankrupt governments of Europe issue these vast quantities of paper money is in no wise different from the principle of inflation upon which cor¬ porations issue large quantities of so-called “securities” of a face value greatly in excess of the actual value of their assets. Actual Value and Inflated Valuation When we discuss a subject of this kind we encounter all kinds of objections. Thus I have discovered a disposition on the part of certain passionate defenders of, and apolo¬ gists- for, the Capitalistic System to challenge the conten¬ tion that it is wrong and wicked to overcapitalize an indus¬ try in excess of its actual value. ‘ ‘ What is value ? ’’ asked one of these valiant defenders. “Who can say what a piece of property is actually worth ? ” To philosophically define the word value and enter into a discussion of its absolute character and related characteristics, would require a sepa¬ rate volume; but for the benefit of those sensitive souls, disposed to be generous in defense of their beloved System, let us take a concrete example. The sundry properties that were consolidated into the 106 The New Capitalism United States Steel Corporation seem to have had a value (most liberally computed) of $562,000,000 on March 31, 1901; but on April 1,1901, or thereabouts, these same prop¬ erties were declared to have a value of $1,400,000,000. If there is to be any discussion about the exact meaning of the word value, or what constitutes value, it seems to me that I, rather than those opposed to me, have a right to ask questions. Who, for example, gave Mr. Morgan the right and the power to capitalize for $80,000,000, properties (The National Tube Co.) which one of his own agents declared were worth, everything included, only about $19,000,000? Who gave Mr. Morgan the right and the power to add to the “value” of the properties of the Carnegie Steel Company, estimated by Mr. Carnegie him¬ self as worth between seventy-five and one hundred million, a mythical value of three or four hundred million? When these elementary questions have been answered satisfactorily by those qualified and possessing authority in the premises, I shall be glad to discuss the subject more fully in due time. In the meantime, and for the sake of clarity, I wish to state here that for the purposes of this book, when I speak of value of property I have in mind the amount of capital actually invested in the properties concerned. And let it be understood that, in addition to the amount of capital actually invested, I am willing to make due allowances and liberal concessions—in brief I am willing to accept a fair and reasonable estimate of values of properties, but not an excessively inflated valuation, arbitrarily fixed by interested parties. When Is a Crime Not a Crime In December, 1921, Henry Ford proposed a plan for the financing of the Muscle Shoals plant. Mr. Ford proposed that instead of floating a bond issue which would inevitably fall into the hands of Wall Street brokers and bankers, the Government issue 1,500,000 new $20 bills ($30,000,000) which he said would be backed “by the imperishable and inexhaustible energy of the Tennessee river, ’ ’ which energy The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 107 Mr. Ford intended to harness to the Muscle Shoals plant. I shall say nothing either in criticism or in commendation of Mr. Ford’s proposal; it is of no consequence at this time whether I consider it meritorious or otherwise. What interests us is the savage attack made upon Mr. Ford and his plan, by a number of bankers and financial writers who protested against it for sundry reasons, chief among which was their contention that the water in a river has no stability. (In comment I desire merely to say that the water in the Tennessee, or any other river, for the matter of that, has greater “stability” than the water in the stocks of most of the Capitalistic corporations.) The aforesaid bankers and financial writers said that they considered the mere suggestion that the Government issue paper money “backed by nothing more stable than the unharnessed power in the Tennessee river” nothing short of a crime. Isn’t it rather strange that the bankers and financial writers who pretend to be horrified at Mr. Ford’s proposal, have in all these years discovered nothing criminal in the Capitalistic practice of issuing unlimited quantities of paper “securities” by corporations against arbitrarily cre¬ ated and excessively inflated property “values.” Nor have they found anything to condemn in flooding the market (at the rate of five or more billion a year) with “securities” based on nothing more substantial than a mythical “earn¬ ing power.” But Mr. Ford’s proposal, which involves the issuance of a measly thirty million real dollars (backed by the United States Government as well as by “ the imperish¬ able and inexhaustible energy of the Tennessee river ’ ’) they characterize as a “ crime. ’ ’ Who can understand the work¬ ings of the Capitalistic mind; who can follow its serpentine logic ? As Inflation Increases—Value Declines It is rather singular that the Capitalistic economists, so fecund in formulating economic ‘ ‘ laws ’ ’ that explain injus- 108 The New Capitalism tices against non-investors, and justify outrages upon the general public, have been so utterly lacking in vision and barren of ingenuity as not to have hit upon the obvious economic law with regard to overcapitalization. I hope they will not accuse me of impertinence for venturing to formulate a “law” that should have been put into words several decades ago. Here is the law, stated in general terms: The value of stocks declines in inverse ratio to the in¬ crease in the inflation of capitalization. The greater the amount of securities issued the less valu¬ able the securities are bound to become. If against the assets of a corporation, liberally valued at, say, one million —four million of securities are issued, then the actual value of the securities is twenty-five cents on the dollar. That is to say, there is only twenty-five cents of actual value in every dollar of the so-called “securities.” The bona fide investor who pays $100 for a $100 stock certificate is paying $75 for inflation—a value that does not exist—except on paper and in the minds of the officials of the corporation. In the event of liquidation of an excessively overcapitalized corporation, the stockholders could not, even under the most favorable circumstances, realize more than a small fraction of the amount they invested. The corporation officials know that there is no value there; indeed it has been repeatedly admitted in so many words. 2 Overcapitalization Defined But when we view this whole subject from the standpoint of the wage earner—the non-investor—a different vision is unfolded to our intelligence. No appeal is made to the imagination; no thrill of delight fills the soul. Blunt ques- 2 Within recent years an ingenious device has been invented. The inspiration for the substitution of “no par value” of stock issues, is probably to be found in a burning desire to circumvent the Income Tax law. But if so it is a case of killing two birds with one stone. Not only is the Income Tax law circumvented, but the constantly dimin¬ ishing value of stocks is concealed from all those who give no thought to anything except stock market quotations. Stocks issued without “par value” retain their fluctuating gambling value. Unwary investors, especially “widows and orphans,” are not expected to discover nor to pry into the mysteries of this rather ingenious device. The Capital Crime of Overcapitalization 109 tions as to the why and wherefore, and the significance of it all, demand a comprehensible answer. Reduced to com¬ mon sense terms: What is overcapitalization? Overcapitalization is the process of creating fictitious wealth by a scratch of the pen, and entering it on the books of a corporation as if it were actual capital, regarding it as if it were actual wealth, and rewarding it as if it were actual capital. Mark you! I differentiate between actual capital—capital behind which there are actual assets, and counterfeit capital, behind which there are no assets. It is this absence of actual assets that makes such capital fictitious wealth. By cwercapital I mean capital or wealth that does not exist, and since it does not exist it can have no earning power; and having no earning power, it cannot and should not be rewarded. Yet both are handsomely rewarded under the system of overcapitalization. Indeed it was to reward fictitious wealth and counterfeit capital that the clever scheme of overcapitalization was invented. What would you think if an employer of a thousand people with a weekly pay roll of say $25,000, were to dis¬ tribute another $25,000 a week among another thousand men and women who did no work whatever in his estab¬ lishment? Within how many weeks, do you think, that employer would be bankrupt, or would be restrained as irresponsible, probably at the instigation of some indignant stockholder? Yet that is precisely what the Capitalistic System is doing when it pays dividends on tens of billions of inflated capitalization and imbues with an “ earning power” wealth that does not exist. Capital that has never been invested and ‘‘wealth” that does not exist, is not entitled to any reward, any more than men and women who render no service are entitled to a reward. Where the Party of the Second Part Coynes In Let it be remembered that I haven’t one word to say against wealth that is real and capital that is actual—that is, wealth that represents actual property, and capital that 110 The New Capitalism is covered by actual assets; to both I am willing to accord a decent reward. But when I speak of ouercapital I mean wealth or capital that does not exist; and since it does not exist it can have no earning power; and having no earning power it cannot and should not be rewarded. But interest on this non-existing wealth; and dividends for this non¬ existing capital, are ruthlessly collected from the Party of the Second Part, from those who have no participation in the non-existing wealth and no share in the non-existing capital—that is to say, from the wage-earners—the non¬ investors—the public. The summarized effect of all this on the Party of the Second Part—the wage-earners, the non-investors, the pub¬ lic—can be expressed in a few words. It has given us the phenomenon called the High Cost of Living. -In other words the people are compelled to pay interest and divi¬ dends on billions of non-existing wealth and capital. As a result prices have been advanced to a point where wages are no longer sufficient to maintain a decent living standard. As long as corporations overcapitalize and corporations and individuals are permitted to collect tribute from the public on an inflated valuation of their properties—so long will there be unrest and turmoil, bound, eventually, to end in disaster. There is but one remedy. Overcapitalization and Inflation must be abolished or destroyed. CHAPTER XI The Railroads—An Object Lesson in Overcapitalization A S a “horrible example” of the evil of overcapitali¬ zation, and all that inflated valuation implies, I point to the railroads of the United States. Prom 1876 to 1913, 754 roads, involving 145,176 mileage, have been under receiverships. During the year 1913 alone, seventeen roads, operating 9,020 miles, and having a gross capitalization of $477,780,820, were placed in the hands of receivers. 1 From 1914 to 1919 inclusive, seventy-seven additional roads, with 35,053 mileage, and a stock and bond valuation of $1,793,687,304, were placed under receiver¬ ships. 2 According to the same authority, from 1876 to 1919 there were 1099 railroad foreclosures. Today nearly all the roads, according to the authority of railroad officials, are bankrupt, in the hands of receivers, or on the verge of bankruptcy. This is passing strange, for if ever a business has had advantages, and opportunities to make money, it is the railroads. There isn’t a thing on your body, nor in your home or office; hardly a thing you eat, or wear, or use, on which the railroads have not had a “rake off” and on many articles several “rake offs”; for nearly everything that enters into use or consumption—every article of com¬ merce—is transported at least once, and frequently two and three times in the raw, semi-finished or finished state via the railroads. 3 1 “Statistics of American Railways for 1913.” 2 “The Manual of Statistics—Stock Exchange Handbook, 1920.” 3 In 1913 Senator Gore of Oklahoma stated that the value of the farm products amounted to six billion dollars, and that the railroads received five hundred million dollars merely for hauling them. The railroads are today receiving more than a billion and a half for merely hauling coal. Take the item of freight for any commodity; it is a colossal sum in the aggregate. And* the public pays it all. And I am not saying one word about the “Pittsburgh Plus” plan, under which the public pays millions for freight that was never expended, on goods that were never hauled. Ill 112 The New Capitalism There is not a single business in the United States that has received greater encouragement or been given so much help, financial and otherwise, enjoyed subsidies, guarantees and privileges; land grants, the right of way and eminent domain—as the railroads. Prom the very beginning they were considered a great national asset, and legislation, both federal and state, favorable to their existence, development and growth, was freely enacted. And yet today, practically all, with a few conspicuous exceptions, are bankrupt, in the hands of receivers, or on the verge of bankruptcy. The properties are run down, equipment and roadbeds are admittedly in a sorry state, maintenance and upkeep have been neglected to a criminal degree. So terrible was the condition of the railroad sys¬ tems, so low was their efficiency, that when the Government took over the railroads upon our entrance into the war, it was imperative to immediately appropriate 750 million of dollars to put them into fairly decent condition. The peo¬ ple of the United States were forced to provide the 750 million dollars necessary to rehabilitate the railroad prop¬ erties owned by the Wall Street Capitalists. It is well known that many of the railroads have not been paying any dividends on their stock for years, besides de¬ faulting interest on their bonds, while increasing, rather than reducing, their funded debt. Why are the railroads in so critical a condition today? The dominant reason is that they have been outrageously overcapitalized, while those who own and control them—the Wall Street Capital¬ ists—have been reaping enormous incomes variously dis¬ guised as expenses, fixed charges, reserves, etc., on an inflated valuation. Inflated Valuation There are some financial writers who would have us believe that the railroads are not overcapitalized. Their claim is disproved by the known facts. One has but to delve into the history of some of the prominent roads to discover OVERCAPITALIZATION and INFLATION The Railroads—An Object Lesson 113 written in big letters all over the properties. Moreover, official investigations of some of the modern railroad scan¬ dals brought many ugly things that had to do with watered stock and stock jobbing, to light. Besides there are Court records that substantiate the fact. About ten years ago the capitalization of all the railroads was said to be fifteen billion dollars. With these attentive ears of mine I heard Senator Cummins, co-author of the Esch-Cummins Bill, publicly declare at that time that “one- half of this amount is ‘water’.” 4 Yet not long ago the Inter¬ state Commerce Commission, basing its estimate on that ingenious Capitalistic device ‘ ‘ replacement value, ’ ’ gave to the railroad properties a valuation of $18,900,000,000, and it is upon this valuation that the Esch-Cummins law in¬ structed the Board to adjust rates so as to yield a return of six percent. 5 There may be those who see nothing wrong in the Capital¬ istic inflation device called “replacement” valuation. I am sorry for them, and I’ll not argue with them. But I •’ll state my objection to the “replacement” device in the briefest possible form. “Replacement” valuation means that the public is being charged interest on an investment that was never made, interest on high wages that were not paid, interest on high priced materials that were not used, interest on stocks that have no assets behind them, interest on bonds issued against nothing. Oh, yes, I know that ‘ ‘ replacement valuation ” is in gen¬ eral use—but that doesn’t make it right. And its general use explains many things that enter into the High Cost of Living problem. For example: One of the reasons why rentals are high is because they are based on a “replace¬ ment valuation ’ ’; the tenants are charged high rents com¬ puted on high wages that were not paid, and high priced 4 This statement was made on the stage of Orchestra Hall, Chicago. I sat within twenty feet of the speaker. 5 Edgar E. Clark, Chairman, said that the Commission based its “valuation” first, on the cost of reproduction as of the date of valuation; then upon the cost of reproduction less depreciation, which represents the depreciated condition of the property as of that date; and then the actual cost to date. 114 The New Capitalism materials that were not put into the building, etc. Those afflicted with moral obliquity may defend, but they cannot justify, the practice. t An Old—But not the Sweetest Story Ever Told 1 ‘ Replacement valuation ’ ’ is only a new name for an old Capitalistic crime. Almost from the very beginning the railroads adopted bookkeeping methods which falsified cost of construction as well as their capitalization. D. C. Cloud in his “Monopolies and the People” (pub¬ lished in 1874) says: “Their balance sheets do not present the truth in any instance, and have not that purpose, being only an exhibit that will apparently justify the many extortions and decep¬ tions practiced by the corporations. The actual cost of constructing and stocking the road is not given; instead we have the cost as represented by the stocks and bonds issued and watered And he gives many examples and the per¬ tinent facts and figures. Senator La Follette in his speech before the Senate 6 de¬ clared that the Hepburn-Dolliver Bill “required an ac¬ counting from the railroads as to what they were doing, a uniform system of bookkeeping, so that the Interstate Com¬ merce Commission could find out wdiether they were doctoring their reports made with regard to these various charges, upon which rates charged the public were based.” Senator La Follette further stated that year after year since the passing of the Hepburn-Dolliver Bill, the Com¬ mission said to Congress: “We cannot tell whether these maintenance charges are honest or not. The system of bookkeeping is such that we are all at sea about it. We know nothing about it, and the railroads may be taking an undue advantage of us.” 6 February 21, 22, 1921. Published in the Congressional Record. March 14, 1921. The Railroads—An Object Lesson 115 Just One “News” Item “Washington, Dec. 2.—Use of intercorporate holdings in figuring rates was charged against the railroad corporations of the United States by Frank J. Warne, economist for the railroad brotherhoods, in testimony before the Senate Inter¬ state Commerce Committee. He added that as a conse¬ quence continuously lower returns are reported by the railroad companies. “Mr. Warne said that the capital accounts of the cor¬ porations showed investments of approximately $5,213,- 000,000 in stocks and bonds of other companies, or about 25 per cent of the entire outlay claimed as transportation investment. Such investments, he asserted, were not always governed by their anticipated revenue production, but were made for the purpose of controlling or influencing man¬ agements. “The intercorporate holdings, the witness said, had re¬ sulted in many forms of evil in financing, not the least of these, he added, being the deception practiced on the public in the corporation’s efforts to show poor returns on the investments as a whole. “Mr. Warne said other results included inflation of property investment, overcapitalization, involving the ex¬ cessive issues of securities; speculation with corporate funds, ‘reckless and profligate’ financing, secret and con¬ fusing bookkeeping, manipulation or juggling of accounts and falsification of records.” 7 Hut why waste more space to establish the fact of over- capitalization since it proves itself. The Virtue of Persistency For years prior to the war the railroad executives clam¬ ored for rate increases. For years they argued that the rates they were receiving did not yield them a big enough income on the ‘ ‘ amount invested ’ ’; and they offered a won¬ derful array of statistics to show that they were entitled to a much higher profit on their “investment.” In 1913, 7 Chicago Her aid-Examiner, Commercial Edition, December 3, 1921. 116 The New Capitalism Samuel Rea, as President of the Pennsylvania Railroad Company, in the course of giving his testimony before the Interstate Commerce Commission in the matter of increased freight rates said: “We know it is essential for us to maintain adequate dividends as well as an adequate margin over the dividends if we are to obtain from the investing public the capital needed to provide the additional facilities to take care of the usual growth of traffic; and we must have some leeway against business depressions, which occur periodically, and for other extraordinary emergencies that may arise.” All Good Things Come to Those Who Wait The war was a windfall for the railroads. It brought them all the blessings for which they had sighed for many years. For one thing, it brought them a goodly sum of money, taken directly from the public to rehabilitate their broken down properties; besides the Esch-Cummins Bill, to say nothing of sundry other good things. But alas! their joy was not unalloyed, for a part of the increased revenue flowing into the coffers of the roads, went to Labor, and that is a thing not even to be dreamed of in the Capitalistic philosophy. Eliminating Labor from the Equation Even before the Esch-Cummins Bill was passed the rail¬ roads opened aggressive war on Labor; for it is no part of the Capitalistic scheme that those who labor be permitted to enjoy a greater measure of prosperity than is sufficient to enable them just to subsist. The benefits accruing to salaried employees from the Adamson Law, and those be¬ stowed by the railroad administration and the Railway Wage Commission during the war had to be revoked or nullified. Toward the end of 1920 a nation-wide campaign began in earnest. Railroad executives, and railroad sta¬ tisticians unloosed a flood of oratory, press literature and an avalanche of statistics, all calculated to show, 1: That railroad employees were being overpaid; and 2: that unless The Railroads—An Object Lesson 117 all of the revenue provided by the Esch-Cummins law could be kept in the hands of the Wall Street crowd the rail¬ roads and the country would surely go to hell. On January 31, 1921, the Railroad Managers met in Chicago for the specific propaganda purpose of excluding Labor from participation in any share of the Government award under the Esch-Cummins law. At the opening ses¬ sion Mr. W. W. Atterbury, Chairman of the Labor Com¬ mittee of the Railroad Executives’ Association, and Vice President of the Pennsylvania lines, demanded immediate abrogation of the war time wage adjustment, and stated that only a wage cut totalling $500,000,000 a year can pre¬ vent a panic. The Railroad Managers were successful; the wage reductions they demanded were allowed. At the same time the railroads announced that there would be no re¬ duction in freight and passenger rates. Perish the thought! Railroad Wage Statistics The statistics with regard to wages, employed in the campaign, are particularly interesting. They came from a dozen different directions, but all from one source. There is a deadly similarity about them. It is clear that the rail¬ road statisticians all drink out of the same cup, and eat out of the same hand. One of the earliest and most conspicuous of the statisticians was Samuel O. Dunn, editor of Bailway Age.' In an address before the New York Railroad Club (January 21, 1921) he explained that the inability of the railroads to earn the return expected was chiefly due to “the enormous payroll.” “In 1914,” he said, “the railroads had 1,700,000 employees, and paid them $1,337,000,000. In 1917 they had about the same number of employees and paid them $1,740,000,000. Today, because of the establish¬ ment of the eight-hour day and the advance in wages which has been granted, they have about 1,950,000 employees who are being paid $3,600,000,000 a year.” 138 The New Capitalism Accepting Mr. Dunn’s figures we arrive at the conclusion that the average wage per railroad employee In 1914 was $ 787 a vear 8 In 1917 was 1024 a year In 1919 was 1846 a year Merely to sIioav that it is possible to arrive at different results from a computation of the same statistics I give the following from the report of the Railway Wage Commis¬ sion according to which: “Fifty-one percent of all employees during December, 1917, received $75 per month or less, 80 percent received $100 or less; that even among locomotive engineers the majority received less than $170 per month, and that be¬ tween the grades receiving from $150 to $250 per month there was less than 3 percent of all employees, aggregating less than 60,000 out of 2,000,000. “One hundred and eighty-one thousand, six hundred and ninety-three men received between $60 and $65 per month; 312,761 received from $65 to $75 per month; the average pay of the clerks being $56.77 per month; section- men received $50.31 per month; the average pay of un¬ skilled labor was $58.25 per month; station service employees averaged $58.57; freight brakemen and flagmen averaged $100.17; and passenger brakemen and flagmen averaged $91.10.” The report adds: “These, it is noted, are not prewar figures; they repre¬ sent conditions after a year of Avar, and two years of rising prices. And each dollar now represents in its pOAver to purchase a place in which to live, food to eat, and clothing to wear, but 71 cents as against the 100 cents of Jan¬ uary 1, 1918.” 8 Slason Thompson said in 1914 that the “average” holdings of the railroad stockholders was $15,000. At a six percent dividend rate the “average” railroad stockholder, giving not an hour of his time or service to the roads, would receive as his reward $900, which is $113 more than the “average” railroad employee received as wages for a year’s work in 1914. The Railroads— An Object Lesson 119 Cut—“From Nearest the Heart” But let me return to Mr. Dunn’s statements and sta¬ tistics. He insisted that operating expenses must be cut. But note you well! the cutting was to apply to only one operating item— labor; although it would be much easier to cut some of the other operating items, such as coal, materials and supplies, particularly since the same financial group that controls the railroads also controls coal, and practically all materials and supplies charged against rail¬ road operating expense—and are reaping enormous profits from the sale of their own commodities to themselves. Take, for example, the item of coal. The cost of locomotive fuel in 1900 was $90,593,965, or $475 per mile per annum; whereas in 1920 it was $672,891,964, or $2778 per mile per annum; an increase of $582,297,999, or an increase of $2303 per mile—for coal. Increase in wages does not ex¬ plain this enormous increase in the cost of fuel, which came from the mines belonging to the same group of men who also own the railroads. Prank Farrington, head of the Illinois miners, in an address (March 28, 1921) said that the railroads consume one-third of the soft coal output and do not pay a decent price for it, leaving the public to stand the difference. The railroads are given coal contracts at less than cost of pro¬ duction. 9 If the facts are as stated by Mr. Farrington, one wonders how the railroads explain the nearly $600,000,000 increase in their coal bill over former prices. Parenthetically, while on the subject of coal, it may be stated here that the average freight rate for coal, before the war, was about $1.50 a ton, while the present rate is about $3.00. That is to say, the public is paying to the railroads $825,000,000 more in freight cost than formerly. This is for bituminous coal only. I have not gone to the trouble of looking up the statistics for anthracite coal. In brief, the miners get about $1.12 a ton for mining coal, 9 See Chicago Tribune, March 29, 1922. 120 The New Capitalism while the railroads get $3.00 a ton for merely hauling it. There’s something wrong somewhere. 10 A Few Pointed Questions I have no desire to argue the several points involved in the various wage controversies going on at present. But I will say that when Messrs. Dunn, Atterbury, J. DeWitt Cuyler, Julius Kruttschnitt, Slason Thompson, et al ., try to interpret the chronic inability of the railroads to make a creditable showing by the present high cost of labor— wages—they are simply stultifying themselves. Why did not the railroads make a better showing in all the previous years when wages were considerably lower than they are at present? Was there ever a time when the railroads made money? If the railroads did not, in the past, and are not now mak¬ ing any money, if they are a losing venture, as many of the railroad executives would have us believe, how will you explain the dogged tenacity with which the Capitalistic Wall Street group clings to these “unprofitable” prop¬ erties? W. W. Atterbury, Chairman of the Labor Com¬ mittee of the Railroad Executives’ Association, and Vice President of the Pennsylvania lines, on January 31, 1921, publicly stated that the railroads were on the verge of bankruptcy, and to prove that he spoke the truth the Pennsylvania railroad lowered its dividend rate to the stockholders from six to four percent. 11 But on January 28, 1921, only three days before Mr. Atterbury’s gloomy address in which he emphasized the serious financial condition of the railroads, his road, the Pennsylvania, sold a $60,000,000 fifteen year 6y 2 percent bond issue within an hour’s time. The issue was heavily oversubscribed. I find it difficult to explain the avidity 10 President Lewis, of the mine workers, said, March, 1921, that the average income of the miners in the bituminous field in 1921 was only about $700. Yet in October, 1921, soft coal sold for $10.41. The cost of labor was $1.97. Who gets the difference? - 11 Mr. Atterbury subsequently repeated his statement to the Penn¬ sylvania employees by way of proving to them that they must accept lower wages. Receivership stared them in the face, he told them. The Railroads—An Object Lesson 121 with which Capitalistic “investors” subscribe for “secur¬ ities” of unstable properties in a business that, according to Mr. Atterbury and other railroad officials, is insolvent, and whose earnings are below normal. Incidentally, it may be added here that the new Pennsylvania bonds were promptly admitted to trading on the New York Stock Exchange. Only a few more questions while I am on this subject! Who were the first millionaires in the United States ? The Vanderbilts, Goulds, et al. And how did they build up their immense fortunes ? Out of profits made from railroad operation and stock transactions. Who are the multi¬ millionaires today? The Harrimans, Hills, Rockefellers, Morgans, et al., the railroad magnates—whose aggregate wealth—a goodly portion of which came from railroad profits and stock operations—runs into the billions. No! it isn’t difficult to understand why some of the rail¬ roads out of which a small group of insiders have made immense fortunes, are bankrupt, or on the verge of bank¬ ruptcy. 12 The reason is not far to seek. Read the history of the railroads in the United States. Sold out from one to three times a year for the past fifty years, on the Stock Exchange, each time at a tremendous profit to a small group of manipulators! Stockholders unhesitatingly frozen out, bond holders cheated, properties wrecked, property ac¬ counts juggled—to say nothing of the shameful transactions revealed by Court inquiries into such roads as the Rock Island, New Haven, and other roads. The “Widows and Orphans'' in the Lion's Ben We have been told that there are about 600,000 stock¬ holders in the first class roads, and that there are many “widows and orphans” among them, but we are not told 12 However near to “bankruptcy” some of the roads are may be judged'from the following item which appeared in the Chicago Journal of Commerce, March 1, 1920. “Washington, Feb. 28 (Special).—The Chicago, Burlington and Quincy Railroad Company was today granted permission to issue $60,000,000 capital stock as a stock dividend to be paid out of surplus earnings.” This is only one of many similar “news” items. 122 The New Capitalism that the report of the Interstate Commerce Commission of March 25, 1919, shows that the majority of the stock in each one of these roads, and their subsidiaries, is held by fewer than twenty of the big stockholders in each road. Nor has any statistician for the railroads ever pointed out that the largest part of the six percent return guaranteed by the Esch-Cummins law, amounting to over a billion dol¬ lars, will go to the big stockholders—a few thousand in number. The bona fide small stockholder, if he will be bene¬ fited at all by the distribution, will share in only a small part of it, for it can be clearly showrn that the small investor is always the goat. Scant consideration is extended him either by the railroads, or any of the corporations in whose securities he has, in good faith, invested. A few of the most recent occurrences will at least give color to my asser¬ tion with regard to the small stockholders in railroad, and other, securities. In the first place there has been a terrific fall in the market price of railroad stocks (and all corporation stocks). This means a terrific shrinkage in the value of the holdings- of small investors—a loss which means a great deal to them. For example: ‘ ‘ The preferred stock of the Chicago, Milwaukee and St. Paul Company was sold to the public by the Company years ago at par, $100 per share. Divi¬ dends have been suspended upon it, and the stock is chang¬ ing hands in the market under $40 per share.” 13 (A loss of $60 a share.) Before the war the Pennsylvania Railroad, considered one of the most substantial roads, was paying six percent. In 1921 the dividend rate was reduced to four percent. Needless to say the market price of the stock declined. Slason Thompson, director of the Bureau of Railway News and Statistics, is authority for the statement that for the past quarter of a century the dividend rate on all railroad stocks “has not averaged three percent.” 14 13 Monthly letter of The National City Bank (New York), Novem¬ ber, 1921. 14 “Statistics of American Railways, 1914.” The Railroads—An Object Lesson 123 Let the bona fide small investors take note of this: the dividend rate on their holdings has not averaged three per¬ cent. And when we take into consideration the losses they have sustained during the last quarter of a century through the fall of market values of their holdings, even the less than three percent dividend is wiped out of existence. The financial writer who recently said “Many railroads turn out to be poor investments” told a bitter truth. While on the subject of the small investor in railroad securities, the following, by B. C. Forbes, another financial writer, is of interest here: “When the late J. P. Morgan was indicted, along with Charles S. Mellen, in connection with certain New Haven- Grand Trunk Railway maneuvers, he took to bed absolutely inconsolable. When, several years later, William Rocke¬ feller was indicted, along with other New ITaven directors, he confided to me one day, in very grave tones, that it was not comfortable to be under indictment and to have the possibility of a prison sentence hanging over one. “These indictments are recalled to mind -by the suit brought by a protective committee of Denver & Rio Grande Railroad stockholders against men who were directors of the road. The stockholder’s committee petitions the Supreme Court to compel the directors to account for $200,000,000 alleged to have been lost through stock manipulation, con¬ spiracy, collusion and forced and fictitious sales of railroad property. “It is probably well to have this whole Denver & Rio Grande-Western Pacific matter cleared up to the satisfac¬ tion of all parties. While the standard and character of the men sued made it hard to believe for a moment that they would have laid themselves open to the charges made, nevertheless the losses sustaind by Denver & Rio Grande security holders have been so heavy that intense bitterness and suspicion have been created. “the first purchase of securities I ever made was ten shares of Denver & Rio Grande preferred stock. I paid about $800 for it. I sold it for about $100. Naturally, like 124 The New Capitalism other stockholders, I had a feeling that the Denver & Rio Grande got the thin end of the stick in its dealings with Western Pacific, which virtually gobbled up the whole property. “If the suggestion of taint attaches to the Denver & Rio Grande directors they ought to welcome the receipt of a clean bill of health from the Supreme Court. On the other hand—well, let the law take its course.” 15 The bona fide small investor who flatters himself that he is a beneficiary of the Capitalistic System would do well to wake up out of his dream. An Interlude If any one imagines that the railroads, even though they succeed in materially bringing down wages of all railroad employees, will be content with the resultant increase in revenue or profit, let him disabuse his mind of any such imaginings. Let him remember that since 1907 the Inter¬ state Commerce Commission has permitted an addition of seven billion dollars to the property investment account of the roads, although the mileage increased only by about 24,000 miles—about nine percent increase in mileage. But read on! Walker D. Hines, former director general of railroads, declared before the Senate Interstate Com¬ merce Commission that the American railroads must spend more than one billion dollars a year in property improve¬ ments for years to come. Mr. Hines expressed opposition to changes in the transportation act on the grounds that such alterations would destroy possibilities of betterment by the railroads. From Mr. Hines’ statement we can log¬ ically conclude two things: First, that the railroads have no intention to reduce freight and passenger rates even after their “liquidation of wages” is completed; and sec¬ ondly, that the “property account” of the railroads will be increased for years to come at the rate of a billion dollars a year. Increase of property account is, after all, simply 15 B. C. Forbes in the Chicago Herald-Examiner, March 28, 1921. The Railroads—An Object Lesson 125 a matter of bookkeeping, rather than of actual investment. But that is not all! S. Davies Warfield, President of the National Association of Owners of Railroad Securities (a rather big title) stated before the same committee that a less return than that provided by the Esch-Cummins law would not maintain transportation. ‘ ‘ The question for the moment is,” said Mr. Warfield, “can sufficient revenue be attained from rates and fares that will be considered rea¬ sonable by the public and the shippers, or will part of the money have to be supplied by taxation?” Prom these, and many other statements made by railroad executives and representatives it is clear what is going on in the Capitalistic mind. The Government—that is the public—has already been compelled to supply more than a billion dollars to bolster up the railroad properties, and if all the “claims” presented are allowed, probably an¬ other billion of the public's hard earned money will have been poured into the coffers of the roads. I have listened to eloquent denunciations of the Adamson law, which, it cannot be denied, was favorable to railroad employees, if you consider a law that grants a wage more nearly commensurate with living costs as a special favor. I have heard and read bitter attacks upon the Railway Wage Board and the Railroad Administration during the war. But not one word of criticism had the speakers and writers to make against those whose wrong doings and mis¬ deeds are written in many railroad hearings, investigations and Court records; not a syllable of reprobation against those who, through sundry methods of exploitation of Labor and the public (as well as the small investors) have augmented their fortunes; not a whisper of condemnation against those whose mismanagement is responsible for the wretched condition of the properties entrusted to their care, and to rehabilitate which a heavy burden of taxes has been placed upon our shoulders. I do not understand the temper of a public that will allow itself to be fleeced without so much as a peep of pro¬ test. And yet the past deeds and future designs of the 126 The New Capitalism railroads are “like glass; the very sun shines through them. ’ ’ But the Railroad Executives Are Right! When the railroad executives contend that they cannot pay decent wages and also pay themselves huge sums as dividends on stock and interest on bonds—they are right, absolutely and demonstrably right. It is impossible for any business, whatever its character, to pay dividends and inter¬ est on an excessively inflated valuation. It cannot be done longer than for a period of about twenty years; after which the system is bound to break down. It can be carried on for a longer period only on one condition, and that is that the money necessary to pay dividends on non-existing cap¬ ital be extorted from the general public bj r simply ruinous rates or prices. In this regard, however, the railroads are handicapped. They cannot continue to raise freight and passenger rates indefinitely. There is a limit beyond which it is impossible to go. If freight rates become too exor¬ bitant it reacts on the volume of freight traffic, and auto¬ matically reduces the volume of revenue. If passenger rates are raised to a point that the public considers exces¬ sive, it automatically checks travel, and this, in time, seri¬ ously affects the roads’ revenue. And so it is not difficult to understand the unwillingness of the railroads to pay decent wages to the employees, as it is only by cutting wages and keeping freight and passenger rates exorbitant that they can pay themselves dividends on their watered stock and interest on their bonds. The public must pay, the wage earner must pay, and the small investor must pay. The Conclusion AVliat is the real purpose of this chapter ? Simply this— to go on record as saying that what has happened to the overcapitalized railroads in the United States is going to happen to every overcapitalized industry or business of whatever kind. It is inevitable! Any corporation whose securities issues, based on inflated valuation, are greatly in The Railroads—An Object Lesson 127 excess of actual assets; any industry that rewards capital that doesn’t exist, is hound, ultimately, to end in disaster. Through the device of lower wages and higher prices the Capitalistic group may succeed for a while longer to delay the day of reckoning; but it cannot avert the disaster. And in every instance the wage earners—the non-investor group, the public, must pay the whole bill. CHAPTER XIT The Stock Market I AM aware that the stock market, or Stock Exchange, is considered by many as an essential institution. With¬ out a stock market, we have been told, industry would languish, investments could not be made, etc., and that taking it all in all the world could not very well get on without it—no progress could be made. Originally the Stock Exchange might be said to have had legitimate functions and served a legitimate purpose. “In their origin Stock Exchanges appear to have been free to the use of anyone who wished to buy and sell, and it was probably with this function in view that some of the older exchanges, notably the Paris Bourse, were located in build¬ ings erected at the public expense.” 1 But the stock exchange of today lias departed both from the original intent and purpose. Its conservative character of a public convenience has degenerated into a madly speculative game for the immediate and ultimate benefit of a select coterie of Financial potentates and Cap¬ italistic wizards. Membership in a modern Stock Exchange is “regarded very valuable, those in New York having been quoted as high as $97,000 in the most prosperous times.” 2 The first book I read, about thirty years ago, on the sub¬ ject of the Stock Exchange and stock transactions was entitled “Ten Years in Wall Street.” I can’t recall the author’s name. The stock transactions were then confined almost exclusively to rail and transportation stocks. The industrials had not yet developed into marketable securities. Books of more recent date, such as “The Stock Exchange i “The New International Encyclopedia,” Vol. XVIII,' p. 579. 2 “Monetary and Banking- Systems,” by Maurice L. Muhleman, L.E.M. 128 The Stock Market 128 from Within,” by W. C. Van Antwerp; ‘ ‘The Work of Wall Street,” by Sereno S. Pratt, and “The Stock Mar¬ ket,” by S. S. Hnebner, Ph.D., give a fair idea into what kind of an institution the stock market has developed, or degenerated. Were it my particular design to expatiate on the chi¬ canery of the stock market, and to expostulate on its utter depravity, nothing would better serve the purpose than to quote liberally from some of the books written in defense of and by way of apology for the stock market. But since moralizing is foreign to my present plan I will not concern myself with aught that has not a direct bearing on the sub¬ ject under discussion. Shearing the Lambs in the Shambles Why do I write of the stock market and its transactions at all ? For very definite reasons, which I shall state briefly. For one thing I want to emphasize that the stock market and all its transactions are for the enrichment of a small group. Authorities differ as to the number of investors. The latest estimate is by Professor Huebner, who claims that “exclusive of the numerous holders of Government bonds, there are probably 4,000,000 persons who are share¬ holders and bondholders in American corporations.” Accepting his estimate it is to be noted here that many of these 1 ‘ investors, ’ ’ and for whom financial writers evince such tender solicitude, are mere lambs, invariably coming out of the pit bleeding, gored by the bulls and clawed by the bears—while the inner circle of Capitalistic stock market gamblers and manipulators ultimately reap what¬ ever profits are derived from the buying and selling of stocks. G. C. Selden, in an article entitled “The Machinery of Wall Street: Why It Exists, How It Works, and What It Accomplishes, ’ ’ says: ‘ ‘ Small investors, even though they may be very numer¬ ous, do not usually have much influence on the immediate movements of prices. The main contest is between the big 130 The New Capitalism investors—who might as well be called speculators, except that they can always command money or credit enough to pay for their stock in full if necessary—and the other class of speculators, who will take a loss if the market goes against them far enough.” 3 Playing the Market on Margin Briefly the bona fide small investor is not a conspicuous figure in the stock market. He buys stocks, of course, and sells whenever the opportunity offers, at a profit. The important thing to remember is that the bona fide small investor pays the full market price for his stock. How¬ ever, all the purchases and sales, by and on behalf of small investors, in the aggregate are a bagatelle when compared with the marginal stock transactions. It has been said that 90 percent of all stock transactions are of a speculative character. That is to say, options on large blocks of stock are bought on margin. The speculator “puts up” let us say, a ten-point margin—that is to say, ten percent of the value of the stock. If he sells before the ten points are ex¬ hausted he makes a profit. If, on the other hand, the market falls below ten points, and he is unable to put up another margin to protect his option, he loses. It is by this practice that “fortunes” are made and lost. The Principle Set Forth Let us try to understand the principle underlying gambling in stocks on margin. John Smith (let us call him)—may his tribe decrease!—let us say has a thousand dollars which he puts up as a ten-point margin in the month of January of a given calendar year, for an option on a ten thousand dollar block of stock. If the stock rises ten points within the next few days, and he sells at the right time, he disposes of the ten thousand dollar block of stock, in which he never had more than a tenth part inter- 3 The Magazine of Wall Street, November 25, 1916. The Stock Market 131 est, at a clear profit of one thousand dollars—that is to say, he has doubled his one thousand dollars. If he repeats his transaction for twelve consecutive months—and let us, furthermore—in order to simplify the illustration of the principle involved—say that he never puts up more than a thousand dollars as margin, his reward at the end of twelve months will be as follows: Original “capital” $1000. Putting this up as a ten percent margin he will have “purchased” a ten percent equity in a $10,000 block of stock. Since we are assuming a monthly re-investment of the original $1000 he has pur¬ chased $120,000 worth of stock, although he never pos¬ sessed more than $1000 actual money, and made a total of $12,000 in the twelve months. 4 What entitles John Smith to such a profit? Is it his shrewdness, his sagacity, his thrift, his economy, or is it his industry that is being rewarded ? It is none of these. He simply had the ‘ ‘ courage ’ ’ to risk his $1000, make or lose ; he took a chance; he gambled. He is not entitled to any such reward. He has done absolutely nothing; he has con¬ tributed nothing to society, nothing to the welfare of the public. Why, then, should he be rewarded? Why indeed? He has not helped, nor given his service to the industry, or industries, in whose stocks he gambled. I need hardly waste any time in stating what is known to nearly everybody, that no mere uninitiated “investor” of the piker variety would ever be permitted so easily and so successfully to play the market. That is not the way the game is played. I merely want to illustrate the principle upon which the stock market is operated. Now let us assume a fall in the market, and consequently the ten-point margin would not be sufficient. Another ten percent margin will be necessary. To protect himself and his “investment” John Smith borrows from the bank or banker: that is to say, John Smith borrows your money and mine (our savings) with which to speculate in stocks. Bil- 4 And if he were to pyramid his “winning's” he would make hun¬ dreds of thousands out of his original $1000. 132 The New Capitalism lions are borrowed every year for speculative purposes on the Stock Exchange. These loans to speculators are known as “call loans/’ Thanks to the Capitalistic System of speculating on mar¬ gin, John Smith can make a fortune; though of course he also runs the risk of losing the money he has or has bor¬ rowed, and of going broke. The real winners, ultimately in the stock gambling game are the inner circle 5 composed of a few thousand men who manipulate the market and win whether it goes up or down. Business Is Not Directly Benefited This chapter is taking me further afield than I had in¬ tended to go. Certainly I had not intended to write at any length of stock transactions, operations, manipulations, etc. My purpose in writing this chapter was really to say that none of the stock transactions are for the benefit of business itself. Not any of the money won in the speculative stock market enters directly and ipso facto into the channels of productive industry. The transaction is between individ¬ uals—one buyer and one seller. Whatever money passes between them is from pocket to pocket; not from pocket to the corporation’s treasury. The Public, Is Not Benefited Furthermore, all the stock transactions are not of the slightest benefit to the eighty million non-investors. The eighty million derive not a solitary advantage from all the stock sales; just the reverse, for I think I can put it down as an axiom that not a dollar of profit is ever made by any¬ one in the stock market or elsewhere but the profit comes from somewhere; and that “somewhere” is generally the non-investor’s pocket-book. In the end the non-investor 5 I have been told by one who knows the game that the real inner circle is composed of only about 100 men—who constitute a syndicate. The Stock Market 133 group 6 must pay the total bill of all stock winnings. If the non-investor group does not pay, then tell me from what source the winnings in the stock market are derived. Why, some will say, * 1 A certain number win and a certain number lose: just as in a poker game, a certain amount of money is put into the game by a certain number of players. At the end of the game the same amount of money is there —only it has changed hands. 7 ’ Precisely! just as in a poker game! But sirs! there are no marginal transactions in a poker game; the players do not put up ten cents on the dollar; neither do they borrow from the players nor from the innocent bystander—not unless the rules have been changed recently. Nor do they expect the general public to make good their losses. Who Is Benefited? If the winnings of the lucky ones in the stock market are not derived from the general public; if, as some will probably assert, the winnings of a certain number are the losses of a certain number—then every point I have scored in this chapter stands admitted. And the condemnation of the stock market is eminently fitting. A few of the four million “investors,” beyond a doubt, are greatly benefited by stock speculation, but neither business, nor the general public, is directly benefited. IIoiv One Billion Can Grow Into Billions Now let us assume for the present that a given num¬ ber of professional gamblers go into the stock market with a certain amount of money—let us say one billion dollars— and that this amount is both lost and won in the course of twelve months. Consequently it is still in the game at the end of the year, with this difference, that it has been placed to the credit of the winners on the books of banks; and the 9 6 The bona fide small investor also helps to pay the bill. “Managers, when successful in operations on the Exchange, have pocketed the profits, but when unsuccessful, have thrown the loss on the stock¬ holders,” says Ernest Von Halle in “Trusts or Industrial Combinations in the United States.” 134 The New Capitalism losers have been eliminated from the game. So far so good! The following year this same amount of money will again be used by the winners; and let us say that they continue to win at the maximum rate. Here’s the principle: Within ten years there will have been credited to sundry persons winnings aggregating billions of dollars, although only one billion of money w T as actually entered in the game. Who can tell me how much actual cash is put into the stock gambling game in the course of a year ? Who can tell me how much credit (call loans) is employed therein? Who can tell me how much is lost and how much is “made”? Who can tell me what proportion of the winnings each year is taken out of the game and placed to the credit of indi¬ viduals in banks? If I had these and a few other relevant data I should like to have, I could, by simple arithmetic, prove the damnable character of the stock market; and the mystery of inflated fortunes, and inflated bank accounts would dissolve into thin air. The Big Game Played in a Big Way The stock transactions on the New York Stock Exchange for the year 1920, was 223,084,035 shares. Computing each share at par value 7 the stock transactions for the year 1920 involved $22,308,403,500. This covers only the stocks of those corporations listed on the New York Stock Exchange —about 1000. It does not include the transactions for the same group of stock on the exchanges of other cities, 8 or stocks traded on the New York Curb Market. It is esti¬ mated that the annual sales on the Curb average about 60,000,000 shares; while those of the exchanges outside of New York aggregated about 35,000,000 shares in 1920. There is no way of arriving at definite figures as regards the amount of money actually involved in all stock transac¬ tions in the course of twelve months in the United States. 7 The par value of most listed stocks is $100. Those whose par value is less than $100 are only a small percentage of the total. 8 Boston, Philadelphia, Chicago, Baltimore, Pittsburgh, Washington, Detroit, Cleveland, Cincinnati, New Orleans, Los Angeles, and San Francisco. The Stock Market 135 In the first place, the New York Stock Exchange—the biggest business institution in the United States—certainly doing the greatest volume of business—keeps no books, i.e., officially; nor does it publish official reports or statements. Moreover the fluctuation in market quotations, the rise and fall of prices of stocks, make it difficult even to ap¬ proximate. However from the unofficial data that we have it is safe to say that in normal times from twenty-five to thirty-five billions of dollars change hands on the various stock Exchanges every year. And this is only for stocks. The bond transactions are comparatively small in volume. In 1920, for example, the bond sales on the New York Stock Exchange amounted to $3,955,036,400; whereas in 1918 they amounted to only about two billion. The reason for this is that bonds are of a less speculative character—and that cash, rather than margins, enter into their purchase and sale. Capitalistic Anachronisms Out of the welter of chicanery apparent in the specu¬ lative stock game, two things stand out clear and strong: First: the speculative investor is not a stockowner in any sense of the word. They merely hold an option on stock for a few days, weeks or months. They are mere transients, not permanent members of a company. They have no per¬ sonal or vital interest in the business itself; its manage¬ ment, its conduct, or its affairs. Their chief concern is in the “earning power” as it is reflected in the market quo¬ tations. The average marginal speculative stockholder cannot be said to be an integral part of a corporation. Generally speaking I will say that a majority of the speculative stock¬ holders in a given corporation on January first of a cal¬ endar year, are not stockholders in said corporation at the end of the year, particularly if there is a decline in the market quotations. Here we have a condition that gives neither solidity nor responsibility to the existing corpora¬ tions. It means perpetual changing of /leadership; it is 136 The New Capitalism erroneous to speak of ownership when there is none. The group of “speculative investors,” or temporary stock- holders, rotates. The speculative investor flits from flower to flower, tarrying longest where there is the most honey— the most likely prospect of a sightly profit from the pur¬ chase, or sale, of stock. The average speculative investor, or stockholder shifts from corporation to corporation—I will not say that he transfers his loyalty, for he has no loyalty—sticking to one or the other as long as all’s well— and deserting it as soon as difficulties arise or adversity sets in. The average speculative marginal investor is a coward -—an adept at scuttling a ship. The second anachronism is that hundreds of corporations are sold over and over in the course of every twelve months. This is particularly true of the corporations whose stocks are listed on the New York Stock Exchange. Let me give you just one illustration. The United States Steel Corporation has outstanding $360,281,100 preferred stock, and $508,302,500 common stock—consequently a total of $868,583,600. During the year 1920 the sales of the United States Steel Corporation stock on the New York Stock Exchange alone, amounted to 13,585,300 shares of the com¬ mon stock and 224,200 preferred. Since the par value of the United States Steel Corporation stock is $100, the stock transactions involved $1,380,950,000, which is an amount considerably greater than its outstanding issue. The Case Clearly Stated The following excerpts from the speech of Hon. Albert B. Cummins, in the Senate, Monday, September 1, 1913, on a bill to reduce tariff duties and provide revenue for the Government and for other purposes, are worth reading, in that they are the utterances of a man considered an author¬ ity on the subject. Said Senator Cummins: “I take, as an illustration, the year 1912. The dealings upon the exchange were less that^year than the year before, and therefore it is entirely fair to take the year 1912. “In that year there were sold upon the exchange in The Stock Market 137 New York, bonds—and I am giving the bonds simply for the purpose of instituting a comparison—amounting in the aggregate to $653,497,000. I want Senators to remember the small, meager amount of bonds sold upon the New York Stock Exchange when I come to state the amount of stock sold in the same market during the same time. “In the year 1912 there were sold on the exchange in New York, 63,704,779 shares of railway stocks alone. The par value of the stock so sold was $5,052,823,900. Of in¬ dustrial and miscellaneous stocks there were sold upon the exchange, in the year, 72,413,946 shares of the par value of $6,150,899,600. Of all stocks there were sold 136,118,725 shares, with an aggregate par value of $11,203,723,500. “I pause here to point out the fact that the aggregate value of the railroad stocks sold or pretended to be sold during that year upon the exchange, amounted to about four-fifths, or certainly more than three-fourths of all the railroad stocks of the United States. All the railroad stocks are not listed upon the New York Exchange; but the aggregate stocks, common as ivell as preferred, of all the railway companies of this country, does not greatly exceed $7,500,000,000. I state it in round numbers. Of the stocks listed upon the New York Stock Exchange there were sold during that year $5,052,823,900. “It goes without saying that 90 percent of these sales were purely speculative. Certainly not more than 10 per¬ cent of the stocks of the railroad companies of this country actually changed hands during the year 1912, and yet three- fourths of those stocks were nominally sold upon the New York Exchange alone . “We might as well face the question whether we intend to enter upon a campaign against selling short in this country. I believe it is as serious a menace to industrial stability and financial strength as is now before the Amer¬ ican people. Some time we must take up in earnest the problem of suppressing these gigantic gambling transac¬ tions, and I think this is the time to do it. My amendment demands that we do it now. . . . 138 The New Capitalism “There are a great many people who believe that the short sale— that is, the sale of a commodity or a product or a stock by a man who does not own it, but who expects to go into the market when the time for delivery comes and either settle upon the market price as it then is or buy at the market price the thing he has sold, in order to make delivery—is a valuable element in the business of the United States. It has been so argued for a long, long time. I do not think so. It is said that short sales are necessary to create a market for things that people actually want to sell, and in order to insure a condition which will enable a man to sell anything, the moment he wants to sell it, at the market price. I do not think so. When one has a thing that somebody else wants to buy, there will always be an opportunity for the seller and the buyer to meet. . . . “But as it is now, it is not a place for the transfer of actual shares. It is a place where bold and experienced men balance their wits. It is a place in which men of great mental capacity and audacity as well, fight for supremacy, employing, not alone the means which ought to influence the price of stocks, but every means which may tend to affect the market. . . . With Regard to Railroads “In 1912 the Atchison, Topeka & Santa Fe Railroad Co. had listed on the New York Stock Exchange its common stock. It amounted to $168,430,500. At the end of the year, as we are assured by those who know something of the subject, practically the same persons owned the stock who owned it at the beginning of the year; and yet during the course of the year the stock of this company to the amount of $129,319,700 was sold and bought upon the New York Stock Exchange alone. . . . “The Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul Railroad Company’s . . . entire common stock amounted to $116,348,200; but during this year there were sold and bought on the New York Stock Exchange stock of this company to the amount of $149,277,200. At the end of the year practically The Stock Market 139 the same persons owned the stock that owned it at the beginning of the year; and the fluctuations in the market price, steady and permanent as it ought to be, ran from 117% to 99%. “How many fortunes were wrecked in that fluctuation it is impossible for me to say. There was no material differ¬ ence in the actual value of the stock during that year. It was just as certain to pay dividends at one time as at another. The future of the country remained the same. The business at its command continued without great change or variation. Yet during the course of the year, up and down, under the influence of these speculators who sought nothing else than their own advancement, and their own profit, this stock varied from 117% to 99%. “Again, the Erie Railroad Co. had outstanding that year $112,378,900 of stock, but there were sold on this exchange shares aggregating $245,033,100—almost two and a half times in the one year the aggregate value of all the stock of the company. “The Canadian Pacific, another company which is en¬ gaged in legitimate railroad business, whose earnings do not change very greatly, had listed upon this stock exchange stock of the aggregate value of $180,000,000. During the year there were traded in shares of the value of $159,- 693,800, and the market price of the stock ranged from 226, the low point, to 283, the high point, without any reason whatsoever for the fluctuation. “The Great Northern, another rather steady property when it escapes from the hands of those who desire to manipulate its fortunes for their private interest, had listed $209,981,875 of stock: and there passed back and forth, in this fictitious and unreal way which is known in no other business in the world except that which is done upon such an exchange, shares of the value of $119,236,700. “The Lehigh Valley is a road that has seemed to be the favorite of these speculators in New York, although it is a railroad doing a most legitimate business and supplying a service that must continue without essential change. Its 140 The New Capitalism stock amounted to $60,501,700, yet men pretended to buy and sell upon the exchange during this year, $175,625,000, and its market price ranged from 155% to 185%. “The Missouri Pacific had $83,251,085 of stock. Some¬ body bought and sold on the exchange $113,320,800 of it without any real change of ownership, and it fluctuated from 35, the low point, to 47%, the high point. “The Northern Pacific, with $248,000,000 of stock, saw its shares bought and sold to the extent of $151,551,800. “The Reading, another of these great composite rail¬ roads, well established, doing a business which must con¬ tinue so long as the people of this country do any business at all—and I beg, now, that Senators will especially remem¬ ber this—had a capital stock of $70,000,000. Yet these peo¬ ple in New York, for themselves or for these blind and inexperienced men who seek to find a fortune where for¬ tunes are not to be found, sold, and somebody bought. $1,114,468,250 of its stock. In other words, all its capital stock was bought and sold more than fifteen times during the course of the year. “The Southern Pacific had stock 1 to the amount of $272,672,405, and of its stock there was sold during the year $129,139,400. “Of the common stock of the Union Pacific there was outstanding $216,627,800. There was bought and sold dur¬ ing that year $1,062,600,000, and the range of market value was from 150% to 176%. “The speculators, of course, like stocks that are easily depressed and easily increased in price. And Here Are a Few Industrials “But I now turn to another kind of stock. I call them industrial or miscellaneous stocks. The first one that I mention is Amalgamated Copper; known to every man who has any interest in what takes place among the great specu¬ lators of the country. Its stock amounts to $153,887,930. It was traded in during 1912 to the extent of $812,869,500. I doubt exceedingly whether at the close of the year there The Stock Market 141 was any substantial difference in the ownership of the stock as compared with the beginning of the year. The lowest price was 60, the highest price 92%, a range of 32% per cent, or one-third of the par value of the shares them¬ selves. “The American Beet Sugar Co., of which we have heard a great deal in recent years, had a common capital stock to the value of $15,000,000. There were sold and bought on this exchange during the year shares of this company to the aggregate value of $108,612,400, more than seven times the entire amount that had been issued by the company. “The American Can Co., another company out of which great fortunes have come, had stock of the par value of $41,233,300, and yet there were sold on the exchange dur¬ ing the year shares amounting to $379,658,300, quite nine times the value of all the stock then outstanding. “The Stock of the American Smelting and Refining Co., another institution which has been utilized for winning great fortunes, was $65,000,000, and of that $15,000,000 had been withdrawn and deposited to secure certain bonds, and therefore really it had outstanding but $50,000,000. Yet the trading in this stock amounted during the year to $227,741,000. Its low point was 66%, its high point 91. “The General Electric Co. had $77,325,200 of stock. The trading amounted to $50,551,000. “The United States Steel Corporation, the greatest in¬ dustrial organization of the time, or of any other time iff this or any other country, had outstanding common stock of the par value of $508,302,500, and yet somebody sold and somebody bought during the course of the year, shares of this stock amounting to $2,462,622,400. The low point was 58%, the high point 80%. ” The Capitalistic Corollary Why, and for whose benefit, are these stocks bought and sold year after year? The non-investors, i. e ., the public, derives no benefit whatever. Are the industries benefited thereby, or only a certain number of individuals within the 142 The New Capitalism so-called “investor’’ group? The answer is obvious. Tre¬ mendous as are the profits derived by the chief owners of the big corporations, whether from operation of railroads or public utilities, etc., or from the manufacture and sale of industrial products, the profits they derive from their stock transactions and manipulations (to say nothing of interest, dividends, and commissions) are probably greater. There are many other things besides stocks in which the gambler speculates—scores of staple commodities, wheat, corn, rye, barley, oats, petroleum, cotton, butter, eggs, etc., and various kinds of produce. Besides real estate, the re¬ peated buying and selling of which (and a sightly profit on each “turn over” to the speculator) has given us inflated “values” and higher rents. The same principle that gov¬ erns the stock market controls the speculative market what¬ ever the commodities may be. The marginal speculator takes his profit (needless to say there are also sometimes losses) or inflated returns, out of the price fluctuations, while the consumer, i. e., the public, pays the bill. The Period to This Chapter What prostitution is to society, that is what the stock market is to legitimate business—with this difference—that houses of prostitution were once tolerated as the less of two evils—whereas the stock market, in spite of its flagrant immoralities, boasts of being an institution upon which the salvation of the nation depends. Society has never accepted prostitution as an honorable business; nor have those practising the profession ever sought to paint the halo of holiness around their transac¬ tions. But Capital has forced society to accept the stock market as if it were an honorable and sacred institution; besides placing at the disposal of those who ply their ne¬ farious trade within its purlieus, the nation’s financial resources—that is to say, the people’s money—the savings of the non-investors. CHAPTER XIII Our National Wealth P ROFESSOR WALKER in his “Political Economy” says: “Economists have found much difficulty in de¬ fining wealth; and not a few writers, especially of late, have chosen to abandon the word altogether.” Notwithstanding Professor Walker’s statement that not a few waiters have abandoned the word wealth, our eco¬ nomic literature has become cluttered with more or less erudite definitions of, and elaborate treatises on wealth, its nature, distribution, etc. These various definitions and treatises are often in conflict with each other, for the rea¬ son that the writers are not in agreement with regard to the fundamentals involved. The Best Definition of “Wealth” While it may be difficult for Capitalistic economists to arrive at a crystallized definition of wealth, the man in the street finds it less puzzling to determine what wealth is when applied to himself. He takes an invetory of all he owns and owes, and the difference between the two is his wealth. Therefore, wealth, in the popular mind, is some¬ thing measureable, something computable, something that can be reduced to figures. The average man may not be able to give a scientific definition of the word wealth, but most of us do not find it at all difficult to compute how much or how little of it we have. The very best definition of wealth I have ever heard—the simplest and, I will add, the most scientific definition, came froip the lips of an expert accountant. “Wealth,” he said, ‘ ‘ is the difference between assets and liabilities. ” It is this definition that will guide me in the writing of this chapter. 143 144 Tlie New Capitalism Statistics on the Wealth of the United States What is the wealth of the United States today? The Census Bureau has published no official estimate nor sta¬ tistics since 1912. Nevertheless, in 1917, after our entrance into tiie war, the then Secretary of the Treasury, William G. McAdoo, said our national wealth was 255 billions. 1 The latest estimate for 1920 is 288 billion. It goes without saying that both of these estimates are pure guess w T ork, and probably grossly exaggerated. But for the present we will accept them for what they are worth. With the esti¬ mates for 1917 and 1920, added to those for 1900, 1904 and 1912, published in the 1921 United States Census Re¬ port, we can at least get an approximate idea, if not of the actual wealth at least of the supposed growth of wealth in the United States : 1900.$88,517,306,775 1904.107,104,211,917 1912.187,739,071,090 1917.255,000,000,000 1920.288,464,000,000 2 Growth of the National Wealth Carlyle has said somewhere: “A judicious man looks at statistics not to get knowdedge, but to save himself from having ignorance foisted on him.” In this spirit let us examine the statistics with regard to the increase in our national wealth. During the century from 1800 up to the year 1900 the wealth of the United States grew to 88 billion dollars; or at an average rate of about 880 million dollars a year. From 1900 to 1920 our wealth, according to the statistics before us, grew from 88 billion dollars to 288 billion dollars —an increase of approximately 200 billion dollars within 1 In 1912 when our National Wealth was declared to be 187 billion, the assessment valuation was sixty-nine and a half billion. In 1917 the National Wealth was estimated by Mr. McAdoo at 255 billion; the assessment valuation was only 88 billion. 2 The Journal of Finance and Commerce in May, 1920, said the National Wealth was 500 billion, an absurdity on the face of it. Our National Wealth 145 twenty years, or at the rate of about 10 billion a year. How is it possible for the wealth of a nation to increase so suddenly, so rapidly, so tremendously ? There is but one answer. It isn’t possible, and it didn’t happen! No such growth in wealth could have been brought about by any known process of healthy development; no such tremendous yearly increase could have been produced by legitimate means. One Hundred Billion—Sheer Inflation What, then, is the explanation? The explanation is simple enough. You will please observe that the tremen¬ dous increase in our national wealth began approximately in 1900, i. e., the same year that overcapitalization began to assume gigantic proportions. Much of the increased vol¬ ume of the “wealth” which the nation is supposed to pos¬ sess, is sheer inflation. There are no commensurate assets. The tremendous increase is for the most part fanciful; the' colossal increment in wealth is fictitious. If I were asked to make a guess as to the probable amount of our national wealth I would say that it does not exceed 188 billion. But I consider even that amount too high, for I do not believe that our average yearly legitimate increase since 1900 was at the average rate of five billion a year. But judge for yourself. According to the United States Census (Statistical Ab¬ stract, 1921) the national wealth in 1880 was $43,642,- 000,000, and in 1890 it was $65,037,000,000—an average increase of $2,139,500,000 a year. By 1895 the national wealth had risen to $77,000,000,000, an average increase of $2,400,000,000 a year. By 1900 it had mounted to $88,- 517,000,000, which was at the rate of about $2,750,000,000 a year. From 1900 to 1904 the increase was at the rate of about $4,600,000,000; from 1904 to 1912 at the tremendous rate of about ten billion a year; and from 1912 to 1920 at the rate of about twelve and a half billion a year. To admit, therefore, a possible yearly increase of five billion dollars during the past twenty years—a total of 100 146 The New Capitalism “National Wealth” Statistics from the U. S. Census Statistical Abstract, 1921 National Wealth; Estimated under Specified Heads in 1900, 1904 and 1912 (Source: Reports of the Bureau of Census, Department of Commerce) Form of wealth Gold and silver coin and bullion . Manufacturing mach ’y tools, etc. Railroads and their equipments . Total Street Railways, Etc.: Street Railways . Telegraph Systems .. . Telephone (Systems . . Pullman & private cars Shipping and Canals. . Irrigation Enterprises. Privately owned waterworks . Privately owned central electric light and power stations. Total All Other: Clothing and personal Ornaments .. Furniture, carriages, etc. Total Grand total 1900 Dollars 46,324,839,234 6,212,788,930 3,306,473,278 ' 749,775,970 1904 Dollars 55,510,247,564 6,831,244,570 4,073,791,736 844,989,863 1912 Dollars 98,362,813,569 12,313,519,502 6,238,388,985 1,368,224,548 1,677,379,825 1,998,603,303 2,616,642,734 2,541,046,639 3,297,754,180 6,091,451,274 9,035,732,000 11,244,752,000 16,148,532,502 69,848,035,876 83,801,383,216 143,139,573,144 1,576,197,160 211,650,000 400,324,000 \ 98,836,600 537,849,478 2,219,966,000 227,400,000 585,840,000 123,000,000 846,489,804 4,596,563,292 223,252,516 1,081,433,227 123,362,701 1,491,117,193 360,865,270 290,000,000 267,752,468 275,000,000 402,618,653 562,851,105 2,098,613,122 3,495,228,359 4,840,546,909 10,265,207,321 1,455,069,323 s 6,087,151,108 '424,970,592 326,851,517 1,899,379,652 7,409,291,668 495,543,685 408,066,787 5,240,019,651 14,693,861,489 826,632,467 815,552,233 2,000,000,000 2,500,000,000 4,295,008,593 4,880,000,000 5,750,000,000 8,463,216,222 15,174,042,540 18,462,281,792. 34,334,290,655 88,517,306,775 107,104,211,917 187,739,071,090 * Including live stock on farms and ranges and in cities and towns. Our National Wealth 147 billion, is certainly liberal. Therefore I consider my esti¬ mate that our national wealth does not exceed 188 billion as extremely fair. In brief, I maintain that since 1900 over 100 billion dollars of fictitious “wealth” has been included in all statistics pertaining to our “National Wealth.” If I am correct in saying that the national wealth is 100 billion inflation, then the general public is paying about $6,000,000,000 a year interest on this inflated, non-exist¬ ing wealth. If I am correct in saying that the inflation in our national wealth is 100 billion, then the Capitalistic System has placed a debt of $5,000 upon every family, the annual interest on w r hich amounts to $300 per family. There will be those, of course, who will challenge my statement that 100 billion dollars of our statistical national wealth is sheer inflation. They will say that I am in error. Let them prove it! They cannot deny that there is con¬ siderable inflation. If they accuse me of exaggeration as regards the amount of inflation I wish to say that I shall gladly revise my estimates on condition that they will fur¬ nish me with complete and absolutely correct data showing contrary conditions. Until the proof of my error is forth¬ coming, my guess and estimate must stand. My guesses and my estimates are fully as valuable as the guesses and esti¬ mates of any other writer on economic subjects. However, for the purpose of this chapter I am willing to accept the official statistics for our “National Wealth,” just as they are, without making any deduction for infla¬ tion. But I will ask you to remember the expert account¬ ant’s definition of wealth, viz., “the difference between as¬ sets and liabilities.” The National Assets What do the statistics or estimates (see opposite page) of' our national wealth cover? Wealth or assets? I hold that they cover assets only. As proof I single out the item “Railroads.” In 1912 the wealth of the “railroads and their equipment” is given as $16,148,532,502. But where 148 The New Capitalism do we find mention of the liabilities of the railroads? The railroad properties are bonded (i. e., mortgaged) for over ten billion, which means that the railroad properties are hypothecated for approximately two-thirds of their esti¬ mated value. Thus I could take item for item and show that the sta¬ tistics for our national wealth are, to put it mildly, irrele¬ vant and misleading. I ask every business man who reads this chapter whether in all his life he has ever seen a trial balance in which only assets are given, and no mention whatever is made of liabilities. AVhat would he think of an accountant who made a glowing report of the wealth represented by his assets, without saying at least something of the debts that must be paid—the liabilities. The National Liabilities I have no intention of pursuing this phase of the subject to the bitter end. To do so in any worth-while fashion would require a considerable amount of space. But merely to indicate the possibilities let me ask: What are the Na¬ tional Liabilities? For surely you will not deny that there are liabilities. Look over the trial balance of any corpora¬ tion and you will see that there are liabilities scheduled which cut rather alarmingly into the assets. (While on this subject, and merely in passing, I have always won¬ dered why “Capital Stock”—AVhich is presumably the amount of capital a given number of persons constituting a corporation ‘ ‘ invested ’ ’ for the acquisition of their assets , such as land, buildings, machinery, equipment, etc.—should also be their liability. A contradiction is involved here. But let us return to our subject.) The national assets in 1920 amounted presumably to 288 billion. Remember that; then read the following: “Debts of the Government, of states, cities, counties, school districts, improvement districts, transportation cor¬ porations, all industrial corporations, private mortgages and bank loans, amount to more than $150,000,000,000, Our National Wealth 149 approximately $1,500 for every man, woman and child in the United States. Figures by Richardson.” 3 The Trial Balance “ Wealth is the difference between assets and liabilities,” said the expert accountant. Which being the case we ar¬ rive at the conclusion that the national wealth is only $138,000,000,000. Here are the figures : National Assets .$288,000,000,000 National Liabilities . 150,000,000,000 National Wealth.$138,000,000,000 The Public Pays the Interest and Principal It is of tremendous importance to keep the liabilities in mind, for, according to the Capitalistic logic the non¬ investors will have to pay the interest as well as liquidate the principal of the entire debt. The national liabilities are estimated as 150 billion. This means that the public is paying not less than six percent, or a total of 9 billion dollars a year interest on this debt. And if the practice of setting up a sinking fund to ultimately cancel the principal of the debt is general, then the public is paying consider¬ ably more than 9 billion a year. I do not know within what period of time this liability will be liquidated; some note and bond issues run to A. D. 1956, and some even be¬ yond that year. But let us assume that the liabilities will not be increased; and that the entire debt (liabilities) will be paid off promptly at the end of twenty years. 4 In that case the public will have paid as interest, 180 billion dol¬ lars; and by way of liquidating the principle of the debt 150 billion dollars; or a total of 330 billion dollars. 3 Frederick R. Burch in The Dearborn Independent , Jan. 28, 1922. 4 It is an absolute certainty that twenty years hence the National liability will be considerably greater than 150 billion. I have already shown that maturing - securities are not “retired” ; on the contrary, they are being perpetuated. We have seen that for every dollar of maturing securities, nine dollars of new securities are issued. Conse¬ quently when I “assume” the cancellation of the 150 billion national liabilities at the end of twenty years, I’m dealing in a pure hypothesis. 150 The New Capitalism Putting the case into the simplest form, the national liabilities, amounting at present to 150 billion dollars, means that a debt of $7,500 has been placed on every fam¬ ily, and the interest alone on which amounts to at least $450 per family. Getting to the Point But let me return to the point of my subject—the Na¬ tional Wealth. “Wealth is the difference between assets and liabilities.” If a piece of property valued at ten thou¬ sand dollars, and of which I am presumably the owner, is mortgaged for $8000, what is the amount of my wealth? Answer: $2000! Correct! But, you will say: Nevertheless there is $10,000 worth of property in existence. Quite true! but it isn’t mine; I have no title to it; it is encumbered—there are notes and mortgages amounting to $8000 against it, on which I am compelled to pay interest. My equity is $2000. Those to whom I owe $8000—those who hold the notes and mort¬ gages, have the other $8000. They—not I—own the wealth I am supposed to have. Now we are getting into the very heart of our subject, and I am going to make a statement of tremendous fact; a statement that is incontrovertible; a statement susceptible of proof; a statement based upon examination and analysis of an overwhelming amount of evidence; a statement of staggering portent to all the people of the United States— particularly to the wage-earners, the small salaried men and women—the non-investors—the public. The “National Wealth” is mortgaged to the limit, and the few hundred, or thousand, constituting the Capitalistic- Mammonistic group—four hundred or four thousand indi¬ viduals, families or estates—(make it forty thousand, or four hundred thousand) hold the mortgages. The major portion of the national assets—the valuable, profitable, pro¬ ductive properties, and natural resources, are virtually owmed by these few thousand. What they do not own out¬ right they dominatingly control. Not content with a rea- Our National Wealth 151 sonable profit from their wealth, they hit upon the plan of creating a tremendous liability against same, through the instrumentality of note and bond issues. I do not pretend to know what portion of the tremendous note and bond issues, aggregating tens and tens of billions, are in the hands of the ‘ ‘ investor public ’ ’; what portion is held by the few thousand constituting the Capitalistic-Mammonistic group. It would be interesting if this information could be obtained. And it would be still more illuminating if we had definite data as to the amount of the notes and bonds originally purchased, let us say, by the “investor public,’’ that found their way into the banks and are held by them as collateral. In the final summing up, I think, it would be found that the major portion of national assets and liabilities are concentrated in the hands of a few thousand —make it four hundred, or four thousand, or forty thou¬ sand, or four hundred thousand, if you like. (And I have not said one word as yet, nor will I particularly dwell on it now, of the immense profits made by a few from the flota¬ tion of securities issues of all kinds, their underwriting, commissions, etc.) The point I wish particularly to em¬ phasize here is that the public—the wage-earners, the non¬ investors, are paying interest both on the assets and the liabilities—into the hands of the Capitalistic group. Not only that but the public—the wage earners, the non-inves¬ tors, will ultimately have to pay the principal of the debt —i. e. liquidate the liabilities. But I have already made this clear to all those who are not purblind. A Word to tiie Dust Throwers I realize, perhaps better than most of my readers, since I have lived longer with my subject, the danger of gener¬ alizations. For this reason let me emphasize that I am not overlooking the fact that in the national liabilities are in¬ cluded items which, properly speaking, are not issued by the Capitalistic group—for example, federal, state, and municipal bonds. But it will not be denied that the non¬ investor portion of the public pays the greater part of the 152 The New Capitalism interest; and ultimately also the principal of these national (or public) debts. I’ll waste no time in insisting that the public pays practically all taxes. It is admitted that busi¬ ness does not pay the federal income tax; business merely advances the tax; ultimately it is collected from the public, the major portion of the amount involved being paid by that large contingent whose income is small—the wage earners and salaried men and women, the non-investors, and the bona fide small investors. Let There Be Light Note that I have added the bona fide small investors. I have done this purposely: First, because it is a fact; and secondly, because the Capitalistic group has impressed those who never think, that a very large number of small investors share in the emoluments of the Capitalistic Sys¬ tem. “If Big Business is in a conspiracy,” said Mr. Schwab, “quite a few people are involved in it.” IIow many bona fide small investors are there? I have estimated their number at a million and a half. (You may increase their number if you have access to statistics that justify an increase.) What are the average holdings of the average small investor? Who knows? I don’t! Let us make a guess. Let us say that the par value of the hold¬ ings of the average bona fide small, non-speculative investor in securities of corporations, is $1000. In that case their combined holdings would total $1,500,000,000—and their combined income, computed at six percent on their invest¬ ment would aggregate $90,000,000, which is certainly a trifling portion of the total Capitalistic income. But let us not be too conservative in our computations. Let us say that their average holdings are $5000. In that case their combined holdings would total $7,500,000,000, and their combined yearly income $450,000,000, which is still a small percentage of the aggregate amount involved. Further along in this work of mine I shall revert to the bona fide small investor in corporate securities, and show Our National Wealth 153 that he is not a beneficiary of the Capitalistic System; in¬ deed he is penalized to the same extent as the non-investor. Let the Authorities Speak for Us But whatever contentions those favorably disposed toward the present Capitalistic System may raise to mini¬ mize the evil inherent in the System; whatever tactics they may pursue to throw the student off the track; however they may labor to controvert my statements—there is one thing they cannot deny, and that is that the corporate wealth of the nation, whatever its amount may be, is con¬ centrated in the hands of a few hundred or thousand—four hundred, or four thousand, or forty thousand, or four hun¬ dred thousand, or four million—as you choose! About one hundred and forty-seven years ago Adam Smith wrote a book, which he called “The Wealth of Na¬ tions. ’ ’ But the wealth of a nation, is invariably owned by a comparatively small number of families or persons within a nation. That is true of all nations; it is particularly true of the United States. In 1890 the aggregate wealth of the United States was $65,000,000,000. According to an emi¬ nent economist and statistician of that time, Dr. Charles B. Spahr, this wealth was distributed among the then twelve and one-half million families as follows: Aggregate Average Families Wealth Wealth 125,000 $33,000,000,000 $264,000 1,375,000 23,000,000,000 16,000 5,500,000 8,000,000,000 1,500 5,500,000 800,000,000 150 12,500,000 $65,000,000,000 $5,200® That, approximately, was the distribution a generation ago. Today a third of a century later, there are 22 million families, less than 100 percent increase; and the aggre- 5 These figures beautifully illustrate the absurdity of the “average wealth per family” so generously apportioned by statisticians. In the above statistics by Dr. Spahr the average wealth of five and a half million families is $150 per family; and the average wealth of another five and a half million families is $1500 per family. But lo! to each of these 11 million families the statistics allot $5200 of wealth. 154 The New Capitalism gate wealth is said to be $288,000,000,000, an increase of 343 percent. Thirty-three years ago Dr. Charles B. Spahr computed that seven-eights of the families in the United States held but one-eighth of the national wealth, while one percent of the families held more than the remaining 99 percent. In 1918 Professor E. A. Ross declared that: “Two per¬ cent compose the rich and very rich, who own about one and one-half times as much as the other 98 percent to¬ gether. ’ ’ According to the latest statistics, compiled by Henry H. Klein, First Deputy Commissioner of Accounts of the City of New York, and published in his book “Dynastic Amer¬ ica’ ’ (1921), even less than one percent of the families own one-half of the country’s wealth. According to Mr. Klein, one family (John D. Rockefeller’s) owns approxi¬ mately one percent of the country’s wealth, or $2,400,- 000,000; over forty families have wealth in excess of $100,000,000; more than one hundred other families, in excess of 50 million dollars each; more than three hun¬ dred other families, in excess of 20 million dollars each. In addition to these Mr. Klein gives a list of sixty-five fami¬ lies whose wealth is between 10 and 20 million, and sixty- five whose wealth is between 5 and 10 million. “The list of those who died in the present generation leaving between one and five million is too long to print,” says the author of “Dynastic America.” “It contains several thousand names. ’ ’ 6 Mammonism—The National Menace Professor E. R. A. Seligman, head of the Department of Economics of Columbia University, recently defined Capitalism as “that form of industrial organization where the means of production and by that I mean primarily un¬ der modern technological conditions—the machine, and the 6 1 happen to know that Mr. Klein has taken great pains to gather the data for his statistics, and for this reason consider his com¬ pilations of great value in a study of our national wealth. Our National Wealth 155 funds required to work the machine, are in the control of private individuals. 777 That is a very good definition for Capitalism; but the point I raise is that the character of Capitalism has changed completely during the past twenty years and no longer de¬ serves to be called Capitalism, but by its new name, MAMMONISM. Therefore, adapting Professor Seligman’s definition to the altered conditions, we may say that Capi¬ talistic Mammonism is that form of industrial organization where the means of production—the machine—and the funds required to work the machine, are concentrated in the hands of a very small number—a few thousand indi¬ viduals, families or estates, and into whose coffers most of the profits flow. The Capitalistic Sport of Knocking Down Straw Men A number of the Capitalistic apologists, for reasons not difficult to understand, have recently put forth arguments and statistics calculated to show that a greater distribution of wealth, or a more equable division of the profits, would be of little benefit to the workers or the public in general. An article 7 8 by George E. Roberts (Vice President of the National City Bank of New York), entitled “If We Divided All the Money—How Much Do You Think You Would Get? 77 emphasizes that if all the wealth in this country were divided among the people, each would receive only a small sum—a negligible amount hardly worth while both¬ ering about. Mr. Roberts, referring to Professor Willford Isbell King’s book, “Wealth and Income of the People of the United States, 7 7 says: “Professor King found that if all the profits which now go to pay interest and dividends were to be divided among all the wage earners, the result gained to the wage earners could not be more than 25 percent of their present income 7 Debate between Professor E. R. A. Seligman and. Professor Scott Nearing, Lexington Theatre, New York City, January 23, 1921. 8 Originally published in the American Magazine and reprinted in pamphlet form, 1920. 156 The New Capitalism from wages. Of course, if the wage earner owned his home, or had any other investment, the loss on this might wipe out the gain in the salary or wages.” Mr. Roberts furthermore tells us that Professor David Friday, who also “has made a similar study of incomes . . . found that the average wage in the chief industries in 1918 was about $1320 a year. 9 . . . and that if all interest and dividend payments, that is, the amount realized from the use of capital employed in carrying on the same industries, the average wage would be increased only about $330 a year.” Mr. Roberts a little later approaches the subject from a slightly different angle, and shows, or attempts to show, that if the big salaries paid to officials and managers w r ere divided among the workers, it would be only a trifling sum for the workers. In the case of the Bell Telephone system such a division, we are told, would have raised the average pay of the workers only 17 cents a week, or $9.00 a year. Why this kind of figuring; what prompts it if not a burn¬ ing desire on the part of the conspicuous members of the Capitalistic group to throw dust into the eyes of the public —that dear public which they violently protest they love so much, and of which they are always so considerate? Who is clamoring for an equal division, either of wealth or of profits ? Certainly not I; nor any considerable part of the people. There may be in the United States a few hundred thousand extremists who are clamoring for an equal divi¬ sion of the country’s wealth, properties, and its earnings; but there are, in round numbers, fully one hundred million people who are not crying for the moon, and who are not asking that the national wealth and the national income be equally distributed or evenly divided among them. Pre¬ cisely what is to be gained by setting up a straw man and then valiantly knocking him down? 9 I do not know upon what statistics Professor Friday computed his average wage of $1320. My own computations would seem to indicate that Professor Friday’s average is exceedingly high. Our National Wealth 157 There’s Method in Their Madness Ill tell you what is gained by it. They want to hide from the public: First: that an abnormal part of the national income is retained by them; and secondly : that it was by the petty process of extorting a few pennies, a trifling sum, a seemingly negligible amount from the non¬ investors that the Capitalistic group has built up its gigantic System, accumulated its colossal capital and piled up its fabulous wealth. The Capitalistic System began with penny extortion; it has developed into a System of dollar extortion. You can easily compute it for jmirself. If the Capitalistic System can, under one pretext or another, in addition to a fair and legitimate profit, extort an average of ten cents a day from each of the 100,000,000 men, women and children in the United States (which is fifty cents a day per family) it is enriching itself by ten million dollars a day—or $3,650,000,000 a year. Penalizing the Non-Investor $750 a Year According to my computations the Capitalistic System is collecting considerably more than fifty cents a day, over and above a fair profit from the average non-investor (and also from the small investor) family. According to my figures it is collecting more than $2.00 a day from each non-investor family—$750 a year—through the medium of higher living costs. In view of the fact that the living costs of the average family have advanced from about $650 in 1900 to $1550 in 1920, I consider my estimate of $750 a year extremely conservative. I do not mean to say that all of this $750 is confiscated by the few thousand consti¬ tuting the Capitalistic nucleus; it is distributed among whatever number constitutes the Capitalistic System. Let us not forget that His Royal Highness—the Landlord— who has just recently come into his own, and who lias learned every Capitalistic trick—is getting a considerable slice of it. And a fair part of it goes for taxes—but the non-investor pays! 158 The New Capitalism What the Non-Investor Pays If you find it difficult to grasp that the non-investor family is mulcted of about $750 a year, remember what the non-investor pays: He pays the interest on the actual investment, as well as interest on the inflated valuation of all properties; interest on the stocks, and on the bonds issued against the inflated valuation; besides interest on every dollar of capital borrowed by corporations in the course of doing business. He pays, moreover, every dollar of rent, every dollar of insurance, and every dollar of taxes, for all of these items are overhead expense and are charged up to cost of production; and the non-investor pays them all. He also pays a certain amount set up as reserves, sur¬ plus, depreciation, sinking and sundry Capitalistic funds. And he pays his own wages, and the salaries of the corpor¬ ation officials and managers. Just a word of comment about the latter item. Blame Mr. Roberts, if it is a digres¬ sion. The Reverse Side of the Shield It may be true, as Mr. Roberts tells us, that if the salaries of the officials and managers of corporations were divided among the wage earners and small salaried em¬ ployees, that each worker would receive only a few dollars —say ten or twenty dollars a year more. So far as I know nobody has raised the question to date. But since Mr. Roberts, and others, have computed what such income of officials, managers, etc., if distributed among the employees would amount to, I insist that they also show the reverse side of the shield. Thus we have seen that 317,579 corpor¬ ation officials in 1918 paid themselves as “compensation” an amount aggregating $2,225,543,259. In other words, each of ,the sixteen million wage earner or non-investor families in 1918, contributed over $100 toward paying the salaries of the 317,579 corporation officials. If I felt disposed to push the inquiry further, and relentlessly pursue the argument so blithely begun by Mr. Our National Wealth 159 Roberts, I would ask him why should the wage earners pay the salaries of the corporation officials and managers, out of their wages. His answer, no doubt, would be interest¬ ing, and perhaps reveal the queer processes of the Capi¬ talistic mind. ‘‘Speak, thy servant hears!” In the meantime I should like to whisper a word of friendly counsel into the Capitalistic ear—namely that skating on thin ice is a dangerous sport; also that it is not wise to monkey with a buzz saw, or poke a stick into a hornet’s nest. Excessive Capitalistic Pro jits Let me repeat that I never have, and do not now, ask for an equal division of the profits (and certainly not of wealth). I hold, and shall at all times defend the prin¬ ciple, that capital—legitimate and actual capital—is entitled to a reasonable profit, and that the Ijona fide investor is entitled to a fair return on his investment. No! it is not a wider distribution of the present excessive profits that I would advocate—but a system of economics under which there would be a considerably smaller volume of profit than at present, going to the Capitalistic group— or Capitalistic “investors”—a system under which exces¬ sive profits would be impossible. Here you have the gist of my thought on this entire subject. Less Capitalistic Pro jit and Greater Wage Savings In plain English—the profits of the Capitalistic System are excessive, and the non-investor pays. Isn’t it rather strange that not one of these bright men who have com¬ puted how small a part of the excessive profits, if they were evenly distributed, would go to Labor, has ever pointed out thaf the profits are excessive, nor has one ever tried to score the point that if the profits of the Capitalistic System were less excessive—the average family (granting, of course, a reasonable wage or family income) could save at least a small portion each year out of its income. Nor has 160 The New Capitalism any statistical expert ever gone to the trouble of trying to express in figures precisely what less corporation profit, and more savings on the part of the wage earner families, would mean to the latter. Thus: If each of 16,000,000 wage earner families had been enabled to save only $100 a year (about 27 cents a day) during the past twenty years—each family would have saved $2000, or collectively the stupendous sum of $32,000,- 000,000. And if they could have saved $200 a year (about fifty- five cents a day) each family would have $4000, or collec¬ tively a wealth accumulation of $64,000,000,000. And so on! “Many a little makes a Mickle,” applies to the wage earner as well as to the Capitalist. Figuring Another Way Nor has any keen minded Capitalistic analyst ever pointed out that if the Capitalistic System can continue to extort from sixteen million families—say an average of $500 a year—it w r ill collect $8,000,000,000 a year or $160,000,000,000 during the next twenty years. No! Not a more equable distribution of the excessive profits among a large number but a decided diminution of the excessive profits that are now demanded by the com¬ paratively small number constituting the Capitalistic Sys¬ tem. That is all that those who work for a wage are demanding when they ask a fair recompense for their labor —not a division of wealth, but an opportunity to acquire some of it; not an undue proportion of the national income, but a chance to save a fraction of it, so that they might not be thrown on the rude mercies of the world—when sick¬ ness, age, or infirmity steals upon them. Is their demand unreasonable ? Concentration of Wealth . Political Economy is said to be “the science that treats of the nature, the production and the distribution of wealth As a matter of fact Political Economy, without Our National Wealth 161 pausing to deny that it is a ‘'science,” concerns itself not at all with the distribution of wealth, but rather with the concentration of wealth. “Distribution of wealth 7 ’ in economistic circles is clearly a figment of the mind. Surely when 80 per cent of a nation’s population, in spite of an admitted productive power, possess little or no wealth, and are deliberately prevented from sharing in the wealth they admittedly produce, there should not be such loud talk about its distribution. To speak of the wealth of a nation, or its distribution, when a majority of the families consti¬ tuting the nation possess no wealth—or just enough to keep them out of the poorhouse—is playing deuces wild with words. CHAPTER XIV The National Income I T is significant that there are no worth-while statistics pertaining to the “National Income”—that is to say, the aggregate income of all the people living within the nation. It would be comparatively easy to compile such sta¬ tistics if all concerned were honest enough to furnish the necessary data. The government is spending tens of millions of dollars annually for the gathering of data, and the com¬ puting, compiling and classifying of statistics on hundreds of subjects in most of which the general public has neither concern nor interest. So far as I know, no systematic effort has ever been made to definitely ascertain the actual income of all the people of the nation, derived from all possible income sources. There are in existence unrelated sets of earnings or income statistics for a few groups, gath¬ ered and compiled by government bureaus, but they are fragmentary, and, on account of their incompleteness, worthless for any practical purpose. Most of them are estimates or generalizations based upon data obtained from, or for, a limited number of persons within a given group; and one doubts the accuracy of the data. Under the cir¬ cumstances their scientific value is nil. Even the “Statistics of Income” compiled from the income tax returns, under the direction of the Commis¬ sioner of Internal Revenue for 1917, when all persons with a net income of $2000 a year, and since 1918, when all persons with a net income of $1000 a year, were obliged to file an income tax return, are of no particular value, for the published statistics give no hint of the actual total income of even those who reported, and none for those whose net income fell below $1000. 162 The National Income 163 George E. Roberts, Vice-President of the National City Bank of New York, in an address delivered npon the occa¬ sion of his retirement from the Presidency of the American Statistical Association, 1 bewailed the fact that there was no reliable information with regard to the national income; no comprehensive statement showing “how it was disposed of, who absorbed and enjoyed it,” etc.; and declared that such a statement 1 ‘ would take the place of anonymous esti¬ mates in circulation.” It is, perhaps, nugatory to ask why has the American Statistical Association, in the more than eighty years of its existence, never made an effort to obtain the data necessary for a set of worth-while statistics pertaining to the incomes of all the people derived from all sources. Either the American Statistical Association is lacking in ingenuity and does not know how to go about accomplishing so simple a task, or else it believes in the saying “where ignorance is bliss ’twere folly to be wise.” In the absence, then of any definite information on so vital a subject as the incomes of the people of the United States, and the sources from which their incomes are derived, we must turn to the studies of men who, consider¬ ing the limited data and fragmentary material at their disposal, have made computations which, while neither scientific nor conclusive are at least interesting and indica¬ tive. The Income “Authorities” I have before me as I am writing this chapter, Professor Willford Isbell King’s “The Wealth and Income of the United States.” Professor King is recognized among the statisticians and students of sociology and of the econom¬ ists in this country “as a very eminent man in his particu¬ lar field.” (His studies do not extend beyond the year 1910.) Also a recently published book entitled, “The Income in the United States—Its Amount and Distribution l “The Equilibrium in Industry,” an address delivered Dec. 29, 1920. 164 The New Capitalism from 1909-1919 —and which purports to be a summary of an exhaustive statistical analysis of the income of the United States for each year, 1910-1919, prepared by the staff of the National Bureau of Economic Research: Wes¬ ley C. Mitchell, Willford I. King, Frederick R. Macaulay and Oswald W. Knauth. Also the Statistics of Income, compiled from the returns for 1918, under the direction of the Commissioner of Internal Revenue. Besides a half dozen books of a less pretentious character, dealing in a fragmentary and desultory way with Incomes, Profits, Wages, etc. I had originally intended to go into an extended analysis of all available income statistics and statements pertaining thereto, but discovered that this would lead me too far afield. For the sake of brevity I have concluded to con¬ fine myself in this chapter to a few independent comments, observations and conclusions, on some of the principal points involved in the subject—the National Income. What Is Income ? I suppose, to do myself justice, I ought to go into lengthy definitions of Income, Profit, etc., and sundry other terms conspicuous in the Capitalistic glossary and current in Accountancy parlance. But I will not enter into that at present. Nevertheless when the Secretary of the United States Treasury Department maintains, and the Supreme Court of the United States, decides that stock dividends are not income, it is easy for a mere student to run a-foul of Capitalistic finicalness. Briefly let me say that every profit is an income, but not every income is a profit. For example, wages are income, but not profit. But when income is convertible into property, capital or wealth, then it becomes profit, no matter with what mystic terms the fact is disguised or obscured. But you may dismiss what I say on this subject, and be guided entirely by what the economic authorities have to say. Professor King says: “A workman’s wages, interest on loans, the rent of land, and the profits of business men, The National Income 165 are all classified as income. A man is said to receive income through gifts or inheritance, through a rise in the value of property in his possession, through winnings from lotteries or gambling, or from the sale of products which he himself manufactures or produces from the soil.” We may accept this definition as coming within the limits of permissibility, though in an argument I should protest against considering “a rise in the value of prop¬ erty” as income. 2 However, it is not to argue but rather to clear the subject of inherent obscurities that I am writing this chapter. To me an income, statistically figured, must be an actual money income, or convertible into money or property, capital or wealth. The line must be drawn some- Avhere, for if things other than actual revenue derived from one of the admitted and legitimate sources are computed as income, money statistics are meaningless, and the whole subject is reduced to an absurdity. “Reductio ad Abswrdum” This tendency to include under 11 Income ’ ’ sundry things to which it is utterly impossible to give a money value, is rampant among statisticians and economists, and Professor King admits it. ‘‘In recent years,” he says, “most econo¬ mists have added to the income list those pleasures which a person receives from the use of free goods. A man enjoys a beautiful sunset. Does he not receive income as truly as the man who enjoys the Oriental rug in his home ? One is free and the other costs money, but both alike appeal to the man’s sense of beauty.” Absurdity can go no further! The pity is that the idio¬ syncrasies of statisticians, and vagaries of economists are becoming painfully apparent in their so-called “Income studies.” For example, on page 59 of “The Income in the ^ I think I have shown at sufficient length how “the value of property” has been artificially and arbitrarily inflated—to the tune of billions of dollars. I am willing to consider the dividends or inter¬ est derived from the inflated valuation as “income” but not the rise In the inflation itself. If anyone insists on including the fictitious Inflation in value in the statistics, it behooves me to say that the proper place is in the Wealth statistics—not the Income section. 166 The New Capitalism United States”—(one of the books before me)—it is seri¬ ously proposed to include in the “national income” the hypothetical wages of eighteen to twenty million “Amer¬ ican women, sixteen years of age and over, engaged in their own homes without monetary remuneration.” Thus, for 1919 we find $900 allotted per housewife; and the “money value” of their aggregate services is computed at $18,450,- 000,000. However great a value one may place on the services of housewives, (and the value of their services is inestimable) what has value to do with actual income? The truth is that housewives throughout the world are not receiving any money compensation; and statisticians have no right whatever to credit them with a money revenue that they do not receive. The outstanding, glaring fact is that the eighteen or twenty million American housewives are not receiving $18,450,000,000 in the course of twelve months for the work they do in their homes. Why, then, pretend that they are? Sunsets, and evening stars, fresh air, clear skies, and cool summer breezes, however delightful and enjoyable, are not Money Income. That’s flat! The mythical wages of house¬ wives buy no hats, nor shoes, nor bread. Let’s have done with this kind of economic tom-foolery! The Non-Investor’s Income Is Gross and Disappears Before entering upon an analysis of the national income I want to fix another point clearly in the mind of the reader. I am not aware that a single economist has ever commented on the fact that in all the statistics for incomes there is a queer mixture of gross and net income. With regard to the non-investors their income is in all cases gross. This is predicable of all wage earners, which includes the small salaried men and women, small business men, most professional men, in brief all those receiving the equivalent of an average wage. I beg the readers to bear this in mind. The income of the wage earners is gross. There are no The National Income 167 reserves, no surplus, no undivided profits, no depreciation and replacement fund, no dividend-earning assets, no in¬ terest bearing securities, no principal, no wealth, no capital, nothing except their wage income, which in most cases is spent before it is received. Out of this gross income (their wages) the non-investors must pay the living expenses of themselves and those de¬ pendent upon them, which leaves them penniless at the end of the year. While the wage earners are accredited by the statisticians with having received a formidable amount of wages (income) in the course of twelve months—the sta¬ tistics are silent concerning the fact that generally speaking the wage earner’s income has entirely disappeared by the end of the year. The Investor’s Income is Net, and Accumulates Whereas the income of investors, of those whose revenue is derived from other sources than wages—from invest¬ ments or speculation—dividends, interest or rent, is net income— i. e. profit. If it is argued that these, too, must pay their living expenses out of their income, I’ll agree. But there is this to say—that after a reasonable deduction for living expenses a vast amount of the income remains and is converted into additional profitable investments, from the accumulation of which the investors will derive a constantly increasing revenue in the succeeding years. How great the aggregate amount of net income is can be judged from the capital accumulations during the past twenty years, which show an increase in the national wealth of about ten billion a year. Nor must we forget that in addition to interest, dividends, rent and sundry profits, many of the investors receive a salary or compensation, which, in most cases, is far in excess of living expenses. Thus, for example, the United States Income Statistics for 1918 show that in that year 317,579 corporations reported $2,225,543,259 as “compen¬ sation of officials.” 168 The New Capitalism National Income Estimates According to Professor King (Table XXX, p. 158) the total national income for the year 1910 was $30,529,500,000. According to Otto H. Kahn, the total national income for the year 1918 was $55,000,000,000. Estimates made by statistical experts place the national income in 1918 between fifty-five and sixty billion. It is immaterial whether we fix upon fifty-five or sixty billion as the approximately correct estimates for 1918. The following statistics from ‘ ‘ The Income in the United States” (Table 2) make an attempt at giving the amount of income and the sources from which derived, and are, therefore, of especial interest here. Percent of 1918 Total Income Agriculture . $12,682,000,000 21.01 Mineral production . 2,013,000,000 3.33 Manufacturing A. Factories . 16,018,000,000 1,280,000,000 26.53 B. Construction . 2.12 C. Other trades . 1,704,000,000 2.82 Transportation A. Railway, Pullman, Express, Switching, and Terminal Companies . 3,684,000,000 6.10 B. Street Railway, Electric Light and Power, Telegraph and Telephone Companies . 1,042,000,000 1.73 C. Transportation by water. . . . 506,000,000 .84 Banking . 767,000,000 1.27 Government . 5,352,000,000 8.87 Unclassified industries and miscel- laneous income . 15,318,000,000 25.38 $60,366,000,000 100.00 By Way of Comment I cannot forbear to make a few comments on Ihe above statistics. For example—take the item Agriculture. According to the United States Statistical Abstract (1920) the value of the farm wealth produced in 1918, is given as The National Income 169 $22,480,000,000. In the above statistics (Table 2), the in¬ come derived from Agriculture is given as $12,682,000,000, which raises the questions: How is the “income” com¬ puted ? Is the income gross or net ? Has an allowance been made for rent and food? For interest on investment, and salaries of owners or managers? Does the figure given cover the income of all those engaged in agriculture, or only of the farm owners, tenants, share farmers, etc. ? Are wages paid to farm laborers, included in the figure given? Is the unsold portion of the farmers’ products included in “income”? Are the theoretical wages of the farmers’ wives for household work or farm labor taken into con¬ sideration, etc.? When sunsets and waterfalls, and rain and sunshine can be considered as “income,” it behooves one to inquire carefully just what has been included in income, and what deductions and allowances have been made, etc. Or take the item Government. I, for one, question the right to include Government in any Income schedule. Under no circumstances can the income of the Government be considered as part of the national income; it is clearly a national expense. None will dispute that the expenses of the Government are paid out of the income of the people, principally out of the wages of non-investors through the medium of direct and indirect taxes. But if it is contended that it is legitimate to consider the expense of Government as a national income item, then I shall insist that the full amount of government expense be included, state, city, county, etc., as well as federal. I could note a few other incongruities in Table 2, but that is irrelevant at this time. However, just to satisfy my curiosity, I should like to know whether no income is derived from stock transactions—the repeated buying and selling of securities, stocks, bonds, notes, mortgages, etc., by a comparatively small group of “investors.” Surely it is a considerable item. Also the Board of Trade transactions in cereals, produce, etc., involving billions in the course of 170 The New Capitalism a year. Also where is the income derived from the buying and selling of real estate, land, buildings, etc. Also what percentage of the national income is derived from the Insurance business? Etc., etc. Is it possible that all these things are lumped under “Unclassified Industries and Miscellaneous Income”? If so I should like to see them classified, and itemized. Merged Statistics But these things are really beside the question at this time. What concerns us most just now is that the statistics in Table 2 give no hint nor clew as to the wage earners’ share in the national income. And that is what I want to know most. If the national income in 1918 was sixty bil¬ lion, or as the conservative Mr. Kahn claims, fifty-five billion, what proportion of the income went to the wage earners, the small salaried men and women—in brief the non-investors ? No “study” that I have ever seen answers this question. In the book, “The Income of the United States,” Table 21 (p. 107), gives a “rough estimate” of the income from all sources of salary and wage workers. I should say the estimate is rough, exceedingly rough—wages and salaries lumped as usual, and the meager salary of the clerk merged into the munificent reward of the employers. The ‘ * rough estimate ’ ’ raises a point worthy of some note in a chapter dealing with the national income. For some mysterious reason “Wages and salaries” are lumped in practically all income statistics; also in corporations’ re¬ ports. Moreover, under “salaries” is included the salary paid to the clerk employee and to the high officials. I find it difficult to make myself believe that this lumping of wages and salaries is not a deliberate effort to conceal how small a part of the national income goes to those who work for a wage or small salary—the non-investors.' But what¬ ever the concealed motive or hidden purpose, the fact is glaring—the statistics speak for themselves; wages and sal¬ aries are merged; and “salaries” includes the salaries of The National Income 171 clerks and officials. Table 21 is utterly worthless for the purpose of determining what portion of the national income goes to the wage earners. Untangling a Skein of Statistics But let us make an attempt at approximation by com¬ puting some of the pertinent statistics given in Table 22 for the year 1918. From the statistics for Farmers we discover that the aggregate income of 4,433,000 farmers, having an income of less than $2000 a year, was $4,600,000,000, (or $1038 per farmer). The aggregate income of 2,008,000 farmers having an income of more than $2000 a year was $6,300,- 000,000, (or $3137 per farmer). Consequently the farm¬ ers’ share of the income was $10,900,000,000, (or an average of $1676 per farmer). From the statistics “all income receivers except farm¬ ers,” (Table 22), we learn that the aggregate income of 30,450,000 persons having an income of less than $2000 a year was $32,100,000,000, (or $1054 per person). The aggregate income of 3,400,000 persons having an income of more than $2000 a year, was $17,400,000,000, or $5118 per person. Here, then, we have three groups: 1. Farmers; 2. Those whose income was less than $2000; and, 3. Those whose income was more than $2000. Counting those whose income fell below $2000 generally as wage earners, and those whose income exceeded $2000 as constituting the investor group, we get the following result: Average Total number Aggregate income per person Farmers ... 6,441,000 $10,900,000,000 $1676 Wage earners. 30,450,000 32,100,000,000 1054 Investors. 3,400,000 17,400,000,000 5118* 40,291,0003 $60,400,000,000 3 It is only fair to say that the economists who compiled these statistics included among - those employed 2,500,000 soldiers, sailors and marines, to each of whom they generously allotted an average income of $700, or a total of $1,750,000,000. 4 It is interesting to note here that in 1918, according to Table 27 in the same work (p. 136) only 842,458 persons in the United States had an income of more than $5000 a year. Who can reconcile these statistical contradictions? I confess my inability. 172 The New Capitalism The Average Income Per Family So far, so good! But when we try to reduce the income of the forty million persons to a family basis, we discover that there is something fundamentally wrong somewhere. In 1918 the population was 105,000,000, (21 million fam¬ ilies). If we consider each farmer and each investor as the head of a family of five, these two groups account for about fifty million persons, or approximately ten million families. This would leave fifty-five million persons, or eleven million families, as constituting the wage-earner group. Of these fifty-five million, it would appear, 30,450,000 were, in 1918, engaged in gainful occupations (or about 2.77 persons per family) which w r ould yield an income of $2918 per wage- earner family; w 5 * 7 hich is preposterous. To the credit of economists be it said that none has ever statistically allocated so handsome an “average income” to the wage-earner families—not even figuring into the income account, sunsets and housewives’ imaginary wages, and lumping “wages and salaries” as is their custom. It must be admitted that they have been fairly conservative, as may be judged from the following statistics appearing in Professor King’s tables (p. 128 and p. 169). Family Income Average Money Wage in Dollars per employee, per annum 1850. 535 $204 1860. 613 265 1870. 889 397 1880. 735 323 1890. 941 398 1900. 1109 417 1910. 14945 507 All through the war the average income per family was estimated between $1500 and $1850. Let us adopt the latter figure for the present. In the course of the past 5 From Professor King's Table XLIV (p. 228) we learn that in 1910 over half (’51.54 percent) of the families in the United States had an income of less than $800 a year; 11.89 percent had an income between $800 and $1000 a year; and 12.26 percent had an income between $1000 and $1200. In other words, in 1910, over eighty percent (81.69 percent) of the families in the United States had an income of $1200 or less. The National Income 173 few years I have read a number of articles speaking dis¬ paragingly of the statistical average family, and their sta¬ tistical average income. An anonymous writer in The Saturday Evening Post not long ago, was particularly sar¬ castic in his remarks. I share the anonymous author’s objection to the statistical average family income, but for a different, reason. My objection is that the average is ob¬ tained by dividing the total wages, salaries and compensa¬ tion of all those listed as “ engaged in the gainful occupa¬ tions” equally among all the families. Consequently a large number of families, whose actual income falls con¬ siderably below $1850 a year, are made statistical sharers in wages and salaries they do not receive; whereas thou¬ sands whose income exceeds from ten to a hundred times, and a thousand times $1850, statistically are placed in a class to which they do not belong. It is well to remember here that in 1918 less than twelve percent of those engaged in gainful occupations filed an income tax report. If the statistical $1850 “average income per family ’ ’ is unfair, as the anonymous contributor to The Saturday Evening Post would have us believe, it is unfair only to the millions of families whose actual income falls below $1850. But if the statistical “average income per family” was as high as $1850 in 1918-1920, the average is not $1850 at present, for the group of wage earners and salaried men and women. Their theoretical participation in the statis¬ tical $1850 annual income was temporary, lasting less than three years, and has been utterly destroyed by material decreases in wages and salaries, to say nothing of loss of wages on account of unemployment, or actual loss through enforced idleness, during the two years following the armistice. But whatever may be the portion of the national income that goes to the wage earner or non-investor families, never forget that little or none of it is in their possession at the end of the year. Their necessary living expenses consume their gross income. 174 The New Capitalism The Investor’s Share Not so with the investor group. According to the statis¬ tics given in this chapter, 3,400,000 persons had an income in 1918 totaling $17,400,000,000. Let us say that this amount represents the income of the investor group. How was it distributed? The statisticians are silent. We must therefore, make our own deductions. What part of this stupendous sum went to the bona fide small investors? Again there are no statistics. Shall I say ten percent, or $1,740,000,000 ? I doubt it! But if you think otherwise you may double or treble this amount. 6 In Chapter V, you may recall, I set aside one million investors “ whose investments are in things other than the securities of corporations.” What part of the $17,400,- 000,000 went to them ? Who can tell ? And what part went to the speculative investors? Does anyone know? Of one thing we are quite certain, and that is that the lion’s share of the $17,400,000,000 income went to the four hundred, or four thousand (or forty thousand, or four hundred thousand, if you prefer), who derive enormous incomes from many principal sources: 1: From the Banks. 2: From the Insurance Companies. 3: From the Railroad and Transportation Systems. 4: From the Public Utilities. 5: From their Monopoly of the Raw Materials and Natural Resources. 6: From their Control of the Leading Industries. 7: From Stock, and Board of Trade, Transactions. 6 Let those who may be tempted to double or treble the amount of income of the bona fide small investors remember that $1,740,000,000 is six percent on twenty-nine billion dollars. Or let them take a glance at the Stockholders Statistics appearing in the Annual Report (1921 of the American Telephone and Telegraph Company—a typical corpo¬ ration) according to which there were 186,342 shareholders of record on December 31, 1921. Of this number 63,857 held five shares or less; and 84,134 between five and twenty-five shares. These are the small stockholders. In the A. T. and T. Co., 128,000 employees are stock¬ holders. The National Income 175 Concealed Incomes But in addition to the $17,400,000,000 of admitted income there are concealed incomes, which are in reality profits camouflaged as expenses, reserves, etc. For, just as it was necessary to disguise the crime of overcapitalization (i.e. capitalizing profits) by the invention of some euphonious, indefinite phrases, such as “merger value,” “combination value, ” “ earning power, ” “ good will, ’ ’ etc., it was found necessary to invent accounting and cost systems to camou¬ flage the reprehensible Capitalistic practices and particu¬ larly to conceal: 1: That the profits are vast—considerably greater than six percent even on the inflated capitalization. 2: That the bona fide small investor does not participate appreciably in their distribution. 3: That the enormous profits are extorted from the gen¬ eral public—principally the wage earners—the non¬ investors. Capitalistic Accounting and Cost Systems The scientific accounting and cost systems, devised by some of the acutest minds, are still in a state of evolution; they are being revised, amended, and improved constantly. Books and special periodicals dealing with the fine and subtle points of accounting, are published in increasing number. Nearly all of the colleges and universities have special accounting courses. In brief, the highly scientific Capitalistic accounting and cost systems are now in general use; even concerns and individuals that cannot be said to be a component part of the Capitalistic System have adopted them, for their great benefit to those who employ them can¬ not be denied. No question is ever raised regarding their validity, their fairness, or their justice. As a matter of fact most, if not all, of the big corpora¬ tions, keep two sets of books—one for those on the inside, showing the actual condition and earnings—and another for the stockholders and the benefit of the public. This sys- 176 The New Capitalism tem of keeping two sets of accounts was brought out in a number of the federal inquiries held at different times during the past dozen years. Capitalistic Secret Reserves But I have no desire to enter into a discussion of account¬ ing and cost systems, their principles, subtleties and tech¬ nicalities. Therefore I shall confine myself to a brief gen¬ eral discussion of a few of the camouflaging practices, or rather devices, now almost universally employed and con¬ sidered entirely legitimate—devices which serve the triple purpose of keeping prices at a high level; pre-empting a goodly percentage of the profits for themselves; and exclud¬ ing the bona fide stockholders from participation therein. I will not particularly dwell on the items: interest; fixed charges; overhead expense; maintenance expense; salaries of officers; and sundry items calculated to keep production cost at the highest possible notch, for I am at this moment dealing with concealed profits, not with the cost raising devices. The devices that conceal profits are the several secret reserves. But let an authority on accounting explain them : ‘ ‘ Secret reserves may take several forms, as writing down to a comparatively small figure valuable assets, providing excessive depreciation, providing excessive reserves for bad debts, or contingencies, valuing stocks of materials and products on hand at values largely below T either cost or market, or including special reserves for future contingen¬ cies under the head of accounts payable. Inasmuch as the majority of industrial corporations do not publish their gross earnings, such reserves can easily be made, and are made continually in a form in which they do not appear in any way in the published accounts, and are known, there¬ fore, only to the directors and managers.’’ 7 7 From “Accounting' Practice and Procedure,” by Arthur Lowes Dickinson, “Balance Sheet Liabilities,” Chapter VI, p. 151. The National Income 177 A Concrete Example I can best illustrate the principle involved by giving an actual example. John Skelton Williams, at the time Comp¬ troller of the Currency in his letter to Elbert Gary, speak¬ ing of the 1918 report, said that the United States Steel Cor¬ poration ’s net earnings amounted to $549,180,000, but made deductions which left net earnings of only $274,603,000. “This deduction,” said Mr. Williams, “included an item of $96,675,000 for maintenance and repairs, though the company was carrying on its books to the credit of ‘depre¬ ciation and extraordinary replacement’ the impressive sum of $191,281,000.” And this sort of thing, mind you, has been going on for a quarter of a century. I do not know—I cannot esti¬ mate—how many billions of dollars of concealed profits in the aggregate have been diverted by corporations, man¬ agers, owners and officials into the coffers of a few thousand constituting the “inner circle” of the Capitalistic-Mam- monistic group. My guess is that several billions a year are thus “set aside.” And I believe it’s a conservative guess. I do not think that I am unfair to the Capital¬ istic “investor” group when I say that in addition to its admitted income of $17,400,000,000 in 1918, it can be cred¬ ited with an “income” of several billions of concealed profits. But whatever the actual figures—the fact cannot be denied. The Established Order All the available statistics with regard to wealth and income establish one thing beyond the shadow of a doubt, namely—the concentration of wealth in the hands of a few. This is not exactly a phenomenon, for “ ’twas ever thus,” even 'from the beginning. Indeed the concentration of wealth in the hands of a few was for centuries practically accepted by the masses as a matter of course. Moreover, they believed that they were helpless to alter it. But during the past century tremendous changes have 178 The New Capitalism taken place in the world. The masses are no longer dis¬ posed to contemplate the continued process of concentration with patient indifference. For a hundred years they have been more or less insistently asking a hundred questions which may be summarized thus: ‘ 1 Why should a favored few garner, or be permitted to garner, all the riches of the earth; to accumulate for themselves all the wealth, and the manifold blessings and advantages that (real or fancied) the possession of wealth implies or is supposed to imply. Why should they be permitted to own and to acquire all the prop¬ erties from which wealth is derived? Why should they be permitted to practically confiscate for their own private en¬ richment the resources which Nature gave to all the people? WTiy should we, year after year, sweat and toil, labor and slave, merely for them? Why are they and they alone entitled to the usufruct of our labor? We are no longer satisfied with a bare living; we want a greater share of the wealth we produce, and which is markedly swelling the cof¬ fers of those who already have vastly more than they need, and more than is good for them, or for us. This concentra¬ tion of the country’s wealth is wrong; it is an injustice, and it must cease.” And hundreds of more or less capable thinkers and writ¬ ers have tried to answer these questions more or less intelli¬ gently, more or less intelligibly, while thousands of others have come to the defense of what it pleases them to call “the established order.” Thus far the advocates of “the established order” have been victorious—the concentration of wealth in the hands of the few continues, and is a demonstrable fact. But it is becoming increasingly clearer to those not entirely blind, that “the established order” is by no means the accepted order; indeed is being rejected by a continuously increas¬ ing number. The end of the “established order” is ap¬ proaching. CHAPTER XV ■ ■ “Labor, Capital and Brains” I N October, 1920, the American Bankers’ Association held its forty-sixth annual Convention in Washing¬ ton, D. C. In its report the Committee on Resolutions 1 * ‘ ‘ fully realizing that a special duty devolves at this time on the bankers of this country to aid as best they may in meet¬ ing conditions and solving problems with a view to the welfare of the nation” (meaning, of course, their own wel¬ fare) declared itself as follows: “ With special emphasis we would call the attention of labor to the essential unity of the three great elements entering into the industrial structure, labor, capital and brains. A fair balancing of interest between these factors in production of wealth must be maintained to insure their common prosperity. Failure to recognize this balance may easily wreck industry, and we call upon each factor involved to recognize this basic truth , 9 ’ etc. The Slogan “Labor, Capital and Brains.” This is the new substi¬ tute for that other slogan, “Labor, Capital and Manage¬ ment,” which for a while was freely employed by writers and speakers—the valiant apologists for, and defenders of, the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. But “Labor, Cap¬ ital and Management” was so clearly an absurdity—Capital and Management could easily be shown to be in all cases identified—one and the same thing—cut out of the same piecer of cloth—that it has now practically disappeared from the writings and utterances of those, who, by pen or i See Journal of the American Bankers Association, November, 1920, page 289. 179 180 The New Capitalism word of mouth, discoursed in favor of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. In every instance Capital and Man¬ agement are synonymous, and the two in deadly unison are arrayed against Labor. The same can be said of the new version, “Labor, Cap¬ ital and Brains.” Like Capital and Management, Capital and Brains are one and the same thing. The same indi¬ viduals who control capital are also considered ipso facto the possessors of brains—the sole possessors, the sole inher¬ itors of that rare thing. The two—Capital and Brains— are an interlinked unit—a solid phalanx arrayed against Labor. The Propaganda The slogan is not new; it was not invented by the Reso¬ lutions Committee of the American Bankers’ Association; it has been current for some time. But the Bankers’ Asso¬ ciation has infused into it the breath of vitality. It will become more conspicuous. We will probably hear it repeat¬ edly from now on, for the Public Relations Committee of the American Bankers’ Association at the same time reported that: “More than 650 of the leading newspapers of the country have been supplied every two weeks with bulletins contain¬ ing news of banks and the association. The editors have been exceptionally responsive.” . . . “Nearly a hundred financial papers and writers have received a weekly news service. These editors have re¬ sponded in a most wholesome fashion. . . . “Public opinion, that elusive mistress of fortune, is courted assiduously these days with various forms of public relation by people in all walks of life, and is recognized in the constructive efforts of most all organizations,” etc. In an article in the North American Review (March, 1921) entitled “The New Socialism,” by John Corbin, we find the new idea as exemplified in the slogan “Labor, Capital and Brains” neatly interpreted. “In the realm of industry,” writes Corbin, “there is more than labor, more “Labor, Capital and Brains” 181 than capital—more than the two combined and eager to work in harmony. The body and the members are power¬ less without the brain that is strong and clear—force to lead, and, when need is—to rule.” The Capitalistic Claimants Probably before this book of mine is completed I will run across many repetitions and paraphrases of the new slogan, “Labor, Capital and Brains.” In the meantime let us analyze it briefly. In the minds of those who will employ it, Capital and Brains will, of course, always mean one and the same thing. They will never associate Brains wdth Labor. It will be assumed that only the Capitalistic Entre¬ preneurs have Brains; by no process of reasoning will ‘‘Brains” ever be conceded to reside in any other head. Only into the Capitalistic cranium has the Creator injected Brains. In the opinion of Capitalistic Entrepreneurs the “brains” in a calf’s head are superior to those in Labor’s head, for they can, at least, be scrambled. By “Brains” is meant a superior intelligence—ability, talent, genius—a sort of “divine right.” The Capitalistic group alone, it would seem, has intelligence, ability, talent, genius. Cap¬ italistic “Brains” is a wonderful thing in nature. Yet all the great inventions and discoveries were made, not by the Capitalistic confraternity, but by workers, men who, while working for a wage in shop or factory, or at the bench; or in their moments of studious leisure, pondered over the mysterious principles of their branches of labor, and devoted their best energy to the mastery of principles and technique—invented machines, improved them, per¬ fected them, and the sum total of whose multiplied benefits today constitute the principal asset, capital, wealth—and the chief means of enrichment, of the Capitalistic group. If it served any other purpose than to show the utter stupidity of the new slogan, and thus stultify the Capital¬ istic crowd, I should like to give over a chapter or two of this book to a brief paragraphic record of some of the most important achievements in the field of inventions and dis- 182 The New Capitalism coveries, beginning, let us say, with Richard Arkwright, inventor of the spinning jenny. Such a record would establish beyond cavil or dispute, that if brains had not resided in bountiful quantities in ordinary heads, the Capitalistic brain today, assuming that it would have the ability to function at all, would die of inanition. It is because there was a high quality of brains developed long prior to and entirely independent of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System, that the sundry indi¬ viduals constituting the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group owe their success and fortune. Has J. Pierpont Morgan added anything to the sum and substance of human happi¬ ness? For what great mechanical invention is Elbert Gary conspicuous in the eyes of the world? We speak of Besse¬ mer steel, but “lo and behold ye”—the Bessemer process was not invented by Sir Henry Bessemer, but by William Kelley, an iron maker of Eddyville, Kentucky, whose ex¬ perimentations antedated Bessemer’s by nearly ten years. Both Bessemer’s and Kelley’s processes would have yielded no practical results but for the discoveries of Mushet and Gorannson, particularly the former’s. But ‘ ‘ Mushet’s Brit¬ ish patents lapsed, and became public property, owing to his poverty and other unfortunate circumstances. ’ ’ Mushet died ‘ ‘ poor and unknown, while Bessemer was knighted by Queen Victoria for his invention and received royalties aggregating $500,000 a year.” 2 Calling the Turn Nearly ten years ago the Capitalistic group (or more accurately speaking the dominant heads of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur banking group) sought to win for themselves the unstinted applause of the world for their wonderful “brains.” Louis D. Brandeis treats of it in an interesting chapter 3 in his book “Other People’s Money.’’ He tells us that J. P. Morgan & Co., declared in a letter to the Pujo 2 “The Marvels of Modern Mechanism," by Jerome Bruce Crabtree, p. 333. 3 “Big - Men and Little Business," page 135. “Labor, Capital and Brains’’ 183 Committee that ‘ 4 practically all the railroad and industrial development of this country has taken place initially through the medium of the great banking ho uses / 1 And then Mr. Brandeis proceeds to show that just the reverse is true, that 4 4 nearly every such contribution to our comfort and prosperity” was “initiated without their aid,” and it was not until after success had been attained, or ‘ 4 the possibility of success had been demonstrated,” or not until ‘ 4 the funds of the hardy pioneers, who had risked their all, were exhausted,” that the financial “brains” came “into relation with these enterprises.” 4 4 This is true of our early railroads, ’ ’ writes Mr. Brandeis, 4 4 of our early street railways, and of the automo¬ bile ; of the telegraph, the telephone and the wireless; of gas and oil; of harvesting machinery, and of our steel industry; of the textile, paper and shoe industries; and of every other important branch of manufacture.” And in support of his contention he gives the pertinent facts with regard to the industries mentioned. “By Their Works Ye Shall Know Them” Capital and Brains!—leaving Labor for the moment entirely out of the equation, Capital and Brains forsooth! At this very moment the country is in industrial turmoil and economic upheaval, thanks to the Capitalistic Entre¬ preneur System evolved by Capitalistic Entrepreneur brains. For nearly two years the Great Industries were practically at a standstill, and millions of workers out of employment or working only part time. According to the balance sheets of some of the leading corporations—in spite of the tremendous increase of business and the greatly increased prices, and enormous profits reaped during the past twenty years, they were on the verge of bankruptcy. Some of them saved themselves by 4 4 reorganization ’ 1 schemes, evolved by Capitalistic 44 brains”—by the flotation of more and more watered stocks, and bond and note issues. 184 The New Capitalism “A Modern Instance” In February, 1921, W. W. Atterbury, Vice President of what is presumably the most prosperous railroad system in the country, made the statement that practically all the railroads are insolvent, and more than intimated that the only thing that can save them from disaster is to cut down the wages of railroad employees. On September 26, 1921, Mr. Atterbury told the members of the Mutual Benefit Society of the road, which met in Philadelphia on that date, that wages must come down or the roads would be forced into Government control, or receiverships. “It is true,” he said, “there isn’t much left for a further reduction in wages, and it isn’t pleasant to hear or contem¬ plate; but there faces us either reduction or receivership.” 4 For many years the railroads have been in a notoriously bad condition. Many of them have gone through the hands of receivers. At the time of the war, when the Government took them over, some of the important railroad properties were in a dilapidated condition. To rehabilitate them it was necessary to provide funds borrowed from the non- investor public. And even when the roads were turned back it was found imperative to supply the roads with addi¬ tional funds, borrowed from the non-investor public, besides passing a law guaranteeing returns to the “investors” in railroad “securities.” And yet the Capitalistic Entrepre¬ neurs dare to shout “over the roofs of the world”: “With special emphasis we would call the attention of labor to the essential unity of the three great elements entering into the industrial structure, labor, capital and brains.” “Whom the Gods Woidd Destroy” A peculiar symptom of madness—a sort of ‘ * divine right” lunacy, is beginning to manifest itself among the self-appointed trustees of the nation’s wealth—those who have deluded themselves into the belief that “capital and 4 Chicago Tribune, September 27, 1921. “Labor, Capital and Brains” 185 brains” are theirs by ordination of Providence—that they are financial and industrial supermen, set apart and above ordinary men, endowed with supreme intelligence, wisdom and authority, and that as a sacred duty which they are beginning to construe as a divine right, it behooves them to exercise their superior prerogatives by assuming not only IDolitical dictatorship in the nation, but also leadership over citizens, controlling their conduct, regulating their pleas¬ ures, formulating their thoughts and directing their opin¬ ions. Books, magazine articles and editorials have been written in which this lunacy is clearly apparent. A brief excerpt from an article written by a man who, by virtue of his position as Vice President of one of New York’s largest Capitalistic banks can be said to speak as one inspired, will suffice to give color to my comment: “The leaders and managers of American industry, the men who by reason of their abilities hold the positions of power and influence in the community, must accept a greater responsibility for the common welfare than they have felt in the past. If they want society to develop a common outlook and spirit they must exert themselves to that end. They must show that spirit themselves. They must show themselves outside the circle of their own private interests and identify themselves with the common interests. They must help give that direction and supervision to com¬ munity interests which are so much needed. “This responsibility they must take whether they like it or not. Whatever goes wrong with society for want of intelligent guidance and affects the living conditions of the people unfavorably, reacts upon business. The average man does not think very deeply or reflect very profoundly about causes; he judges mainly by visible results. It is up to th'em to show the common man how to be efficient, to make him prosperous, and to satisfy him that he has a stake in the country. It is squarely up to them to win the confi¬ dence of the masses. Success may not be easy, but in all fields the ability to overcome obstacles is one of the condi- 186 The New Capitalism tions of leadership. The man who cannot measure up to the requirements simply fails as a leader,” etc. 5 Or as John Corbin succinctly put it: “The body and the members are powerless without the brain that is strong and clear —free to lead, and, when need is —to rule.” The Bourbonic Plague Let those who have fallen victim to the Bourbonic plague of Capitalistic hallucinations hold communion with them¬ selves before it is too late. Let them keep in mind what mortal illness befell those nobles who suffered from similar delusions around A.D. 1789, who, we are told by Taine, had arrogated all the prominent positions in the Kingdom, with all the advantages accruing thereto, namely, “authority, property, honors, or, at the very least, privileges, immun¬ ities, favors, pensions, preferences and the like.” Let us hope that our modern “nobles” who prate of “capital and brains” and boast of their superior wisdom, authority and power may not lose their senses even as those who circa 1789 imagined they were made of a superior kind of clay, lost their heads. But I am less concerned with Capitalistic Grossenwahn —the Capitalistic tendencies, pretentions and boasts, than I am with what applies peculiarly to the economic life and welfare of the people; and it is to the consideration of those particular phases of my subject that I will confine myself in this chapter. Pouring the Oil of Fact on the Waters of Capitalistic Conceit To those who, like George E. Roberts and others, assume or contend that “brains” reside only in the heads of the Capitalistic group; and that business ability and genius cannot be developed in anyone not of the Capitalistic group, I want to state with all the emphasis possible that—I will 5 Excerpt from “Wealth—Its Use and Control,” by George E. Roberts, Vice President, National City Bank of New York, in Adminis¬ tration, The Journal of Business Analysis and Control, January, 1921. “Labor, Capital and Brains” 187 not say nine times ont of ten, but six times out of ten—in commercial life the actual work is done by the men in the ranks, but the credit for it is wholly claimed by those hold¬ ing positions of power and influence. Under the System devised by the Capitalistic group, the “underling” has no right to go over the head of a department; the subordinate cannot deal directly with the chief. I know of scores of cases where foremen, superintendents, and heads of depart¬ ments, take precious good care that no report of merito¬ rious or extraordinary work done, shall reach the ears, or fall under the notice, of those high in authority, for they are jealous, and afraid that unusual ability on the part of a subordinate might usher them out of their positions. I know of cases where men who gave evidence of possessing unusual ability and honesty, were, under one pretext or another, persecuted, or summarily dismissed. Indeed all the “brains” to be found in the Capitalistic Enterpreneur group have been recruited from the ranks of the supposed brainless. John Oakwood, in an article in The Annalist (September 19, 1921) said: “The country’s leading banks, say those with resources of $100,000,000 or more, nearly as many of which are located outside of New York as are in the metropolis, are commanded by men whose average age is about fifty-five years, who on the average have been in banking about thirty years, and who, in the great majority of cases, began as messengers or clerks and have worked their way step by step in the practical business of banking. A great many more of them were born in small towns than in big cities. ’ ’ 6 Or listen to this from the pen of Roger W. Babson: “Were the fathers of these great captains of industry college graduates? No. Were the fathers of these great captains of industry bankers ? No. Were they rich manu¬ facturers and merchants? No. These great captains of industry, these men who have built America’s greatest rail¬ roads, factories and stores, are the sons of poor parents— 6 “No Financial Moses Need Apply,” by John Oakwood, in The Annalist, September 19, 1921. 188 The New Capitalism the sons of farmers and ministers and wage workers. The statistics of this particular study even show that the great majority of these industrial builders were the sons of par¬ ents whose income averaged less than $1,200 per year. If the captains of industry of the last quarter of a century came from the ranks of the masses, the captains of industry of the next quarter of a century are going to come from the same source. The bankers, manufacturers, and mer¬ chants of the next generation will not be the sons of the bankers, manufacturers and the merchants of today. They will be the sons of farmers, professional men and wage workers of today.” 7 The Threefold Intent Behind the Slogan The threefold intent of the Capitalistic propaganda crystalized into the slogan “Labor, Capital and Brains” is clearly apparent. It is intended: 1: To impress upon the public mind that the constituent members of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System are entitled to immense rewards for their double possession— Capital and Brains. 2: To send the lesson home to those who work for a wage that if it were not for the Capitalistic “brains” Labor would be in a sorry plight. 3: To convey to those who constitute the non-investor group that without Capitalistic “brains” the world would be in a sad condition and surely go to the demnition bow¬ wows. As regards the first, namely, that Capital plus Brains is entitled to immense rewards, let me go on record once more as saying that I have never held nor contended that “brains” should go unrewarded. There are those who have ten talents and those who have only one talent, and I contend that the rew r ard should always be commensurate and liberal. But Capitalistic Brains does not seem to be satisfied with any decent reward—it wants it all. The combination of Capital and Brains is content wfith nothing 7 Chicago Daily News, July 16, 1921. “Labor, Capital and Brains” 189 less than a hundred percent return on its supposed double investment. Look at the statistics for Wealth and Income. Reflect for a moment on the fact that today probably about ten percent of the population owns ninety percent of the country’s wealth. A rather liberal reward consider¬ ing that as a rule the real brains were furnished, not by the Capitalistic crow r d, nor members of their families, but by generations of brain owners vested in the garb of workers. Let me ask one question of those who sing the siren song “Capital and Brains.” In 1918 the admitted Capitalistic emoluments amounted to seventeen and a half billion. How much of this amount was a distinct return on Capital, and how much on Brains? Or do the two constitute an intimate, endogenous, inseparable hermaphroditic entity. With regard to the second intent concealed within the Capitalistic slogan “Capital and Brains”—let me quote a statement made by Charles M. Schwab: “The pressure of large amounts of capital invested in industry does not crush the workingman. On the con- traiy, only by large investments can the prosperity of the workingman be furthered.” Indeed? One begins to wonder how workingmen man¬ aged to get along before industries were consolidated and combined. Surely Mr. Schwab will admit that workmen had jobs before Capitalistic Trusts and combines were formed. He will also admit that industries grew and flour¬ ished in the years antedating the origin of ‘ ‘ Big Business. ’ ’ I should like to see him prove his contention that “only by large investments can the prosperity of the workingman be furthered.” But before attempting this it might be well for Mr. Schwab to read the report of The Interchurch World' Movement Committee on the steel strike of 1919. The other implication that those who labor do not pos¬ sess and cannot develop “brains”, I have already suffi¬ ciently answered in this chapter. But for emphasis Ill add that there are thousands of men in the ranks every- 190 The New Capitalism where who have great executive and managerial ability, ambition and initiative, who need but an untrammelled opportunity to equal and surpass many of the men holding positions of power and influence. And they have—what many Capitalistic Entrepreneurs—chiefs, executives and managers have not—still a sense of honor and of moral responsibility—a conscience. My answer to the third clear intent of the Capitalistic slogan, “Capital and Brains,” is the contents of this book. I grant to the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs the possession of brains—but brains infected with maggots. To the par¬ ticular brand of Capitalistic brains we not only can, but must, attribute the wretched economic condition that pre¬ vails throughout the world today. Who is responsible for the steady increase in the cost of living during the past twenty years? Who is responsible for the depreciation of the wage dollar. Who is responsible for the decrease in the purchasing power of money ? Whom are we to blame, or whose praises shall we sing, for the prolonged business stagnation, and for the unemployment of millions of men and women? “Brains” Brains! Ah, yes, it is a very remarkable kind of “brains” that can originate a business system which finds it necessary to employ three dollars of capital to produce one dollar’s worth of goods; a very special kind of “brains” that has succeeded in developing a business sys¬ tem necessitating the borrowing of from two to three dollars where formerly one sufficed; a most extraordinary kind of “brains” that can set in motion and keep in per¬ fect running order, for its own exclusive benefit, a busi¬ ness machine that compels the public to spend from three to four dollars for what could formerly be bought for one dollar. Hats off, ye non-investors, to the BRAINS that has done all this for you! CHAPTER XVI The Shrinking Dollar W E have heard a great deal within the last decade of the shrinking dollar, as if the dollar were compara¬ ble to the modest violet shrinking bhishingly from view. Why call it a shrinking dollar, since there are a half hundred terms that would more aptly describe its evanescent career? For example, you might say that the dollar of today, compared with the dollar of former years, is lean, or shrivelled, or anemic, or emaciated, or attenuated, or debilitated, or lacerated, or mutilated, or emasculated, or sick, or stricken, or an invalid, or devitalized, or incapaci¬ tated, or deteriorated, or depreciated, or depressed. Any of these descriptive terms—just to note a few—will fit the case better than shrinking. But the economic doctors have a horror of calling a spade a spade. They are reluctant to call things by their right name. Their innate modesty does not permit them to tell the naked truth; to their delicately attuned ears the truth is bitter, harsh, ugly and repellant. So as not to disturb the peaceful slumber of the expectant relatives, they prefer to let the patient writhe in pain on his Procrustean bed. And so they prate more or less learnedly of the “shrink¬ ing dollar’’ rather than saying in so many words that prices have gone up; and that the going up of prices has necessarily reduced the purchasing power of the dollar, depressed its value, depreciating it calculably by precisely as many cents as prices went up. Depreciation of the Wage Dollar In 1896 the American dollar was at its best—a perfectly healthy dollar; it was worth one hundred cents; it could 191 192 The New Capitalism buy a maximum quantity of goods. Then the period of overcapitalization began. Almost immediately prices of commodities began to ascend, slowly at first, but surely. Taking the prices of 1896 as basic w r e discover that for every cent of increase in the aggregate prices of the com¬ modities, the wage dollar, i.e., the non-investor’s dollar— went down by one cent in purchasing power. No finer example of the inverse ratio can be found than in the phe¬ nomena of ascending prices and declining purchasing power. Appreciation of the Capitalistic Dollar But that isn’t the whole story. For every cent of decrease in the purchasing power of the wage dollar, i.e., the non-investor’s dollar, the Capitalistic dollar increased in value one cent. It is far, far from the truth to say that shrinkage is predicable of all dollars. Only the wage dollar depreciated in value; and because the non-investor’s dollar depreciated in value the Capitalistic dollar appreciated in value. Again we have another fine example of the inverse ratio; besides a splendid illustration of cause and effect. The Word of an Authority According to Professor Kemmerer the dollar of 1920 had only about 27 cents the value of the dollar in 1896. This means that in the course of about twenty-five years the value, or purchasing power of the wage dollar depreciated at the average rate of about three cents a year—a tragedy only to those who must spend their entire income for the mere privilege of living—for food, clothes, shelter, and the sundry things that constitute the minor comforts of life. Where did this lost value go ? Whither did it w r ander ? It did not evaporate; it was not blown away; it did not dis¬ solve into thin air. No! it entered into the vampire Capi¬ talistic dollar. While the wage dollar became weak, and wobbly, and emaciated, the Capitalistic dollar waxed big, and strong, and lusty. While the wage dollar depreciated The Shrinking Dollar 193 at the rate of about three cents a year, the Capitalistic dollar appreciated at the cumulative rate of about three cents a year. Figures That Tell the Tale The following Table approximately illustrates the simul¬ taneous weakening of the wage dollar and strengthening of the Capitalistic dollar: How the Wage Dollar How the Capitalistic Depreciated in Pur- Dollar Appreciated chasing Power in Value Wage Earner’s Dollar Capitalistic Dollar 1896_ . $1.00 $1.00 1897.... . 0.97 1.03 1898... . . 0.94 1.06 1899_ . 0.91 1.09 1900.... . 0.88 1.12 1901.... . 0.85 1.15 1902.... . 0.82 1.18 1903.... . 0.79 1.21 1904.... . 0.76 1.24 1905.... . 0.73 1.27 1906.... . 0.70 1.30 1907.... . 0.67 1.33 1908.... . 0.64 1.36 1909.... . 0.61 1.39 1910_ . 0.58 1.42 1911.... . 0.5 5 1.45 1912_ . 0.52 1.48 1913_ . 0.49 1.51 1914.... . 0.46 1.54 1915_ 1.57 1916.... . 0.40 1.60 1917... . . 0.37 1.63 1918_ . 0.34 1.66 1919.... . 0.31 1.69 1920. .. . . 0.28 1.72 For more than a dozen years I have puzzled over the phenomenon of the shrinking dollar; for as many years I have endeavored to express the shrinkage in words and fig¬ ures, and I think I have finally succeeded in doing this to the satisfaction of all except those who derive, or have de¬ rived, immense material benefits from the transmutation that has simultaneously depreciated the wage dollar and appreciated the Capitalistic dollar. It goes without saying 194 The New Capitalism that many of those who constitute the investor group—- the darling beneficiaries of the Capitalistic System, who prefer to conceal from the world that their sustenance comes principally from the loins of their fellowmen; and that the major portion of their income or profits is directly de¬ rived from the wage earner’s dollar—will vehemently pro¬ test against my exposure of the phenomenon showing the depreciation of the wage dollar, and the inverse apprecia¬ tion of the Capitalistic dollar. ‘ ‘ Why, ’ ’ they will say, ‘ ‘ no economist ‘in good standing,’ no statistical expert, no ac¬ cepted authority, has ever interpreted the shrinking dollar as set forth in this chapter. ’ ’ The Philosophy of the Economists And they are quite right! No Capitalistic economist, no statistical expert, no accepted authority has ever gone to the trouble of lucidly stating the facts in the case—neither with regard to the “shrinking” dollar, nor with regard to many other economic phenomena in which the average man and woman is vitally interested. Indeed it can be shown that they have gone to great lengths at times, to obscure the truth or camouflage economic facts into indecipherability. I am not finding fault with the Capitalistic economists, “in good standing,” nor with their allies, the statistical experts and accepted authorities. I’ll pay them the com¬ pliment of saying that they do not make, and never have made, any pretentions with regard to the science they pro¬ fess—a “science” from which every ethical principle has been ruthlessly removed, and every moral consideration remorsely eliminated; a “science” that admittedly does not concern itself with the welfare of humanity—but only with Wealth. Proudhon has said that “Political economy, which is re¬ garded by many as the philosophy of wealth, is in fact nothing but the organized practice of robbery and misery.” Ruskin expressed the same opinion when he said: “You were ordered by the Founder of your religion to love your neighbor as yourself. You have founded an entire Science The Shrinking Dollar 195 of Political Economy, on what you have stated to be the constant instinct of man—the desire to defraud his neigh¬ bor. ’ ’ These are not reckless dicta of extreme or radical men. But if you are disposed to hold that they belong to the school of extremists, suppose you consider for a moment this statement made by N. W. Senior, ‘ ‘ the foremost econo¬ mist between Ricardo and Mill,” held in greatest esteem in his generation, and to this day by economists who claim to be “in good standing.” With almost brutal frankness Senior boldly declared: “ It is not with happiness but with wealth that I am concerned as a political economist; and I am not only justified in omitting, but, perhaps, am bound to omit, all considerations which have no influence on wealth. ’ ’ The Wisdom of the Serpent Which being the case we can hardly blame economists for having put all the emphasis on the shrinking wage dollar and entirely ignoring that other phenomenon, the expanded Capitalistic dollar. They have admitted the meta¬ morphosis of the wage dollar into a 25 cent dollar (approx¬ imately) within twenty-five years; it is no part of their duty to proclaim to the world that within the same period of time the Capitalistic dollar has apotheosized itself into a 175 cent dollar. We can hardly expect them to inform the men and women workers of the nation (three-fourths of whom are in the wage earner or non-investor group) that they are being paid with 25 cent dollars, while the Capitalistic group is rewarding itself with 175 cent dollars. In all the discussions attendant upon wage increases since the armistice, I have never come across a single writer who even so much as hinted that Labor is being paid with depreciated wage dollars, while Capital’s meed is propor¬ tioned with appreciated dollars. And yet that truth lies flat at the bottom of the whole question. However, I shall have more to say on the subject of Wages in Part II of this book. 196 The New Capitalism Make no mistake—the economists, experts, authorities, etc., have the ability to explain the mystery of the High Cost of Living. Indeed they could if they would, with comparative ease, explain to the world that it is on account of the admirable generosity with which the Capitalistic group rewards itself, that the purchasing power of the wage dollar has shrunk to such sad proportions; and that on account of the Capitalistically superinduced “shrink¬ age ’ ’ those who work for a wage must pay nearly four dol¬ lars for what formerly cost only one dollar. Another Tell-Tale Table The following Table, which I have constructed on the premises stated, gives an idea of what has taken place d What Could Be Bought in 1896 for $ .25 . .50 . .75 . 1.00 . 2.00. 5.00 . 10.00 . 50.00 . 75.00 . 100.00 . 200.00 . 250.00 . 500.00 . 750.00 . 1 , 000.00 . In 1920 Cost Approximately . ..$ 1.00 1.75 2.50 3.25 6.50 16.25 32.50 ... 162.50 .. . 243.75 ... 325.00 .. . 650.00 .. . 812.00 ... 1635.00 ... 2457.50 ... 3250.00 A Word of Caution When analyzing the above statistics I beg the reader to remember these things: 1: That the comparison is between the years 1896 and 1920 . It is important to keep this clearly in mind while reading this chapter. Some statisticians, when speaking of i In order to enable the reader to grasp the point more easily I have taken the liberty to use the twenty-five cents value of the depre¬ ciated dollar as basic, rather than the twenty-seven cent dollar spoken of by economists. The Shrinking Dollar 197 the shrinking dollar, make comparisons between later years, for example, between 1914 and 1919. Naturally such com¬ putations, based on more recent years, show a lesser degree of shrinkage than when the comparison is between years more widely apart. 2: That the increase shown applies to living costs in the aggregate, and not to single items. It would be absurd to say that the article that cost twenty-five cents in 1896 cost one dollar in 1920, although beyond a doubt, for some com¬ modities the increase was even greater than my figures in¬ dicate. 3: Under 11 living costs” I include all living commodities —food, clothes, rent, and whatever enters into the volume of living goods consumed by an average family, particularly by the eighty percent of families I have designated as non¬ investors. How near my computations are to those of the accepted authorities may be judged from the fact that according to Dun’s Index Number the wholesale prices of three hundred articles in 1896 was $74.32, whereas in 1920 it was $260.41. My computation for $75 in 1896 demanding $243.75 in 1920 is, therefore, not wide of the mark. And when it is remembered that Dun’s Index Number is based on whole¬ sale prices, while my computation presumes retail prices, it is clear that I am exceedingly conservative. 2 Bradstreet’s Index Number shows that the prices of 157 commodities, which could be bought for $591 in 1896, had risen to $2087 in February, 1920. 2 It is to be remembered that most Index Numbers are based on wholesale prices. If retail prices were used instead a different result would follow. Moreover, they concern themselves only with com¬ modities, not with “living costs,” and take no cognizance of rent increases. Nor do they take into consideration that for many of the commodities, such as clothes, shoes, all kinds of wearing material, fabrics, textiles, etc., while prices have increased, let us say in round numbers, one hundred per cent, quality has been reduced by about one-half, thus putting the average family to the necessity of purchas¬ ing a double quantity. In brief. Price Index Numbers are of pre¬ carious value. Certainly they do not show the actual increase or decrease in the aggregate living costs. 198 The New Capitalism The Non-Shrinkability of the Capitalistic Dollar No Capitalistic economist, statistical expert or accepted authority has ever pointed out that the Capitalistic dollar is non-shrinkable; that the dollar in the hands of a Capitalistic overlord retains its full strength; that when Capitalistically employed there is no lost value to be noted in the dollar. Let me briefly illustrate the point. Fifty thousand John Smiths—each a small salaried man —pay out of their meager income, fifty dollars a year as premium on a one thousand dollar Life Insurance Policy. The Insurance Company invests these $2,500,000 in a new building. Let us say the building could have been erected in 1896 for $1,250,000. What has raised the cost of the building? Increase in cost of material, supplies, etc. But the same Capitalistic principals who own or control the Insurance Company, also have a monopoly of all the build¬ ing materials, supplies, etc. Consequently they pay the big¬ ger price to themselves. And the bigger price, based sup¬ posedly on a bigger investment, yields them a bigger profit. Then there are the higher freight rates; but the same group that owns or controls the Insurance Company, and the materials and the supplies, also owns the railroads; there¬ fore is directly benefited by the higher freight rates. 3 (Don’t interrupt me with the stock explanation that mate¬ rials, increases in the price of supplies, freight, etc., are due to increase in wages. It is just the other way around. Moreover, I shall show in the second half of my book, that whatever increase in wages Labor has had was invariably taken away again through the medium of still higher prices.) Now let us assume that the borrowing of money enters into the construction of the building. And let us say that on account of the increase in the price of materials and supplies, freight rates (and wages, if you will), it is neces¬ sary to borrow double the amount the Insurance Company 3 And I’ll not say a single word about the “Pittsburgh Plus’’ plan at this time. The Shrinking Dollar 199 would have borrowed in 1896; and therefore the principals are paying twice as much interest. But remember the same group that owns the Insurance Company, and the railroads, and has a monopoly on materials, supplies, etc., also owns the banks; and so is the immediate beneficiary of the larger borrowings and the higher interest charges. Very well! The building, when completed, has an in¬ creased value of one hundred percent. Consequently the Capitalistic owners of the building can issue bonds for double the amount they would have issued in 1896. And they reap double the amount of commissions, and double the fixed charge—interest. Moreover, the larger bond issue increases the borrowing capacity of the holders; for, bonds are credit instruments, and accepted by banks as collateral. And when the building is ready for occupancy, the Cap¬ italistic owners charge their tenants twice as much rent as they would have demanded in 1896. Thus they derive twice as much income from the building. At no point can it be said that the Capitalistic dollar has lost any of its value, purchasing, or earning, power. Bigger income, bigger profits, are visible everywhere, and raining more profusely than ever into the lap of the small Capitalistic group. But — But when John Smith dies, his $1000 policy will have a purchasing power of only $250, measured in the 1896 value; the difference—$750—being absorbed by the higher prices his widow or family must pay for the needful things of life—thanks to the Capitalistic System, controlled and manipulated by those to whom the late head of the family had been paying his premium of $50 a year regularly. Truly there is a ‘‘shrinkage” in the dollar, but only when it passes out of Capitalistic hands, or is employed in other than Capitalistic transactions. Let me give you what is probably the most striking illustration of all, and which will impress you with the real meaning of ‘ ‘ shrinkage . 1 ’ 200 The New Capitalism How the “Shrinkage” Affects Savings In 1896 the savings depositors had on deposit in savings banks of the United States, a total of $1,935,466,468. In 1896 the dollar had a one hundred cents purchasing power. In 1920 the savings depositors had on deposit in the sav¬ ings banks of the United States a total of $6,536,596,000. But by 1920 the purchasing power of the dollar had shrunk to approximately twenty-eight cents. Consequently the purchasing power of the $6,536,596,000 on deposit in 1920 had a purchasing power equivalent to $1,830,246,880 in 1896. No better illustration of the “shrinkage” in the wage dollar than this. In brief, the nearly five billion dollars saved during twenty years, gave no increase of purchasing power to the owners. The amount of money you saved, penny by penny, whether you have it in a sock or in a savings bank, has today a purchasing power only about one-fourth of what it was in 1896. That is to say, what you could have bought in 1896 with one dollar of your savings, will take nearly four dollars of your savings if purchased today. Nor is there any immediate prospect that a change of conditions will materially improve the purchasing power either of your wages or savings. Nor is there any evidence of willingness on the part of the Capitalistic group to materi¬ ally increase the purchasing power of your wages or value of your savings. On the contrary! If the Capitalistic group can get away with it; if it succeeds in its double pur¬ pose of increasing its income—interest, dividends, and profits—by bringing down wages approximately to the 1914 level, while maintaining a high level of prices—the purchas¬ ing power of your wages and savings will shrink still more. Precisely where it will stop it is idle to speculate at this time. The Shrinking Dollar 201 The Most Damnable Capitalistic Device In a previous chapter I have stated that the Capitalistic System, through sundry clever devices, extorts about $750 a year from the average family. But the most ingenious Capitalistic device, by the general employment of which the $750 is extorted, while at the same time the shrinkage of the wage dollar is made to appear as if it were a perfectly natural phenomenon—the necessary effect of an irresistable cause—is what is known as the Percentage System of figuring increases in cost, and which percentage increases determine the price of every article of merchandise. I have had occasion to denounce this reprehensible prac¬ tice a number of times in the past, and shall lose no oppor¬ tunity to hold it up to obloquy today. What is wrong with the Percentage System of computing increases? Is it not perfectly legitimate and fair? Let me show you how it works, and then judge for yourself whether it is beneficent or otherwise—whether it is fair, or unfair. Let us say that the basic price of cattle is $6.00 per hun¬ dredweight. Then it raises to, let us say, $12.00. “Aha!” says the wholesale slaughterer—“An increase of 100 'per¬ cent! I must increase my price to the retail dealer 100 percent —plus an additional profit on the increase.” The retail dealer gets his invoice, looks it over and says: “Aha, an increase of 100 percent! I must raise my price to the consumer 100 percent, plus, of course, a profit on the increase.” And so through the agency of the Percentage System of figuring increases of prices the consumer is compelled to pay three separate 100 percent increases (and sometimes more than three). Do you wonder any longer at the present “high level of prices” for all the commodities—food, rent, clothes, shoes, coal, steel, in brief every article that enters into living costs? Here you have the principle and the modus operandi of the Percentage System of figuring increases, now univer¬ sally used, and supposed to be perfectly legitimate, set forth. 202 The New Capitalism I call it the most damnable of all Capitalistic devices. And yet, so far as I know, it has never been challenged. In all these years I have never once, in any financial, commercial, or trade paper, nor from any public or after-dinner speaker, nor statistical expert, nor professor of economics, nor skilled mathematician, nor any text book on cost account¬ ing, read or heard so much as a whisper of protest against nor exposure of, this blatant sophistry and damnable humbug. The Percentage System is essentially a pyramiding sys¬ tem, and I for one, demand its abrogation as a matter of simple justice. Take any commodity—coal, for example: add to the 1914 price all the actual increases computed in dollars and cents —wages of miners, insurance, taxes and sundry items that can be legitimately included in “cost of production”—and note the difference between the cent sys¬ tem of figuring increases and the Percentage System. But I shall have more to say on this subject in Part II of this book. For the present I ’ll merely say that the uni¬ versal discontinuance of the Percentage System and the adoption of the cent system alone, would quickly bring down prices to a normal and decent level, and forever make impossible violent price fluctuations. Besides the shrinking wage dollar would cease shrinking, and regain a goodly portion of its pristine vigor. CHAPTER XVII The American Standard of Living W E frequently hear it said, generally by those who never look below the surface of things, who give no serious thought nor study to any subject, whose reading is confined to a desultory perusal of the daily papers (gorging themselves on headlines), whose scientific knowledge or intelligent understanding of economic prob¬ lems is nil, whose opinions are based on casual observations in their own restricted circle, whose views of life are derived from their own limited experience, who base all their con¬ clusions on a few cases known to them, or their own par¬ ticular case, that the American Standard of living is the highest in the world. By that is meant that the wage earn¬ ers in the United States receive higher wages, eat better food, wear better clothes, live in better houses, and amid better surroundings, enjoying more comforts and even some luxuries; in brief that, generally speaking, they are better off than the wage earners of Europe and other countries. In order to save time and space let us accept the state¬ ment without cavil or without pausing to analyze it—as if it were and always had been, literally true. Let us say that the American Standard of living is the highest in the world, and that the economic condition of the wage earners of the United States is superior to that of the workers of Europe, or Asia, or Mexico. Organized Labor Established the Standard But why is the American Standard of living higher than the standard of any other people? The answer comes naturally: because wages are higher. And why are wages 203 204 The New Capitalism higher? The answer is simple: because organized wage earners insisted that they shall receive a fairly decent recompense for their labor. It was their persistence alone that has given us what is called the American Standard of living—a standard admittedly somewhat higher than the standard of European countries. For our “higher stand¬ ard of living” certainly no thanks whatever is due to the Capitalistic group, who from the beginning, year in and year out, fought against every demand for better wages; and who granted wage increases only reluctantly and grudgingly, and that, too, in spite of the fact that they had invariably nullified the benefits of each wage increase by a previous increase in the prices of their commodities. But Organized Capital Claims the Credit It cannot be denied that our higher standard is the result of organized Labor’s stubborn and often bitter fight for higher wages—to that and that alone. Notwithstanding which provable fact the Capitalistic group has for years claimed the credit, as if our “higher standard” had been of their making—a gratuitous gift graciously bestowed upon us out of the plenitude of their generosity. For example, James J. Hill, in his “Highways of Prog¬ ress” 1 (p. 122) says: “So far as modern industrial meth¬ ods are concerned we may fairly say that their net result has been to cheapen production, and thus place more of the comforts of life within the reach of the people. ’ ’ Mr. Hill also contended that big business combinations and conse¬ quent lower cost of production 2 inevitably yield lower prices and higher wages, and therefore “cheaper and more abundant food, shelter and clothing,” etc. 1 Published in 1912, Doubleday Page & Co., New York. 2 It can be proved that generally speaking big combinations did not lower cost of production ; on the contrary raised it considerably. But assuming that they did “lower cost of production,” no benefit accrued to the public from the reduction ; just the reverse. The American Standard of Living 205 Shall the Standard Be Maintained f Not to Capital, but to organized Labor, belongs the full credit for having established what it pleases many to call the American Standard of living. Indeed the present bitter fight between organized Labor and organized Capital, more properly speaking, between organized wage earners and the organized Capitalistic group, revolves around the question whether the American Standard of living shall be main¬ tained, or whether it shall be reduced to the admittedly lower European standard; and ultimately to the low Ori¬ ental standard. The Capitalistic group has demanded that the American Standard shall no longer be maintained; and organized Labor is fighting for its maintenance. Who will win? Organized Capital or organized Labor? It must be admitted that thus far organized Capital has nothing but victories to report. Indeed it may be truly said that organ¬ ized Capital has been brilliantly successful. Lotvering the Standard I cannot follow the fight step for step, and shall, there¬ fore, content myself with noting a few of the obvious results thus far obtained by organized Capital. The Department of Labor in the “Monthly Labor Review, ” July, 1920, gives an analysis of some of the effects of increased cost of living on family budgets. It found, among other things, that there was a less quantity of fresh beef, fresh pork, salt pork and poultry purchased in 1918-19 than in 1901. “In many cases the decrease in quantity is striking, such, for instance, as in fresh pork from 87 pounds in North Atlantic States in 1901, to 19 pounds in New York, and 22 pounds in Portland, Me., in 1918-19. ” Decreases with regard to the consumption of many'other articles of food are noted, among them eggs, milk, butter, lard and sugar. Making a comparison of the total number of pounds of food purchased in 1918-19 by the standard family in each of the five North Atlantic cities, the analysis shows that: “In none of the cities listed 206 The New Capitalism in the report does the total reach that of the health and decency budget of the Bureau of Labor Statistics, * ’ and that “the food actually consumed in these cities of the North Atlantic group falls considerably below the 3,500 calories generally recognized as the standard by food experts. ’ ’ Those who refuse to grasp the significance of the fore¬ going will, perhaps, be able to see a little light when they ponder over this: “Dr. Wood of Columbia University, after an exhaustive investigation, informs the public that 25 percent of the 20,000,000 school children of the United States are imper¬ fectly nourished.” 3 The Difficulty of Making Ends Meet The United States Department of Labor, during 1921, published a number of tables pertaining to changes in the cost of living in some of the big cities. From the report issued June 20th (the day on which I am writing this) covering ten cities, I give the expenditure data pertaining to the first city on the list, viz., Baltimore, Md.: Items of Expenditure Food. Clothing. Housing. Fuel and Light. Furniture and Furnishings Miscellaneous . Percent of Total Expenditure _ 42.0 _ 15.0 _ 14.0 .... 5.0 .... 4.3 _ 19.7 These percentages applied to an average family of five with a statistical income of $1,500 a year, computed in dollars and cents, give the following results: Per Year Per Person Per Person Per Person (5 Persons) Per Year Per Week Per Day Food.$630.00 $126.00 $2.43 35 cts. Clothing. 225.00 45.00 .87 12^ cts. Housing. 210.00 42.00 .81 11*4 cts. Fuel and Light. 75.00 15.00 .29 4 cts. Furniture and Fur’shings. . 64.50 14.50 .28 4 cts. Miscellaneous . 295.50 59.10 1.14 16 cts. 3 From a pamphlet entitled “Fabric Facts,” published by Strang Hewat & Co., Inc. The American Standard of Living 207 Surely it is not necessary to make any extended comment on these items in the family budget. They speak for them¬ selves; they need no lengthy explanation. But since there are those who refuse to see the light, no matter how clear it may be, let us briefly analyze the first item— Food —for which an average family of five, having at least theoretically a joint income of $1,500 a year, is supposed to expend $630 within twelve months. Food prices at the time these sta¬ tistics were computed by the Government, were supposed to be considerably less than peak prices in 1920; but the average housewife, as she scans her weekly expense for meats, groceries, vegetables, milk, butter, eggs, ice, etc., wonders how she can feed her family on the statistical $630 a year; for an annual expenditure of $630 for food means only about $12.00 a week, which is an allowance of about $2.43 per person per week, or about 35 cents a day per person. Considering that the average healthy person eats three meals a day it means about twelve cents per meal. Hats off to the housewife who, considering prevailing prices, can, day after day, put up a nourishing meal at an average outlay of only about twelve cents per head. Well may the husband, who, perhaps, takes his noonday luncheon at some cheap restaurant, paying ten cents for a bowl of soup, fifteen cents for a sandwich, ten cents for a cup of coffee and five cents for a doughnut or two, and twenty-five cents for half a cantaloupe, wonder how she does it. Thus could I analyze item after item in the household budget, but I do not deem it necessary except for those who are blind because they do not want to see, and I haven’t much space to waste on them. Just one word, however, with regard to the “Miscellaneous” item. It would be interesting to know what “Miscellaneous” covers. For example, assuming that two of the five persons work, and that they must both use the street car coming and going, it means sixteen cents a day per person, or thirty-two cents for both, and counting three hundred days a year it means 208 The New Capitalism an expenditure of $96 for street car fare alone. 4 We may indeed speak of the “high standard of living,” and give organized Labor credit for having established it; but God knows organized Capital is making us pay the price for its maintenance. The Item of Rent The National Industrial Conference Board Review Re¬ port, Number 44 (December, 1921) on “Changes in the Cost of Living” says: “Investigations made by authori¬ tative agencies indicate that, in normal years preceding the war, average wage earners’ families so apportioned their expenditures as to spend approximately 43 percent of the total for food, 18 percent for shelter, 13 percent for cloth¬ ing, 6 percent for fuel and light, and 20 percent for sun¬ dries.” Computed in dollars, the item of rent is $270 a year, or about $22.50 a month, which is a huge joke. I’ll venture the statement that a majority of wage-earners residing in the large cities and fair sized towns (unless they live in hovels and dumps) are paying considerably more than $22.50 a month. I maintain that the average yearly rental is nearer $400 than $270 per family. Confining myself to conditions in Chicago, rentals, on an average, have been raised fully one hundred percent. Thousands of families that lived in fairly decent neighborhoods, paying perhaps from $35 to $65 a month, were confronted with the alternative of paying twice as much rent or moving. As a result tens of thousands of families were compelled either to move into less desirable neighborhoods, or go into smaller quarters, or double up with another family, or break up their home altogether, storing their furniture and boarding, or retrenching in other things. In many cases to meet the situation other members of the family, not infrequently the wife and mother, entered the ranks of workers. There are no statistics, but it is quite believable that in the aggregate throughout the United States hundreds of thousands of 4 Since the above was written there has been a slight decrease in the street car fare in some cities. The American Standard of Living 209 families have been compelled to materially revise their standard of living downward—thanks to the well laid and cleverly organized plans of the Capitalistic System. I care not what arguments you might advance to explain the con¬ dition, or minimize the guilt of those responsible. I am, for the present, dealing with the fact —that the ‘ ‘ American Standard 7 ’ of living has been lowered. The Capitalistic System There will be those who will say: Why blame the Capital¬ istic group for the well nigh universal increase in rents? Morgan, Gary, Schwab, et al. do not own the houses in which the wage earners live; they are not the landlords. Quite true! but they, i.e., the dominant members of the Capital¬ istic group, control the banks, which, as is well known, have given practically no assistance to the public, and certainly made no effort to relieve the distressing situation. More¬ over, they control the building materials market, and the prices they arbitrarily fixed for them had made building prohibitive. But that is not the point. Let us put the entire blame for the exorbitant rents on real estate men, and landlords. Why did they raise their rents—practically doubling them? What was their excuse? On what did they base the increase, and how did they compute it? On the Capitalistic principles: 1: Inflated valuation; 2 : Arbi¬ trary raising of the price of property by selling and resell¬ ing ; 3 : Basing rentals on ‘ ‘ replacement ’ ’ valuation; 4: The employment of the Percentage System of figuring increases. You may, if you choose, exculpate certain individuals within the Capitalistic group—but you cannot exonerate the System—you cannot defend the principles, nor the methods, no matter by whom practiced, particularly since their universal employment is responsible for what I charge —namely the compulsory lowering of the American Stand¬ ard of living. 210 The New Capitalism Holding Up the European Standard as an Ideal The anonymous writer in The Saturday Evening Post referred to in a previous chapter, makes a strong point of the extravagance of the American wage earner. He can¬ not understand why the American born wage earner com¬ plains about his wages, considering that foreign born workers (he speaks particularly of steel workers) manage to save a considerable sum out of their wages. Of course the anonymous writer did not go to the trouble of explaining that there are millions of foreign born wage earners in this country who do not live according to the American Standard. Eight or ten or twelve (and more) persons—men, women and children—are huddled together in two or three squalid rooms in dirty tenement houses, or hovels, paying only a nominal rent. Needless to say, in some cases the women work; and frequently, also, the chil¬ dren. They buy only the cheapest food and clothes. They purchase nothing that adds to their creature comforts, which being the case it is possible, that out of their aggre¬ gate earnings they save a fair portion. But if they lived according to what is called the American Standard, if, in¬ stead of living in miserable rooms in a crowded tenement house or hovel, they lived in decent quarters or neighbor¬ hoods ; if they consumed the food that an average American consumes, or made any attempt at even ordinary social im¬ provement, it is quite likely that the savings of these foreigners would be considerably less than our anonymous critic would have us believe they are. True, many of these foreigners are living in out-of-the- way places, far removed from the centers of civilization. How they live, the food they eat, the clothes they wear, is their own affair. But to hold them up to men and women of America as proof that it is possible to save out of wages which are demonstrably inadequate for the maintenance of of a decent living standard, or as an example worthy of emulation, or to intimate that the foreigner is thrifty and economical and the average American is shiftless and The American Standard of Living 211 extravagant, is exceeding the speed limit of imagination; nay it is the height of impertinence and an insult to every decent American man and woman. The Truth Without Trimmings Perhaps the anonymous author has never read the report of the Interchurch World Movement Committee on the Steel strike of 1919, according to which: ‘ ‘ The annual earnings of over one-third of all productive iron and steel workers were, and have been for years, below the level set by the government experts as the minimum of subsistence standard for families of five. “The annual earnings of 72 percent of all workers were, and have been for years, below the level set by government experts as the minimum of comfort level for families of five. “This second standard being the lowest which scientists are willing to term an 'American Standard of living’, it follows that nearly three-quarters of the steel workers could not earn enough for an American standard of living. “The bulk of unskilled steel labor . . . earned less than enough for the average family’s minimum subsistence. “The bulk of semi-skilled steel workers earned less than enough for the average family’s minimum comfort. “Skilled steel labor is paid wages disproportionate to the earnings of the other two-thirds, thus binding the skilled class to the companies and creating division between it and the rest of the force. ’ ’ 5 The Economic Sin of Extravagance Let me say it once, and without further parley, that during the past twenty years there has crept into the nation’s life, like a slimy snake into a fair garden, wanton extravagance and sinful wastefulness, a sort of national thriftlessness and shiftlessness, for which no economic rem¬ edy can be formulated. Nor shall I waste much time in 5 Chapter IV, “Wages in a No Conference Industry.” 212 The New Capitalism tearful commiseration for those who, with their eyes wide open and of their own free will, are jazzing toward their economic doom. There are today, principally in the big cities, I know not how many million men and women who are living away beyond their means; in better style and in better neighborhoods than their income justifies; wearing clothes and eating foods they cannot afford; running auto¬ mobiles, and into debt, in an endeavor to maintain a false social status and a standard of pretense despite an empty purse; and their number is growing alarmingly. Shall I venture an estimate of the numerical strength of this tribe? Is it ten percent of the population—or two million families, involving not only the men and women, but also the children? Is that too low an estimate? I’ll double it if you think I am too conservative. It is imma¬ terial! I am less interested in the exact number than in the fact that these ten, or more, million thriftless economic derelicts, and shiftless social pretenders, are amongst us, and we must take some note of them in passing. But this is certain—that they belong chiefly to the economic groups whose individual earnings are in excess of $1500 a year. Few in the classes whose family income is from $500 to $1500 are included in the category of the socially pre¬ tentious and economically shiftless. Let none dare urge that many a girl working in store or office, factory or shop, wears silk stockings instead of lisle or cotton; or perhaps in an evil moment, or hour of aber¬ ration has invested a goodly portion of a year’s wage in a fur coat; or that the laundress goes to the movies with her children an average of once or twice a week; or that the colored porter in the barber shop smokes fifteen cent cigars. Let none with glib tongue enumerate the venial economic sins of a comparatively small percentage of foolish or deluded wage earners, lest I be tempted to bombard him with a few leading questions that will glaringly reveal his own much more flagrant economic transgressions. The big fact to remember is that the earnings of a majority of wage earners and lower salaried men and women, are insufficient The American Standard of Living 213 to enable them and their families to live in decent comfort. No dust throwing tactics can obscure this fact. Eighty per¬ cent of the workers’ families, according to the 1910 statis¬ tics, had an income of $1200 or less a year—an amount, considering prices of living goods—clothes, food, rent, etc., that fell below even the subsistence level. In 1920 the eighty percent of the workers’ families may have had an average income of $1500 or $1600, but they were in no wise economically better off, for the increase in the cost of living was greater than the increase in their wages. Changing Living Standards We sometimes hear it said that the condition of the wage earner of today is infinitely superior to that of the laborer of several centuries ago; and that he is enjoying comforts that a few hundred years ago would have been considered luxuries by lords and kings and queens. There may be a measure of truth in this, for we read: “The houses, even of the rich and great, were, in the sixteenth century, mostly destitute of glass windows; and the cottages of the poor were not only universally without them, but also without chimneys! The luxury of a linen shirt was confined to the higher classes. The cloth used by the bulk of the people was mostly of home manufacture; and, compared with what they now make use of, was at once costly, coarse and comfortless. All classes, from the peer to the peasant, were universally without many articles the daily enjoyment of which is now deemed essential even by the poorest individuals.” 6 This, we are told, was the general condition in the six¬ teenth century. By the nineteenth century the condition of the “rich and great” had improved considerabty. But what 'about those who labored for a wage ? The following from the same work throws some light on this phase of our subject: 6 “A Descriptive and Statistical Account of the British Empire,’' by J. R. McCulloch. Vol. II, Chap. V. 214 The New Capitalism “The Rev. Mr. Smith, in his Agricultural Survey of Wigtown and Kirkcudbright, published in 1810, gives, on authority of persons then living, the following details with respect to the state of husbandry, and the condition of the people towards the middle of last century: . . . “ ‘Their houses were commonly wretched dirty hovels, built with stones and mud, thatched with fern and turf; without chimneys; filled with smoke; black with soot; hav¬ ing low doors, and small holes for windows, with wooden shutters, or, in place of these, often stopped with turf, straw, or fragments of old clothes. . . . “ ‘Nothing but the frugal, penurious manner in which the peasantry then lived could have enabled them to subsist and pay any rent whatever. Their clothing was of the coarsest material; their furniture and gardening utensils were often made by themselves; their food always the pro¬ duce of their farms, was little expensive, consisting chiefly of oatmeal, vegetables, and the produce of the dairy; if a little animal food was occasionally added, it was generally the refuse of the flock, unfit to be brought to the market. ’ 1 ’ Living Standards Around 1850 John Stuart Mill, quoting from Mr. Holyoake’s History of the Rochdale (Cooperative) Society, gives a glimpse of the condition of Rochdale working men in the first half of the nineteenth century: ‘ ‘ These crowds of humble working men, who never knew before when they put good food in their mouths, whose every dinner was adulterated, whose shoes let in the water a month too soon, whose waistcoats shone with devil’s dust, and whose wives wore calico that would not wash, now buy in the markets like millionaires, and as far as fineness of food goes, live like lords.” One may criticize the rhetoric of Mr. Holyoake for speak¬ ing of workmen and their families around 1850 buying “like millionaires,” and living “like lords,” but whether or no, that is not the important point, as far as we are The American Standard of Living 215 concerned. That their economic condition was materially improved is certain; the important point is that no thanks was due to their economic overlords; they, the workmen themselves, improved their own condition—raised them¬ selves to a higher level of living, in spite of their Capital¬ istic masters. But if the working classes of England “lived like kings’’ in 1850, they were not “living like kings” in the year of Our Lord 1922. There are today several million unem¬ ployed workers in England who subsist on doles, precisely as did the workers a century ago under the Poor Laws. 7 Does that spell economic progress, or economic retrogres¬ sion? Can the workers of England be said to have gone forward, or to have been hurled back? But if the condition of the wage earners in the United States, or elsewhere, is better than that of the laborers of a century or two ago, no thanks is due to the “rich and great”—to lords or kings or queens, who, history shows, would have preferred to keep those who toil in perpetual bondage. And if the condition of the nobles and aristocrats of today—of lords, kings and queens, is vastly better than the condition of the lords, kings and queens of former times, who deserves the credit? Who invented the thou¬ sand and one things that have added to their comfort? Why, those who toiled for a wage, a meager wage, a bare living wage! Who has a better right to share in comforts than those who created them; who a prior right to the con¬ veniences added to life than those, whose skill and inge¬ nuity called them into existence? A Boast Blasted But is the condition of the wage earner of today so much better'than that of the laborer around 1650, when the labor of husband and wife and two children old enough to work were required to earn enough to enable them to live? 7 In 1910-11 over a million people in Great Britain were in the poorhouse. 216 The New Capitalism Let us see. According to the latest published statistics, Thirteenth Census of the United States, 1910—in 1910 the total number of persons ten years of age and over, engaged in the principal gainful occupations, was 38,167,336, of which 30,091,564 were males and 8,075,772 were females. Of the total number of persons, 10,828,365 were children between the ages of ten and fifteen years of age, divided as follows: boys—5,464,228; girls—5,364,137. This means that more than twenty-five percent of all wage earners are children, an important point to remember, especially when computing the average income per family. It is also well to bear in mind that a steadily increasing number of wage earners are women, and that the wages of women are considerably less than the wages of the male workers; and the average in all cases below what could be called a living wage. It will not be denied that there is a growing number of married women who find it necessary to join in the labor of the husband in order to make the eco¬ nomic ends meet or enable them to keep the ends together. This is particularly true of families residing in the big cities. Fifteen years ago it might have been said that a considerable number of women were entering the ranks of wage earners, not so much driven by any economic necessity but as a matter of choice, merely that they might live in better style and enjoy comforts and pleasures which they could not obtain otherwise—a not unnatural desire. But this is less markedly true today, for the economic pressure has increased tremendously within recent years; and what was once a matter of choice has now become more a matter of necessity. When it becomes necessary in order to maintain a fairly decent living standard, for wife and children to enter the ranks of wage earners, you have taken an economic step back and to the conditions that prevailed two and three hundred years ago. When it is necessary, as it was in 1650, and as it is today, for wife and children to jointly labor to The American Standard of Living 217 earn the amount required for a family to live, no real eco¬ nomic advance has been made; at least there is no great reason to boast, or to prate of “ a higher standard of living. ’ 1 The New Pauperism I think it will not be disputed by anyone that our eco¬ nomic system, as far as those who work for a wage or salary are concerned, is a from hand to mouth system. What the average wage earner receives on Saturday, at most carries him through the week. With regard to most wage earners, and salaried men and women, it would be entirely safe to say that the wages they receive pay not for what they will consume, but for what they have already consumed. So, then, the economic system is even worse than a from hand to mouth system;—it is, more correctly speaking, a debtor system—by virtue of which the wage earner is kept con¬ stantly in arrears, in a state of chronic indebtedness. He consumes before he earns. That, my friends, is poverty of the direst kind. That is the New Pauperism established by the Capitalistic System. From a condition such as this it is only a step to the economic coolieism of China and India, and the peonage of Mexico. It may take a quarter or a half century to complete the job of utterly degrading those who work for a wage; and unless determined opposition not only by organized Labor, but by all those who work for a wage, or its equivalent, in brief by the non-investor group is offered, the Capitalistic program will succeed beyond a doubt. CHAPTER XVIII Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 1 i From the Book of Daniel, Chapter V. (1) Belshazzar the king- made a great feast to a thousand of his lords, and drank wine before the thousand. (2) And being now drunk he commanded that they should bring the vessels of gold and silver which Nebuchadnezzar his father had brought away out of the temple, that was in Jerusalem, and that the king and his nobles, and his wives and his concubines, might drink in them. (3 ) Then they brought the golden vessels that were taken out of the temple of the house of God, which was at Jerusalem, and the king, and his princes, his wives, and his concubines, drank in them. (4) They drank wine, and praised the gods of gold, and of silver, of brass, of iron, of wood, and of stone. (5) In the same hour came forth fingers of a man’s hand, and wrote over against the candlestick upon the plaster of the wall of the king’s palace ; and the king saw the part of the hand that wrote. (25) And this is the writing and that was written. Mane, Tekel, Upharsin. (26) This is the interpretation of the thing: Mane; God hath numbered thy kingdom, and finished it. (27) Tekel; Thou art weighed in the balances, and found wanting. (28) Upharsin; Thy kingdom is divided, and given to the Medes and Persians. S CORES of writers are interpreting the greatly dis¬ turbed conditions in the world today as foreshadowing the doom of civilization. I do not agree with these prophet writers. What is going on throughout the world does not signify the breakdown of civilization. It is either the prelude to the utter collapse of the Capitalistic System, or else a trumpet blast of triumph, heralding its complete success. Long before the war I had written down this sentence in my notebook: “The Capitalistic Entrepreneur System can exist for fifteen or perhaps twenty years. Then one of two things must happen: either it will break down completely; or it will continue to maintain itself by increasing the burdens upon the people; succeeding in which it will grow mightier and more tyrannical with the passing of the years / 1 218 Mane—Tekel—U pharsin 219 My prediction was not merely a guess; it was the answer to a simple problem in arithmetic, as simple as the formula two plus two makes four. In 1913 I believed (and I think I was right)—that the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System was in its death throes. During the first dozen years it maintained itself by the simple process of raising living costs. But since prices of living commodities cannot be raised indefinitely without producing a reaction—for there is a limit beyond which the patient public will not, or more correctly speaking cannot, go; and since the people were beginning to murmur and to think aloud, I concluded that the end of the System was imminent. Only a war of gigantic proportions could save it. And a war came. Making the World Safe for Timocracy Aristotle tells us that there are three political constitu¬ tions: Kingship (or monarchy), aristocracy, and timocracy, which latter “people generally call constitutional govern¬ ment. ” “Of these,” says Aristotle, “timocracy is the worst. ’ ’ Timocracy, he explains, ‘ ‘ recognizes the principle of wealth.” The World War, we were told, was fought to “make the world safe for Democracy.” The war did nothing of the kind. It made the world safe for TIMOCRACY —for the rule of wealth. No historian will ever say, or attempt to show, that the World War of 1914-18 was deliberately planned and provoked by the Capitalistic groups of Europe and the United States working in unison; but the phil¬ osopher and student of history will have no difficulty in¬ showing that the fates have a way of playing right into their hands. The International bankers (among whom the United States bankers are dominant at present) have been and are, the chief beneficiaries of the recent war. The ill wind that fanned the fierce flames of the holocaust, almost destroying the whole civilized world, blew good only to them. For one thing the Capitalistic System was saved from collapse. 220 The New Capitalism Moreover, the well nigh universal misery and wretched¬ ness produced by the war gave it a new lease on life, and a tighter grip on the throat of the world; for, when people are reduced to poverty and beggary, they are docile and submissive. There is a popular belief that hunger makes men desperate. That is a fallacy. Show me a nation where hunger is chronic and starvation stalks, and I’ll show you a nation that is slavish, submissive, docile and unresisting. There is no fight in people weakened by hunger. Far from being desperate they are grateful for the few husks thrust before them as before swine. • The Capitalistic Program But I do not want to pursue this distressingly seductive theme further. I must hurry along. What I have said above was for the purpose of emphasizing what to my way of thinking is the clear intent of the Capitalistic-Mammon- istic group constituting the Capitalistic-Mammonistic Sys¬ tem in the United States—viz., to reduce the people of the United States to a condition of helpless poverty and abject servility. That is the Capitalistic program, and quite a few numbers have already been played. The performance is going well, and with a flourish. Whether I am right or wrong in saying that the war saved the Capitalistic System from disaster, it is clear that since the war the Capitalistic group has acquired an excess of confidence in its impreg¬ nability, and a renewal of faith in its ability, not only to conserve itself perpetually but to strengthen itself still more; and to crush its antagonists. The war and its con¬ sequences seem to have beguiled those constituting the Cap¬ italistic group into the belief that the Capitalistic System they have established, can be made to endure forever. Reaching Out for More Not content with having acquired control and practical ownership of all the profitable properties in the United States—the banks, insurance companies, transportation Mane-—Tekel—U pharsin 221 systems, public utilities, natural resources, raw materials, and leading industries—they are now reaching out to gobble into their maw those properties overlooked, or con¬ sidered of minor importance during the first twenty years of their regnancy. Scores of ‘‘news” items have appeared during the past year clearly indicating what is going on in the Capitalistic mind. A brief excerpt from a single article by a well known financial writer, B. C. Forbes, will suffice to illustrate the point: “Wall Street rumor is busy forming two ambitious steel combinations, a comprehensive coal consolidation, oil mer¬ gers galore, the welding together of various important cop¬ per companies, annexations of automobile plants by larger ones, and other assimilations of similar units by trusts of influential independents. . . . “Moreover, our brainiest financial and industrial giants do not confine their reckonings to the present surplus of productive capacity. They look ahead, and, looking, they foresee the time when America will require vastly greater productive capacity than now exists. “When that time comes—and there is little doubt that it is coming—everything will be right for the flotation of mergers. “If the Washington conference achieves the results Presi¬ dent Harding joyously predicts, the way will be paved for the summoning of international financial leaders to a con¬ ference which may also contrive to evolve workable plans for getting the world back on its feet. ’ ’ 2 The World on Its Bach Read with especial care the last paragraph of the above item. Note the reference to the “international financial leaders,” and who, we are told, may “contrive to evolve workable plans for getting the world back on its feet. ’ ’ To my humble way of thinking the “international financial leaders” (among whom our American Investment bankers 2 Chicago Herald-Examiner, December 13, 1921. 222 The New Capitalism are conspicuous), are laying plans, not so much to get the world back on its feet as to get it on its back, and then to plant their feet on its face. The war has given our former Investment bankers their opportunity to become International bankers; and when the “workable plans” of the ‘‘international financial lead¬ ers” are completed I hold it will be discovered, perhaps too late, that a few thousand individuals are holding the economic destinies of all the peoples of the earth—includ¬ ing the United States—in the hollow of their hand. Euro¬ pean students of economic problems have long ago awak¬ ened to a realization of what is going on the in the Interna¬ tional Capitalistic mind. They speak quite plainly of “the international cooperation of Capitalism”—and boldly de¬ clare that the plan is “to impose new standards of living on the proletariate of Europe.” 3 4 Indeed the economic subjugation of the people of Europe is already accom¬ plished. There remains but to subdue us. The One Hindrance in the Capitalistic Road The only obstacle in the way of the complete success of the plans of the Capitalistic potentates is organized Labor in the United States, and every effort is being made to crush it out of existence. One of the chief weapons,—the scientific employment of which was made possible by the universal havoc produced by the war, against organized Labor, is what is called ‘ ‘ our ’ ’ foreign investments. Ameri¬ can capital is being “invested” by American International “investors,” in immense quantities in European industries, and in sundry enterprises in other foreign lands. Ameri¬ can Capital!—that is to say—the savings of the wage- earners, the non-investors, or the credit based on their sav¬ ings, is being “invested” (God save the mark!) particu- 3 M. Philipps Price in Labor Monthly (February 15, 19-22), a British Magazine of International L*abor. 4 “More than $2,000,000,000 of American capital is now invested in foreign enterprises paying dividends of hundreds of millions of dollars, and the volume of American investment abroad is increasing daily.” Arthur Sears Henning, Chicago Tribune, April 2, 1922. Mr. Henning, it would seem, is ultra- conservative. Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 223 larly in European industries where labor, as everyone knows, is poorly rewarded. And in due time the cheaper product of the poorly paid European labor, financed with the savings of American wage-earners, will be dumped in increasing quantities into the American market in competi¬ tion with the output of American workmen. As a result hundreds of thousands, if not millions, of American work¬ men will be subjected to inconstancy of employment, and their families to the hardships and misery following en¬ forced idleness. Thus a permanently “mobile labor sup¬ ply’’ the great Capitalistic desideratum , will have been created, and from that day forward wage workers in the United States must accept the low wages that Capital offers. Besides, there is no better way of keeping the other millions who are fortunate enough to have jobs, quiet and tractable, than to keep the alternative of losing their jobs dangling constantly before their eyes. The “Lodged and Ancient Grudge” Against Labor Today those who own the nation’s wealth and control the nation’s money and credit, more than ever look upon those who work for a wage as a necessary evil to be en¬ dured only because vast profit accumulations, and the still greater concentration of the nation’s wealth in the hands of a small coterie of Mammonistic Capitalists demands their continued existence. Today organized Capital, more than ever, looks upon organized Labor as ‘ 4 the abomination of abominations ’ ’—as something intolerable and to be utterly destroyed. Indeed the work of destruction which began many years ago has progressed to a point where organized Labor, outmaneu- vered at every turn, finds itself at this very moment des¬ perately hard pressed. The fight between Capital and Labor—(it was never any¬ thing less than a fight; let those who sincerely believe, or insincerely pretend to believe, that Capital and Labor are 224 The New Capitalism more amiably disposed toward each other, hug the delusion to their hearts)—the fight between Capital and Labor is getting fiercer and bitterer. We can indeed say, and quite truly, that Capital and Labor are getting closer together— to each other’s throats; closer to each others hearts, but there is a knife in the hand of each. “Divide and Conquer” Machiavelli ? s notorious work, “The Prince” (published A. D. 1532), is a “scientific account of the art of acquiring and preserving despotic power, and a calm, unvarnished and forcible exposition of the means by which tyranny may be established and maintained.” “Divide and Conquer!” is an old slogan, and the favorite formula of tyrants and despots, of politicians and Mammonistic Capitalists who have learned from centuries of experience that as long as they can keep people from uniting—or better still—quar¬ relling among themselves—thus keeping them divided— they are safe. Capitalism easily surpasses the Machiavellian code in the employment of ingenious tactics. First it divided wage earners into opposing groups—the organized workers and the unorganized workers; and then it subdivided each group into contentious factions. In the case of the unorganized workers in certain important industries, those of foreign birth predominate. The difference of languages keeps them not only apart but in turmoil. Whereas in the organized groups we find greater homogeneity, but bitter antagonism between radicals and conservatives. Besides there are many other elements of disintegration and destruction at work. The Capitalistic Coup d’etat But the greatest achievement of Capitalism is that it has succeeded in inaugurating a nation-wide system of espio¬ nage. Thousands of hireling agents—“under-cover men” or “operatives” they are called, have been hired to mingle with workmen, to win their confidence and then to betray Mane—Tekel—U pharsin 225 them. The information obtained is frequently used to dis¬ criminate against members of unions. This is ‘‘boring from within” with a vengeance. Espionage has been developed into a system, and the results achieved thus far seem to be eminently satisfactory to the Capitalistic group. Through this system of espionage existing labor unions have been disrupted and disorganized. But particularly does it aim to make organization impossible. The supplementary report recently published by the In¬ terchurch World Movement exposes the system and its workings, and shows that it is one of the basest inventions of modern Capitalism. It shows conclusively that “the existence of widespread, well financed, privately incorpo¬ rated spy concerns constitutes an integral part of industrial corporations’ policy of ‘not dealing with labor unions’ ” and that these Capitalistic hireling agents, “under-cover men,” or “operatives,” are “inside the plants, or inside the unions, or outside both, and during the strike (of 1919) spied, secretly denounced, engineered raids and arrests, and incited to riot.” Some of these “spies” working for the Capitalists, get into the labor unions, assume leadership and manage to have themselves elected to important offices. Needless to say, to create dissension within unions, and to discredit labor organizations in the eyes of the public, is one of the big aims of the Capitalistic espionage system. 5 In addition to the organized Capitalistic “Service” Com¬ panies—that is Spy Service placed at the disposal of any Capitalistic employer for a price—some of the larger cor¬ porations maintain a spy system of their own. Mr. Atter- bury, Vice-President of the Pennsylvania lines, testified before the Railroad Labor Board (March 22, 1921) that his railroad “maintained an extensive spy and espionage system among its employees” and that it “had little ars¬ enals at various plants where guns and ammunition were 5 Whoever is interested in this phase of the subject is advised to read “Public Opinion and the Steel Strike of 1919”—the supplementary Report to the Commission of Inquiry, Interchurch World Movement. Published by Harcourt Brace & Co., New York. 226 The New Capitalism kept.” To maintain this “police” system the Pennsyl¬ vania railroad spends $800,000 a year, which, of course, the public pays. The “Open Shop” Campaign For more than twenty years the Capitalistic group has been preparing for the time when with little or no danger to itself it might give the death blow to organized Labor. That time has arrived. The war greatly strengthened the Capitalistic group; while its consequences placed those who work for a wage into an unfavorable position. And Mam- monistic Capitalism came forward with a well thought out plan—a thoroughly organized, a thoroughly systematized campaign, to render organized Labor hors de combat. Needless to say Capitalism did not label its campaign “a campaign to destroy organized Labor”; that would have been crude, and I, who have observed and studied Capi¬ talistic tactics and strategy for-many years, am the last one to accuse the Machiavellian Capitalistic group of crudeness. Not only is the Capitalistic campaign to destroy organized Labor not called by its right name, but it is cleverly dis¬ guised as a pseudo patriotic movement—‘ ‘ A Campaign for the Open Shop—the American Plan,” it is called. And “Citizens” Committees with millions of dollars at their disposal have been formed in strategic places—pledged not to let up in the fight until organized Labor is destroyed root and branch. Superficial students of industrial and economic subjects are under the impression that the campaign for an Open Shop, which in reality is a fight against organized Labor, began towards the end of 1919. They are in error. The fight against the closed shop (more properly speaking, against organized Labor) began on June 17, 1901. Six weeks after the Steel Corporation was organized and began operations, a meeting of the executive committee was held in New York city. But so as not to be accused of misstate¬ ment, or prejudice, let me quote what happened at that Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 227 meeting from the official report of the Congressional Inves¬ tigation of the United States Steel Corporation: Labor Unions “The attitude of the United States Steel Corporation toward organized Labor was early determined. On June 17, 1901, six weeks after the Steel Corporation was organ¬ ized and began operations, a meeting of the executive com¬ mittee was held in New York City. At this meeting Mr. Charles Steele, then a member of the firm of J. P. Morgan & Co., and also a member of the executive committee of the Steel Corporation, was present. The question of the atti¬ tude of the corporation toward organized labor was exten¬ sively discussed at this meeting. As a final result of the deliberations of the executive committee, Mr. Steele brought forward the following proposition, which the records show was finally voted upon, and the president of the Steel Cor¬ poration instructed to convey it to the presidents of the subsidiary companies, to wit: “That we are unalterably opposed to any extension of union labor and advise subsidiary companies to take firm position when these questions come up and say that they are not going to recognize it, that is, any ex¬ tension of unions in mills where they do not now exist; that great care should be taken to prevent trouble, and that they promptly report and confer with this corpo¬ ration. “Following that declaration, the evidence clearly shows how American laborers felt. Justly or unjustly, they con¬ sidered themselves persona non grata in the works of the United States Steel Corporation. Thereafter the great bulk of American union laboring men in the iron and steel in¬ dustry understood that they were not wanted at the works of the United States Steel Corporation. The process of filling the places of these union laborers is interesting and important to observe. American laborers loyal to their 228 The New Capitalism unions could not be had. Something had to be done to get laborers. Southern Europe was appealed to. Hordes of laborers from Southern Europe poured into the United States. They were almost entirely from the agricultural classes, knew absolutely nothing about iron and steel manu¬ facture, but were sufficient to fight the labor unions. They were absolutely unskilled, but they could work, especially as common laborers. In times of special necessity even ad¬ vertisements for foreign help of this class were spread broadcast. A sample of these advertisements, which the evidence shows were caused to be circulated by subsidiary companies of the Steel Corporation, is as follows: “ WANTED.—Sixty tin house men, tinners, catchers, and helpers to work in open shops; Syrians, Poles, and Rouma¬ nians preferred; steady employment and good wages to men willing to work; fare paid and no fees charged for this work. Central Employment Bureau, 628 Pennsylvania Avenue. “This advertisement appeared, as the evidence shows, in the Pittsburgh Gazette-Times of July 14, 1909. (See page 3074 of hearings.) “The result is that about eighty percent of th* unskilled laborers in the steel and iron business are foreigners of this class. With the benefit of a skilled American foreman such a crew can work out results in unskilled labor production. The profits of this system of labor employment go to the Steel Corporation, while the displaced American workman shifted as best he could. “Following the elimination of Union labor, and the in¬ troduction of the above-described foreign laborers, an inves¬ tigation was made as to the conditions of laborers, hours of labor, home life, etc. As to the hours of labor, the evidence before the committee was conclusive that long hours of labor prevailed in the iron and steel industry, especially in the unskilled departments. Under the direction of the United States Commissioner of Labor, a very careful and thorough investigation as to the hours of labor in the steel industry Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 229 has been made. From this official report we quote without comment: “During May, 1910, the period covered by this investi¬ gation into the steel industry, 50,000 persons, or 20 percent of the 153,000 employees of the blast furnaces, steel works, and rolling mills covered by this report, customarily worked seven days per week, and 20 percent of them worked 84 hours or more a week, which, in effect, means a 12 hour working day in the w T eek, including Sunday. ‘ 1 This hardship of 12 hour days and a 7 day week is still further increased by the fact that every w T eek or two weeks, as the case may be, when the employees on the day shift are transferred to the night shift, and vice versa, employees remain on duty without relief either 18 to 24 consecutive hours, according to the practice adopted for the change of shifts. The most common plan to effect this change of shift is to work one shift of employees on the day of change through the entire 24 hours, the succeeding shift working the regular 12 hours when it comes on duty. (See page 2837, hearings.) 11 While we deem it unnecssary to quote the testimony of other witnesses, it is true, as the testimony shows, that they fully corroborate these statements of the United States Commissioner, and, in fact, some of the witnesses are much stronger in their statements. “As to the daily lives and conditions of living of these laborers, the testimony taken is voluminous, far too exten¬ sive to even summarize in this report. The testimony cer¬ tainly shows conditions undesirable, and far below what is ordinarily understood to be the American standard of living among laborers in our country. Some of the details are revolting, both as to sanitary and moral conditions. Taking the ordinary family as a unit, the wages paid, even if the head of the family is constantly employed, are barely enough to provide subsistence. ’ ,e 6 Quotations from United States Steel Corporation Investigation. These living conditions were found to exist among steel workers in the United States Steel Corporation ten years ago. 230 The New Capitalism The American Plan From this excerpt from an official Government report you can judge for yourself what is at the bottom of the Capitalistic “American Plan.” The present campaign for an “American Plan” is but the corollary of that other American plan inaugurated by the United States Steel Cor¬ poration when in its fight upon organized Labor, more than twenty years ago, it began to fill its plants with cheaper European labor, replacing native and naturalized Ameri¬ can citizens with recent arrivals,—immigrants from all parts of Europe. The present “American Plan” is Capi¬ tal^ last desperate charge upon organized Labor. And the hidden design is to reduce all those who labor, whether for a wage or salary, to a condition of perpetual servility and permanent poverty. Dragging Down the Salaried Employees Let none imagine that the Capitalistic System intends merely to degrade the industrial wage earners to a common level. No! The Capitalistic System is thorough; it does nothing by halves. Its campaign to “liquidate labor”— to cut wages below the decent living level—includes the salaried employees. Hundreds of thousands of salaried men and women throughout the United States were dis¬ charged during the slack period, then hired back at a lower salary, or replaced by cheaper help. Items such as the following appeared frequently in the daily press during the past year: “The Pittsburgh Coal Company will make reductions of 15 percent on September 1 in the wages of between 3,000 and 4,000 members of its salaried staff. ’ ’ “A 10 percent pay reduction, effective October 1, is an¬ nounced by the E. I. DuPont de Nemours Company. The cut will affect all salaries from the president down.” 7 7 These items appeared in the Chicago Herald-Examiner. August 31, 1921. Mane—Tekel—U phar sin 231 In an article entitled ‘'The White-Collar Job and the Big Jolt” by James H. Collins, in The Saturday Evening Post (September 3, 1921), a “New York Employment spe¬ cialist ’ ’ is quoted. That gentleman divides the workers into three great groups—: Industrial, Agricultural and Market¬ ing —this latter being composed of those engaged in mer¬ cantile trade, clerical and sales work, etc.—in brief the salaried class. According to this “specialist”: “When re-adjustment comes in the marketing group prices will drop, people will be able to buy more with their wages, and production will gradually be restored.” The “re-adjustment,” of course, has reference to the cutting of salaries. A brief excerpt from Mr. Collins’ article suffices for the present to give point to my statement that the campaign to reduce wages includes salaried employees: ‘ ‘ Reduction of the salaried staffs has proceeded, industry by industry, as different lines of business have been affected by the depression. It began with silks in the spring of 1920, ran into clothing and shoes, spread from manufac¬ turer to jobber, and jobber to retailer, invaded automobiles and farm implements. One industry’s hard times some¬ times made brisk times for another line of business, as with exporting, where cancellations and accumulated goods in foreign ports threw work upon banks and branches abroad. But eventually banking organizations were affected, the peak of employment being reached in that line about last February, when it became necessary to cut bank staffs five to ten percent, letting executives go, along with clerical workers. “Every employment organization, whether semi-public, like the Knights of Columbus and the Young Men’s Chris¬ tian Association, or the purely private business enterprise, reports about the same conditions—more salaried men seek¬ ing work than ever before in their history, ten applicants for every position, and anxious inquiries from unemployed salaried people in other places who imagine that conditions 232 The New Capitalism are better elsewhere, and want to crowd into the already congested cities.’’ Cannot the salaried employees read their doom between the lines ¥ The One Thing Capitalism Cannot Destroy Will the Capitalistic group and System succeed in de¬ stroying organized Labor, and reducing all those who labor to the ranks of serfs? When we consider what the Capi¬ talistic group has already accomplished and that organized Labor’s condition has never been so precarious as at pres¬ ent, one is tempted to answer the question in the affirma¬ tive. But in spite of all the seeming successes, in the face of all the past Capitalistic victories, I ’ll say with all the emphasis I can command, that Mammonistic Capitalism will not suc¬ ceed—that it will not triumph. Why ¥ Because it has over¬ looked a very vital point. I ’ll tell you what I mean. When M. Clemenceau was urged by some of the French deputies to bring about the utter destruction of Germany by dismemberment, Clemenceau answered that to dismem¬ ber Germany would be an easy task, but that there is one thing that he could not hope to succeed in destroying, and this one thing is the unity of spirit of the German people. “There is no unity deeper than the unity of spirit,” he said, “and that unity no human hand can touch. You do not create or destroy unity by diplomacy. It is something that exists in the hearts of men. We love what we love, we hate what we hate. When the moment of peril comes we know what side to take; when the call to battle is heard, we know where to stand. ’ ’ 8 This is a lesson of history that the Bourbon Mammon¬ istic Capitalists have never learned. If, as the wise states¬ man Clemenceau well said, you cannot destroy unity of spirit by diplomacy, history shows that it can much less be destroyed by violence! It is quite possible that Mammon- s The Living Age, July 17, 1920. Mane—Tekel—TJpharsin 233 istic Capitalism will succeed in seriously harassing organ¬ ized Labor for a time. Let us go so far as to say that it will succeed in crushing it entirely, even trampling it un¬ derfoot for a while. But it will be a sorry and brief victory for Mammonistic Capitalism, for out of the trials and tribu¬ lations to which Mammonistic Capitalism is at present sub¬ jecting all those who work for a wage, or salary; out of the smouldering embers of their common resentment, there will arise, phoenix-like, a spirit of unity and solidarity, and a unanimity of action that will break every link in the Capitalistic-Mammonistic chain that binds them. Torn and tortured, bruised and bleeding,—organized and unorgan¬ ized Labor will pick itself up out of the dust and dirt, bind up its wounds and retire long enough to let them heal. Then, its teeth set, its fists clenched, and its face calmly turned toward the future, full panoplied, and accoutered as never before, it will emerge for a bigger and mightier contest than the world has ever seen. It will have learned the secret of its own weakness, which is a disunited front. If those who work for a wage, men and women, organized and unorganized, will learn this one lesson, their tempo¬ rary defeat will turn into a tremendous and lasting victory. The Mammonistic Conquest Throughout these chapters I have used the word CAPI¬ TALISM , not because it accurately described what I have in mind, or existing conditions, but because Capitalism conveys to the popular intelligence more than its superla¬ tive designation MAMMONISM. Mammon was the Syrian god of riches. The rich, the greedy ,the avaricious worshipped at his altar. Capitalistic Mamihonism, or Mammonistic Capitalism as we know it to¬ day, is the sordid greed for wealth; the vulpine hunger for riches; a vulturous appetite for profits, a ravenous craving for emoluments, a fiendish lust for power, and many other things that cannot be described in polite language. 234 The New Capitalism It must be clear to whosoever has carefully followed me thus far, that the Capitalistic-Mammonistic conquest of the people of the United States is well nigh completed. A small group of Mammonists, who are the nucleus of the Capitalistic System—owns the major portion of the na¬ tion’s wealth. Moreover, it practically owns and certainly controls, the banks, the insurance companies, the railroad and transportation systems, the public utilities, the raw materials, natural resources and leading industries. By virtue of its supreme sovereignty it reaps the biggest por¬ tion of the profits derived from the employment of Capital and Labor, in whatever enterprises. I will not particularly emphasize here that the administration of our Government is in a large measure controlled, and its policies dictated, by this small Capitalistic-Mammonistic group; however, it is even so. But I will emphasize that the destinies of thirty million workers, and the fate of sixteen million non-investor families, is entirely in the hands of this small group. Legitimate Capitalism Let none imagine that I am opposed to legitimate Capi¬ talism ; I am not! Capital is essential to progress, to life. Capital is the prime requisite for business. Without Capi¬ tal the wheels of production cannot function; and the car of commerce cannot move. No sane man can have any quarrel with legitimate Capital, nor take exception to any of its legitimate functions, nor begrudge it a fair reward. But when Capital ceases its legitimate operations, and transcends the respectable limits of decency; when it be¬ comes a name for greed and a synonym for cupidity and injustice; when the whole concern of those who employ it is the quick accumulation of riches regardless of the methods used, regardless of the means employed, no mat¬ ter whom it injures or whom it hurts, then it reveals itself as the monster of Capitalistic Mammonism, and quite natur¬ ally we may expect some more or less audible protests from its victims. The Capitalism of which I speak in this book Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 235 is the Mammonistic variety. Capitalism with the rabies. It is Capitalistic Mammonism, not Capitalism, that must be destroyed. My Argument Summarized Let it be understood that I have never, and do not now, advocate what is sometimes spoken of as an equal division of property, or of wealth. Against both of these proposals I set my face. I uphold the principle of the doctrine of property rights; but I strongly protest against the concen¬ tration of all the productive, profitable properties in the hands of a few. I will at all times defend the right of the individual to hold property, but I favor an economic con¬ dition under which the right to have and to hold property will be enjoyed by a greater number. In brief I summarize my argument into the advocacy of an economic system under which those who work for a wage will participate in the usufruct of their labor, and which participation automatically gives them an oppor¬ tunity to save a part of their wages, and invest same in the enterprises which their labor makes possible, and their patronage profitable. If simple justice is extended to those who labor for a wage, Mammonism will come to an end, and never more lift its ugly monster head upon the earth. “The Established Order” There are those who speak of the “established Order” as if it were something holy, fashioned by the hand of God Himself, and for the exclusive benefit of a few. There is no such thing as an established Order. From the beginning of the world the “established” Order has changed, pro¬ gressively—generally gradually, but sometimes suddenly. Thus the Order, that can be said to have been the estab¬ lished Order from 1850 to 1900, came to an abrupt end the day the United States Steel Corporation was organized; and by that act a new Order was created almost over night. But this new Order , i ‘ conceived in sin and brought forth in 236 The New Capitalism iniquity”—is now old and decrepit and disreputable. Nay, it has ceased to be Order at all; it is ‘ 1 the established Dis¬ order. ” But whether you call it Order or Disorder, it is no longer acceptable to a majority of the people. Surely there is none so bold as to say that it is the duty of the people to support an Order under w T hich all the wealth and all the profits flow through myriad streams into the coffers of a few hundred or thousand Capitalistic Mammonists. It is not the duty of the people to support and make permanent an Order under which they are gradually being reduced to economic serfdom. Nay, it is their duty to change the Order under the tyranny of which they are slowly being forced into a condition of poverty and slavery. A Bird’s Eye View If any one doubts the sinister design of the Capitalistic Mammonists to reduce the wage earners of the nation to servility and economic serfdom, let him consider at least a few of the things they have imposed upon us: They have depreciated the wage dollar—reduced the pur¬ chasing power of money; They are compelling us to pay approximately four dol¬ lars for what formerly cost one dollar; They have given us the High Cost of Living; They have compelled us to lower our standard of living, •—doubling our rents, and prices of foods, wearing ap¬ parel, etc.; They have succeeded in establishing conditions by virtue of which the income of an average family will be insuffi¬ cient to live in decency and comfort; besides compelling an increasing number of women and children to enter the ranks of wage earners; They have cut wages and salaries to a point that will make it well nigh impossible for a wage earner to lay aside even a small surplus (savings) ; Within recent years they have put millions of men and women to the necessity of consuming what little surplus Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 237 they may have managed to save, by dint of thrift and sac¬ rifice, in those better times before the Capitalist c-Mam- monistic System was fully developed. They have foisted upon us a system of from hand to mouth existence; Thanks to them the average wage earner—the average family—is constantly a week or month, or several weeks or several months, in arrears; for the wages or salary they receive pay not for what they are going to consume, but for what they have consumed—and that is Pauperism of the direst kind. But why lengthen the list of Capitalistic-Mammonistic achievements, when a single sentence tells the story. The Capitalistic Mammonists have pressed us into the dust. Can they keep us there ? They can! unless we break their stranglehold. And I say it can be broken! It must be broken! It will be broken! A Strong Cup of Coffee Senator Atlee Pomerene, in an address before the Ohio State Bankers Association, Cleveland, Ohio, discussed the economic problems of the day. 9 * He concluded by saying that he had received many let¬ ters from his constituents, but one of them, he said, gave the cause of the disturbed conditions more tersely and more forcefully than all the rest. He said the explanation of present conditions is “the country is getting over a big drunk.” “I am afraid,’’ continued Senator Pomerene, 11 he told the truth. Whether we are of the employer or employee class, whether we belong to the idle rich or to those who are objects of charity, let us all take a strong cup of coffee, sober up and work and save. It will clear our vision. It will help solve the problems that confront us.” With all due respect to Senator Pomerene, who, I believe, is a well intentioned man—though a mighty poor economist 9 See Congressional Record, July 15, 1921, p. 4007. Needless to say Senator Pomerene discussed his subject from the Capitalistic, not from the non-investor’s standpoint. 238 The New Capitalism —this is the sort of economic nonsense one encounters fre¬ quently in these days. No! the country is not just ‘ ‘ getting over a big drunk.” The country has been on a bestial de¬ bauch for more than twenty years, and is at present suffer¬ ing from the consequences of its vile excesses and shameful immoralities practiced for nearly a quarter of a century. A more drastic specific than a “strong cup of coffee” is needed. In fact there is no cure known to science for what ails the patient. The corruption has progressed too far; it has reached the final stage. Trouble With a Cup of Coffee But apropos of Senator Pomerene’s “strong cup of cof¬ fee.” I wonder whether he has ever read that amusing book called “The Peterkin Papers”! I read it when I was still in my teens. The very first paper is entitled ‘ ‘ Trouble with a Cup of Coffee. ’ ’ Mrs. Peterkin had just prepared a cup of delicious coffee, but absent-mindedly had put salt into it instead of sugar. She called her family together and explained the difficulty, and asked their advice. Agamemnon, just home from college, suggested that they call in the chemist, a most learned man. They go to him and state their errand, prom¬ ising to pay him in gold. He agrees to go with them. Into the cup of coffee the chemist puts a half hundred different kinds of chemicals. Still the coffee is not fit to drink. They pay him for his trouble, and he departs. Again the disturbed Peterkins hold council, and they decide to call in the herb-woman. She agrees to try her skill. Into the spoiled cup of coffee she puts tansy, penny¬ royal, caraway seed, spearmint, cloves, sweet marjoram, basil and rosemary, wild thyme, catnip, valerian and hops. But still the coffee wasn’t fit to drink. She decides that it’s bewitched, and goes home. In desperation the Peterkins decide to ask the Lady from Philadelphia, a most wise woman. She suggests that they Mane—Tekel—Upharsin 239 throw out the cup of doctored coffee and make a fresh one. Delighted, they decide to do so. And the moral of this tale is that salt and chemicals and herbs have been stirred, for nearly a quarter of a century, into the economic coffee—myrrh—which we are supposed to drink—not absent-mindedly but deliberately and with malice aforethought, by Capitalistic cooks with evil designs upon our economic health and social well-being. We mean to throw out the cup of coffee with salt, and chemicals and herbs in it, and henceforth do our own brewing, according to our own formula. Scrambled Eggs Since Senator Pomerene’s homely remedy has brought us into the vicinity of the kitchen. I recall a pertinent question asked by the most illustrious of all Capital] stic-Mammonis- tic chefs, J. Pierpont Morgan, a few years before his death. He admitted that things were pretty badly mixed up, but complacently dismissed the whole subject with the query: ‘ ‘ Can you unscramble eggs ? ’ ’ No! we can’t unscramble eggs, but we can fire the cook whose sole culinary ability consists in scrambling eggs. The country is sick of the continuous, exclusive and excessive diet of scrambled eggs that has been forced down its un¬ willing throat into its rebellious stomach. Nor is the situa¬ tion improved by the discovery that the scrambled eggs with which the country has been fed for the last quarter of a century, were rotten eggs. The terrible grip of Mammonistic Capitalism must be broken. Carthago est delenda, cried Cato; and Carthage was destroyed. The god Mammon must be dethroned; Moloch must be toppled over. “Impossible!” “Impossible!” a hundred thousand, perhaps a million, or several million, voices will cry in unison. But read the 240 The New Capitalism following from Carlyle’s essay on “Chartism,” from the chapter entitled ‘ ‘ Impossible! ’ ’ ‘ ‘ ‘ But what are we to do ? ’ ” exclaims the practical man, impatiently on every side: “ ‘ Descend from speculation and the safe pulpit, down into the rough market-place, and say what can be done!’ ”—0, practical man, there seem very many things which practice and true manlike effort, in Par¬ liament and out of it, might actually avail to do. But the first of all things, as already said, is to gird thyself up for actual doing; to know that thou actually either must do, or, as the Irish say, “come out of that.” “It is not a lucky word, this same impossible; no good comes of those that have it so often in their mouth. Who is he that says always, There is a lion in the way? Slug¬ gard, thou must slay the lion, then; the way has to be travelled! . . . “It was proved by fluxionary calculus, that steamships could never get across from the farthest point of Ireland to the nearest of Newfoundland; impelling force, resisting force, maximum here, minimum there; by law of Nature, and geometric demonstration:—what could be done ? The Great Western could weigh anchor from Bristol Port; that could be done. The Great Western, bounding safe through the gullets of the Hudson, threw her cable out on the cap¬ stan of New York, and left our still moist paper-demonstra¬ tion to dry itself at leisure. ‘Impossible!’ cried Mirabeau to hi s secretary. ‘ Ne me dites jamais ce bete de mot, N$vtt xame to me that blockhead of a word! ’ “To the practical man, therefore, we will repeat that he kas, as the first thing he can ‘do,’ to gird himself up for actual doing; to know well that he is either there to do, or not there at all. Once rightly girded up, how many things will present themselves as doable which now are not at- temptable! ’ ’ 10 10 “Chartism/' by Thomas Carlyle, Chapter X. 241 Mane—Tekel—Upharsin The Servile State Hilaire Belloc, in his most interesting book, ‘ ‘ The Servile State, ” graphically describes how by the middle of the seventeenth century a dominant few had established them¬ selves as the overlords of creation. He speaks of it as “the new wealth”—“with all the realities of power in the hands of a small, powerful class of wealthy men, the King still surrounded by the fancies and traditions of his old power, but in practice a salaried puppet. And in that social world which underlies all political appearances, the great domi¬ nating note was that a few wealthy families had got hold of the bulk of the means of production in England, while the same families exercised all local administrative power and were, moreover, the Judges, the High Executives, the Church and the generals. They quite overshadowed what was left of central government in this country. J 9 “By 1700,” continues Mr. Belloc, “half of the English were dispossessed of capital and land. Not one man in two, even if you reckon the very small owners, inhabited a home of which he was the secure possessor, or tilled land from which he could not be turned off. . . . England had already become Capitalistic. She had already permitted a vast section of her population to become proletarian, and it is this, and not the so-called “Industrial Revolution,” a later thing, which accounts for the terrible social condi¬ tion in which we find ourselves today. . . . “In an England thus already cursed with a very large proletariat class, and in an England already directed by a dominating Capitalist class, possessing the means of pro¬ duction, there came a great industrial development. “Had that industrial development come upon a people economically free, it would have taken a cooperative form. Coming as it did upon a people which had already lost its economic freedom, it took at its very origin a Capitalistic form, and this form it has retained, expanded, and per¬ fected throughout two hundred years. 242 The New Capitalism “It was in England that the Industrial System arose. It was in England that all its traditions and habits were formed; and because the England in which it arose was already a Capitalistic England, modern Industrialism, wherever you see it at work today, having spread from England, has proceeded upon the Capitalistic model. ’ ’ Etc. The Challenge to Mammonistic Capitalism Mr. Belloc’s book from which I quoted the foregoing, contains many other passages which w r ould throw T consid¬ erable light on our own economic affairs. But we must con¬ tent ourselves for the present to merely emphasize what he so admirably discloses, that the desperate economic con¬ dition of the world, including, of course, the United States, can be directly traced to the dominant ascendancy and supreme sovereignty of Mammonistic Capitalism which began its operations several centuries ago, and has con¬ tinued its deadly work with almost scientific fiendishness until today the whole world is, economically speaking, being throttled to death. The immediate question that presses for an immediate answer in the United States (as well as elsewhere), is: Shall Mammonistic Capitalism be permitted to tighten its stranglehold upon the throats of the people—upon the throats of those who -work for a wage—who constitute the non-investor group; or shall it be compelled to release its throttling death grip? To merely content ourselves with giving a stentorian answer is not enough. Valiant action must accompany our words. Great deeds must be performed, such as will bring the Capitalistic-Mammonistic group to its senses, if not to its knees; and the non-investors—those who work for a wage or salary, or the equivalent, into their rightful heri¬ tage. To point THE WAY is the purpose of the Second Part of this book. PART II THE NEW ORDER This world, ’tis true, was made for Caesar, But for Brutus, too . CHAPTER XIX “Where There’s a Will ? J W HEN one begins to look under the surface of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System—a System which takes into consideration only the welfare of a com¬ paratively small group of individuals, and entirely ignores the interests of the non-investor portion of the pub¬ lic, one wonders why the eighty million non-investors have never made any serious attempt to organize for their own protection. I do not mean in a social or political way; (the one is impossible; the other unnecessary and undesirable, at least for the present) I mean in a purely economic way; I mean to protect themselves and their families from further exploitation, and save themselves from the permanent poverty into which they are slowly, but none the less surely, drifting. If ever there was a reason for the non-investor group to seriously consider such a step, that reason exists today as never before. If ever the neces¬ sity for self-protection existed, it is urgent today. What the non-investors have lacked to date is leadership, and a rational, workable program. No one has ever showed them the way, nor pointed out how their economic freedom might be won. The purpose of this book is to show them the way; let us hope that the leaders will arise among them in dwe time. The fundamental weakness of all economic remedies thus far proposed, is that they call for group action and strive only for group benefits; whereas what the world needs today is a program that calls for mass action, the net result of which will yield mass benefits. There are eighty million men and women who constitute the non-investor group. Of this number approximately thirty million are « 245 246 The New Capitalism engaged in gainful occupations, that is, working for a wage or salary, or for a recompense the equivalent of a wage or salary. These thirty million men and women workers (Oh, yes, there are children included in the number, millions of them, more’s the pity and greater the shame—children who ought to be in school), represent a tremendous power—a power that is now going to waste because unorganized. I call upon them to constitute themselves into a unified group. I exhort them to combine their scattered strength into a formidable power. I urge them to organize themselves into an economic unit, which for the purpose of this book I shall call THE NEW ORDER. The Will to Do Have they the will to do it? That is where the people are weak. Generations of buffeting have weakened their wills, and created a state of mind that has robbed them of all initiative—and even of the courage to try. Keeping their nose to the grindstone has dulled their vision and ruined whatever of keen far-sightedness they may once have possessed. The vital energies of their natures have been drained by the struggle for existence. So long have they stood in open-mouthed wonder at the supposed omnipo¬ tence of the organized few that they have lost all conscious¬ ness of their own strength. Compelled to wrestle with the little, vexatious problems of their daily lives, they have not dared to dream, much less venture to attempt the solution, of the one supreme problem—their economic independence and their social well being. Driven, and accustomed to being driven, they have never allowed themselves to think of ever being Masters of their own lives, Masters of their own fortunes, Masters of their own destinies;—Captains of their own finances, Captains of their own industry, Cap¬ tains of their own souls. “A House Divided Against Itself” I have said that we have no caste system in the United States; but we have something that is unspeakably worse. “Where There’s a Will” 247 There is no homogeneity among us. We are split into warring camps and quarreling groups, opposing parties and fighting factions, along political, social, racial, religious and economic lines. There is not a single question on which we are united; not a single issue on which we present a solid front. And when I speak of we I mean particularly the eighty percent composed of wage earners, and salaried men and women, constituting the non-investor group. Indeed if my plan contemplated organizing a national association of the eighty million non-investor population now scat¬ tered and disorganized throughout the forty-eight states, I would despair, or at least be tempted to set it down as an unaccomplish able plan. But the thing that makes such an association not only possible but already a partially accom¬ plished fact, is the actual existence of the nucleus of the New Order, the one power which thus far has saved us from sconomic serfdom and through which alone society can be re-created. The machinery through which a struggling humanity can redeem itself is in running order. Organized Labor—the Niocleas of the New Order It is not accurate to say that the eighty million non¬ investors are entirely unorganized. A part of the non-in¬ vestor group is organized. I refer to that portion of the eighty million known as organized Labor, or wage earners —not all of the wage earners but a considerable number. According to the statistics there are in the United States approximately thirty million wage earners and salaried men and women. Of these it is reported that six or seven mil¬ lion are more or less thoroughly organized. The most pow¬ erful Labor organization, and the one having the largest membership, is the American Federation of Labor, to which about four million of wage earners belong. Then there are independent Labor organizations, brotherhoods, or unions, and amalgamations of workers in specified industries. All told the total membership in Labor organizations is approxi¬ mately seven and a half million. In other words, about one-fourth of the wage earners are organized. It matters 248 The New Capitalism little as to their precise number; the stress is to be laid entirely on the fact that they are organized, imperfectly, and not ideally, perhaps, but organized, therefore the nucleus of a greater organization. ‘ ‘ Aye, there’s the nib! ’ 1 Even though organized Labor numbered only a million members I would still say that the nucleus of the New Order is in existence today, and able to carry out all the plans I have in mind with regard to the NEW CAPITALISM. Around this nucleus, it is reasonable to suppose that, while it will not be easy in the beginning, yet with per¬ sistent effort it will be possible to gather the active support and cooperation of a fair percentage of men and women engaged in gainful occupations who do not belong to any Labor organization, and who have no affiliation whatever with organized Labor; for, let me make myself entirely clear—the New Order is not to be composed exclusively of those who are members of Labor organizations, but is to include anyone desirous of lending a helping hand in the work of improving economic conditions—of making people happier, the world a better place to live in, and life more enjoyable. No one will be barred, whatever his rank or station in life may be. Wage earner and salaried person; property owner or tenant; lawyer, physician, druggist, dentist, farmer, shop-keeper, or to whatever occupational group each may belong, is eligible to membership. A Call to Organized Labor But while I have in mind the organization of the non- investor portion of the population, eighty million men and women—sixteen million families—I realize that such an •rganization is well nigh impossible save through the agency of organized Labor. Organized Labor is to be the nucleus Of the greater organization that will shape itself by degrees and in due time. Organized Labor has the power, if it will but effectively and intelligently use it, to break the back¬ bone of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. The Capital¬ istic Entrepreneur group is not afraid of Labor as at pres¬ ent organized, or rather disorganized; it does not stand in “Where There’s a Will” 249 dread of its power. Indeed the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group has rather successfully undermined Labor’s might. It has divided those who labor into opposing camps; it has corrupted individuals and disrupted groups; and at this very moment, is engaged in dealing death blows to all organ¬ ized Labor. Organized Labor should need no call from me to save itself. For its own sake, then, I cry out to organ¬ ized Labor, or what is left of it—save yourselves—and save the nation. Your death means the nation’s death! Rouse yourselves. Act today; tomorrow it may be too late. I do not know whether organized Labor or any organized Labor groups will heed my cry or act upon my suggestion, but at any rate I shall indulge in that assumption in this chapter. I will delude myself into the belief that at least five million wage earners are willing to make an effort to win economic freedom for themselves, their families, and all those not an integral part of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System—for the sixteen million non-investor families. The organization of five million wage earners into one compact body is the first step. For the purpose of this book, and so as to make myself plain, and more easily under¬ stood, I am going to imagine the actual existence of the New Order, with a membership of five million members, drawn entirely from the ranks of organized Labor. For truth to tell, unless organized Labor sees the wisdom, or the possi¬ bilities, of my plan, and decides to take a hand, there is little hope for the non-investors. Things will go on as they are, nay, go from bad to worse, until the final crash comes. Very well, then! Here we are, five million strong—all wage earners—organized, consolidated and co-ordinated under the New Order. What is our program? What steps will we take; how will we proceed? The Sustaining Props of Capitalistic Supremacy In the first part of my book I have endeavored to show the dominant position of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs; and the tyranny of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. I do not consider it necessary to summarize all the points I 250 The New Capitalism have scored against the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group and System, preferring to believe that at least some of the things I have written have made an impression and are still remembered by the readers. It will suffice to remind the readers that the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group is com¬ posed of a small number; I care not whether you make it four hundred, or four thousand, or four hundred thousand, or four million. This compact, powerful group owns and controls practically all the “wealth’’ producing properties in the United States. Not content with that it has, through the device of overcapitalization, inflated the na¬ tional wealth by one hundred billion; against which it has issued immense quantities of “securities.’’ On the inflated wealth, the people are compelled to pay taxes, rents, divi¬ dends and interest. Moreover the giant Capitalistic Entre¬ preneurs have a monopoly of the nation’s finances, con¬ trolling absolutely, money and credits through their system of banks. They have moreover a monopoly of all natural resources, raw materials and the leading industries, trans¬ portation systems, public utilities, etc. All these monopolies and controls are made possible to the Capitalistic group first by its control of Capital; and second by its control of Labor. If this double control can be broken the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System will col¬ lapse and sink into the mire of its own rottenness; and the people—the wage earners, the non-investors—will come into their own. The Basic Capital Fund In the light of all I have said let me ask: How did the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs build up their power? By the autocratic use of capital and credit. Whose capital? Our capital, for, the Basic Capital Fund of the nation is the property of the eleven million savings depositors, most of them, it will be admitted, belonging to the non-investor' group. Indeed it may be well to remind the readers that these eleven million savings depositors have on deposit an “Where There’s a Will” 251 amount greater than the amount of money in circulation. On July 1, 1920, the total amount of money in circulation was $6,087,555,007; on the same date the 11,427,555 savings depositors had a total of $6,536,596,000 in the savings banks of the United States— in other words, a half billion dollars more than money in circulation. The savings of the eleven million savings depositors con¬ stitute the nation’s working capital. More accurately speaking, the eleven million savings depositors have placed their aggregate savings into the hands of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group, which this group is using over and over in its various enterprises—monopolizing materials and industries, controlling markets, fixing prices—in brief, strengthening and enlarging the power of the Capitalistic System. Savings Bank Philosophy The savings depositors receive three, or let us liberally say four percent per annum for their savings. The average amount of savings per depositor is, let us say $500. Con¬ sequently the average savings depositor receives as a reward for leaving his money on deposit in Capitalistic banks for twelve months, $20.00. Oh, does he? Not much! for, every dollar he leaves on deposit is used in the aggregate, by an average of five different individuals or corporations, each paying an average rate of let us say, five percent, to the bank for its use. Every person or corporation using this money and paying interest thereon, charges it up to cost of production—that is, adds it to the price of the commodi¬ ties produced— and the total amount of interest is collected from those who purchase the commodities. The savings depositor receives $20.00 a year as interest on his sav¬ ings; in reality he is penalized three or four times the amount he receives as interest, by those who use his money. There is something tragically funny about the fact that the savings of the w T age earners, are the basic working capital of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group and the bul¬ wark of the Capitalistic System. It is by the astute and 252 The New Capitalism unscrupulous use of the savings of eleven million non¬ investors of the working group that a comparatively small group of men have been enabled to take possession of prac¬ tically all the properties in the United States, making xabu- lous profits; increasing their wealth enormously, and build¬ ing up vast fortunes. It would be amusing, were it not so tragic, to reflect that the Capitalistic group is at this very moment using the savings of the eleven million non-investor depositors to reduce them to a condition of abject servility, permanent poverty, and hopeless dependence. Capital Needs the Worker’s Savings Labor is dependent upon Capital, scream the economists; but I say that Capital is dependent not only upon Labor, but upon the very savings of the wage earners. It is easy to see that if the eleven and a half million savings deposi¬ tors each kept his or her money (which, you will admit, is their undisputed right) in a sock instead of depositing it in the savings banks (which banks are a vital part of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System) the country, to say the least, would be in a quandary. Plainly speaking, it cannot be denied that the savings of the eleven and a half million depositors (mostly non-investors) are not only the nation’s basic working capital fund, but the nation’s credit and com¬ mercial system is entirely based upon its constant circu¬ lation. In his book, “Highways of Progress,” 1 James J. Hill says: * ‘ Of the nearly $4,000,000,000 of deposits in the savings banks of this country, the bulk consists of the savings of labor; and this represents but a portion of its accumula¬ tions. With such resources, the workingmen of the coun¬ try might, if they chose, practically control a large part of its industry within a few years. From every point of view, the workingman, representing the greatest number whose i Published 1912, Doubleday Page & Co. 41 ‘Where There’s a Will” 253 good a sound industrial order must seek, appears to be in the world of wealth production. ’ ’ If Labor is dependent upon Capital, I’ll say that the Basic Capital Fund belongs to Labor, and it is only neces¬ sary for Labor to learn how to use this basic fund for its own and all the people’s benefit. Ye eleven million depositors in savings banks—arouse yourselves! Ye unorganized non-investors—pinch your- f selves! Ye are asleep. Ye do not know what is being done; ye are unconscious of the plan that is being put into execu¬ tion this very moment. Yours are still the six billion dollars basic capital; they will not be yours ten or twenty years hence if you do not bestir yourselves, for through a less wage and a greater increase in the cost of commodities you will be compelled gradually to withdraw your savings merely to meet your current living expenses. I beseech you, do not let the Capitalistic group transfer the six billion dollars now deposited to your credit, to its credit, via the medium of lower wages and higher living expenses. I have no hesitancy in saying that the conspiracy is on to bring this ■condition about. If the Capitalistic group can succeed in its iniquitous design your last vestige of hope will be gone. The Wage Earners Can Control Capital Now what we propose to do is gradually to take control of this Basic Capital Fund (indisputably the property of non-investors) away from the small group of Capitalistic Entrepreneurs and place it under control of the New Order. We do not intend to disturb the existing funds. We will, for the present, leave them where they are. But all new savings, from now on, will be placed into a Central Treas¬ ury, or designated banks organized by the New Order, and whose officers will be authorized henceforth to confine the employment of our savings solely for the best interests of the wage earners and the public, and not, as at present, permit them to be used by and for the sole benefit of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. 254 The New Capitalism Do not get impatient! I haven’t begun to open the door; I haven’t even put the key in the lock. The splendors concealed within the palace will be fully revealed to you in due time! I am striving to make my plan perfectly clear to every man and woman of even ordinary intelligence. That is why I am throwing rhetoric to the winds, and language out of the window. I am not attempting to write a literary masterpiece. I have a message for the people, not only for the eighty percent of our population but for everyone who cares to read. If occasionally I falter in the delivery it is because I realize that my audience is not accustomed to me, and perhaps incredulous, and some even suspicious. If I digress once in a while it is to give them time to think over something I have just said. If I hesi¬ tate a moment it is not for lack of something to say, but because I do not want to overwhelm them with my own enthusiasm. Creating a Capital Fund Under the New Capitalism Capital is the prime requisite for any undertaking—it is the sine qua non for whatever plans we may have in mind. The creation of Capital funds, therefore, is the first and most important concern of the New Order In brief, if five million persons (members of the New Order—and at the same time members of organized Labor) were to agree to pay into a certain bank, or banks, which they entirely con¬ trol—or shall I say for the present—into a Central Treas¬ ury, five dollars a month, for a period of three years, none of which is to be used for other purposes than may be designated by the Supreme officials of the New Order, it is easy to see that this would give us a Basic Capital Fund of $300,000,000 the first year; $600,000,000 at the end of the second year; and in three years $900,000,000—an amount which I deem sufficient to completely break not only the Capitalistic Entrepreneur stranglehold, but the backbone of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System of tyr- “Where There’s a Will” 255 anny and oppression. In ten years, by this simple method, three billion dollars would be raised. But I am getting ahead of my story. Let me put it this way: Each of the five million wage earners is to pledge him¬ self to pay into a Central Treasury a total of $180 within three years; or $60 a year at the rate of $5 a month. This is about seventeen cents a day. The Signers of the Declara¬ tion of Independence pledged their lives, their fortunes, and their sacred honor to win political independence for the nation. It remains to be seen whether five million wage earners can be found who are willing to pledge themselves to pay seventeen cents a day for a period of three years, to win economic independence for themselves, their families, and all the people of the nation. The United States Gov¬ ernment, or rather the people, spent about four billion dollars to emancipate a few million negro slaves. It re¬ mains to be seen whether five million wage earners can be found who are willing to invest $60 a year for a period of three years to emancipate themselves, their families, and the whole nation from a more galling yoke of economic slavery. Can it be Bone V It goes without saying that the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group will wisely shake its head in unison, and smile while saying: “It can’t be done.” But in that case “the wish is father to the thought.” The plain truth is, the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneur group does not want to see it done, and hopes that it will not be done. Indeed the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group will, by every possible means at its command, fair and foul, bitterly oppose and viciously attack the New Capitalism; for, if any considerable number of men and women were to subscribe each five dollars a month for a period of say three years—it would mean the doom of the Capitalistic System, of which the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs are today the chief beneficiaries. 256 The New Capitalism If anyone says that it can’t be done, I ask: 14 Why can’t it be done?” For one thing the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group has seen to it that the average man and woman who works, shall receive no greater wage or salary than is ab¬ solutely necessary to subsist. Yet, in spite of this fact, eleven million of them have saved, probably most of them by denying themselves many little comforts and pleasures, six billion dollars, which they have put into the savings banks of the United States. This alone, for one thing, shows what can be done when there is the will to do it. One Way of Doing It But to convince the doubting Thomases, and merely to show what the non-investor group can do, once it makes up its mind, suppose I were to counsel or suggest that the eleven million savings depositors, who have deposited to their credit in the savings banks of the United States nearly six billion dollars, withdraw each one half of the amount he or she has on deposit; or that one-half of the savings depositors withdraw each the full amount of his or her deposits to be used as the Basic Capital Fund under the New Capitalism; a fund of three billion dollars would be created thereby. Of course I advise no such thing; in fact I counsel against it: for these two cogent reasons: First , the withdrawal of so large an amount, within a period of six months or a year, would not only seriously cripple but utterly wreck every bank in the United States, ruin practically all, or most of the industries, and bring on a condition approximating chaos. Secondly (and this is what concerns us most), the New Order would not be in any position to advantageously employ so vast a sum for the time being. Therefore, to place at the disposal of the New r Order, funds considerably in excess of all practical requirements, would bring no ma¬ terial benefits to the owners of said funds. For all imme¬ diate and essential purposes of the New Order during the “Where There’s a Will” 257 first three years, an amount not to exceed $300,000,000 a year will be entirely ample. My counsel to all, who, after reading this book, see the advantage and manifold benefits to be derived from the New Capitalism, is to leave their deposits in savings banks intact for the present, or at least not to draw therefrom more than five dollars a month, or a total of sixty dollars in twelve months—and to do that only in case they find it impossible to save the requisite amount from their present earnings, or spare it from whatever funds they may have in hand, or immediately available. The Proof of the Wage Earner’s Ability But the greatest proof of what the people can do, if there is real need or inspiration to do it, is to be found in what they did during the war. Ten million men and women— most of them wage earners, belonging to the non-investor group—bought twenty billion dollars worth of Liberty bonds. Beyond a doubt wage earners purchased several billion dollars worth, paying for them, if not spot cash, at least within a few months from date of purchase. In view of which fact, will anyone say that it is unthinkable that five million men and women could or would invest , for their own purposes and benefit, five dollars a month for a period of three years? Another Positive Proof As another proof of what can be done I point to the increases in rents during the past three years. Rents throughout the United States have been increased from fifty to one hundred percent. The point is that the people have paid, and are today paying, the increased rental. (And'by the way—quite parenthetically—if the New Order had been in existence and in operation five or six years ago, landlords could not have raised rents, and would not have dared to demand the outrageous increases they did exact and are at present exacting from the people. We would 258 The New Capitalism have opposed our united strength to their outrageous pro¬ cedure. And I wish to go on record today as saying that if the New Order comes into existence, and the New Capi¬ talism begins to function—rents will be lowered again to approximately where they were in 1914. We will have the power to compel the landlords to be decent, and we mean to use it.) But taking the rent situation as it stands today—the average tenant family is paying several hundred dollars a year more for the item of rent than formerly. Perhaps to pay their increases in rent they are compelled to make many sacrifices, but somehow they manage to pay it. Which only proves what can be done. As Seen From Another Angle The evidence of the people’s ability to provide funds for whatever purpose, is accumulating. On March 18, 1921, P. P. Claxton, National Commissioner of Education, in a formal statement made for the purpose of showing that the people of the United States spent more money for luxuries than for education, published a compilation of comparative statistics. In the course of his statement Mr. Claxton said: “According to Government returns for 1920, the people of the United States spent for luxuries in that year $22,700,000,000 ; 2 more than twenty-one times as much as they spent for education only two years before, and $6,000,000,000, or thirty percent more than we have spent for education in all our history. 2 While I doubt that the people spent the enormous s.um of $22,700,- 000,000 in a single year for “luxuries” I will not controvert the Gov¬ ernment’s figures at this time. But I will say that when correlated with the statistics for income, investments, increase in wealth, in capi¬ tal, in savings, in prices and rents, volume of business, wages and salaries and necessary expenditures for the essential living items— that there is a contradiction involved somewhere. Precisely where it is not the purpose of this book to discover. “mere There’s a Will” 259 ‘‘Expenditures for luxuries in 1920 were as follows: For Face Powder, Cosmetics, Perfumes, etc.$ 750,000,000 Furs. 300,000,000 Soft Drinks . 350,000,000 Toilet Soaps. 400,000,000 Cigarettes . 800,000,000 Cigars . 510,000,000 Tobacco and Snuff. 800,000,000 Jewelry . 500,000,000 Musical Instruments . 250,000,000 Luxurious Service. 3,000,000,000 Autos . - . 2,000,000,000 Joy Rides, Pleasure Resorts and Races. 3,000,000,000 Cake and Candy. 350,000,000 Chewing Gum . 50,000,000 Ice Cream . 250,000,000 Food Luxuries . 5,000,000,000 Who can tell what percentage of the aggregate expendi¬ ture for luxuries was made by the four million investors and their families; and what percentage by the wage earn¬ ers—the sixteen million non-investor families? But no matter. Will any one, with these figures before him, dare to assert that if the people of the United States wanted to do it, they could not raise, for the purpose of their economic emancipation, or any other purpose they might have in mind, an amount considerably in excess of that contem¬ plated by my plan? What the Capitalists Think Whatever may be the actual facts as regards the spending proclivity of the general public, it is at least interesting to hear what the opinion is in Capitalistic circles with regard to the saving ability of the wage earners. In an address 3 entitled ‘ ‘ Keal Labor Problems,’ ’ delivered before the Chi¬ cago Association of Commerce, Dr. Charles A. Eaton said: “Where are we to find new resources and capital for working the industries of the country ? We have got to find it. I tell you, gentlemen, that it is right here in the surplus, the savings of the working people of the nation. . . . 3 Published in the Association’s official organ, Chicago Commerce, March 12, 1921. 260 The New Capitalism ‘‘There are billions of dollars a year ordinarily in the savings of workers, and the place for the investment of those savings is in the industries of this nation, not to lay it in a sock, but in the industries of this nation. . . . ‘ ‘ I believe that we could turn into the industries of this country about two billion dollars a year from that one source alone, and every investor so guaranteed and so looked after and cared for and educated, would become a tower of strength against all the revolutionary doctrines of radical¬ ism and stupidities that are sweeping over the world today. There is a great field there.’’ Dr. Eaton’s address seems to have found favor with Chamber of Commerce Associations, under whose auspices he has spoken in other cities. When he asks “Where are we to find new resources and capital,” etc., and says “We have got to find it,” etc., he gives the unpleasant impres¬ sion of being a delegated spokesman for, or a component member of, the Capitalistic group. At any rate his views, as expressed in his address on ‘ ‘ Real Labor Problems ’ ’ are of the conventional type, and the kind that would win approval before audiences composed of members of Cham¬ ber of Commerce Associations. I do not know how much study Dr. Eaton has given to his subject; nor upon what evidence, or statistics, he bases his statement that the work¬ ing people can, or actually do, save two billion dollars a year. But assuming that he is right with regard to the amount —then the raising of less than one-sixth of that amount a year, as contemplated by my plan, would seem to be comparatively easy and simple. Capital Inveigles the Wage Earners But whatever the actual amount of the savings of the wage earners of the United States, as a matter of fact the Capitalistic group has set in motion its machinery gradually to transfer their “savings” from the socks and savings ac¬ counts into the treasuries of the corporations of the Capital¬ istic System, through their schemes of selling stock to their employees on easy payment plans. If the recently published report of the American Telephone and Telegraph Company, “Where There’s a Will” 261 (according to which 128,000 of the 186,342 stockholders of record on December 31, 1921—were employees of the Bell system companies “paying for stock at the rate of a few dollars a month”) can be accepted as an indication of the Capitalistic design, it is quite likely that within a few years there will be more than five million employee stockholders in the various corporations, and their holdings in the aggre¬ gate will run into the billions. It does not seem to occur to the corporation employees who invest a part of their wages in the stocks of the corpo¬ rations by which they happen to be employed, that they are only placing their savings permanently at the disposal of the very group that is exploiting them; and that any divi¬ dends they may derive from stockholdership in such cor¬ porations, will necessarily be paid out of the price increases of the very commodities their labor produces. 4 Capital Proposes My proposal that the wage earners of the United States create their own capital funds is not so novel as it would seem; a suggestion similar to mine was recently made by a prominent New York banker, Mr. Otto H. Kahn: “The Labor Unions in this country claim a membership of 4,500,000. If every member laid aside $1 each week, the available sum at the end of one year would amount to $234,000,000. That is a pretty tidy sum to start business with, in various lines. Personally, I should be glad to see the experiment tried and should welcome its success. The more workingmen come into direct contact with, and acquire direct knowledge of, the realities, the complexities, cares and risks of business conduct, the better it will be.” 5 4 According to the Boston News Bureau there has been a gradual but steady decrease in the number of shareholders in some of the big corporations during 1922 : “The Pennsylvania Railroad reached its record total of stockholders last March, at 141,921 ; and since then there has been a consecutive string of small monthly decreases involving a reduction by September 1, of 4,038 holders. The Steel Corporation total of Common share¬ holders reached its peak last December, at 107,439, since which time there has been a decrease of 11,132.” (Literary Digest, Oct. 28, 1922.) 5 Excerpt from an article “How Shall We Get Back to Better Business,” by Otto H. Kahn, in System Magazine, July, 1921. 262 The New Capitalism As an example of how great minds run in the same chan¬ nel, especially if their owners have their habitat in the Wall Street district, read this from a Commencement ad¬ dress delivered by George E. Roberts, Vice President of the National City Bank of New York: “ There are 2,000,000 railroad employes in the United States now receiving an average of something over $1,500 per year each. If they would save $50.00 per year each, they could buy control of the New York Central Railroad system in the first year, and of all the systems running from Chicago to the Atlantic Coast within five years, at the pres¬ ent market prices of stocks. ’ ’ 6 Whether these suggestions, made almost simultaneously by Messrs. Kahn and Roberts, were offered in good faith or not, they serve the purpose of showing that my proposal to the wage earners and the non-investors is not without merit. The distinctive difference between their proposal and mine is that our savings and our capital funds will be put into our banks, not into their banks, and to be used by us, not by them. That’s the vital difference. Has the Wage Earner Faith in Himself However, it is clear that the Capitalistic group has great faith in the ability of the non-investors to save. It is, there¬ fore, inconceivable that the non-investors themselves should have less confidence in their ability to save, or hesitate to invest their savings for their own benefit, and to their own lasting advantage. If no words of mine can persuade them, let them be animated by what the workers of England and France did for themselves around the ’40s of the last cen¬ tury. In 1844, twenty-eight workman formed a cooperative association, 7 beginning with a capital of twenty-eight 6 “Supremacy of the Economic Law,” Commencement Address at the Iowa State University, June 15, 1920. 7 These cooperative societies steadily increased and multiplied, and today are found everywhere in England ; indeed they can be said to have stood between the English workers and their utter degradation and economic enslavement. Recently published statistics show 4,000,000 members, and their yearly sales amounting to £200,000,000. “Where There’s a Will” 263 pounds. By 1860 the membership had grown to 3450, and their capital to 37,710 pounds. Bastiat in his “Harmonies of Political Economy” (published about 1860) speaking of the Friendly Societies—“powerful and reciprocal associa¬ tion between the working classes ’ ’ says: ‘ ‘ The total number of these associations for the United Kingdom amounts to 33,223, including not less than 3,052,000 individuals—one- half of the adult population of Great Britain. . . . Their revenue is five millions sterling, and their accumulated cap¬ ital amounts to eleven millions and two hundred thousand pounds .’ 1 John Stuart Mill (whose “Principles of Political Econ¬ omy” was published in 1848) in Book IV, Chapter VII, gives an interesting description of the Industrial Work¬ men and Farmers’ Cooperative Association which sprang up in France and England about the middle of the nine¬ teenth century. In France at that time, the wage of four francs a day, or 1200 francs for a three hundred day year, was the best paid. Speaking of the Association in France, Mill says: (p. 360) “The capital of most of the Association was originally confined to the few tools belonging to the founders, and the small means which could be collected from their savings, or which were lent to them by other work-people as poor as themselves. In some cases, however, loans of capital were made to them by the republican government; but the asso¬ ciations which obtained these advances, or at least which obtained them before they had already achieved success, are, it appears, in general by no means the most prosperous. The most striking instances of prosperity are in the case of those who had nothing to rely on but their own slender means and the small loans of fellow workmen, and who lived on bread and water while they devoted the surplus of their gains to the foundation of a capital.” The Will to Do — Or the Alternative Surely what was done by the workmen of England and France seventy-five years ago, under exceedingly adverse 264 The New Capitalism circumstances, can be duplicated by the wage earners of the United States today, where conditions are more favorable. I do not know how many millions, or billions, of dollars a year the thirty odd million men and women workers actu¬ ally save in the aggregate out of their wages; but this I do know, that they can, and that, too, without half trying, save the amount that I consider necessary for the consummation and complete success of their economic emancipation under the New Capitalism. It may necessitate a sacrifice on the part of some, for millions of wage earners have been sub¬ jected to a long period of idleness; some have consumed their scant surplus (savings) while others have been plunged into debt. Indeed, unless the wage earners, the non-investors, act promptly, and make whatever sacrifices are necessary for a year or two or three, to win their economic independence —things will go from bad to worse. The hardships to which they have been subjected during the past year or two will become chronic and irremediable. My plan proposes that 5,000,000 organized wage earners raise a Basic Capital Fund of $300,000,000 a year, for a period of three years. This is about one-twentieth of the amount which, according to such authorities as the Iron Age and the Chicago Journal of Commerce, the wage earn¬ ers lost during 1920-1921 through enforced unemployment. Unless those who work for a wage bestir themselves promptly they will henceforth sustain losses through en¬ forced idleness, aggregating annually billions of dollars. It is up to them to decide whether it is to their best inter¬ ests to save and invest $300,000,000 a year for a period of three years out of their wages, or to sustain a loss of several billions a year on account of idleness or irregular employ¬ ment, for that is the alternative. CHAPTER XX “—Therf/s a Way” THERE there’s a will there’s a way.” I am en- %/%/ deavoring in this book to point the way; the will * ▼ must be developed by those most concerned—by organized Labor. Organized Labor, as yon know, has been having a great deal of trouble with organized Capital, and it must be admitted that thus far organized Capital has had the upper hand. The Capitalistic Entrepreneurs have the whip in their hand, holding it more firmly than ever. At this very hour they are using it with telling effect, not only upon the back of Labor but also upon the backs of all the non-investors. While I am heralding the New Order as theoretically composed of the non-investors, nevertheless I realize that it is Labor—organized Labor—that will have to bear the brunt of the battle. Organized Labor must do the fighting, this time not for itself alone but for the non-investors—the gen¬ eral public as well. The plan I am proposing is Labor’s big opportunity. It is the only chance it has to win, and with the right leadership it will win; not only win but come out of the contest victorious and with flying colors. Today the formula reads: Capital plus Labor Equals Uncontrolled Power. If my plan is adopted the formula henceforth will read: Labor plus Capital Equals Regulated Strength. It is all very well for the economists to say that Capital and Labor are dependent upon each other; that without Capital, Labor cannot function. Less emphasis is placed by them on the indisputable fact that without Labor, Capital must corrode. All the capital in the world cannot make the machinery of Industry move without Labor. But Labor, 265 266 The New Capitalism which is the machinery of Industry, can set itself in motion by the simple expedient of providing its own capital. Cap¬ ital is powerless to supply its own labor; but Labor can supply its own capital. According to the present arrangement all the capital is controlled by one small, organized, coordinated group, while the larger group—Labor—has not yet learned the lesson to organize and coordinate itself. The small, organized, co¬ ordinated group which controls capital, dictates to Labor, while Labor, as long as it is unorganized or only partly organized, and uncoordinated, does not control its own strength, therefore cannot effectually cope with Capital— therefore cannot protect itself. The strongest weapon in the hands of Capital is the helplessness of Labor as a force. Capital is powerful only as long as it can control capital and the forces of labor. Deprived of these advantages, Capital becomes helpless—as helpless as Labor is today. Labor is weak so long as it allows a small group of Capital¬ ists to command its forces and to use its strength. If Labor will venture to employ a little of its own capital it will be not only strong and mighty, but invulnerable, invincible, dominant. Hitherto Labor has been beholden to Capital; I propose that henceforth Capital shall be beholden to Labor. I could go on writing in this fashion by the hour, but to do so would only try the patience of the readers and delay action. Action is more important than words at this crit¬ ical juncture. Let me, therefore, return to my theme. Organized Labor, according to my plan, within a year’s time will have a fund of $300,000,000; within two years $600,000,000; and at the end of three years $900,000,000 at its disposal. What is to be done with it? To what use is it to be put ? I ’ll answer without any waste of words : To wrest control of the industries, one by one, from the Cap¬ italistic Entrepreneurs; to break their tyrannical power; to crush the despotism of the Capitalistic-Mammonistic Entrepreneur System. “There’s a Way” 267 To Those Who Cry “Impossible!” 1 ‘ Impossible!’ ’ you will say. And I answer that it is not impossible. Let us assume the existence of our Basic Capital Fund. Let us say that the hour for action has arrived. Let us say that in a given industry, which we will call X, there are ten plants—each employing one thousand workers—a total of ten thousand working in the industry. We will open up negotiations for one of the plants. We will, of course, ascertain whether the owners of any of the plants in the industry X are willing to enter into negotiations with us for the purchase of their plant. If they are, the officials of the New Order will ask for a complete and truthful state¬ ment of assets, liabilities, etc., and all data essential to ascertain the correct status of their business. We will ask them what they consider a fair valuation of their plant and business; the amount for which they will sell. Actual value alone will be considered by us. A pric£ based upon an inflated valuation will not be entertained for a moment. If a plant and business is actually worth one million dollars, but capitalized for five million, we will offer to take it over at the actual, but not at the inflated, valuation. Over- capitalization will not be recognized by us. We repudiate “earning power” as a basis for determining value. That is a point upon which there can be no compromise. Under no circumstances whatever will we ever offer, or consent to take over, a plant at more than a reasonable value. We will be fair in our estimate of value; we will make an offer that can even be called liberal; we do not propose to be nig¬ gardly or to take advantage of anyone; but we will con¬ sistently refuse to pay a price in excess of a fair and reasonable value. If the owners of the plant will accept our fair offer we will take over the plant and business on the following terms: we will pay a part of the price agreed upon in cash, the balance, (for which bonds will be issued) to be paid in yearly instalments, with interest at say five percent. Under 268 The New Capitalism certain conditions we may find it preferable to pay the full amount involved in cash. We will, furthermore, offer to retain the present managers, clerical and sales force, etc., for it will be our plan to proceed with as little disturbance of the established routine as possible. All this, of course, on the assumption that the business is in a satisfactory con¬ dition at the time of negotiations. If, however, we cannot come to an understanding within a reasonable time, or if our fair offer is declined, that ends negotiations for this particular plant for all time. Let me emphasize that the New Order intends to negotiate only once for a plant. Our fair offer having been rejected, we will immediately proceed to erect a plant of our own, equip it with machinery, etc., organize the trained forces neces¬ sary for the conduct of the business, thoroughly systematize the plant, etc., and when we are ready to operate we will call for one thousand workers, taking them either all from one plant (probably the one with which we have had recent negotiations) or else a hundred from each of the ten plants; or two hundred from each of five plants—whichever way may be deemed best under existing circumstances. No general, inflexible rule can be laid down to apply to all cases. Each set of conditions must dictate the policy to be followed in each individual case. There may be occa¬ sions, even, when it may be advisable or desirable not to make overtures for the acquisition of an existing plant. It may be altogether preferable to simply go ahead and erect and equip a plant, and then either to withdraw the required number of workers from a single plant, or, by a system of distributive requisition, draw a certain quota from each of the plants constituting the industry. A One-Tenth Control In either event, whether we purchase a plant actually running or put up a plant of our own, the New Order will have complete control of one-tenth of a given industry. We will be in competition with the Capitalistic group and System. This one-tenth control is the opening wedge! “There’s a Way” 269 Whether we will go deeper into an industry or enterprise will depend entirely upon the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. If they are disposed to be decent and to meet our compe¬ tition fairly, we will rest content with the one-tenth control; if they become ugly and evince a disposition to fight us unfairly, or to crush us, we shall then find it necessary to enter more aggressively into whatever industry, or indus¬ tries, we may have seen fit to engage, and extend our con¬ trol, in due time. For the present we do not intend, nor will it be necessary, to take over an entire industry in order to carry out the immediate purposes of our plan. Once we actually engage in an industry, a scientific study of everything that enters into it will be made; particularly as regards wages and cost of production. I hold that it is possible to appreciably bring down costs, not by the Cap¬ italistic method of cutting down wages, but simply by elim¬ inating or reducing a number of the items which now appear as “fixed charges,” “overhead expense,” etc. We will have a decided advantage over our competitors with regard to some of these items, w r hich now enter into cost, for the reason that in every instance we will begin business with a clean slate and no handicaps. Our plant will be capitalized at its actual, not at an inflated and fictitious valuation. And because we will not be overcapitalized we shall have no dividends to earn or pay on watered stock— on Capital that does not exist. Ample working capital will be provided by ourselves , therefore we will have no interest to pay to any Capitalistic banks. These are only a few of the more obvious advantages, and I mention them merely to indicate the possibilities of the New Capitalism under the regime of the New Order. Verb urn Sapientibus Satis The Old Order—the present Capitalistic Entrepreneur System—quite naturally will not welcome our entrance into the sundry fields of industry, now entirely controlled by them, with shouts of delight, but rather with a chorus cry of rage. Indeed it is a dead certainty that every obstacle 270 The New Capitalism will be put into our way in an effort to make the carrying out of our plan impossible, or at least difficult. But we expect that, and will be prepared to counter any attack and meet any emergency. Incidentally, let me say that if we do not succeed in pur¬ chasing a plant already running, and will be put to the necessity of building a new plant, it is easy to see that there will be an excess of plants—one that is vacant and unpro¬ ductive, therefore profitless to the owners—a dead invest¬ ment on the hands of the Capitalistic group. Does the Capitalistic System relish the prospect? Can the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneurs read between the lines? The Basic Principle—Plus This briefly states the basic principle of my plan with regard to the industries, and in which organized wage earners are particularly interested; while at the same time showing possibilities of its development and application to other than industrial lines; besides giving a gentle hint to the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs who have deluded them¬ selves into the belief that they are invulnerable, and that their dominant position is impregnable. To clearly state the principle and show the possibilities of my plan, and incidentally to sound a note of warning to our economic overlords is all I propose to do for the present. Not Revealing All I have no intention of revealing my whole plan at this time, nor how all its details will be carried out. That would be the height of folly, for the enemy would learn precisely what to expect and would, beyond a doubt, attempt to pre¬ pare to meet every emergency. I prefer to keep him guess¬ ing, and in the dark. Therefore I am unfolding only as much as is good for him and safe for us. I am willing to play his game of cards, but I will not show him the cards I hold in my hand. A general plans his campaign with care and caution, and decides on his line of action with boldness and courage, but “There’s a Way” 271 he does not publish his intentions where the enemy may read them and so prepare against them. I will not say precisely just how we will proceed. I will not say just how, and when, and where we will strike. I will not reveal, at this time, what industries we will negotiate for, or enter first. Suffice it to make clear that we will go forward, and that we will strike when we are quite ready, often in most unexpected places—and proceed in a manner that cannot be foreseen nor prepared against. My whole plan of action is decided upon; and all will, in due time, be unfolded to those who have a right to hear and who will be entrusted with the carrying out of every detail of my plan. Besides, these are things that will concern us only after we are organized and have created our Basic Capital Fund. Consequently I shall confine myself chiefly to a discussion of whatever has to do with the essential features of my plan. The Supreme Board of Trustees I have already stated that the New Order is to be a nation wide organization. Needless to say, it will be builded around a Central organization, the Supreme officials of which will have plenary power; they will be the dominant and directing heads and constitute a national Trusteeship for the members of the New Order. And since anyone— whether an industrial worker or engaged in any other occu¬ pation—can become a member of the New Order, I have in mind that the national officers shall be composed of say twelve men—six chosen from and representing organized Labor, and six chosen from and representing that portion of the non-investor public engaged in other pursuits. These twelve men are the Supreme Board of Trustees. The voting power, the directing power, in brief plenary power, rests entirely in their hands. The selection of these twelve men is of the utmost importance. They must be men of more than ordinary intelligence and ability; sincere, unselfish, just, of tested integrity, proved rectitude and unwavering fidelity; men of principle, character and conscience—the soul of honor; men of unquestioned honesty, and, above all , 272 The New Capitalism incorruptible; in brief, men who will do the right, and who are willing to die for what they believe to be the right. I have been told that it w T ill not be easy to find twelve such men, but I am confident that they can be found. Upon these twelve men the success of the New Capitalism depends. You may organize, five million, ten million, twenty million men and women; you may raise three hun¬ dred million, or three billion, or thirty billion of capital, but unless the twelve men who are to be ‘ 1 the head and front ’’ of the New Order—and into whose hands the welfare of eighty million men, women and children is to be entrusted, can be found, nothing can be accomplished. Assuming that these twelve men can be found and are willing to serve the people for nothing more than a reasonable salary—a recom¬ pense hardly proportionate to the service they will be ex¬ pected to render to the public—an organization of unbreak¬ able strength will have been launched. Need I stress here that the utmost care will be exercised in so organizing that at no time can control be taken away from the New Order? My plan guards against every eventuality; indeed has taken every possible contingency, every exigency that may arise, into consideration. Every precaution will be taken. We’ll take no chances of any kind. Our stipulations will be clear and clean cut; our con¬ tracts iron bound. This one lesson w r e have learned from the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs, and we will use it for the benefit of all the people. Plenary Power, supreme author¬ ity, absolute control, and complete stewardship is vested in the twelve Supreme officers of the New Order—the Supreme Board of Trustees of our Economic Commonwealth. A Move in the Right Direction While we may depart from the corporation organization methods in vogue today, nevertheless in describing what we intend to do or how we intend to proceed, I shall use the terms that are current. Consequently I’ll put it this way. Any industry or enterprise into which we may enter, will be capitalized at actual value fairly determined. A safe ‘‘There’s a Way” 273 quota of the stock will be common stock. This will be placed in trust in the hands of the twelve national Supreme officers, constituting the Supreme Board of Trustees. The balance of our stock issue will be preferred stock, divided into two equal parts. One-half of this preferred stock will be offered to those workers within the industry concerned, and to the workers (wage earners) in whatever industries they may be engaged; the other half will be offered to the general public —that is to anyone not engaged in the industries—in brief to whoever cares to invest. None will be excluded; and there will be no discrimination. But since I am assuming that the New Order, for the first three years, will be composed probably wholly of organized wage earners, let me return to a consideration of their exact status under the New Capitalism. You will recall that each is to pay into the Treasury of the New Order, five dollars a month, or sixty dollars a year, for a period of three years. This amount, be it clearly understood, is not to be a contribution or donation. Ten dollars a year will be set aside as membership fee, to be used as I shall presently explain; and fifty dollars will be considered as an invest¬ ment and treated as such. For every fifty dollars a Cer¬ tificate of Deposit will be issued until such time that we actually enter into an industry, when it will be exchanged for a stock certificate. From that moment each will become a preferred stockholder, or rather stockowner, in whatever plant or plants we may take over or erect. Thus the virtual ownership of the plants of a given industry will be vested in the workers themselves. The control of the plant or plants in whatever industries we may enter, will, of course, be held in trust by the Supreme Board of Trustees. When Wage Earners Become Investors Thus the wage earner automatically becomes an investor. Consequently from the time we go into active operation the workers holding the preferred stock in a given industry will draw, in addition to their wages, dividends of a minimum of six percent (which will be increased when and as con- 274 The New Capitalism ditions warrant). Workers in a given industry can also obtain stock in any other industry they may desire. More¬ over, they are not limited as to any amount. Any member desiring to invest larger amounts has the privilege to do so. Needless to say, since there are five million members rep¬ resenting, perhaps, several hundred different trades, or engaged in different crafts, not all of which will be affected during the first few years of our existence, provision will be made so that all may have an opportunity to participate in one or the other enterprise in which we might be inter¬ ested, for, let it be remembered, we will not concern our¬ selves exclusively with industrial enterprises; we will strike out into sundry directions in our endeavor to break the despotic tyranny of the Capitalistic-Mammonistic System, and gain our economic independence. The Membership Fee The Membership Pee, as I have stated, is to be ten dol¬ lars. I have lived for years with my subject; I have care¬ fully studied my plan from every possible angle; I know its every possibility, its every demand; its every requisite for success. I have made a complete list of the things that must be done, and a tentative estimate of cost, and can say that the fifty million a year I am setting aside will be ample for all essential and imperative purposes. First of all, it will be necessary to build and maintain an organization throughout the nation. That is important, and whatever the cost may be there can be no slighting of a single detail. The organization of the New Order will call for the best quality of “brains”—and a goodly quantity of it. If any one imagines that I am proposing a kinder¬ garten association let him disabuse his mind quickly. What we intend to do will be no child’s play. We shall have to deal with a dangerous, troublesome, resourceful and tricky adversary, a combination of men who have been in supreme and unchallenged control for decades of years, and who naturally may be expected to put up a desperate fight, nor scruple about the weapons with which they mean to combat “There’s a Way” 275 us. None realizes as I do the tremendous power of these unscrupulous men. I am not deluding myself for an instant. But more of that anon. In the second place, my plan includes the establish¬ ment of Colleges and Institutes, in which there will be a number of important departments: Technical, scientific and research; legal; legislative; statistical, etc. Political Economy, Accounting and Cost Finding Systems, Banks, Finance, Exchange, and Commerce, will be subjected to a thorough and complete analysis. We will get at the bottom of the Wage Question, Taxes, Tariffs, etc. In brief the false principles around which our economic life has been twisted, will be subjected to expert investigation and analysis in an endeavor to unearth the Facts and discover the Truth. But the most important and most necessary thing of all is the building up and maintenance of a powerful and influ¬ ential national press. This includes the issuing and circu¬ lation of the organization’s publications and whatever other literature may be deemed necessary to bring and keep the New Order, its purposes and work, its findings and achieve¬ ments, conspicuously before the public. Without a great national press and “pitiless publicity” service, the New Order would surely fail. With this important institution provided for we are prepared to meet any contingency that might arise, or cope with any conditions that may be created by those who do not want to see us succeed. The Capitalistic Cry of Horror The Capitalistic Entrepreneur group may be depended upon to raise a cry of horror and indignation at so great a “waste” of the “poor wage earners’ ” money. That is a favorite trick of theirs. Listen, for example, to this howl from the Wall Street Journal, quoted in the Chicago Jour¬ nal of Commerce, (November 11, 1920) : “No free country can afford to tolerate an irresponsible central organization like the American Federation of Labor, with the stupendous annual income of $48,000,000, in a 276 The New Capitalism position where it can defy the common law as applied to conspiracy. ’ 7 If no “free country” can afford to “tolerate” a “cen¬ tral organization ’ ’ that has ‘ ‘ a stupendous annual income ’ ’ ($48,000,000)—( provided out of its own wages ) let me say to all friends, supporters, defenders and beneficiaries of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System that an enslaved people intends not only to create a “central organization” but to provide, out of its own wages (and savings), many times the “stupendous” sum complained of by the Wall Street Journal —for the specific purpose of combating those who for years have defied not only the common law but the laws of simple justice, ordinary honesty, and common decency; and who are today engaged in a conspiracy to crush Labor and reduce the populace to a condition of hopeless servitude and permanent poverty. And they will pay whatever price, figured in sacrifice, and dollars and cents, may he necessary to curb, or if necessary crush, the cruel, inhuman and mon¬ strous Capitalistic-Mammonistic Entrepreneur System. The point on which the Capitalistic group will probably concentrate its attacks, is the salaries that it will be neces¬ sary to pay to those who will serve the New Order in one cayjacity or another. When the Grain Growers of the United States, in order to break the grip of the Capitalistic- Mammonistic group upon their throat, recently formed a national organization, sure enough, a cry was raised that they were paying their officers big salaries. So vicious was the propaganda set in motion by the interests anxious to break the new organization, that the United States Grain Growers, Inc., found it necessary to make a public defensive statement. I quote from the Commercial Edition of the Chicago Herald Examiner, (June 27, 1921) : “Enemies of the movement,” the statement asserts, “are attempting to discredit it in the eyes of the farmers by mag¬ nifying the importance of the fact that at the first meeting of the board of directors, salaries for officers were fixed as follows: President, $16,000; Secretary, $12,000; Treas¬ urer, $15,000, and General Counsel, $15,000.” “There’s a Way” 277 Talk about big salaries! According to the 1918 Federal Income Tax Report the officials in 317,579 establishments in that year paid themselves as ‘ ‘ compensation, ’ ’ the enor¬ mous sum of $2,225,543,259. In other words each of the sixteen million wage earner or non-investor families in 1918, contributed an average of $139, merely to pay the salaries of the 317,579 corporation officials. The fifty mil¬ lion dollars we propose to set aside, out of our wages, be it remembered, for all purposes, is less than three percent of the amount with which the corporation officials reward their services to themselves—and which amount is charged up to the public as “cost of production.” The Adequacy of Our Capital Fund There is one point on which I desire to give a little light in this chapter. There will be those whose mentality, accus¬ tomed to move within circumscribed limits, cannot visualize what lies beyond their radius of immediate perception. To these a Basic Capital Fund aggregating only three-fourths of a billion will seem altogether inadequate for our economic regeneration. They forget that one of the coordinate pur¬ poses of my plan is to bring into existence a chain of banks or financial centers strategically placed, all under our im¬ mediate control. They forget that business is not done exclusively with cash capital; credit plays a prominent part. To what extent credit is employed may be best judged by observing the financial practices of the Capitalistic System. It is no secret that ninety-five percent of the country’s bus¬ iness is done on the credit basis, that is, for every one dollar of actual cash capital, nineteen dollars of credit are im¬ pressed into service, that is, extended by those who control the nation’s finances through the medium of sundry inter¬ related banking and money institutions—to those in the industrial and other enterprises—by the Captains of Finance to the Captains of Industry, by the Capitalists to the Entrepreneurs—in brief by themselves, to themselves —and for their own exclusive benefit and profit. 278 The New Capitalism If the New Capitalism were to adopt precisely the same tactics that the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System employs, and set in motion the identical machinery, our first year’s Basic Capital Fund of $300,000,000 would be a basis for a volume of credit nineteen times greater—or a total of $5,700,000,000; and the larger Basic Capital Fund of $900,000,000, accumulated during a period of three years, would represent credit possibilities aggregating more than 17 billion dollars. In saying all this I want to be understood as merely emphasizing the credit utilization of Capital as practiced under the present control of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. That there are dangers a-plenty in such a condi¬ tion must be apparent to all those who have more than an elementary understanding of financial practices. The dan¬ ger of collapse is ever present, and every possible precau¬ tion must be taken. I speak of these things at this time and in this place merely to show what the present Capitalistic System has discovered to be the safe, not to say legitimate, limit of possibilities 1 —possibilities which I should scruple to exploit, as well as hesitate to exhaust, preferring always to keep rather within the limits of a sounded safety than to venture into the uncharted seas of possibilities; for, as I have pointed out in another chapter, one of the causes of high prices is directly traceable to the almost limitless employment of credit. The greater the employment of credit in the conduct of business the greater the load of interest charges upon the people, and, therefore, we will be careful not to go beyond the reasonable, requisite and always safe limits in this important matter. When Finance is King I will merely hint at present that in the science of finance there is less of science than of sorcery. The-miracles of i Writing on the Foreign Trade Financing Corporation which was organized with $100,000,000, C. B. Evans, in the Chicago Journal of Commerce . January 17, 1921, said: “In the development of the prospectus the same capitalization of $100,000,000 with power to issue debentures up to $1,000,000,000, as first proposed, is adhered to.” Ergo, nine dollars of credit inflation for every dollar of capital. “There’s a Waf ’ 279 banking can be explained by chicanery rather than by supernatural powers. I am purposely omitting a chapter dealing with ‘‘Banks and Their Practices /’ because in it I would be compelled to say many things which had better be left unsaid at this critical time. Nevertheless, a little light from authentic sources will give verisimilitude to some of my statements with regard to banking practices made in this chapter. Finance is King, and “The King Can Do No Wrong!” It seems the dominant group of the banking and finan¬ cial system holds itself above accountability and entirely removed from the sphere of criticism. It resents having any of its tactics questioned or any of its transactions investi¬ gated. As an example, in the case of the New York Legis¬ lative Committee, Samuel Untermyer, Counsel (January 5, 1921) proposed that the great financial institutions and insurance companies be investigated. Mr. Untermyer declared that “an insidious campaign through hired propa¬ gandists was on, to defeat the contemplated work of the Committee in investigating the loan market.” Or read this excerpt from an editorial in Forbes Maga¬ zine (July 9, 1921) : “Incidentally, that was a sorry figure cut by Forrest F. Dryden, president of the Prudential, when he refused to explain certain financial transactions which very badly needed explaining, that is, if Mr. Dryden hoped to retain a reputation for honesty. The only deduction to be drawn from Mr. Dryden’s willingness to be held in contempt rather than lay bare the truth, and from Mr. Lindabury’s excited efforts to butt in to muzzle his Prudential colleague, is that the facts could not stand daylight. From what was revealed by Mr. Untermyer, it would look as if the Pru¬ dential insiders had favored their own pockets.” Or this news-item from a daily paper: ‘ ‘ The Pittsburgh Clearing House Association was accused by Comptroller Williams of the Currency today (February 25) of having forbidden its member banks to furnish data 280 The New Capitalism asked for in the national bank call issued yesterday. ? ’ ( Her¬ ald Examiner, February 26, 1921). A Callous Conscience and Sensitive Nerves At the American Bankers Association in October, 1920, there was complete unanimity with regard to every reso¬ lution. “The only resolution which caused any discussion was that which referred to the United States Comptroller of the Currency. That officer had one lone defender on the floor of the Convention, and the resolution as presented was adopted with only one dissenting vote.” John Skelton Williams, Comptroller of the Currency, had some time before charged that certain New York banks were exacting unnecessarily high rates of interest. In passing it may be stated that Comptroller Williams stated what are known facts. Nevertheless the sensitive body known as the American Bankers Association strongly disapproved of “such utterances by a public official,” and in a resolution declared that they were calculated ‘ ‘ to create an unfounded hostility between bankers and the public, even to breed violence of action and dangerous disturbance of the public mind. ” 2 No! It is not at all remarkable that those most con¬ cerned have invested their sundry financial transactions with an air of mystery, and that they are loath to reveal how they perform their tricks. But these are matters into which we will go more deeply when the proper time arrives. 3 Now or Never There was never so propitious a time as the present to institute a New Economic Order and inaugurate the New Capitalism. We will have the great advantage of begin¬ ning with a clean slate in every way. Besides the banking, • • # 2 Journal of the American Bankers Association, November, 1920. 3The Pujo Commission in its report stated: “Most of the State institutions and of the principal national banks in the reserve cities of New York, Philadelphia, Boston and St. Louis, refuse or omitted to make any return whatever and denied the power or jurisdiction of the committee to inquire into their affairs.” “There’s a Way” 281 industrial and commercial interests, in brief the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneurs, are staggering under a tremendous load. We do not want to take advantage of their dilemma, but it cannot be denied that the present situation is fraught with manifold opportunities for us. This, of all times, is the opportune moment for setting in motion the wheels of the New Order—the machinery of the New Capitalism. Now is the time to organize; now is the time to raise the Basic Capital Fund; now is the time to plan and arrange all preliminaries so as to be ready to strike when the favor¬ able hour arrives. Now or never! Indeed we should have acted twenty years ago, before the Capitalistic Entrepre¬ neur System had so thoroughly entrenched itself. It would have been much easier to put incipient Capitalistic Entre¬ preneur power to rout in 1900, or say 1905, than it will be today. It would have been easier for the masses of the people to throw off the shackles with which they were being bound; easier for them to crush the incubus; easier to drive the beast out of its lair; easier to clip its claws; easier to extract the fangs of the monster. Twenty years ago it would have been possible to hinder the ascendancy to dominance of the small group of men who today are the nub of the Capitalistic-Mammonistic Entrepreneur System. Today, I admit, it is more difficult to challenge their supremacy; there are more obstacles to overcome, more pitfalls to encounter. We must display greater shrewdness and sagacity, and exercise more care. But if it is more difficult today it is also more necessary. It is our only escape from a mighty conspiracy and a con¬ stantly growing menace. In sheer self defense the people must unite their strength and combine their power to break the chains of their economic bondage. If they fail to act promptly, then let them prepare their ankles for the gyves of slavery fastened unbreakably to prison walls. A Clarion Call This is a clarion call to action! A call to quit talking and do something. Act now! or forever hold your peace. 282 The New Capitalism Break the bonds of economic slavery, while yet you have the strength to do it. “Act—act in the living presence, Heart within and God o’erliead.” Delay is dangerous, and every year lost will by that much weaken the cause of the people and strengthen the Capi¬ talistic Entrepreneur System. I will not say that five or ten years hence it will be too late, but I will say that unless resolute action is taken promptly, more drastic action, less gentle, less polite methods, may be necessary later. Of one thing you may be sure—that from this day forward tremen¬ dous efforts will be made to drive a wedge between the pub¬ lic and the laboring classes. No stone will be left unturned in an endeavor to widen the rift between organized Labor and the unorganized people. Here lies the only hope of the thoroughly organized Capitalistic Entrepreneurs to per¬ petuate and increase their despotic power and tyranny. Thus endeth this chapter, in which I have tried merely to give the readers a hurried summary of the essentials of my plan, and a glimpse of the possibilities of the New Capi¬ talism. CHAPTER XXI Our Principles and Policies I F I were given a commission to make this world over according to my own ideals, or were asked to improve it in conformity with my ideas, I would make few changes. Certainly there would be no upheaval. Such changes as I might be tempted to make would be entirely in individuals, into whose hearts I would try to infuse a degree of honesty, and into whose minds I would endeavor to inject a decent regard for their followmen. But the institutions I would accept as they are, leaving them intact, when right, and improving them only when necessary. The thing that most recommends my plan is the fact that it does not require destruction of a single thing, nor call for disturbance of any kind. We shall be able to proceed without pulling the 11 established order” up by the roots. Because we want to build a habitable house for ourselves is no reason why we should raze our neighbor’s cabin, or his castle, to the ground. There are economic theories a-plenty, each with a certain following. There are so-called remedial schemes without number, but each dependent upon a radical making over of everything. Some sweepingly condemn the whole economic structure, and contend that nothing short of pulling down the pillars of the temple will bring relief. These theories fail to take into consideration that the fabric of society is the texture of civilization; and that a remedy based on wanton destruction, is no remedy at all, and brings with it only ruin and chaos. The plan I propose is the only plan with specifications that calls for action—not destructive, but constructive action—upsetting nothing, destroying nothing. No violence; no confiscation of property; no expropriation; no division 283 284 The New Capitalism of wealth; no overthrowing of the present system of govern¬ ment; no enactment of new laws or abrogation of the old. Indeed all laws now on the statute books are to our advan¬ tage, for—note you well—the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs have been alert, and have had entered on the statute books of the nation, hundreds of laws that are favorable to them¬ selves, all of which can now be employed to our advantage —and will admirably suit our purposes. There are some things we shall try to change by degrees, and some that must be altered in due time, but we shall proceed in an orderly manner and always within the sanctioned limits of the law. What undoubted wrongs exist we shall certainly strive to right, and we hope that we may have the coopera¬ tion of all decent men and women within the nation, in our endeavors. A Definite Program The New Order must have a definite program, based on clearly defined fundamental principles. We are perfectly willing that the whole world may know precisely what we stand for, and what we will strive to accomplish. First of all, we believe in a square deal for everybody. We intend to deal fairly with and act decently toward everybody—every set of interests, every group—whether entrepreneurs, producers, manufacturers, wholesale dealers, retail dealers; and even essential so-called middlemen. Bmt above all we shall insist that a square deal and decent con¬ sideration be given to the men and women included in none of the above groups,—the farmers, the wage earners, the salaried men and women, and those not on any regular pay-roll—in brief, the non-investor group—sometimes spoken of as the ultimate consumers—the public. The Capitalistic Entrepreneur group has never believed in the square deal; certainly it has never practised it. It has never considered the welfare of the great masses of the public—only its own selfish interests. It is not our intention to materially alter the established order of business. Nothing is more remote from our minds Our Principles and Policies 285 than to destroy what is good and acceptable even in the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. We will protect every legitimate interest, but we will eliminate the false principles of exploitation. We will defend the right to a fair profit, but we will not endure the profiteer. We will support and cooperate with every decent business man, be he producer, manufacturer or merchant, or in whatever legitimate line he may be engaged, as long as his methods are honest and his aim is not merely selfish. We will ascertain whether all of the so-called middlemen are essential to the proper and economical conduct of business. Those necessary will be retained; those unnecessary will be eliminated. With Regard to Industries It will be our aim for the present to enter into industries only to whatever extent may be necessary to bring com¬ modity prices from their present altitudinous height down to a reasonable level. If the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs show an earnest willingness to be decent—to readjust their wicked System—abandon their unjust methods, lay aside their crooked tactics and sinister practices, and give the public a square deal, that will be satisfactory to us. But we will not accept mere promises; we want performances. No undue delays will be tolerated. Procrastination is not only the thief of time; in this critical period it is also the thief of the people’s money—their earnings and their sav¬ ings. We will be fair and reasonable; but we will stand for no tom-foolery nor for dilly-dallying. Mammonistic Capitalism, to save itself, must, willy-nilly, become decent —must reorganize itself on our basis. We do not propose ever to act rashly, and never unfairly. Our entrance into any industry will be prompted by the existence of intolerable and unjustifiable conditions in said industry. If the prices of a product are, according to our way of computing, unreasonably high, that is to say, de¬ monstrably excessive or exorbitant—extortionate upon the consumer—we will call upon the manufacturer to reduce them to decent limits. If he is unwilling, claiming that it 286 The New Capitalism can’t be done, or that he is producing at a loss, running on a trivial margin of profit, etc., we shall gladly give him an opportunity to prove his case. We will call for his cost sheets—his trial balance—and study the history of his in¬ dustry, examine his investments, inventories, and whatever figures and data he may have to substantiate his claim. You may rest assured that all the evidence will be critically analyzed, carefully computed, and fairly judged. If upon a thorough investigation it is disclosed that the manufacturer is not at fault—that he is not making an enormous profit on his actual investment—but that the retailer is guilty of extortion, we will give the retailer a fair opportunity to adopt reasonable practices. We will proceed with him much as we shall proceed with the manu¬ facturer. The Profiteer The producer, the manufacturer, the jobber, the whole¬ saler, and the retailer—each is entitled to a profit. We accept as an axiom that profit is the stimulus to business, to progress and to growth. Without a fair profit in pros¬ pect no man would care to go into business. We want it understood that it is at no time our plan to destroy profits. We are not opposed to profits. Indeed, we believe in a decent profit—a profit large enough to provide against any current or reasonable future contingencies. But we oppose double profits, camouflaged profits and extortionate profits. We are determined to curb and crush unconscionable profi¬ teering—to wipe out of existence the tribe of ruthless profi¬ teers. We will be fair in defining what constitutes a legiti¬ mate and reasonable profit. No honest producer or manu¬ facturer, no decent merchant, need have any misgivings as to our designs, aims or intentions in this regard. But the dishonest producer or manufacturer and the dishonest mer¬ chant may, with reason, stand in fear of us. It may be taken for granted that we will at no time inter¬ fere in any business where fairness and decency, justice and honesty, are in evidence. Certainly we will never pro- Our Principles and Policies 287 ceed recklessly, nor without good and sufficient reasons. It is not our aim to harass established business at any time. Our object and purpose is to create conditions that are fair and decent to all concerned, to the producer, the manufacturer, the retailer, the public, and, of course, to the wage earner—and to see that they are permanently maintained. No arbitrary stand will ever be assumed by us. No ill- considered attitude and no hasty action will be taken. We will move with caution and prudence, yet with precision and boldness. No step is to be taken without a complete understanding of what we are doing, and a comprehensive knowledge of what is to be done. In every case the officials of the New Order must be sure of their ground. No Miracles Let it be clearly understood, the New Order does not pretend that it will work miracles. It took centuries to bring about the conditions that afflict us today; we cannot expect to change them in a week. The evils that now characterize the Capitalistic System crept in little by little; our elimination process must proceed in like fashion. The basic wrongs inherent in the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System—and upon which it has builded its strength and its power—can, must, and will be destroyed by us, but gradually, and always within the sanctioned limits of the law. But there will be no sudden changes, and no violent up¬ heavals. Living costs will not come down with a thump. Wages will not be immediately increased; such improve¬ ments as can be made with regard to prices and wages, will be made, but cautiously and gradually. The Capitalistic System has declared that wages cannot be increased, nor prices lowered; we deny the Capitalistic claims, but we will find out for ourselves whether there is, or has ever been, any justification for them. Briefly, we do not propose to effect any radical changes over night, nor to bring about a perfect adjustment of all problems within twenty-four 288 The New Capitalism hours. We will not enter into a Marathon race before we have learned to walk. Remember that the Capitalistic Sys¬ tem arrived slowly and cautiously—step by step, gropingly, and always with the certain knowledge that its feet were planted on firm ground. We will do likewise. In this one thing at least, we will imitate the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group. Stock Exchange No! my plan proposes no immediate changes whatever in the “existing order,” bad as that “order” is. We will accept things pretty much as they are. Such changes, or rather improvements, as may be deemed necessary or de¬ sirable, will be made in due time and after careful analysis and mature consideration. For the present, however, we will disturb nothing; not even that which, because it brings no economic benefit to the people, deserves to be destroyed. For example: I have pointed out in a special chapter, that the stock exchanges, while undoubtedly of great value to a few hundred thousand, or a million, speculators, serve no useful purpose as far as the general, non-speculating, non¬ investor public is concerned. They are not necessary to the bona fide small investor. But in spite of all this we shall not aim to destroy the stock exchanges. No! let those who desire to gamble continue their gambling operations, but they must do it hereafter with their own money, not with ours. Let the speculator and the Capitalistic Entre¬ preneurs buy and sell their “securities” to each other if it affords them any pleasure—and profit. But while they are having their fun among themselves we will offer the genuine investor—the man or woman who actually desires to safely invest a certain amount of money, and be content with a fair and legitimate profit,—an opportunity to invest in actual properties, in actual securities. Our stocks, behind which there is an actual but not an inflated value, will always be worth one hundred cents on the dollar; they will not be worth $100 today and $85 tomorrow. Our dividends may fluctuate; the value of our stocks will not fluctuate. t Our Principles and Policies 289 An Apology to the Small Investor All through this book I have had but one regret—viz., that I have been compelled to include in the Capitalistic ‘ ‘ investor group ’ ’ a million or so small investors—men and women who have invested small sums in good faith in some of the Capitalistic enterprises, and by so doing became the • prey of financial pirates, the innocent victims of bulls and bears. The stocks they bought for a hundred dollars a share, today have a market value of perhaps only fifty dol¬ lars—are worth about fifty cents on the dollar in the market. Their dividends in many cases have been passed in late years. But even though they have received dividends yearly, do they realize that the value (purchasing power) of their dividends during the past twenty years has been steadily decreasing—that, for example, a dollar of dividends in 1920 had a value (purchasing power) of only thirty-eight cents compared to the dollar in 1913. In other words, if a small investor received $60 of dividends on a $1,000 in¬ vestment in 1913, and $60 in 1920, the amount he received in 1920 had a purchasing power of only $22.80 as compared with the purchasing power in 1913. A few corporations have come to realize that this depre¬ ciated purchasing power of dividends is a weak link in the Capitalistic chain, and are trying to overcome it by raising their dividend rates from six to eight and nine percent. But raising the dividend rate will not restore the lost pur¬ chasing power. To bring the purchasing power of divi¬ dends up to the full 1913 strength it would be necessary to raise the dividend rate from six percent to about seventeen percent. What corporation intends to do that? I’ll an¬ swer ! Not one! But those that have or will raise their rate from six to eight' or nine percent, propose to derive the additional amount necessary for the payment of the greater dividend rate, either by maintaining or raising still higher the prices of their particular commodities. In other words— 290 The Sew Capitalism the stockholders themselves will be made to help provide the additional revenue that would enable the corporations in which they are stockholders, to pay them a higher divi¬ dend rate. It is only proper that the “widows and orphans/’ as well as the thousands of employees who are being per¬ suaded, inveigled or coerced into becoming “investors” in the stocks of the corporations employing them, should un¬ derstand the Capitalistic logic with regard to the small investor, and the Capitalistic arithmetic with regard to their investments. The Small Investor Under the New Capitalism To the bona fide small investors in the so-called securities of the sundry transportation, industrial, public utilities corporations, etc., I want briefly to emphasize the distinc¬ tive difference of their investment under the Capitalistic inflation System—and under the system I propose. 1: Under my plan their investment will always be worth one hundred cents on the dollar. Its value will be permanent, not change from day to day, or hour to hour. 2: They will receive, let us say, a minimum of six per¬ cent on the par or permanent value of their investment (and if conditions permit, more than six percent). No bona fide small investor in the Capitalistic corporations has ever received more than six percent—and in the aggregate they have received less. The Pennsylvania Railroad, for example, recently reduced its dividend rate from six to four percent. Many of the big corporations passed their divi¬ dends for 1920 and 1921 entirely. 3 : And this is a most important point! Under my plan whatever amount of dividends an investor may receive will have a 100 percent purchasing power; whereas under the overcapitalization System the dividends he is receiving have a purchasing power of, let us say, 50 percent. Conse¬ quently, six percent on an investment in our corporations, will have as great a purchasing power as a twelve percent return from an overcapitalized corporation. Our Principles and Policies 291 4: Any dividends which an investor receives and saves, will at all times have a 100 percent purchasing power. This is not the case at present. The dividends an investor saved twenty years ago had a 100 percent purchasing power, but today he can buy less than one-half the amount, volume, or quantity he might have been able to buy twenty years ago. But these are points which we propose to discuss more in detail once the New Order is in existence. The Banks The Sampsonian strength of the Capitalistic Entrepre¬ neur group, the foundation stone upon which the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneur System is builded, rests entirely on its money monopoly—its absolute and complete control of the nation’s cash resources and credit facilities. This has been stated so often, and proved so conclusively, and is so ob¬ vious, that I consider it almost a waste of time to repeat it. What does the New Order propose to do as regards the Capitalistic banks? Break them, destroy them? No! We will let them alone; we will let them go on with their mad dance. We will let them have their banks—and their Sys¬ tem, to do with as they please. We’ll not touch a hair of their head. But we will take precious good care that they shall not, hereafter, touch a hair of our head. We will start banks of our own; not a whole string of them at once, but gradually, one after the other—and our funds and credit facilities will be used for our own benefit, and our services placed at the disposal of those who want to convert their savings into real investments. In brief the depositors will own the banks, and will derive whatever profit is to be de¬ rived, from the use of their savings. We will not loan one dollar of our money to any speculator or for any specula¬ tive purpose. We’ll help and cooperate with the decent business man—the legitimate business man ,the farmer, the home builder. The promoter, the gambler, the profiteer, will receive no help from us. 292 The New Capitalism Boards of Trade The Board of Trade is the twin brother of the Stock Ex¬ change. The latter facilitates gambling in securities, the former in farm products and food supplies. The same group of traders can be found in both pits. Speculative buying and selling, and marginal transactions, can be pre¬ dicated of both institutions. With regard to boards of trade, Senators Kenyon and Capper have clearly shown that some of the crops of the United States are sold over from seven to ten times in the course of a year. For whose benefit? The farmers? No! The public’s ? No! For the undoubted benefit of a few thousand speculators. “Years ago,” said Senator Capper, “the people of the United States demanded the suspension of the infamous Louisiana lottery. It is against the law to run a gambling house anywhere within the United States. But today, un¬ der the cloak of business respectability, we are permitting the biggest gambling hell in the world to be operated in the Chicago Board of Trade. The grain gamblers have made the Exchange building in Chicago the world’s greatest gambling house. By comparison, Europe’s suicide club at Monte Carlo is as innocent and innocuous as a church bazaar. ’ ’ 1 Gambling, marginal transactions, profit taking—these are the sustaining props of boards of trade. Gambling is an ancient sport, and will probably continue to the end of time. Marginal transactions are of more modern origin, and have as their basis the use of other people’s money. We can refuse to allow our money to be used for specula¬ tive and profit taking purposes. If we cannot stop gam¬ bling, we may be able in course of time, to devise ways and means by which the things gambled in can be diverted from purely speculative institutions to legitimate markets; —ways and means by the employment of which the profits i From Senator Capper’s Speech at Smith Center, Kansas, October 13. 1920. Our Principles and Policies 293 will go to the actual producers rather than to speculative gamblers; and even enable the public to participate in a share of the profits through the medium of lower prices. But all this is too big a subject—too tremendous a theme, with too many ramifications to be discussed in a paragraph or two. Suffice it to say, for the present, that stock ex¬ changes and boards of trade will come under the studious scrutiny of the New Order. The Fair Purpose of My Plan From all this it can be seen that I am not proposing any radical changes or violent upheaval. Indeed, I’ll go so far as to say that we do not want affiliated with us any¬ one who advocates changing the political, social or economic order through the medium of violence. Let it be understood that I am not calling those who work for a wage to deeds of vengeance. I am making no appeal to their cupidity. I am but asking them to use their common sense to protect themselves and their children from further exploitation. I uphold the doctrine of property rights, but strenuously oppose the concentration of all the property in the hands of a few. I will at all times defend the principle of the individual’s right to hold property; but at the same time I shall labor to bring about a condition whereby the right to have and to hold property will be enjoyed by a greater number. The extension of the right to a considerably greater number than at present, and the actual acquisition of property by lawful means, as well as the enjoyment of the legitimate benefits that accrue to the possessor,—that, in brief, is the Alpha and Omega of the System of Eco¬ nomics, I am proposing. A Question and an Answer Can the New Order succeed? I answer:—Yes—beyond a doubt, for all the elements under which the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System developed itself to tremendous pro¬ portions will be in existence and employed by us to the utmost. We will have the capital; we will control our own 294 The New Capitalism labor; and what is more to the point, we will have the good will of the public at large for whose aggregate benefit, rather than for the selfish advantage of any group, we will operate. Service will be our slogan—Service at as low a cost as is consistent with business prudence. Service at a price that will not only not beggar the wage earners, but enrich them. The Attitude of the “Big Interests” I am going to pay the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs the compliment of saying that they will, discover the possibili¬ ties of the New Order under the New Capitalism long before those most concerned; and since I am familiar with the tactics of the “Big Interests’’ I know to what extreme measures they will be tempted to resort to prevent the New Order from organizing, and the New Capitalism from be¬ coming a menace to them. In fact I have noted down all the things they will be likely to do in their desperate at¬ tempt to kill our child aborning. When once my plan is understood, and the first step toward organizing the non-investor group has been taken, through the nucleus of organized Labor, you may rest assured that a great contest of strength will ensue. The powers that be will launch a nation-wide poison propa¬ ganda, bring forth their strongest weapons, employ their subtlest strategy, their ablest generalship, their most ruth¬ less tactics, and seek to win in the contest with deadly gases and liquid flames of fire. Through their banks they will attempt to checkmate our every move, to strangle us —to throttle us. But let them try. They will find us pre¬ pared to counter their every stroke, to checkmate their every move. Not until we are molested will we show our teeth, and even bite if it is necessary; not until we are attacked will we strike back; not until we are threatened with violence will we fight, and then to the death. We serve notice right now that we will not offer the right cheek when our left is smitten. We shall practice patience, but leave humility to the saints. CHAPTER XXII Who Is “The Public”? B UT before organized Labor can attempt to inaugurate a New Order, it will have to take an inventory of itself. It behooves me, therefore, to emphasize the two false bases upon which organized Labor has been build¬ ing its organization to date. It is because organized Labor did not discover that the bases were false that its super¬ structure is toppling over. I mean Labor’s wrong attitude toward the public, and its false concept as regards wages. If what I shall write in this chapter, and the chapters deal¬ ing with wages, will help to clarify views; if organized Labor will grasp the full import of these two basic subjects; if seeing the error of its way in the past it can persuade itself henceforth to a clearer vision of its status and true relationship to those not of its fold, much will have been accomplished. A good beginning will have been made. You may have noticed within recent years, in the daily press, financial papers, trade journals, manufacturers’ offi¬ cial organs, and commercial publications of all kinds, one of the most effective slogans in the Capitalistic category— viz., that nothing must be done, or even tolerated, that is detrimental to society—to the community, or the public. How tenderly solicitious these Capitalistic spokesmen have suddenly become of society; how graciously considerate of the community; and what wonderful champions of the general public. The assumption is, of course, that the Capi¬ talistic group has never in all its history done anything that was not, ever and always, for the immediate welfare of society, and for the best interests of the community, and invariably for the good of the public. While the inference and the open charge is that every attempt that Labor makes to better its condition is a distinct slap in the face of the 295 296 The New Capitalism public—an offense against the community—an attack against the very pillars of society. Let me briefly examine this new slogan, and lay bare its arrant knavery—its camouflaged hypocrisy. To the propo¬ sition that neither organized Capital nor organized Labor has a right to do aught that is detrimental to society, or an injustice to the community, or an attack on the public, I give heartiest assent. And then I assert that everything that the Capitalistic group has done from its very inception has been diametrically opposed to the best interests of so¬ ciety—of the community and the general public. That this is more than an assertion I hope at least some of the chap¬ ters of this volume will partially show. But lest some eco¬ nomic wiseacre, or offended Mammonist, take issue with me on this score, I challenge him to disprove my claim that the whole Capitalistic System, and all its operations, are specifically for the benefit of a comparatively small group. I challenge him to deny that the public actually pays the dividends on the inflated valuation of the overcapitalized corporations, and interest on all the inflated “values” of productive properties. I challenge him to prove that the public is directly benefited by the Stock Exchange transac¬ tions. I promise him that I will be largely attentive while he categorically enumerates the blessings showered upon the public by selling the grain crops of the United States over several times a year. I am willing to be silent while he demonstrates, arithmetically or otherwise, just how the general public is the beneficiary of the system of overcapi¬ talization and inflation. If any organized institution is to be criticised, or con¬ demned, or destroyed, because it is injurious to the best interests of society—harmful to the community—and brutal to the general public—that institution is the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System. “The Party of the Third Part” But there is another and a more insistent side to this question, a brief discussion of which seems to me entirely Who Is “The Public”? 297 in order here. Who is the general public, which it pleased Governor Allen of Kansas) et id genus, to dub “the Party of the Third Part”? How is this “Party of the Third Part” constituted? Who composes it? The country is made up of twenty percent of investors, and eighty per¬ cent of non-investors. Consequently the public is composed of twenty percent of Capitalistic “investors” and eighty percent of non-investors—of wage earners and salaried men and women. If, then, any group of wage earners, or salaried men and women in their role of workers, seek to protect or defend themselves, or deem it necessary in order to vindicate a fundamental principle, to resist, to strike, let us say, and thereby cause temporary inconvenience or even suffering to the public, they are inflicting inconvenience and suffering principally upon themselves. I rather sus¬ pect that the part of the public that protests is chiefly the twenty percent of Capitalistic “investors”—beneficiaries of the Capitalistic System, which in every instance is re¬ sponsible for strikes and miscellaneous disturbances. Let us have no further nonsense about the wrong that Labor, in a struggle or death grapple, inflicts upon the public— that is—principally on itself. Strabismus Now the surprising thing is that organized Labor, or more correctly speaking some of its leaders and spokesmen, do not seem to have realized this fact. They speak and act as if there were indeed “a Party of the Third Part”—a portion of the population that belongs neither to the inves¬ tor nor to the non-investor group—that stands between Capital and Labor—a sort of innocent bystander, and help¬ less victim of the multitudinous quarrels and fights between the Capitalistic group and the wage earner group. In its preliminary report the Convention Committee on Social Service declared: ‘ ‘ The problem of Labor and Capi¬ tal is no longer one which concerns only, or even mainly, these two essential parties to production. As never before it is a community problem, a national problem, and an in- 298 The New Capitalism ternational problem—in a word, the problem of humanity. Frank Morrison, Secretary of the American Federation of Labor, in answer to a request for an opinion on the pre¬ liminary report, seized upon this declaration, and in the course of his analysis combated the theory that the commu¬ nity—i. e. the public—is a party to and therefore con¬ cerned in any dispute between laborers and Capitalists. He maintains in substance, that the public has no interest in the laborer—that its interest is confined to the commodities laborers produce. This, however, he maintains, does not make the public a party to industrial relations. If the public took an interest in and concerned itself with the economic welfare of the workers Mr. Morrison would probably concede the public’s concern in Labor disputes. “I believe,” said Mr. Morrison, “a fair statement of the case is that the community’s interest in the worker is founded upon its one desire for the worker’s commodities, and not upon any belief in the right of the worker; its con¬ cern is not with the wages paid to the workers, or the con¬ ditions under which they work, but rather with the con¬ tinuous operation of industry, so that its wants may be supplied without interruption. After these wants have been supplied it is a matter of no concern to the commu¬ nity what becomes of the worker. ’ ’ 1 Mr. Morrison substantially argues that if the public mani¬ fests no interest in the condition of those who labor, nor evinces any concern whether the wages paid them are suf¬ ficient to enable them to live in frugal comfort and decency, then the public has no right to consider itself an injured party when Labor finds it necessary, either in order to secure better wages, or living or working conditions, to tem¬ porarily cease its operations. I have no desire to enter into a discussion of Mr. Mor¬ rison’s views here summarized. While discerning a meas¬ ure of plausibility in his logic I question the wisdom of his stand or contentions. I do not blame him for viewing the i The National Labor Digest, August, 1920. Who Is “The Public”? 299 question purely from the worker’s standpoint, particularly since without the use of their most effective weapon—the strike—(and strikes frequently mean a temporary incon¬ venience to the 1 ‘ public ’ ’) the condition of those who labor would be what it was fifty years ago; nay, worse, in that no improvement whatever in their condition, working or living, would have been made. When Capital Goes on Strike Mr. Morrison might easily have strenghtened his argu¬ ment by asking: What interest does the public evince in those who labor when Capital sees fit to strike (as was the case for more than two years after the war and as a result of which between four and five million men and women were thrown out of work). Capital's most recent and pro¬ longed strike was not only a temporary inconvenience but a prolonged hardship, and an irreparable injury to the four or five million families of men and women who were out of work, or working only part time. Did the public pro¬ test? Did the public take a single step to end the incon¬ venience and hardships to which the four or five million men and women and their families were subjected? Did it make a single move to alleviate the suffering that Capi¬ tal’s strike had imposed? Has it concerned itself with the money losses of the four or five million; or is it particularly disconcerted by the reflection that most, if not all, of them, consumed their scant savings, while many were hurled into debt? Two Sides to the Question Even those not ordinarily disposed to favor those who work for a wage will have to admit that there are two sides to the question, and that Mr. Morrison and others who have upon occasion taken the stand that the public, which is not vitally interested in those who labor, has no right to feel aggrieved when those who labor find it necessary in order to obtain a decent wage, or to improve their condition, occa¬ sionally to inconvenience the community. In view of the 300 The New Capitalism obvious fact that the public gives scant consideration to those who labor at any time, and no consideration at all when wage earners are in trouble, it is not difficult to understand the occasional tone of bitterness one discerns in the writings and utterances of Labor leaders. One cannot blame them when they ask at least inferentially :—‘ 1 What has the public ever done for us ? What consideration does the public give us; what interest in our welfare does the public take; what gratitude does it show for the personal sacrifice we have made and as a result of which this very public is now enjoying a better standard of living than Capital was willing to concede to it? If the general public is better off than it ever was; if it has improved its general condition, is it not largely owing to the fact that we fought the public’s fight—incurring loss of wages and savings, and even jeopardizing our freedom and our lives—when we in¬ sisted on better wages and better working conditions, more reasonable hours, etc., of all of which things the public is and has been the beneficiary ? ’ ’ Wdiking Into the Trap To all of which argumentation any fair-minded person can easily subscribe. Nevertheless, and in spite of all this, I consider it unwise on the part of Labor leaders and spokesmen to indulge in harsh utterances as regards the public, particularly since it is the apparent design of the Capitalistic group to spread the idea that organized Labor is opposed to the public; that it considers its own interests superior to the interests of the public;—in brief that what¬ ever is to the interest of organized Labor is necessarily op¬ posed to the public interest and detrimental to the public’s welfare. Readers will recall the Allen-Gompers debate, in the course of which Governor Allen asked Mr. Gompers the following question: 11 When a dispute between capital and labor brings on a strike affecting the production or distribution of the neces¬ saries of life, thus threatening the public peace and impair- Who Is “The Public”? 301 ing the public health, has the public any rights in such a controversy, or is it a private war between capital and labor? If you answer this question in the affirmative, Mr. Gompers, how would you protect the rights of the public ? ’ ’ The circular announcing the publication of Governor Allen’s book, entitled “The Party of the Third Part,” com¬ pares the question Governor Allen asked Mr. Gompers to the question Lincoln addressed to Douglas in their famous debate; and adds that no matter whichever way Mr. Gom¬ pers might answer, it would ruin him . 2 I am not concerned with the Allen-Gompers debate or controversy. I wish merely to emphasize the admitted de¬ sign of Governor Allen to ruin Mr. Gompers, i. e., to dis¬ credit organized Labor in the eyes of the public; and to add that when the leaders and spokesmen of organized Labor go on record with statements which, to say the least, are ungracious, they are walking with both feet into a cleverly concealed steel trap laid by organized Capital. Or to vary the figure somewhat, they are furnishing the powder for the Capitalistic guns. The Change in Public Sentiment 1 doubt whether the public, in the mass, cherishes any serious resentment against organized Labor on account of an occasional inconvenience, or even temporary hardships, resulting from a strike either for better wages or better working conditions, for, be it remembered that the general public is principally composed of men and women who work for a wage or salary, although most of them are not organized, and do not belong to any Labor union. In a general way, then, I would say that the public \s sympathy is with organized Labor, or at least has been up to within recent years. If there has been any change in the public’s sentiment or attitude it is not on account of any temporary inconvenience resulting from an occasional cessation of work on the part of organized Labor, but rather for an 2 According - to the same circular Mr. Gompers did not answer the question, but later he issued a statement. 302 The New Capitalism entirely different set of reasons. The public—and I speak more particularly of the millions of unorganized men and women who, like those who are organized, work for a mere living wage or salary—has observed for some years now that certain organized Labor unions have used their organ¬ ized strength and power selfishly, and ruthlessly, utterly disregarding the rights or welfare of everyone else. For example, in 1919 there was a strike of the Chicago street railway motermen and conductors, and traffic was tied up. After a few days the not unreasonable demands for an increase in the wages of street railway employees were granted. But this increase in the wages of railway employees was made the excuse for a further increase in fares. Formerly the car fare was five cents; now it is eight and ten cents. This means that every man and woman who works, and who uses the street cars, surface or elevated, going to and coming from work, must now pay six or seven cents a day more than formerly—or about twenty dollars a year. 3 It is generally believed that the surface and elevated lines gained more from this increase in fare than the railway employees. In like fashion the milk wagon drivers’ strike, conducted about the same time and supposedly under similar auspices and with the same results to the general public—viz., that the average family was compelled to pay considerably more for its milk, cream and other dairy products. It has been computed that of the total amount of the increase only about 45 percent went to the drivers and other employees, and 55 percent to the operators. These are only two instances, in a single city, of hundreds that could be cited, to show how isolated groups of Labor unions in all parts of the United States, have been instru- 3 In June, 1922, the fare on the Chicago surface lines was reduced by order of the Court, to seven cents. The railway company promptly announced that the seven cent fare would result in a reduction of $9,000,000. On July 3, we read in the Chicago Daily News : "The 11,000 motormen and conductors on the Chicago Surface Lines will be asked tonight to take a wage reduction of 25 percent, or thirty cents an hour, from the present scale of eighty cents.” Who Is “The Public”? 303 mental in burdening the general public with a considerable aggregate increase in their living expenses. The recent revelations with regard to hundreds of engineered strikes, generally instituted by so-called ‘ ‘ business agents ’ ’ of Labor organizations for their own private benefit and gain, all of which are to a certain extent responsible for considerable increases in the rent item of families, to say nothing of ad¬ ditional increases in the prices of commodities manufac¬ tured or sold in buildings affected by such “hold up” strikes, have accentuated the bitterness that the general public is beginning to feel toward Labor, particularly organized Labor. The Press “Tells the World” The daily press is not allowing any opportunity of giving full publicity to every offense of this nature to escape. Thus we read in the^hicago Daily News (July 16, 1921) : “Assistant State’s Attorney E. Stanley Hodges an¬ nounced that an investigation of alleged interference with the milk supply, said to have been practised by milk wagon drivers, would be started in the near future. “ ‘I have summoned the officials of the Milk Wagon Drivers’ union for questioning,’ said Mr. Hodges, ‘and if the evidence bears out the charges made to the office we will go before the grand jury asking for indictments. “ ‘The complaints, most of which have come from Chi¬ cago housewives, charge that there is an agreement among the drivers that dealers cannot be changed—that if a cus¬ tomer wishes to buy from other milk dealers he or she is informed that it is against the rules of the union. In some instances, it is alleged, the milk supply has been cut off and the customer forced to walk to stores for it. “ ‘If there is really an interference of this sort we will stop it',’ said Mr. Hodges. ‘It is criminal to tamper with the milk supply during hot weather. In the case of families with babies it may result in death, and in that case we would be justified in holding the boycotting driver for manslaughter.’ ” 304 The New Capitalism This is only one of many similar cases that have been brought to the attention of the public within recent years. Hundreds could be cited in any big city, and thousands in the United States. It is not at all singular that the irrita¬ ting frequency of their occurrence has produced changes in the public mind and attitude in spite of the fact that a considerable portion of the public is composed of men and women who work for a wage or salary, or a recompense the equivalent of a wage. Moreover there is hardly a family that has not at some time or other, been the victim of some of the hundred and one restrictive rules and arbitrary regulations which Labor unions seem to insist upon, under the mistaken impression that they are necessary for La¬ bor’s protection and well being, and the strict observance of which generally means annoyance, discomfort, and ex¬ pense, to all not belonging to a Labor organization. When organized Labor employs high-handed tactics it is playing a losing hand. But when organized Labor allows itself to be betrayed into an attitude of seeming hostility to the public, through ill-advised or intemperate utterances of its leaders and spokesmen, it is guilty not only of blun¬ dering but of folly. A Study in Contrasts Why cannot organized Labor learn a lesson from organ¬ ized Capital? Take, for example, the following statement made by Richard S. Hawes, in his address as President of the American Bankers Association (October 19, 1920) : “ Three factors are concerned in all these misunder¬ standings (between Capital and Labor) : labor leaders, in¬ dustrial leaders, and the more often disregarded public. The latter’s interests usually suffer most, because of the rules under which the contest is held. The welfare of the general public is most important. In the settlement of dis¬ putes, consideration should be given to the effect upon the public, and full responsibility placed.” Or listen to this cooing statement made by that great humanitarian, Elbert H. Gary, who for years has been Who Is “The Public”? 305 the valiant protector of the “rights” of his employees to work twelve hours a day and seven days a week, and whose whole career has been one prolonged act of affectionate consideration for the public, and loving regard for the public welfare: “It will cheerfully be admitted that the interests of the general public, so-called, are first to be considered. When they clash with private interests, the latter must be sub¬ ordinated. On this principle our Government is founded. It is essential to the protection and happiness of all the people,” etc. 4 Compare the foregoing statements (Mr. Hawes’ and Mr. Gary’s) of tender solicitude for the public, with the brusque and caustic declaration by a representative of organized Labor. At the hearing 5 before a subcommittee of the Committee of Interstate Commerce on the Poindexter Anti-Strike Bill S. 4204 (Senator Poindexter presiding), Henry Sterling, Legislative Representative of the Ameri¬ can Federation of Labor entered a protest against the Poindexter bill. In the course of his statement Mr. Sterling said: ‘ 1 The chief reason alleged for the enactment of the anti¬ strike legislation is the convenience of the public. The public must not be inconvenienced. The public must have everything come its way, just as it should come; but did it ever occur to you, Senator, that the public does not give a damn for the man who works ? Unless he kicks and squirms and stops working he never gets a remedy for anything. ‘ ‘ The public is like the priest and the Levite that passed over on the other side. The public is the one great sinner in the industrial field. The public makes all its conditions and controls them. It is not alone that the public is indif¬ ferent ; it is positively criminal in its indifference at times. 9 The children in the mills in the South might work them- 4 “Principles and Policies of the United States Steel Corporation.” Statement fay Ellbert H. Gary, Chairman, at the Annual Meeting - of the Stockholders, April 18, 1921. 5 May 20, 1920. 306 The New Capitalism selves to death and the public would not care. It is only when the agitator comes along and points out what is the offense to the public conscience. They never will notice it unless it is pointed out. The only wrong done in the indus¬ trial conflict is to the so-called innocent third party, and as soon as we who work for a living take some effective meas¬ ures for our own welfare, then you want to put us in jail.” It is only fair to say in extenuation that ‘ ‘ the convenience of the public” was given as the chief reason for the pro¬ posed anti-strike legislation; and it was by way of answer¬ ing the “reason alleged” that Mr. Sterling delivered him¬ self as quoted. Nevertheless such statements are illumina¬ ting, in that they clearly show a confused state of mind. Confusion Everywhere There are two things I charge against organized Labor as regards its crudely stated animadversions on the public. iFirst, that it is utterly lacking in tact: Secondly, that it has no clearly defined idea as to who constitutes the public. The first charge I have sufficiently established in this chapter. But, as regards the second, I desire to urge a few palliating circumstances. Organized Labor is not alone in its confused notions regarding the constituency of the pub¬ lic. The press of the land, and men holding high official positions, cannot be credited with any greater degree of clarity than organized Labor. You .will recall, perhaps, that in 1919 the Chief Executive of the nation, Woodr6vV Wilson, called an Industrial Conference at which Capital, Labor and the Public were to be represented. Now glance at this list of the fifteen men who were invited by Mr. Wil¬ son to represent the 'public: “Among those invited and specially designated to ‘represent the Public Interest’ in this Confer¬ ence, behold Rockefeller (Standard Oil)'; Gary (Steel Trust) ; Brookings (Union Trust Co.) ; Chadbourne (Railroads); Dawes (Central Trust Co.) ; Burgess (National Banks) ; Gallaway (Cot- Who Is “The Public”? 307 ton Trust); Endicott (United Shoe Machinery, Smelting Trust, etc., etc.) ; Feiss (Clothing Trust) ; Gay (Editor, Morgan owned Paper) ; James (Manufactures and Banks) ; Jones (N. J. Zinc Trust) ; Landon (American Radiator Trust) ; Meredith (U. S. Chamber of Commerce) ; McNabb (Known in San Francisco as ‘McScab’) ; Sweet (Beet Sugar); Titus (Oil).” 6 Surely there is none to assert that these men are truly representative of the public, or deny that all of them fitted more appropriately into the Capitalistic group. In reality, in the so-called Industrial Conference, Labor had two dis¬ tinctly segregated Capitalistic groups arrayed against it— one admittedly and distinctively Capitalistic, the other also Capitalistic but masquerading as the public group. If then, Labor—more particularly organized Labor—owing to the great confusion as to who’s who, has blundered in tactics and in language against the public, its mistakes can be ex¬ plained as well as condoned. With Regard to the Future But if there has been confusion in the past there is no excuse for its continuance in the future. The new economic division clearly draws the line. The public is composed of all the people—divided into twenty percent investors and eighty percent non-investors. In the latter group we find jiractically all those who work for a wage; some are organ¬ ized, some are not. Organized Labor is in the non-investor group. Since the interests of organized Labor are identical with the interests of all non-investors, it is the height of folly for organized Labor to proceed as if it were not a component part of the non-investor group—composed of eighty percent of the population, i. e., of the general public. Consequently any move or step, any action or word on the part of the leaders or officials or representatives of the organized portion of the public, that alienates the sympathy 6 La Follette’s Magazine, October, 1918. 308 The New Capitalism and moral support of those not organized, is the acme of folly. Let organized Labor ponder over this truth before it is too late, and mend its ways. Labor’s True Strength The greatest strength of organized Labor is found—not within its own ranks—not among its necessarily limited membership, but in the sympathy and moral support of that portion of the public having no investments, and whose income is derived from wages and salaries. There, I say to organized Labor, lies your true strength. These approxi¬ mately eighty percent of the population, are your sustain¬ ing props. True, it is an unorganized strength, an unas¬ sembled power, an undirected influence—but it is up to you to organize and assemble and to direct its support in your favor—not against you. Remember that you have no press that reaches all the people; your official organs do not fall under the public eye. Remember that there are millions not actively affi¬ liated with you who derive their information about you from an unsympathetic daily press. Remember that a ma¬ jority of the population gets its slant or bias concerning your virtues or your iniquities from the papers or periodi¬ cals it reads. Avoid narrowness and selfishness. There is nothing more fatal to your aspirations than the attitude “organized Labor for itself, and may the devil take the hindmost”—a sort of “public be damned” policy. Protect the eighty million—(of which you are a con¬ siderable part). Do not segregate yourself; do not strive only to protect yourself, and let everybody else not belong¬ ing to your particular organization go hang. That is an unwise attitude, a foolish policy—a suicidal procedure. Protect the eighty million and the eighty million will sup¬ port you. Above all, put your house in order. CHAPTER XXIII The Science of Wages P OLITICAL economists are fond of smothering burn¬ ing questions in a wet blanket of quasi-technical verbi¬ age. Thus, for example, in every treatise on Political Economy, lengthy chapters appear on “Wages.” We are told, with many fine distinctions and technical differentia¬ tions, what wages are and what they are not. We are told that there is a great difference between money w r ages and actual or nominal, wages; between money wages and com¬ modity wages; between gold wages and bread wages, etc. To explain all this, some writers have found it necessary to write voluminous works covering hundreds of pages. It seems to me that the whole discussion on wages can be greatly simplified. Instead of verbosely distinguishing, with much show of learning, between money wages, and actual or nominal or commodity wages, all of which means nothing, and clarifies nothing to the man and woman who works for a wage—on the contrary, only confuses them— why not reduce the distinctions to terms comprehensible to the average man or woman? Why not express it thus: Money wages is a stipulated amount of money a man or woman receives for having performed a certain piece of work, or for having worked a certain number of hours or days. Actual or nominal or commodity wages is the amount of money that a man or woman must pay out during twenty- four hours a day for seven days a week in order to merely live and be fit to work at all. Therefore, in the aggregate, what the economists call money wages represents the amount of money a man or 309 310 The New Capitalism woman receives for, let ns say, forty-eight to sixty hours of work within a week’s time; and what they call actual or nominal wages is the amount he or she must pay out during the 168 hours constituting the week. These two definitions seem to me to cover the subject completely, for all prac¬ tical purposes. The Exchange Value of Wages—the Important Thing Since the wage earner has no alternative but to exchange his wages for the necessary living commodities the all im¬ portant thing about his wages is their exchange value. In any discussion on wages the stress is to be put on the exchange value of the wage dollar. If a small quantity of wages can purchase a given fair quantity of living com¬ modities then the exchange value of the wage dollar can be said to be high. Whereas if a large quantity of wages is demanded for the same quantity of living commodities, then the exchange value of the wage dollar can be said to be low. The exchange value of the wage dollar rises or falls inversely as prices of living commodities rise or fall. If we go back as far as 1896 and accept the value of the dol¬ lar and prices prevailing then as basic, we discover that the exchange value of the wage dollar has shrunk precisely by as many cents as prices of living commodities advanced. The wage dollar of 1920, as compared with the wage dollar of 1896, had an exchange value of only about 27 cents. This shrinkage in exchange value was produced by the rise in the cost of living commodities. It may be stated here, in passing, that there has been no rise in the exchange value of the wage dollar from 1896 to 1920—only a steady decline. It is rather singular that the political economists, so adept in inventing and formulating economic “laws” and describing their operations and effects, have thus far over¬ looked, or shall I say, ignored, what is easily the nexus of the whole wage question, viz., their exchange value. None The Science of Wages 311 of them, so far as I can recall, has ever written a chapter on this pivotal point in the entire wage controversy. Not one has ever pointed ont that at the bottom of any demand for more wages is the desperate endeavor on the part of the workers, in the face of constantly rising prices, to maintain a reasonable exchange value for their wages. Not one has ever gone to the trouble of explaining that those who labor, particularly when they are organized, may have something to say about the amount of wages that shall be paid them, but they have absolutely nothing to say about the exchange value of the wage dollar; in brief, that Labor may stipu¬ late the amount of its wages; it cannot regulate their exchange vdlue. Nor has one ever emphasized the futility of Labor’s deperate endeavor to maintain the exchange value of the wage dollar in the face of Capital’s grim determination not only to keep the quantity of wages low but also their exchange value. And yet here we have the seeds of the deadly conflict between Capital and Labor— the roots of the bitter hostility between those who pre¬ sumably pay wages and those who work for a wage. Capital Does Not Pay Wages From the very beginning Capital has been unwilling to accord more than a bare living wage—indeed less than a living wage per worker. And when Capital, a quarter of a century ago, began systematically to raise prices, making it necessary for workers to demand more wages in order to enable them to meet the various price increases—Capital¬ istic Entrepreneurs howled as if every dollar of wages apportioned to Labor came directly out of their pockets; and to this very hour they act as if the paying of wages is taking the bread out of the mouths of their own wives and children. Yet, as a matter of provable fact, Capital does not pay wages at all. Labor pays its own wages out of the values it creates. Certainly it cannot be disputed that wages are paid out of Labor’s own product. A century ago a number of economists advanced the 312 The New Capitalism “Wages Fund” theory. 1 This theory emphasized, among other things, the dependence of Labor upon Capital, and insisted that wages were paid out of Capital—a fixed and predetermined fund. The theory was in due time exploded. It is no longer held that wages are paid out of Capital. Professor Seligman says in so many w r ords that “wages are not paid out of Capital; they are only advanced out of Capital.” The amount of money advanced by Capital is taken directly out of the product of Labor—not out of any capital fund. In other words, Labor “earns its own re¬ muneration”—actually pays its own wages. Capital merely finances their payment; for its own sake and con¬ venience expedites the exchange of the products of one group of workers for those of other groups, making at the same time a profit on the transactions involved—that is on the Several turnovers. Taking industry in the aggregate it is conservative to say that in normal times there is an average of four capital “turnovers” in the course of twelve months. In some cases the turnover is quicker, in others slower—but four times a year is, I believe, a fair average. Consequently as regards the wages of the workers in an industrial estab¬ lishment the amount of money necessary to enable an employer to finance the payment of the wages of his work¬ ers is one-fourth of the total amount paid out in the course of the year. Let me reduce my statement to figures, and so as to sim¬ plify my contention still more I will select the industrial labor group for which statistics are available. In 1914 there were 7,036,337 workers engaged in 275,791 establish- i John Stuart Mill in 1869, neatly explained the “Wages Fund” theory as follows: “There is supposed to be, at any given instant, a sum of wealth which is unconditionally devoted to the payment of wages of labor. This sum is not regarded as unalterable, for it is augmented by saving, and increases with the progress of wealth ; but' it is reasoned upon as at any given moment a predetermined amount. More than that amount it is assumed the wages-receiving class can not possibly divide among them; that amount, and no less, they can not but obtain. So that the sum to be divided being fixed, the wages of each depend solely on the divisor, the number of participants.”— Quoted from “The Wages Question,” by Francis A. Walker. The Science of Wages 313 merits. Their wages aggregated $4,079,332,433, for the year. To finance the payment of the total amount of wages involved here, only one-fourth of the amount, or $1,019,833,108 was required within twelve calendar months. This amount—mark you well—was not paid out by the Capitalistic employers without any hope of ever getting it back; it was merely advanced by them for their own sake and convenience, knowing full well that through the vari¬ ous established channels of trade, all wages must quickly flow back into their coffers, to be again and again dis¬ tributed by them among the same workers, as wages. “Turnover” or “Handover” Yes! We have heard much within recent years of Cap¬ ital ‘ ‘ turnover.’ ’ It is on the turnover, or rather the frequency of turnover, we are told, that Capital makes its profits. But when we probe deeper into the subject we find that it isn’t out of the Capital “turnover” so much as out of the wage “handover” that the Capitalistic group derives its enormous profits. Those who work for a wage or salary have no alternative but to hand back to the con¬ stituent members of the Capitalistic System practically every dollar of their wages. Generally speaking what a worker earns in a week is consumed within a week. The wage he receives is not his to keep; he is compelled to hand it back. In most cases it is consumed (spent) before it is earned (received). An Economic, Paradox Did you ever stop to think that the average wage earner receives not fifty-two times twenty or thirty dollars (or whatever his weekly wage may be)—in the course of a year, but only twenty or thirty dollars—fifty-two times a year? Sounds like a paradox, doesn’t it? Well, it is a paradox— not a verbal paradox but an economic paradox—and I’ll explain precisely what I mean. He receives the same twenty or thirty dollars fifty-two times a year. Remember he must hand bach whatever he receives each iveek. It 314 The New Capitalism isn’t as if he could keep all he earns each week, and let it accumulate into a fund. His weekly wage—a stipulated amount—is turned over to him fifty-two times a year; and he is compelled to hand it back fifty-two times a year, or starve. Approximately twenty-seven million men and women work for a wage or salary. 2 With what they earn they must support themselves and their families. For their labor they receive, let us say, an aggregate of twenty billion a year from the Capitalistic System; but in the course of the year they hand their twenty billion back to the com¬ ponent members of the System. They gave twelve months of labor for the twenty billion dollars, but they had to give it practically all back in exchange for the living commod¬ ities, for food, clothing, shelter, and sundry things neces¬ sary to life, or, its minor comforts. And this performance is repeated not once in a lifetime but once every year. They receive another twenty billion the next year. No, not another twenty billion! It is the same twenty billion that they received the year before, and which, under the Capitalistic System it is not intended they shall keep. They are merely permitted to look at it for a few days, and hold it in their hands; the process of handing it back is a continuous performance. Why “Money Wages” Means Nothing Money has been defined as the yardstick of values. If we accept this definition and apply it to wages, it follows that the men and women who work for a wage or salary are paid only in yardsticks which they are not permitted to keep—only to handle for a few days. Before the end of the week the yardsticks have found their way back into the lumber-yards of those who distributed them—none too graciously; in most cases not so much as a fraction of an inch remains from the week’s supply of yardsticks. z According to Professor Alvin H. Hansen, of the University of Minnesota, there are 6,229,161 farm laborers, 2,074,792 lower salaried, 1,572,225 servants; industrial wage earners 14,556,979. unclassified 2.317.538. American Statistical Association, December, 1920. The Science of Wages 315 Money has been appropriately defined as a “medium of exchange.” It is that, and only that, to the workers—a medium that must be exchanged by them for the things needful to life. They have no alternative. Money has also been called a “circulating medium.” Aye, it is; and the compulsion to make it circulate is inherent in every wage dollar. It has been said that ‘ ‘ Profits are the wages of Capital. ’ ’ Then by the same rule of logic we ought to be able to say that “Wages are the profits of Labor.” The one is as absurd as the other. “Profits,” we are told, “is the amount that remains after all costs have been paid.” A goodly amount of profit remains to Capital after Capital has paid all costs, including labor. Whereas no profits remain to Labor after Labor has paid merely its living costs. Labor’s Meager Reward The plain truth is that the workmen and women receive nothing as a reward for their labor—nothing beyond a bare subsistence. Comparatively few—and that only by dint of the most rigid economy, manage to save a few paltry dollars. I say paltry, for the savings accounts statistics show that the savings of the eleven million depositors is only a few hundred million a year—a few dollars per capita. You may double or treble or quadruple the amount of their “savings” if you are to consider what may have been paid by them for insurance, protection, etc. Where Are the Wages of Yesteryear? If all the wage earners, which includes all salaried people and those receiving more or less regular lionoria for their services—the equivalent of a wage or salary—received an amount aggregating, let us say, an average of only ten billion dollars a year for the past twenty years, their joint earnings for the twenty years would total the stupendous sum of $200,000,000,000. What has become of this two hundred billion dollars of wages? Where is it? Whither THE WAGE EARNER’S FAMILY INCOME AND WHAT BECOMES OF IT 75 From more than a dozen different Tables, I have constructed in the course of my studies on Wages, I have compiled the above Chart as approximately showing the distribution of the Wage dollar—or rather, the average wage earner’s family income. Needless to say the figures are only approximate estimates, but, I believe, conservative and fair. In arranging the above Chart I assumed a theoretical $1500 a year income from wages for an average family, contributed by more than one worker per family. A $1500 yearly wage income would mean a wage income amounting to about $28.86 a week; or $4.11 a day. The distribution is about as follows: Rent.$225 Farm Food Prod. 225 Mfgd. Food Prod. 150 Clothes . 225 Mfgd. Com’dities $150.00 Freight . 150.00 Fuel and Light. . 37.50 Public Utilities. . 37.50 Taxes . .$150.00 Misc. .. 112.50 Savings 37.50 Total $1,500.00 There are many other ways of computing the wage income distri¬ bution. For example, you might say that the workers in a wage earner’s family work 7.7 weeks for the Landlord; 7.7 weeks for the Farmer; 5.2 weeks for the Manufacturer of Food Products; 7.7 weeks for Clothing and Wearing Apparel Manufacturers and Dealers; 5.2 weeks for the Manufacturers of and Dealers in other Living Com¬ modities; 5.2 weeks for the Railroads (Freight); 1.3 weeks each for the Fuel and Light Companies and the Public Utilities Corporations; 5.2 weeks for the Government (Federal, State, City, etc.); 3.9 weeks for the Miscellaneous Items essential to living; after wdiich they may (if they are very thrifty) keep the wages of 1.3 weeks’ work for themselves. 316 The Science of Wages 317 has it disappeared? What of all this vast sum is left to those who worked for it—earned it? I am omitting a dozen pages filled with rather interest¬ ing statistics in pursuit of this inquiry, because it would unduly lengthen this chapter. Instead I will tersely state my conclusions by saying that the average wage earner ‘ i saves 5 ’ less than five cents out of every dollar of his wages. This isn’t because he is unwilling to save, but rather be¬ cause, under present economic conditions, it is impossible. “Sixty-five percent of our people are poor”; said Professor E. A. Ross in 1918, “that is, they have little or no prop¬ erty except their clothes and some cheap furniture, and their average annual income is less than $200 per capita.” A Helpless “Capitalist” It, is all folly to say that every worker is a “ capitalist ’ ’; it is more than mere folly; it is the voice of hypocrisy speaking through the mouth of knavery. Every working¬ man and workingwoman is a capitalist, we have been told with irritating iteration during the past few years. Indeed! A queer kind of capitalist, you will admit, is he who is under compulsion to pay out every dollar of his wages week after week, merely for the roof over his head, for food for his body and clothes for his back. A queer kind of capitalist is he who has no choice but to “invest” his “capital” (labor), and his “dividends” (wages), for so many pounds of food and so many yards of cloth—and for a place in which to live. A queer kind of capitalist, who has no alternative except to let his capital and his divi¬ dends flow back through devious channels and by sundry devices into the coffers of the economic lords of creation— the constituent members of the Capitalistic group. The “Wages of Capital” But how does the Capitalistic group fare the while? Those constituting the Capitalistic group make their profits by virtue of the fact that the wage earners—the non¬ investors, are compelled to hand back to them in the form 318 The New Capitalism of rent, and the needful articles of food, clothing, etc., they must purchase in the course of a year, practically the full amount of their wages. What profit does the Capitalistic group make on this “handover” of wages? Ten percent, or twenty, or thirty, or forty, or fifty percent ? Who knows the exact amount of the profits of the Capitalistic group; who has the authentic statistics? I can compute the ‘ ‘ profits ’ ’ from a correlation of various sets of available sta¬ tistics, but this would lead us too far afield. Moreover, I am less interested at this time in the exact amount of the profits than in the principle underlying the transactions between the wage earners, i. e., the non-investors, and the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs—the Capitalistic group. Nevertheless while we are on this subject I will quote a paragraph from a minority report (on the Revenue Bill of 1921) submitted to Congress by the Honorable Claude Kitchin of the Committee of Ways and Means, and which gives an idea of the profits of some of the big corporations: “An analysis of the returns as detailed in the report of the Commissioner of Internal Revenue since January 1, 1916, up to and including the present commissioner’s report of July 12, 1921, will show that corporations in the United States made net profits from January 1, 1921, in round numbers $50,000,000,000—to be more exact, $47,000,000,000. After deducting all the taxes they paid since January 1, 1916, income, excess profits tax, and other war taxes, they have a clear profit left of $38,000,000,000, more than four- fifths of which was made by less than 10,000 corporations, and more than half of which was made by 1,026 of the big profiteering corporations, which includes the Steel Trust, the Bethlehem Steel Co., the Dupont companies, the vari¬ ous Standard Oil companies, the Coal Combine, the Woolen Trust, the Meat Packers, etc.” But whatever the exact amount of all the profits of the entire Capitalistic group may be, this is certain, that a considerable part of the profits garnered by the group is made out of the wages of the workers. View the subject from whatever angle you will; consider it from whatever The Science of Wages 319 standpoint yon please, you must arrive at this conclusion— that a considerable portion of the “profits” of the Capital¬ istic group are made out of the wages of the workers. Turning on the Searchlight All this is a demonstrable fact! Then why is Capital so determined that those who work for a wage shall receive a minimum of reward for their labor? There is no logic in Capital’s reasoning with regard to wages. What, then, is the psychology of the Capitalistic mind? Whatever charges can be made against Capital the chief Capitalistic Entrepreneurs cannot be accused of ignorance, short-sight¬ edness, or blindness. They know wdiat they are doing every hour of the day and night, and why they are doing it. Their weather eye is never closed. They know that Capital does not pay wages; that Labor pays its own wages. They know that practically every wage dollar flows back into the Capitalistic coffers, and that Capital makes a goodly por¬ tion of its profits because Labor must exchange its wages for the living commodities. They know that the more wages Labor receives the more wage earners will spend, or rather purchase; the more wage earners purchase, the greater will be the volume of business; the greater the volume of busi¬ ness the bigger will be the production, the market, and the profits. Or let me express it thus: The greater the recompense Capital grants to Labor, the greater will be the savings (and investments) of the wage earners; the greater the sav¬ ings (and investments) of the wage earners, the greater their contentment: the greater the wealth and prosperity of the nation. And one begins to wonder just why the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs are so reluctant to apportion decent wages to Labor; and why they so steadfastly fight against increasing wages. And it is still more incomprehensible why they have banded themselves together as at present, in a com¬ mon, organized endeavor to still further cut wages—cut 320 The New Capitalism them to a point clearly insufficient to enable those who work to meet the high and still rising living costs. It would not injure the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs if they would apportion decent wages, or raise wages and maintain them at a decent level. It would deduct nothing from their capital, and their wealth accumulations would proceed the same. But evidently they have concluded that by raising prices and lowering wages their profits can be considerably increased; and that their wealth will, conse¬ quently, accumulate all the faster. One discerns behind the unwilling attitude of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs with regard to the paying of fair wages, a sinister triple purpose: to crush not only those who labor for a wage or salary, but the whole tribe of non-investors into the dust; to keep them from accumulating a surplus; to hold them perpetually in economic subjection. In no other way can I explain their bitter determination to destroy organized Labor, whose chiefest offense thus far has been that it has insisted on a quantity of wages sufficient to enable workers to at least meet the steadily mounting living costs; a wage adequate for the decent maintenance of an average family. Labor’s Side of the Controversy Labor is entitled to more than it receives. Labor, far from being irrational has been more than reasonable—has been patient, long suffering, decent toward society and more than fair to Capital, though at times, particularly under the stress of great tribulations, it may have been guilty of the excesses of aroused passion. I am by no means disposed to defend physical violence. None condemns sabotage more vehemently than I do. But let us be reasonable and fair. Labor, theoretically, has natural rights, but no legal rights. Moreover, its natural rights, grudgingly admitted in normal times, and always circumscribed with legal restrictions, are, in a crisis, denied, nullified, enjoined and abrogated. It must be remembered that Labor has no other property than its ability to work— and that is a kind of property not protected by specific The Science of Wages 321 laws. Labor cannot invoke tlie power of the state either to defend its property or protect its inherent rights; while on the other hand the power of the state is frequently invoked by Capital to interfere with the natural rights of the workers. Since Labor cannot call for federal troops, the state militia or the community constabulary to protect its property, which is its labor; or defend its rights, small wonder that occasionally groups of workers, who, consider¬ ing themselves abused or aggrieved, conclude that they are dependent upon themselves—and so employ their physical strength to gain redress for their wrongs or to bring about an adjustment of their grievances. In saying all this I want it understood that I am not condoning violence; but rather I am laying some of the extenuating circumstances before the fair minded reader. The history of strikes since the inauguration of the big combines under the dominance of the Capitalistic Entre¬ preneur group, reveals that most strikes were for wage increases, and that in most cases wage increases were reluctantly granted, and only after the employment of coercive tactics on the part of the workers concerned. But whatever might be said of the tactics employed, I challenge the most ardent apologist of the Capitalistic System to prove that Labor has ever made a demand for what is unreasonable—unless you call the perfectly natural desire to live decently, and in moderate comfort, an unreasonable demand. Capitalistic Victories Certain sensitive Capitalistic souls have, within recent years, grown petulant because economic writers habitually speak of an average family and the average income per family. I, for one, am quite willing to dispense with the statistical family of five; and their statistical family in¬ come. I am perfectly willing to speak of the wages per worker. But if we accept that basis for our computations we will find that at no time have the wages per worker been sufficient to enable a family of five to live—not to say 322 The New Capitalism in decency and comfort—but merely to subsist. Oh, yes, we speak of an average family and its average income, but when we remember that there are in round numbers, forty million men, women and children “engaged in the gainful occupations” we are practically admitting that the average family is supported by tivo workers; that it takes the earn¬ ings of two persons to maintain an average family. Does not this alone prove that the Capitalistic System of Mammonisin has been gloriously victorious? It is paying less than a living wage per worker. For an amount of wages—a reward that never was, nor is it today, more than just sufficient to purchase the necessaries of life, and per¬ haps a few minor comforts—it compels two members of an average household to render service. It must be clear to anyone who has a head with which to think, that this con¬ dition constitutes not a single but a double victory for the Capitalistic-Mammonistic Entrepreneur System. One would think that the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs, contemplating the complete success of their shrewdly com¬ puted plans, would rest content with their successes and achievements, and be disposed henceforth to assume a benevolent, if not generous, attitude, toward those who labor for a wage. But no! Mammonism is like corruption that feeds on itself. The Capitalistic Entrepreneurs today, in spite of the fact that they do not pay the wages of the workers, vociferously exclaim that they are paying to Labor higher wages than they can afford to pay; and Mammon¬ ism has set its machinery—a wonderful mechanism—in motion, to bring down wages to a point where the joint earnings of two persons will no longer be sufficient to meet the living costs of an average family of five. The Vendetta The fight is waxing bitter. Those who labor for a wage are not blind to the fact that the Capitalistic System is but endeavoring to intensify and perpetuate its ancient injus¬ tice toward those who toil. They see the vast wealth accu¬ mulations of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs growing yearly The Science of Wages 323 greater; and their own wages growing less in quantity and smaller in exchange value. Stripped of cumbersome and confusing phrases the roots of the bitter quarrel between Capital and Labor are found in the unwillingness of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs to increase the exchange value of Labor’s wages. Not only is there observable an utter unwillingness to increase the amount of wages—there is evident a design to still further decrease the exchange value of the wage dollars of those who labor. Here, then, you have the relationship that exists between the Capitalistic group and the Labor group—between the Capitalistic “investor group” and the non-investor group. Relationship? Call it rather Apartship—for relationship implies some sort of connection, more or less intimate or formal; or consanguinity, close or remote; a common tie of some kind; a bond of mutual interest, or a community of interests. But there is, and there can never be as long as the present Capitalistic System exists in full foree and effect, anything even remotely resembling amity between these two mutually antagonistic groups. They are as wide apart in their status and their aims as the poles. It is more than a rift that separates them; a chasm lies between them. Prom the very nature of their diametrically opposed and conflicting interests, it is obvious that bad feeling and enmity will keep them always apart. They have, and can have, nothing in common. As long as the wage earning non-investor more or less clearly realizes what is a demon¬ strable fact—that he is permitted to retain (save) only a beggarly few cents out of every dollar of his wages, while the Capitalistic investor claims as his share profits — whether euphemistically called interest, rent, dividends, surplus, or what not—from ten to fifty cents out of every dollar of the worker’s wages, the vendetta will continue until one or the other group is annihilated, or the false principles of the economic system, responsible for the feud, are utterly destroyed. CHAPTER XXIV The Philosophy of the Quantity Wage B UT while I insist that Capital could pay, or rather apportion, a liberal quantity wage and be none the worse off for according it, it behooves me to show the reverse side of the shield to the wage earners them¬ selves. As far as the wage earner is concerned the im¬ portant thing about his wages is not the quantity but the exchange value of his wage dollar. Labor has had some¬ thing to say about the quantity of its wages, but it has had absolutely nothing to say about the exchange value of its wage dollars. This is why wage earners find themselves today, in spite of what might be called a fair sized quan¬ tity wage, in a rather desperate situation. Just as the whole labor question is one of exchange — one workman exchanging his product for the products of other workmen, (money being merely the acceptable count¬ ers with which the exchange is facilitated or consummated) —so the whole question of wages resolves itself into one of exchange value, not of quantity. A high quantity wage with a low exchange value is an economic maladjustment. If quantity were the important thing, a Russian workman receiving forty or fifty thousand rubles a day would be better off than workmen anywhere in the world; but, alas, the exchange value of his thousands of rubles is almost nil. The wage compensation of the German artisan was never so high as it is today; but the exchange value of his marks was never so low. The mere quantity wage is an ignis fatuus which if persistently pursued will lead the pur¬ suers into a morass of difficulties and the bogs of despair. When Quantity Wages Were Small Karl Marx contended that Capital derived its profits from the unscrupulous exploitation of Labor. I have no 324 Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 325 desire to enter into a discussion of the Marxian doctrine, nor of any of its derivatives and more modern variants. In this hook I am concerned less with economic gospels and theories and more with economic facts and fundamental principles. However, in the times of which Marx wrote, Capital’s exploitation of Labor was supposed to be carried on through the apportioning of a small quantity wage as Labor’s share of production. That is not true today, for since Marx wrote his indictment against Capital, wages have doubled and trebled. In the aggregate quantity wages have reached their highest point in the whole history of eco¬ nomics. But even though the high wages paid during the war were to hold from this day forth; even though Labor were to receive an ever increasing portion of its production, there would still be no relief, for the exchange value of wages is and will, under the established Capitalistic Sys¬ tem, continue to remain low. Quantity Wages and Living Cost Increases Up to 1896 wages and living costs per family, generally speaking, ran along parallel lines. It required all a man’s wage (and those of the contributing members of his house¬ hold) to pay for the essentials of living. Savings out of wages in those years were the result of a denial of the com¬ forts, enjoyments, and not infrequently, of the necessaries of life. With the dawn of the twentieth century began the ascendancy of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group. Almost immediately the intent of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs revealed itself in gradual increases in the prices of their commodities—in the gradual reduction of the exchange value of wages. Definitely speaking the High Cost of Living began about twenty-five years ago. Statisticians and economists are agreed that during the year 1896 the dollar had a maximum purchasing power—wages their maximum exchange value. Then the Trusts and monopolies were organized, as a result of which prices began to ascend; and as prices increased 326 The New Capitalism the purchasing power of the dollar decreased—and the exchange value of wages began to decline. It is to be noted that the advance in prices, particularly for articles of daily consumption, was gradual, a quarter of a cent, half a cent, a cent at a time. So gradual were these increases we scarcely noticed them; at least we did not complain. It was organized Labor that first took note of the gradual upward turn of the cost of commodities line and began to demand increases in its wages to enable it to meet the in¬ crease in the cost of commodities—living costs in general. Naturally, organized Labor fought only for itself, but it cannot be denied that the success of its own struggles for a better wage and living conditions also improved the wage and living conditions of those who were not organized— those who did not fight. Had organized Labor not waged its fight, economic serfdom and peonage would have resulted long ago. But in spite of its valiant fight organized Labor has been only partially successful in its attempts to keep its wages running parallel with living costs. In spite of the fact that it has succeeded in compelling several increases in the quantity of its wages it has not succeeded in narrowing the distance between the two lines. It did not succeed in maintaining the exchange value of wages. I need hardly emphasize that in 1914-1919 a new eco¬ nomic era began. Immediately after the war began prices of practically everything advanced rapidly; this time not a quarter of a cent, a half cent or a cent at a time, but by nickles and dimes, and quarters, and dollars. By 1919 living costs were practically double what they were in 1914. (This time the landlords took a hand in the increases, and it must be said that they made up for the time they lost from 1900 to 1914.) To meet the sudden and tremendous increases in living costs, organized Labor demanded further increases in its wages. These demands were, in the main, granted without a prolonged struggle on the part of Labor, or sullen resist¬ ance on the part of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. The Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 327 Government had adopted the stupid 10 percent plus cost system, and no matter how much Labor demanded or re¬ ceived, the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs and constituent mem¬ bers of the Capitalistic System were the beneficiaries. In fact the more wages Labor received the greater the cost, and the greater the profits of the employers of Labor. The system was satisfactory both to the workers and the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. Both imagined themselves in the seventh economic heaven. Thousands of wage earners were receiving a greater quantity of wages than ever before in their lives. Small wonder that many of them completely lost their heads, imagining themselves richer by so many dollars a day, a week or a month. It was only the quantity of wages they saw; they did not stop to consider that the increase in the quantity was granted to enable them to meet the quantity increase in price. The exchange value of their wages had not risen a single point. The Simple Arithmetic of Wage Increases Professor Kemmerer has said that compared to the dol¬ lar of 1913 the dollar of 1920 had a value of only 38 cents. 1 What does this mean? It means that if we consider the wages paid in 1913 as basic the wage dollar was a 100 cent dollar; whereas the wage dollar in 1920, on account of the tremendous increase in the prices of living commodities, had an exchange value of only 38 cents. The following Table shows the comparative exchange value of wage dol¬ lars in 1913 and 1920: Exchange Value of Wages in 1913 $ 1.00. 5.00. 10.00. 15.00. 20.00. 26.00. 30.00. 40.00. 45.00. 50.00. Exchange Value in 1920 .$ .38 . 1.90 . 3.80 . 5.70 . 7.60 . 9.50 . 11.40 . 15.20 . 17.10 . 19.00 l “High Prices and Deflation,” by Edwin Walter Kemmerer. 328 The New Capitalism Still another way of expressing it is to say that for a given quantity of living commodities which in 1913 could have been purchased for one dollar of wages, it was neces¬ sary to pay $2.63 of wages in 1920. The following com¬ parative Table shows the amount of wages required in 1913 and 1920 to purchase a given quantity of living goods: 1913 1920 $ 1.00 5.00 10.00 15.00 20.00 25.00 30.00 35.00 40.00 45.00 50.00 100.00 $ 2.63 13.15 26.30 39.45 52,60 65.75 78.90 92.05 105.20 118.35 131.50 263.00 And so on. It is clear, therefore, that unless the workers in 1920 received $2.63 of wages for every dollar of wages they received in 1913, they were worse off in 1920 than in 1913. The Proof of the Pudding I can understand why those who are deriving vastly in¬ creased profits from the considerably higher prices, in order to exonerate themselves from the suspicion of profiteering, pretend that the higher wage paid to Labor is responsible for the higher prices they are charging for Labor’s prod¬ ucts; but I cannot understand why Labor continues stup¬ idly to insist that it has been vastly benefited by its several wage increases, and that, too, in the face of an overwhelm¬ ing amount of evidence to the contrary. The very fact that Labor has demanded more and more wage increases proves conclusively that its aggregate wage increases dur¬ ing the past twenty years, have not been equal to the aggregate price increases during the same period. All sta¬ tistics show this conclusively. I have said, and I will repeat it, that while Labor has Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 329 had something to say about the quantity of its wage, it has had nothing whatever to say about the exchange value of its wages. But even as regards the quantity of its wage, Labor has been unable to maintain anything like a parity between wages and living costs, as the following statistics clearly show: Union Scale of Wages and Hours of Labor, May 15, 1918. Bulletin No. 259 (October, 1919), of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. From the figures in Tables 8 and 10 of the comparative increase in rates of wages and in retail prices of food between 1907 and 1918 may be stated in percentage form, thus: Atlanta .Weekly rates of wages increased 43 percent Retail prices of food increased 109 percent Baltimore.Weekly rates of wages increased 41 percent Retail prices of food increased 125 percent Boston .Weekly rates of wages increased 34 percent Retail prices of food increased 99 percent Chicago .Weekly rates of wages increased 35 percent Retail prices of food increased 102 percent Cincinnati .Weekly rates of wages increased 37 percent Retail prices of food increased 106 percent Denver .Weekly rates of wages increased 38 percent Retail prices of food increased 91 percent New Orleans.Weekly rates of wages increased 33 percent Retail prices of food increased 109 percent New York .Weekly rates of wages increased 27 percent Retail prices of food increased 101 percent Philadelphia .Weekly rates of wages increased 51 percent Retail prices of food increased 97 percent Pittsburgh .Weekly rates of wages increased 44 percent Retail prices of food increased 104 percent St. Louis .Weekly rates of wages increased 40 percent Retail prices of food increased 119 percent San Francisco.. Weekly rates of wages increased 34 percent Retail prices of food increased 74 percent Seattle .Weekly rates of wages increased 39 percent Retail prices of food increased 90 percent The significance of these statistics grows when it is re¬ membered that over 40 percent of the average family budget goes for food. 330 The New Capitalism The following statistics of the Department of Labor (published in 1921) giving the comparative index numbers for union tvage rates and for the cost of living, strikingly illustrate the utter inadequacy of quantity wage increases. Year Union Wage Rates Cost of Liv 1913 100 100. 1914 102 103. 1915 102 105.1 1916 106 118.3 1917 112 142.4 1918 130 174.4 1919 148 199.3 1920 189 216.5 Labor's Emphasis on Quantity I do not blame wage earners for putting all the emphasis on the quantity of their wages, nor for believing that the size of their pay envelope is the all important thing, and that the more wages they receive the better off they are. I do not blame them for insisting on big wages to meet their already big living costs; nor for demanding wage increases to meet increasing living costs; nor for objecting to wage reductions, particularly in the face of the provable fact that living costs have not been materially reduced, in fact are, in the aggregate, fully as high as they were in 1920. Since his pay envelope is the only thing that stands between the wage earner and the poorhouse, small wonder that he attaches so great an importance to its size. His labor is the wage earner’s only productive property, but under the Capitalistic System it is not intended that that property shall receive any other reward than a mere liv¬ ing—and even that is grudgingly granted. Nevertheless it is a tremendous mistake to imagine that a big quantity wage is the supreme economic desideratum, or a panacea for all economic ills. No greater misconcep¬ tion is possible; no greater economic fallacy has ever en¬ tered into the heads of men; no greater delusion has ever played havoc with the imagination of the average man and Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 331 woman who works, whether with hand or head. From the very beginning I have held that the greatest mistake that Labor ever made was to demand an increase in wages every time the cost of living advanced. What Labor should have insisted upon was not more wages but a greater ex¬ change value for its wages. If Labor had stood pat twenty years ago—if Labor had not demanded—if Labor had (oh, vagrant idealism!) positively refused to accept more money wages but insisted instead on a stabilized exchange value for its wages—the cost of living could never have mounted, and the complex economic problems that now harass us could never have attained their present proportions and gravity. If Labor twenty years ago had been able to see beyond the tip of its own nose it could have compelled an adjustment on the part of the Capitalistic group which would have forestalled future trouble, and rendered im¬ possible of occurrence the many evils that afflict the world today. In making the quantity of its wages the para¬ mount issue, Labor has done itself an almost irretrievable injury. I do not blame Labor for its strabismus; nor Labor lead¬ ers for following the line of least resistance, or choosing the easiest way out of what seemed to them a dilemma—in reality enmeshing themselves inextricably in (a vicious circle. I dare say that Labor, individually and collectively, had not concerned itself with economics; in fact hardly knew that there was such a thing as the ‘ ‘ science ’ ’ of Politi¬ cal Economy. It was not until the Trusts were organized and the relationship between wages and the cost of living was thrown out of plumb, that a few—a very few—among those who toil, began to think hazily along economic lines; and I fear me much that there has been considerable muddled thinking ever since. The great control that certain Labor leaders in the olden days gained over the rank and file of workers was directly traceable to this wrong concept regarding quantity wages. The rank and file of workers grumbled to their leaders. But every complaint on the part of the rank and file was 332 The New Capitalism invariably met by the statement: “Yon used to get $1.50 a day. I got you $3.00 a day; ain’t you satisfied?” The argument was unanswerable. It was true! After all, their leaders were responsible for the higher wages they were now receiving. Not one of them ever saw that the higher wage carried with it no increase of purchasing power. Not one discerned that increase in the quantity of wages carried with it a proportionate decrease in the exchange value of the wage dollar. Painted Victories Samuel Gompers, President of the American Federation of Labor, in Collier’s Weekly (November 27, 1920) said: “By hard fighting the American working people have left behind them one abuse after another. They have taken the children out of the industries, they have abolished the sweat shop, they have reduced the hours of labor, they have renovated the whole factory system, they have given the workman a place respected in the community, they have taken away his rags and removed from him forever the badge of inferiority. Much of this progress has been gained through the ability of workers to organize cessa¬ tions of work. ’ ’ Mr. Gompers, and other Labor leaders and champions, may be pardoned for pointing with swelling pride to some of the palliative measures that have been established through legal enactments, principally at the behest of or¬ ganized Labor, such as improved sanitary conditions; limit¬ ing the hours of labor, abolishing the sweat shop, greater protection against accident or disease, better working con¬ ditions for women and children; the minimum wage; the employers’ liability act, the compensation act, and sundry benefits by law secured, but the resultant cost of every “benefit” secured by organized Labor has .been perma¬ nently charged up to increase in the cost of production, overhead expense, fixed charges, etc., and is being paid for by Labor itself, via the medium of higher prices. Indeed the supposed benefits of all remedial or protec- Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 333 tive labor laws have invariably re-acted on the entire non¬ investor group. Whatever increases in wages have been gained by the well organized Labor groups have been charged up as increases in cost of production, and are being paid by those who are organized and those who are not organized, many of whom have had no increases in wages. When the winning of a fight for better wages by one small group of non-investors means a loss to all the other non-investors, it is, to say the least, a sorry victory for the beneficiaries. When seventy percent of the workers are penalized for the benefit of the other thirty percent, something is radically wrong in the formula. But ignoring, for the present, the deleterious effects of wage increases on the general public, and putting the best possible interpretation upon organized Labor’s well meant fight to improve its own condition (and incidentally the condition of all non-investors) can organized Labor be said to have been successful, even with regard to itself? If twenty-five years ago the average wage per worker was, let us say, $12.00 a week, and is today as the result of a series of stubborn strikes, $24.00 a week, is not that suffi¬ cient proof that Labor has been victorious—that it has im¬ proved its condition 100 percent. If living costs had remained where they were twenty years ago, and Labor had succeeded in doubling its wages the while, it could, indeed, claim that it has bettered itself. But living costs did not remain stationary; they moved forward more rapidly, and generally considerably ahead of the increase in wages. The relative distance between liv¬ ing costs and wages is the same today as it was twenty, or thirty, or forty years ago. The exchange value of wages is no greater; and the purchasing power of money and savings is considerably less than in those former years. To clinch the matter let me ask—Is a workman who re¬ ceives $12.00 a week, and who hands the $12.00 back to those from whom he received it in order to live, worse off than the worker who receives $24.00 a w^eek and who must 334 The New Capitalism hand the entire $24.00 back to those from whom he received it, in order merely to subsist? If the wages of every worker were increased by one thousand dollars a year, and living costs were to be in¬ creased by one thousand dollars, it is clear that wage earners would be no better off. And if the workers’ wages were increased another thousand dollars the following year, and living costs likewise advance another thousand dollars, still they would be no better off. Is it necessary to pursue this point further ? Is it not clear that there is no economic salvation, no hope of amelioration, in mere quantity wages ? When Bubbles Burst There are, no doubt, those who belong to that school of philosophy which pretends to see ‘‘books in the running brooks, sermons in stones, and good in everything,” and who will urge that the larger quantity wage means a more extensive purchasing ability—that is to say, that a larger variety of things can be bought with more dollars than with fewer dollars. I shall not argue to the contrary; indeed, for the sake of better stating my point, I ’ll pretend that the larger amount, even though it has no greater exchange value—no greater purchasing power—is prefer¬ able. Have we not a better standard of living today than was enjoyed twenty or thirty or forty years ago? Yea! Are not people today buying more luxuries, enjoying more com¬ forts than they did twenty or thirty or forty years ago? Again I ’ll agree! But then I will say in rebuttal that, deluded by mere quantity increase, so high have we raised our standard of living that we will not be able to maintain it much longer. Surely there is none to deny that the re¬ cession has already begun. Millions today are not living in the same way they were living even five years ago. Much curtailment in quantity and quality of essential foods, and other living commodities is observable. Replacement is slower. The more careful husbanding of the current re¬ sources has become imperative. Saving is almost out of the question. Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 335 Economic Maladjustments Beyond a doubt more social and economic maladjust¬ ments are observable during the past twenty years than during all the centuries preceding, and most of them are directly traceable to the insane notion that a larger quantity of wages means greater prosperity for the recipient. The greatest wrong that has come from the system of high wages and low exchange value is that it has made ‘millions of people reckless and extravagant. When quantity wages w T ere lower, but carried with them a high exchange value, people spent conservatively; they watched their pennies and nickels and dimes. A few dollars were saved. When quantity wages increased, accompanied by a proportionate decrease in exchange value, unfortunately most wage earn¬ ers saw only the increase in quantity; they did not see that the exchange value of every wage dollar had actually and automatically declined. In reality they were no better off! But this they did not see, and do not seem to com¬ prehend. Many of them followed the line of least resist¬ ance—“easy come, easy go.” The old virtues of economy and thrift went flying through the window. Wages were spent without thought and without sense. It will, I fear, take some time before thousands of wage earners will change the bankrupting, poverty-bringing habits they acquired during a period of seeming, and only seeming, prosperity. 4 Let us be honest with ourselves. Black clouds are gath¬ ering in the heavens overhead, heavens from which the once radiant star of hope has all but disappeared. How long will it be before the storm will break? We have begun to descend from the mountain top. The only ques¬ tion is how long will it take to complete the downward journey; how many times will we stumble and fall in the ipevitable descent. We may not be entirely exhausted when we reach the bottom, but we shall realize then—too late—that our dream is o’er—that we have descended into a vale of tears—only to enter the deeper valley of death. If I see more than others it is not because I have a deeper 336 The New Capitalism ken and a keener vision, but because I have looked longer and with more careful eyes. I pray that the years to come may reveal that my fears were, if not unfounded, at least exaggerated. Hard Facts Returning once more to the earth, out of the realm of visions, I have no hesitancy in saying that Labor—organ¬ ized and unorganized—has never had a single real triumph; it has never gained a vital point in any controversy; its victories were always concessions. Its several wage in¬ creases have only added to its and our living costs. Not a single benefit that is real, not a single advantage that is clear cut and permanent has ever been accorded to Labor by the constituency of the Capitalistic System. Labor has won in some of the minor skirmishes; it has won a few strikes; it has gained a few trivial concessions; it has a few favorable wage compromises to its credit. But until Labor can say that it has increased the exchange value of the wage dollar it cannot boast of any substantial triumph. The Perpetual Interest Charge on Wages There is still another point that must not be overlooked with regard to quantity wages. It will not be disputed that Labor pays its own wages; whatever the quanta— Labor pays it to itself. But not only does Labor pay its own wages, it also pays the interest on its wages. Conse¬ quently the greater the quantity of wages Labor receives the greater the amount of interest it must pay on its own wages. This is a most astounding fact, one rarely dis¬ cussed by economic writers. And yet it is one of the most important points in the whole wage question—so important that I shall be at some pains to make it perfectly clear to even the humblest intellect among us. It will not be denied that Capital considers every dollar of wages paid for the production or construction of per¬ manent goods as an investment. Therefore, Capital charges wages permanently against the property, and insists on Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 337 collecting interest on the total amount of wages paid, per¬ petually, from the public—the constituent majority of which is composed of wage earners. Let me explain just what I mean. The House that Jack Built Let us say that in the year 1905 a group of twenty workmen, each receiving $2.00 a day, completed a house, doing all the work, excavating, masonry, bricklaying, wood¬ work, plastering, painting, etc., within forty days. The house, when completed, and lot—represent, let us say, an investment of $6,000. Of this amount Labor received $1,600. Please note that the item of labor will henceforth be included in the investment value, and interest on it will be computed not once, but once every year thereafter. Now let us say that John Brown, one of the men who worked on the building, rents it from the owner (who com¬ puted the rental, let us say, at 8 percent on his investment), for $40 a month, or $480 a year, and lives in it for fifteen years. What happens? John Brown, the tenant, actually pays 8 percent on all the wages paid to those who built the house in which he lives. He pays $480 a year rental. Of this amount $128 is interest on the $1,600 of wages paid to himself and nineteen other workmen. 2 John Brown received as wages for the forty days work he did on the house he occupies, a total of $80; but he pays interest not only on the amount he himself received, but also on the amount the other nineteen workmen received. A fifteen years’ tenancy in that building means that John Brown will have paid a total rental of $7,200, of which amount $1,920 is computable as interest on the wages paid to the .workmen who constructed the house fifteen years ago. In other words John Brown paid, in the course of fifteen years, in the shape of rent, $1,920 interest on $1,600 2 Not only does John Brown pay interest on the wages he and nineteen other workmen who built the house in which he lives, received; he also pays interest on the wages the workers who fashioned the materials, tools, etc., received. 338 The New Capitalism wages he and nineteen other workmen received fifteen years ago. The House that Jack’s Son Built Bnt living costs have gone np. John Brown and his fel¬ low workmen demanded and received sundry increases in wages. In 1920, let us say, John Brown’s son and his fel¬ low workers, all following the trades of their fathers, are receiving each a wage of $8.00 a day. Just to illustrate the effect of this let us say that the lot, and all the material, are the same price as they were in 1905—that the building trades alone had wage increases. In that case the twenty workmen, each working forty days and receiving $6.00 a day, would be receiving $240 per man, or a total of $4,800. This would bring the value or cost of the $6,000 property up to $9,200. John Brown, Jr., rents the building. Assuming that the landlord is content with 8 percent on his investment, John Brown, Jr., will be paying $61.33 rent a month, or $736 a year. John Brown, Jr., received $240 as his share for the labor done on the building he now occupies as a tenant. When he pays his rent he pays, as interest, on his own and the wages nineteen other workmen received while build¬ ing the house in which he lives—a total of $384 a year. In the course of fifteen years he will have paid as interest on $4,800 wages which he and nineteen other workmen re¬ ceived fifteen years ago—a total of $5,760. John Brown is considerable of an optimist, not to say, cheerful idiot— if he considers himself better off than his father. 3 Another Illustration Surely there is none to deny that every dollar of wages that has been paid for the construction of the railroads in the United States has become a permanent part of the in¬ vestment, and the public today is paying interest on those wages. So will the generations to come. Tens of thousands of those whose labor built the railroads are dead and gone— 3 And what holds for dwellings is likewise true of all buildings, offices, stores, shops, factories, warehouses, storage houses, etc. Philosophy of the Quantity Wage 339 but the wages they once received are still carried on the books of the companies as an investment; and interest on that wage investment of tens of thousands of dead and buried workers is still demanded from us. 4 Here is food for thought. Labor not only pays its own wages, but pays the interest on the wages of all workers. And these interest charges, as shown in the case of dwell¬ ings, the railroads, and many other properties, or commodi¬ ties, are perpetual. On the wages Capital pays once in a current year, Capital charges interest for a long period of years. The higher the aggregate wage the greater the interest charge on the entire volume of wages paid. 5 It is a vicious circle. All that Labor receives as wages is paid back in the shape of rent or interest, one way or another. Let Labor sit up and take notice. “It Makes a Difference Whose Ox Is Gored” What w r ould you say if I were to argue that since the wages paid for the production, or construction, of perma¬ nent goods became a permanent and integral part of an investment, then it follows that those whose labor increased the value of the property, and gave permanency to the investment, ought to reap the benefit? Beyond a doubt a cry of horror and the chorus shout of “Absurd!” from the lips of millions,—constituents and beneficiaries of the Capitalistic System,—would rent the air. And yet the intimation I put forth is less absurd 4 It is bad enough that the public is compelled to pay interest perpetually on wages that were paid for the construction of the rail¬ roads and the materials that went into them decades and scores of years ago; but the heinousness of compelling the public to pay interest on wages that were never paid, and high priced materials that were never put into the properties, on the basis of “replace¬ ment valuation,’’ must be obvious to the veriest tyro in economics. 5 It can be shown that the public pays interest also on all wages paid for the production of transient goods—goods to which no permanency attaches—the consumptive products, such as shoes, clothes, all kinds of wearing apparel, fabrics and textiles, food articles, perishable goods, coal, etc. etc., the difference being that the interest is computed once on the gross volume of the goods produced within twelve months. In the case of transient goods the wage invest¬ ment is repetitive and interest is collected from the public from year to year. Whereas, in the case of permanent goods the wage investment is considered permanent, the interest charge is perpetual, and Capital collects it year after year. It’s a distinction without a difference. The public pays. 340 The New Capitalism than the actual practice of the Capitalistic System of today, by virtue of which wages paid once are made to appear perpetually on the books of corporations, and on which wages interest is collected year after year from the very persons whose labor enhanced the value of the invest¬ ment, from the wage earners, the non-investors, the public. I am merely asking a question; I am putting forth no ad¬ vocacy in this paragraph; but it seems preposterous that those who gave not a single hour of labor should be the per¬ petual beneficiaries of the permanent value which wage earners admittedly gave to their investment. But I do not want to pursue this most interesting argu¬ ment to its logical end. To do so would be interesting, but alien to the purposes of this book. The one point, however, that I wish to emphasize is this: If those whose labor added a certain value to various kinds of properties—are not to derive a benefit other than a wage—at least they ought not to be penalized and made to pay perpetual inter¬ est on the wages they, or their associates, may once have received. Quantity—Not the Ultima Thule I have emphasized that mere quantity wages is not the summum bonum nor should it be the ultima thule of any economic arrangement. The exchange value is the impor¬ tant thing. Today Labor is receiving what might be called a maximum wage, but the exchange value of its wages was never lower. This is a point which Labor owes to itself to un¬ derstand fully. Nothing is gained by self-delusion. Certainly I who am writing this book will not deceive those who work for a wage. I would have them know the truth. I will not lie to them. I will not indulge in ambiguity; I will not equivocate. Until the lesson that the exchange value of wages is the crux of the wage question is learned, no progress can be made. The Genesis of Wages and Living Costs CHAPTER NXY I N this chapter I shall confine myself to a brief discus¬ sion of a few of the salient points entering into a com¬ parative study of Wages and Prices. In the minds of most people there is a more or less confused notion, sedu¬ lously propagated by the myrmidons of the Capitalistic En¬ trepreneurs, that wages and prices are intimately connected —that wage increases are responsible for price increases, etc. A moment’s reflection would dispel this altogether erroneous impression; for in every instance prices went up first; wages were increased afterwards (reluctantly enough) to enable wage workers to meet the previously advanced prices. In view of which indisputable fact we may eliminate wage increases as a came for price increases; just the reverse is true. To say or to lead people to believe that wage increases are responsible for increases in living costs, is putting the cart before the horse—a deliberate falsehood. 1 A Basic Economic Lie I’ll waste no time in verbosely proving what everybody knows, that naturally enough wages enter into the cost of commodities—but wages is not the only item that enters in; as a matter of fact wages are, for many commodities, the smallest item. Several economic writers have recently stated that wages constitute 70 percent of the cost—an absurd statement utterly disproved by hundreds of sets of statistics. 0. -A. Mather, a staff writer of the Chicago Tribune, in l W. Jett Lauck in a highly interesting and illuminating pamphlet of 92 pages, prepared for the United States Railroad Labor Board, shows conclusively that increased wages to labor are in no way responsible for increased prices. 341 342 The New Capitalism an article (October 18, 1921), gives some interesting sta¬ tistics pertaining to this subject. According to these sta¬ tistics the wages of railroad employees, who, it is dinned into our ears, receive the highest recompense of all workers, in 1901 represented 38.8 percent of earnings; in 1916, 41 percent; in 1917, 43.7 percent; in 1918, 54 percent; in 1919, 55.4 percent, and in 1920, at the peak, 60.0 percent. In other industries: Wages in the United States Steel Corporation, for example, amounted to 33 1-3 percent of earnings; General Motors Corporation 38 percent; Inter¬ national Harvester Co. 40 percent. 2 Some, not content with giving the impression that Labor receives the lion’s share of all production, have gone even further. Representative J. W. Fordney, author of the Fordnev Tariff Bill, which contained the notorious ‘ ‘ Amer- ican valuation” plan, speaking before the State Manufac¬ turers’ Association in Chicago (September 29, 1921) said: “There is not a manufactured article produced in the United States in which the labor cost is less than 90 per¬ cent of the total cost.” Congressman Fordney may hide behind the subterfuge that “wages” and “labor cost” are not one and the same thing, but the general public doesn’t know how to differentiate; in the mind of the average per¬ son the two are closely allied, if not identical. James B. Morman, economist for the Federal Farm Labor Board, in an article September 17, 1921 issue of The Magazine of Wall Street says: “We find that the one dominant factor in changing price levels is the labor ele¬ ment.” “The cost of labor,” he says further on, “is the all-important and general factor.” And then he proceeds to explain that in “labor costs” are included not only wages actually paid to wage earners, but salaries, commis¬ sions, and even profits. Here are his words: “Summing up the entire problem we find that the one 2 In all probability these percentages include salaries of officials, managers, etc. If wages paid to wage workers alone were com¬ puted, the percentage would be considerably lower than those given by the corporations. So, too, would the wages per wage earner be less than reported. Wages and Living Costs 343 dominant factor in changing price levels is the labor element. It is true that a few other incidental elements enter into and affect prices in the processes of transporting, manufacturing and retailing products, but the all-impor¬ tant and general factor is the cost of labor. Even what are called ‘profits,’ ‘commissions’ and other costs for han¬ dling raw materials or goods in unfinished or finished form are the ‘wages’ charged by middlemen for services of themselves and their employees in the processes of pass¬ ing such products on toward the ultimate purchaser for use or consumption. The mere difference in terms does not alter the principle involved whether the remuneration is called wages, salary, commission or profits. ’ ’ 3 If all these things are included under “labor costs” no wonder Congressman Fordney says “labor costs” consti¬ tute 90 percent of the total cost. I am unable to understand why Labor allows the Capi¬ talistic claim that wage earners receive the lion’s share of recompense, to go unchallenged. A principle is involved, of which wage earners owe it to themselves to make an issue. Hasn’t Labor a head as well as a fist ? Speaking for myself, I should like to have all those who assert that wages constitute 70 percent of the cost of commodities, and those who, like Mr. Fordney, declare that labor cost is not less than 90 percent of the total cost —prove their contention —let us say, for example, with regard to steel rails, or any other manufactured article for the matter of that; or for a commodity such as coal, for example. The “Percentage” Device But let us pursue our studies anent prices and wages. No! Wage increases are not responsible for increases in prices of commodities, or in living costs in general. This is so obvious that I almost consider it a waste of space to dwell at length on this point. The utterly dishonest and disreputable Capitalistic device of computing increases in 3 Excerpt from "Why Commodity Prices Fluctuate,” by James B. Morman, in The Magazine of Wall Street, September 17, 1921. 344 The New Capitalism percentages , is responsible for the wrong impression that has taken hold of the average person’s mind—that wage in¬ creases are responsible for price increases, or for what collectively we call increased living costs. It is to be re¬ gretted that the average man or woman has neither the time, nor facilities, for examining into this subject. It is indeed remarkable that not one of the hundreds of writers on economic subjects, whose writings are regularly pub¬ lished in the daily press, in financial, trade papers and commercial periodicals, have ever gone to the trouble of ex¬ posing the scurvy trick. “There can be no doubt,” says one so-called economic writer, ‘ ‘ that if a hat-maker receives $1.50 a day for making hats that sell for three dollars apiece, and his wages have been increased 100 percent—so that he now earns three, that the increase in wages neces¬ sarily raises the price of each hat to six dollars.’’ The questions in the case of the hatmaker to be answered are: How many hats does the hatmaker turn out in a day, and how many cents will his $1.50 (or 100 percent) increase in wages add to the cost per hat? But most pseudo-economic writers prefer not to bother with such trifling details. It seems to be so much simpler, and alto¬ gether more convenient and satisfactory, to deal in per¬ centages. George E. Roberts, Vice President of the National City Bank of New York, in one of his pamphlets says: “People seem inclined to blame the big corporations, ‘ big business, ’ the ‘trusts,’ or somebody in that category, for the rising costs of living. But the price tables show that the prices of manufactured goods have increased by lower percentages than the cost of the labor and the raw materials that en¬ tered into them.” This is a typical example of Capitalistic camouflage— an artistic blending together of half truths, perversions of the truth and just plain lies. I challenge Mr. Roberts to substitute for the dishonest percentage basis of figuring increases, the dollars and cents basis, which if he will do a different state of affairs than he claims, will be revealed. Wages and Living Costs 345 The “Cent” System versm the “Percentage System” I call for the abrogation of the Percentage System of computing increase in costs and prices, and the substitution of the cent system. Let me briefly illustrate the difference in principle between the two systems. Let us say that when the basic price of hogs was $6.00 per hundredweight (six cents a pound) the wholesale slaughterer sells the hog products to the retail dealer for twelve cents a pound; and the retail dealer sells same to the public for eighteen cents a pound. Now let us say that the price of hogs has gone up to $12 per hundredweight—an increase of six cents per pound, or rather an increase of 100 percent. This 100 percent increase is passed along to the consumer. Under the ex¬ tortion of the Percentage System of figuring increases the retail dealer now pays twenty-four cents a pound for the hog products, and sells same to the public for forty-eight cents a pound. The percentage increase formula reads about as follows: Basic Prices 100 per cent increase per pound Prices per pound Hogs . 6 cents Hogs .12 cents Hog products to dealer. 12 cents Hog products to dealer. 24 cents Same to the public.18 cents Price of same to public.. 48 cents The consumer pays three separate 100 percent increases. But under the cent system of figuring increases the formula would be as follows: Basic Prices Six cents increase per pound Prices per pound Hogs . 6 cents Hogs .12 cents Hog products to dealer. 12 cents Hog products to dealer.. 18 cents Same to the public.18 cents Same to public .24 cents This'would be fair and reasonable—the consumer would pay the actual number of cents increase in the basic cost once , not a 100 percent increase three times (or oftener) as is the case under the Percentage System of computing increases. 346 The New Capitalism The Science of Profiteering It is under the guise of this Percentage System of com¬ puting increases that profiteering has been raised to the dignity of a science. It is not difficult to see that since the average commodity passes through three or four hands before it ultimately reaches the consumer, each person or firm figuring percentage of increase, that the sale price will reach such a sightly figure, even though the increase in wages per unit of production, figured in dollars, or cents, is trifling. Thus, for example, if the item of wages on a given article which the manufacturer sells to the wholesaler for one dollar is 30 cents, and the wages go up 100 percent, or to 60 cents, the manufacturer will raise his price to the wholesaler 100 percent, or to $2.00. The wholesaler, who used to sell the article to the retailer for $1.50, will now raise the price 100 percent, or to $3.00. The retailer, who used to sell it for $2.00, will now sell it for $4.00. This example is intended to show the principle of the Percentage System in figuring wage and price increases. The point to be emphasized is that the final purchaser, alias the ultimate consumer, pays three (or more) separate 100 percent increases. It is an excellent system from the profiteer’s standpoint. For the sake of greater emphasis, I’ll repeat, that in all cases prices were advanced before wages were increased. But even if the wage increases had preceded increases in commodity prices, or in living costs, it could be shown that in all cases the increase in prices, per unit of produc¬ tion, were considerably greater than the increases of the workers’ wages. A single specific example will suffice to illustrate my contention: In 1915, according to the Shoemakers’ Journal, August, 1921, the amount of wages paid for making a pair of a given quality of men’s shoes, was 60 cents;-this shoe sold retail for $3.50. In 1918 the amount of wages paid for making the same shoe was $1.02 —an increase in wages of 62 cents per pair; Wages and Living Costs 347 but the retail price was advanced to $10 and $12 —an in¬ crease to the consumer from $6.50 to $8.50 a pair. Steel Prices and Wages That the quantity increase in prices, per unit of produc¬ tion, is, generally speaking, considerably greater than the quantity increase in wages per unit, is bountifully exem¬ plified in the steel industry, for which complete data for wage and price increases are available. The data for wages are from the official announcement made by Elbert H. Gary, Chairman of the Board of Directors, August 19, 1921; and those for prices are taken from the Iron Age: Feb. 1, 1915 $2.00 Feb. 1, 1916 2.20 May 1, 1916 2.50 Dec. 15 , , 1916 2.75 May 1, 1917 3.00 Oct. 1, 1917 3.30 Apr. 16 ,1918 4.80 Aug. 1, 1918 4.20 Oct. 1,1918 4.62 Feb. 1, 1920 5.06 May 16 , 1921 4.05 July 16 , 1921 3.70 Aug. 29 ',1921 3.00 * Price not given. Bessemer Bessemer Steel Rail Pig Iron at at Mill Pittsburgh $28.00 $14.55 28.00 21,51 33.00 21.95 38.00 35.68 38.00 45.15 * 37.25 55.00 36.15 55.00 36,60 55.00 36.60 55.00 42.90 47.00 26.16 47.00 22.84 47.00 21.96 Bessemer Basic Pig Steel Billets Iron F.O.B at Pittsburgh Furnace $19.50 $12.50 33.50 17.69 45.00 18.00 57.50 30.00 86.00 41.60 49.38 33.00 47.50 32.00 47,50 32.00 47.50 33.00 55.25 42.25 37.00 22.00 32.25 19.38 29.60 18.20 Comment is hardly necessary. The figures speak for themselves. Similar price increases can be noted for all of the 88 iron and steel products listed in the War Indus¬ tries Board’s Price Bulletin No. 33. All conclusively show that the dollar and cents increases in the prices of the articles produced, were considerably greater than the dollar and cents increases in the wages of those who produced them. 4 John Skelton Williams, at the time Comptroller of the 4 As a matter of fact an official of the Bethlehem Steel Corporation himself admits that wage increases are not the principal reason for the increase in the prices of iron and steel products. I quote this official’s statement further along" in this chapter. 348 The New Capitalism Currency, in his letter to Elbert H. Gary says, speaking of the 1918 report of the United States Steel Corporation: “We find that they received an average of $87.70 per ton for every ton of the 14,124,986 tons of rolled steel and other products shipped to domestic and export trade.” According to Mr. Williams “the United States Steel Corporation paid out during the calendar year 1918 on pay rolls, including administrative and selling departments, as well as all manufacturing departments, a total of $452,- 663,524”—(in other words a trifle more than thirty dollars per ton for all wages and all salaries). Mr. Williams declares that the earnings of the United States Steel Corporation “were so large that the Company could, during the year 1918, have doubled the salaries and wages paid to everyone of its 268,710 employees and offi¬ cers, amounting to $452,663,524, and would have had a surplus of $96,517,000 left over.” From all of which it is clear that the quantity increase in the price of steel products was not caused by any quantity increase in wages; and that the dollar and cents increase in prices was many times greater than the dollar and cents increase in wages. One Dollar Wage Increase—Two Dollars Living Cost Increase These disposed to argue that the tremendous increase in retail prices was caused by marked increases in the prices of the various materials going into commodities, are involv¬ ing themselves in a vicious circle. If the increase in the price of every kind of material going into a shoe (or any other commodity) is fairly computed in dollars and cents, instead of percentages, it will be found that the aggregate increase in the price of all materials used does not begin to justify the tremendous increase in the price of shoes (or other commodities). No matter what article you take, whether manufactured or one whose production is not complicated with other ma¬ terials—coal, for example—if the cent system is used in- Wages and Living Costs 349 stead of the Percentage System, it will be found that in every instance the price increase per unit of production, was considerably greater than the increase in wages per unit of production. Which being the case, it is unfair to Labor and to the public, to pretend that so-called high wages are responsible for the prevailing high prices. No matter which industry we analyze in an endeavor to discover the relationship, if any exists, between wage increases and price increases, we observe the same phe¬ nomenon. For every dollar of wage increase per unit of production, there has been an increase of from two to ten (and more) dollars in the price of the commodity con¬ sumed. And for every dollar of increase that wage earn¬ ers received the living costs increased not less than two dollars. When I say this I wish it to be understood that I am not guilty of exaggeration; on the contrary I am un¬ derstating the actual condition, particularly if we ex¬ tend the discussion to cover living costs in general—which includes the item of Rent. From 1900 to 1914 the cost of living—that is with regard to all commodities produced by Labor, or into which the element of labor entered—all except rent—practically doubled; but wages did not double within the same period. In 1900 the cost of living per family was approximately $650. By 1914 the cost of living had mounted to $1,100,— an increase of $450; whereas the wages per worker had advanced from $417 in 1900 to only $580 by 1914 ,—an increase of only $163. The only thing that made the situa¬ tion endurable was the fact that rents did not rise ma¬ terially between 1900 and 1914. For whatever reason land¬ lords did not dare to raise their rentals appreciably up to that time. Doubling the Rent From 1914 to 1920 living costs practically doubled. 5 This 5 In November, 1919, the Bureau of Applied Economics reported that the minimum of subsistence level was approximately $1,575 in the latter part of 1919 ; whereas the cost of maintaining - the minimum of comfort level was $1,760 in June, 1918 ; and approximately $2,000 in 1919. 350 The New Capitalism time the landlord took a hand. Rents were practically doubled, were increased 100 percent, since that is the language some understand best. Why? On account of the increase in the wages of those engaged in the building trades, some will quickly answer. Indeed? What are the facts? The facts are that probably ninety-five percent of all the buildings and apartments occupied by tenants were built under old wage rates and scales. Many of the build¬ ings are ten, fifteen, twenty and more years old—erected when all building wages (and materials) were low. But for all buildings, regardless of when erected, rentals were increased, in round numbers, an average of 100 percent. The landlords computed the increases on the basis of present day building costs—present day prices for wages and materials. They reasoned thus: If we had put up our building in 1920 instead of in 1900, or 1905, or 1910, it would have cost us thus and thus much; therefore we are justified in charging rentals based upon 1920 prices of wages and materials. 6 This is the kind of rotten economic logic that is universal today, and not a single economic writer, or statesman, to challenge it. Wages That Were Never Paid Still confining myself to the item of wages paid to the workers in the building trades, I have shown in a preced¬ ing chapter that the tenant pays annual interest on every dollar of wages that goes into a building, whether applied on the production of the material or for the labor of actual construction. That’s bad enough; but to charge the ten¬ ants interest on labor that was never performed, and on wages that were never paid—is a crime against common decency and though sanctioned by “economic laws” and “good business practice,” I denounce it as a heinous offense against the public. And what I say of dwelling places applies with equal e Those with keener vision will probably emphasize the increased price of coal, taxes, insurance, janitor’s wages, etc. Very well! but let them compute the aggregate increases in dollars and cents, not in percentages. Wages and Living Costs 351 force to office and store buildings, factories, warehouses, storage plants, etc., all of which helps to explain not only the increase in the prices of commodities—but living costs in general. It is bad enough to compute prices of com¬ modities on the basis of higher costs actually chargeable, but to compute them on fictitious costs is an economic crime that cries to heaven for vengeance. Here w r e see two of the Capitalistic devices employed to exploit the public; 1,—the Percentage System; and 2,—charging rentals on the basis of what it pleases some to call “re¬ placement value.” At any rate, out of all this, one thing stands out clear and strong, and that is that Labor—the wage earners— cannot be blamed for the 100 percent increase in the item of rent with regard to 95 percent of buildings. Nor are wage earners responsible for the high prices of most com¬ modities. The Nation’s Tremendous Freight Bill By far the greatest increase in the list of “costs” is the item of freight. The several freight increases allowed to the carriers means that the public is paying freight bills amounting to several billion dollars a year over former years. Just a few examples, to give substance and edge to my statement. A lumber dealer, writing to Capper’s Weekly , July 2, 1921, says in his letter: “Ten years ago or less, it cost $5.50 a thousand to put lumber in our yard. That is what freight bills called for then. Now it costs $21.75 per thousand feet.” In the 1921 “literature” prepared by the National Coal Association (Washington, D. C.) we read as follows: “Freight rates have approximately doubled since 1914. Where the average freight rate was about $1.50 a ton in pre-war days, the average rate now, so far as it is possible to strike an average, is about $3 a ton. For long distances from the mines the freight rates run much higher than $3 a ton. 352 The New Capitalism “This increase of $1.50, applied to a yearly production of 550,000,000 tons, represents an advance in the cost of coal to the consumer of the country over, on account of freight charges, of $825,000,000.’ ’ The following is from an item that appeared in the Chicago Daily News, October 10, 1921: “ Kelationship between increased freight rates and cement prices is shown in a statement prepared by the Universal Portland Cement Company. It says in part: “ ‘The freight rate from Buffington, Ind., to Milwaukee, for example, in 1917 was 23 cents, and now is 49 cents a barrel. This is an increase in freight rates since 1917 of about 113 percent. “ ‘In considering these comparative increases of 37 per¬ cent in cement prices and 113 percent in freight rate, it should be borne in mind that the effect of increased freight rates is not confined to the cost of moving the finished product from mill to destination; the higher rates apply also on incoming raw materials, and thus affect the cost of manufacture as do taxes and other factors over which the manufacturer has no control. ’ ” According to an editorial note by Arthur Brisbane (October 10, 1921) : “You can buy brick now wholesale at $16 a thousand. That sounds cheap, compared with $40 and more not long ago. It sounds dear compared with $6 and $8, the old price for ordinary brick. But the price of brick makes little difference when you consider the price of hauling. To haul a thousand bricks less than fifty miles, some rail¬ roads charge $15, about 100 percent more than brick used to cost delivered, not so long ago. They say ‘Freight rates do not affect the consumer.’ They do, if you pay a cent and a half to carry one brick fifty miles.” Letting the Cat Out of the Bag But the most authoritative proof that for many commodi¬ ties freight rates, rather than high wages, are responsible for the prevailing high prices, we find in the September Wages and Living Costs 353 1921 Monthly Review Letter issued by the National City Bank of New York, of which George E. Roberts, already quoted in this chapter, is the author: “Mr. Grace, President of the Bethlehem Steel Company, has made a statement explaining that if allowance is made for the increase in costs due to railroad charges, steel products are now lower than before the war. In an¬ nouncing new and lower prices for steel products, going into effect on July 5th, last, Mr. Grace said: “ ‘The increase in freight rates has been the largest factor in increasing the cost of manufacturing steel prod¬ ucts because the making of a ton of finished steel involves the transportation of more than five tons of raw materials. The cost factors next in importance are raw materials and labor. “ ‘Taking as an example the price of structural shapes, under the new schedule of prices, 2 cents a pound, or $44.80 a gross ton, the comparison with pre-war prices, reflecting concretely the three more important cost factors is as follows: “ ‘1st: The increase over pre-war cost in transportation on ore, coal, limestone, scrap and miscellaneous supplies amounts to $7.85 per ton of finished steel. ‘ ‘ ‘ 2nd: The increase in the cost of coal, ore, limestone, alloys, refractories, lubricants and miscellaneous supplies at point of shipment amounts to $7.10 per ton of finished steel. ‘ ‘ ‘ 3rd: The increase in the cost of labor under the present wage scale, as compared with pre-war wages in the steel plant proper, is $5.64 per ton of finished steel. “ ‘The figures I have used are the result of actual com¬ pilation made by.the Company’s comptroller in the every day conduct of the business.’ “Iron and steel products enter into farm implements, railroad costs, and the costs of every line of industry. ’ ’ I have nothing to say in comment of Mr. Grace’s state¬ ment at this time, except that his figures show that of the increase in the price of the finished steel per ton, $7.85 354 The New Capitalism went to the railroads, $7.10 to the mine owners, and those who have a monopoly on raw materials, and $5.64 to labor. Needless to say neither Mr. Grace, nor Mr. Roberts of the National City Bank, offered the above statement by way of exonerating Labor from the unjust charge that the high wages paid to industrial workers are responsible for high prices. Quite the reverse. The statement is really intended as a twin argument for a still further reduction in the wages of railroad employees and in the w T ages of industrial workers. The intended inference is that freight rates are high on account of the wages railroads are pay¬ ing their employees. The Monthly Review Letter of the National City Bank of New York, from which I have already quoted, mentions that reduction in wage rates “ probably would permit of an even greater reduction in freight rates, particularly if it is accompanied by corresponding reductions throughout all the industries, because the stimulus given to business would increase the volume of railroad traffic. Railroad rates are under public supervision, and there is every reason to believe that they would be made to conform to increased earnings. “ Finally, such a general reduction of industrial costs would reduce the ‘cost of living,’ not only to railroad em¬ ployees but to wage-earners, farmers and everybody, in¬ crease the purchasing power of the entire population, en¬ large the consumption of all products, and improve the whole situation. ’ ’ 7 The Bach-Fire of Capitalistic Logic Harking back once more to Mr. Roberts’ queer statement that “the prices of manufactured goods have increased by lower percentages than the cost of the labor and the raw materials that entered into them ’ ’—there * is a modicum T The wages of railroad employees were reduced by $400,000,000 notwithstanding which reduction railroad officials immediately announced that freight rates would not be lowered. The evident design of the Capitalistic interests is to bring the wages of railroad employees down to the level of workers in the industries. Wages and Living Costs 355 of truth in his claim that the increase in the cost of raw materials has helped to increase the price of the finished product. But Mr. Roberts fails to state that the same Capitalistic Entrepreneurs who own the important indus¬ tries also have a monopoly on the raw materials—and that prices are fixed by them for the raw materials, and the finished products independently of the wages paid to the workers. And that quantity prices of raw material and finished product have been increased far in excess of the quantity increase in the wages of the workers. And since freight rates seem to play so conspicuous a part in the price of materials and products — and therefore living costs—it may not be amiss to emphasize here that the same group that controls the industries and raw materials, also controls the railroads. The Unassailable Fact Stated I think I have shown to anyone disposed to be fair, that the quantity increase in wages is not responsible for the quantity increase in the prices of living commodities, or commodities in general. In the first place prices went up first; wages were increased afterwards (and generally under compulsion) merely to enable wage earners to meet the advance in living costs. Moreover, for every one dollar increase in wages, living costs went up not less than two dollars. Under these circumstances the injustice and the absurdity of blaming Labor for increases in living costs is obvious. CHAPTER XXVI The Cost of Living Basis of Wages T one of the Chicago theatres recently, several sheep appeared on the stage in one of the scenes of the JL -m.play. During the day these sheep were kept in the lobby of the theatre as an advertisement. Everybody who passed that theatre in the course of a day, paused for a moment, or perhaps only turned his or her head to glance at the sheep—a unique sight in a crowded city. The sheep received no wages or salary, neither for the part they played on the stage, nor for their advertising value or power. They received nothing but their upkeep. And this is precisely the case with the wage earners whose wages are computed on the “cost of living’’ basis. The average man or woman who works is allowed nothing more than his or her upkeep—clothing, food, shelter. A mere living is all that is grudgingly allowed to those who labor for a wage. The sheep’s owner has an advantage, in that the upkeep of sheep embraces only the items of food and shel¬ ter ; nature, not their keeper, provides them with clothing. The Servitude of the Workers The principle of basing wages upon cost of living is traceable all through economic history. For many cen¬ turies the economic line of demarkation was sharply drawn between master and slave. To the masters belonged the earth and all it brought forth through the labor of their slaves, their bondmen, their serfs, their servants. All property, all rights, all authority, all power, was vested in the hands of a few, to whom belonged the land, the riches and the treasures; the offices, the honors, and the emolu¬ ments. The right of the few to rule, to govern, to com¬ mand, to take, to own, to control, was never questioned by the poor. There is no sense in denying that from the be- 356 Cost of Living Basis of Wages 357 ginning of what it pleases ns to call civilization, society was founded on slavery. Servitude was universally considered as the natural state of the poor; misery and wretchedness as their normal condition; hardships and suffering as their portion by ancient heritage. A bare existence was all that was allowed them; it was all they expected, and they were disposed to be grateful even for that. Taking it all in all, it is not strange that those who had grown rich and become powerful through the toil of others, and who were accustomed to keep for themselves the entire usufruct of labor, did not readily accept the idea of re¬ warding those who in former times had served them without any recompense whatever. Nor is it remarkable that when the absolute necessity of rewarding those who toiled had to be recognized, the same old principle of allowing those who labor just enough recompense to enable them to live, was applied. Wages Around A. D. 1650 Adam Smith, the first edition of whose noted work, * ‘ The Wealth of Nations,” was published in 1776, writing “Of the Wages of Labor,” relates that: “Lord Chief Justice Hales, who wrote in the time of Charles II, computes the necessary expense of a laboring family, consisting of six persons, the father and mother, two children able to do something, and two not able, at ten shillings a week, or twenty-six pounds a year. If they cannot earn this by their labor, they must make it up, he supposes, either by begging or stealing. ’ ’ 1 It is not my purpose to examine into Adam Smith’s views with regard to wages, but to his credit be it said that he favored a liberal wage, not, perhaps, so much as a reward of labor as on account of the advantage that would naturally accrue to the wealthy from the greater contentment, and the greater industry of the laboring class; and particularly because it encouraged marriage i Adam Smith says that Chief Justice Hales “appears to have inquired very carefully into the subject.” 358 The New Capitalism among the poor and stimulated their fecundity, thus in¬ suring for industry “the multiplication of laborers,” which “multiplication,” needless to say, implied cheaper labor and consequently bigger profits for those who owned both the capital and the wealth. The “Law” of Wages as Stated by Ricardo Ricardo, whose “Principles of Political Economy and Taxation” was published in 1817, is considered to have been the first to formulate the principles underlying the law of wages. He says (Chapter V), in his discussion on “Wages”: “The power of the laborer to support himself, and the family which may be necessary to keep up the number of laborers, does not depend on the quantity of money which he may receive for wages, but on the quantity of food, necessaries and conveniences become essential to him from habit, which that money will purchase. The natural price of labor, therefore, depends on the price of food, necessaries and conveniences required for the support of the labourer and his family. With a rise in the price of food and neces- aries, the natural price of labor will rise; with the fall in their price the natural price of labor will fall. ’ ’ 2 According to the Economists—'Tis an Iron Law The writings of Adam Smith and his contemporaries in the eighteenth century, and those of Ricardo and his dis¬ ciples in the nineteenth century, have, with such modifica¬ tions and adaptations as became necessary by changes, been accepted as representative and standard by the en¬ tire group of political economists of the twentieth cen¬ tury. This is particularly true with whatever concerns the laboring class, and as regards the subject of their wages. As a consequence the relative economic condition of the workmen of today is in no wise an improvement over the economic condition of the laborer who lived in the time of Charles II. Wages, relative to living costs, 2 Ricardo also says: “There is no other way of keeping profits up, but by keeping wages down.” Cost of Living Basis of Wages 359 are no greater than the wages of the laborer of two or three centuries ago. The Old Wage Law in Modern Clothes Dogberry has said that “comparisons are odorous,” and indeed they are sometimes, but if so it is because the things compared themselves are foul. Yet comparisons, if made in a spirit of fairness, are often illuminating, if not edi¬ fying. Let us attempt a comparison between the laboring family which around the middle of the seventeenth cen¬ tury received a recompense of twenty-six pounds a year, and w'hose necessary living expenses were computed at ten shillings a week—and the laborer (and his family) of more modern times. If it is permissible, for the sake of conveni¬ ence, to account the value of the pound at around five dollars in our money, then the seventeenth century com¬ mon laborer and his family received a yearly wage amount¬ ing to $130—which was then considered a sufficient amount for a family of six. Evidently the $130 was not an average income for all families; it would seem that the earnings in many cases were not sufficient to meet the necessary living costs, for we are told that “if they can¬ not earn this by their labor, they must make it up, either by begging or stealing.” 3 How does this amount of wages paid in 1650 in England, compare with the amount of earnings of American artisans two centuries later in the United States ? From the sundry statistical records I have examined I can but conclude that there is no unity of agreement as regards the amount of wages paid in the United States in the first half of the nineteenth century. Even those computations for the sec¬ ond half are based on partial statistics or incomplete data for certain industries. Wherever we may find them, from whatever source they may have been derived, or however they may have been computed, no scientific value attaches 3 The chronic inadequacy of the wages of English laborers for the necessaries of life is repeatedly observed by James E. Thorald Rogers in his work “Six Centuries of Work and Wages.” 360 The New Capitalism to them. They are at best approximations, in many cases guesses, but the best available. According to Professor Willford Isbell King, the average yearly money wages per man were as follows: (Table XXXI, p. 168.) Census Years Average Money Wage 1850.$ 204 1860. 265 1870. 397 1880. 323 1890. 398 1900. 417 1910. 507 1915. 600 4 1920. 1200 4 My own data and computations would lead me to believe that Professor King's statistics, especially for the years 1850 to 1900, are rather low as an average for all workers. However, I am quite willing not to press my own findings, preferring to accept those of a recognized authority. It is to be noted here that in point of quantity the wages of an American wage earner in 1850 were less than a hun¬ dred dollars higher than the income of an English laborer’s family in 1650. The contrast in economic and industrial conditions between 1650 and 1850 is so great that a com¬ parison is impossible, and I shall attempt none. The one point I want particularly to emphasize here is that wages have always advanced at a slow rate. To illustrate this let us take the “family” income of the English laborer of 1650 and the family income in the United States, which in 1850, according to Professor King, was $535. Consequently the increase has been at the cumulative rate of about two dol¬ lars a year. I shall leave this subject at this point, merely wishing to say that when we consider wage increases it will be observed that the quantity of wages increased at a rather conserva- 4 Professor Friday, in his book “Profits, Wages and Prices” says that wages had risen by 1919, so that the average wages will prob¬ ably exceed $1,300 per annum, or more than twice the average wages of 1914. The money wage for 1915 and 1920 is a compromise estimate of conflicting computations made by .various “authorities.” I con¬ sider it a liberal estimate. Cost of Living Basis of Wages 361 tive rate; always after the living costs had advanced; and always lagging away behind the quantity increases in living costs. Generally speaking—since 1900, for every dollar increase in wages, living costs advanced two dollars. Wage Increases Altvays Inadequate That is the one lesson we learn from a study of statistics, particularly when each person correlates them with his own experiences and observations. All through the years, particularly during the past twenty-five years, living ex¬ penses rose first, and wages generally under compulsion, were reluctantly advanced later to enable those most con¬ cerned to meet the mounting living costs. Never (with the possible exception of the years from 1917 to 1920) were wage increases equal to the living cost increases that had preceded. In 1919, when wages had reached their zenith, the average wages per worker were considered as between $1200 to $1300. In November of 1919 the Bureau of Applied Economics (Washington, D. C.) computed that “the annual cost of maintaining a family of five at a mini¬ mum of subsistence level at prices prevailing in the latter part of 1919, was approximately $1575. ” 5 Two Important Points With regard to the wage increases made during the years 1917-20, I have examined and computed hundreds of sets of statistics that have come to me regularly from the vari¬ ous departments of the Government, and hundreds of pri¬ vate compilations of hundreds of sets that appeared in the leading trade, industrial and financial publications; besides sundry works dealing with economic questions, and a num¬ ber of corporation reports. To save the readers’ time, and space in this book, I will briefly summarize my findings and conclusions with regard to that group engaged in the manufacturing industries. I. The average wage around 1915 was less than $600 a 5 In the April Number, 1922, of the “Monthly Labor Review” pub¬ lished by the U. S. Department of Labor, we are given the informa¬ tion that the yearly increases of miner’s families averaged only $1,590.65 while the average expenditures per family was $1,705.86. 362 The New Capitalism year per worker. According to Professor Friday, who has made a fairly thorough inquiry into the subject, and whose computations are based on the latest available statistics up to the beginning of 1920, “The annual wages in 1914 of employees of manufacturing corporations were $685 per employe.” It is to be observed, however, that Professor Friday’s figures include industrial wage workers and sal¬ aried employees within the industries. According to the Census Statistics there were in 1914 in the various manu¬ facturing industries, 7,036,337 wage earners, whose total wages were $4,079,332,433—an average of $580 per worker. 2. The sundry increases in wages, since 1914, even granting that they would have increased wages 100 percent, did not yield an average wage for all industrial workers of $1200 a year. This figure was, beyond a doubt, exceeded by some work¬ ers in certain industries, but it is not an average for all workers in all industries. Deceptive Statistics As a matter of fact the average increase fell below 100 percent. 0 True, in many instances I have seen, the increase of total wages in cities and states exceed 100 percent—but this is offset by the fact that the increased volume of wages was distributed among a greater number of workers, the division yielding often an average of less than a thousand dollars per worker. For example, in the city of Wilming¬ ton, Delaware : 6 7 In 1914 the average number of wage earners was 15,048; and the aggregate wages was $8,674,000. In 1919 the average number of wage earners was 21,414; and the aggregate w T ages was $19,352,000. An increase in wages of 123.1 percent. 6 In its Bulletin No. 274 the Bureau of Labor statistics gives the “Union Scale of Wages and Hours of Labor, May 15, 1919.” Its report is based on “912,000 union workers in the organized trades and occupations of 61 of the principal cities of the United States.” “In all trades taken collectively the income in weekly wage rates on May 15, 1919, was J/3 percent over 1913. 7 The statistics are those of the Department of Commerce, pub¬ lished by the Bureau of the Census. Cost of Living Basis of Wages 363 That sounds big, but when actually computed we find that in 1914 the average wage per worker was $577, and in 1919 it was $900. It must be apparent to all, that in spite of the 123.1 percent wage increase for 1919 it was $675 below the minimum subsistence level. Or let us take a state —Rhode Island, for example. The statistics are as follows: 1914 1919 Percent of Increase Wage earners 113,425 139.665 23.1 Wages $59,366,000 $137,671,000 131.9 But when wages are computed w T e find that in 1914 they were $523 per worker, and in 1919, $987 per worker, a money increase of $464, or an increase of 89 percent. There is but one obvious conclusion; the workers were decidedly underpaid in 1914; nor was their relative condi¬ tion improved in 1919. In all cases—for all cities and states—the large percentage increase in wages, computed in dollars and cents, did not begin to enable them to meet the large money increase in the cost of living. As already pointed out, the only thing that saved the situation for all wage earners was the fact that in a majority of cases more than one worker contributed to the support of a family. Statistical Wages of Steel Workers The United States Steel Corporation is supposed to have paid the highest wages to industrial workers, particularly during the period of the war. One writer, Edward A. Bradford, says: ‘‘Never were such wages paid as now. Some manual workers in the steel industry earn $10,000 a year. ” 8 Professor David Friday says: “The average wage per man in the United States Steel Corporation was $905 in 1914, $1,042 in 1916, and $1,902 in 1919.” It is to be regretted that Professor Friday did not explain at the same time that the ten and twelve-hour day 8 The Annalist, January 28, 1918. Is it permissible to ask Mr. Bradford: “How many wage workers in the steel industry earned $10,000 a year?” 364 The New Capitalism was still in force for a considerable number of employees in the plants of the United States Steel Corporation, and that the figures he gives are not wage rates but actual earnings, i. e. y all wages received including overtime. The following news item, published in the Chicago Tribune, August 2, 1921, sheds light on the wages paid to the workers in the United States Steel Corporation plants: “New York, Aug. 19, 1921.— (Special)—The United States Steel Corporation today announced another adjust¬ ment in the wages of its employees, the third to be put into effect since the decline in steel prices began. . . . “The official announcement made by Elbert H. Gary, chairman of the board of directors, follows: “ Tn view of the prevailing low selling price of steel as compared with costs of production, it is necessary to make reductions in wage rates, and therefore we will recom¬ mend to subsidiary companies that the general rates of day labor be decreased to thirty cents per hour, to become effective Monday, August 29, and that other wages and salaries be equitably adjusted.’ ”... The following Table shows wages of unskilled labor after each advance in wages since 1915, the percentage of each advance and the cumulative advance of each, with statistics for the last three adjustments: 1915 10 hr. day $2.00 Advance Percent Advance Feb. 1, 1916 2.20 10.0 10.0 May 1, 1916 2.50 13.6 25.0 Dec. 15, 1916 2.75 10.0 37.5 May 1, 1917 3.00 9.0 50.0 Oct. 1, 1917 April 16, 1918 3.30 10.0 65.0 4.80 15.0 90.0 Aug. 1, 1918 4.20 10.5 110.0 Oct. 1, 1918 4.62 10.0 131.0 Feb. 1, 1920 5.06 10.0 153.0 May 16, 1921 4.05 *20.0 ' 102.0 July 16, 1921 3.70 t 9.5 85.0 Aug. 29, 1921 3.00 *18.9 50.0 * Reduction. t Elimination of time and a half for overtime work over eight hours. Cost of Living Basis of Wages 365 It is to be remembered that in spite of recent modifica¬ tions the ten and twelve-hour day. is still in force in the several plants of the United States Steel Corporation. The twelve-hour day is still defended by Mr. Gary as impos¬ sible of abrogation. If the earnings per worker in 1919, amounting, according to Professor Friday, to $1902, were computed at the highest rate ever paid, viz., about fifty cents an hour, it will be found that the average steel worker worked approximately twelve hours a day in order to earn $1902. At the wage rate of August 29, 1921—$3.00 for a ten- hour day, or thirty cents an hour—a steel worker working eight hours a day and three hundred days a year, would earn $750 a year. But there has been no material decrease in living costs. Despite the much advertised decrease in the wholesale prices of some commodities, the retail prices have remained singularly inflexible. And for many com¬ modities the quality has been lowered to such an extent as to necessitate purchasing double the former quantity. On an average, especially when we include the item of Rent, the $1575 considered necessary for a mere subsistence, is just as necessary today as it was in 1910. “The End of a Perfect Day” But granting for the present that the wage earners for a period of two or three years were, indeed, “in clover that the wages they received were the highest that had ever been paid them in the history of the world; and that wages, considering that an average family draws its support from more than one worker, were more nearly adequate, per¬ haps even in some instances more than adequate, to meet even the considerably higher living costs—granting all that, and anything you may care to add in order to bolster your possible contention that the wage earners’ condition, especially during the years 1917-1920 was ex¬ cellently fine; granting aught you might say on this sub¬ ject—I will put a deadly period to your sentence by de¬ claring that the brief season of the wage earners’ glory is 366 The New Capitalism permanently over; and that all the Capitalistic machinery is in full motion to take away from them every temporary advantage that might have been grudgingly granted them under stress of extraordinary circumstances; and that within another few years all wage earners and families of wage earners, will find themselves precisely in the same economic condition they were in in former times; nay, they will probably be worse off than ever before. The Plight of the Salaried Employees I'll go a step further and say that after the Capitalistic Entrepreneur “readjustment” will have been completed, not only the industrial wage earners but all workers—all non-investors—will find it increasingly harder to make ends meet than ever before. It is rather singular that nearly all writers who have essayed to deal with the subject of wages and living costs, base all their conclusions on computations regarding wages paid to industrial workers. And yet there are many mil¬ lions more who are in the group known as salaried work¬ ers, for whom, as well as for the industrial workers, there have been two separate 100 percent increases in living costs, but for most of them there has been no proportionate increase in salary. To illustrate what I mean suppose we"take the statistics for the salaried officials, clerks and so forth, in the manu¬ facturing industries as given in the 1920 Statistical Ab¬ stract (Table No. 447, page 804) ; those for 1919 are from the Department of Commerce Summary of Manufactures. Salaried Officials, Salaries Clerks, etc. 1899 364,120 $ 380,771,321 1904 519,556 574,439,322 1909 790,267 938,574,967 1914 964,217 1,287,916,951 1919 1,447,761 2,893,046,000 Average Salary Per Person $1045 1106 1188 1136 1998 Please remember that from 1896 to 1914—the cost of living advanced 100 percent; to meet which the salaried workers, as the above statistics indicate, had an average Cost of Living Basis of Wages 367 increase of less than a hundred dollars. From 1914 to 1920 there was another distinct 100 percent increase in living costs, and an increase of only $862 in salaries. I have no intention of going into an analysis of salaries as distinguished from wages. To do so in any worth-while manner would require many pages. My reason for calling attention to this consistently ignored phase of the subject at this time is to emphasize that ordinarily when we speak of wages as having gone up 100 or more percent during the past five or six years, the increase is applicable to a limited number of wage earners only. It is true, let us say, for eight or ten million, but it is not true for fully as many others who statistically are not accounted as wage earners. According to the Monthly Labor Review (March, 1922) published by the United States Department of Labor, the per capita salaries increased only 50 percent during the five-year period 1914-1919. Yet the increase in the living expenses of these salaried employees during that period, was fidly 100 percent. If we lump salaries and wages, and particularly if we subtract from the total salary roll the enormous salaries of officials and principals, in which the average small sal¬ aried person shares only statistically, it will be found, I believe, that the average money increase in the pay per worker was considerably less than the money increase in living costs. I doubt whether the average increase from 1914 to 1919 in wages and salaries per worker, would ex¬ ceed 60 percent. But remember that the increase in the cost of living was 100 percent for 100 percent of the work¬ ers—whether wage earners or salaried employees. It is clear that this subject concerns the salaried men and women even more than the so-called wage worker. Looking Ahead But what was yesterday is of less importance than what will be tomorrow. Therefore, let us determine what the economic condition of the non-investors will be after the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs will have completely ‘ 1 adjusted” 368 The New Capitalism wages and salaries. I shall try to give the readers a simple and easily comprehended answer. For the present I will overlook the fact that the cost of living increased from 1896 to 1914 a round 100 percent, and that wages were not increased in proportion. In order to simplify my contention I am going to proceed for the present as if the increase in wages and salaries from 1896 to 1914 had kept pace, dollar for dollar, with the increase in the cost of living. In which event I am assuming that in 1914 the average family wage income of the average wage earner and salaried employee, sufficed to enable them to meet the prevailing costs of living. Consequently w T e may express it thus: In 1914 one dollar of wages or salary was equal to one dollar of living cost.- Wages 1914 Living Cost $1.00 $1.00 Then prices began to ascend rapidly, so that the living costs in 1920 were 100 percent higher than in 1914. It is to be emphasized here that the 100 percent increase in the living costs is predicable of 100 percent of the population. But most of those working for a wage or salary are un¬ organized, and only those who are organized succeeded in compelling a material increase in their wages. Let us say that in the aggregate the increase in wages and salaries, if distributed among all the wage and salary workers, was, in round numbers, 60 percent. That is to say, for every dollar of wages the average wage earner or salaried man or woman received in 1914, he or she received $1.60 in 1920, whereas the one dollar living cost of 1914 had risen to two dollars by 1920. The formula may then be expressed as follows: Wages Living Cost 1914_$1.00 1914 $1.00 1920_ 1.60 1920_2.00 Capitalistic Unwillingness to Lower Living Costs The Capitalistic campaign which is still in full swing, has certain clearly defined objects in view. First of all it Cost of Living Basis of Wages 369 was inevitable that the prices of some commodities should fall. 9 But it is apparent to those who study price sched¬ ules, that those who have been the beneficiaries of big profits from high prices will not permit prices to fall to the 1914 level. Hundreds of statements of public speakers, writers, bankers, merchants, statesmen, government offi¬ cials, et al., could be quoted here to show the declared determination and avowed purpose of the Capitalistic group that prices of commodities shall not go back to the 1914 level. A few will suffice as pointing a moral, as well as adorning a tale. For example: Elbert H. Gary, of the United States Steel Corporation, declared repeatedly during 1920 and 1921, that steel prices would not come down. Since his last utterance steel prices have been lowered, but they are still far above the 1914 prices. 10 Henry C. Wallace, the new Secretary of Agriculture, in his first public statement, said: ‘ ‘ This talk of bringing prices, whether farm prices or other prices, back to the pre-war normal, is morally wrong and economically impos¬ sible.” In a later statement Secretary Wallace repeated the above utterance with a few more trimmings: “We can pay off our debts much easier if we maintain a price level more nearly the level at which the debts were incurred.” Col. John P. Wood, of Philadelphia, (President of the American Woolen Co.) appearing before the Finance Com¬ mittee having the Fordney Emergency Tariff Bill under consideration, on behalf of the wool manufacturers said that the government had been “unwise” in promulgating a campaign against high prices. The Manufacturers Record, which blames the Federal 9 While beyond a doubt some of the wholesale prices of com¬ modities were lower in price in 1921 than they were in 1919, and 1920, nevertheless the increase in the item of Rent has robbed the average man or woman of whatever advantage might be derived from lower commodity prices. The aggregate “living costs” remain about the same, the difference being that a greater proportion goes to the Capitalist in the role of landlord and a smaller proportion to the Entrepreneur in the role of commodity producer, manufacturer or dealer. 10 Steel prices are again in the ascendent. 370 The New Capitalism Reserve Bank for price reductions, in its issue of Febru¬ ary 24, 1921, said: “The war of the Federal Reserve Bank to break down prices and prosperity was a crime against civilization,” etc. (Parenthetically let me say that I could give hundreds of quotations from the writings and speeches of bankers, merchants, statesmen, etc., saying in effect that wages must come down nearer to the pre-war basis.) The New Level of Prices and Wages At any rate my guess (it is more than a guess, but so as not to be compelled to enter into a lengthy discussion I’ll call it simply a guess)—my guess is that the new level of prices will be fixed about midway between the prices of 1914 and 1920; that is to say: the article that cost $1.00 in 1914, and had risen to $2.00 by 1920, will cost $1.50 from now on. On the other hand the Capitalistic campaign contem¬ plates bringing down wages and salaries as near as possible to the 1914 level. From the wage cuts made thus far for the various kinds of labor, (reductions ranging from 10 to 25 percent for skilled labor, and from 25 to 50 percent for unskilled labor) I compute that the cut in wages and sal¬ aries will average 25 percent for all workers—wage earners and salaried men and women. That is to say, the wage earners and salaried men and women will have their average 1920 wage of $1.60 cut 25 percent, which will leave them $1.20 or twenty cents more for every dollar of wages over the wages of 1914. The formula now reads as follows: Wages Living Cost 1914. $1.00 $1.00 1920 . 1.00 2.00 1922 and thereafter. 1.20 1.50 This, I think, is a result that the average wage earner and the moderate salaried man and woman can verifv with actual figures as pertaining to themselves. To bring the whole subject nearer to the actual figures, let us say that Cost of Living Basis of Wages 371 the average weekly wage of the average worker in 1914 was $20.00, and that this amount enabled him or her to just meet the cost of living. The formula then reads as follows: Wagea Living Cost 1914 .$20.00 1914 .$20.00 1920 increase 60%. 32.00 1920 increase 100%... 40.00 1922 decrease 25%. 24.00 1922 decrease 25% 30.00 Here you have the arithmetic of the prices and wages situation as it will be from now on, about as clearly as it can be expressed when averages are employed. The Old Level of Profits The Capitalistic campaign, however, includes another fixed purpose, not observable on the surface. If the Cap¬ italistic Entrepreneurs can succeed in stabilizing com¬ modity prices midway between 1914 and 1920, so that they will receive henceforth $1.50 instead of $1.00 as in 1914; and lowering wages down to a point where they will pay $1.20 for labor for which they paid only $1.00 in 1914, it is clear that they will enjoy a margin of profit considerably in excess of that they reaped in 1914. But that is not enough to satisfy the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs; they will not willingly give up their maximum war time profit. If, therefore, they can succeed in reducing the number of workers, at the same time increasing output per worker; or increasing the number of hours; or eliminating those por¬ tions of their contracts with labor by which they are com¬ pelled to pay time and a half for over time;—if they can succeed in increasing by one method or another Labor’s production, without an increase in wages, they will have succeeded in creating a condition by virtue of which their aggregate volume of profits will approximate the aggregate volume of war time peak profits. The Corollary At the same time they will have created a condition which will have brought the average American workman nearer to the level occupied by the average European 372 The New Capitalism workman. The ability to save will be practically taken away from the average man and woman. The labor of two persons will be required to enable the average family to merely subsist. A bare living, and in many cases not even that, will be the rule rather than the exception. As Chief Justice Hales expressed it—“If they (the workers) cannot earn this by their labor they must make it up by begging or stealing. ” This, it has seemed to me for years, is the “ideal” the Capitalistic group is striving to achieve. I cannot shake off the feeling that there is this definite design behind the whole Capitalistic-Mammonistic scheme. If the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs succeed in putting through their program—and thus far they have been suc¬ cessful in having their own way—the American Standard of living will be nearer than ever to the European standard of living; and the condition of the wage earners and sal¬ aried employees will, in a few years more, be hopeless. CHAPTER XXVII Wages Under tite New Capitalism I N the several chapters dealing with Wages, I hope I have succeeded in giving an intelligible interpretation. At any rate, I think I have made clear at least these few things: 1: That Capital does not pay wages. 2: That Labor pays its own wages. 3: That Labor pays the interest on its wages. 4: That a big quantity wage with a low ex¬ change value (or purchasing power) is of no advantage to the wage earners. If these elementary propositions are tenable it behooves the New Order to bring about an early and scientific adjust¬ ment of the Wages question under the New Capitalism— one that will give those who work a fair and reasonable wage, and to the people greater benefits and more advan¬ tages, than accrue to them under the ‘ ‘ established ’ ’ Cap¬ italistic Order. Let me emphasize once more that the important thing about wages is their exchange value. Indeed if I were compelled to choose between a system of a big quantity wage and a low exchange value, or a less quantity wage and high exchange value, I would, by all odds, choose the latter. But whatever our views with regard to the quan¬ tity, or the exchange value, of wages may be, we must accept the situation as we find it. The Capitalistic Entrepreneur group has declared over and over, that anything higher than a subsistence wage cannot be paid;. that the paying of wages in excess of a bare living would mean the destruction of the industries. I hold a contrary opinion; to my way of figuring the pay¬ ing of fair and reasonable wages does not mean the destruc- 373 374 The New Capitalism tion of the industries, but it does mean a material reduction in the enormous Capitalistic profits, without which the Capitalistic -Mammonistic Entrepreneur System cannot flourish. However, to be perfectly fair, we will take the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs at their word. We will accept as basic the wage rates and scales that may be in existence at the time we begin to function. Our Chief Endeavor Our chief endeavor will be to bring down the cost of living. If we cannot assure those who labor of a larger quantity recompense for, say eight hours of work a day, we can guarantee them a material reduction in the prices of the things they must purchase during sixteen hours a day. Let none harbor delusions with regard to what we pro¬ pose to do, and what we shall aim to accomplish. Assuming that we will organize into a compact national body—with organized Labor as the nucleus—(for without the active help and co-operation of organized Labor all efforts will be useless, nothing can be accomplished)—our initial aim will be, not to increase w T ages, but rather to bring down the prices of commodities—the cost of living—in brief, to increase the exchange value of wages. For millions of families in the United States the present wage is not sufficient to enable them to meet the ordinary living expenses. Indeed were it not for the fact that in many of these families there are several members working, dire poverty would be their doom. All the statistics con¬ clusively show that the wages per worker are considerably below the minimum family subsistence level. The only thing that saves the situation is this quite accidental fea¬ ture, predicable of a majority of families, that more than one person is at work. It is their joint and aggregate earn¬ ings that enable the average family to get through. If each male worker were married and the sole support of an aver¬ age family of five, poverty would be prevalent among all wage earners; while if families were dependent upon the Wages Under the New Capitalism 375 wages paid to female workers, they would long ago have sunk into misery and wretchedness. We propose to change this in due time. To keep down the wages of a worker below a living standard on the theory that there are other workers in his family—wife, daughters or sons, sisters or brothers, and that between them they can manage to “get by,” is only keeping the road to the poor- house open, and the jails well filled. A Fundamental Principle Fair and reasonable wages for all workers will be a fun¬ damental principle under the New Capitalism. If too low wages are being paid in any line of industry, or for any kind of service, it will be our earnest purpose to raise them to a point where they will be fair and reasonable. If, on the other hand, it will be found that for certain kinds of work or service, excessively high wages are being paid, we shall seek to make what must be considered a fair and reasonable adjustment. But I rather think that by the time this book is published, the Capitalistic System will have completed the “liquidation” of all wages, and that we shall not be obliged to waste any of our time revising wages downward. For several years now we have been told, with maddening insistence, that some groups of work¬ ers are receiving unconscionably high wages. But no stress has been put on the fact that only the wages rates are high —that the actual annual earnings of those engaged in occu¬ pations in which high wage rates prevail, constitute only an average living wage. No particular stress has been placed on the very vital fact that many of the workers receiving high wage rates work only part of the time. Nor has it been deemed worthy of emphasis that all wage earn¬ ers are being paid with considerably depreciated w T age dollars. Labor Will Fix its Oivn Wage The New Capitalism will insist on a fair and reasonable wage for all workers. There is, and can be, no such thing 376 The New Capitalism as a fixed wage applicable for any and all kinds of labor. There is skilled and unskilled labor; there is labor that is productive and labor that is non-productive; there is labor that is menial, requiring no high order of intelligence for its performance, and labor that demands more than ordi¬ nary intelligence. The scientific classification and grading of service, and determining its fair and reasonable reward, is part of our plan. It will be our endeavor, in due time, to determine what constitutes a fair and reasonable wage for each of the different kinds of labor. But whatever kind of work or character of labor, or quality of service, one thing is certain—that wages must be ample, and not merely intended to enable the wage earner and his family barely to subsist. In my system of economics even the lowest wage implies an excess of sufficiency for subsistence. For I hold that even the humblest worker, and his family, is entitled to more than a bare subsistence; just as I hold that any indus¬ try that cannot flourish save by paying less than subsistence wages does not deserve to survive. It is to be remembered that my proposal provides that the scientific adjustment of wages and wage rates, shall be made by those most concerned—by Labor in the aggregate, acting through accredited representatives. Hitherto Cap¬ ital alone has dictated wage terms, and Labor had no alternative but to accept them. Henceforth, Labor will decide for itself what is a fair and reasonable wage for every kind of work and service. This important matter settled to the satisfaction of all concerned, means the end of strikes —“a consummation devoutly to be wished.” Wages, and a Margin of Profit A standard wage, that shall also be permanent, i. e., not subject to fluctuations), and always ample, that is, a wage which after the exchange involved in the purchase of the necessary living commodities leaves a reasonable surplus in favor of those who work for w r ages—would yield not only a satisfactory solution of the wage question but solve prac¬ tically all of our economic difficulties. One would not— Wages Under the New Capitalism 377 one could not—quarrel with a wage whose quantity is not only always adequate for the purchase of the essentials of life and its implied reasonable comforts, but always some¬ what greater than the purchase price of the things involved in the maintenance of a comfort level of living. I hold that there is a point somewhere—precisely where I am unable to say, though under my system it can and will be ascertained—at which wages could be permanently fixed and prices practically stabilized, which would yield to Labor a fair recompense, and to Capital a fair profit, besides maintaining a nicely balanced economic equilibrium between income' and living costs, wages being always some¬ what in excess of living costs, thus leaving a margin of profit (surplus or savings) to the wage earner. Capital is Uncompromising Up to the beginning of the twentieth century the ten¬ dency of Capital was to increase its profits by keeping down wages. But with the inauguration of the scientific Capitalistic Entrepreneur System, Capital became more ambitious, and determined to increase its profits not only by keeping wages low but also by gradually increasing prices. But this seriously disturbed the exchange value of wages and the purchasing power of money, partially to recover which Labor found itself put to the necessity of demanding progressive wage increases. These were reluc¬ tantly granted. But the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs, hav¬ ing tasted of the flesh-pots of Egypt—i. e., garnered a greater profit—refused to be driven from their banquet table, and sought to maintain the greater profit by still fur¬ ther increasing prices, mendaciously blaming the somewhat higher wages they were compelled to pay to Labor. And thus it continued all through the years, and all through the war, up to the end of 1920. Then we entered upon what it pleased some to call the ‘‘liquidation or re-adjustment” period. Capital first low¬ ered wages, then, reluctantly, prices, though in no case, if fairly computed in dollars and cents, have prices been 378 The New Capitalism lowered to the same extent as wages. The liquidation is not yet completed; the adjustment is still going on. How long it will take Capital to finish the job I am unable to say. But I will venture the guess that in the final summing up, Labor will find itself worse off than ever before. Capital is Unwilling to Share in Losses The Capitalistic philosophy demands that when the profits are big, i. e., largely in excess of normal, Capital shall keep them all for itself; Labor is not to share in them. But when profits are small, falling even a fraction below normal, Capital immediately insists that its deficit be made up out of the Avages of Labor. In all the Capitalistic palaver about “cutting down costs’' it has never occurred to a single contingent in the Capitalistic group to suggest cutting down anything but wages. Labor must bear the brunt of any “saving” it is desired to affect. The Capitalistic group is unwilling to apply any “saving” device to itself—to Capital. It is quite willing to deduct from Labor’s wages enough to make up for any loss; but never willing to deduct even a fraction of the loss from Capital’s reward. If there is business stag¬ nation ; if the wheels of commerce do not move; if the chan¬ nels of trade are clogged and it is necessary to ‘ ‘ save, ’ ’ the only source whence the Capitalistic group is willing to “save” is from Labor’s reward—from Labor’s wages. The Capitalistic group insists upon its pound of flesh— in sunshine or in rain, in fair weather or in foul. Let the evil days come; they fall entirely upon the shoulders of Labor. Let the fat years reign—never in all its history has Capital been willing to accord to Labor more than a bare living wage—not even in its most prosperous times. Let the lean years set in, Labor, not Capital, pays the pen¬ alty. If there is scarcity of consumption, the wage earner suffers, not Capital. If there is scarcity of production, again the wage earner pays. I hold that when things go awry, for whatever reason, Labor should not be made to bear the entire burden; Capital should be made to share it Wages Under the New Capitalism 379 —to bear at least a part of it. If the conditions are dis¬ turbed or abnormal, Capital tries to save its own bacon by compelling the workmen and women to accept a smaller wage, in order that its profits may remain the same as in normal times. Labor Always at the Mercy of Capital The Capitalistic System has built up its brutal strength, its despotic might, its cruel power, on the principle of “earning power,” but when Capital’s earning power does not come up to expectation, when it falls below r 6 percent, Capitalists reimburse themselves out of the pay envelope of those who labor. The “earning power” of Capital and the exchange value of wages, are in direct conflict; as the one rises the other is bound to fall. The increase in the earning power of Capital is derived chiefly from the decrease in the exchange value of wages. Conversely it should be true that a decrease in the earning power of Capital produce an increase in the exchange value of wages. But no such phenomenon is observable. The whole intent of the Capitalistic System is to prevent this perfectly natural phenomenon from taking place. Whenever for whatever reason, a decrease in the earning power of Capital threatens the Capitalistic System insists on a decrease in wages—and thus maintains its max¬ imum earning power—its maximum profit. There is no escape for the wage earner from the adverse operation of this Capitalistic device. No matter which way the wind blows—Capital always protects itself—Labor always suffers. Stabilizing Wages and Prices However, in this chapter I want to show the solution my system proposes. We will ascertain the point of safety for Labor and Capital; at which we shall endeavor to stabilize wages and prices, thus stabilizing the exchange value of wages and the purchasing power of money. This stabiliza¬ tion will be made at a point that will leave a fair profit for Capital—and a fair profit, that is a wage, that will 380 The New Capitalism leave a surplus or savings over living costs—to Labor. That is one of the primary purposes of the system of eco¬ nomics I am proposing in this book. Let me summarize the essential features of my plan with regard to wages and prices. It is intended: 1: To establish an equilibrium between wages and prices; 2 : To increase the exchange value of wages; 3: To increase the wage earners’ ability to save. The Government of the United States has declared that the dollar shall be a unit of value, and the equivalent of one hundred cents. Our Capitalistic Entrepreneurs how¬ ever, have decreed that the exchange value of the wage dollar, and its purchasing power, shall be considerably less than one hundred cents. The New Capitalism intends to recover a considerable portion of the dollar’s lost value by standardizing wages and stabilizing prices; thus materially increasing the exchange value of wages and the purchasing power of money. The economic stability and the commercial safety of our nation, and the material welfare, not to say happiness, of the people, depend upon the very elementary principle that the value of money be practically permanent, its purchas¬ ing power nearly stable, and the exchange value of wages free from serious fluctuations. This principle, I hold, can be permanently established and maintained, chiefly by organized Labor. Depreciation of the “Human Machine” Nor is that all that organized Labor can accomplish under the New Order, and through the instrumentality of the New Capitalism. Labor can raise its status to a height not attainable under the “established” Capitalistic Order. At present the average worker is only a wage earner, who in order merely to live is compelled to exhaust his capital (i. e., his labor) and consume his dividends (i. e., his wages). In brief, the wage earner is nothing more than a machine, but receiving less consideration at the hands of Capital than the machines in shops, factories, mines and Wages Under the New Capitalism 381 mills, and for which the Capitalistic System carefully com¬ putes ‘ ‘ depreciation. ” But not for the wage earner—the human machine; no allowance is made by Capital for “depreciation” of the human machine, or for its obso¬ lescence, or exhaustion. “A Modern Instance” Slason Thompson, statistical expert for the railroads, said in 1914 that the average holdings of the railroad stock¬ holders was $15,000. What does this mean? It means that if all the railroad stock were divided equally among the •stockholders, each “investor” would be allotted $15,000 of stock. With this as a basis let us make our computations. Needless to say the average railroad stockholder, as far ■as the properties in which he holds stock are concerned, is a non-producer—a non-worker. Nevertheless he receives in the course of twelve months, dividends which, computed at 6 percent per annum, amount to $900—an amount greater than the average railroad employee, working eight hours a day, and probably in excess of 300 days a year, receives as wages. 1 Continuing our computations: At the end of twenty- five years the average railroad stockholder will have received in dividends a total of $22,500, for which not one hour of labor has been given, not an hour of service rendered; and his capital of $15,000 still remains intact, and its earning power at its full strength. Whereas, at the end of twenty-five years the average rail¬ road employee will have received in wages a total of $20,250, for which he has given 11,500 days of labor—92,000 hours of service. It will be conceded that a man who toils eight hours a day for twenty-five years, has expended consider¬ able of his strength; and that his earning power decreases with his productive power. A few years more and his capital (labor) is exhausted, and his dividends (wages) will cease. He is ready for the economic scrap pile. If at the end of twenty-five years the average railroad i In 1914 the average wage per railroad employee was $810. 382 The New Capitalism stockholder dies, he leaves to his heirs $15,000, after having drawn $22,500 in dividends. Whereas the average railroad employee, having been compelled to consume both his cap¬ ital and his dividends, will probably be buried at his children’s expense. The Smoke Screen “Small Investor” But, the stock of the railroad is not equally divided. The $900 per stockholder is only a statistical distribution, based upon that precarious device called, in this particular case, “average holdings.” The average small investor has no such income. I do not pretend to know what the yearly income per small stockholder is, for, information that would enable one to make computations is not available. But I will venture to guess that in the case of the railroads, the average small investor receives only a fraction of the sta¬ tistical $900. I should say somewhere between $100 and $200, and I consider that a liberal estimate. 2 The lion’s share, that is $700 or $800 of each “average investor’s” statistical dividend revenue, goes to a few thousand big stockholders—the financial potentates who annually con¬ vert their collective and concentrated incomes into vast new Capital accumulations, while the average small stock¬ holder, in all probability, is compelled to consume the income derived from his small holdings. The Wage Earner’s “Reserves” One would not quarrel with the Capitalistic System, which has persistently excluded the human machine—the wage earner—from participation in any depreciation fund, if it were disposed to be more liberal with regard to his wages. But Capital has never been willing to accord to Labor a wage that would enable each worker to build up a reserve against the calamitous years when his earning power becomes less, or he is incapacitated through infirmity, sickness, accident, or other causes. 2 In 1914 Mr. Slason Thompson declared that the average yearly return on railroad investments for the past twenty-five years “has not averaged three percent.” Let the small investors in railroad and other Capitalistic securities take note. Wages Under the New Capitalism 383 A wage that is calculated to merely allow a wage earner and his family to live, deprives the wage earner of the opportunity to accumulate a surplus against contingencies and eventualities. Under my system the wage earner will be enabled to do for himself what Capital has either refused to do for him, or has deliberately prevented him from doing for himself. Under my system the wage earner will be more than a mere machine. He will be a component part of the industry in which he is employed. For the work he does he will receive a wage as at present—not, however, a mere living wage, but an ample wage that will enable him to set up protective reserves—both a depreciation fund and a surplus fund. Tifie Wage Earner Investor and Capitalist Moreover, he will deposit his earnings in banks whose funds are used by himself, not by speculators and gamblers. Thus he will be given an opportunity to invest his savings for his own benefit—rather than for the benefit of others. Whatever profits will be derived from the investment of his savings and reserves, will accrue to himself and not to persons who give not an hour’s work to the industry—who perhaps, do not even know where the properties in which they are security holders are located—who have never set foot in the plants from which they derive dividends—or who, perhaps, are not even residents of the United States. 3 Briefly my plan contemplates increasing the number of investors considerably, to such an extent that practically all wage earners and salaried men and women, will be, or at least could be, small investors, deriving separate incomes from their labor and their investment, during the greater part of their lives. I may be boasting when I say that we will succeed in doing what the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs, with all their 8 Prior to the war it was estimated that about five billions of Euro¬ pean capital was invested in American securities. One wrtier went so far as to say that more than ten billions of English Capital is invested in the United States alone. I give these figures as mere estimates. 384 The New Capitalism “brains’’ have failed to do, what they are so desperately trying to do at the present time—viz., to greatly increase the number of small “ investors. ’ ’ Under my plan all the workers—that is to say a majority of the public who are now and will continue, under the Capitalistic Entrepre¬ neur System, to be classed merely as wage earners, will have an opportunity to change their status from non-investor to investor and capitalist. We will make stock owners , not stock holders of them; co-partners in our enterprises; co-owners of our properties; co-sharers in all the benefits accruing to an investor and in the profits reaped by a Capitalist. No Altruism in Business There is not a single instance on record of any man, or group of men, going into business primarily to promote the public welfare. The sole impetus has ever been the desire to make money; the prime motive— Profits. The railroads of the United States were built not so that people might conveniently and cheaply travel whithersoever they please, or that they might have their supplies transported from the place of production to their homes at a minimum cost. Nor were they built for the purpose of giving employ¬ ment to a considerable number of people. The inspiration for their building must be sought wholly in the vision of immense profits for their builders and promoters. And this perfectly natural aspiration is predicable of every suc¬ cessful industry. If any benefits redound to the public at large, or to any considerable number of the public, that is always incidental, or, which is more likely, because in the promulgation of benefits the profits were to be found. Profits, ever and always, were the inspiration, the im¬ petus and the beacon light. Profits—and “the public be damned! ’ ’ Pro jits Under the New Capitalism Will we turn up our noses at profits? We will not! Indeed there is one good thing about the tremendous price Wages Under the New Capitalism 385 increases and concurrent wage increases that have been made during the past twenty-five years. It will give the New Capitalism a fine opportunity to prove its value to the workers—to that large group who are today non¬ investors. Here is the formula: High prices and high wages have yielded immense profits to the Capitalistic group and constituent members of the Capitalistic System. We accept the status quo. We accept the high prices and the high wages. We will maintain wages at the high point and then deliberately, gradually, systematically, reduce prices —i. e., living costs. The corporate profits quite naturally, will be less—but the savings of the individuals will be greater. These savings are profits in the true sense of the word, but instead of appearing conspicuously on the books of our corporations they will appear conspicuously in the pockets of the workers. Instead of being retained by a few, as at present, our profits will be distributed among the many through the medium of lower prices, i. e., as a result of a greater exchange value of wages and a higher purchasing power of money. In brief, there will be no elimination of profits; the only difference being that henceforth they will be savings. More¬ over, these savings will become Capital accumulations, con¬ vertible into investments, the normal returns or dividends on which will accrue to the savers themselves as investors, not as at present, to the Capitalistic users of the savings of the wage earners. Pro jits and Capital Accumulations There are those who will say that the maintenance of high wages and the lowering of prices are mutually ex¬ clusive—that it is impossible to pay high wages and reduce living costs. Well, we shall see whether they are right; we propose to find out for ourselves. In the meantime let us not forget that the capital accumulations during the past twenty years have been at the rate of ten billion a year. These immense capital accumulations were derived from the bountiful Capitalistic profits accruing from sundry 386 The New Capitalism sources; inflation of capitalization, money monopoly, monopoly of raw materials, manufacturing industries, transportation systems, public utilities, speculation in farm products, exorbitant rentals,—and from stock gambling. Under my system the capital accumulations will not be so great. Indeed it is for the specific purpose of cutting down capital accumulations that we propose to organize. Since there will be no money monopoly as it exists today there will be a considerable reduction in the “ profits” derived from this source alone; but a greater saving will result to the public. With regard to the industries—we will have no inflated capitalization; no dividends to pay on non-existing capital. This will decrease “profits” but increase savings. And since there will be no speculating in our stocks possible, a source of revenue now wide open to promoters, speculators and gamblers will be practically cut off. All of which will have a tendency to cut down what has hitherto been called in Capitalistic parlance, profits, or capital accumulations. But savings will increase. Let me illustrate the principle: Let me say that in a given year twenty-five billions of wages were paid, and that living costs totaled twenty-five billions. The exchange of the twenty-five billions of wages for twenty-five billions of living commodities, yielded a profit that enabled a few million of the Capitalistic System to heap up say, five bil¬ lions of capital accumulations. Under the New Capitalism wages would remain the same —twenty-five billions—but living costs would be lowered to twenty billions, let us say. The difference, five billions, will remain in the possession of the wage earners as savings. That is the vital difference that I shall ask you to keep constantly in mind. Their savings will become the capital accumulations of the workers, whose income from wages will be augmented by an income from their investments. “How can a nation be rich without having rich men in it?” asked a financial writer recently. I will answer that question after the writer quoted answers these few questions: Wages Under the New Capitalism 387 1: What is the difference whether the aggregate of a nation’s wealth—for instance that of the United States, said to be 288 billions—is owned by four million families or by twenty million families? 2: Which nation is richer—the one whose productive properties are owned by four million families of investors or by twenty million families of investors? 3 : Is it preferable that the profits derived from the indus¬ try of the nation’s workers be concentrated in the hands of a few, or more widely diffused among the many? 4: If the national income in 1918 was, as claimed, fifty- five billion, would the nation be poorer today if the uncon¬ sumable portion were reinvested by twenty million families rather than by only four million of the twenty million families ? I could ask a few other pertinent questions, but these will suffice for the present. And Mamvnonism Must Bleed to Death Let it be understood that I have never, and I do not now advocate, what is sometimes spoken of as an “equal division” of profits or of wealth. Against such proposals I set my teeth. But I do demand that henceforth the pres¬ ent non-investor public—the wage earners—shall be given a greater opportunity of saving a fair part of their wages, and an opportunity of investing their savings in enter¬ prises that belong to them rather than in enterprises that belong to a mighty few. And that they, rather than the mighty few, shall receive whatever profits might accrue from the joint investment of their capital (savings) and their labor. If this can be done (and the whole purpose of my book is to show that it can be done), the problem of the distri¬ bution of profits and wealth will be solved in a manner that is legitimate, fair and just. And the evil of Mam- monism—the concentration of all the wealth in the hands of a few, will cease to afflict us. CHAPTER XXVIII The Cost of Living Under the New Capitalism T HROUGHOUT this work I have endeavored to con¬ fine myself strictly to facts and figures, all of which I have used as a basis for my various statements, con¬ tentions, computations, deductions and conclusions. In this chapter I am going to indulge my fancy just a little, and even allow my imagination to roam at will. Let me, therefore, continue to suppose the existence of the New Order, and that the New Capitalism has begun to function. It will take at least one year to raise the initial $300,000,000. Beyond a doubt, with all potentialities ex¬ ploited to the fullest extent (as can be seen from Chapter XIX) we could raise the requisite initial capital within ninety days; but that is not desirable, for the reason that before we can effectively employ our capital it will be necessary to thoroughly and completely organize, and plan our campaign—measuring every step of the way, and the distance we are to go. And this, I figure, will take at least twelve months, during which time—be it remembered —we would be accumulating $300,000,000 of our Basic Capital Fund. We shall hardly care to begin aggressive operations before that time. Even after setting ourselves in motion the effects of our operations will not be materially felt during the first year; not until the following year will we be able to show unmistakable results. I say this pre¬ ferring to be conservative in making promises, or painting visions, or raising hopes, for I would rather surprise all those who will be interested in watching our .progress, by exceeding their expectations, than disappoint them by fall¬ ing short of their fulfilment. 388 Cost of Living Under New Capitalism 389 Briefly summarized the endeavor of the New Order under the New Capitalism will be to bring the living costs of the average wage earner (or non-investor) family down to a point that will leave a surplus of wages to be invested by the wage earners themselves, in enterprises that will yield an income in addition to wages. The Normal Level of Living Costs But before we can establish a normal level of living costs, it behooves us to ascertain what can be considered a rational and attainable level. Precisely where is a normal or rational level of living costs to be found ? In what year can it be said that living costs were at a normal or rational level? In 1896 prices were at their lowest; the dollar had its greatest value; wages their greatest exchange value. Is this the normal or rational level? I shall say no! But even if it were—and if returning thither were desirable and the ultima thule of all economic endeavor, the return trip would have to be so slow as to become wearisome to the travelers. It would have been easier ten years ago; today it is well nigh impossible, and we may just as well dismiss the thought from our minds, once and for all. Moreover, the war has produced certain economic effects that must be reckoned with—that cannot be ignored. To make a long story short I have set as an attainable goal the living costs of 1915—not, however, by the familiar Capitalistic Entrepreneur method of lowering wages first. In fact my plan does not contemplate the cutting of wages; on the contrary it insists on the main¬ tenance of prevailing wages. The Living Costs Per Family Let us confine ourselves for the present to the subject of “living costs,” and see how they mounted under the gegis of the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System, and of which mounting the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs were the principal beneficiaries. The cost of living for an average family in 1900 was 390 The New Capitalism about $650 a year. This cost increased in the last twenty years about as follows : Average yearly increase. 1900 .$ 650 1910 . 850 $20.00 1915 . 1,100 50.00 1920 . 1,5501 90.00 The increases were less by leaps and bounds than by a steady, gradual growth. For the first ten years of the Capitalistic System the increases were at the rate of about $20 a year. For the next five years, at the rate of about $50 a year. From 1915 to 1920, at the rate of about $90 a year. All the increases were cumulative and are now permanent. If there is no marked recession in the retail prices of all classes of commodities, or a considerable increase in quality (and matters in this regard will grow worse instead of better under the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System); if rents remain at their present high figure, it means that from now on every average family will pay $900 a year more each calendar year than in 1900, or $9,000 during the next ten years. It means that the 16,000,000 non-investor families henceforth—thanks to the ingenuity of the Capitalistic arrangement—will pay $14,400,000,000 a year more for the bare privilege of living then they did twenty years ago. Think of it!—$14,400,000,000 a year, or a total of $144,000,000,000 during the next ten years. Under the New Capitalism we propose to bring down the living costs, not suddenly but gradually, steadily, and pro¬ gressively. We propose to reduce them at the rate of about $50 a year. Within five years we would bring down the cost of living commodities from $1550 to about $1350; and within ten years to approximately the 1915 level, i.e., to about $1100. This reduction would mean a saving of $450 a year for an average family, or a saving of $4,500 in ten years per family. i Throughout this book I have conservatively considered $1,500 as the living cost of an average family, in spite of the fact that unbiased statisticians have computed that a family can not live in decent comfort for less than $2,000, some even claiming $2,600 as a minimum. Cost of Living Under New Capitalism 391 This means an aggregate saving for the 16,000,000 non¬ investor families of $7,200,000,000 a year, or $72,000,000,000 within ten years. Take your choice, my fellow workmen and non-invest¬ ors ! Under the old Capitalism you will be compelled to pay to the Capitalistic System during the next ten years $144,000,000,000 more than the living costs of 1900. Whereas, under the New Capitalism you will be enabled to save $72,000,000,000 within ten years. Paying Tribute to Caesar It ought to be possible to bring living costs down to less than a thousand dollars a year, but several elements will make this difficult, if not impossible. This check on our ability to lower living costs much beyond the 1915 level, is, in a measure, due to the fact that we will have to contend for a while w T ith adverse conditions created by the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneur System which cannot be remedied all at once. It must be remembered that the Capitalistic group has a monopoly on practically all the basic materials that enter into industry; coal, iron, lumber, oil, etc. Under the circumstances the basic materials, and consequently, fin¬ ished products, will cost more than they would if they were not monopolistically controlled. In due time we mean to break this monopolistic stranglehold on the basic raw ma¬ terials, and finished products, but we realize that it will require time to bring this about. The outstanding feature of the situation is that the giant Capitalistic Entrepreneurs have so powerful a grip on many of the important materials and products that for a while we shall be compelled to pay tribute to them. Their monopoly in due time will be broken —that is part of my plan; but I should not care to set a time limit for the present. The Nation’s Tremendous Freight Bill I have already shown that the same group that abso¬ lutely controls the nation’s finances, and has a monopoly of the basic materials and the industries, also owns and 392 The New Capitalism controls the transportation systems of the United States. I shall waste no time in expatiating on what is generally known, that the increase in the nation’s freight bill has more than doubled within recent years. A glance at the following statistics 2 for the “freight revenue” of the rail¬ roads, will show this conclusively. R. R. Freight Revenue. 1900 .$1,049,000,000 1910 . 1,925,000,000 1920 . 4,373,989,717 A chapter could easily be written on this subject; there is so much to say about it. But at the present moment I am concerned only with one feature, and that is, that as conditions are, or rather will be after the railroads have “ adjusted” the wages of all the railroad employees, the nation will be compelled to pay, annually, considerably more freight on its commodities than in former years. In due time the New Order will demonstrate the possibility and urgency of relief from this tremendous item of freight charges; but nothing can be done immediately. All that is said here is for the purpose of emphasizing that it is one of the formidable handicaps which the Capitalistic System has constructed, and with which we shall grapple as best we can for the first decade of years. Inflated Real Estate Values There are other disadvantages under which we will be compelled to operate for some time—thanks to the iniqui¬ tous principles established by the Capitalistic System. I refer particularly to the system of arbitrarily inflated values of properties. Inflation is universal; it applies not only to the properties from which the basic materials are derived, and to the manufacturing industries—basic or derivative—it is predicable of all kinds of properties—par¬ ticularly land. Real estate values everywhere, or, more properly speaking, real estate juices, have been doubled 2 Railway Statistics of the United States, for 1920. Cost of Living Under New Capitalism 393 and trebled, many increased tenfold, thanks to the stimulus for speculation and for “profit-taking” given to the real estate speculators by the Capitalistic System. The increase in the value, or rather in the prices, of city property since the adoption of the Capitalistic System’s method of computing “values” has been enormous. Natu¬ rally the inflation of “values” means higher rents and consequently a bigger “overhead expense,” all of which has increased prices to the non-investor group, and is likely to prevent the cost of living from coming down to its ulti¬ mate normal level for some years to come. The increase in rentals, within recent years, instituted throughout the United States, is responsible for a considerable increase in living costs. I do not mean only the rents paid by indi¬ viduals and families, but also the rents for offices, stores, factories, warehouses ,etc., and which find their way back into the living costs. I should say that the average is easily 100 percent increase. The rentals of stores, shops, offices and lofts, were, during the war, raised from fifty to three and four hundred per¬ cent. This was brought out in the Lockwood Committee investigation in New York. Increases of fifty percent were so common, Samuel Untermyer, Committee Counsel, said, that he would not trouble himself to read them into the record. “Some of the buildings named by Mr. Untermyer were, the Standard Oil Building, 26 Broadway, where it was charged, one rent was increased from $1,500 in 1916 to $4,700 in 1921, and another from $15,000 in 1920 to $32,000 in 1921; Corn Exchange Building, 15 Williams St., from $1,200 in 1918 to $2,400 in 1921; 470 Fourth Avenue, $4,500 in 1920 to $12,000 in 1921.” . . . “Among the many instances of increased rents was one where a tenant whose lease called for $9,000 two years ago, now pays $24,000 for the same suite. “There were some cases where offices renting five years ago for a few hundred dollars, were leased this year for several thousand dollars. Tenants who paid $2 a square 394 The New Capitalism foot last year in a down-town sky-scraper, sign leases for 1921 requiring payment of $6, $7, and $8 for the same space.” 3 The conditions that exist with regard to the increases in rentals applies to all the cities in the United States. Thou¬ sands of small business men and women have been forced out of business because their rent had been raised to a point that made continuance unprofitable. The Crushing Burden of Taxes But even though it were possible to break the Capital¬ istic Entrepreneur stranglehold with regard to monopolies and inflated values and high rents, within a single year’s time, there are two items which we cannot of our own ability reduce, namely the taxes that have arisen out of the recent war, and the tariffs. Briefly stated, the Federal Government collects, and will indefinitely collect, from the twenty million families, annually, from four to five billion dollars a year in taxes. In the Mid-Month Review of Busi¬ ness, September 15, 1921, published by the Irving National Bank of New York, statistics compiled by George W. Norris, Governor of the Philadelphia Reserve Bank, pertaining to the annual governmental expenditures, are given. Before the war these were computed to be $33 per family of five. Now they are $214.80 per family of five. Surely there is none to dispute that the wage earners— the non-investors—pay the major portion of all taxes directly and indirectly. The following is an excerpt from an article ‘ ‘ The Crush¬ ing Burden of Taxation,” published in The Boston Com¬ mercial , April 8, 1922: “The Boston Chamber of Commerce has been collecting some data from state and federal sources to show the bur¬ den of taxation, which was borne by the citizens of Massa¬ chusetts that year. From them we have been making a few calculations that deserve more than passing notice. “In the year 1910 the internal revenue taxes collected in 3 Commercial Edition Chicago Herald-Examiner, June 10, 1921. Cost of Living Under New Capitalism 395 Massachusetts were $7,400,000, and state, county and local taxes totaled $85,800,000, or a combined tax on the people of Massachusetts of $93,200,000. The population of Mas¬ sachusetts in 1910 was 3,366,000, which made a per capita tax of about $28. Taking the census figures of 4.3 persons to a family, the tax per family in 1910 was $120 or $2.30 a week. “Ten years later the federal government levied on Mas¬ sachusetts for $259,000,000 and the state, county and local tax was $198,000,000, or a total tax of $457,000,000, an increase of 400 percent. In 1920 the population had in¬ creased to 3,852,000, making the per capita tax nearly $120, and the family tax approximately $520 or ten dollars per week. “It is idle to claim that these taxes are paid by anyone but the ultimate consumer and the ultimate consumer on whom the burden falls the heaviest is the man who works for wages.” George Wheeler Hinman, writing in the Herald-Ex¬ aminer (February 10, 1921), says that Congressman Sisson told the House of Representatives a few days ago that the total expense of all the Governments in the United States —national, state, county and city—are $15,000,000,000 a year. This means that ‘ ‘ the average man with a family of five has to pay, in one way or another, some $750 as his share. He may pay it directly in taxes, or indirectly in prices, or partly in taxes and partly in prices; but he has to pay it somehow.” Whatever the exact amount of federal, state, county and municipal taxes paid by the average family, it is apparent that in the aggregate taxes constitute a burden of tremen¬ dous proportions, for the lifting of which the New Order does not pretend that it can fashion an Archimedian lever. But while we can promise no immediate relief from taxes, the whole subject of Taxation will be studied from the standpoint of the ultimate payer of all taxes—and a way may be found to lighten the load. 396 The New Capitalism The Tariff Tax Then there is the Tariff. What the Tariff means to the average family may be judged from the following excerpts from a speech on the Fordney Tax Bill, by the Hon. Percy E. Quin, of Mississippi, published in the Congressional Record, July 13, 1921: “Today it takes one-third of the cost of all products to pay the railroad transportation. You have raised the transportation of railways more than $1,000,000,000 yearly, and yet in power all of this time and nothing has been done to stop it. The gentleman from Kansas (Mr. White) yes¬ terday quoted from the President’s message where he said that the rates of transportation would have to come down. This was one of the great evils of the day. Today in the United States the annual cost to the American people for railway transportation is $4,000,000,000. The annual tax of municipal and county taxes—State and Federal—makes a total of $9,000,000,000; four and a half or five billions of that is out of the Federal taxation power of the United States Government, and through this monstrous bill you propose to put through here you are going to take out of the taxpayers of the United States at least $3,000,000,000 or $4,000,000,000 more money, and less than $500,000 or $600,000 of it will go into the Treasury of the United States. Where does the difference between the amount that goes into the Treasury and that which comes out of the pockets of the people of this Republic go ? You are putting it into the coffers of the rich, the corporations, trusts, and partnerships of this Republic.” On June 25, 1922, Senator David I. Walsh, of Massachu¬ setts, made public statistics showing that the increased rates in agricultural products in the tariff bill, under discussion in the Senate, will add $13.15 annually to the cost of living of every individual in the United States: “At the very period when we are attempting to deflate the enormous costs of production and the excess prices prevailing as a result of war conditions, it is proposed to increase the cost Cost of Living Under New Capitalism 397 of living to the American people to the extent of $1,316,- 569,449 per annum.” The Tariff question will be carefully studied by us—from the non-investor’s standpoint, and not from the Capital¬ istic standpoint. Increase in Price and Decrease in Quality But while our hands will be tied for some years to come, with regard to a number of the fortuitous items that find their way into the cost of our sundry living commodities, there are some things with regard to which we will be strong enough to compel amelioration. For example: There is one point in the “cost of living” which no one seems so far to have discovered or discussed; nor do the various index numbers take it into consideration, viz., that for a large number of articles, such as clothing, shoes and sundry kinds of wearing apparel—textiles and fabrics—not only are prices practically double what they were in 1914 but the quality has been materially reduced, thus putting the whole nation to the necessity of buying approximately double the quantity. For all these items the increase has been not one hundred percent, but nearer three hundred percent. Ac¬ cording to the statisticians, the item of “clothing” consti¬ tutes about sixteen percent of the average family budget; which being the case, the non-investor families (or wage earners) pay out an aggregate of about four billion dollars. The expenditure of about one-half of this immense sum is made necessary on account of reductions in quality, a shrewd calculation made by the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs. It is not to be supposed for a minute that the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs reduced quality in order to keep a large number of workmen employed. By no means! They re¬ duced quality because it necessitates double the consump¬ tion—consequently means double profits to them. In other words, Capital, with regard to the industries w r here there lias been a material reduction in quality, makes twice as much as formerly on the output per workman; for the price 398 The New Capitalism of the present inferior article is approximately the same as the price of the former superior article. Reduction in quality (to say nothing at this time about a noticeable reduction in the quantity for an ever increas¬ ing number of articles) means the expenditure of billions of dollars a year. We propose a material increase in the quality, not only of clothing but with regard to many arti¬ cles of family use. This will mean a tremendous saving in the family budget. My Modest Claim As regards the cost of living of the average family: I hold that, under the New Capitalism it will be possible to bring down prices of the aggregate living commodities to a point which will enable the average family to save from $100 to $450 a year. It may take from five to ten years before the maximum figure is reached, but even during the first five years the saving will be appreciable. It is not to be supposed for a moment that the New Order will concern itself only with manufacturing industries. It will include within its sphere of operation, economic adjust¬ ments in sundry directions. Anything that has helped to increase the cost of living unduly, or refuses to return to a more rational level of prices, will be grist for our mill. We are determined to increase the exchange value of the dollar, to restore its maximum purchasing power. We pro¬ pose to revitalize the emaciated, debilitated wage dollar, not by a weak saline injection, but by blood transfusion from the giant Capitalistic dollar—treatment that may be a trifle heroic, but absolutely necessary and effective. No Utopian World Let none imagine that the New Order is in any way intended as a Utopia; let none delude himself into think¬ ing that its complete success will usher in the millennium. Neither a Utopian world, nor a millennial heaven on earth will result from the adoption of my plan. But it will bring the country back to a common sense basis of business, and Cost of Living Under New Capitalism 399 common sense views of life will begin to control the world. That is about as much as I expect to achieve through the medium of my plan. The New Capitalism is intended to usher in an era of Common Sense-ism—the only ism that has never been advocated—that no one has ever suggested. The New Capitalism is not a catholicon for the ills of the world. It is not an alchemy that converts dross into precious metal. It does not pretend that it will shake Hes- perides apples into the lap of Labor. It holds out no promise of great wealth to anyone. All it will aim to do is to place those who labor in a position that will assure them the highest possible recompense for work performed, while enabling them to live in decent comfort, and retain (and invest) a fair portion of their earnings, against the inevitable ‘ ‘ rainy day. ’ ’ There will never be a system of economics that will straighten out all tangles, or be equable for all. My plan is not calculated to take care of the foolish, the imprudent, the lazy, the shiftless, the thoughtless, the extravagant. These ye have always with you. I have no idea how a man can eat his cake and have it too. I know of no way in which common sense can be pounded into the heads of foolish people. I do not know of any way in which people can spend all they earn or make, and also have a compe¬ tence at the end of twenty or twenty-five years—a reserve fund for old age, infirmity, sickness and accidents. My plan, however, will give every man and woman his or her choice—each can choose to be sensible or foolish—provident or improvident—frugal or prodigal, thrifty or shiftless. My solace is that tens of millions of those who, with the best of will, can, under the present conditions, hardly make ends meet or barely keep the ends together, will henceforth be enabled to save a fair portion of their earnings, which profitably invested, will secure them and those dependent upon them, against poverty and wretchedness. CHAPTER XXIX “Out of the Fryihg Pax into the Fire” E VEN a cursory examination of economic history reveals that numerous attempts have been made at different times by the people of European nations to break and thrust off the shackles of their economic serfdom. Socialism is rampant in Germany. In Russia the new eco¬ nomic order is Bolshevism. In France, we hear, or at least did hear up to a few years ago, much of Syndicalism. In England the Guild movement seems to be gathering strength. In Italy, until recently, a mixture of Socialism, Syndicalism, and Bolshevism prevailed; now Fascism is in the saddle. While there is no universal agreement with regard to principles, nor uniformity as regards programs, most of the economic reform movements in Europe have certain ten¬ dencies in common. Thus, for example, we observe in every country where the revolutionary spirit is rampant, a growing desire on the part of the people to overthrow their rulers and the existing governments, some extreme doctrinaires going even so far as to advocate the destruc¬ tion of all government. The inspiration for this attitude is easy to understand when we keep in mind that in most European nations the people have practically nothing what¬ ever to say with regard to their own political affairs and destinies. They are subjects, rather than citizens; ruled, rather than governed. What makes their resentment all the bitterer is their knowledge that those who rule over them politically, also rule over them economically. The Fallacy of a Worker's Republic And so, out of the babble of economic voices across the ocean, we can distinctly hear shrill mention of what it pleases some to call the rule of the proletariat, or a “ work¬ ers' republic.” From the economic standpoint a “workers’ 400 “Out of the Frying Pan 401 republic” is at best a madman’s dream. In Russia they tried to establish one; with what success is generally known. In Italy, and in other countries, several attempts have been made within recent times on the part of groups of work¬ men, to take over, sans ceremonie, the leading industries. Every such attempt is bound to fail ultimately; or else, to succeed, must become a proletarian tyranny, no less repug¬ nant than the Capitalistic tyranny it was designed to destroy. In England, if I may base my conclusions on such long¬ distance studies of the Guild movement as I have been enabled to make from the writings of such men as Douglas, Penty, Cole—and others—Labor is preparing for the day when it proposes to assume active control of the industrial workshops. England’s Labor movement is seemingly bet¬ ter organized than in other countries; the workers have a definite plan and program; but granting all this I can dis¬ cern no hope of economic betterment, neither for the work¬ ers nor for England’s general public. I may be wrong as regards England! but applying the principles involved in the rule of the proletariat—or a “workers’ republic” to conditions in the United States, and with -which I am fairly familiar—I unhesitatingly say a so-called “workers’ republic” is not only utterly repug¬ nant to me; but entirely unthinkable. No Revolutionary Program in the United States Briefly, any and every brand of revolutionary doctrine or radical economic reform movement that may be defens¬ ible and perfectly logical in Europe where political and economic conditions are entirely different, and, it would seem, decidedly worse than in our own country, is inap¬ plicable to the United States, and cannot succeed here. True, we find here and there isolated radical groups, whose leaders, entirely lacking in originality, have borrowed sun¬ dry tenets from the various European revolutionary doc¬ trines and incorporated them into a sort of program, which, however, makes no appeal to the imagination of the average 402 The New Capitalism sensible man and woman; a program so extreme, and vio¬ lent, that it does not, cannot, and never will, win the approval of any considerable number of the general public in the United States. Rather would we bear the ills we have, several times multiplied, than fly to others that in all likelihood would be more unendurable. A Fundamental Fallacy In “industrial socialism’’ I can discern only this one erroneous thought, that the earth and all it can be made to bring forth, belongs to the industrial workers, and that industrial workers have a prior claim to the usufruct of all Labor. This is precisely the fallacy upon which the Cap¬ italistic System has builded itself. The principles involved are so obviously untenable that I shall not delay the reader a moment in emphasizing their falsity. To my way of thinking there is not the slightest difference between an economic system whose bountiful emoluments, as is the case today, are selfishly pre-empted by a few million minority —the many more millions majority being made to suffer— and a system which proposes that the same emoluments shall hereafter be appropriated by a different minority, which would not lighten in the least, but make heavier, the burden of the greater majority. While I differentiate between industrial socialism and organized Labor, for the two are as wide apart in their ideals and their policies as the poles—nevertheless I have observed that group dominance and control of industries is not entirely repugnant to certain Labor groups. Needless to say, I do not sympathize with their aspirations, which I think are based on insufficient understanding of the fun¬ damental principles involved, rather than inspired by any evil design. Economic Amelioration Vagaries But while we have not in the United States any organ¬ ized economic movement, or any economic doctrine that has won for itself the endorsement and support of any con- “Out of the Frying Pan—” 403 siderable number.of people, we have a rather variegated collection of theories and so-called remedies, each of which has succeeded in winning a limited number of adherents. During the past few years I have read at least a dozen books and articles in which the writers suggest various ways by which Labor could get control of industries—as if that in itself were a panacea for all our economic ills. If there were any truth in that assumption the people of Russia would today be at the zenith of their economic prosperity, for there the proletariat has taken over the industries, with what results to themselves and the country is now pretty generally understood. But political and economic condi¬ tions in Russia are different from our own, and I do not consider it either fair or necessary to draw a parallel be¬ tween the happenings in Russia and what would likely happen in our own country, were like measures adopted. With regard to the proposals of the several writers who have ventured seriously to propose the possibility of Labor’s control of the industries, the suggestions they make seem plausible enough until analyzed; and then they fall to pieces. Labor is to take over the control—by purchase, I infer— of the industries just as they are—including overcapitali¬ zation, watered stock, bonds, notes, liabilities, cost systems, overhead expense, fixed charges and all; the difference would be that the profits and the accruing interest and dividends would go to the workingmen instead of as at present, to the Capitalists or the investors. This is sup¬ posed to be of some immediate benefit to the workers. It isn % as I shall show; but granting for the moment that it would be of advantage to the workers, it would certainly yield no benefits and certainly no advantages to those not numbered among the workers in the several industries taken over. It would solve none of our economic difficulties. Production costs would remain the same; prices of com¬ modities would be as high as ever; rents would not be low¬ ered; in brief it would not decrease the burden nor lessen the hardships now resting on the average non-investor family. 404 The New Capitalism Any economic scheme that has for its immediate objective an increase of benefits for a minority, a single group, at the expense of the majority is in no wise different from what we have today, and consequently does not win my approval. Any economic proposal that seeks to confine its benefits to a fraction of the workers, and excludes all others from par¬ ticipation therein, does not merit serious consideration. That is precisely the trouble now\ The benefits all accrue to a group, the Capitalistic group, while the larger group— those who work for a wage and who are no part of the Capitalistic System, must bear the brunt of it. Let us for a moment imagine that the ten million workers engaged in the mechanical and manufacturing industries actually had gained control, (and by perfectly legitimate means, let us say,) of all the industries; and whatever benefits would accrue would belong exclusively to the ten million workers. Of what benefit would the transfer of control or ownership be to twenty or twenty-five million of men and women workers who are not engaged in any of the industries concerned? None whatever! An Economic Experiment From a newspaper editorial, a clipping, (December 11, 1920) I learn that an ex-minister in Cincinnati is at pres¬ ent the president of a large clothing factory, in the conduct of which he applies the Golden Rule. Some of the results noted in the item before me are these: “Wages have been increased forty percent. Invested Capital is earning sixty percent. Profits above sixty percent are equally divided between owners and workers. Perfect content reigns in the factory. ’ ’ I made no effort whatever to look up this matter, or make any inquiries concerning it, since to give detailed informa¬ tion with regard to the various economic experiments is not included within the scope of my book. I do not know what the conditions in said clothing factory are today; but assum¬ ing they are unchanged, and basing my statement upon the meager data contained in the newspaper item from “Out of the Frying Pan 405 7 7 which I have quoted, I would conclude that the factory is conducted in some respects along the lines advocated by those writers who consider Labor’s control of the indus¬ tries as an economic remedy. 1 * * * * * If the statement that “in¬ vested capital is earning sixty percent ’ 7 is not an exaggera¬ tion, then the ex-minister ’s clothing factory is certainly run on a basis calculated to be of the greatest advantage to the workers ivithin that factory; in that case few, if any, benefits, redound to the general public. Basing my assump¬ tion entirely upon the information contained in the item referred to, I am inclined to think that the products of the ex-minister’s clothing factory are sold at approximately the same high prices asked for the products of other plants. If I am correct in assuming this, then the opportunity for noting an essential difference between the ex-minister’s plan and my own plan has arisen. Decent wages for workers are the prime consideration of my plan; nor do I overlook the necessity for reasonable profits. But more important than either or both of these features are lower prices to the public for the commodities produced, for this alone makes wages and profits valuable. It is not my plan to make the New Order advantageous only to certain groups of indus¬ trial workers, but to make it of the greatest possible benefit to all workers—that is—the general public. The Deadly Distinction I want to emphasize this distinctive feature of my plan. If its successful establishment meant merely the improved condition of small groups of workers—or the laboring group in the aggregate; if it meant simply the transference of an unjust and tyrannical power now in the hands of the organized Capitalistic Entrepreneurs to the hands of organ- i Since writing - the above I have discovered that the ex-minister is the Rev. Mr. Nash. Besides critical articles have been published about his plan and plant in the Neio Republic and The Nations with all of which, however, I am not concerned. I shall confine myself strictly to a discussion of the principles involved. Nothing that I have read with regard to the Rev. Mr. Nash’s clothing factory alters the principles involved in his experiment. 406 The New Capitalism ized Labor, then, economically speaking, the public in gen¬ eral would be no better off than it is today. High prices and the high cost of living would still be evils, all the more distressing because maintained by the very people who complained loudest against them. As stated before—I may be in error in having arrived at certain conclusions with regard to the ex-minister’s clothing factory; but even so—it gives me an opportunity to accen¬ tuate a point which I shall be at great pains to make per¬ fectly clear in the course of this book. We mean, indeed, to destroy the unjust and tyrannical power of the Capi¬ talistic Entrepreneur System. The tremendous power the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs now exercise will be wielded by us, but never unjustly or tyrannically. In our hands that power must be beneficent, and exercised in a strictly just manner so as to yield the greatest good to the greatest num¬ ber. Another point that I desire to accentuate on every pos¬ sible occasion in the course of this book, is that big profits do not constitute the ultima thule of my plan. On the contrary we shall strive to bring about a condition that will considerably reduce the excessive profits now garnered by the Capitalistic Entrepreneur group; for it is quite provable that big profits are the corollary of high prices of the living commodities. As long as prices are high and profits big, so long will the purchasing power of the dollar be proportionately below par; so long will wages have a minimum exchange value. To pay liberal wages for labor performed will be a definite striving of my plan—but high wages are of no avail unless accompanied by a higher purchasing power—a greater ex¬ change value. A maximum wage with a minimum exchange value is demonstrably an economic maladjustment of no special advantage to the worker, nor of benefit to the public in general; but a maximum wage with a maximum exchange value—that is an ideal with a practical purpose—an ideal that we shall strive to realize. “Out of the Frying Pan—” 407 Again the Question of Exchange If it were possible for each trade, craft, or guild, to abso¬ lutely control its own industry, and raise the prices of its products ad libitum —and so add to its wages also, enormous profits,—Labor would still not have improved its relative condition one particle, for the profits made by the workers in one craft would be taken away by the workers in all the other crafts. Let us take, for example, the clothing indus¬ try. Under Labor’s control of the craft, the profits made by the clothing workers would be taken away again by the shoemakers, the hat makers, the shirt makers, the dress¬ makers, the milliners, the furniture makers, etc., etc. Not only that, they would be compelled to pay excessively high prices for many things that are not produced in shops and factories and mills; for example, rent, and the many prod¬ ucts of the farm necessary to their existence. Absolutely no advantage would result to the wage workers from inde¬ pendent group control of the industries; their economic condition would in nowise be improved; indeed, they would be worse off than they are today. Playing With a Loaded Gun Labor must keep these two essential things in mind: 1: That wages come out of the product of Labor itself. In other words, in the course of production one workman exchanges his labor for the labor of other workmen. When the hatmaker buys a pair of shoes he helps to pay the wages of the shoemaker; and the shoemaker helps to pay the wages of the hatmaker when he buys a hat. There is no escape from this rule. No system of ^economics can ever be devised that would alter this exchange of labor feature, and its corollary that the wages of one group of laborers are ultimately paid by all the other laboring groups. 2 : That all profits come directly out of Labor’s wages— or let me rather say out of the exchange of wages by those who labor for the commodities necessary to life. Conse¬ quently Labor in the mass would not improve its condition 408 The New Capitalism one iota. Living costs would not only remain at an abnor¬ mally high level, but undoubtedly would rise still higher; and while the workers themselves might, by a division of the profits among themselves, increase the quantity of their wages or income, they would be no better off at the end of the year, for their greater quantity income would have no greater exchange value; and their savings no greater pur¬ chasing power. For the present I want to impress upon the readers, par¬ ticularly on those who are wage earners, that the New Order is not to be an organization of and for the exclusive benefit of workingmen, but of and for the benefit of all those who constitute the group of non-investors. Nor is the New Capi¬ talism intended to give temporary advantages to a few of them; but rather permanent benefits to all of them—with¬ out exception. The Inherent Weakness of Organized Labor The inherent weakness of all Labor organizations lies in the fact that the workers constituting them have organized themselves merely as wage earners. Six or seven million men and women have organized to protect themselves as wage earners, but they are unorganized as consumers—as non-investors. Indeed it could be demonstrated that the protection that Labor has gained for itself when serving in the capacity of wage earners, has been detrimental to the laborer and his family in the role of consumer and non¬ investor. Every advantage that Labor has gained through its organization is taken away in its unorganized capacity as consumer and non-'investor. In other words, Labor has protected itself for eight hours a day; but has left itself open to a thousand attacks during the remaining sixteen hours a day. Labor has protected itself for 2400 hours a year, but is absolutely unprotected during 6360 hours each year. Moreover, Labor, in protecting itself during eight hours, has been the innocent cause of imposing greater hardships upon a large percentage of the non-investor group of consumers—that group which is not organized or “Out of the Frying Pan 409 ? 1 could not derive any immediate benefit whatever from or¬ ganization. Into this group I will put all the salaried men and women, as well as those who, receiving no regular wages or salary, derive a revenue from their labor, or service, the equivalent of a wage or salary. But that is not the phase of the subject that I desire to discuss. I merely want to emphasize that Labor has organ¬ ized itself for collective protection for eight hours only, and left itself entirely unprotected during sixteen hours a day. Labor has, or thinks it has, protected itself against Capital, but I say that Labor has not protected itself against the Capitalistic System. What Labor has seemingly won from a few hundred thousand employers is taken away from it by several million profiteers. Protection during eight hours; exploitation during sixteen hours a day. Labor collectively is protected eight hours a day; the individual laborer still remains unprotected the greater part of the day. Let us take an average family of five, of which one is the wage earner. This means one member is protected for eight hours a day while actively engaged in the role of wage earner; he is not protected, and his organization can give him no protection, during the other sixteen hours. And the other four members of his family remain unpro¬ tected twenty-four hours a day. I have tried to put my thought in a manner easily under¬ stood by the average man and woman. I call upon my readers to ponder over my presentation a few moments, which, if they will do, they w T ill clearly see the point. As long as a wage earner can give himself no greater protection than at present; as long as he does not protect every member of his family every hour of the day, so long will he have de¬ rived no actual benefit, and certainly won no material ad¬ vantage from his organization. I have entitled this chapter ‘ ‘ Out of the Prying Pan into the Fire,” because it aptly describes the situation, for if the several groups of wage earners were in actual control of the industries, and they would raise both their wages and the prices of their products so that their aggregate income 410 The New Capitalism from these two sources would be one-fourth or one-third higher than it is today, they would still not have improved their own condition, for the reason that the exchange value of their wages would be lower than ever; and even though their savings would be larger than before (though I am dis¬ posed to doubt that) the purchasing power of their savings ■would be considerably less than it is today. And the eco¬ nomic status of the millions of men and women workers, those not engaged in the manufacturing industries, would be a great deal worse. Briefly, any economic reorganization plan that does not include within its program a definite design to raise the exchange value of wages and to increase the purchasing power of money (or savings) will bring no relief to the workers in the capacity of wage earners, nor to the workers in the role of consumers and non-investors—that is, to the general public. The Open Road to Disaster It is to be noted, too, that all the writers who had visions of Labor’s control of the industries as a remedy for our economic ills have overlooked the most important point— namely, the necessity for capital and credit. They have given no hint as to how the capital necessary to gain con¬ trol of the industries, or the capital and credit necessary to run them, is to be raised. And, most of all, they entirely overlooked the very important point, viz., that, even grant¬ ing the possibility of group control of the several industries, they would still be at the mercy of the Capitalistic group that controls the system of banks upon which they would have to depend for credit necessities, and to whom they would have to yield up their securities as collateral—in brief, in whose favor they would be compelled to hypothe¬ cate their plants and business. Foreclosures, refusal to renew notes, or extend credit facilities, receiverships and bankruptcies would be the order of the day. Indeed, it is on record that during the past few years several Labor groups have struck out for themselves, and that most of “Out of the Frying Pan 411 » 5 them have gone to pieces on the rocks of insufficient finances, and credit withdrawals, refusals and curtailments. It is well to remember that it was by virtue of their dominant control of the financial resources of the nation that the Capitalistic group attained its supremacy, even to the extent of crushing or controlling powerful rivals—and so- called independents. Any economic plan that disregards the existence of this cruel power is foredoomed to failure. It must be reckoned with, or else circumvented or check¬ mated. The greatest possible stupidity that organized Labor could perpetrate would be to break itself up into small, inde¬ pendent units—each group bent upon getting a maximum of revenue—‘ ‘ all that the traffic can bear ’ ’—out of its par¬ ticular industry. Were I a Capitalistic Entrepreneur I should not only welcome, but do all in my power to encour¬ age even to the extent of financing, so foolhardy a procedure on the part of Labor, for it would be the easiest thing in the world to crush group after group—and, once crushed, they would be out of harm’s way forevermore. The only possible chance that Labor has to lift itself out of eco¬ nomic thraldom is to constitute itself into an organized group; not to break itself up into disintegrated and unre¬ lated units. The Lesson of the Past Fifty years ago business was conducted on an entirely different basis than it is today. Then business ability, integ¬ rity, and efficiency of the proprietors of a business counted for something. Business was truly competitive; there was real rivalry, often keen, sometimes bitter. The man who went into business provided his own funds, managed his own finances, and established his own credit. As his busi¬ ness grew he took in a partner or two. Stock companies were almost unknown. Out of their profits they extended their business; out of their profits , be it understood. Or, if they borrowed, they paid back what they borrowed out 412 The New Capitalism of their profits. Their plant was considered by them as their machinery for making a fair profit—gradually increas¬ ing their wealth by increasing the size of their plants and the volume of their production. The foundation of every big industry was laid in the last half of the nineteenth century, under the then prevailing system. Most of the pioneers were successful business men—men who took a natural pride in making a success of their business. Finan¬ cially they were prosperous; they did not become mil¬ lionaires over night; it took years to lay the foundation of a fortune; and years to build the superstructure. Then came the period of Trusts. At first pools and syndicates were formed. Combinations of Capital were followed by the combination of the important manufac¬ turing plants. The founders of the plants, or their descend¬ ants, were persuaded by seductive offers to enter the com¬ bine. Most of them did, accepting as their reward stock of a par value several times in excess of the actual value of their properties and assets. Many of the existing plants that had been in competition with each other were deemed unnecessary under a system of combination that was cal¬ culated to entirely eliminate competition, and were closed up or dismantled. For several decades there had been many more or less successful attempts made at combination, but not until the organization of the United States Steel Corporation, which combined the biggest plants in the most important indus¬ try in the United States into one gigantic corporation, was launched, were the inherent possibilities of organized com¬ bines revealed. How the organization was effected, and that it was successful, is now pretty generally known. It is not any part of my design to go into details either with regard to the United States Steel or any other corpora¬ tion. I want merely to remark that the United States Steel Corporation set the example. The ‘ ‘ reorganization ? 1 of most other industries quickly followed, so that not only the big industries but the less important businesses were “Out of the Prying Pan—” 413 organized along the same lines as the powerful combines. Competitive methods were no longer a part of trade and commerce; the semblance alone was kept up. Today price fixing is the rule; cost-finding systems are perhaps not uniform, but certainly universal. Items are now charged up against “cost of production,” and taken out of “earnings,” which were formerly taken out of profits. The purchasers of the commodities produced are taxed with sundry items of “cost,” such as insurance, all taxes, depreciation, replacement, interest on investment, interest on bonds, etc. For the present, suffice it to say that all the principles and practices of the big fellows have been successfully and universally copied by the little fel¬ lows. Not a lesson has been overlooked. The Value of Organization The most important lesson, however, and which has not been overlooked by any one group of individuals, is the lesson of the importance of organization, unity and soli¬ darity. From top to bottom, business is organized—com¬ pletely, thoroughly organized. The bankers, the financiers, the brokers, the producers, the manufacturers, the employ¬ ers, the wholesalers, the jobbers, the retailers, and even the various branches and departments of business of what¬ ever kind—all thoroughly and completely organized—all constituting a single system—a harmonious whole; the con¬ stituents singing the same songs, saying the same prayers, worshiping the same golden calf—all tied together by the common bond of self-interest expressed in dollars and cents—in bigger profits and greater riches. There you have, in brief, a bird ’s-eye view of the Capital¬ istic System. Even those who cannot be said to be either Capitalists or Entrepreneurs, but have been or are benefi¬ ciaries of the System or its practices, think in unison, or, more properly speaking, they have their thinking done for them by the so-called Captains of Industry and Finance, and are content to be merely echoes. There is complete 414 The New Capitalism unanimity, for their interests are identical. They are a chorus of acquiescence, or agreement. Not a single dis¬ cordant voice is lifted at any of their banquets; not a dis¬ senting vote is heard in any of their meetings. There are no radicals among them, no independents, no dissenters, none to kick over the traces. Every contingent has, moreover, its own press—a power¬ ful, well-financed and well-supported press. There are hundreds of trade journals, or journals having to do with the sundry interests of the different groups. The One Conclusion This is the System against which I propose that the non¬ investors organize themselves, and of which organization Labor is to be the nucleus. The lesson of unity, organiza¬ tion and solidarity is the one lesson to be mastered. The folly of disintegrated and unrelated units acting independ¬ ently of each other must be apparent to even the merest novice. A solid and united front will be necessary to op¬ pose the forces whose strength lies not so much in numbers as in their complete homogeneity and their perfect morale. CHAPTER XXX Economic Changes and Adjustments HERE is one phase of the economic side of the natipn’s life that we cannot much longer hide from ourselves. We are fast approaching a condition under which industrial stagnation in business will become more frequent, and periodical labor lay-offs become the rule. Herbert Hoover, Secretary of Commerce, in 1921 pointed out that the present is the fourteenth industrial depression we have had since the Civil War. If I have read the signs aright, the wage earners may just as well make up their minds that from this time on there will be an industrial disturbance every five or six years. It is inevitable un¬ der the Capitalistic Entrepreneur System, which cannot flourish under stable conditions. Fluctuations—rises and falls, ups and downs—are the essence of the System. As an example, if prices of stocks remained stable for two con¬ secutive years the stock exchanges would collapse like so many houses of cards. The immense profits in the stock game are made out of fluctuations in market prices. That these fluctuations are manipulated is no secret. If immense profits in the securities market are derived from artificial fluctuations, the same principle can be applied with similar results to industrial conditions. Therefore, disturbances and crises are desirable things from the Cap¬ italistic standpoint, particularly as regards Labor, for, if those who work for a wage had five or ten years of con¬ tinuous prosperity, they would acquire so great a degree of economic power, importance and momentum that they could not be controlled, which would be fatal to the Cap¬ italistic Entrepreneur System. The best way to keep wage earners in the proper frame of mind, and docile and sub- 415 416 The New Capitalism missive, is to keep the prospect of periodical industrial de¬ pression—loss of jobs, of wages, or savings—hovering con¬ tinually over their heads. The Course of Events It is quite possible that many who read this do not see, and are unable to discover, any planned design in the peri¬ odical industrial depressions that have afflicted the nation in the past, and so will not admit design in those that will afflict the nation—particularly the non-investors—in the future. Very well! I shall not press the point at this time. Indeed I am quite willing, for the present, to confine myself to a consideration of sundry events which seem to play right into the hands of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs —events in the shaping of wdiich it cannot be said they are playing the conspicuous role of villain, but events the evil effect of whose reaction is visited on the heads of the wage earners—the non-investors, the public. For example: The industrial development of the country within the past twenty-five years has been phenomenal. It was not so much a gradual growth as a tremendous, sud¬ den forward leap. In many lines of production the in¬ crease was doubled and trebled. I do not want to lumber this chapter with an array of statistics. For this reason I refer the readers to the latest Statistical Record of the Progress of the United States as recorded in the Statistical Abstract for 1922, where he will find enough data to either confirm or disprove my statement. The statistics, if ana¬ lyzed and correlated, show that the growth prior to ]900 was steady and gradual; the rate of increase was normal. But after that we note a more rapid expansion. While the population increased from 75 million in 1900 to about 105 million in 1920—an increase of 40 percent—the increase in our progress in the past twenty years was at the rate of .100 to 300 and even more percent. An admirable record, surely one to be proud of and rejoice over! But it cannot be kept up. Perhaps the simplest way to show the quick, not to say sudden, progress is to point to the increase in Economic Changes and Adjustments 417 bank clearings from $84,582,450,081 in 1900 to $462,920,- 250,000 in 1920. The Limit of Healthy Growth The point I want to make is that we cannot maintain the same percentage of increase; the tremendous industrial, commercial and even agricultural expansion during the past twenty years cannot be repeated during the next twenty years. The century from 1800 to 1900 can be said to have been the years of adolescence, of our “productive progress.” A study of the statistics for the years from 1900 to 1920 reveals an enormous step forward, an abnormal, not to say unnatural, increase in our productive progress, due to artificial stimulation through the medium of infla¬ tion and an unusual combination of circumstances and events. As an example, take the automobile industry. Twenty years ago it was in its infancy. Twenty years ago a mere corporal’s guard of our citizens had automobiles. Today there are nine million pleasure cars in use. But it would be folly to compute that, therefore, twenty years hence eighteen million pleasure cars will be in use; and forty years hence, thirty-six million. Healthy boys and girls keep on growing until about the age of twenty. Then suddenly their growth stops, and all the remaining years of their lives will not add an inch to their height. She, you will admit, would be a foolish mother who, knowing that her son at the age of twenty wore trous¬ ers forty inches in length, would therefore conclude that by the time he reaches forty he will wear trousers eighty inches in length. Put into bold relief, we are no longer in our ’teens; our nation’s “productive progress” has passed beyond the “growing” years; we have transcended the normal limits of growth; we have reached a point beyond which, in the nature of things, w r e cannot increase in vol¬ ume or percentage per capita —a fact which our purblind Captains of Finance —alias Captains of Industry—refuse to admit. As a result of their insistence that we shall con¬ tinue to grow—that at the age of forty we shall wear 418 The New Capitalism trousers twice as long as we w T ore when we were twenty— they have put the nation on stilts, and they are goading us on to a fall. Speed Without Motion There will not be, there cannot be, the same percentage of increase, neither in production nor in manufacture, nor in sales. Production is regulated by consumption. With regard to many things, particularly articles of food and of manufacture, production is already in excess of normal consumption. Why blink the fact? Why lie about it? During January of 1920 Elbert H. Gary declared that during the next five years we would increase our crops 100 percent. Assuming that we do—who is going to benefit by this excessive increase in production? What are we going to do with the additional 100 percent of cereals, etc. ? The people will not consume twice as much; that is certain. Just the reverse is likely; for the people are consuming less and less on account of high prices. Nor can we depend on larger exports, for it is reasonable to suppose that the United States will not be alone in its in¬ creased production; other parts of the world will increase as well. And certainly the population of the United States and the population of Europe will not double during the next five years. Who, then, will be benefited by a 100- percent increase in crop production, with no proportionate increase in consumption and in the markets? As late as June, 1921, at a time when the steel mills were running at about 20 percent of capacity, Charles M. Schwab publicly declared that we were not producing enough. “We must increase our production,” he said. Increase produc¬ tion of what? If Mr. Schwab really believed what he was saying, why didn’t he start his own plants going full tilt? Why didn’t he put the men back to work in his own mills ? Crying “Wolf, Wolf” When There is no Wolf During and following the war we were told that there was underproduction; the cry was raised by Chambers of Commerce and the sundry sycophantic hirelings of the Economic Changes and Adjustments 419 Capitalistic System that what was needed was more pro¬ duction. Then came the buyers 7 strike, and the retailers 7 strike, and the wholesalers 7 strike. The manufacturer was caught with vast quantities of raw materials and finished products in warehouses and on his shelves. The retailers had previously, under persuasion of manufacturers or wholesalers, stocked up rather better than ordinarily. The general public, too, had been induced by the retailer to buy double quantities. “Better buy two or three pairs of shoes, 77 said a shoe clerk in Chicago’s leading department store to me in January, 1919. “Why? 77 I queried. “Because prices are going to go still higher.” “If prices will go still higher,” I answered, “it will be simply for the reason that you will have succeeded in inveigling a sufficient number of fools into buying two or three pair of shoes at present outrageously high prices in stead of only one pair. If I, and every other person in need of a pair of shoes, can be coaxed, or cajoled into buying two or three pair of shoes, it means that your firm will sell two or three times as many shoes as formerly; and the wholesaler will sell two or three times more shoes; and the manufacturer likewise. Then the cry will be raised that the demand is abnormal, and this will only help to keep up prices. Moreover, your firm will give out interviews to the press that the people are buying recklessly and extrava¬ gantly—two or three pair instead of one, and— 77 But the young fellow didn 7 t understand. I was wasting my time. At any rate, when the buyers 7 strike struck the country it became apparent that there was not, and had not been at any time—even when the cry “we must produce more” was loudest—what could be called underproduction. Pro¬ duction had always been equal to, and even in excess of, the normal demand. The semblance of underproduction was created by the irrational endeavors on the part of the manufacturers, wholesalers and retailers to stimulate and maintain a condition of abnormal consumption. 420 The New Capitalism Precisely what is the game ? What is behind this studied attempt on the part of certain interests to give the impres¬ sion that there is underproduction when just the reverse is true ? Are they themselves deluded ? I do not believe it. Why the continued deception? Is there a Senegambian in the wood-pile ? Then let us find him. To Stimulate Capital Accumulations The conditions which made the tremendous sudden in¬ crease possible during the past twenty years are not in operation today. The reaction has set in. This reaction will affect the various parties involved—the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs, the wage earners, and all the non-investors, differently. It is more than likely that the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs will put forth every possible endeavor to maintain the same percentage of increase in their wealth accumulations during the next twenty years as during the past twenty years. How great this percentage is may be fairly computed from the statistics for “ national wealth,” which was 88 billion in 1900 and 288 billion in 1920—an average increase of ten billion a year. What methods will be employed by them to still further increase their “national wealth” is easily guessed. Wealth inflation will continue at the same or a greater rate; interest charges will probably be increased; high com¬ modity prices, and rents, also, will continue ; transporta¬ tion and freight rates will remain high; higher tariffs will be added to “cost of production”; “overhead expense,” “maintenance costs,” “administration expense,” and “fixed charges” will be pushed beyond the present high figures; and the quality of many commodities will be re¬ duced, thus putting people to the necessity of purchasing twice as much as formerly. The effects of all this will be visited upon the heads of the wage earners and salaried men and women, in brief will be felt in every home by all non-investors, in the role of consumers during sixteen hours a day. As wage earners or workers they will get rather the worst of it, in that they Economic Changes and Adjustments 421 will be made to feel the effects also while at work in mine or mill, shop or factory, store or office. Their wages will be cut to the bone; their hours of labor will be increased; their output per day, or week, increased. And, of course, for many there will be periodical lay-offs—longer seasons of idleness, during which they will be compelled to con¬ sume their scant savings, or run into debt. The Gapitalistic-Mammomstic Juggernaut This is no sickly dream. This is no purple prophesy. It is not even a fanciful guess; it is a statement of prosaic fact. The things I enumerate are not going to happen at some time in the future,—they are happening today; this very hour. They have been shaping themselves for over twenty years and are now developed to a point of alarm¬ ing perfection. A little polishing here, a finishing touch there, a tightening of screws all around, and the Capital- istic-Mammonistic Entrepreneur machine which has been building for more than twenty years will be in smooth running order—a Juggernaut that crushes and kills every¬ thing in its path as on it sweeps. The wage earners will be, as they have always been in the past, the worst sufferers from the onward rush of this monster machine. They still have the power to stop this mighty engine of destruction if they can but muster up the courage and develop the will, to do it. In another decade it may too late. But they must be made to understand, what they do not seem thus far to have been able to grasp, that there are other elements than the item of wages in¬ volved in their economic welfare. There is, for example, the constantly growing menace of unemployment for an increasing number. More Workers Than Jobs—A Capitalistic “Ideal” In plain English, there are, and under the supremacy of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs there will continue to be, more workers than jobs. I should hesitate to put all 422 The New Capitalism the blame for this state of affairs on the Capitalistic Entre¬ preneur System, but there is considerable evidence that unemployment of a certain percentage of workers has from the very beginning been conspicuous among the Capitalistic “ideals.” When the great consolidation of steel industries took place, dozens of plants were closed— and dismantled, and thousands of men were thrown out of employment. This was euphemistically called “a sav¬ ing of waste”—“the doing away with duplication of effort,” etc. The reduction in the number of men on the payrolls meant a saving, not of waste, but of wages— consequently an increase of profit. 1 The working day of many of the steel workers not thrown out of employment on account of the closing of plants, was lengthened to ten and twelve hours, not a few being compelled to work seven days a week. This system, with some modifications made on account of public sentiment, is still in effect in most of the plants of the United States' Steel Corporation, Mr. Gary persistently refusing, under various pretexts, to inaugurate an eight hour day for all wmrkers. An eight hour day would mean the employment of many thousands of additional men. Apart from the fact that an increase in workers means an increase in the size of the payroll, which would produce if not a marked, still a noticeable effect on the earnings, there is the more im¬ portant consideration that it would practically exhaust the now available supply of steel workers. Not that that in itself is a serious dilemma, for the United States Steel Corporation has repeatedly proved that it is equal to any emergency, as, for example, when, in 1901, in its fight on the unions, it replaced American workingmen out of the foreign labor market. No, that isn’t it! The United States Steel Corporation has a reputation to sustain—the reputation of having for- i "When Elbert H. Gary was before the Lockwood Committee (June 2, 1922), Samuel Untermyer reminded him that in 1921 the United States Steel Corporation had only 45 percent of its capacity employed, and yet made more money than when the full capacity was employed. This confirms my own theory that the profits of the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs will be greater when fewer are employed. Economic Changes and Adjustments 423 mnlated and systematically promulgated a set of ideals now universally adopted by the entire Capitalistic System. The particular ideal with which we are concerned in this chapter, is the ideal of so maneuvering as to create and maintain a condition that provides for “a docile and flexible labor supply”—in other words, a certain percent¬ age of workers constantly available to replace other workers. Labor in Competition with Labor This “ideal” has been splendidly maintained thus far. I shall make no stress of the fact that in 1915 there were fully as many people out of work as in 1922. Of greater significance is the report of the Hoover Committee on the Elimination of Waste, which estimates that in the best years, like 1917 and 1918, there “was a regular margin of unemployment amounting to more than a million men.” This is the ideal the Capitalistic System has set for itself in normal times—a condition where there will always be a margin of a million or so wage earners out of work, seeking employment, willing to take any job at the em¬ ployer’s price. The consolidation of the big industries was brought about and justified on the principle that it is ruinous to have Capital in competition with Capital; but the consoli¬ dators deem it highly desirable to have Labor in competi¬ tion with Labor. Evidently what is sauce for the goose is not always sauce for the gander. When Labor is in competition with Labor, Capitalistic Entrepreneurs can urge the ancient claim that Labor is a “commodity,” and that wages are regulated by the “law of supply and de¬ mand.” Professor Ely, in his interesting work, “Studies in the Evolution of Industrial Society,” says that Professor John B. Clark “has worked out a theory of wages which, in his opinion, enables us to ascertain the true product of Labor, which should be then assigned to Labor. What Labor re¬ ceives under perfectly free competition, ‘with Labor ideally 424 The New Capitalism mobile, 7 is he says, the true product of Labor. ‘The really natural standard of pay lies between the amount that idle men may here and there consent to take and the amount that a union, which guards its monopoly by force, may be able to extort; and it lies at about the level of what a union that is extended and efficient, but not monopolistic, can get. The standard that is so indicated would be one which well-constituted courts could recognize, etc. 7 7 7 2 All this but emphasizes the Capitalistic Entrepreneur ideal with regard to Labor—an ideal which the System has fully attained; and the determination to maintain which explains much of the bitterness of the fight of the Capitalistic System against organized Labor. “A certain degree of unemployment, 77 said the New York Times in 1921, “is corrective of many social dis¬ orders. 77 This is not unlike David Harum’s philosophy, that ‘ ‘ a certain amount of fleas is good for a dog; it keeps him from worrying about being a dog. 77 God help the nation that can devise no better corrective for its social disorders than wholesale unemployment and resultant misery and wretchedness, for a considerable number of its families. “I Die of Thirst by the Side of the Brook” The early English economists rather favored a high "birthrate, on account of the resultant cheapness of labor, which would inevitably redound to the benefit of the •/ Capitalists. Quite naturally their views were shared by the leading statesmen—the ruling Capitalistic class of the time. In 1798 T. R. Malthus published his “Essay on the Principle of Population as It Affects the Future Improve¬ ment of Society. 77 Malthus argued that “Population has the constant tendency to increase beyond the means of subsistence 77 —that the constant tendency of all living 2 The words which I italicize, viz., the amount that "a union which guards its monopoly (?) by force(l) may be able to extort (?) ” are objectionable, and open to criticism, in which, however, I shall not indulge at this time; that would be beside the question imme¬ diately involved in this chapter. Economic Changes and Adjustments 425 beings is to increase faster than the food supply. Malthus contended that population tends to increase in a geometri¬ cal progression, thus: 1, 2, 4, 8, 16, 32, 64, 128 while the means of subsistence can increase only in an arithmetical progression, thus: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8. Almost the whole so-called thinking world accepted the Malthusian theory without cavil or question. Today it is still reverently expounded in the universities, and emi¬ nent economists continue to preach it not only in England but also in the United States, with this difference, that whereas Malthus confined his theory to a consideration of the relation of the population to the means of subsistence —the food supply—the modern economists have given it a more inclusive application, namely, that population has the tendency to increase beyond the means of subsistence including all production; this in spite of the fact, too, that it can be shown by a wealth of statistics that Malthus’ fears, at least as far as the United States is concerned, were entirely unfounded. The means of subsistence—the food supply—is greater per capita than ever; we are producing rather more than we can consume. We are unable to find markets for what we produce. Millions of people throughout the world—slowly starving—would be glad to get our surplus, but, alas, they haven’t the means, the money; they are already on a starvation basis of wages. In their countries the Capitalistic System has been completely successful. In brief, in the United States, production of commodities in general has outstripped consumption; and not the re¬ verse, as so many Capitalistic Entrepreneurs and econo¬ mists would have us believe. Why does Mr. Gary seek to give the impression that a hundred percent increase in cereals is needed during the next five years? Why does Mr. Schwab (and scores of others) insist that we are not producing enough when just the reverse is true? Ask the stars! Mayhap they can answer! 426 The New Capitalism An Economic Dilemma The neo-Malthusians face the difficulty more bravely. They do not try to disguise the fact that we are producing more than we can consume. Indeed they attribute the Capitalistic tendency (which they defend) to pay nothing more than a bare living wage, to the over-presence of workers—a greater supply of workers than is needed. And the solution they have to offer is the deliberate limitation of the birth rate—that, or dire poverty for the whole tribe of wage earners. And yet the deliberate limitation of births, it seems to me, carries with it its own condemnation. Let it be under¬ stood that whatever my private views may be with regard to the deliberate restriction of births, in this book I shall not allow any ethical consideration to enter in. I am view¬ ing the economic aspect of the subject, purely from a business standpoint, putting it on its lowest possible plane, or rather keeping it on the low level where I found it. Keeping all these things in mind I maintain that the production of population (consumers) is, if not a nation’s chiefest asset, at least its most important industry. When that industry, for whatever reason, languishes, economic disturbances are bound to result. The normal progress of a nation depends on the maintenance of a normal birth¬ rate. Curtailment of the normal birthrate is bound to curtail normal consumption. The economic equilibrium of a nation can be maintained only as long as a nation does not neglect the production of consumers (children). But when a nation increases production of commodities and cuts down the number of consumers of the commodi¬ ties, then something worse than Malthus foresaw has be¬ fallen the world. Olive Schreiner, in her book, “Woman and Labor,” ar¬ gues that there is no need of maintenance of .what can be called the normal birthrate, for today, she says, one worker produces enough for ten persons. Not exactly true! But—accepting Miss Schreiner’s statement as if it were an Economic Changes and Adjustments 427 arithmetically correct fact, why not consider also its cor¬ ollary, that if one worker today produces for ten persons , it follows that ten consumers are necessary to consume what the one produces. And how are we going to keep np con¬ sumption if we refuse to produce the ten consumers neces¬ sary for what the one produces? In former times, if we accept Miss Schreiner’s loose way of putting it, one worker on the average consumed what he produced, whereas today, one man produces for himself and nine others. But how can we hope to cope with this new situation if we delib¬ erately curtail the production of consumers—that is, if we keep down the birthrate? To the positive checks on population enumerated by Malthus—war, pestilence, famine, disease, vice, crime, etc., —and the preventive checks urged by the neo-Malthusians —John Stuart Mill encouraged another check, viz., that resulting from ‘ ‘ the opening of industrial occupation freely to both sexes,” and which “industrial and social inde¬ pendence of women” would produce, he contended, “a great diminution of the evil of overpopulation.” But we may seriously question whether society as a whole is benefited to any extent by a wholesale transference of those who, in the design of nature, are intended to be pro¬ ducers of consumers to the list of producers of commodities. Indeed it is an open question which only those immediately concerned—the women themselves—can answer, viz., whether they themselves are economic gainers or losers; and whether, after all, they are not helping with their own hands to set the stage for a terrible catastrophe involving the whole human race. Penalizing the Worker for His Fecundity There is much in Malthus ’ elaborate treatise on the Prin¬ ciple of Population which compels acquiescence; and there is much commendable logic in his argument; nor was Mal¬ thus a monster of unmorality, as some would have us be¬ lieve. It must be remembered that he wrote of a time, and up to a certain period, and around a series of economic 428 The New Capitalism facts that were pertinent at the time he wrote. Indeed there are lands where many of the conditions described by Malthns have not materially improved even to this day. But I am not speaking of those lands. I am not thinking at this moment of India, Japan, Russia, China, Turkey, etc. I am confining myself strictly to the United States, for which territory I am willing to go on record as saying that for the next two centuries the menace of overpopulation will not seriously affect us. My quarrel, if you care to call it such, is not with Malthus or his theory, but with those economists in the United States who have deliberately per¬ verted the Malthusian formula into an argument defending and justifying the payment of less than a living wage to the tribe of workers. Just read, for example, the following from “The Wealth and Income of the People of the United States,’’ by Pro¬ fessor Willford Isbell King, (p. 249) : “Of late we have heard a tremendous demand from would-be social reformers for a ‘living wage.’ We hear the employers on all sides denounced as heartless villains because they do not pay enough to allow their employees to live in decency and comfort. But this sentiment seems to arise from a superficial analysis of the difficulty. Why are the employees not in a position to demand a satisfactory return for their services? Whose fault is it? And the ultimate blame must be laid not upon the employers but upon the parents and grandparents of the workers them¬ selves. Why did these ancestors of the present generation bring into the world children whom they could afford neither to educate nor to train for some occupation, the products of which were sufficiently in demand to make a living wage easily secured ? Why indeed ? Simply because these same parents and grandparents were either incom¬ petent, ignorant, or unwilling to restrain their animal pas¬ sions. Here we have an excellent example of-‘visiting the iniquity of the father upon the children unto the third and fourth generation’.” To my humble way of thinking the emphasis placed by Economic Changes and Adjustments 429 certain Capitalistic economists on the doctrine of birth restriction, and their contention that wages are low be¬ cause there are too many workers, is solely for its psycho¬ logic effect upon the workers themselves. If the haunting thought that he himself, and not the Capitalistic System, his own “iniquity,” or the “iniquity” of his ancestors, and not the iniquity of the Capitalistic System, is to blame for his economic helplessness and quandary, can be firmly rooted into the consciousness of the average wage worker, and of his wife and progeny, a kind of sordid docility will eat into their souls, a sickly resignation overpower their wills; after which their resentment against the “established order” will never be more than a feeble protest. A Puzzling Problem But however we may interpret the Apologia of the Cap¬ italistic economists and their defense of a system of wages notoriously inadequate for decency; however we may con¬ temn the obtuseness or blindness of those who, in the face of an admitted excessive productive ability, advocate a reduction in the number of consumers, it cannot be denied that the situation is fraught with difficulties, and in its entirety constitutes an enigma of gigantic proportions. In the days of Malthus it was believed that the time was inevitable when population would outstrip the means of subsistence. Conditions today prove that just the reverse has happened. Production is vastly greater than con¬ sumption. There are more workers than jobs; more mer¬ chandise than markets. And things will grow rather worse than better in this regard, in the years to come. The Wrong Solution Perhaps Bichard Arkwright’s townsfolk, who, as Car¬ lyle tells us, “rose in mob” against the barber inventor of the spinning wheel “for threatening to shorten labor, to shorten wages; so that he had to fly, with broken wash-pots, scattered household, and seek refuge elsewhere,” (even his wife turning against him)—had a clearer vision of what 430 The New Capitalism was in store for them and their descendants than we are willing to admit, for is it not written that “the children of this world are wiser in their generation than the children of light ? ’ ’ At any rate it would seem that the things they dreaded have truly come to pass in England, where, we are told, a system of “ca’ canny,” of “go slow,” is sapping the eco¬ nomic vitality of the nation. This is not because the Eng¬ lish workmen are lazy, or unwilling to give fair service for their wage, but rather because there are more workers than jobs—and by dragging out their work they imagine that they are doing a wise thing, distributing the work among a greater number. A fool philosophy if ever there was one! Adding Fuel to the Fire In our own United States things, economically, are not so bad as in England,—not yet; but, alas, the fool philos¬ ophy of the British workmen is beginning to manifest itself in the muddled minds of some American workers, who imagine that by prolonging a job they are—doing what ?— Helping other workmen? No! not so much that as better¬ ing their own condition—increasing their own wages, obtaining more pay than they otherwise would for perform¬ ing a certain piece of work. Apart from the utter dishon¬ esty of such a procedure it is the stupidest kind of logic. When a workman can, reasonably computed, complete a given job in one day’s time, but puts in two days, he does not make himself richer, but his neighbor poorer. And when, as the enemies of Labor insist, work that was form¬ erly performed by one skilled worker, now, under restrict¬ ive rules requires two or three skilled workmen, a situation is created that is bound to alienate the sympathy of the public, as well as weaken Labor’s cause. “In normal times,” says James H. Collins, -“economists estimate, if our industrial organization works five and a half eight-hour days, it will produce so much that the coun¬ try can consume only about four days’ output. One and Economic Changes and Adjustments 431 one-half days’ output must be shipped abroad. As we are now selling little abroad, and our buying power is at an average of less than 50 percent, we are really using only two days’ output. Briefly, there are more people in the marketing and financial departments of industry than are needed to do the business of the country. When we get back to normal many of these people will be eliminated— the high-profits merchants and the salaried workers who were overpaid or rendering no real service.” 3 “No one,” says Professor John R. Commons, “can squarely defend all of the restrictive policies of unions, but if they are carefully examined . . . they will be found to be not so very different from the restrictive policies of employers and of non-unionists. In all cases these policies have their source in the knoivledge that there are not, at all times, enough markets to take all of the work and the product at fair wages and profitable prices .” The Pot Calling the Kettle Blach If Labor is attempting to limit production so that it will be employed twelve months a year, and Capital is attempt¬ ing to speed up production so that it can “lay off” Labor on an average three or four months a year—who is the greater culprit? On whose side is the greater right; on whose the greater wrong? Which group is more justified? I make no defence and offer no justification for either group. But while I am on this subject let me add that he w T ho can see any difference between the fixed determination of the employer to get as much work as possible for as little wages as possible, and the growing determination of the worker to get as much wages as possible for as little work as possible, has a finer sense of moral values than I have. A Eift in the Clouds No! this country is not suffering from an excess of pro¬ ducers so much as from a dearth of consumers. Undercon- 3 From “The White Collar Job and the Big' Jolt,” by James H. Collins, Saturday Evening Post, September 3, 1921. The New Capitalism sumption, rather than overproduction, is our economic dif¬ ficulty. And this underconsumption is, in a great measure, attributable to the niggardly wage alloted by Capital to those who labor; and certainly accentuated thereby. Things cannot go on forever as they are going; there must be a fundamental readjustment or something will break—something go to smash. Since the Capitalistic Entrepreneurs have nothing else to offer except periodical unemployment and less than a living w r age, it behooves the New Order to “find a way” out of the encircling difficulties. I shall not particularly emphasize here what seems to me the logical and basic solution, namely—a greater number of marriages, which would naturally yield an increase in the number of producers of consumers; but that is a social, rather than an economic solution, and it is the economic, rather than the social, side of the problem that I desire to discuss. Therefore I propose as a possibility under the New Order, a reduction in the number of the working hours of the producers. Or it would be possible to institute a system of fewer working days. Also raising the age limit, which would keej) out of the ranks of the workers boys and girls of tender years. Also retirement from active labor at an earlier age, which is possible only if wages are fair and reasonable, and other sources of income have been opened to the workers. These, be it remembered, are not “ideals” that I should care to incorporate as tenets of the New Order, nor propose as an integral part of my system —but I should certainly advocate them, should it ever seem necessary or desirable, in order to safeguard the many against the evil of unemployment and less than a living wage—the fecund parents of misery and poverty. The Great Triumph This brings us to the pivotal point of this whole subject —the question of constant employment of the workers and uninterrupted business. I have said, and I shall repeat it here, that a system of fair and reasonable wages, with a maximum exchange value, is preferable to a system of Economic Changes and Adjustments 433 excessively high wages with a minimum exchange value, for these two very important reasons: 1: Fair and reasonable wages will permit the employ¬ ment of a larger number of workers than would be possible under a system of excessively high wages. 2: When wages are reasonable, prices will be lower than when wages are excessively high. When prices are reason¬ able, people will buy more. It is this purchase stimulus that keeps the machinery of industry and the wheels of commerce going. The purchase of more commodities will insure, as nothing else can, steady prosperity and the con¬ tinuous employment of workers. If nothing else were to be gained by the New Capitalism than these two things—the constant employment of prac¬ tically all workers, and continuous business—Labor would have achieved its greatest triumph. CHAPTER XXXI What About the Farmer % T HE earliest form of wealth was land. The first monopoly was a land monopoly—the complete own¬ ership of which was centered in a few, who were wealthy because they owned the land, and who grew wealthier from year to year because to them, by virtue of their ownership, belonged the usufruct of the labor of those wdio in order merely to subsist were compelled to make their land productive. Thus the economic subjection of the populace of Europe, literally speaking, can be said to have been rooted in the soil—a subjection which continued after the passing of the system of Feudalism; 1 and exists to this day, though in a more modified form, in spite of the French Revolution of 1789, and even more modern revo¬ lutions. Our Escape from Land Monopoly Luckily the United States has escaped the economic evils that arise from a monopoly of the land by a few, although a careful study of the development of our country reveals a tendency toward individual ownership of immense tracts of land, which might, in due time, have developed into a monopoly by a few; but a number of things saved us from this particular brand of serfdom. Among the obstacles unfavorable to the development of a land monopoly may be mentioned the vast extent of the territory—the abun¬ dance of land, its free and wide distribution, the difficulty of access, the lack of transportation facilities, a small popu¬ lation, and a limited market for the products of the soil, i I emphasize the system of Feudalism because only the crude system, or form, was changed—the principles, practices and policies of Feudalism continue to this day, have, in fact, been advanced to a science. 434 What About the Farmer? 435 particularly since many families owned or occupied small tracts of land which they cultivated. In 1800 the United States was considered an agrarian nation, 85 percent of the population being listed as agricultural. But the one great thing that economically intervened and saved us from the menace of a land monopoly was the development of the industries, which tempted many by offering vastly greater opportunities; and held out a greater promise of profit and a greater reward of wealth to those who had the courage to venture upon their pursuit. Never¬ theless today the productive farm land of the United States is widely distributed among nearly six and a half million owners, whose aggregate wealth is estimated at eighty bil¬ lion dollars. The nation owes a debt of gratitude to the farmers of the United States, that wonderful race of men and women, who, in spite of many hardships and handicaps, and numerous discouragements, stuck to the land, and who by dint of hard toil, patience and perseverance, raised husbandry to the dignity of a great industry. The Homer who can fittingly commemorate the heroism and valor of those hardy pioneers into an epic poem, is not yet born. The Nation's Rock of Gibraltar The farmers of the United States themselves seem not to realize that all these years they have stood, and they stand today, a formidable bulwark of safety between the Mam- monistic Capitalists and the economic enslavement of the nation—I mean that portion of the population which I have called the non-investor group, and to which the farmers themselves—though some may be loath to admit it—belong. At any rate, throughout this book, for the reasons stated in Chapter IV, I have included the farmers in the non¬ investor group. In spite of the fact that the farmers of the United States, strictly speaking, are investors, the aggregate income they derive from their joint investment and labor, on an average is hardly more than the equivalent of a fair living wage. From the 1919 Income Tax report 436 The New Capitalism we learn that for the 418,945 individuals engaged in “Agri¬ cultural and related industries/’ reporting an income, the average net income was less than $3000. Taking income as a basis, I think I am justified in considering the group of farmers, in spite of their investment—of an estimated value of eighty billion—as wage earners, or non-investors. And this classification gains in merit when we remember that like the wage earner, the average farmer has been, and is, the helpless victim of the Capitalistic system; the foot¬ ball of the Capitalistic group. The Rock Shaken by Capitalistic Winds I have said that the people of the United States have escaped the evil of land monopoly; but they did not entirely escape paying the penalty of a form of land monopoly as sinister as any to be found anywhere on earth. Who owns the forests, the oil lands, the coal and iron mines—the nat¬ ural resources of the nation? Not the farmers! But a small coterie of men who, for the most part, have their habitat in Wall Street, LaSalle Street, and other formida¬ ble centers of finance, and to whom the farmers, no less than the wage earners, are compelled to pay a heavy tribute. Oh, yes! the farmers own millions of acres of productive land; but they do not reap the full measure of benefits to which they are entitled as owners and producers; for the same group of men who, through methods we need not inquire into at this time, have gained absolute possession of all the valuable coal and iron, oil and timber lands, also reap incalculable profits from the products of the lands owned by the farmers—profits, which, in point of quantity, are as great, I believe, as the clear profits of the agricul¬ tural owners. I will not pause to dilate on the mechanism of boards of trade, and chambers of commerce, nor descant on the methods of these institutions through whose agency the leading cereal crops are sold from five to ten times over in the course of a year. None knows better than the farmer that boards of trade, and chambers of commerce, are not What About the Fanner? 437 conducted for the farmer’s benefit—and certainly not for the benefit of the public. Nor will I waste any time on the commission houses and their methods; nor make any attempt to show the sundry devices by which immense profits are made by a few thou¬ sand non-producers out of the produce of farms—butter, milk, eggs, poultry, fruits, cotton, etc. Nor will I interrupt the pursuit of the main theme of this chapter to emphasize the economic anomaly and gro¬ tesque absurdity of men living hundreds of miles from farms—men who own nor hoe nor plow T , who did not give so much as an hour of toil to the tilling of the soil— sitting in offices fixing the prices of all farm products, rais¬ ing them one day, lowering them the next, and so on, mak¬ ing a profit on each fluctuation. Would the United States Steel Corporation allow farmers to fix the price of steel products? Would the packers permit the farmers to fix the price of lard or pork, or veal, or canned goods ? They would not! No wonder the farmers of the United States are banding themselves into national organizations, firmly resolved that hereafter they shall have something to say about the price of their own products. No wonder they feel that if it is necessary, as the Capitalistic protagonists contend, to sell farm crops from five to ten times in the course of a year, that they themselves mean to profit thereby. On the Trail of Truth I have not hesitated in this book to tell Capital what I think, nor have I spared Labor in my criticism. I would be false to myself if I did not also tell the Farmers the truth as I see it, regarding the economic situation as it affects them, or as others are affected by it. In all fairness, therefore, let me go on record as saying that if the farmers of the United States, through their national associations, could wrest control of marketing institutions from the Capitalistic group; and if by virtue of that absolute control they themselves would hereafter pocket the profits which 438 The New Capitalism at present go to gamblers and speculators—the public would not be benefitted one iota. Nothing more could be said to have happened than a transference of large profits from the group of speculators and gamblers to the pockets of the farmers. But as far as the general public is con¬ cerned, living costs would remain practically the same; there would still be no relief from high prices. I have labored in this book to expose the fundamental fallacies that have complicated the whole economic contro¬ versy. Among other things I have shown that the wage earner, in spite of a high quantity wage, is no better off than he was twenty or twenty-five years ago. It behooves me now to apply the principles vindicated thus far, to the situation as it affects the farmer. In a general way I will say that the farmer, like the wage earner, is today precisely in the same position he was twenty years ago; he is no better off; he hasn’t advanced a single step. Indeed I seri¬ ously question, whether, following the Capitalistic lead, the farmers have not betrayed themselves into self deception. The Flattery of Statistics In spite of rosy statistics showing a tremendous increase in the value of farm properties—when we apply the acid test we discover that a considerable part of the statistical increase in the value of properties—or in the wealth of farmers—must be called Inflation, that is to say—is an increase in a theoretical market price rather than in value . That this increase in price has been advantageous to a lim¬ ited number of individuals within the farmer group goes without saying; but it has brought no substantial benefits to the farmers in the aggregate. No doubt some will attempt to defend the price increase by the notorious 11 law of supply and demand ’ ’; while others will urge the mythical Capitalistic device “earning power” as the logical explanation. As regards the former, viz., ‘ ‘ the law of supply and demand,” I shall say nothing at this time, except that I have omitted two chapters I had written about it from this volume, because I intend, at some later What About the Farmer? 439 time, to discuss this damnable “law” in extenso, within the proportions of a fair sized volume. As regards “earning power, ’’ I have had some things to say in the first part of this book which may still be remembered by the readers. If so, it will suffice, then, to apply the principles involved to the subject under discussion in order to reveal the mockery of that Capitalistic trick. When the price of land is in¬ creased on the basis of its maximum “earning power,” quite naturally there is a point beyond which the price can¬ not go without diminishing the normal return to the owner of the land, thus reducing its value. This is precisely what is the trouble at the present time. So high has the price of land become that it is impossible to make it yield a reasonable return except by raising the prices of all farm products to a practically prohibitive point; which, as I shall endeavor to show in this and the next chapter, penal¬ izes the city consumers while bringing no material ad¬ vantage to the farmers themselves. Increase in Price—Decrease in Value Briefly then, as far as the farmers in the aggregate are concerned, a quantity increase in the price of farm land; or a quantity increase in the prices of farm products, means little or nothing to the farmers in the aggregate, for the reason that the purchasing power of money has declined to such an extent, that the bigger amount of money they receive either for their land or products has a minimum exchange value. It must be clear to all that no increase in the earning power of productive property can be predicated, so long as a decrease in the purchasing power of the money received for its products is predicable. Consequently the value of land was no greater in 1920 than in 1900. Only one thing can increase its value, and that is a marked increase in its productivity. There may have been a slight increase in this regard per average acre during the past twenty years, but certainly not enough to justify a threefold increase in price. Only one explanation can be advanced to justify the threefold increase in the 440 The ]STew Capitalism price of land, namely that it was necessary to offset the fall in the purchasing power of money, and so maintain the value the land had in 1900. The Difference Between Price and Value I shall waste no time defining value. To do so with any degree of completeness—to pursue the chameleon character of value through all its nuances, would require a book the dimensions of the volume before you. Rather will I illus¬ trate the difference between price and value in a manner easily understood by all already interested. Let me assume that a farmer bought a farm in 1900, paying a thousand dollars therefor, and that he sold it in 1920. Unless he received four thousand dollars he lost money, for the shrinkage in the value or purchasing power of money has been so great during the twenty years (from 1900 to 1920) that four dollars are but the equivalent of the former one dollar. Conversely, if a farmer bought a farm and paid four thousand dollars for it, he purchased no greater value, though paying a threefold bigger price for it. For the exchange value of the farmer’s dollar has shrunk as much as the exchange value of the wage-earner’s dollar. Until this point is hammered into the brain of every intelligent man there is bound to be much muddled thinking along economic and commercial lines, and “confusion worse con¬ founded. ’ ’ Victim or Culprit? It is clear, from all this, that whereas the farmer is receiving a considerably larger quantity of money for his property in a sale, he is compelled to pay considerably more for whatever property he may purchase with the proceeds. But he is not growing richer. He is not increasing, and cannot, increase the purchasing power of his money—the exchange value of his dollars; and without any increase in these, all his transactions are merely an even exchange, regardless of the quantity of money involved. What About the Farmer? 441 Who has disturbed the purchasing power of money; who is responsible for the fall in the exchange value of the dollar? Not the farmer, although he has been unjustly blamed for the depreciation of the dollar. Indeed I’ll defend him from the charge. More than that, I’ll show that not only has he not been benefited, but on the con¬ trary, he has been the principal sufferer from the fall in the purchasing power of money. He has been the victim, not the culprit. The Farmer's Fabled “Wealth” First I ’ll show that the farmer was no wealthier in 1920 than in 1900. The depreciation in the exchange value of the farmer’s dollar, and in the purchasing power of his money, seriously affects the farmer’s wealth. Here are the relevant statistics: Number of Value of Farm Farms Property 1900 . 5 , 737,372 $ 20 , 439 , 901,164 1910 . 6 , 361,502 40 , 991 , 449,090 1920 . 6 , 447,998 80 , 500 , 000,000 Please note the increase in the “Value of Farm Prop¬ erty” from twenty billion in 1900 to eighty billion in 1920. But it is to be remembered that the exchange value, or pur¬ chasing power, of the dollar, shrank from a 100 cents value in 1900 to a value of about 25 cents in 1920. 2 In other words, using the purchasing power of money as a basis: the twenty billion dollars in 1900 had each a 100 cents value, or a twenty billion dollar purchasing power; whereas the eighty billion dollars in 1920 had but a value of 25 cents, or a total of twenty billion dollars of purchasing power. In brief, the seemingly formidable increase from twenty to eighty billion dollars was a theoretical price increase, and not an increase in actual value, or wealth; a quantity in¬ crease, not a purchasing power increase. As a matter of 2 According to Professor Kemmerer the dollar in 1920 had a value of twenty-seven cents as compared with the dollar of 1896. But for the sake of easy computation by the reader I am taking 1 the liberty to fix the approximate value of the 1920 dollar at twenty-five cents. 442 The New Capitalism fact the eighty billion dollars in 1920 had no greater value, or purchasing power, than the twenty billion dollars in 1900. No doubt the farmers in the aggregate, considered themselves vastly wealthier in 1920 than in 1900; in reality they had not progressed at all, for as regards the purchas¬ ing power of their wealth, and the exchange value of their money, they were no better off than they were twenty years ago. More Money but Less Purchasing Poiver As regards his farm production, unless the farmer in 1920 received four dollars for every dollar he received in 1900, he is making less money than formerly. As a matter of computable fact there has been no such increase in the prices of farm products. The peak prices the farmer en¬ joyed for a brief period during the course of the war, beyond a doubt yielded him an increase in quantity of money, but hardly in purchasing power, as the following statistics “Wealth Production of Farms” (Statistical Ab¬ stract, 1920, p. 180), clearly show: Wealth Produced Total Gross. 1900 . 5 , 009 , 595,000 1910 . 9 , 037 , 391,000 1911 . 8 , 819 , 175,000 1912 .. 9 , 342 , 790,000 1913 . 9 , 849 , 513,000 1914 . 9 , 984 , 961,000 1915 . 10 , 774 , 491,000 1916 . 13 , 406 , 364,000 1917 . 19 , 331 , 000,000 1918 . 22 , 480 , 000,000 1919 . 24 , 961 , 000,000 1920 . 19 , 856 , 000,000 Since our comparison is between 1900 and 1920 we will confine ourselves to a consideration for these two years only. The approximately twenty billions of wealth the farmers produced in 1920 just about equalled in purchasing power the five billion they produced in 1900. What About the Parmer? 443 No Accruing Benefits As a result of the enormous increase in the so-called land value—or rather market price, and the increase of all indus¬ trial products—considerably greater than the increase in the prices of his farm products,—the farmer must borrow vastly greater sums of money than formerly. I do not know how much more money, but continuing the ratio adopted in this chapter I should say that he must borrow four dollars where formerly one dollar sufficed. If in 1900 it was necessary for him to borrow a thousand dollars, in 1920 he borrowed four thousand. But the four thousand had no greater purchasing power or exchange value, than the former one thousand. In other words he is paying inter¬ est on four dollars instead of one. At five percent he is actually paying twenty cents interest, where formerly he paid five cents; twenty dollars, where formerly he paid five dollars; two hundred dollars, where formerly he paid fifty dollars. Or reverse the proposition. Let us suppose that the farmer is a lender instead of a borrower, and that he receives as interest twenty cents where formerly he received five cents; twenty dollars where formerly he received five dollars; two hundred dollars where formerly he received fifty dollars; but note the difference. His twenty cents today has no greater purchasing power than the five cents formerly; the twenty dollars will buy no greater quantity of goods than he could have bought with five dollars twenty years ago; the two hundred dollars makes him no richer than the fifty dollars a score of years before. I will not pause to inquire whether there has been any material increase in the amount of taxes the farmers paid in 1920 over the amount they paid in 1900. Let each farmer answer for himself. But if the tax rate has been advanced on account of the supposed increase in the amount of the farmers’ wealth, or the supposed increase in the value of their property—(and no doubt it has) they were worse off in 1920 than in 1900. For be it remembered that all through 444 The New Capitalism the years the decline in the value or purchasing power of the farmer’s dollar has been as great as the decline in the wage earner’s dollar. The farmers must never lose sight of the fact that for them, as well as for the wage earners, the exchange value of the dollar, the purchasing power of money, has shrunk considerably. If he buys he must pay so many more dollars; if he sells he receives more dollars, but they have a smaller purchasing power. The Chief Beneficiaries I have shown that the farmer in reality does not grow richer by a quantity increase in the price of his land; nor has he been benefited by an increase in the price of farm products. Who, then, has been the beneficiary ? The answer is simple! The Capitalistic group, or the constituent members of the Capitalistic System! If it were possible to obtain all the statistics involved it could be demonstrated that the Capitalistic group has for years derived profits from four distinct agricultural sources: 3 1: From speculation in the principal cereal crops, both before and after they are harvested. 4 2: From selling and re-selling sundry agricultural prod¬ ucts after they leave the farm. 3: From the larger quantity of borrowings of farmers, 5 3 On account of the supplementary processess necessarily involved I am deliberately excluding manufactured products as a source of profit derived by the Capitalistic group from agricultural production. 4 Senator Capper, in an article in HearsCs Magazine (March, 1921), says: “More wheat was sold in Chicago last October than was raised in the entire United States in 1920. Last year’s corn crop was sold fourteen times in Chicago before a bushel of corn had reached the markets. More than $100,000,000 was lost in three months by speculating in cotton and wheat, nearly half of which was cleaned up by commission houses and brokers.” 5 The latest census statistics reveal that the mortgage indebtedness on farms increased from $1,726,172,851 in 1910 to $4,003,767,192 in 1920, or 131.9 percent. It is estimated that the interest bill of the farmers of the United States on mortgages and loans amounted to about $200,000,000 a year. Since the above was written, still later statistics seem to indi¬ cate an even worse state of affairs. Thus in an editorial (HeraId- Examiner, February 22, 1923) we read that the American farmers’ income is “nine billion dollars. He owes twelve and a- half billion, his interest charges are a Ibillion, and his taxes a billion and a quar¬ ter, maybe a billion and a half.” The following from an article by Robert Watson Winston, describ¬ ing conditions in the state of North Carolina (see The Nation, Febru¬ ary 21, 1923), gives a poignant picture of existing conditions: “Tens of thousands of small farmers are owned body and soul by the landowner and the money-lender. Their crop is mortgaged What About the Farmer'? 445 and interest charges vastly greater in size on account of higher prices of farm lands and to enable them to purchase the higher priced implements and equip¬ ment. 4: From the higher prices the farmer must pay for his implements, tools, etc., and, of course, for the sundry articles of merchandise necessary to his existence. I have no means of knowing how great is the volume of profit derived by the Capitalistic group, but in the aggre¬ gate, I think, (if it were possible to obtain the actual sta¬ tistics) the clear profit of the Capitalistic group is as great as the clear profit of the agricultural group. Indeed it is greater, for, as I have already pointed out, the dollar in the hands of the Capitalistic group has always a 100 cents value; whereas in the hands of the farmer only a fraction of its original value remains. The Capitalistic Weather-Vane Is it possible that the Capitalistic group, not content with the profits from the farmers’ production, is now reaching out for actual possession of the land? Is it possible that the Capitalistic System has formed plans to capitalize the productive ability of the farm workers, as they have already capitalized the productive ability of industrial and other workers? Or rather—to overcapitalize the farming indus¬ try as it has overcapitalized the manufacturing industries, transportation systems, public utilities, etc.? This is cer¬ tain to happen if the various farm groups succeed in their endeavors to control their output and the markets, thus depriving the Capitalistic group of some of the enormous profits they have been reaping for years from their board of trade transactions and manipulations. Only a few months after I privately expressed the above thought, the actual proof of the design and of the carrying before it sprouts, and if cotton and tobacco prices reach a low level, which happens many years, not only is there no margin over and above the debt, but a deficit which leaves the farmers deeper in the mire than ever. . . . Competent observers have estimated that between two and three hundred thousand of these tenant farmers—• 'croppers,' as they are called—and their families are not possessed of the wherewithal for even the simplest sort of decent life.” 446 The New Capitalism out of the Capitalistic project fell under my eyes. In the March 17, 1921, issue of the Manufacturers Record (Bal¬ timore, Md.), we read: “ Formation of a Farm Finance Corporation in South Carolina to help handle the cotton crop of 1921 is under way, and with the recent action of the South Carolina Legislature looking to the standardization of grades of the staple held in warehouses, is expected to he completed in a short time. ‘ ‘ This was announced here by Bernard M. Baruch, broker, head of the War Industries Board and of the economic division of the peace delegation of the United States, who has had a series of conferences with J. S. Wanamaker, president of the American Cotton Association, and who expects to furnish at least a part of the initial capital for the corporation. “Mr. Baruch said that whatever stock he purchased in the enterprise would be offered by him to the citizens of South Carolina at cost, as he is anxious for the corporation to be controlled entirely within the state. In addition to furnishing a part of the necessary capital, Mr. Baruch said he woidd handle the securities of the corporation. Mr. Baruch is a South Carolinian by birth. “Asked if an effort would be made to dispose of all the stock within South Carolina, he said disposal of the secur¬ ities would involve no effort, in his opinion, and that he expected the stock to be quickly sold, as it was a first rate investment. “It was reported some weeks ago that such a corpora¬ tion was to be organized in South Carolina to handle the tobacco crop, but this Mr. Baruch denied, saying that the present plan had doubtless given rise to this rumor. He said the American Cotton Association had given its full approval to the scheme, and that he understood similar corporations would be formed in other States under the auspices of the association.” What About the Farmer? 447 The Capitalistic Net Who can doubt that the success of this experiment means its permanent establishment, and its further extension to all farm properties? Who can doubt that the Capitalistic group, having gained control of all natural resources, the basic materials, and the industries; having reached out and captured all the industries, even those entirely unrelated to their original charters—is now reaching out to draw into their net the one industry which thus far they have been unable to grab—the agricultural industry. I may be mistaken in my opinion—I sincerely hope I am—but my guess is that the Capitalistic System is trying to get con¬ trol of and regulate farm production; that it has its plans all laid to organize the important staple producing farms of the nation on the same basis that it has organized the industries—viz., by overcapitalization—and issuing im¬ mense quantities of securities against the inflation. While I believe that the Capitalistic group, to complete its economic conquest of the nation—and of the world—is now reaching out for the farms—I want to make clear the thought that is in my mind. I do not think that the aim of the Capitalistic group is to own or purchase outright the farm lands of the nations. That is really not necessary, for even now it fixes the prices of the products of the farms and controls the market, and that is sufficient for all imme¬ diate Capitalistic purposes. But see what the Capitalistic group loses by not being enabled, at the present time, to buy and sell lands on the stock market! What a splendid source of income is as yet closed to it! My guess is that within ten or twenty years farm lands will have issued against them, stocks and bonds, largely in excess of their present valuation, and Wall Street will literally be deluged with watery wealth. When Wall Street Controls the Farms Why, indeed, should not all the productive farm land of the nation be bought and sold at least once, if not twice, a year, just as the industries and railroad systems are bought 448 The New Capitalism and sold once or several times every twelve months ? Why, indeed? When we stop to reflect that land tenure today is not what it was thirty years ago, and that the tenant class is growing, we begin to realize that the first step towards a breaking up of the diversified land ownership has actually been taken, and as a result, it will be easier to arrange stock, or security holdership, in farm lands. If one farm can be made, with the Capitalistic System of figuring “earning power,” “cost of production,” etc., to comfortably support two people, or rather families, namely owner and tenant, it can be made to support a still greater number. In other words the Capitalistic System is gradually bringing about conditions with regard to farm lands in the United States that, we may rest assured, it will utilize to its own great advantage when it considers that the proper time has arrived. “Will you walk into my Parlorf” Will the farmers bite on the bait? Will they succumb to the lure of speculative profits, or will they stand firm for what is right and fair and just and decent ? Will they walk into the Capitalistic trap? I do not know, for human nature is weak; and it is the common experience of man¬ kind that an appeal to cupidity and self interest is gen¬ erally more successful than an appeal to decency and common sense. As I see it the farmers of the United States have come to the parting of the ways. They must choose their path—one leads to Wall Street and ultimate ruin, the other to actual farm ownership and safety. Today the farmers stand between the Mammonistic Capitalists and the non-investor group as the French soldiers stood against the invading German army, except that in the present situation the Capitalistic group is the invading army. And if the farmers of the United States wish to save, themselves as well as the nation, there must come from their lips, as did from the lips of the French soldiers at Verdun, the chorus cry: ‘ ‘ They shall not pass. ’ ’ The nation has its ear to the ground! CHAPTER XXXII Where Will the Farmer Stand? T HERE is no excuse for any misunderstanding be¬ tween the agricultural portion of the population and the industrial portion. It is to their mutual interest that the farmers and the wage earners find the ground of common agreement. I have sought, in this book, to impress upon the wage earner that the quantity of his wages is of less importance than their exchange value; and necessarily so, too, I would impress upon the farmer that high prices for his products carry with them a depreciated exchange value—a considerably lessened purchasing power of his money. As I see it the farmer should be just as much interested in the exchange value of the workers’ wages as in the exchange value of the prices he receives for his prod¬ ucts ; and the wage earner should be just as much interested in the prices the farmers receive for their products as in his own wages. For just as one worker exchanges his labor for the labor of other workers, so the farmer exchanges his labor (products) for the labor (products) of the workers in other branches of production (industry). The exchange of labor and of labor’s products, is the sum and substance of a nation’s economic life. The goods of one group are exchanged for the products of all other groups. Unless goods are exchanged, stagnation sets in. The Interdependence of Economic Groups In other words, the various economic groups are mutually dependent. It is all folly to say that one group of pro¬ ducers is more important than all the other groups. It is quite true that husbandry was the first industry. Food is the first requisite; and because it is so we can indeed say that the farming industry is of the utmost importance to 449 450 The New Capitalism a nation’s life. For we are not living in primitive times, when families could (and many did) produce their own food essentials, even depending on hunting and fishing for a part of their food supplies. Happily all those things are in the dim past. The system of exchange of products is here to stay; that’s why it’s so great a pity that the various groups have not yet grasped the fundamentals involved in the interchange transactions. The Exchange of Products The average wage earner is principally concerned in, and most affected by, prices of products, whether agricultural or industrial, that must be classified as essential living com¬ modities, viz., clothes, food and shelter. Whereas the aver¬ age farmer is less concerned about his food commodities, since he raises them for himself; and only in a moderate degree in clothes; while shelter or rent, in the majority of cases, is less of a vexation to the farm owner than to the average wage earning city dweller. But on the other hand the farmer is vitally interested in many commodities in which the average wage earner or city dweller has no direct concern; for example, in plows, har¬ nesses, implements, tools, wagons, etc., a hundred com¬ modities essential to the conduct of a farm. 1 While I am unable to say what proportion of their income the farmers of the United States exchange for the com¬ modities produced by the industrial wage-earners, it is, no doubt, a large amount in the aggregate, as the following statistics would seem to show: 1914 1919 Value of Farm Products Value of Manufactured Products $ 9 , 894 , 491,000 $ 24 , 246 , 434,724 19 , 856 , 000,000 62 , 427 , 905,000 i And I haven’t said one word about the many commodities that neither wage earner nor farmer uses or purchases; yet both wage earner and farmer are penalized in that they ultimately pay the higher prices, the higher interest charges and, of course, the bigger profit on articles, purchased, I might say, exclusively by the Capital¬ istic group; and the purchase of which only adds to the value of their investment; for example: steel rails, locomotives, engines, ma¬ chinery, etc. Where Will the Farmer Stand? 451 But even though the farmers of the United States had spent every dollar of the nearly ten billion they received in 1914 for their products; or the nearly twenty billion they received in 1919, for manufactured products, it must be remembered that only a part of their purchases are made for what are called ‘ ‘ living commodities, ’’ while a consider¬ able part of their purchases of manufactured goods are tools, implements, equipment, machinery, etc., and there¬ fore less an expenditure than an actual investment, which increases the value of their properties. Whereas the wage earner can show neither investment nor profit. If the farmer buys a plow, who makes a money profit—the wage earner ? No! the Capitalistic employer of those who made the plow makes the profit. At no time does the wage earner receive more than a living for having made the plow. 2 3 And so it is for every manufactured commodity that the farmer must purchase. All the profits go to the Capitalistic group —none of it to the wage earner group. The Inter-Relation of Economic Groups Moreover, to the wage earner attaches the compulsion to spend all he earns; and a fair part of his earnings are expended for farm products. Of the approximately forty million men and women “engaged in the gainful occupa* tions” ten million are listed as agricultural. But instead of launching a new division based on workers, let me rather employ the simple division of farm families and city fam¬ ilies. In round numbers there are ten million farm families 1 and ten million city families. Consequently the average farmer produces for his own and one city family. Or we may express the formula conversely by saying that every 2 A comparison of the annual revenue of the six and a half million farm owners given under “Value of Farm Products’’ (see p. 450), and of the wages of the industrial wage earners is interesting: Number of Industrial Total Amount Wage Earners of Wages 1914 .7,036,337.$ 4,079,332,433 1919 .9,098,119. 10,545,905,000 3 This division would seem to embrace farm workers and farm owners, and tenant farmers. 452 The New Capitalism city family supports itself and one farm family. I will not particularly emphasize in this chapter that the tenant farmer is growing more numerous. But since we are deal¬ ing with the economics involved in the subject, it behooves me to say that, translated into clear language, this would seem to indicate an unhealthy tendency, in that the con¬ tinued growth of the tenant farmers would ultimately put the average city family to the necessity of supporting two farm families—owner and tenant. I could pursue this phase of the subject over many, many pages, but nothing would be gained thereby. The specific purpose I have in mind is to emphasize that agricultural and industrial production go hand in hand. The farmers and the wage workers are interdependent; they exchange their products; their interests are common, mutual and identical; their relationship reciprocal and complementary. There can be, there must be, no conflict between them. There is only one technical difference between them; the industrial workers receive wages, whereas the farmers are dependent upon prices. Excessive Farm Production The war has demonstrated the great productive ability of the farmers of the United States. Not only does their normal production adequately supply the normal needs of our own population, but a surplus remains for export. With intensified production our farms could easily produce enough to supply a considerably greater number of people. If there is any logic in the Malthusian theory that the con¬ stant tendency of a nation’s population is to outstrip its food supply, the farmers have shown that we need not waste any of our time in worry. Considering their wonderful productive ability, so splendidly proved during the period of the war, neither this generation nor the next, nor the next, will be subjected to suffering on account of an inade¬ quate farm production. Where Will the Farmer Stand*? 453 A Disastrous “Remedy” The particular menace—and it is not a purely theoretical condition—that hangs over the farmers of the United States today, is that their normal production is greater than the consumption. So real is this menace that no less a person than the Secretary of the Department of Agriculture, Henry C. Wallace, himself a farmer, or at least publisher of several farm papers, and, therefore, supposed to be conversant with farming conditions in his own state as well as with the farm situation throughout the nation, recently suggested that production of some of the cereals be cur¬ tailed 25 percent. The dominant idea in Secretary Wallace’s mind when he made the suggestion, was that by the deliberate curtailment of output prices of farm products would remain nearer to the level of war time prices. Secre¬ tary Wallace, no doubt, believes that curtailed farm pro¬ duction is to the farmers’ interest. A moment’s reflection reveals the fallacy of his proposal. When Secretary Wallace advocates a 25 percent less farm production for the purpose of keeping up high prices for farm products he entirely overlooks the city dwellers, who would be compelled to pay materially increased prices in consequence of a lessened production. He also seems to forget that the materially increased prices for farm prod¬ ucts, as a result of curtailed production, would automatic¬ ally lessen consumption. In the end, neither producer nor consumer would be benefited economically. It is an absolute certainty that the average city worker (wage earner) cannot increase the amount of money he pays for farm products. According to Government statistics the average family pays 40 percent of its family income for food. If the family income is $1000—then $400 goes for food products. If the family income is $1500—then $600 goes for food products. Assuming that the average wage earner’s income is sufficient to meet the living costs of an average family, he is paying forty cents out of every dollar he earns merely for food. I do not mean to say that all of this amount 454 The New Capitalism goes directly to the farmer, for many of the farm products are subjected to manufacturing processes, and go through the hands of middlemen before ultimately reaching the wage earner’s table; but it cannot be denied that a consid¬ erable part of the 40 percent expended by an average family for food, goes to the farmer. Reduced Wages Curtail Consumption Now that wages have been reduced from 25 to 50 percent, for practically the whole tribe of city workers,—wage earn¬ ers as well as small salaried employees,—the family income will be less. This reduction in income, even though still 40 percent were figured as applying to the item food, would necessarily reduce the amount spent by an average family for food. If a worker’s family income in 1920 was $1500, and he spent 40 percent, or $600 for food; and his income is cut to $1000, still spending 40 percent he automatically cuts down the food allowance to $400. But if prices remain approximately as they were when his income was $1500, a cutting down in the quantity of consumption is imperative. A Remedy Worse than the Disease Let me illustrate in the simplest possible way why farmers would not benefit by deliberately curtailing their produc¬ tion. Let us assume for the purpose of this illustration that the nearly six and a half million farm owners in a given year raise 800,000,000 bushels of wheat—a normal crop, let us call it; and that the price is one dollar a bushel. Then it occurs to them that by cutting down production by one half, the price will be two dollars per bushel. The result, then, would be a 400,000,000 bushel crop, for which they would receive as much at two dollars a bushel as they re¬ ceived the year before for 800,000,000 at one dollar a bushel. You will observe that in the aggregate they do. not receive any greater quantity of money in spite of the higher prices they received. But let us assume that on account of the great scarcity created by the deliberate reduction in production the price Where Will the Farmer Stand? 455 of wheat would go to three dollars a bushel. Would they receive $1,200,000,000 for their 400,000,000 bushels? No! for there would be so decided a drop in consumption as to nat¬ urally cut down their sales; for it is to be remembered that thus much and no more can the average wage earner spend for food. Consequently, if prices of food products go up he purchases less quantity. Or he might insist on w r age in¬ creases to enable him to purchase the usual quantity of food; but in that case the prices of all non-food commodities which the farmers must normally purchase, would advance, and the greater quantity of money the farmer receives for his wheat, would disappear in the greater amount he must pay for what he must purchase. The curtailment remedy defeats its own purpose; is, in brief, no remedy at all. The argumentative farmer might say that for the smaller crop he will require less seed and only half the land; and of course his work is cut down by one half. Quite true! but that way lies the road to ruin, which may indeed be delayed a few years, but in the end disaster will surely overtake him. Let those who are wise read as they run. Two Formulas The ideal formula, and to the maintenance of which the farmers should bend their efforts, is, normal production, normal prices, and normal consumption. Tamper with this formula and trouble ensues—trouble for all concerned. I lay it down as an axiom, that the economic equilibrium can¬ not be disturbed with impunity—the penalty must be paid sooner or later, not only by one party but by all parties concerned. This must be clear to everyone who is not utterly devoid of common sense, not to speak of logic. Judge for yourself. Assume, for the moment, normal production and abnormal prices. The result is subnormal consumption, and that means if not absolutely a less, at least no greater, income for the producer, to say nothing of the incidental suffering of the victims of a less than normal consumption. But the viciousness of Secretary Wallace’s proposal be- 456 The New Capitalism comes apparent when one reduces it to a formula. What he proposes is subnormal production, attended by abnormal prices. This would lower still more an already subnormal consumption. It would, moreover, intensify the suffering of the wage earner families—and visit deleterious conse¬ quences upon their constituent members—particularly the children. But overlooking this fact, which belongs rather to the realms of sociology than economics,—clearly the pro¬ ducing farmers would not be the beneficiaries of any arbi¬ trary system which may best be expressed as follows: Sub¬ normal production, abnormal prices, and -subnormal consumption. In short the farmer would not be benefited in the least. Even though curtailed production might bring him higher prices per ton, bushel, or pound, the higher prices would not bring him a bigger amount of money in the aggregate. Lessened farm production with resultant higher prices for a smaller unit of production, does not and cannot increase the farmers ’ quantity of money income, for, those who must buy would meet the situation by cutting down their pur¬ chases probably even beyond the smaller supply produced. It is unbelievable that a man of Secretary Wallace’s intelli¬ gence should seriously propose to the farmers of the United States so disastrous and vicious, an economic ‘ ‘ remedy. ’ ’ 4 “Exchange Value” Once More But even though the farmer, by producing less and charg¬ ing higher prices for the smaller quantity produced, could increase his quantity income, his economic condition would still in no wise be improved, for the exchange value of his money, its purchasing power, would be no greater. Even though it were possible to keep up the higher war prices for farm products the farmer would still be no better off, 4 In his letter to W. E. Holler, of the Flint, Mich., Chamber of Commerce, Secretary Wallace wrote: “Kill off the fallacy that it is immoral for farmers to adjust their production to the probable demand by curtailing- a particular crop in the face of a present or prospective over supply and ruinously low prices—a thing manu¬ facturers have been doing- from the beginning- of time .”—Quoted from The Chicago Herald-Examiner, June 23, 1921. Where Will the Farmer Stand? 457 for the high prices he receives for what he sells would be absorbed by the high prices he would be compelled to pay for what he must buy. The high prices he receives for what he produces are reduced to nullity by the high prices he must give for what others produce. The process of exchanging high priced agricultural prod¬ ucts for high priced industrial products is essentially a can¬ cellation process. No benefit whatever accrues, either to the agricultural producer or to the industrial producer (i. e. wage earner). And when I use the word producer here it is in its literal sense, for the average farmer is a wage earner, before he is an investor. Without his labor his in¬ vestment is dead. He cannot go to Europe for a year or two or three years and expect to derive benefits from his property unless he is a large landowner, and has his busi¬ ness so thoroughly systematized that his personal labor or supervision is not necessary to its continued success. There are some such in the United States, but their percentage of the total is negligible. In the majority of cases the agri¬ cultural proprietor must give his personal supervision and labor. Which being the case he must, for all practical economic purposes, consider himself classed with the wage earners, rather than with the Capitalistic group. It is from non¬ investors (wage earners) rather than from investors (Capi¬ talists) that the farmer derives his livelihood and his profits. It is from the continued patronage of the non-investors (wage earners) that the farmer will hereafter, as in the past, derive his greatest benefit. Indeed the welfare and prosperity of the industrial wage earners and the welfare and prosperity of the agricultural wage earners are of a piece. They cannot be separated without injury to both parties. The Solitary Solution Prices for farm products have seriously slumped, as far as the producer (the farmer) is concerned, but the slump has brought no relief to the consumer (the wage earner), 458 The New Capitalism who is compelled to pay in the course of his retail purchases of them, fluctuating prices whose average through the year at least approximates the prices he paid for them in 1920, for be it remembered that the aggregate living costs of the average wage earner’s family, which includes the item rent, are practically what they were when living costs were at their peak. There is but one hope for both farmer and wage earner, and that is not in higher prices or higher wages, but in a greater exchange value of the wages of the industrial work¬ ers and a greater purchasing power of the prices which are the wages of the agricultural worker. The power to restore the dollar to its maximum value lies in the hands of the wage earners and farmers. The farmer must take his stand—either he must array himself on the Capitalistic side against the wage earning non-investors; or he must take his stand ivith the wage earning non-investors, against the encroachments of the Capitalistic group, thus saving not only the wage earner but himself, from complete submergence. It should not be difficult for the farmer to decide. For all these years he has been at the mercy of the Capitalistic group. Has the Capitalistic group ever considered the far¬ mer's welfare? Let each farmer answer the question for himself. Is it reasonable to suppose that the Capitalistic group, whose whole endeavor is to pile up greater and greater Capital accumulations, and to concentrate the na¬ tional wealth within the hands of a few,—will hereafter extend greater consideration to the agricultural producers than it has to the industrial wage-earners? The One Hope Driven to desperation, and in sheer self defense, the far¬ mers are organizing themselves into national associations. Will they be successful? Frankly, I doubt it, principally for the reason that in one vital thing they are, and will con¬ tinue to be, dependent upon the organized Capitalistic group. As long as they must rely upon the Capitalistic Where Will the Farmer Stand*? 459 group for financial assistance to enable them to pay their mortgages, or move their crops, so long will they be weak and vulnerable—their Achilles heel remain exposed. Under my system, in due time, this dependence upon Capitalistic assistance, and which is never extended, and even refused unless a sightly profit is in sight, will be removed, and our cooperation substituted to safeguard the farmers, and serve their best interests. I can only hope that the various national associations of agricultural producers will be in existence and in perfect working order when we begin to operate, for it will be alto¬ gether simpler for us to cooperate with the farmers organ¬ ized than with them disorganized. We can be of greater service to them if they are a component, homogeneous, united group than divided into smaller units—heterogene¬ ous, scattered and ineffective. We may not be able in the beginning to help the farmer so much with what he buys as with what he has to sell. We can be instrumental in pre¬ venting the profits of his production from falling into the hands of the non-farm owning, non-farm working Capitalis¬ tic group. More than that, under our regime, every dollar of money he receives, will have a vastly increased exchange value; and every dollar of profit a considerably higher purchasing power. CHAPTER XXXIII No Political Party I EARNESTLY beseech those into whose hands the man¬ agement of the affairs, and the control of the destinies of the New Order will be committed, to make no at¬ tempt, and permit no attempt to be made, to organize the New Order into a political party. The manifold reasons for the undesirability of giving a political character and complexion to our organization are so obvious that I hesi¬ tate to enumerate them. Still there may be some who hav¬ ing insufficiently considered the importance and magnitude of the project advocated in this book, may not clearly com¬ prehend my caution and counsel. For the benefit of these I will briefly summarize my reasons and arguments. Business in Politics In the first place let us remember that those constituting the Mammonistic-Capitalistic Entrepreneur group are not organized into a political party, yet they thoroughly con¬ trol the politics of the nation, dictating the platforms and policies of both of the major parties—not only of the vari¬ ous states but of the national government as well. It is unnecessary to enter upon a lengthy discussion of this phase of my subject. The conclusive facts are recorded in thousands of pages of official investigations and reports. Moreover, not so many years ago, our popular magazines engaged in a campaign of exposure which clearly established the premises here stated. To fill pages and pages of this book with excerpts and quotations would be like writing a voluminous treatise to prove that water is wet. Nevertheless to clear myself of any charge' of misrepre¬ sentation or exaggeration I will quote the first official utter¬ ance on the subject made by President Cleveland in his 460 No Political Party 461 Fourth Annual Message to the Congress of the United States (December 3, 1888) : “We discover that the fortunes realized by our manufac¬ turers are no longer solely the reward of sturdy industry and enlightened foresight, but that they result from the dis¬ criminating favor of the Government and are largely built upon undue exactions from the masses of our people. The gulf between employers and the employed is constantly widening, and classes are rapidly forming, one comprising the very rich and powerful, while in another are found the the toiling poor. “As we view the achievement of aggregated capital we discover the existence of trusts, combinations, and monopo¬ lies, while the citizen is struggling far in the rear or is trampled to death beneath an iron heel. Corporations, which should be the carefully restrained creatures of the law and the servants of the people, are fast becoming the people’s masters. ’’ 1 “Big Business” Statesmen Succeeding Presidents in their addresses or messages to Congress expressed similar sentiments with regard to the growing menace of Trusts, Combines and Monopolies. But after the organization of the United States Steel Corpora¬ tion we discern a less critical attitude; in fact, a decided change of front became distinctly observable in some of the official utterances. Accusations and condemnations are transmuted into palliation of deeds, and admiration for and laudation of, the doers. Thus in his first Message to Congress (December 3, 1901), President Roosevelt said: “The captains of industry who have driven the railway systems across this continent, who have built up our com¬ merce, who have developed our manufactures, have on the whole done great good to our people. Without them the material development of which we are so justly proud could never have taken place. Moreover, we should recognize the immense importance of this material development of leaving i Messages and Papers of the Presidents, Vol. VIII, p. 774. 462 The New Capitalism as unhampered as is compatible with the public good the strong and forceful men upon whom the success of business operations inevitably rests. The slightest study of business conditions will satisfy anyone capable of forming a judg¬ ment that the personal equation is the most important factor in a business operation; that the business ability of the man at the head of any business concern, big or little, is usually the factor which fixes the gulf between striking success and hopeless failure. . . . “The mechanism of modern business is so delicate that extreme care must be taken not to interfere with it in a spirit of rashness or ignorance. Many of those who have made it their vocation to denounce the great industrial com¬ binations which are popularly, although with technical in¬ accuracy, known as “trusts,” appeal especially to hatred and fear. These are precisely the two emotions, particularly when combined with ignorance, which unfit men for the exercise of cool and steady judgment. In facing new indus¬ trial conditions, the whole history of the world shows that legislation will generally be both unwise and ineffective un¬ less undertaken after calm inquiry and with sober self restraint. Much of the legislation directed at the trusts would have been exceedingly mischievous had it not also been entirely ineffective. . . . “There is widespread conviction in the minds of the American people that the great corporations known as trusts are in certain of their features and tendencies hurtful to the general welfare. This springs from no spirit of envy or uncharitableness, nor lack of pride in the great industrial achievements that have placed this country at the head of the nations struggling for commercial supremacy. It does not rest upon a lack of intelligent appreciation of the neces¬ sity of meeting changing and changed conditions of trade with new methods, nor upon ignorance of the fact that com¬ binations of capital in the effort to accomplish great things is necessary when the world’s progress demands that great things be done. It is based upon sincere conviction that combination and concentration should be, not prohibited, No Political Party 463 but supervised and within reasonable limits controlled; and in my judgment this conviction is right. ’ ’ 2 One is not surprised, therefore, that in 1907 the President of the United States abetted the United States Steel Cor¬ poration in the absorption of the Tennessee Coal and Iron Company, the acquisition of which was “particularly ad¬ vantageous to the Steel Corporation, because of the iron and coal properties that go with it.” (Investigation of the United States Steel Corporation Hearings, p. 1129.) 3 Statesmen on “Big Business” in Politics That conditions had not materially altered—except for the worse—since President Cleveland’s declaration of 1888 may be judged from the following from Woodrow Wilson’s book, “The New Freedom,” published in 1913: ‘ ‘ One of the most alarming phenomena of the time, . . . is the degree to which government has become associated with business. I speak for the moment of the control over the Government exercised by Big Business. Behind the whole subject, of course, is the truth that, in the new order, government and business must be associated closely. But that association is at present of a nature absolutely intoler¬ able; the precedence is wrong, the association is upside down. Our Government has been for the past few years under the control of heads of great allied corporations with special interests. It has not controlled these interests and assigned them a proper place in the whole system of busi¬ ness; it has submitted itself to their control. As a result there have grown up vicious systems and schemes of govern¬ mental favoritism (the most obvious being the extravagant tariff) far-reaching in effect upon the whole fabric of life, touching, to his injury, every inhabitant of the land, laying unfair and impossible hardships upon competitors, imposing taxes in every direction, stifling everywhere the free spirit of American enterprise. . . . It is an intolerable thing 2 Messages and Papers of the Presidents, Vol. X, pp. 422, 423, 424. 3 Senator La Follette is authority for the statement that over twelve thousand firms were combined during the seven years of President Roosevelt’s administration. 464 The New Capitalism that the Government of the republic should have got so far out of the hands of the people; should have been captured by interests which are special and not general. In the train of this capture follow the troups of scandals, wrongs and indecencies, with which our politics swarm . . . “We know that something intervenes between the people of the United States and the control of their own affairs at Washington. It is not the people who have been ruling them of late,” etc., etc. More Recent Testimony On April 16, 1921, Senator La Follette delivered an ad¬ dress in Washington, D. C., under the auspices of the Na¬ tional Council of the People’s Legislative Service, from which I quote the following: “The great issue before the American people today is the control of their own government. “A mighty power has been builded in this country in recent years, so strong, yet so insidious and far-reaching in its influence that men are gravely inquiring whether its iron grip on government and business can ever be broken. “Again and again it has proved strong enough to nomi¬ nate the candidates for both political parties. It has domi¬ nated the organization of legislative bodies, state and na¬ tional, and of the committees which frame legislation. Its influence has been felt in cabinets and in the policies of ad¬ ministrations and has been clearly seen in the appointment of prosecuting officers and the selection of judges upon the bench. In business it has crippled or destroyed competi¬ tion. It fixes the prices of the necessaries of life and im¬ poses its burdens upon the consuming public in defiance of the law. In transportation, after a prolonged struggle for government control, it is absolute master of the highways of commerce. In finance its power is unlimited. With the connivance of the trustees of the people, it has acquired vast areas of the public domain and has monopolized the natural resources—timber, iron, coal, oil. And this thing has grown No Political Party 465 up in a country where, under the Constitution and the law, the CITIZEN is sovereign. “This great power which has taken from the American people the control of their own government, is the product of Monopoly and Organized Greed. ‘ ‘ At this hour, as never before in the history of this coun¬ try, the Congress of the United States is being subjected to influences which are undermining representative govern¬ ment. “Never before, in a generation of time, has the national capital attracted so menacing an army of lobbyists seeking from the representatives of the people unjust concessions to special interests, ” etc. Plain Words Scores of other statesmen are on record with definite and specific charges, accusing the Capitalistic group of consti¬ tuting an “invisible government.” But to establish a fact already known is not the purpose of this chapter. Let me, therefore, continue with the more practical considerations involved in my counsel not to venture upon any attempt to organize a political party under the auspices of the New Order—at least not for many years to come. The first requisite for a successful party is a powerful national press. While the New Order will endeavor to build up a national press, years necessarily must elapse before one sufficiently strong to cope with all the established Capital¬ istically owned and controlled periodicals can be developed. The foolhardiness of launching a party without a press must be apparent to all. Moreover, we would for many years be a third and a minority party, and in competition with the existing major parties, which would place us beyond the pale of their consideration. Without a party of our own, we can claim the attention of both parties. Both parties will court our favor and covet our assistance; and so be careful not to an¬ tagonize or offend us. Thus we would exercise a greater 466 The New Capitalism influence and power than if we were entirely detached from and opposed to them. But even though it were possible, after a score or so of years, to win in a state or national election, we would expose ourselves to possible defeat in some following election, just as one or the other of the existing major parties regularly suf¬ fers defeat at present. The inevitable result would be that before long we would find ourselves, in order to combat the chicanery and trickery of politicians, put to the necessity of giving a larger measure of attention to politics than to economics, thus inviting both political and economic dis¬ aster. When the Tail Wags the Dog Political economists are prone to accentuate that the po¬ litical and economic life of a nation are inextricably inter¬ woven; that politics and economics are inseparably linked together. And there is a measure of truth in their contention. That is why in European countries fiery doctrinaires are preaching that their economic emancipation and their politi¬ cal liberation can be brought about only by the overthrow of the existing governments. ‘ ‘ Socialism, ’ ’ said Lenin, * ‘ is impossible without the domi¬ nation of the proletariat in the state. ’ ’ In other words, the proletariat, according to Lenin’s philosophy, is to be the state. This is in no wise different from the famous saying of Louis XIV— L’Etat, c’est mois —“I am the State.” In Europe there may be reason and justification for the several attempts that have been, and are being made, to ameliorate economic conditions by radical political changes; but not in the United States. And I seize this opportunity to note the distinctive difference between my plan and the sundry politico-economic isms with which the public is more or less familiar. I place myself in uncompromising opposi¬ tion to those who declare that the economic redemption of society can be accomplished only through the instrumental¬ ity of the State. I hold that an economic system that de¬ pends for its maintenance upon the exercise of political No Political Party 467 power, or that has for its basic principle the destruction of wealth, the elimination of capital, and the confiscation of property regardless of the established processes of law; or the dispossession of a group, because a few, or even many, within that group have wrongfully acquired property or wealth, cannot be approved. Any economic program that calls for the violent overthrow of the existing political order, whether that order is acceptable or not, is, to say the least, a dangerous doctrine. Nor have I any sympathy with any economic scheme that is synonymous with a leveling process. All radical reform plans and their derivatives, by whatever name they may be called, I sweep aside, not so much because they are revolutionary but because they would not change for the better—but rather for the worse, the conditions against which the world is in protest. Granting that the present Capitalistic order of society is tyrannical and un¬ just, the substitution of any of the radical isms would still continue that tyranny and injustice. Its acceptance would merely transfer tyrannical control and power from the hands of the Capitalistic group to the hands of a none the less tyrannical* group—call it proletariat or by whatever name you choose. The Power of the Ballot Happily we in the United States are more fortunately situated than the people of Europe. Though tremendous changes have taken place in our country’s political principles and policies during the past few decades—changes which perverted our government from a Democracy into a Timoc¬ racy—while many public officials have proved unfaithful to their trust and betrayed the people, there reposes in our hands the franchise through the intelligent exercise of which every existing evil can be removed or eradicated. 4 I hold that fundamentally our political life and our eco¬ nomic life are distinct; certainly they are not irremediably 4 De T-ocqueville, author of “Democracy in America,” in one of his letters said: “All the world over. Governments are just as rascally as nations will allow them to be. This is the only limit to their vices.” 468 The New Capitalism interwoven as they seem to be in the European countries. Speaking with particular reference to the United States— I am inclined to think that the Capitalistic economists have hitherto put an undue stress on the Political features of the “science” of Political Economy. We propose to put the greater stress on the Economy side. Instead of worrying over the porisms of Political Economy, we will build up a science of Economic Politics—or rather let me call it—Economic Polity. A century and a half of experience has revealed that the people cannot hope to improve their economic con¬ dition through the medium of politics. Perhaps it will be easier for them to improve politics by first improving their economic condition. A people that is held in economic sub¬ jection cannot be politically powerful, however much writ¬ ers and speakers may disguise the fact by mouthing the word ‘ ‘ Democracy ’ J and its variants. As long as the people are economically enslaved, so long will they be held in political bondage; and all the oratorical boast about ‘ ‘ popu¬ lar government” and “government of the people, for the people and by the people” are but words, words, words— meaningless phrases and inept platitudes. Not until they are economically powerful can the people become politically potent. At any rate—let it never be forgotten that the New Order is primarily an Economic Association, organized for the definite purpose of bringing about the economic welfare and security of the people. If we are true to our prin¬ ciples the New Order can get along without any political party; the New Capitalism can succeed independently of politics. “A Daniel Come to Judgment” At the Annual Meeting of Stockholders 5 of the United States Steel Corporation (April 18, 1921) Mr. Elbert H. Gary read a paper entitled “Principles and Policies of the 5 It would be interesting to know how many of the 160,000 stock¬ holders of the United States Steel Corporation attended the meet¬ ing ; and their names and addresses; and the amount of the actual holdings of each would add to the interest. 469 No Political Party United States Steel Corporation.” I have no intention of analyzing these “Principles and Policies” at this time; nor even of discussing Mr. Gary's utterances, beyond saying that, of course, he reiterated his avowed opposition to labor unions. “I firmly believe that complete unionization of the industry of this country . . . would be the beginning of industrial decay,” said Mr. Gary. Let that pass without comment. I am not interested in that aspect of the controversy at this time. It is only the last sentence of Mr. Gary’s discussion of ‘ ‘ labor unions ’ ’ on which I shall concentrate for a moment. Says Mr. Gary : “It seems to me that the natural, if not the necessary, result of the contemplated program of labor unions, if suc¬ cessful, would be to secure the control of the shops, then of the general management of business, then of capital, and finally of government.” Mr. Gary’s fears are well founded, but he has the cart before the horse. He has somewhat mixed the order of procedure. Under the New Capitalism, the people, with organized labor, as the nucleus will endeavor first to secure control of capital—their own capital, if you please—the very capital which Mr. Gary and the entire tribe of Capi¬ talistic Entrepreneurs are today using in a high-handed fashion, and have ruthlessly utilized for all these years; and by the unchallenged use of which he and his friends and associates have grown fabulously wealthy; besides ac¬ quiring an uncontrolled power which he and his kith are now employing to suppress and enslave those who labor for a wage. No, Mr. Gary, you are in error; the “contemplated pro¬ gram of labor unions” under the rule of the New Capital¬ ism, does not contemplate “to secure the control of shops and management of business ’ ’ until it has taken away from you and your kith the ruthless control of capital and all that this implies. Your fear that the labor unions will finally secure control of government need not disturb you for a while as yet, for as the author of the New Capitalism I distinctly warn against political maneuvers. But since 470 The New Capitalism I am on this subject; since you yourself raise the point, what possible objection can you offer against any group, truly solicitious for the people’s welfare, I will not say try¬ ing to secure 11 control of government, ’ ’ but endeavoring to take the control of government away from you and your Capitalistic associates? Or do you really believe that the average citizen is so densely ignorant as not to know that Big Business—the corporations, the Capitalistic Entrepre¬ neurs—the Mammonistic Capitalists—absolutely control the politics of the nation ? The End of Timocracy I have already quoted Aristotle to the effect that there are three political constitutions: Kingship (or monarchy), aristocracy, and timocracy. “Of these,” says Aristotle, “timocracy is the worst,” because it is the rule of wealth. “From timocracy,” continues Aristotle, “the transition is to Democracy .” Timocracy in the United States cannot maintain itself except by the potency of party rule; and party rule is wan¬ ing fast. At any rate the transition from Timocracy to Democracy will not be brought about by any of the existing political parties (in whose vapid platform promises the people have lost all confidence), but by the people them¬ selves who, in the years to come, will choose their own can¬ didates, and give their support to men and principles rather than to selfish Capitalitic measures, disguised as partisan programs. It is this belief that persuades me to say that there may, —indeed I think there will—come a time when a political organization truly representative of the eighty (and more) million non-investors will be formed, but not in the usual way. Ordinarily a few irrelevant platitudes formulated into a ringing platfrom, a picturesque or dazzling leader and a striking party name, were considered sufficient to arouse popular sentiment and win for it the support of the people. The New Order must operate along different lines. It No Political Party 471 must first of all demonstrate its fitness, and prove that its principles are safe and sound, and its leaders worthy of an increase of trust. These things conclusively proved through a series of years, the spontaneous sentiment of the voters among the eighty (and more) million will shape itself into a majority which in due time will insist on expressing itself as a unit at the polls. In the meantime from the eighty (and more) million will come the legislators and judges and the officials of federal, state and city governments, and who will carry into their public service the conviction that the interests of the eighty (and more) million are at least as important as the interests of the twenty million. It will be years before this metamorphosis can take place, but in the New Order it will surely come to pass. Without any effort or design this party will slowly shape itself, and all that will be needed to give it entity, is a name. CHAPTER XXXIV The Concluding Chapter W E have been told of the Englishman who, while confined in the Debtors’ Prison, wrote a treatise on how to wipe out the national debt of England; whereat we are supposed to laugh. But we have never been told what his plan was; therefore none can tell whether it was meritorious or otherwise. Nor is there anyone who can deny that if his plan had been tried the national debt of England might have been liquidated. Nor can anyone as¬ sert that said debtor was more foolish than the government that put him behind the bars. It is entirely within the realm of possibilities for one sent to prison for debt to devise a plan that might bring freedom from debt to the nation that sent him there. Certainly it is not more incongruous than a barber inventing the spinning- wheel. When you come to think about it, nearly all great discoveries and inventions were made by most unlikely peo¬ ple—by people who were considered failures, or fools, or lacking in wit; or ne’er-do-wells, or dreamers— Theorists , we call them today. Some of the most biting sarcasm I have ever heard, fell from the lips of speakers before Cham¬ bers of Commerce crowds, and before Economic Associa¬ tions; it was leveled at Theorists. The sarcastic denuncia- tors were, or at least considered themselves, practical men. It did not occur to them that they were of the lowest order of theorist—that is, parrot theorists—setting forth the theo¬ ries of others—expounding doctrines which they themselves lacked the intelligence to originate; dicoursing on prin¬ ciples which others, not they, had the ingenuity to discover. Theorists and Theories Now as a matter of fact, whatever of progress has been made in the world, or whatever development with regard 472 The Concluding Chapter 473 to civilization, it is the result of theories. The American continent was discovered because Columbus had a theory. When Washington and Jefferson, et at; founded the Ameri¬ can Republic, they were theorists,—not practical men! They had a theory of government—which, by the way, is still in its experimental stages, likely within the next decade or two to prove itself a success or a failure. As long as we ad¬ hered to the principles underlying their theory our country was safe; but now that we ignore their principles, and are departing from their theory, the country is in danger; in more serious danger than I care to admit. But whatever our Government may be today; or will have proved itself to be ten or twenty years hence, this must be admitted—that the American Government, when first proposed, was a theory; its organization and development, the work of theo¬ rists. In fact, every great achievement in the world was first proposed as a theory! Watt, who discovered the power of steam, was a theorist; Fulton, who applied the discovery to navigation, was a theorist; Stephenson, who turned it to land purposes, was a theorist. The telephone, the telegraph, the wireless, the aeroplane, the biograph, the automobile, the radio, radium—hundreds of other inventions and dis¬ coveries, were but the fruition of theories. Write this down in your notebook: Theorists, not practical men, have pushed the world onward and upward. Theorists, not prac¬ tical men, are the hope of the world today. One of the cleverest things that Gilbert K. Chesterton has ever written is this: ‘ ‘ There has arisen in our time a most singular fancy; the fancy that when things go very wrong we need a practical man. It would be truer to say that when things go wrong we need an unpractical man. Certainly at least we need a theorist. A practical man means a man accustomed to mere daily practice, to the way things com¬ monly work. When things will not work you must have the thinker, the man who has some doctrine why they work at all.” 474 The New Capitalism The Failure of Practical Men There is a world of truth in these words. If you want to know what a frightful mess practical men have made of human affairs everywhere, you need but look about you, or read your daily paper. Who is responsible for the eco¬ nomic, and other, troubles of the world today ? Why, prac¬ tical men! Who is responsible for the world muddle ? Again the answer is—practical men! Who invented the various methods and sundry systems that are threatening to cul¬ minate in chaos? The answer is simple—practical men! Who is aggravating and intensifying the universal unrest ? Practical men! Who is getting the world deeper and deeper into the mire? Echo answers—practical men! The ter¬ ribly disturbed conditions in the United States and else¬ where, are the result of the plannings, scheming and plot¬ tings of practical men! Which being the case, from prac¬ tical men, good Lord, deliver us! Therefore, avaunt, ye practical men! Enter the theo¬ rist! You need not take off your hat to the theorist, nor bend your knee to him; but at least do not pelt him with stones, nor stick out your tongue at him. The theoretical man adheres to the fundamentals, unswervingly, uncom¬ promisingly. In his reasoning processes he hews to the line and lets the chips fall where they may. He neither dissem¬ bles ; nor deludes himself; nor deceives his fellow man. He speaks the truth, as he sees it; and calls things by their right name. Smash his principles and his theories fall to the ground. But ‘‘until thou canst rail the seal” from off his bond, “thou but offend’st thy lungs to speak so loud.” President Wilson went into the Peace Conference—an unpractical man, a theoretical man, a leader; he came out of it a practical man, a compromiser, a defeated man. Had he adhered to the fundamentals—had he even held uncom¬ promisingly to his enunciated theories, the historian a hun¬ dred years hence would be compelled to declare him one of the greatest men, perhaps the greatest man, of all times. The Concluding Chapter 475 False Maxims A modern writer has said that the world is governed by a half hundred maxims, most of which are false. This is literally true. It is particularly true with whatever per¬ tains to economics. The whole porismatic “science” of Political Economy is constructed around maxims most of which are false. These false maxims have been current so long that they are accepted as axioms. Men who in all their lives have never so much as looked at the outside of a book on Political Economy,— (and who wouldn’t have the intelli¬ gence to understand what they read were they ever to ven¬ ture upon the perusal of a few pages of such a book, should it accidentally fall into their hands)—mouth them as if their mere utterance constituted the finality of human wisdom. Thus I have heard men of supposed intelligence prate of the “established order” as if it were a sacred and unchangeable thing—entirely ignoring that what we call the “established” order today, was not in existence a half- century ago. Time and again I have heard the statement “prices are regulated by the gold supply” made by men who could not, for the life of them, tell how much gold, coin and bullion, there is in the United States; or how many grains of gold are contained in the standard gold dollar. And I have heard men who were both ignorant and illiterate defend the excessive price of their particular commodities by the ‘ ‘ law of supply and demand. ’ ’ It was of this ‘ ‘ law ’ ’ of which DeQuincey wrote: “A crazy maxim has got pos¬ session of the whole world; viz., that price is, or can be, determined by the relation between supply and demand. ’ ’ Maxims that are false; half truths; perversions of the truth; and plain lies—these are things with which the world has been governed for many, many centuries. “Go, my son,” said a Swedish Chancellor to his son, “go and see with what little cost of wisdom this world is governed. ’ ’ “Where Ignorance is Bliss” How, then, in spite of the falsity of the maxims, and the remarkable unwisdom of those who govern us, did the world 476 The New Capitalism manage to get along as well as it did ? The answer is given by the cynic who said that five percent of the people think; tan percent, think they think; and eighty-five percent would rather die than think. If it were otherwise it would not have been possible for a few thousand (or a few million, if ‘ ah will) to gather the wealth of the world into their laps, leaving to the many millions just enough sustenance to keep body and soul together. And it would not have been pos¬ sible to foist upon the people a “science” which pretends to concern itself with the distribution of wealth, when in reality it concerns itself only with the concentration of wealth in the hands of a few, and the exclusion of the many millions from participation therein. “Go, my son,” said a Swedish Chancellor to his son,— “go and see with what little cost of wisdom this world is governed.” “Go,” might a scholar, in like manner say, after a thoughtful review of literature, “go and see how little logic is required to the composition of most books. ’ ’ 1 The One Non-Progressive Science DeQuincey, writing in the first quarter of the nineteenth century, had in mind those books on Political Economy written toward the end of the eighteenth century, and dur¬ ing the early decades of the nineteenth. “Political Econ¬ omy,” he wrote, “does not advance. Since the revolution effected in that science by Ricardo (1817) upon the whole it has been stationary.” In the science of Political Economy, he maintained, “Nothing can be postulated—nothing can be demonstrated; for anarchy, even as to the earliest prin¬ ciples, is predominant.” But it is not to give concurrence to his views that I quote from DeQuincey’s writings, but rather to lead up to a vital point, and which seems to me pivotal, in the plan I am pro¬ posing. The early economists (among whom Adam Smith stands out as the Father; and whose book, “The Wealth of Nations,” is by some called “the Bible of Economics”) deduced their principles from the conditions actually exist- ♦DeQuincey’s Essay on “Malthus.” The Concluding Chapter 477 ing at the time they wrote—long before Industrialism had appeared. And it is upon these antiquated ‘ 1 principles ’’ (in reality porisms) that modern economists are still build¬ ing the nation’s economic life. It is quite comprehensible that a book, written nearly a century and a half ago, and which purports to state the “principles” upon which the wealth of a nation—particularly England’s wealth—neces¬ sarily rested, might be esteemed today as “the Bible of Economics”—but in that case I should insist on calling it the Old Testament, whose usefulness as an economic 1 ‘ guide, philospher and friend” ceased with the dawn of the New Industrial Revelation. The tremendous changes that came over the world as Industrialism developed during more than a century’s time, surely call for a New Testament in the Economic Bible. Political Economy is the only “science” that hasn’t progressed, in spite of the fact that the automo¬ bile has displaced the ox-cart. When Teeth were Literally Pulled Not so many years ago signs in barbers’ shops and win¬ dows announced: “Leeching, Cupping and Bleeding Done Here; Also Teeth Extracted.” I distinctly recall a tooth¬ pulling operation performed by the town barber— Schweitzer by name, on old Ulmer, the luckless patient. I can see old Schweitzer now, his feet encased in red socks, and slippers worn down at the heels, standing on a common kitchen chair, behind old Ulmer reclining in the barber chair, and boring with all his strength with a corkscrew¬ like instrument into the groaning Ulmer’s tooth (or was it, perhaps, a vice, and he was fastening his hold on the tooth); and then pulling so hard that he fell backward from his chair, pulling old Ulmer, who was holding on grim death to the barber chair, along with him. Did he get the tooth? I do not know, for frightened by old Ulmer’s blood-curdling yells, as if he were being murdered, I took flight. This was less than two score years ago; I think I was about twelve years old at the time. None will deny that dentistry has made some progress since then. 478 The New Capitalism Medical and Economic Doctors In any second-hand book store you will find on the twenty-five cent counter, hundreds of medical books written by men who only a few years ago, were considered authori¬ ties. So tremendous and quick has been the progress in medical science and everything appertaining thereto, that those works are hopelessly out of date, and of interest only to antiquarians or collectors of curious books. In every department of human endeavor revolutionary changes have taken place, but not in Political Economy. Economic doctors still perform their miracles by “Leeching, Cupping and Bleeding. ’ ’ In brief, political economists, now as then, reason from the Capitalistic standpoint and for the exclusive benefit of those constituting the Capitalistic System. It is under the protective logic of their writings that Industrialism begot Capitalism, and Capitalism begot Mammonism. It cannot be denied that Capitalism and Mammonism are self sufficient and successful institutions, and the explana¬ tion for this is to be found in the fact that from the begin¬ ning every moral principle and every ethical consideration has been carefully excluded from all works dealing with economics. In the Bible of Moses and the Prophets you will find all the rules of morality, by the practice of which civilization gradually reared itself aloft. None of these rules are found in the “Bible of Economics.” It is to their rigid exclusion that we must attribute the growth and success of Capitalism and Mammonism. Moses, we are told, granted a bill of divorce to the Jews because they were hard-hearted; but the Economic Fathers, of their own volition, absolutely divorced Ethics from Po- lical Economy; and the whole human race has been com¬ pelled ever since to pay alimony to those constituting the Capitalistic family. No wonder the world—that is to say, most of the people in it, are poor and discontented. No won¬ der there is misery and wretchedness, and crime and degra¬ dation, among them. Where will it end, and how? 479 The Concluding Chapter “The Moving Finger Writes” It was reflections such as these that urged me to the writ¬ ing of this book—the new Evangel of Economics. It was in the contemplation of what might happen unless the world (and that without much delay), comes to its senses, that I found the inspiration for my plan. In my previous writ¬ ings I addressed myself to the powerful men who today hold the economic destiny of the nation, aye, of the world, in the hollow of their hand. I knew, of course, that any appeal to them was futile. Neither Moses and the Prophets, nor Christ Himself, could move them. Nevertheless, unless they curb their insatiable greed for WEALTH, and their gluttony for PROFITS—the deluge will surely come. Yes, the deluge! I am not a pessimist; neither am I a cheerful idiot—sometimes euphemistically called an optim¬ ist by the unthinking. But I try always to be calmly sen¬ sible, and to view things as they are. I have never been able to deceive myself, nor to throw dust into my own eyes. Nor am I an alarmist. Neither am I a prophet, nor the son of a prophet, nor the seventh son of a seventh son. But when I see the black clouds gathering, and the lightning’s flash, and I hear the ominous roll and terrific crashes of thunder, and say “There’s a storm brewing; it’s going to rain—” I am not a pessimist, nor an alarmist, nor am I prophesying; I am only reading what is plainly legible in the sky; I am only saying what must be clear to all who are neither blind, nor deaf, nor perverse. Just as we can read with fair accu¬ racy the disturbed elements in nature, so we can in a meas¬ ure, interpret the social unrest, the economic upheaval, the political disturbances, and the growing discontent, mani¬ fest in the United States and throughout the world today. Appealing from Peter to Pavl Since any appeal to the Mammonistic masters and Capi¬ talistic over-lords of this earth is bound to fall on deaf ears; since, moreover, it is clear, judging from the sundry things happening at the present time, particularly in the United 480 The New Capitalism States, that they do not intend to release, but to strengthen still more their stranglehold upon the throats of the people, I turn to the people themselves to tell them what is so clear to me—that their future destiny rests in their own hands. - Probably I shall not escape the charge of “setting class against class.’’ James E. Thorold Kogers, M. P., in “Six Centuries of Work and Wages—the History of English Labor ’ ’—says in his preface: ‘ ‘ The charge of setting class against class has always been made by those who wish to disguise their own indefensible advantages by caluminating the efforts of those who discern abuses and strive to rectify them. ’ ’ Jeremy Bentham, in his essay, “Britain in 1817,” says: “Propose anything good; the answer is at hand:—wild, theoretical, visionary, Utopian, impracticable, dangerous, destructive, anarchial, subversive of all governments—there you have it.” The Plan I propose is necessarily a theory, until it as¬ sumes the proportions of an experiment, in which case I maintain that it will demonstrate itself a complete success, for the reason that the principles upon which it is based are fundamental and sound. I do not think it necessary in this chapter to give a sum¬ mary of all I have said but I will add a word of warning. Let none imagine for a moment that the things I propose shall be done will be as easy of performance as is the read¬ ing, or as was the writing of this book, written only after twenty years of thought, study, analysis and computation. Above all, let none imagine that the Capitalistic-Mammon- istic Entrepreneurs will surrender instantly, or that they will not put up a bitter fight. Indeed while the non-invest¬ ors are guffawing over a Charlie Chaplin picture, or dawd¬ ling over their evening paper; while the wage' earners are yawningly making up their minds whether they are awake or asleep; and while certain Labor groups are nebulously debating whether, after all, quantity wages for themselves are not preferable to economic independence for all the non- The Concluding Chapter 481 investors, they are diligently taking steps to prevent this new child from growing up. Back to Earth) Throughout the writing of Part II, I have, for the sake of convenience, imagined the existence of the New Order, and visualized the New Capitalism as if in actual operation. Will the New Order ever become an entity ? Will the New Capitalism develop into a reality f I do not know! I have lived too long to harbor delusions. But this I do know, that if ever Labor will lift itself to a higher plane it will be through some such plan as mine; not necessarily the precise plan I have formulated, but at least one built upon the fun¬ damental principles, which I have merely restated. It is quite possible that years will elapse before those most concerned will begin to discern merit in my plan. Per¬ haps the present generation will have passed away; but the time will surely come—say around the year 1975—when some one who has not entirely lost the power of analysis, the capacity to think, and the ability to reason, will com¬ pute “what might have been” had my plan been followed. He will seize upon my statement that under the New Capi¬ talism the average non-investor family will be enabled to save from $100 to $450 a year, and compute what the savings of sixteen million families would have amounted to within twenty-five years, say from 1925 to 1949. His figures will read about as follows: At the rate of $100 a year their aggregate savings would have amounted to $1,600,000,000 a year, or $40,000,000,000 within twenty-five years; or $2,500 per family. At the rate of $200 a year, their aggregate savings would have amounted to $3,200,000,000 a year, or $80,000,000,000 within twenty-five years; or $5000 per family. At the rate of $300 a year, their aggregate savings would have amounted to $4,800,000,000 a year, or $120,000,000,000 within twenty-five years; or $7500 per family. At the rate of $400 a year, their aggregate savings would 482 The New Capitalism have amounted to $6,400,000,000 a year, or $160,000,000,000 within twenty-five years; or $10,000 per family. At the rate of $450 a year, their aggregate savings would have amounted to $7,200,000,000 a year, or $180,000,000,000 within twenty-five years; or $11,250 per family. And he will be at some pains to make clear that the figures represent only aggregate savings ,—that if the savings had been cumulatively invested in the sundry enterprises of the New Order, and earned from five to six percent a year, and compounded—the Capital accumulation would at end of the twenty-five years be considerably more than double the amount of the savings. To illustrate what he means he will take the case of a man twenty years of age in 1925, and who under the New Capi¬ talism would be enabled to save, let us say, $200 a year; and who invests each year’s savings in, say six percent, securi¬ ties of the enterprises of the New Order, and allows his sav¬ ings and interest to accumulate. At the end of twenty-five years, or by the time he is forty-five years old, this man would have accumulated a fund of over $11,000. He will— But why pursue this theme further. “Though I were to speak with the tongue of men and of angels”; though I were to continue to write in this fashion till doomsday, I could add nothing to what I have said, nor augment my argument, to show that 4 ‘ Men at some time are masters of their fates: The fault, dear Brutus, is not in our stars, But in ourselves, that we are underlings.” A Postscript M Y interest in economic subjects dates back a quarter of a century. From early boyhood I was an in¬ defatigable reader; fiction was my chief delight. During my college days I changed from fiction to belles- lettres —essays, poetry, drama. History was added in due time. The one subject which I knew had a literature of its own, yet which failed to interest me, was Political Economy. Statistics were my pet aversion. One day there fell into my hands a little book of essays on economic subjects. I have forgotten the author’s name and the title of the book—but no matter. Not being par¬ ticularly interested in the subjects discussed I read it cas¬ ually, until I came to the following sentence : “The poor are getting richer and the rich are getting poorer. ’ ’ This statement—one of supposed fact by a supposed authority—made me pause and ponder. Instinctively I felt that the writer was not telling the truth. I took a mental survey of the little suburb in which I lived. I knew every family and its circumstances. They were for the most part working people, all of them poor. As far as these sev¬ eral hundred families known to me, were concerned, the author’s statement was not true. None of them was getting richer—all of them were as poor as they had been ten or fifteen years before, and I concluded that at least one-half of the sentence quoted above was a lie. But how about the other half, viz., that “the rich are getting poorer”? There were no rich men in my commu¬ nity, but there were ten or twelve families in those times considered well-to-do—small business men worth between ten to perhaps fifteen thousand dollars. Were they getting poorer ? Yes! some of them were; in fact a number of them ultimately became bankrupt. So there was some justifi- 483 484 The New Capitalism cation, after all, for the author’s statement that “the rich were getting poorer.” It was literally true with regard to the few who abided in my immediate neighborhood. But being of an inquisitive mind I was not satisfied with the fact. I wanted to know the why and wherefore. What were the underlying reasons for this anomaly? I wanted to know precisely what was responsible for the change in the status of the well-to-do. What was making them, if not poor, at least less wealthy? There could be no peace for me until I had found the complete answer to my sundry questions. In due time I made the discovery that a tremendous change was taking place: The small business man could not compete with the encroaching big business man. To attempt competition was inviting bankruptcy. A few, prob¬ ably not realizing what was going on, were foolish enough to try it, with the inevitable result: they were pushed against the wall. In particular, at this moment, I recall the fate of a splendid family known to me, living in an¬ other part of the city, the father and sons of which had built up a lucrative business, dealing in oil. Then along came the Standard Oil Company, undersold them, and so drove them out of business. I can call by name, too, a number of small butchers, and a sausage maker, who were compelled to go out of business because they could not com¬ pete with the big slaughterers. But all this is now ancient history. Thus I arrived at the conclusion that what the economic writer had stated, viz., that the poor were getting richer, was not true; nor was it true that the rich were getting poorer. The thing that was true, and which he did not state—was that the small business man was being ruth¬ lessly eliminated. My interest in economic subjects was now thoroughly aroused. True, I had hoped to be able to pursue my studies without bothering much about statistics, which always worried and mystified me. In brief, for several years I followed the line of least resistance—concentrating on those subjects which did not depend on wearisome statistical ' A Postscript 485 tables for their comprehension and mastery; and slighting those which did. But I soon discovered that if I wanted to get at the bottom of things I would have to conquer my antipathy for statistics. This I bravely resolved to do. It was a bitter pill, but I swallowed it. For a year or two I continued my studies faithfully, but without enthusiasm, doggedly groping my stumbling way among the labyrin- thal mazes of charts, diagrams, statistical tables, and per¬ centages. Then suddenly a great light began to break in upon me. I had frequently heard the defiant challenge: ‘ ‘ There are the figures, and figures don’t lie.” Like everybody else I accepted the rather trite and silly saying as a truism—-an indisputable and incontrovertable fact—the argument un¬ answerable. But in due time I discovered that it was pos¬ sible to lie through the medium of figures as well as through the medium of words. A Scottish philosopher neatly ex¬ pressed it when he said: “As the statist thinks, the bell clinks.” Moreover, just about this time I made, the acquaintance of a prominent public man—“a gentleman and a scholar,” who had spent a number of years in an important branch of the Government service. With him I discussed many things, particularly statistics. He told me of a certain case in which, to his knowledge, certain official statistics had been altered by order of a certain high official, to suit this official’s purposes. While this startling piece of information did not help to increase my faith in statistics, nor my respect for statisticians, it did increase my determination to get under the skin of statistics. It was a French philosopher who said that men employ speech to conceal their thoughts. After many years of patient analysis of thousands of sets of statistics, and their correlation, I am willing to go on record as saying that the purpose of statistics seems to be to conceal the truth, and to confuse, confound, and deceive the public. By the same process of logic I have arrived at the com elusion that the whole “science” of Political Economy is built around a framework of half truths, perversions of half truths, and plain and statistical untruths. And I 486 The New Capitalism determined that one day I would write a book which would lay bare the fundamental fallacies of this vaunted “ sci¬ ence, ” and the glaring sophistries of those who exploited it; while at the same time setting forth the true principles and premises, and upon which alone it is possible to build an orderly economic system. And I flattered myself that the net result of my labors would constitute a veritable Symphony in Economics. With this definite purpose in mind I continued my eco¬ nomic studies, making copious notes and many computa¬ tions, while writing down all the independent conclusions at which I was arriving. On July 4, 1920, I began the actual work of composition. For a whole year I wrote— an average of a thousand words a day. But the more I wrote the bigger became my task, and my subject. At the end of twelve months I took an inventory of the progress I had made. I found that while I had written a full three hundred thousand words I had hardly scratched the surface. All that I had done in a year ’s time was not even a phrase of my planned Symphony. It was then that I saw the magnitude of the task I had set for myself, and the utter hopelessness of ever accom¬ plishing so prodigious and ambitious an undertaking. I realized that to do justice to myself and to the subject, I would have to write not one, but twenty books—twenty ponderous volumes, the writing of which would demand years of studious solitude and intensive concentration, none of which I could afford to give. Besides, who would read a work of such proportions? Regretfully I abandoned my original plan to write an Economic Symphony. What I am offering the public under the title “The New Capitalism” is nothing more than a few elementary lessons on a few of the principles of economics, and those, corrective of technique rather than exhaustive of the theme. There is hardly a paragraph that could not be developed into a chapter; hardly a chap¬ ter that could not be elaborated into a book. Therefore let it be understood that the various chapters constituting this single volume are not a compendium, not even an out-* A Postscript 487 line of the more ambitious work I had in mind when I began to write. * ‘ The New Capitalism ’ ’ is nothing more than an attempt to strike the deeper and the rarely sounded notes in our nation’s economic life, a work essentially fragmen¬ tary in character, the fragments pieced and fitted together into, I hope, a not inharmonious whole. Under the circumstances it is not strange that a kind of incompleteness should be apparent here and there. To sim¬ plify what is essentially mixed and complicated; to devise a simple solution for a hundred intricate problems; to shape a definite plan out of a confusion of cross purposes; to make a single consistent garment out of multi-colored patches; to weave a myriad tangled threads into gorgeous vestiture for naked Truth; to build a habitable house out of rotten timbers;—these are the things that I have attempted to do in this book—and beside which the mani¬ fold labors of Hercules were as a series of playful diversions. While I have been at work on this volume during two whole years, every line was written after a full day’s work at other tasks had already been performed—written during the few free days and leisure hours and spare moments; on Saturday afternoons and Sundays and holidays, and nearly every day from after dinner until midnight, and beyond. Already tired and wearied from the regular day’s work, I often drove myself to the task I had set for myself. As I look back today I wonder how I did it without breaking down; and I do not hesitate to say that I should not care to repeat the performance. I purposely avoided moralizing, and reduced to a min¬ imum a strong natural tendency to philosophize. Nor did I make any attempt at fine writing, for Literature and Sta¬ tistics are incompatible, or at least contradictory terms. With almost rude violence I suppressed every inclination to indulge in flights of rhetoric, nor did I allow myself to engage in discursive dissertation merely for the sake of verbal pyrotechnics, preferring to sacrifice style for truth, form for substance, and picturesqueness for the one end in view—to make what I was writing comprehensible and in¬ teresting to the average man and woman. 488 The New Capitalism Statistics! Oh, yes! there are statistics! But remem¬ bering my own aversion to them long ago I used them spar¬ ingly, and only to whatever extent was necessary to illus¬ trate a point, establish a fact, demonstrate a principle, or justify a conclusion. For the same reason I have introduced a few statistical computations of my own. I shall not be surprised if my temerity in this regard will be met by gibes and jeers; and that I will be duly written down as an eco¬ nomic heretic or charlatan. Of one thing you may be sure, that those who will protest the loudest against any inde¬ pendent computations are the very ones who have for years, without so much as a whisper of objection, swallowed all the false, garbled and misleading statements and statistics, and upon which they have slyly built their arguments, or their fortunes. Those who do not find a single thing to criticise in the Capitalistic System will find much to con¬ demn in my book, and absolutely no virtue in my plan. I did not bother much about pretty terms for my plan; just ordinary words sufficed. I speak of the New Order in contradistinction to the old, or ‘ ‘ established, * f order, which is composed of a comparatively small number—a decided minority; whereas the majority is to be the constituency of the New Order. Through the potency of the New Order there is to come into existence the New Capitalism—as dif¬ ferent from the old or established Capitalism as night from day. The plan in its entirety I shall not object to become known as the Baldus Plan. The system of economics that can be developed out of it, might not inappropriately be called the Baldusian System, around the principles of which a truly Economic Commonwealth can be made to arise. I fully realize that I have fallen far short of a supreme human achievement, yes, even of my own expectations; nevertheless, there are a few things I want to say on behalf of my book and myself. In the first place, the writing of ‘‘The New Capitalism ’’ was primarily a labor of love, and as such I give it to the world. At the same time I have no delusions. I have lived too long to expect either gratitude or appreciation; and I have read enough of history to know that mankind rewards A Postscript 489 its servitors with persecution, while society crucifies its saviors. My second claim is that throughout the writing I have adhered steadfastly to the fundamentals. I may be in error with regard to some minor points entering into my theme, but as regards the fundamentals, I stand pat, and will not compromise. In defense of the fundamentals I’ll take, if need be, my solitary stand against the world. I say this in spite of the existence of that most pitiful and numerous breed of creatures, who in the conceit of their ignorance sweep aside principles that do not comport with their selfish notions—those intellectual and moral pigmies who would deny the proposition that ‘‘man is a biped” for the reason that they actually know a man who has only one leg, or no legs at all. But my chief and proudest claim is that I have been in earnest, and I hope I have succeeded in being fair. If there is an occasional vehement word, or a stentorian sentence, construe it as emphasis rather than vindictiveness, for I carry no malice against any man; nor is there in me bitter¬ ness against any human institution. I have the satisfying consciousness of knowing that from the beginning of this work to its completion this day, my intention has been sincere. To the many millions then—to those who are not a com¬ ponent part of the Capitalistic System, and never will be, I have this to say. On July 4, 1776—one hundred and forty-six years ago today, the Founders of our Republic declared their political Independence to the world. In that same year, Adam Smith published his famous book “The Wealth of Nations” (called by some “The Bible of Eco¬ nomics”) the principles and tenets of which have gone far towards holding the nations of the earth, including our own, in economic bondage and subjection. “The New Capitalism” is, as it were, your Declaration of Economic Independence. I have written and signed it; I can do no more. S. A. Baldus. July 4 , 1922. ■ • • . ' ' V , 1 ; \m ♦ \ / ' / Date Due DEC rW l) 3 jqh'2'^ X ( 5» ■, f 0£C3i 51 yy os'T <* OPi i <** •■" ' ■ " 5 "p 155 ' ) * ■** . \ mA [ ; | <* ✓ BOSTON COLLEGE LIBRARY UNIVERSITY HEIGHTS CHESTNUT HILL, MASS. Books may be kept for two weeks and may be renewed for the same period, unless reserved. Two cents a day is charged for each book kept overtime. If you cannot find wh.it you want, ask the Librarian who will be glad to help you. The borrower is responsible for books drawn on his card and for all fines accruing on the same.