/<7/^3.-3--S LIBRARY OF THE THEOLOGICAL SEMINARY PRINCETON. N. J. Presented by Hoe Widow o ■f G-eoroe Dwabin^k BL 60 .H55 1894 Hill, David J. The social influence of Christianity PRIVATE LIBRARY OF II. NEVIfl KERST, No. The Social Influence of Christianity With Special Reference to Contemporary Problems. BY DAVID J. 'HILL, LL.D., President of the University of Rochester. THE NEWTON LECTURES FOR 1887. Let him that stole steal no more : but rather let him labor, working ivilh his hands the thing which is good, that he may have to give to him that needeth. — Saint Paul. BOSTON : SILVER, BURDETT & COMPANY, 110-112 Boylston Street. 1894. Copyright, 1888, By Silver, Burdett & Co. TO CATHARINE J. PACKER, THIS VOLUME IS LOVINGLY DEDICATED. PREFACE. This volume consists of eight lectures delivered before the Newton Theological Institution, in May, 1887, at the invita- tion of the president and faculty, and through the liberality of the Hon. J. W. Merrill. The lectures are now published at the request of the president, faculty, and students, and consti- tute the second published volume of "Newton Lectures, 11 the first being "The Hebrew Feasts, 11 by Professor William Henry Green, d.d., ll.d., of Princeton Theological Seminary. The lecturer was permitted to supplement his general prep- aration as a teacher of political economy and sociology during the past ten years, by six months of travel and observation in the principal countries of central and southern Europe with these lectures constantly in view, and by six months of spe- cial reading in the literature collected before and during his journey. He desires to make public acknowledgment of the sustained interest shown by all who attended the course of lectures, and especially of the personal courtesy and hospitality of President Hovey and the members of the faculty during his pleasant visit at Newton. V- CONTENTS. I. What is Human Society? ... .... II. What has Christianity done for Society? III. Christianity and the Problems of Labor . . IV. Christianity and the Problems of Wealth . V. Christianity and the Problems of Marriage VI. Christianity and the Problems of Education VII. Christianity and the Problems of Legislation VIII. Christianity and the Problems of Repression PAGE 9 35 65 95 127 157 187 21 1 [For detailed analysis see page preceding the beginning of each lecture.] I. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? 1. Preliminary Questions. 2. The twofold View of the Sophists. I. THE NATURALISTIC CONCEPTION OF SOCIETY. i. Plato's Theory. 2. Aristotle's Theory. 3. Naturalistic Doctrines in Modern Times. (1) Montesquieu; (2) Condorcet ; (3) Kant ; (4) Quetelet; (5) Buckle. 4. Biological Sociology. (1) Spencer; (2) Schaeffle; (3) Espinas ; (4) Mul- ford. 5. Inadequacy of the Naturalistic Conception. II. THE IDEALISTIC CONCEPTION OF SOCIETY. 1 . Rousseau's Social Contract. 2. The Theocratic Conception. 3. The Kingdom of God. 4. Christian Society. 5. The Ideal in the Formation of Society. III. THE SYNTHESIS OF THE NATURAL AND THE IDEAL IN SOCIETY. 1. Society founded in Human Wants. 2. Society modified by Human Wills. 3. Society perfected through Ideals. 4. Answer to the question, What is human society? THE SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY ? i. An accurate conception of the nature of society- is an essential prerequisite to any valuable discussion of its problems. This conception may be obtained by resolving society into its elementary constituents and discovering the forces and laws by which these elements are united. Human society is composed of individual human beings, who may be considered as its atomic units. The process of analysis is very simple, but the forces of social synthesis and the laws of their action present materials of great com- plexity. Does the cause of association lie in the human individual, or docs it pertain to the environ- ment in which individuals are placed? Does it originate from conscious volition, or does it proceed from organic constitution ? Does it admit of volun- tary counteraction and resistance, or does it produce its results by necessity ? These are questions which must be answered before we can solve any social problem whatever ; for, if the will of man is not in IO SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. any sense the cause of society, it is difficult to imagine how it can transform, or even slightly modify, the social structure. These preliminary questions reduce themselves to one, which may be formulated thus : What is the relation of individuals to the social whole ; is it that of living parts united by natural laws into a greater organism, or is it that of voluntary members freely choosing their form of association ? More briefly still, Is society a natural organism, or is it a voluntary group formed by contract ? 2. We may trace from a great antiquity two dis- tinct and opposing conceptions created in answer to this question. The Greek Sophists, who raised nearly all the questions which men have since been trying to answer, divided the world into two parts : one ruled by the inflexible laws of nature, the other governed by the freewill of man. 1 They considered a part of our human laws as arbitrary or conven- tional ; others, as derived from the constitution of man, and hence the projection of inanimate nature, independent of volition and wholly unalterable. Upon this fundamental distinction have been erected two different theories of society, which we may des- ignate as the Naturalistic Theory and the Idealistic Theory. I. i. Although Plato is best known as an idealist, his social theory belongs to the naturalistic type. For 1 For this doctrine of the Sophists, see Plato's Laws, 889. The best translation is Jouett's. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? \ \ him society is a product of nature, a creature of instinct and environment. Organic need is the de- termining cause of social, as it is of animal, organi- zation. 2 The division of labor in the sphere of industrial production was fully understood by Plato, and its origin was referred to the diversity of natural powers and aptitudes. A state, he taught, is a liv- ing body, similar to an individual organism. Its different classes are like the various faculties of an individual being, and it is endowed with a soul — an emanation of the universal reason. Its growth and decay, its -diseases and its conflicts of function, are similar to those of a living man. But as nature is the creation of God, so also is society. As there is an ideal for the individual man, whose highest attain- ment is perfect virtue, so there is an ideal for the State, the perfect republic. This ideal Plato at- tempted to picture. It is a community in which the wise govern, in which virtue, as he conceived it, is universally cultivated by the union of the best and the elimination of the base, and yet involving the destruction of the family and its affections, the per- petuation of the militant spirit, and the laudation of a narrow nationalism. This most visionary of ideal- ists is still the most radical of realists. The members of the social body are wholly devoid of spontaneity. The realization of the ideal must come from God alone, whose agent is the wise man clothed with power. Little did Plato dream that this " wise man " 2 For Plato's ideas on the nature of society, see his Republic, translated by Jowett. 12 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. was hoped for and expected by the Hebrew people, the Deliverer and Messiah, who should bring to earth, not the narrow national supremacy desired by both Plato and the Hebrews, but the perfect king- dom for which the world was waiting. 2. Aristotle approaches the question of the nature of society with all of Plato's realism, but without his ideal tendencies. For Aristotle the State is the product of nature, and he proceeds to study it from a natural point of view. 3 He points out an impor- tant fact, that the individual cannot exist 'n isola- tion. He finds the social unit not in the individual, but in the pair, the family. But this unit is not an atom; it is composite; it is already an organism, a living molecule whose parts could not subsist alone. This is a fertile conception. It draws society within the boundaries of biology. Society is no longer a dead thing, but a living being. Since it is a living organism, it is subjected to the laws of birth and death, of growth and dissolution, which rule all life. Change is its essential condition. Every atte ipt, then, to impose upon it an immutable constiti ion must prove chimerical. Societies differ according to their times and according to their environments. No constitution can be adapted to all peoples. Again, no living being is composed of wholly simi- lar parts. Society ought to be composed of parts which are separated from one another by differences. This is why the family, Aristotle's social element, is 8 For Aristotle's philosophy of society, see his Politics, translated by Jowett. J WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? I 3 formed of heterogeneous constituents : man, woman, and children. That difference is the condition of their union. Here is not only diversity, but subordi- nation, gradation of power, a scale of authority ; the woman obeying the man, and the child the woman. In this rudimentary society is the beginning of gov- ernment. The father becomes the patriarch, the patriarch the king. Thus is developed the social organism. Nature ordains these differences, from them grows the equilibrium of the whole people ; and so society exists, not by convention and choice, but by inherent constitution and necessity. Each individual finds himself at birth a part of a social whole which neither he nor any other man has cre- ated. Without this preexisting environment he would not be what he is. He is, then, himself the creature of society rather than its creator. Its lan- guage, its traditions, its customs, its laws, combine to shape him and to determine his individuality. How fully this idea was accepted by the Greeks is evident from the value they put upon culture as essential to the making of a man, and also from their word lShottjs, which first meant a " private man," then a "clumsy fellow," and at last a "fool," an " idiot." We may summarize the whole doctrine of pagan antiquity as being in its final conclusions a naturalis- tic and organic theory of society. Without arriving at the definite biological conception that prevails in mod- ern sociology, Greek thought distinctly grasped the idea that society is created by forces outside of man 14 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. himself, yet operating through him as their necessary organ, thus producing not merely an aggregate but a living organism. 3. To follow in detail the history of social theories would certainly prove wearisome, and probably would efface the memory of the most important outlines by filling the mind with insignificant refinements. And yet we cannot do justice to the naturalistic school without a passing notice of the progress it has made. (1) In Montesquieu's epoch-making " Spirit of the Laws" we find the naturalistic conception prevailing. 4 He regards the organization of society as reposing less on human ideas than on instinctive impulsions — such as the sense of dependence on others, the need of aliments, the sexual attachment, and the sympathetic inclinations. Though the State is for the great French jurist the work of mind, its roots reach down into physical conditions out of which it is developed. The laws express this origin and are but the reflex of the natural environment. (2) Condorcet emphasized this tendency of thought by proposing that the methods of the physical sci- ences be applied also to moral and social phenomena. 5 He taught that human progress is subject to physical laws and capable of even mathematical treatment. To measure social phenomena in order to discover their laws ; to draw from the knowledge of their laws the foreknowledge of future phenomena ; to found 4 Montesquieu, Esprit des Lois, Iivre i, chapitre ii. Condorcet, Esquisse d'un Tableau historique des progres de l'Esprit Humain. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? I 5 upon that foreknowledge combinations and preven- tions which would secure the amelioration of the human race, — such was Condorcet's doctrine of the task and the power of social science. (3) Although Immanuel Kant made absolute free- dom the masterpiece of his metaphysics, he regarded the world of phenomena as ruled by invariable laws. In the marvelous harmonies of nature he discerned a secret conspiracy of forces which is, indeed, mechani- cal, but at the same time the expression of a superior will. Human actions were for him determined in great part by general laws of nature. He thought that, as " the laws of the variation of the atmosphere are constant, though no particular can be foreseen at a given point, and in the mass they occasion in a uniform manner and without interruption the growth of plants, the course of streams, and all the other occurrences of the natural economy," so the social phenomena — births and deaths, marriages and divorces — are subject to natural laws. 6 We may trace similar ideas in the writings of Fichte and Hegel, who gave them abundant illustration mingled with the vagaries of a fanciful subjectivism, and espe- cially in those of Herder, who first applied the prin- ciple of natural evolution to history and claimed for it the character of an exact science. (4) Very important additions were made to social science by the Belgian mathematician, Ouetelet, who by measurements and statistics sought to demon- strate the uniformity of social phenomena. His Kant, Allgemeine Naturgeschichte. I 6 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. methods are too technical for popular exposition, but he may be accorded the distinction of having raised statistics to the dignity of a science. His " Social Physics " is a memorable contribution to the science of man and of society. His tables show that acts of the most personal and apparently spontaneous nature are measurable by general rules. For example, the number of murders committed in France in six suc- cessive years, from 1826 to 1831 inclusive, shows a very slight variation ; and the proportion of the instruments of destruction employed is about the same from year to year. Thus, for five successive years the number of murders committed with a gun or pistol does not vary more than eight, the absolute numbers being 56, 64, 60, 61, and 57. Such observa- tions led Quetelet to maintain that "society encloses in itself the germ of the crimes that are committed. It is society itself, in a certain sense, that prepares them, and the criminal is only the instrument who executes them. The social state, then, supposes a certain order of crimes, which result as a necessary consequence from its organization." 7 I do not pause to criticize either the logic or the ethics of this rea- soning, but note it as a stage in the development of sociology. (5) Buckle has attempted the construction of a history of civilization on the assumption " that the moral actions of men are the product, not of their volition, but of their antecedents." Social progress, 7 Quetelet, Physique Sociale ; ou, Essai sur lc Developpement des Facultes de l'Homme. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? I J he says, is "the result of large and general causes which, working upon the aggregate of society, pro- duce certain consequences without regard to the volition of those particular men of whom the society is composed." 8 These "large and general causes" are "climate, food, soil, and the general aspect of nature." Here volition is absolutely excluded as a factor of progress. Quetelet explains social phe- nomena as produced through human volition, but Buckle takes the higher ground that human volition is wholly excluded from effecting social changes. He was clearly a more loyal determinist than he was a faithful observer. 4. It has been reserved for our age to erect a com- plete sociology upon a purely naturalistic basis, treat- ing society as a natural growth, a veritable organism in the strictest sense of the word, as little dependent upon human volition as any example in the animal series. (1) For Herbert Spencer, sociology is simply an extension of biology. 9 He has come upon societies long before arriving at man in the order of evolution. Every individual animal, he affirms, is a society, com- posed of living constituents. The individuality of an animal, far from excluding that of its component elements, supposes and requires it. Organic compo- sition is simply a union of living parts into more extended living wholes. Man is an individual only in 8 Buckle's History of Civilization in England. 9 Spencer's Illustrations of Universal Progress, essay on The Social Organism ; and Principles of Sociology. 1 8 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. a relative sense. He is really a society of smaller individuals. His unity is the result of their organi- zation. He is thus either identical with them or a result of their combination. When dissolution takes place he is no more. These constituents have been differentiated and specialized so that each class has its own function. Human society is to individual men what a single man is to the living cells of his body. It is more than an aggregate, it is a veritable organism. It is not formed by voluntary association any more than an animal body is, but by the uncon- scious grouping of individual men acting according to the laws of their nature. Human society is, therefore, simply an "episode of universal evolution," as necessary as a crystal and as little the work of will. (2) Spencer's principal difficulty in completing the analogy between society and an animal organ- ism is thus expressed by himself : " The parts of an animal form a concrete whole ; but the parts of a society form a whole that is discrete. While the living units composing the whole are bound together in close contact in the animal, the living units com- posing society are free, not in contact, and more or less widely dispersed." Spencer's attempts to explain away this disparity are not so successful as those of the German sociologist, Schaeffle, in his " Structure and Life of the Social Body." In that exhaustive work, the learned author shows that in everv animal organism there is an intercellular substance, which is not composed of the living cells, but acts as a means of separation and communication between them. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? 1 9 The discontinuity of the parts of the social body is not, therefore, a fatal objection to its being con- sidered as an organism, since this is quite in analogy with the structure of animal bodies. The roads, railways, and telegraphic lines of human society serve to bring its constituents into practical coherence, as the nerves of sensation do in the animal body. That these were a late development is quite in analogy with biological history, in which the formation of a nervous system marks an advanced stage of animal evolution. (3) The finishing touch to the naturalistic theory seems to have been given by the French zoologist, Espinas, who, in his " Animal Societies," discovers the necessity and the fact of association in the lowest orders of the animal creation, and supplies many data in tracing the evolution of human society from the rudimentary social life of the inferior animals. " No living being," says Espinas, " is alone. The animals in particular sustain numerous relations with the existences which surround them ; and, without speaking of those which live in permanent commerce with their kind, almost all are constrained by bio- logical necessities to contract, though it be for a brief period, an intimate union with some other individual of their species." 10 (4) Thus the lowest forms of life and human society are connected as products of natural forces operating under a law of evolution. Society is, then, the greatest of animals. But we are led a step 10 Espinas, Des Societes Animates. 20 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. beyond this. In his book on "The Nation," the \ late Dr, Mulford says : " The physical organism is determined in itself by a law of necessity, as the tree which cannot be other than it is ; the ethical organism is determined in a law of freedom, which is the condition of moral action. . . . The conditions of history presume the being of the nation as a moral organism. History is not a succession of separate events and actions, but a development in a moral order, and in the unity and continuity of a life which moves on unceasingly, as some river in its unbroken current. It is only as the nation is an organism that this unity and continuity is manifest in it, and as a moral organism that this moral order is confirmed in it." n Dr. Mulford then adds : "The nation is a moral personality." So it seems that a society is not simply a great animal, but a great person. All this may be very true, but I cannot resist the feeling that in some way we have passed out of the sphere of science into a cloudland of mythology, when the nation is endowed with person- ality. If we have shrunk from Auguste Comte's apotheosis of Humanity as the Supreme Being, how shall we treat this " moral person " to whom Dr. Mulford's speculative mind has introduced us ? How august and majestic this "moral person " must be, to whom we all stand in the relation of microscopic cells to a human body ! Has biology, then, a new religion ? But the moment I try to regain my own sense of personality, which seems swallowed up in this " moral 11 E. Mulford's The Nation, chap. i. WHAT IS HUMAN SOCIETY? 2 1 person," I find myself in trouble. I do not see how a person can be composed of other persons. He would be a congress, not a person. If a person can- not be composed of other persons, then this " moral person," which society is said to be, is either not a person at all, or else is a person apart from its con- stituents, individual men. In the latter case we have a new divinity who is a separate personal being, the soul of the nation. This brings us back to Plato. But if a person cannot be composed solely of other organisms, then I, as a person, am something apart from the constituent cells that form my body. I am a society plus personality. Now, admitting that society is an organism, that is, made up of other organisms, there is something in society that is not organism, the individual personalities that inhabit the constituent organisms themselves. Here we come upon a great truth. It is that the organic theory of society leaves out of account this element of person- ality that belongs to every human individual. As for Dr. Mulford's " moral person," that is but the creature of the power of abstraction. It is the personification, merely, of the social bond — ■ the mythologizing tendency that peopled the Pantheon with creatures of the fancy, alive in the nineteenth century and creating a national divinity. This " moral person" can nowhere be found, except in the individual men of the nation. But each of these men con- sciously knows in himself a personality that is neither the sum nor the product of his component parts. He is an organism plus a person. More precisely, he is a person in an organism. 2 2 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. (5) Admitting the truth of the naturalistic theory of society, as far as it goes, except the completeness of it, we seem to have missed some important factor. That factor is personality. However we may doubt the personality of Dr. Mulford's " moral person," we cannot doubt that we ourselves are persons. The question, then, is : What have persons contri- buted to the constitution of society, beyond what natural forces have contributed ? The naturalistic sociology is merely one of observation and induction. It can observe and report social facts. It cannot do more. It cannot explain progress, which is the one preeminently important social phenomenon. It can- not determine, by its purely physical methods, what ought to be, or that anything " ought to be. " It is utterly powerless to solve any social problem, because its fundamental postulate is that the will and intellect of man have no initiative power, either to create or transform society. As for social responsibility, there can be none for the naturalistic theory. All is determined by natural necessity, and, upon this assumption, " Whatever is, is right." — "I am a man ; nothing pertaining to man do I think foreign from me," — are contained in a comedy whose plot turns upon the survival of an infant daughter commanded to be exposed to death by the very man who uttered this sentence. 13 (2) The education of children was not neglected by antiquity, but it was by no means universal. The most careful education was found among the Hebrews. Greek education aimed at aesthetic cul- ture, but confined it entirely to the few, mostly excluding women and slaves, who made up most of the population. Roman education was likewise re- stricted and had no higher ideal than fitness for political citizenship. " The education of paganism," 13 See the Heauton-timorumenos of Terence. The line " Homo sum ; humani nihil a me alienum puto," according to Augustine, moved the whole audience — though many of the spectators were rude and ignorant— to thunders of applause. WHAT HAS CHRISTIANITY DONE? 55 says an able historian of education, "was imperfect. It was controlled by wrong principles and confined within too narrow limits. It did not grasp the worth of the individual in its fullness. It never freed itself from the narrowness of national character. . . . But with the advent of Christ into the world, there came a new era in history." M Dr. William T. Harris, speaking of this subject, says: "The influence of such an idea as that of the divine-human God conde- scending; to assume the sorrows and trials of mortal life, all for the sake of the elevation of individual souls, the humblest and weakest as well as the mightiest and most exalted, is potent to transform civilization." 15 Henceforth, the life of a child is valued as a precious treasure, and the shaping of its destiny is the noblest work of man. (3) The Roman Empire enjoyed an organized sys- tem of public schools, founded by the emperors, and endowed by such statesmen as Hadrian, Marcus Aurelius, Vespasian, and Theodosius. They ex- tended throughout all the cities of the empire. The early Christians availed themselves of them ; but as they were intended to impart an education whose end was the State, and as their studies consisted mainly in the reading of pagan authors, schools of catechu- mens were founded to prepare candidates for bap- tism. With the invasion of the Franks, the imperial schools were closed. After an interval during which there seems to have been little but domestic instruc- 14 F. V. N. Painter's History of Education, chap. iii. 15 See the preface to the work last cited. 56 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. tion, the Church instituted an educational revival. The Church councils from the sixth century on to the time of Charlemagne repeatedly urge the estab- lishment of parish and monastic schools, which seem to have been opened in great numbers. The palace- school of Charlemagne in which the great Alcuin taught, and others founded under his direction, are well known in history. The foundations of the great universities were at length laid by the Church. The imperfection of all these educational efforts we can- not fail to recognize, but we must not forget the world's indebtedness to them. Christianity, as such, has never antagonized learning, but has proved its most faithful guardian. Besides the conservation of such knowledge as the ancient world possessed, Christianity has contributed an element wholly new in the training of the young. It has impressed upon men the value of the individual and striven to secure his perfection of himself by the development of character and the pursuit of moral ideals. It has also trained the human mind to habits of introspec- tion and self-analysis that lie at the basis of all true philosophy and without which the scientific spirit itself would possess neither form nor impulse. 5. The moral and intellectual changes of a people soon show themselves in legislation. Even under the pagan emperors, Christianity began its amelio- rating and elevating influence upon the laws. The subject presents too many details for our narrow limits, but deserves a special study in such works as " Gesta Christi," by Charles Loring Brace, and " The WHAT HAS CHRISTIANITY DONE'/ 57 Social Results of Early Christianity," by Professor Schmidt, of Strasburg, with their extensive refer- ences to authorities. I can simply enumerate a few of the most significant of these moral victories in the field of legislation. (i) The earliest and most important effect was upon personal status. Constantine removed the paternal power of life and death and rendered the killing of a child a crime equal to parricide. He also extended the son's rights of property. Julian forbade immoderate penalties to be inflicted upon children. Daughters were endowed with heirship. Divorce was restricted to a few causes, as when a husband is a murderer, a magician, or a violator of tombs, or the wife an adulteress or guilty of evil prac- tices. Civil equality was established between hus- band and wife, and adultery was punished with death. Chastity was required by the laws of Justinian, though he weakened again the legislation on divorce. The unnatural vices so frequent in antiquity that Cicero said it was a disgrace not to indulge in them, vices unnamed and unknown in the modern Christian world, were severely punished under Theodosius. Numerous ameliorations were introduced into the life of the slave. To poison or throw him to wild beasts was made homicide. Liberty was declared inalienable, so that no free child could become a slave. The marriage relation between slaves was regarded as indissoluble by separation. Every facility for liberating slaves became the policy of the law. Under Basil (S67) the slaves of a master whose 58 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. property reverted to the State became free ; for so ran the law : " It would be an outrage to the holiness of God, to the wisdom of the prince, and to the conscience of man, not to permit the death of the master to break the yoke of servitude." 16 (2) The laws relating to personal conduct were equally revolutionized. The stranger, who had always been considered an enemy by the German tribes be- fore their conversion, the wrecked at sea, who had been regarded as legitimate prey, and whose vessels were sometimes lured to destruction upon the rocks for the sake of booty, were brought within the protection of justice. Private feuds, which had raged from gen- eration to generation, requiring the avenging of blood by a member of the family, were commuted by payments of money or adjusted by judicial tribunals. " The Peace of God " waved the white flag of truce over bloody battlefields and called the combatants to the silent hush of prayer. Earlier than this the horrible conflicts of the gladiators had been brought to a termination. Honorius vainly tried to stop these inhuman shows by the degradation of the gladiatorial profession. At last (404) an eastern monk, Telemachus, crossed the seas, and at Rome threw himself into the arena between the swords of the contestants. The fury of the crowd demanded his immediate death, but his blood was the last that flowed from human veins in that Flavian amphithea- i« A very discriminating and compendious estimate of the influence of Christianity upon Roman legislation may be found in Morey's Outlines of Roman Law, period iv, chap. ii. WHAT HAS CHRISTIANITY DONE? 59 tre, whose silent, crumbling walls stand as a monu- ment to this fearless martyr. An imperial edict suppressed this cruel sport forever. 17 6. We can barely mention the amelioration of punishment that Christianity has introduced. " No classic legislator, so far as we can recall," says Brace, "had ever cared for that unfortunate class — the prisoners." Prison reform began under Constantine. The accused were to be examined without delay, they were to be treated in a humane manner, persons under arrest were not to be tortured, and prisons were required to have air and light. Paul's confine- ment in that gloomy, subterranean Mamertine prison at Rome may have been, in part, in its results, vica- rious suffering for the accused of the future. In all of this was that exalted view of man which Christ had taught, and God's image was not to be marred. " Let those who are condemned t " reads a sentence of Constantine's, " not be branded on the forehead, that the majesty of the face formed in the image of celestial beauty be not dishonored." 18 But the glory of Christianity is not shown in prison reform, ancient or modern, though it is great, so much as in the changed theory of all punitive treatment. The re- form and salvation of the criminal are aims exclu- sively Christian in their origin. If the sentiment of our age has adopted them as its ideals in punish- ment, it is because of that latent and unconscious Christianity that is working like leaven in the hearts 17 Theodoret, Historia Ecclesiastica, v, 26. 18 Codex Theodosii, liber xv, title 8, 1. 60 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. of men, even while their lips are framing a denial of its presence. We cannot linger longer to recount what Chris- tianity has done for society. If any think that much of our social progress can be attributed to other causes, a survey of the non-Christian world will dis- pel that illusion. Wherever Christian influence has not penetrated, the pre-Christian social conditions still exist. Something depends upon natural temper- ament, indeed, in the reformation of racial character- istics, and few vices or defects of social life are universal. But nowhere is there a true conception of human worth and dignity, where Christ's teach- ings have not been felt. A contempt for labor, with its accompaniment of human servitude ; the regard of caste and class-distinctions, with violent contrasts of wealth and poverty unmodified by pity and charity ; the degradation of woman and disregard of personal chastity ; the indifference to children and their continuance in ignorance and vice ; the in- equality of legislation and the dominion of personal hate and cruel revenge, — these are the social phe- nomena with which we expect to meet whenever we overstep the boundaries of Christian lands and enter the regions where the life and doctrines of Jesus are unknown. That his power is not greater than it is among ourselves is testimony to the magnitude of the work his teaching has accomplished in the world ; for it has met with the same and even greater obstacles, and yet it has triumphantly surmounted them in its WHAT HAS CHRISTIANITY DONE? 6 1 steady but not unimpeded progress. When we con- sider how, in these centuries, it has changed the life and institutions of society; how it has given labor a rehabilitation, consecrated wealth to human benefit, honored and ennobled woman, crowned the head of childhood with the coronet of love and knowledge, swept away traces of barbarism from the codes of law and tempered them with justice and mercy, let sunlight and hope into the cells of the prison and broken the fetters of the slave, — may we not look for its solution of the passing problems of the pres- ent, for its Author has said : " Lo, I am with you alway, even unto the end oi the world"? III. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF LABOR. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF LABOR. I. THE EVOLUTION OF INDUSTRY, i. Eras of Industrial Progress: (i) The Era of Hunting; (2) The Era of Cattle Raising ; (3) The Era of Agriculture ; (4) The Era of the Mechanic Arts. 2. The Correlation of Wants and Wealth. 3. The Causes of Wealth and Labor. 4. Progressive and Improgressive Labor. 5 . The Division of Labor. 6. The Invention of Machinery. II. THE CONTEMPORARY PROBLEMS OF LABOR. 1. The Problem of Increasing Wealth. (1) Is the Increase of Wealth Desirable? (2) Wealth but a Means to Life as an End. (3) The Increase of the Laborer's Productivity. (4) The Avoidance of Waste. 2. The Problem of the Laborer's Rights. (1) The Foundation of Human Rights. (2) The Right to Self and One's Powers. (3) The Right to the Product of One's Powers. (4) Wealth as a Social Product. (5) The Ground of Taxation. (6) The Right of Property. (7) The Right of Property in Land. (8) The Universal Stewardship. III. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF LABOR. I. i. The first problem of society is that of subsist- ence, or the production of those commodities that contribute to life. The first cry of every human being is the bitter wail of hunger. But, as for each individual added to our race provision is made, with- out his own exertion, for the satisfaction of his earli- est needs, so also it was in the infancy of humanity for the first wants of our species. Originating, prob- ably, in some fertile and temperate region of south- ern Asia, the first men were able to satisfy their hunger with the spontaneous fruits of the generous earth, and a genial sky rendered superfluous both clothing and habitations. I know not how great pro- gress in the tilling of the earth the biblical narrative intends to ascribe to the Adam of Genesis, but its own subsequent account of the origin of metallurgy justifies oiiv belief that the Edenic implements were of a very pt imitive character. (i) In the course of the migration and dispersion of men, in which the command to " multiply and replenish the earth " was executed, impinging of the population upon the food-supply, as well as the rigors 66 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. of more severe climates, involved the use of the flesh of animals for food and of their skins for cloth- ing, while caves in the earth, natural or artificial, afforded the protection of dwellings. Thus men found themselves existing in the era of hunting. (2) The perception of the waste involved and the uncertainty of a sufficient supply, when animals were killed at random in a wild state, must early have sug- gested their domestication, and we may picture to ourselves the patriarchal family with its flocks and herds roaming over the pasture-lands, subsisting prin- cipally upon the fatlings of the flocks and dwelling in the movable tents adapted to the nomadic life of the era of cattle-raising. (3) Again, the physical requirements of the growth of population, coupled with contentions arising con- cerning the occupation of the soil, like that reported between Abraham and Lot, ultimately introduced the permanent demarkation of the land into separate holdings, and the establishment of villages for resi- dence. This necessitated the cultivation of the more limited apportionment of the soil, in order to produce by art what was not afforded by nature, and thus began the agricultural era. (4) Finally, the exigencies of defence against the encroachment of hostile neighbors, together with the demand for agricultural implements, required the equipment of armies, the erection of walled towns for refuge, the construction of engines of war and the working of metals, with its attendant division of labor and organization of military, civil, and political CHRISTIANITY AND TAB OR. 6 J institutions, which characterize the era of mechanic arts. The arts thus rendered necessary, after re- maining for centuries subsidiary to the ends which first called them into being, have at last been brought to minister directly and chiefly to the desires of the people ; the militant spirit has become secondary to the industrial, and the principal trait of contempo- rary society is the industrialism that creates its enor- mous wealth and whose interests evoke its highest solicitude. 2. Civilization begins in man's needs and is meant to afford him satisfaction. He is never quite satis- fied, and yet he is not of necessity unhappy in any stage of his industrial progress. The growth of his wants is correlated to the increase of his wealth. The sight of wealth produces new wants. The Paci- fic Islanders are not dissatisfied with life. Contact with civilized men, however, often generates in them new desires and material civilization moves along this line of new wants created by the desire of new wealth. It is universally conceded that men were never in the history of the world so well supplied with com- modities of every kind as they are to-day. The fact is capable of statistical proof, but it is too apparent to require the time and trouble. 1 The cause of the present industrial discontent is the confrontation of wealth and poverty, with its startling contrast of i For the statistical proof of this statement see Giffen's Progress of the Working Classes, pp. 5, 26; Stebbin's Progress from Poverty, pp. 7, 9, and PP- 3°. 33 '■ ar >d Mulhall's History of Prices, pp. 130, 133. 68 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. luxury on the one side and misery on the other. Men who work as common laborers to-day enjoy more of the physical comforts of life than the men and women who landed on Plymouth' Rock. They are not so happy or so contented, and the reason is that they think they have not their fair proportion of wealth. 3. The ultimate cause of wealth is labor, in its wide sense of human activity for the satisfaction of wants. This is an economic commonplace. But the economists seldom discuss the question, What is the cause of labor ? Mallock says it is the desire for social inequality. 2 This is a true but not a com- plete answer. Men labor primarily to sustain exist- ence. When they have the means of doing this, they cease from labor, unless they have an additional impulse. They have this in the desire of social inequality. They see others enjoying more than themselves. They desire to rise into the superior class. This desire renders them industrious and economical. By more exertion and less immediate indulgence they hope to arrive at a superior condition. Progress has followed this line. It results in the acquisition of commodities and possessions that elevate one's estate. Such accumulations are " cap- ital," because they are not only the products of the "head" (caput), but constitute a "head," or source, of further advantage. 4. If we ask in what manner capital is produced, we find that it is not simply the product of labor, but * Mallock's Social Equality, chap. iv. CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 69 of a particular kind of labor. There is labor which is wholly improgressive, whose whole result is neces- sary for the subsistence of the worker. A man who employs the whole day hunting his dinner with a bow and arrow in the forest never acquires any capital. He consumes the product of his day's labor and in the morning must resume his hunting. But there is another kind of labor. It is progressive. The man who invents a trap may catch every day what will last for two days. He may give away the subsist- ence of one day to another man who is willing to use the time for his service. All capital is the result of this kind of labor. It requires some skill. The more skilful it is, the more capital it will produce. A man with a very fertile brain devises ways to obtain in one day the food for many days. This gives him command over as many men who are capable only of "improgressive labor as he can feed. They would as soon serve him as to hunt food. If he assures them subsistence in advance and with certainty, they will probably prefer the certainty of subsistence from him to the uncertainty of subsistence without him. His knowledge and enterprise make him a master. Looking back over human history we are compelled to refer all industrial progress and all increase of wealth to such enterprise and knowledge. Civil- ization has been rendered possible through the improvement of men. Universal ignorance gives us savagery, idleness, and famine. Intelligent chiefs give us barbarism, slavery, and poverty. An edu- cated class gives us civilization, free labor, and plenty. JO SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. Educated masses give us enlightenment, organized labor, and abundance. Universal education will give us refinement, intellectualized labor, and wealth. If we examine these superimposed planes of social exist- ence we shall see that the elevation of man has in- creased wealth ; that the ascent of man has produced the multiplication of his possessions ; that a condition of ignorance is a state in which the mind values tilings only, and that a condition of universal education is a state in which the chief value is placed on man. I infer, therefore, that the influence that has done most to emphasize the value of man and afford an elevated conception of his nature, is the influence that has clone most to create the wealth of the world. That influence, we have already seen, is the influ- ence of Jesus. I take it to be a principal cause of the world's wealth. The conclusion is justified by the fact that the wealthiest nations of the earth are the Christian nations. This leads me to think that Christianity has an important relation to the prob- lems of labor. 5. A principal cause of wealth is the division of labor. It is based on the variation of aptitude and ability to accomplish results and the apportionment of tasks to those adapted to them. Its beginnings are too remote for discovery, but we may readily imagine them in the first human family. Man would natu- rally undertake the heavier and more active work of securing food. Woman would assume the lighter task of its preparation, in conjunction with the maternal care of children. But our knowledge of CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. J I savage life does not warrant this natural assumption. Among the savage peoples we invariably find the whole burden of labor thrown upon woman, the least qualified to bear it, while man spends his days in idle enjoyment. When the plane of existence is reached where more labor is necessary, in order to supply a greater number of wants, we find that those who labor are again not the strongest, but the weakest, the slaves, whose inferior powers render them the more easily reduced to subjection. If we examine history, so far as it throws light upon the subject, we discover everywhere the same abnormal phenomenon — the strong idle, and the weak com- pelled to labor. The only exception is met when we reach those times and those lands where the influence of Christ has been felt. There we find labor accounted honorable, woman more generally released from the burdens of toil, slaves progress- ively liberated from servitude, and strong, free men voluntarily joining in the "rehabilitation of labor." But compulsory labor is the least progressive and the least enterprising kind. All truly progressive labor is free. Accordingly, we find the lands and times that have endured the curse of slavery suffering also from the curse of poverty. From this, also, I infer that the influence of Jesus is a vital element in the labor and industrial life of the world. 6. Another factor in the production of wealth is the improvement of tools, the invention of machines, and the application of natural forces to production or invention. It creates at one stroke a power that 72 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. is equivalent to a thousand men. It extends the emancipation of the slave by freeing men from the slavery of muscular toil. It multiplies the commod- ities of life until those that in former clays were the luxuries of the few become the universal posses- sions of the people. This is the result of progressive, not at all of itnprogressive, labor. It gives to every one, who has anything to buy with, an unearned increment for his money too great for estimation. We read of the "unearned increment of land" and of the " unearned increment of capital." There is also an immense "unearned increment of labor." I do not say that all the inventions of our modern era were conceived with the sole purpose of lighten- ing the burdens of men, but it is an incontestable fact that thousands of them have originated from the desire that a difficult an:l wearisome work might be made easier. It can, however, be justly main- tained that inventions would be wholly without motive of any kind under conditions of slavery. The master has never cared to apply his intelligence for lightening the burden of slaves, and the slave could not thus lighten his burden. The psychology of progress explains the history of progress. If non- Christian lands have produced no labor-saving machinery, it is because oppression did not care, and servitude had not the power, to lighten human toil. For this reason, again, I affirm that the influ- ence of Jesus is the life of industry. CHRISTIANITY AND TAB OR. 73 II. There are two contemporary problems of labor that deserve our consideration. They are the prob- lem of increasing wealth and the problem of the laborer's rights. 1. Is it desirable to continue the increase of wealth and how can it be increased, if desirable ? (1) The acquisitive faculty in man does not hesitate to answer the first part of this double question in the affirmative. Yes, wealth is good, men generally respond. And what has Christianity to say ? Is it possible that Christianity can be a principal cause in the production of wealth, as we have shown it to be, and at the same time censure that increase ? Un- doubtedly Christ rebukes rich men for their greed; and reminds them that material wealth is not the highest good, but does he anywhere condemn the multiplication of commodities to be used for the well- being of man ? I have failed to find in his doctrines any such condemnation. On the contrary, it is everywhere assumed by him that material goods are really good. Lazarus was in pitiable lack of them, and Dives had the full enjoyment of them, and Christ recognizes the fact that the condition of Dives was a more desirable condition than that of Lazarus, apart from the moral qualities and relations of the two men. The shame of the contrast was that Laza- ius lacked while Dives was without compassion. If one may be "diligent in business," and at the same time "serving the Lord," the fruits of diligence cannot 74 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. be morally undesirable. It is impossible for men to develop their higher powers, to find opportunity for self-improvement, to realize the conditions of health and beneficence, without the possession of some measure of wealth. Wealth, then, is good, its increase is desirable, from a Christian point of view. (2) But there is an important limitation of this truth. Wealth is a means, not an end. The whole truth is expressed in the words of Christ : " A man's life consisteth not in the abundance of the things that he possesseth." The really wealthy man is not the man who has most, but the man who can use most, who can make things most subsidiary to his life, who most completely realizes his own and other's weal. Christ enlarges, ennobles, and transfigures the con- ception of wealth. The lower conception excludes all that is noblest, by excluding all that is really human. Possession is a graded and an evanescent power. The barn-builder of Christ's parable never completed his granaries. No matter what material transformation it undergoes, wealth can never be preserved unless it contributes to life. The sooner it does so the better. Not necessarily to be immediately consumed, but to be made the instrument of life. A workshop or a library enters into life, if it be rightly placed, but a pile of unused gold is no better than a pile of unused stones. It may be riches, but it is not wealth. But neither is the workshop or the library wealth, unless skilful hands or active minds come into relation with them. There is the ring of Christ's own truth in Ruskin's words : " There is no wealth but life ; life, CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 75 with its powers of love, of joy, of admiration. That country is the richest which nourishes the greatest number of noble and happy human beings ; that man is richest who, having perfected the functions of his own life to the utmost, has also the widest helpful influence, both personal and by means of his posses- sions, over the lives of others." 3 (3) The increase of wealth is best realized by whatever increases the productivity of the laborer. Whatever lifts a man out of the sphere of improgress- ive labor and places him 'on the plane of progressive labor, increases wealth. It does it directly by enlarg- ing his life, and indirectly by making him a creator of wealth. This idea is entering into the minds of business men as they ponder over these problems of labor. Says a recent writer on this subject, after a survey of the history of industry : " Labor must be treated at least as well as any other source of power. A steam-engine is well housed, well fed with fuel, well oiled, and well governed by a competent engi- neer. For its economic use, it must work smoothly and continuously. We must supply it with all that its material constitution requires. The economic use of the horse demands that he be well fed, well housed, and well treated. We must supply him with all that his physical nature demands for its healthy working. In like manner, the economic use of the man requires that all the conditions of his wellbeing shall be respected. His physical nature must be supported by good food, clean and comfortable hous- 3 Ruskin's Unto This Last, Essay iv, Ad Valorem. 76 OCTAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. ing, and all other good sanitary conditions ; but he has an intellectual being as well ; its health must be provided for by education, by the literature, at least, of his business ; for he is a moral power, sensitive to right and wrong. He must be influenced to right and withdrawn from wrong, or you will have a destroyer, not a worker. But is the economic ground the only one on which this equitable treatment of the laborer is necessary ? Nay, this man is your brother." 4 I know a village in Pennsylvania, owned by a family of Christian men, where all these princi- ples, and even more extended applications of them than is here suggested, have been in practice for years. The neat houses with their pretty gardens and flowers in the windows, with instruments of music in the spare-rooms, the neat schoolhouse and commodious church, have been built for the workmen upon a model plan. During a period when other fac- tories of like kind were almost universally closed on account of low prices, this community went steadily on with its manufacture. No man left work on account of lowered wages, no time was lost, and at the end the goods were ready for the high market for which they had been reserved. Experience has in that establishment added its evidence to faith, that care for the workman brings its own reward. I need not add that the proprietors are Christian men and believe that Christian principles have relation to industrial problems. 4 The Labor Problem, edited by W. E. Barnes, chap, ii, by J. A. Water- worth. CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. J J (4) Another element in the increase of wealth is the avoidance of waste. This opens a broad subject. It is impossible to treat it exhaustively. There is, first of all, the waste of war and its accessories. It is probably true that standing armies and navies are necessary in the present political condition of the world, and that the most certain way to preserve peace is to have well-trained soldiers and officers and implements of destruction so terrific that the mere thought of their destructiveness is sufficient to pre- vent their actual employment. But, at the same time, the cost of sustaining a nation on a war-footing is so enormous that it is a serious drainage on indus- try. First, vast numbers of men are abstracted from the ranks of labor to serve as soldiers and officers, and then, besides their support, the preparation of costly munitions of war is required of those who are left for actual production. Within the last thirty years the debts of the governments of Europe have increased nine billions of dollars. This is owing to four great wars which have had no connection with the rights or progress of man, but have been waged to maintain the "balance of power." The present aggregate debts are twenty billions. The armies and navies and interest on debts absorb fourteen hundred millions annually, of which only a fraction is neces- sary. The combined cost of civil service and educa- tion is about one fourth of the cost of this luxury of the" balance of power." This superfluity is an ex- action of twenty-seven dollars from each laborer and of forty-five dollars from each family of five. In Italy J 8 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. it abstracts fifty dollars, in England sixty-two dol- lars, and in France sixty-five dollars from each family. It is a cruel wrong. Christianity applied to practice would have saved it. It would have settled the wars by arbitration and capitalized their cost as public wealth. The United States presents the picture of a federation of commonwealths with greater territo- rial extent than that of Europe, without standing armies, and with a navy that is a mere jest. The civil war cost more than the purchase of the slaves would have required, to take no account of blood and suffering. The settlement of our claim against England by Christian methods is one of the triumphs of human history. Christianity would carry the same method into industrial warfare, the perpetual struggle that at once embitters and demoralizes men and impedes the creation of wealth. It declares that industry is not, in its ideal, a selfish struggle for existence, a desperate battle of landlord and tenant, of employer and employed, a conflict of interests that forever clash and tend to annihilate one another. It indicates how this problem of wealth-creation can be solved and the only method of solution. It says to arrogant landlordism, your true interest lies in having happy and prosperous tenants ; to envious labor, your hope rests in a universal progress led by enterprise and sustained by capital ; to mercenary capital, your security and permanence depend upon the activity of labor and the pacific participation of all in its rewards ; to avaricious enterprise, your dreams of fortune can become realities only when CHRISTIANITY AND TAB OR. Jg large classes of men are able to enjoy your products. Therefore, cease the strife which, however it may end, must eventuate in some one's overthrow, and the emergence from the smoke of desolation of the more pathetic question, What shall society do with the vanquished ? 2. Perhaps a deeper problem, and one more difficult to solve than that of increasing wealth, is the problem of the laborer's rights, (i) I say the "/adorer's rights," because there are no "rights of labor." Rights belong only to persons, to men as moral beings. And whatever " rights " the laborer has, he has in virtue of his manhood, not in virtue of his labor. It is difficult to escape class distinctions and the idea of class privileges. Rights do not be- long to classes, but to men. What is it in a man that entitles him to rights ? It is the capacity for duty. He is a being whose nature has ends ; it is his duty to realize those ends, and he is morally free to realize them. Suppose he does not. Then he does not realize his manhood. Manhood is not a mechani- cal product of nature. Nature furnishes capacities and faculties, but manhood is the self-determined product of the man himself. To realize manhood, one must be free. The essence of personality is freedom. Rights inhere in personality, because it is free, because it has duties, because it has an end to realize. This cannot be said of any creature lower than man. Such a creature is not an end, but a means. Its purpose of being is not realized in itself. Man is lord over the lower creatures ; bound, no 80 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. doubt, to exercise his lordship in a truly lordly way, in a way comporting with his rational nature and not like a brute, but still possessed of dominion. The animal world exists for him, is for his service, and finds its end in him, not in itself. Man, too, is under the dominion of a Superior, but his end is to become like him, to realize in his own person the spiritual excellence of God. (2) If rights inhere in a man, what rights has he ? The right to realize himself, to attain the ends of his being. This is, with relation to himself, his duty. With relation to others, it is his right. He has a right, therefore, to himself and to the unrestricted exercise of his natural powers. He cannot rightly be enslaved. To enslave him is to disregard this right and to render impossible this duty. If it should be said that another man or a society of men has a right to a man, on what ground could this right be defended ? On what basis would they rest their right ? They might, indeed, claim or possess the power, but they could not vindicate the right. To deny the right of a person to himself and to the exercise of all his natural powers, is to deny all right and to appeal to force. But this is the right of each man, and so of all equally. The only limitation arises when the activities of one interfere with the rights of another. It is in determining this margin of rights that the problem really consists. (3) If a man has a right to himself and to the exercise of his powers, he has a right to the product of his powers ; for otherwise he would be unable to CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 8 1 realize his primary right. His life cannot be a mere passive existence. To realize his manhood, he must have food, tools, and, in certain climates, clothing and shelter. He does not find these prepared by- nature. He has a right to produce them. His right is not identical with the right to a living. It is the right to produce a living. It entitles him to what he produces, but no more. If he take another man's food, under the pretext that " society owes him a living," he makes three false assumptions : First, that any one owes him a living ; second, that society owes this debt, and third, that this man, whose food he takes, is the representative of the society that owes him. The right to produce a living is not a debt at all. Society cannot be held to its payment. Worst of all, another's right to the product of his powers is invaded, if the food be taken. The duty of each man is to respect the right of every other man. The duty of society is to protect each man in this right. The question of a right to a living is one dependent upon several circumstances. If there is food available for ten, and twenty set up this claim, a difficulty will arise. Supposing each of the twenty to have an equal claim, each can have but half what he needs. All may starve and no one can maintain his right to a living. For a man to take his living by force would be to rob the rest and add an injus- tice to a misfortune. But if ten have produced the food for ten, and ten others press the claim of equal division, what becomes of the rights of the ten who have produced their living ? The claim of the idle 82 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. ten is without foundation. They have no right to the food of the others. Even charity will be difficult in the case imagined, but sharing would be charity. (4) The question of rights is apparently complicated by the statement that all wealth, as it exists in soci- ety, is a social and not an individual product. Take a loaf of bread, for example. This, it is said, repre- sents a host of producers. Not only the baker and the miller and the farmer, but the agricultural imple- ment maker, the wood-chopper who cut the timber in the reaper, the iron-workers who fashioned the iron, the miners, the coal-diggers, the teamsters, the wagon-makers, the horseshoers, the harness-makers, and a vast cloud of other contributors whom we seldom think about, are all co-producers of that identical loaf of bread ; that is, it would not be such as it is if these agencies had not conspired to bring- together the conditions of its production. They all have a share in it. By implication, if any one of them were hungry, he might help himself. But which one might ? We have here not only the confusion of rights, but the practical obliteration of them. Is there no one who, above all others, and in opposition to all others, has a right to use this bread ? The workman on whose table it lies paid the baker for it, the baker paid the miller, and the miller paid the farmer for the wheat there is in it. Presumably every co-producer has already received his share for his efforts in producing it. If not, and all want it, it is rather late in the day for the adjudication of claims, and the probability is there will be a free CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 83 fight over it. But the question of right is not the question of division. It is prior to the question of division. It must be settled as the basis of any settlement of the question of division on the princi- ple of right. To fight for the bread is to ignore all questions of right. To ask for the equities is to assume that there is a moral law of division. When the division of claims has been made in accordance with its law, and each claim has been met, what becomes of the social property in the bread ? It is a mere mystification. The bread belongs wholly and absolutely to the man who has bought it and paid for it. He has discharged all claims upon it. Neither society nor any other man than its owner has a right to a crumb of it. (5) The mist now descends upon the question of rights from still another source. The loaf belongs to the man who has earned it by his labor, but has not society a claim upon it through its claim upon him ? Society has made him what he is. It has protected him, it has educated him, it has furnished him a chance to labor. Is there not here a social limitation of individual rights ? Yes, without ques- tion, the man is indebted for many services rendered. For these he ought to pay. The cost of them, so far as it can be ascertained, ought to be made out, and then with all the rest, sharing like advantages, he should pay his proportion of the cost. This is the justification of taxation. If he enjoys a state of society where public roads are used and public schools have shed light along the path, he certainly 84 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. ought to pay for all this. But when this is clone can he eat his loaf without a mortgage upon it ? No, we are told, he must still share it with the poor and unfortunate. But he insists that he has done that in paying his taxes, and has already remembered the poor. When at last can he hope to sit down to an undivided loaf ? Who are these poor that are still unprovided for ? What is their claim ? It is simply the cry of the poor who are always with us, pleading for charity, not pressing a right. It cannot be formulated as a right without an abuse of lan- guage. It is an opportunity for works of mercy, which every Christian man will embrace in his own way, but to call it a "right," to press it as a social obligation that binds a man to action, is to destroy the very possibility of charity in the name of justice. (6) We conclude, then, that the laborer is at last owner of his bread and has a right to it which can- not be rationally disputed. It is in a peculiar sense " property." That it is private is involved in its very nature. It is the fruit of individual powers, put forth under the protection of rights. It is simply the extension of personality. The right of property is not based upon the possession of it, or upon univer- sal consent. The right may exist where the posses- sion does not, and where consent is not universal. The right precedes all property. It is inherent in man as a personal being. Deny his personality, link him with the lower animals, regard him as a product of nature, the highest note in the music of evolution, and there is no right of property ; but then there is CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 85 no right whatever. There remains nothing but con- flicting forces, the triumph of might and the slavery of the laborer. If the laborer has any rights which he can defend by other means than dynamite, if he has any standing before the tribunal of reason, it is because he is a person, because he is that which Christ taught that he is, the image of God, clothed with the majesty of freedom. Christianity solves this problem of the laborer's rights in the light of its conception of man, the conception that has enfranchised the slave, emancipated woman, and snatched the abandoned child from the eagles and the wolves, to place it in the safety of the cradle and the sunlight of the school. (7) The right of private property is challenged by some who admit its general principle, when that property assumes the form of land. Henry George insists that the landlord is a monopolist and that all land is in equity the property of society ; or, as he puts it, "common property." He does not say, how- ever, to whom it belongs, nor is that possible upon his theory. It belongs to all who are, have been, or ever will be on the earth, and equally. Still, he pro- poses to tax all the land in the United States to the full extent of the annual rental, and put the money into the United States treasury. There can be little doubt that, if it ever reached that destination, it would be distributed, but it is doubtful if the " ring" would include all the alleged rightful claimants past, present, and to come. It would happen, however, that thousands of honest and industrious laborers, 86 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. who have put their lives into the improvement of lands, to say nothing of thousands of helpless wid- ows and orphans whom the departed have left behind, would be rendered homeless and reduced to penury, while the scant three per cent, income which Ameri- can acres are paying, when other investments are worth twice that percentage, would go into the hands of officials whose places might be more coveted than the mayoralty of New York City. But if we can readily dismiss this preposterous proposition of one who, like other political agitators, lives on the sensa- tion he creates rather than on the labor he glorifies, we may have more respect for John Stuart Mill, when he says : " When the ' sacredness ' of property is talked of, it should always be remembered that any such sacredness does not belong in the same degree to landed property. It is the original inheritance of the whole species." 5 The idea of a right of prop- erty residing in a " species " is more astonishing than it is intelligible. As the species is indefinite, no individual claim can be determined. How, then, can it be decided whether an individual owner has more or less than his share ? If it is to be settled upon the basis of living claimants, even then it would be practically as indefinite. We must first ascertain the amount of land and the number of persons. A plague in Asia or the submergence of an island in Polynesia would seriously disturb boundaries. If the earth belongs to the " species," the rent of this continent does not belong to the United States 8 Mill's Principles of Political Economy, book ii, chap. i. CHRISTIANITY AND TAB OR. 87 treasury, and when collected a portion should be sent to Belgium, where the population is exceedingly crowded, and, indeed, disbursed throughout the globe, in the form of Christmas presents, based on the ter- ritorial distribution. In that case, it would pay to keep away from the land altogether and the taxes would be reduced and dividends increased by going to sea. Herbert Spencer goes to the root of the question, as a question of theory, and it is simply that, rather than one for practice. He says : " Equity does not permit property in land. For if one portion of the earth's surface may justly become the possession of an individual and may be held by him for his sole use and benefit as a thing to which he has an exclusive right, then other portions of the earth's surface may be so held ; and eventually the whole of the earth's surface ; and our planet may thus lapse altogether into private hands." 6 I do not pause to show that no land is held over which society does not enjoy eminent domain and the right of way for compensation, or that too extensive land- holding is practically unprofitable, or that land is regarded as common property in certain parts of the world without perceptible advantage, or that, as Laveleye has shown, land was originally held as tribal property, and private property is the only regime under which imjDrovement has taken place ; but adhere to the purely theoretical and imaginary form in which the argument is stated. Herbert Spencer defends private property in commodities and 6 Spencer's Social Statics, part ii, chap. ix. 88 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. copyrights. Not being a landowner, but deriving his income from royalties on his books, he sees a great injustice in private ownership of the soil, but none in taxing the people for truth, or such approxi- mations to it as he may personally evolve. Let us now, in the same fanciful manner, draw a parallel to Spencer's argument against landowning. " Equity does not permit a man to own the dinner on his table. For, if a man may own one dinner, he may own another, and if two dinners, then ten, and so on, until he might own all the food-supply in the world, and our planet would be reduced to starvation." If this seems very absurd, Spencer's fancy is not less so. There is as much motive for owning all the food as for owning all the land ; and more, for less money buys a grain crop than buys a farm, and the power over others would be much greater if one could com- mand all the food than if he owned all the land. As a matter of fact, the food-supply, the coal-supply, and the oil-supply in the United States are more nearly in the control of a few men than the land. There are men in Chicago who know that the grain market can be controlled without owning the land. But if a man cannot own food, he cannot own himself. The argument against the ownership of land lies with equal weight against the owning of one's dinner ; but if one cannot own his dinner, he cannot own his body, and if not his body then not his brain, and if not his brain, then not the products of it ; hence Herbert Spencer has no equitable property in his copyright ! CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 89 (8) We conclude that the laborer has the right to the fruit of his labor, and the whole fruit of it, after he has satisfied the like rights of others. This is his right, if there be any ethical foundation of society or any moral nature in man. But there is another aspect of this problem of the rights of the laborer. All that he is and all the natural agents which he employs are bestowments of a higher Power. While no man may interfere with his use of his powers and the fruits of his toil expended upon the materials and forces of nature, there is a claim that underlies all — the claim of the Creator. Christ has presented this neglected aspect of the problem in his parable of the talents. Behind this fortifica- tion of rights in which the producer of wealth in- trenches himself and protects himself from all inva- sion of rights, is that citadel of duty which gives security to them all. It is into this that the defender of his rights must at last retire when pressed by his enemies. He says : " I have duties to perform to my family, to my friends. If you take away my rights, I cannot perform my duties. I am bound to realize manhood, and my rights must be accorded that I may perform my duties." This is the Christian solution of the origin of rights. It says to the laborer : This is your land, for you have cleared its swamps and blasted out its rocks and made it golden with a harvest ; this is your grain, for you have dropped the dry seeds into the moist earth at springtime and have harvested and winnowed and garnered it ; this is your gold, for you have burrowed into the moun- 90 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. tains for it and washed away the sand from it until it glitters in your hand ; but remember, there is upon it all a claim that you must recognize — the claim of Him who fashioned the mountains and hollowed out the valleys and buried the bright nuggets deep in the rocks for you to gather ; the claim of a Father who has placed you among brethren who are like yourself, equal in moral dignity to yourself, if not in powers or possessions, to whom also he has given rights, and whose burdened backs and wearied hands you cannot, as a man and a brother, cause to toil and ache to heap up your treasures or feed your pride. Christianity, respecting and defending every right of man because he is man, with one hand holds the shield of a protecting goddess over the rights of property, and with the other uplifts the sword of justice against the robber and the oppressor. The right of property is simply the right of a steward to discharge his trust without interference. But "it is required in stewards that a man be found faithful." The increase of wealth is attended with great perils, yet Christianity favors and aids that increase. All the sages and philosophers of antiquity dreaded the day when the simplicity of poverty should give place to the luxury of wealth. They had good reason for this fear, for no pagan nation has ever grown rich without the deterioration of its people. A prophetic psalm of ancient Israel expresses a wish which no pagan sage had dared to utter, but only in view of a condi- tion that renders riches safe. " God be merciful unto CHRISTIANITY AND LABOR. 91 us, and bless us, and cause his face to shine upon us, that thy ways may be known upon the earth, thy saving health among all nations. . . . Then shall the earth yield her increase ; and God, even our own God, shall bless us." Ui IV. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF WEALTH. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF WEALTH. I. THE PROBLEM OF DISTRIBUTION. 1. The Problem an Old One. 2. Its Contemporary Complications. 3. The Discussion of the Problem. 4. Christ's Refusal to be a Divider. 5. Christianity gives the Spirit, but not the Science of a Solution. 6. The Method of Arbitration. II. SCHEMES FOR EQUALIZING WEALTH. 1. The Postulate of Socialism. 2. The History and Literature of Socialism. 3. The Equality of Men a False Assumption. 4. The Injustice of Equalizing Wealth. 5. The Fruits of Labor determined by Social Utility. 6. The Specific Forms of Socialism : (1) Revolutionary Socialism; (2) Agrarian Socialism ; (3) State Socialism ; (4) Christian Socialism. 7. Did Christ teach Human Equality? III. THE EQUITABLE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH. 1. Progressive Acquisition. 2. Decentralizing Agencies. 3. The Case of the Proletarian. 4. Industrial Partnerships. 5. Labor Organizations. 6. The World as a School of Morals. 7. Christian Beneficence. £ IV. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF WEALTH. i. When wealth has beer produced, there arises the problem of its distribution. It is not a new- problem, as the history of the conflicts of capital and labor reveals. Ever since the banquet board of life has been spread for men, they have been crowding one another for the best places. But the conditions are ever changing. In earlier times, large classes gave up all hope of a place at the table, and were content to eat a few crumbs in a corner. It is not so to-day. The results of the republican movement of thought are felt throughout the civilized world. Men everywhere feel that they are as good as others ; and, as a Hibernian once said, sometimes a great deal better ! Political equality has become so gen- eral that social elevation is the dream of the lowest. But it is by no means the intention of any to surren- der their places. The same strong desire for per- sonal superiority, as distinguished from personal excellence, that has always been so powerful a motive in men, is still active, and never more so than in our own land and time. In truth, the motive for eleva- tion is even more predominant than ever. The cause 96 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. of this lies in the almost universal presumption of the least fortunate people that all misfortune can be effaced by the possession of wealth. The rush for the banquet is never so prompt and energetic as when the crowd is hungry, and the politically enfran- chised bring a good appetite to the scene of wealth's distribution. 2. While the problem is thus made a pressing one, there are several circumstances that tend to render it complex. One is the unprecedented division of labor, so minute that almost every commodity is a social product. When a barbarian carved a stone into a hatchet with his own hands, there could be no doubt to whom it belonged ; but when a schoolboy purchases a penknife, an army of co-producers rises behind it, each, it may be, with some unsatisfied claim upon it. Another source of difficulty is found in the vast but incalculable progress in the use of mechanical implements and forces, which renders it troublesome to ascertain how large a share of the worldis general advancement may fall to each mem- ber of society. For example : There is no patent on the use of steam. It has become a human inheri- tance to which no class has an exclusive right. What proportion of this common advantage should each person enjoy ? It is said that, although there has been marvelous progress in the production of wealth, there are classes, and these the hardest worked of all, who have not received a perceptible increment of benefit from this and other heirlooms of humanity. The rhetorical author of " Progress CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 97 and Poverty" does not deny the absolute improve- ment of workingmen in civilized countries, but he formulates this alleged though not clearly proved dis- proportion of benefit in the telling but false aphorism, "The rich are growing richer, and the poor, poorer." x It does not mollify the aroused sense of indignation at this apparent injustice, to be told that many of the greatest fortunes have been acquired by men who began life as wage-earners, and that some of the most gigantic estates in the world have been amassed in one or two generations. This is, in fact, the greatest provocation to the envious, that a man in a nominally free country should rise so rapidly above his fellows as in a few short years to " bestride the narrow world like a colossus." 3. The general diffusion of intelligence and the accessibility of information on every subject have conspired to convert the more advanced countries into a vast indignation meeting, where the most vig- orous debate on the constitution of society and the schemes for its reconstruction that has ever re- sounded in the "parliament of man" is at present rolling its tide of spasmodic eloquence and untrained logic upon the understanding and the conscience of this generation. The political economist has heard the definitions and pretended axioms of his "dismal science " mutilated and denounced, ridiculed and 1 For a statistical refutation of Henry George's statement, " The rich are growing richer, and the poor, poorer," see Rae's Contemporary Socialism, chap, ix ; and Mallock's Property and Progress, essay on The Statistics of Agitation. 98 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. refuted, and dismissed as impotent to govern thought or dictate action. The socialistic theorist has pro- posed the most radical and revolutionary remedies, and his more excited cohorts of agitators have dis- turbed the discussion with bomb and pistol, till it has been found necessary to eject them from the world as conspiring assassins. The Christian minister has preached the precepts of peace with various degrees of comprehension of the debate, and with alternating sympathies with his friends among the rich and among the poor, generally with the result of produc- ing the impression that his sentiments were good and his intentions commendable, but sometimes with a sneer that his salary was paid by the men who could spare^the money, and with the intimation that it is not "peace" but "justice" that men want. 4. If we seriously ask, Has Christianity any rela- tion to the problem of wealth's distribution ? we shall at once recall the words of Christ, when the young man came to him, saying, " Master, speak to my brother, that he divide the inheritance with me." And Jesus answered: "Man, who made me a judge or a divider over you ? " Then follows that pregnant passage which no theory of the distribution of wealth can afford to ignore. Turning to the multitude, he said : " Take heed, and beware of covetousness ; for a man's life consisteth not in the abundance of the things which he possesseth. And he spake a para- ble unto them, saying, The ground of a certain rich man brought forth plentifully ; and he thought within himself, saying, What shall I do, because I have no CHRISTIANITY AND WE A IT H. 99 room where to bestow my fruits ? And he said, This will I do : I will pull down my barns, and build greater ; and there will I bestow all my fruits and my goods. And I will say to my soul, Soul, thou hast much goods laid up for many years ; take thine ease, eat, drink, and be merry. But God said unto him, Thou fool ! this night thy soul shall be required of thee ; then whose shall those things be which thou has provided ? So is he that layeth up treasure for himself, and is not rich toward God." What ground have we for thinking that if Christ were in the flesh to-day he would give another answer ? What authority has any disciple of his, in his name, to give another ? The plain duty of Christians is to understand and apply this teaching. It involves : (1) a rebuke to covetousness ; (2) the decla'ration that true wealth does not consist in earthly posses- sions ; (3) the necessity of riches toward God, or spiritual attainment. 5. Has Christianity, then, no relation to this sub- ject ? May not Christian men attempt the problem of distribution ? Certainly we are not assuming to be dividers over men when we seek to ascertain the principles of right division. We are producers of wealth, we have a share in it, and we must know how to divide it among ourselves. If we may draw any practical lesson from Christ's unwillingness to act as judge, it is that he had no principle to apply that men might not by themselves discover. He has else- where recommended that differences be settled by agreement and, if that is impossible, by calling in an IOO SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. arbitrator. He chose not to arbitrate in this case for reasons that are not, indeed, expressed, but are certainly implied. He referred at once to " covetous- ness." The brother who had the inheritance doubt- less had it in accordance with the law. The claimer may have been disinherited for his vices, may have possessed and wasted his share of the fortune, may have been utterly incapable, intellectually and mor- ally, of its proper management. Christ states the spirit with which wealth ought to be regarded. That is really what men need. Victor Hugo once said : "Social philosophy is, in essence, science and peace." Christianity commands that we approach this ques- tion in "peace," but our own faculties may discover the "science." 6. Arbitration is rightly represented as the Chris- tian method of settling disputes over wealth. It possesses the advantage of pursuing the way of peace. But it lacks science. With the best of in- tentions, men may miss the mark of justice if they do not know on what principles to proceed. If there were an omnipresent paternal umpire, endowed with perfect wisdom and impartiality, to administer justice in every case, arbitration would realize perfect equity. But when we consider how complicated are the phe- nomena, how unwilling men are to expose their affairs to other persons, and how reluctant the dis- appointed one is likely to be in accepting a decision, and add to all this the innumerable cases in which the tedious process has to be applied, it is evident that it is not as easy as it is sometimes represented CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. IOI to be. Available in the larger interests of inter- national disputes, because of the comparative infre- quency of the occasions when it must be invoked, it is less powerful in the presence of the personal dis- tribution of property. And yet, it is not only the best means we have, but has proved exceedingly use- ful in France and England, where it has been for years the favorite method of deciding differences between workmen and their employers. The history of arbitration in trade often reads like a romance, and is a perfect vindication of the wisdom of pacific adjustments. On the dark background of waste and violence occasioned by strikes, it shines out like a fiery cross in the heavens, the symbol of blended sacrifice and justice. But even for peaceful arbitra- tion, we need general principles. Once discovered, they may be recognized by all as furnishing the basis of voluntary agreement ; or, if not left to personal choice, they may be incorporated into the law of the land, which is the generalized agreement of a people as to what is right and just. II. I. Aristotle, who in many respects has not been surpassed as a political writer, says : " Everywhere inequality is a cause of revolution." He then adds: " Men agree about justice in the abstract, but they differ about proportion ; some think that if they are equal in any respect they are equal absolutely ; others that if they are unequal in any respect, they 102 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. are unequal in all." 2 If he had written to-day, after reading the current doctrines of socialism, the Stagi- rite could not have expressed himself more wisely. Men believe themselves equal in all but wealth, but feel keenly their inequality in the possession of it. They thence conclude that they ought to be equal in wealth also, and every socialistic theory proceeds upon this assumption. In the undiscriminating mind, political equality involves social equality. Men who are not equal in fact imagine that they are by right. Socialism, however it is judged in the light of its proposals, must at least be credited with an ethical impulse. It is a dream of impossible remedies for imaginary wrongs. It assumes that all wealth is produced by the labor of society, that it is, therefore, the property of society, and that justice can be realized only by dividing equally that which belongs to all. It does not pause to reflect that the units in society have not equally produced wealth, and that the claim of each is pro- portional to his productive contribution. It perceives in the actual condition of men a separation of wealth from its alleged producers, a partition of products by which capital, the creation of labor, is placed on one side of a line and labor, empty-handed, on the other ; while existing law creates an impassable barrier between them, excluding the laborer from the fruits of his labors and obliterating every right by the legalized institution of wrong. It proposes by various means to break through this barrier and to divide this wealth among all men. 2 Aristotle's Politics, book v, i. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH 1 03 2. This is socialism in its generic outline. It has, however, assumed chameleon forms and wears as many masks as Proteus himself. Its history has been so often repeated in the numerous popular books called out by the contemporary demand, like those of Woolsey, Rae, Laveleye, and Ely, to men- tion only a few, that any outline even of its historic development through the writings of its forerunners, the Communists, Babceuf, Cabet, Saint-Simon, Fourier, Louis Blanc, Proudhon, and Owen, and its own doctrinaires, Rodbertus, Karl Marx, Lasalle, and their followers, would be a work of supereroga- tion. All these doctrines have been lately stated, expounded, and criticized by numerous able writers, among them a number of distinguished clergymen, such as Doctors Brown, Behrends, Lorimer, Gladden, Smyth, Newton, and others, who have discussed the bearings of these theories both upon the social order and the ethical life. A brief summary and examina- tion of socialistic doctrines, therefore, in the pres- ence of so much available literature, is all that is to be attempted before we proceed to the wider rela- tions which our plan contemplates. 3. The primary assumption of socialism, often latent rather than expressed, is that men are equal. It is a false assumption. They are not equal in powers, either physical or mental, in skill, or in industry. They are, therefore, unequal in produc- tion. Some produce only a bare subsistence, and a few not even this. Others create a considerable surplus. Improgressive labor consumes the whole 104 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. of its product, while progressive labor accumulates an excess. 3 The producers of wealth are also un- equal in their needs. Science certainly contributes to the creation of wealth, but the man of science cannot live as the day-laborer lives. He must be sustained during a long period of preparation, must be supplied with books and appliances, and must enjoy opportunities of travel. The chemist and the coal-heaver are both laborers, but under unequal conditions of necessary expense and surroundings. Men are unequal also in their achievements, even when they have expended the same amount of energy. More depends upon the judicious direction of power than upon its quantity. It is impossible to measure value by days of labor. One man will do intone day what another will not do so well in two or, possibly, cannot do at all. Such a standard is as absurd as an elastic yardstick. No a priori mathematical conception of equality can solve the problem of distribution. The units are unequal and the laws of the equation are, therefore, not applica- ble. The prime error of socialism consists in im- porting this mathematical idea of an equation into a province of variable units. 4. If each laborer has a right to the whole fruits of his labor, which we have demonstrated in discuss- ing the problem of the laborer's rights, equal par- ticipation in wealth involves the moral paradox of s It may be well for the reader to recur to the distinction between impro- gressive and progressive labor, as given in Lecture III, p. 69, if this distinc- tion is not clearly understood. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 1 05 taking from one who has a greater right and bestow- ing upon one who has a less right. Equality in distribution is, therefore, a repudiation of the ethical ) idea. It cannot be justified on a basis of right. Equality is not equity, if the units who are to partici- pate are unequal. " From each according to his powers, to each according to his needs," is Louis Blanc's monstrous axiom of distribution. It is but a euphemism for the spoliation of the able and indus- trious for the benefit of the weak and idle. When rendered compulsory, as socialism proposes, it is a new form of slavery. That it is an inversion of the old slavery which subjected the weaker to the stronger, does not render it more acceptable. It proposes to enslave the few who are strong by the combined action of the weak. The pigmies may shackle the giant, but first they must put out his eyes. Like another Samson, he would at last end his bondage in wreck and ruin. The individual cannot be thus deprived of freedom, but if he were, the ser- vile spirit would inevitably survive when hope was dead, and weakness and idleness would be preferred to strength and industry. The grand motive in the creation of wealth is the expectation of its enjoy- ment. The adoption of Louis Blanc's aphorism, or any compulsory equivalent, would paralyze labor and introduce an epoch of industrial stagnation and pauperism. 5. The value of a day's labor depends upon its relation to social need. Social utility is the quality in labor that responds to that need and affords it 106 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. satisfaction. It may require as much force to pro- duce a thousand coats that will not fit as to produce the same number of well-fitting garments, or to pro- duce them out of season as in the season when they are needed. But there is obviously a great difference with reference to social need. The well-cut gar- ments will all be sold at a good price, while the others must be sold for less, or remain unsold. A man with a pile of clothes too small for him is hardly better off than a man without any. The socialists overlook this element of quality in labor. Karl Marx argues that all capital is produced by labor and then that the laborers are all and equally entitled to share in its possession. But suppose the tailors take for their share the coats they have produced. Some, though they have worked as hard as any, will be rewarded with the ill-fitting garments which are of no use to them, and they are as badly off as if they had received less wages in money than their more skilful fellows. It is evidently unjust to take away from the expert in order to reward the bunglers. It is equally so to rob the successful for the benefit of the unsuccessful. The whole problem of just distri- bution turns upon the pivot of social utility in response to social need. " Why should the stone- breaker on a railroad receive less money for his time than the engineer of a train, and the engineer less than the president of the company ? It is not because it costs more effort to preside over the affairs of the company ; it is not because it costs more effort to run the train. So far as the putting CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 107 forth of measurable energy goes, the order of rewards ought to be reversed, for the stone-breaker puts forth more foot-pounds of force than the other two. It is not a complete answer to say that the cost of preparation is the measure of reward and that the engineer must be paid for the time used in learning to manage the engine, and the president for the time spent in learning to preside over a rail- road's affairs. The true answer is this : the service of each man is paid according to its worth to the company. If the stone-breaker will not work, others will take his place for what he receives. If the engineer will not work, others will take his place for what he receives. Wages must always rise to this market-price. But the engineer will not work for what the stone-breaker receives. Why not ? Because he can get more for his service. Why can he get more ? Because others are willing to pay more. Why are they willing to pay more ? Because his service has a higher quality than that of the other man. In what does this quality consist? In ele- ments of knowledge, skill, and judgment, in power to do safely and certainly what the other cannot do safely and certainly. Put the stone-breaker in charge of the engine and there would be a destructive acci- dent. Put the engineer in charge of the president's business and there would be unskilful management of the company's affairs, involving loss and possible bankruptcy. It may be settled as certain that the company would not pay the engineer any more than the stone-breaker, if it could hire him for the same. IOS SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. Service has social utility in proportion as it rises in the scale of skill and efficiency. The stone-breaker is little more than a machine, so far as his occupation goes. A machine has been invented to take his place. As power advances from the merely physical to the intellectual and moral orders, it becomes more valuable." 4 6. The specific forms of socialism all share, to some extent, in the generic fallacy of the doctrine. They all propose by artificial means to unite suddenly capital and labor in the same hands. (i) Revolutionary socialism, as represented by the International Workmen's Association, aims to do this by universal confiscation and redistribution of wealth. The political socialists of this school would accomplish their end by the votes of the people, but this method is usually seen to be impracticable, since it implies as its precondition a mental revolu- tion that argument cannot produce. The anarchic branch of this school proposes the overthrow of the present order by physical force and intimidation. Its only argument is dynamite. This is a phase of the question with which policemen and magistrates alone can deal. (2) Agrarian socialism sees a solution of the prob- lem in the confiscation and nationalization of land, not by purchase, but by legal compulsion through insufferable taxation. This is the prescription of Henry George for the ills of society. It is needless 4 Quoted from my brochure on The Principles and Fallacies of Socialism, No. 533 of Lovell's Library. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 109 to dwell upon the injustice of this crude remedy; but, if applied, would it better any one's condition ? If the form of change were simply that present hold- ers of land should pay the whole rent for taxes, they would, in subletting, double the rent, which would increase the price of bread, since rent enters into the price of the products of land, so that non-land- holders would have both increased rent and increased cost of food, while the money thus raised would go in part to public improvements and in part to govern- ment officials. If the change involved the actual expulsion of landholders from their estates, it would provoke a war for the hearthstone that could not be suppressed. This agrarian socialism of George has all the ethical faults of revolutionary socialism with the additional trait of logical absurdity. As another has said : " He would not tax a palace, but the plot under it. He would not tax a line of steamships, but their wharf. He would not tax a lump of gold, but the hole in the ground out of which it was dug." 5 (3) State socialism is a more subtle but equally inadequate solution. It proposes to solve the prob- lem of distribution by adding two new functions to the State : the reparative, undertaking to repair the evils of too great private possessions, by fixing a max- imum beyond which one may not own property and by wholly or partly abolishing the right of inheritance ; and the assistive, awarding grants to workmen for employment, insurance, and industrial enterprise. fl Man's Birthright, by E. H. G. Clark, introduction. IIO SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. This system has numerous adherents in Germany, among them the great chancellor, Prince Bismarck, and many university professors known as " Socialists of the Chair." 6 Some American students of polit- ical and social science in Germany have imported some of these neo-economic notions into our own country, and have given them a certain popularity through newspapers, magazines, and reviews. The so-called "historic" method, which characterizes the new school, is excellent in teaching us what to avoid, but easily imparts to the mind a retrogressive tendency. The worst vice of these economic critics, however, is an erudite vagueness which, in attempt: ing to attain to the unknown, renders very nebulous the whole province of the known. They write rhetorically about the ethical element in economic theory, without pointing out with clearness the basis of right, or showing precisely how rights may be realized. Social theories that have no better title to acceptance than flings at the immorality of the classic economists present a very poor prima facie case. Mackintosh says : " I have known Adam Smith slightly, Ricardo well, Malthus intimately. Is it not something to say for a science, that its three great masters were about the three best men I ever knew ? " ' It is sometimes forgotten that 6 Notably Professor Adolph Wagner, of the University of Berlin, who has formulated a " law of increasing extension of the functions of public power " (Grundlegung, p. 308), and would both limit inheritance and enforce state insurance for workingmen. ' Quoted by Professor Edwin R. A. Seligman, in Science Economic Dis- cussion, p. 14. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. \\\ the founder of that much-reproached science which assumes that self-interest is the principal factor in the world of wealth, was also the author of an eth- ical system founded wholly upon sympathy, and bearing for its motto, "Put yourself in his place." The neoiogists condemn the wage-system, or system of free personal contract between employer and employed, as utterly unworthy of our civilization. But they offer nothing better. There are vague allusions to the "extension of state action," but no precise methods are pointed out by which the State may control the distribution of wealth, with- out the invasion of personal rights which we Amer- icans are accustomed to hold dear. It may be modestly questioned if these writers have not im- ported a temporary phase of German speculation, conceived largely under the influence of a govern- ment that desires to ingratiate itself into the affec- tions of the people by the performance of paternal functions, in order to render permanent an empire but newly created. 8 This new doctrine of the 8 In a speech delivered on the third of January, 1882, Bismarck said : " I have already explained the system which I am come to uphold, according to the instructions of His Majesty the Emperor. We wish to establish a state of things in which no one can say ' I exist only to bear social burdens, and nobody takes thought of my fate.' Our dynasty has for a long time been endeavoring to reach this object. Frederick the Great already describes this mission in saying, ' I am king of the beggars,' and he realized it in adminis- tering strict justice. Frederick William III gave freedom to the peasants. Our present sovereign is animated by the noble ambition to put a hand, in his old age, to the work of assuring to the least favored and weakest of our fellow-citizens, if not the same rights that were seventy years ago granted to the peasantry, at least a decided amelioration in their condition, in order that they can count upon the help of the State." " The whole theory of state socialism, and of a socialist monarch, is summed up in this passage," says Laveleye, from whom I quote it. The Socialism of To-day, chap. vi. 112 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. growing dominance of the State, and diminution of the individual, will be found as repugnant to Amer- ican independence as the lofty German theories of transcendentalism, not less ably or enthusiastically urged upon the American mind a generation ago, proved to our Yankee common-sense. For scholarly young gentlemen, whose reputations are yet in the nascent condition, and whose chosen department of study does not afford the brilliant discoveries of physical science, the introduction of novelties seems a natural policy, and " Omne ignotum pro magnifico," an excellent motto ; but it will require diligence, if in their remaining years, they convince the Amer- ican people that it is either sensible or just to say that a man may possess ninety-nine thousand, nine hundred and ninety-nine dollars and ninety-nine cents, but not one hundred thousand dollars ; that it is a higher form of justice to give the whole or a part of a child's patrimony to the public than to the child for love of whom its father laboriously earned and prudently saved it ; that it is a national good to employ workmen with money from the public treasury in order to give them employment, under the management of public officials whose morals might not be better than those of some customs officers, or to insure men's lives, or to start workmen in cooperative industry. In France, in 1848, Louis Blanc's idea of state subsidies for co- operation among workmen were so far carried into effect that " thirty associations, twenty-seven of which were composed of workmen, . . . received CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 113 eight hundred and ninety thousand, five hundred francs. Within six months three of the Parisian societies failed ; and of the four hundred and thirty- four associates, seventy-four resigned, fifteen were excluded, and there were eleven changes of man- agers. In July, 185 1, eighteen associations had ceased to exist. One year later twelve others had vanished. In 1865, four were still extant, and had been more or less successful. In 1875, there was but a single one left." 9 Such are the historic les- sons of state intervention for the just distribution of wealth. It is more likely to facilitate distribution than to secure justice. 4. It is claimed by the Christian socialists that what the law cannot do in that it is weak, the spirit of Christianity can do in that it is strong. They would equalize wealth by religious beneficence, voluntarily raising and depositing in the hands of workingmen large sums of money for cooperative industry. Forty years ago the communist Villegar- delle compiled a volume of extracts from the Christian Fathers, to show that social property is the Chris- tian ideal. Bishop Ketteler, of Mayence, was a friend of Lasalle and wrote a book in 1864 on "The Labor Question and Christianity," depicting modern society as the revolutionary socialists do, acknowledg- ing all the evils of which they complain. Upon this basis he offered an eloquent plea for voluntary con- tributions from all good Catholics for socialistic experiments. A host of others have followed in his 9 Laveleye, op. cit. p. 73, note. 114 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. train, until there is now in Germany a strong contin- gent of Catholic socialists, strangely enough united politically with the atheistic socialists to forward the schemes of industrial revolution. Quickened to action by the apparent success of the Catholics in leading the minds of workingmen, and fearful of losing all hold on that class through lack of sympathy with its misfortunes, the evangelical Christians of Germany, headed by Dr. Stocker, the eloquent court preacher at Berlin, have also organized a socialistic movement. 10 Herr Todt places the following epi- graph at the head of his book on " Radical German Socialism and Christianity " : " Whoever would under- stand the social question and contribute to its solution must have on his right hand the works on political economy and on his left the literature of scientific socialism, and must keep the New Testament open before him." "Political economy explains the social anatomy, scientific socialism describes the disease, and the gospel indicates the cure." But the masses who are inclined to socialistic ideas quite generally repudiate the "socialists in surplice" and prefer the " socialists in blouse." The movement has made more converts to socialism among Christians than it has converts to Christianity among socialists. Said Herr Most at a joint meeting at which Dr. Stocker was present : " The social democracy will not re- cede ; it will pursue its course and accomplish its 10 The views of Dr. Stocker are set forth in his address on " Die Bibel und die Sociale Frage," delivered before the Evangelical Labor Union at Niirn- berg, which has passed through many editions. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 115 designs, even though all priestdom should rise against it, like a cloud of locusts thick enough to darken the sun. The social democracy knows that the days of Christianity are numbered, and that the time is not far distant when we shall say to the priests, Settle your account with heaven, for your hour has come." u It is clear that oil and water are not more repugnant to coalescence than are Christianity and socialism, considered as types of thought and feeling. Maurice and Kingsley are well known as advocates of what has been called Christian socialism in England, but their doctrines are wholly different from those of the German socialists. 12 "Competition," said Maurice, "is put forth as a law of the universe. That is a lie. The time has come for us to declare that it is a lie by word and deed. I see no way but associating for work instead of for strikes." "It is my belief," said Kingsley, "that not self-interest, but self-sacrifice, is the only law upon which human society can be grounded with any hope of prosperity and permanence." These are appeals for order and renunciation rather than for revolution and reprisal. 7. But it is now time to ask seriously, Did Christ teach the equality of men or favor the equalization of possessions ? When the ambitious mother of Zebedee's children came to him, saying, " Grant 11 Quoted by Laveleye, op. cit. chap. vii. 12 Some account of Christian Socialism in England is given by Laveleye, op. cit., supplementary chapter ; and by Ely, in his French and German Socialism in Modern Times, chap. xiv. I I 6 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. that these my two sons may sit, the one on thy right hand, and the other on the left, in thy kingdom," Jesus replied that she knew not what she asked, and disclosed to her the conditions on which this pre- eminence depends. "To sit on my right hand and on my left, is not mine to give, but it shall be given to them for whom it is prepared of my Father." Inequality and preeminence are not denied, even in the kingdom of heaven, but preeminence is not an arbitrary gift ; it is prepared for the deserving in the divine order. Jesus goes on to explain that among the nations preeminence is based upon dominion, or lordship, but in the kingdom of heaven, on service. " Whosoever will be great among you, let him be your minister ; and whosoever will be chief among you, let him be your servant." Economic greatness is founded upon power, moral greatness is founded upon love. Inequality was recognized in both and not condemned in either. Whatever the opinions of the fathers may be, Christ does not commend equality in the distribution of wealth. If it be asserted that equality is taught in the brotherhood of man, it is sufficient to note that brothers, equal in nature, are not equal in personal powers, personal productive- ness, or personal deserts. In the case where Christ was appealed to as judge between brothers, he showed no concern that they be regarded as possess- ing equal claims, probably because he thought that in equity they were unequal. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. \\n u) III. 1. The equitable division of wealth, which cannot be realized by artificial aids to equality, may never- theless be attained by other means. I say the "equitable" division, not the "equal" division. This proceeds on the assumption that capital should be placed in the hands of labor only by progressive acquisition. It is nature's universal method, the method of growth, illustrated in every province of being, from the formation of a crystal to the consoli- dation of a character. Suddenly acquired wealth seldom remains long in its possessor's hands, or finds its place there even briefly without demoralizing results. The creation of wealth is in its nature a moral discipline, involving industry, patience, tem- perance, and self-sacrifice. Wealth, like preeminence in the moral world, offers its reward normally only to those who have been prepared in the divine order to receive it. Without its virtues, it may, indeed, be dishonestly acquired, but it cannot be permanently retained. 2. The mechanism of distribution is much more perfect than we are wont to fancy. The wealth which one generation accumulates, the next scatters. Close observers hold that it is unusual for business success to remain in the same family for more than three generations. Within the same generation the centrifugal forces are acting. We see the successes of men, but they conceal their failures. In 1881, Dun & Co., the well-known commercial agents, re- Il8 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OE CHRISTIANITY. ported that fifty per cent, of the wholesale merchants doing business in Chicago in 1870 had failed in that single decade. One well acquainted with such affairs says that not more than three per cent, of those who embark in trade end life with success. But, from the nature of it, wealth can be enjoyed only by being distributed. The owner of a vaultful of gold has no wealth in any true sense, until he unlocks the vault and disburses the gold. He cannot gratify the first desire without contributing to the social need. If he wishes interest, he must place his dollars in the hands of one who needs them and can use them. If he would enjoy a dinner, obtain a carriage, or build a mansion, he must put his coins in the hands of cooks, wheelwrights, or architects, who in turn pass them on to others. There is no wealth that does not respond to social need. My lord the Duke of Westminster, with his millions of acres and scores of palaces, cannot have his dinner to-day, except on condition that the cook and the butler have theirs also. 3. But what shall we say of the man who has no means of satisfying social need ? There is no such man, unless he is an idiot, a lunatic, an invalid, or the victim of some misfortune. He then becomes an object of charity, and his case we shall consider later. But the so-called " proletarian " can supply social need. Men are too valuable to be allowed to starve in an industrial age. As Count Tolstoi' has said, " Laborers are necessary. And those who profit by labor will always be careful to provide the CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 119 means of labor for those who are willing to work." 13 Why should a man who can do nothing for himself complain if he lives upon the lowest plane ? If he can do better, let him do so freely. If he is not above the status of the Pilgrim Fathers, let him take up some unimproved land and raise a crop of wheat. Ii he can, let him learn a trade and rise in it. It is the old way, but it is the only honest, manly way. If, as Haeckel says, the development of the individual man is a summary and epitome of the development of the race, let him begin where Adam did, among the fruit-trees, and work his way up. Away with the sen- timentalism and snobbishness of socialism and of semi-socialism, which scoff at the dignity of labor and ridicule the hands of toil. We are not better than our fathers. The proletarian of to-day may be the President of to-morrow, as several of our ablest have been. The true American does not want an equality which he has not earned. He wants to be a man, free to labor where and how he chooses, with liberty of contract and wages proportioned to his usefulness as estimated by his fellows, and through manhood to become the equal of any in the life of freedom and self-conscious nobility. 4. No doubt much may be hoped for from indus- trial partnership and cooperation. There is not a village in the land where there are not men who have risen from poverty to independence by this method. But no enterprise will succeed where there is not ability to plan and manage. It ought not to succeed 13 Count Tolstoi's My Religion, chap. x. 120 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. without it. It would be putting a premium on stu- pidity and inefficiency. It is such ability that finds large rewards as wages of superintendence. If cooperating laborers can supply this among them- selves, or pay for it, they can have it ; but if not, they will fail. Whatever may be said in abuse of the wage-system, it shows the superiority of brains to muscle. Voluntary profit-sharing on the part of employers may be judicious, experience must decide this ; but profit-sharing cannot be logically disassoci- ated from loss-sharing, which in the end might leave small advantage to employees. The practicability of this system has been ably advocated by Sedley Tay- lor in his interesting little book on "Profit-sharing," but it implies a noble altruism not attributed to the "economic man." In spite of his enthusiasm as an advocate of this plan, that writer closes his preface with the "profound conviction that the methods de- scribed in this volume, valuable as they are in them- selves, constitute no panacea ; and that their best fruits can be reaped only by men who feel that life does not consist in abundance of material posses- sions, who regard stewardship as nobler than owner- ship, who see in the ultimate outcome of all true work issues reaching beyond the limits of the present dispensation, and who act faithfully and strenuously on these beliefs." 14 Enforced profit-sharing, like en- forced arbitration, is a pure chimera. It is essentially socialistic, invading the right of contract, and will never be tolerated by a free people. Here, as every - 14 Sedley Taylor's Profit-sharing between Capital and Labor, preface. CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. 121 where in the discharge of the social functions, Chris- tianity alone can solve the problem. If all men were Christians, the labor problem would melt away and be forgotten in the sense of universal brotherhood. Until they are, there is no cure for the evils born of human greed. 5. The organization of labor may legitimately accomplish much, especially in mutual help and in- surance. So far as labor organizations aim at creating fraternal feelings among workingmen, the improvement of the trades, the discovery of needs, and the distribution of men where they are wanted, they are highly commendable and may prove useful. But as human nature is constituted, they threaten to become the most oppressive monopolies in the land, binding the wills and consciences of men, forcing upon them actions contrary to their judgments and their interests ; as when, in the strikes among the coal-heavers in New York, men receiving $20 per week, promptly and satisfactorily paid, were forced by their executive committee into the ridiculous posi- tion, in order to give moral support, of striking for thirty-three per cent, less than they were receiving ! Such centralized corporations, often under the con- trol of petty tyrants who are without reason or con- science, veritable dictators without responsibilities, constitute an imperium in imperio, whose power and passion may well be dreaded. 6. The Christian conception of man and the world does not afford any specific criterion for the division of wealth. Man is endowed with moral freedom and 122 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. the world is a scene of moral discipline. It is an order in which hope and fear, gain and loss, success and failure, must ever be possible, for they are essen- tial to its purpose. Christ's prayer for his disciples was not that they might be taken out of the world, or that the world might be transformed to give them peace or comfort, but that they might be kept from the evil. It is not what we have, but what we are, that makes life sweet and blessed. Wealth is not simply to gratify but to unfold our natures. Its ministry of sensations passes away, but its ministry of discipline is everlasting. " The true secret of happiness," says Canon Westcott, " is not to escape toil and affliction, but to meet them with the faith that through them the destiny of man is fulfilled, that through them we can even now reflect the image of our Lord and be transformed into his likeness." 7. "The poor," said Jesus, "always ye have with you." I cannot see that it will ever be otherwise. It is proof that Christ entertained no dream of social equality. If all were equalized to-day, there would be the poor, if not the rich, to-morrow. The virtue of beneficence will never be outgrown upon the earth. The incapable, the unfortunate, the sick, to say nothing of the idle and the improvident, will ever sit by the wayside, waiting for the coming of the Good Samaritan. For the Christian, the problem of wealth's distribution is largely one of judicious benefi- cence, for the world has learned that there is beneficence that is injudicious and even injurious. An undiscriminating charity has fostered mendicancy CHRISTIANITY AND WEALTH. I 23 and pauperism and there are countries of Europe where no church is without its waiting beggar. William Law, the author of the " Serious Call," gave a literal interpretation to the words of Christ, " Give to him that asketh thee," and with two rich friends resolved to deny himself as much as possible and supply the needs of every applicant. They attracted a great crowd of idle and lying mendicants to the neighborhood, till finally the community had to peti- tion the magistrates to interfere, in order to pre- vent the utter demoralization of the parish. But suppose we should interpret with similar literalness the saying, " If any man come to me and hate not his father, and mother, and wife, and children, and brethren, and sisters, yea, and his own life also, he cannot be my disciple ! " A slow beast needs sharp goads, and Christ stirs and startles the conscience by such awakening words, not as giving laws of action but spurs to reflection. Some counselors, like Her- bert Spencer, advise us to follow our own self-interest, without concern for others, with the assurance that all will thus be happier, because more independent. Between the misdirected almsgiving of the purely sympathetic and the indifference of the selfish, lies the narrow way of wisdom, walking in which, Christ says, " Whenever ye will ye may do them good." We are sometimes told that we ought never to give directly, but only through organizations. This coun- sel overlooks the blessing of personal ministration. The Good Samaritan took a personal pleasure in relieving misfortune. We need the contact with suf- 124 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. fering and the lessons of patience and faith which it often teaches. Besides, it is sometimes the gift of ourselves, rather than of our money, it is our coun- sel, our sympathy, our word of cheer, that would make glad the heart and infuse strength. I have no word of criticism for the noble work of organized charity, but there is much that it cannot do, because it lacks the human personality which in God's order, both for the recipient and the bestower, should be present in every ministration. And, as a rule, the best gift is the one that has most of personality in it. All true strength radiates outward from the centre, A weak heart or a weak mind needs a strong one. Encouragement, advice, knowledge, a place to work in, a nobler work to do, are better gifts than food and clothing ; for they produce these and confer the power that continues to produce them. The best form of beneficence that the world has discovered is helping others to help themselves. V. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF MARRIAGE. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF MARRIAGE. I. THE PROBLEM OF POPULATION, i. Immigration from the Cradle. 2. The Doctrine of Malthus. 3. The Results of Malthusianism. 4- The Inadequacy of Malthusianism. II. THE HISTORY OF THE FAMILY. 1 . The Four Stages of Domestic Evolution. 2. Monogamy, an alleged Transition. 3. Socialism and the Family. 4. Criticism of the Evolution Theorv. III. THE CHRISTIAN CONCEPTION OF THE FAMILY. 1 . Christ's Doctrine of Monogamy. 2. The Divine Plan in the Family. 3. The Family as part of the Moral Order. 4. The Consistency of New Testament Teaching. IV. THE DOMESTIC STATUS. 1. The Status of the Child. 2. The Status of the Wife. 3. The " Emancipation " of Woman. 4. The Dissolution of Marriage. V. CHRISTIANITY AND THE PROBLEMS OF MARRIAGE. I. i. "We occupy an island," says Laveleye, in his work on "Primitive Property," "where we live on the fruits of our labor ; a shipwrecked man is thrown up by the sea : What is his right ? Can he say, invoking the unanimous opinion of jurisconsults: You have occupied the land by virtue of your title as human beings, because property is the condition of liberty and culture, a necessity of existence, a natural right ; but I also am a man, I also have a natural right to make a living ; I can, then, occupy with the same title with yourselves a corner of this ground, in order to live here by my labor?" 1 This parable is illustrated whenever a human child arrives in the world, with the addition that the child not only will presently want his corner of the earth in which to make a living, but immediately needs to be cared for and then to be reared to maturity before he can begin his self-support by labor. Shall we give him a place, or shall we push him back into the sea? Humanity says that he must be snatched from the waves, even at the cost of toil and risk of life. But 1 Laveleye, De la Propriete et de ses Formes Primitives, p. 393. 128 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. here is another mouth to feed and a new subdivision of wealth is inevitable. Evidently, we have before us a social fact that gives rise to important problems. Society has an interest in the growth of population, and, therefore, in the conditions and forms of marriage. 2. The relation of population to subsistence is regarded by Malthus as the central point of all social problems. 2 In this opinion most of the ortho- dox economists of England substantially concur. The doctrine of Malthus is, that population tends to increase in a geometrical ratio, while the food-supply tends to increase in an arithmetical ratio. In plainer terms, while in four generations of men population tends to repeat itself sixteen times, the food-supply tends to repeat itself only four times. The critics who have attempted to answer Malthus's great and epoch-making " Essay on the Principle of Popula- tion " have often done that worthy clergyman the grossest injustice, condemning his doctrine as essen- tially "immoral" and "infamous," without appre- hending his pure and philanthropic motives ; and pronouncing his principle " false," without even understanding it. Malthus nowhere says that popu- lation and food-supply do actually increase and vary in these ratios, but that they tend to do so. All evi- dence that they do not so vary which ignores the tendency, and appeals only to the actual state of the case, simply misses the mark. His book is largely occupied in showing why they do not thus vary in 2 Malthus's Essay on the Principle of Population. CHRISTIANITY AND MARRIAGE. I2Q reality, and the reasons are the presence in human history of war, pestilence, and other depopulating causes. These, it is to be hoped, will in time be abolished. What, then, is to prevent the tendency from realizing itself in fact, by a growth of popula- tion out of proportion to the growth of food-supply ? Malthus answers : " Preventive checks, such as abstention from marriage and temperance in mar- riage." His remedy for poverty is "prudential restraint " in augmenting the race. If there are not too many mouths to feed, there will be bread enough for all. Such a doctrine is not to be silenced with abuse, for it is evidently based on laws of nature and principles of logic. 3. The Malthusian remedy for poverty and distress is, then, the limitation of marriages, first by public opinion and then by law. Let us examine the foun- dations upon which the theory rests as an exposition of the cause and cure of poverty. Overpopulation, if it existed anywhere, would certainly cause poverty. There are, no doubt, countries that are too populous for the general good ; that they are, is evident from the relief that follows emigration ; and yet, no doubt, even more relief might result from better forms of land-tenure and industrial life. The objec- tion offered to Malthusianism by Henry George, 3 that the greater the number of producers the greater will be the wealth produced, does not meet the case ; for it disregards the law of diminishing returns in the cultivation of the soil, which must somewhere be 3 George's Progress and Poverty, chap. iv. I30 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. reached by the growth of population. That it has been nowhere reached is irrelevant to the question. It is absurd to say that there cannot be too many people to the acre. Nor does the answer of Herbert Spencer, 4 that such pressure of population would result in the elimination of the weak and feeble, and thus improve the race, constitute an answer to Mal- thus. Even though this struggle for existence should result in the survival of the fittest, there is no assur- ance that all might not be deteriorated by the hard- ships of the competition, as all are in Tierra del Fuego. The just and true criticism upon Malthusi- anism relates both to its assumptions and its reme- dies. That theory assumes that the reproductive power will continue to act in geometrical ratio ; whereas we know that as organisms rise in the scale of existence reproductive energy is lost. Irish peasants have large families ; but the aristocratic families, with abundance, frequently become extinct. It assumes also that the food-supply is capable only of arithmetical increase, whereas scientific agriculture is continually refuting this supposition. Men are better fed to-day, in all civilized lands, than they were when Malthus wrote, notwithstanding the vast increase in numbers. In truth, it requires a dense population to develop natural resources and a nation's wealth consists in its men not less than in its terri- tory. With regard to remedies, Malthusianism, in attempting to cure one evil, creates a worse. In France, where the doctrine of "prudential restraint" 4 Spencer's Principles of Biology, vol. ii, part vi, chap. xiii. CHRISTIANITY AND MARRIAGE. 131 has been most widely accepted, we see statesmen and physiologists and moralists alike deploring the consequences, while in Paris marriages have de- creased, the institution of vice is legally established, and one third of the children are born outside of the bonds of wedlock. 5 Even in Bavaria, where marriage is legally made difficult, there is an exceedingly large percentage of illegitimates. 6 If vice is worse than poverty, Malthusianism is not its best remedy. Nature has secured the perpetuation of the species by instincts too powerful to be annihilated or effect- ually restrained by legislation, or even entirely by the individual will. If children are not born in the shelter of the home and under the care of responsi- ble parents, they will be thrown into life without other protection than society is prepared to provide, either by law or charity. 4. The fear of poverty is not the most potent restraint upon the practices of men. The proletarian indulges the hope that some of his children may prosper and be of service to him in his declining years. His very name signifies his proclivity. Upon him, therefore, the Malthusian doctrine has but little influence. A stronger motive to abstinence from mar- riage is found in that pessimism that regards life as a scene of suffering and its end an escape from misery. Buddha was its great apostle in the East, and though his millions of disciples professed to 6 The whole subject is discussed, with valuable recent statistics, by Dr. Abel Joire, La Population, Paris, 1885. 6 W. Graham's The Social Problem, chap. iii. 132 SOCIAL INFLUENCE OF CHRISTIANITY. believe that life is an evil, and marriage, which is its foundation, is a source of sorrow, the swarming pop- ulations of Buddhist countries testify to the impo- tency of this religious hostility to life in crushing out the instinct to render it perpetual. The country of Schopenhauer and Von Hartmann is the most prolific in Europe, in spite of the pessimism which their philosophy inculcates. The same pessimism that censures marriage commends suicide, and the prohibi- tion of the first is about as rational and effective as the recommendation of the other.