THE GOYERNMENTS OF FEANCE, ITALY, AND GERMANY BY A. LAWRENCE LOWELL, LL.D., Ph.D. President of Harvard University CAMBEIDGE HARVARD UNIVERSITY PRESS LONDON: HUMPHREY MILFORD OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS 1914 r s\ COPYRIGHT, 1896, I914, BY A. LAWRENCE LOWELL NOV 23 1914 ©CI.A388560 PREFACE This volume is an abridgment of the author's Governments and Parties in Continental Europe, published in 1897. It has been prepared in order that certain portions of the latter, particularly those dealing with the framework of government in France, Italy and Germany, may be more easily used in college classes. Some changes have been made in the text, but only where the legislation of the last seventeen years has changed the actual machinery of government. Matters of opinion are left as they were in the original edition. CONTENTS CHAPTER I FRANCE : INSTITUTIONS PA8B Origin and nature of parliamentary government in England . . 2 The system imperfectly copied on the Continent ... 6 The French constitutional laws ....... 7 History of their creation . , 8 The method of amendment 12 Their legal and moral effect ....... 13 V The Chamber of Deputies 14 V The method of election, scrutin de liste and scrutin d'arrondisse- ment ........... 15 The Chamber a tumultuous body . o .... 18 '' The Senate . 19 Its functions and actual influence 21/ The ministers as a rule not responsible to it . . . . 22 The National Assembly 26 ' The President of the Republic 26 V His functions 27 ■ His powers really exercised by responsible ministers . . 28 The Council of State ......... 30 The ministers 32 \y^ Their responsibility to the Chamber of Deputies . . .33 Their enormojjs^jjower (which is due to the four following mat- ters) 7' "'. '. 33 The paternal nature of the government ...... 34 The centralization of local government ...... 36 The department, with its prefect and general council . . 36 The arrondissement and the canton ..... 40 The commune, with its mayor and communal council . .40 Paris and Lyons ......... 42 The legislative powers of the executive 43 Ordinances and appropriations . . . e s • 44 CONTENTS V The judicial powers of the executive '^7 Difference between English and French history ... 47 In England the royal power grew early and took a judicial form . 48 In France it developed late and took an administrative form 61 Effect of the doctrine of the separation of powers ... 54 Questions of the legality of official acts withdrawn from the ordinary courts ...•••••"'' The administrative courts and the court of conflicts . 67 The state of siege • • • ^3 Effect of the French system on the position of the ministers . 64 Note on Gneist's views on English and French history . . . 65 CHAPTER II FRANCE : PARTIES 69 70 72 74 76 76 81 82 84 87 90 93 The influence of parties in popular government . The parliamentary system normally produces two parties It cannot work well otherwise .... In France there are many parties or groups Causes of the subdivision of parties .... Lack of a political consensus Theoretical character of French political opinions . Lack of the habit of political organization The election of the deputies by majority vote The system of committees in the Chambers .... This undermines the authority of the cabinet and its ability to hold the majority together "The use of interpellations This has a similar effect 9* It is due to jealousy of the ministers Results of the subdivision of parties A change of ministry does not mean change of party The cabinets short-lived As a rule they are coalitions and therefore weak They must confer favors on the deputies to win votes . The deputies in turn must curry favor with the local nominating committees and the constituents • Prospects of the Republic Since the Revolution there has been no change of the party in power without a revolution 114: Possible organic changes 100 103 103 104 105 106 108 113 117 vi CONTENTS CHAPTER III ITALY : INSTITUTIONS i The formation of the kingdom 120 The Statuto 122 The King 126 ''"•■'■' The ministers 127 ^, The Senate 128 ^ The Chamber of Deputies 130 The franchise, the method of election, etc. .... 131 The administrative system 135 The ordinance power 139 The civil service ......... 140 Local government .......... 142 The judicial system 144 The courts and the officials 145 Administrative law and the administrative courts .• . . 147 Weakness of the judicial system .... . . 150 The church 152 The doctrine of a free church in a free state .... 153 The monastic orders . 155 The Pope, and the law of the Papal Guarantees . . . 157 Embarrassing situation of the Vatican 159 CHAPTER IV GERMANY : THE STRUCTURE OF THE EMPIRE The Holy Roman Empire ... .... 164 The growth of Prussia 165 The Germanic Confederation and the Diet 166 The failure of the Liberal attempt at union in 1848-49 . . 168 Bismarck and the war of 1866 171 The North German Confederation and the Empire . . . 172 The constitution .......... 174 Nature of the federal union ........ 175 Legislative centralization and executive decentralization . . 175 Inequality of rights among the members .... 178 The privileges of Prussia 178 The privileges of the other states 181 The Reichstag : its composition 184 Its powers 188 CONTENTS Vll The Bundesrath : its composition Its character and the position of the members Its internal organization ....... Its powers and privileges Its actual influence The Emperor . Interlacing of his powers as Emperor and as King of Prussia The Chancellor He is not responsible to the Reichstag .... His functions and substitutes The judicial system : The Reichsgericht Power of the courts to hold statutes unconstitutional General character of the federal system 191 194 197 199 204 205 207 208 210 211 213 214 216 THE GOVERNMENTS OF FRANCE, ITALY, AND GERMANY FRANCE THE GOVERNMENTS OF FRANCE, ITALY, AND GERMANY CHAPTER I. FRAlfCE : INSTITUTIONS. In order to understand the government of a country it is not enough to know the bare structure of its insti- tutions. It is necessary to follow the course of politics ; to inquire how far the various pubHc bodies exercise the authority legally vested in them ; and to try to discover the real sources of power. It is necessary, in short, to study the actual working of the system ; and although this depends chiefly upon the character, the habits, and the traditions of the people, it is also influenced in no small measure by details, like the method of voting, the procedure in the legislative chambers, and other mat- ters, that are too often overlooked on account of their apparent insignificance. Now in several of the states on the Continent of Europe the main features of repre- sentative government have been copied directly or indi- rectly from English models, while the details have grown up of themselves, or are a survival from earlier tradi- tion. It is not surprising, therefore, that the two are 2 FRANCE. more or less inconsistent with each other, and that this want of harmony has had a pronounced effect on pubHc life. Although most people to-day are familiar with the ParUament- parHameutary system of government as it has ^ITn''''' developed in England, it may not be out of England. place to givc a brief description of it here on account of the profound influence it has had in other countries. The Middle Ages gave birth to two political ideas. The first of these was a division of the people into separate classes or estates, each of which had independ- ent political functions of its own. The second was representative government, or the election — by those estates whose members were too numerous to assemble in a body — of deputies authorized to meet together and act for the whole estate. The number of these estates, and the number of separate chambers in which their representatives sat, varied in the different coun- tries of Europe ; ^ but it so happened that in England aU the political power of the estates became in time vested in two chambers.^ One of them, the House of Lords, contained the whole body of peers, who were the 1 Thus in France, and in most continental countries, there were three, while in Sweden there were four : the clergy, the nobles, the cities, and the peasants. The existence of only two Houses in England might almost be called an accident. (Cf . Freeman, Growth of the English Constitution^ p. 93.) 2 In 1664 Convocation, which was the ecclesiastical chamber, discon-. tinned the practice of voting separate taxes on the clergy, and thus the clergy definitely ceased to be an estate of the realm. (See Hallaniy Const. Hist, of England^ chap, xvi.) ORIGIN OF PAELIAMENTARY GOVERNMENT. 3 successors of the great feudal vassals of the Crown ; while the other, the House of Commons, was composed of the deputies from the towns and counties, who had gradually consolidated into a single house, and might be said to represent all the people who were not peers. By degrees the House of Commons acquired the right of originating all bills for raising or spending money, and hence its support became essential to the Crown. But its members were independent, and on the whole less open to court influence than the peers. They felt under no obligation to support the policy of the government, or to vote an appropriation unless they understood and approved the purpose for which it was to be used; and King William III., during his wars with France, found them by no means as easy to man- age as he could wish. Hitherto his ministers had been selected from both political parties, and hence were not in harmony with each other, and were unable to exert an effective influence in Parliament ; but between 1693 and 1696 he dismissed the Tories, and confided all the great offices of state to the Whigs, who had a majority in the Commons. The result was that the House which had been turbulent became docile; and the ministers by winning its confidence were able to guide it, and obtain the appropriations that were required. This was the origin of the practice of selecting the ministers from the leaders of the majority in Parliament, — a practice which at a later time crystaUized into a principle of the British Constitution.* But of course men who held the most important offices, and at the same time led the 1 Macaulay, History of England^ chap. xx. 4 FRANCE. House of Commons, were certain not to be mere toola in the hands of the King. They were sure to try to carry out their own policy, and when the sceptre of William had passed into the hands of the first two Georges, who were foreigners and took little interest in EngHsh politics, the ministers exercised the royal power as they pleased, and became in fact the custodians of the prerogatives of the Crown. The subordination of the King to his ministers is, indeed, the inevitable re- sult of the system ; for so long as the latter retain their influence over the House, and can direct its votes, they can hold their offices and administer them according to their own views. If the King attempts to dismiss them they can block the wheels of government, by inducing Parliament to withhold supplies ; and if, on the other hand, they cease to be the leaders of the House, and a different party with new leaders gets a majority, the King finds himself obliged to send for these and intrust the government to them. The system which had been devised in order that the King might control the House of Commons became, therefore, the means by which the House of Commons, through its leaders, controlled the King, and thus all the power of the House of Commons and of the Crown became vested in the same men, who guided legislation and took charge of the administration at the same time. The House of Lords, meanwhile, was losing ground. It had no right to initiate or amend money bills, and, what was far more important, it had no influence on the formation or the policy of the cabinet. The ministers were, indeed, often peers, but they were not selected NATURE OF PARLIAMENTARY GOVERNMENT. 5 because they belonged to the majority in the House of Lords, nor did they resign when that body voted against them. Like their colleagues from the other House, they represented the majority in the Commons, and were solidly in accord with it. The House of Lords, there- fore, found itself confronted by the combined power of the Crown and the House of Commons, and this it was unable to resist. In fact the power to create new peers furnished the Crown, or rather the ministers acting in its name, with a weapon always ready to break an obstinate resistance, and at the time of the Reform Bill of 1832 a threat of this kind was enough to compel submission. The Upper House has thus gradually lost authority, until now it does not venture to reject any measure on which the cabinet is really in earnest, — unless perchance, as in the case of the recent Home Rule bill, it is convinced that the House of Commons does not fairly represent the people, and that a new election would result in a victory for the party in oppo- sition. In such a case the refusal to pass the measure is tantamount to a demand for a Referendum.^ The ministers remain in office only so long as they continue to be the leaders of the Lower House and are able to control the majority. When this condition has changed, a vote is sometimes passed to the effect that the ministers have ceased to possess the confidence of the House ; but such an express declaration is rarely used ^ It is a curious fact that the Premier of New South Wales has recently proposed to prevent deadlocks between the Houses by providing that after a bill has been rejected once by the Legislative Council and again passed by the Assembly, the Council shall not have power to reject it a second time, but may require it to be submitted to popular vote. A sim- ilar proposal has been discussed iu Belgium. 6 FRANCE. at the present day, and a hostile vote on any matter ol considerable importance is treated as a proof that the government has no longer the support of a majority. After such a vote, therefore, the ministers resign, and if there is a normal division into two parties the Crown sends for the leader of the opposition, and intrusts him with the formation of a cabinet. The defeated minis- ters have, however, one other alternative. If they think that the House of Commons has ceased to be in har- mony with the opinion of the nation, they can dissolve Parhament in the name of the Crown, and try the chance of a new election. Thus in the English parlia- mentary system the direction of the legislature, and the control of the executive, is in the hands of the leaders of the majority in the House of Commons. For their exercise of power these leaders are directly responsi- ble to the House of Commons, which can call them to account at any time ; while the House itself is responsi- ble to the people, which gives its verdict whenever the end of the term of Parliament or a dissolution brings about a general election. Turning now from the consideration of English forms Parliament- ^^ govcmment to tliosc in use on the Con- menro^n the tiucnt, wc find that the main features of the Continent, gpi^ig}^ Coustitutiou havc bccu vcry generally imitated. In fact, the plan of two chambers, one of which issues from an extended suffrage and has the primary control of the purse, and of a cabinet whose members appear in the chambers and are jointly respon- sible to the more popular one, so that all the ministers resign on an adverse vote of that chamber, is of Eng- ENGLISH SYSTEM IMPERFECTLY COPIED. 7 lish or-igin, and has spread widely over Europe. These features of the parliamentary system are striking, and have become famous, while the procedure in the House of Commons, which enables the system to work smoothly, has attracted far less attention, and has been followed very little. This is peculiarly true of France, where the principle of cabinet responsibility has been adopted to the fullest extent, but where there exist at the same time several practices that help to twist parliamentary government out of the normal form. More curious still is the fact that these very practices have been blindly copied by other countries which intended to imitate the English system. A description of the French government must begin with its structure, with the legal composition OutHne of and powers of the different political bodies. secoShap^ This will occupy the present chapter. In the ^^^' next, the actual working of the system will be consid- ered, especially in regard to the character of poHtical parties ; and an attempt will be made to explain the peculiarities that are found by a reference to the condi- tion of the people, and to those parts of the poHtical machinery that seem to have a marked effect. In other words, we shall begin with the skeleton, and then take up the muscles and nerves. The first thing one looks for in a modern government is the constitution ; but althoug-h the French . . . The French Republic has a constitution, it differs in two Constitu- very important respects from those to which we are accustomed. It is not comprised in any one document, but in a series of distinct laws, and it 8 FRANCE. contains few provisions limiting the functions of the different bodies, or prescribing fundamental rights which the state is enjoined to respect. This is a depart- ure not only from American, but also from the earher French usage, for previous constitutions in France have been long documents and have contained elaborate bills of rights ; although the absence of practical guar- antees has made their effectiveness depend upon the good pleasure of the government. The present consti- tution is very different, and barely provides for the organization of the powers of the state, without even speaking of such important matters as a yearly budget or the tenure of office of the judges. It does Httle more than establish the main framework of the govern- ment by declaring what the chief organs of public life shall be, leaving them almost entirely free to exercise their authority as they see fit. The reason for such a departure from French traditions is to be found in the circumstances of the case. The earlier constitutions in France were attempts to frame an ideal system, but the present one resulted from an immediate need of pro- viding a regular government of some sort that could rule the country for the time, and was drawn up by men who had no behef in its inherent perfection. To understand this it is necessary to glance at the history of the period. The rapid series of defeats suffered by the French History of armics at the hands of the Germans, in 1870, its creation, destroyed the tottering authority of the empire, and as soon as the news of the surrender of Napoleon III. at Sedan reached Paris an insurrection THE CONSTITUTION. 9 broke out on the fourth of September. The republic was at once proclaimed, but this was no time to debate plans for a constitution, and so long as the war lasted the country was ruled by the self -elected Government of the National Defense. When the war was over, a National Assembly with indefinite powers was chosen by universal suffrage. The member of this body who commanded the most general public confidence was Thiers, the historian, and former minister of Louis Phihppe. To him the Assembly intrusted the execu- tive power, and in August, 1871, it gave him the title of President, without, however, fixing any term for the duration of the of&ce. Thiers was constantly urged to introduce the parliamentary system by allowing his ministers to assume the responsibihty for his acts, but this he refused to do, saying that the position in which it would place him, although perfectly consistent with the dignity of an hereditary king, was for him, a little hourgeois, entirely out of the question.^ He held him- self, however, personally responsible to the Assembly for the conduct of his government, took part in the debates on the measures he proposed, and declared that he was ready to resign at any time, i£ the majority wanted him to do so.^ This state of things continued * The law of Aug. 31, 1871, declared that the President as well as the ministers should be responsible to the Assembly. See Dupriez, Les Mi^ nistres dans les Principaux Pays d' Europe et d"" Amerique, vol. ii. p. 320. 2 The law of March 13, 1873, abolished the right of the President tt take part in debate, and while allowing him to address the Assembly^ ordered the sitting to be suspended immediately after his speech. Thi^ was, of course, an attempt to reduce the personal influenca of Thier^ (Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 321-22.) 10 FRANCE. for nearly two years, when a hostile vote forced Thiers to retire. His successor, Marshal MacMahon, was elected for a term of seven years, and as the new President was not a member of the Assembly, his cabi- net became responsible in the parliamentary sense. But although the chief magistrate now held office for a fixed period, and was freed from the caprices of an uncertain majority, still there was no constitution and no permanent organization of the government. The situation was, in fact, a provisional one, prolonged ab- normally by the strange condition of politics. The monarchists formed a majority of the Assembly, but they were hopelessly divided into two sections, — the Legitimists, whose candidate was the Comte de Cham- bord, and the Orleanists, who followed the Comte de Paris. At one moment it seemed not impossible that the Comte de Chambord might become king, and some of his supporters opened negotiations for the purpose ; but these were brought to nothing by obstinacy of the Prince himself, who was a true scion of his race, and would not yield one jot of his pretensions. He even refused to accept the tricolor flag that means so much to Frenchmen, and clung doggedly to the ancient white standard of his house. Under such circumstances, a monarchy was out of the question, and so this assembly The Constitu- ^^ mouarchists at last set to work to organize tionai Laws, g^ republic J or rather a sufficient number of monarchists, feeling that a republic was, for the time at least, inevitable, joined with the minority to estab- lish a government on the only basis possible.^ But 1. Very good brief descriptions of the formation of the Constitution THE CONSTITUTION. 11 although the republican form was adopted, the institu- tions that were set up departed essentially from the ideas which the French had been accustomed to asso- ciate with that term. The present government, like all political systems that have been created suddenly and have proved lasting, was essentially a compromise. From the French repubHcan principles there was bor- rowed, besides the name, little more than the election of the chief magistrate, while from the traditions of con- stitutional monarchy were taken the irresponsibility of the head of the state, and the existence of a second legislative chamber.^ Now it was natural that no one should feel inchned to construct an ideal system on a hybrid foundation of this kind. Moreover none of the parties regarded the work of the Assembly as final, for the monarchists looked forward to a future restoration of the throne, while their adversaries hoped to place the republic before long on a more secure and perma- nent footing. Hence the Assembly did no more than provide for the immediate organization of the govern- ment in as brief and practical a manner as possible. It passed three constitutional laws, as they are called, which are in the form of ordinary statutes, and very may be found in Bozdrlan's Etude sur la Revision de la Constitution, and in Professor Currier's Constitutional and Organic Laws of France. The latter, published as a supplement to the Annals of the American Academy of Political Science (March, 1893), gives a translation into English of all these laws. See also an article by Saleilles on the " Development of the Present Constitution of France." (^Ann. Amer. Acad, of Pol. Sci., July, 1895.) ^ Lebon, Frankreich (in Marquardseu's HandhucTi des Oeffentlichen Bechts), p. 19. 12 FRANCE. short and concise. One of them, that of February 25, 1875, provides for the organization of the powers of the state. Another, that of February 24, 1875, deals in erreater detail with the orgcanization of the Senate. And the third, dated July 16, 1875, fixes the relations of the powers of the state among themselves. The provisional character of the constitution is clearly Amend- SG&T^ in the method of amendment. It has ments. hccn the habit in France to make a sharp dis- tinction between the constituent and legislative powers, the former being withdrawn to a greater or less extent from the control of the Parliament. But in this in- stance both of the great parties wanted to facilitate changes in the fundamental laws, in order to be able to carry out their own plans whenever a favorable occasion might present itself.^ A departure from tradition was therefore made, and it was provided that the constitu- tional laws could be amended by a National Assembly, or Congress, composed of the two branches of Parlia- ment sitting together, which should meet for this pur- pose whenever both chambers on their own motion, or on that of the President of the Republic, declared the need of revision.^ The constitutional laws have been ^ Cf . Borgeaud, Eiahlissement et Revision des Constitutions, pt. iii. liv. zL ch. viii. 2 Const. Law of Feb. 25, 1875, Art. 8. It is not provided whether the Chambers shall declare in general terms that there is a need of revision, or whether they shall specify the revision to be made, and this point has given rise to lively debates; but on the two occasions when a revision was actually undertaken, the Chambers passed identical resolutions specifying the articles to be amended. (Lebon, Frankreichy pp. 74, 75 ; Saleilles, op. cit. pp. 6, 7, 9.) THE CONSTITUTION. 13 twice amended in this way. On the first occasion (June 21, 1879), the provision making Versailles the capital was repealed, and thereupon a statute was passed transferring the seat of government to Paris.^ On the second occasion (August 14, 1884), several amendments were made. Among these one of the most notable changed the provisions relating to the mode of electing senators, and another declared that the repubhcan form of government cannot be made the subject of proposal for revision, — the object of the latter being to prevent the destruction of the RepubHc by constitutional means. The device of providing that a law shall never be repealed is an old one, but I am not aware that it has ever been of any avail. This method of amendment has virtually rendered the Parliament omnipotent, for excepting the provision about changing the republican form of government, there is no restriction on its authority. The Chambers cannot, it is true, pass an amendment to the consti- tutional laws in the form of an ordinary statute, but if they are agreed they can pass it by meeting as a National Assembly. The power of the Chambers is therefore nearly as absolute as that of the British Par- liament.^ The principle, moreover, that the funda- mental law cannot be changed by ordinary statute is devoid of legal sanction, for if the Chambers should choose to pass an act of this kind, no court or official could legally prevent its appKcation.^ But while the * Law of July 22, 1879. This act provides, however, that the National Assembly shall meet at Versailles. ^ Cf. Saleilles, op. cit., p. 11. ^ Cf. Laferrifere, Traite de la Jurisdiction Administrative, vol. ii. p. 5. 14 FRANCE. constitution imposes no legal restraint on tlie Parlia- ment, it would be a great mistake to suppose that it had no effect. On the contrary, it has such moral force that any attempt to pass a statute that clearly violated its terms would awake a strong repugnance ; and indeed a suggestion by the president of one or other of the Chambers that a bill would be unconstitutional has more than once sufficed to prevent its introduction.^ On the other hand, the fact that formal amendments can be made only in joint session, and only after both Chambers have resolved that there is a need of revision, has some influence in preventing changes in the text of the constitutional laws, because the Senate, being the more conservative body, and only half as large as the other House, is timid about going into joint session, not knowing what radical amendments may be proposed there, and fearing to be swamped by the votes of the deputies. Let us now examine the organs of the state in succession, taking up first the Parliament with its two branches, the Senate and the Chamber of Deputies ; then turning to the President as the chief magistrate of the Republic, and finally passing to the ministers as the connecting link between the Parliament and the Presi- dent, and the controlling factor in the machinery of the state. The composition of the Chamber of Deputies is left to ordinary legislation, except that the constitu- The Cham- . o-ni nr'-iorrr'A berof Depu- tional law 01 February 25, 1875, Art. 1, pro- vides for its election by universal suffrage. By 1 Lebon, Frankreich, p. 23. * THE CHAMBER OF DEPUTIES. 15 statute the ballot is secret, and the franchise extends to all men over twenty-one years of age who have not been deprived of the right to vote in consequence of a con- viction for crime, and who are not bankrupts, under guardianship, or in active military or naval service.^ To be eligible a candidate must be twenty-five years old and not disquaHfied from being a voter.^ Members of families that have ever reigned in France are, however, excluded;^ and in order to prevent as far as possible the use of pressure the law forbids almost every state official to be a candidate in a district where his position might enable him to influence the election.^ As a fur- ther safeguard against the power of the administration, which is justly dreaded by the French Liberals, it is provided that all public servants who receive salaries, except a few of the highest in rank, shall lose their offices if they accept an election to Parliament, and that a deputy who is appointed even to one of these highest offices, unless it be that of minister or under-secretary, shall lose his seat.^ The Chamber of Deputies is elected for four years, and consists at present of five hundred and The method ninety-seven members ; ten of the seats being °* election. distributed among the various colonies, and six allotted to Algiers, while the remaining deputies are chosen in 1 Arts. 1, 2, and 5 of the Law of Nov. 30, 1875. Poudra et Pierre, Droit Parlementaire, sects. 482-84, 498-514. 2 Law of Nov. 30, 1875, Arts. 6, 7. 3 Law of June 16, 1885, Art. 4. 4 Law of Nov. 30, 1875, Art. 12. ^ Id., Arts. 8, 9, and 11. A deputy appointed to one of these offices may, however, be reelected (Art. 11} • 16 FRANCE. France. ^ The method of election has varied from time to time between that of single^lectoral dis* lis^e and ^ tricts, a system called the scruHn_d[arr on;' dWron- dissementy and that of the scrutin de liste, which consists in the choice^ all the deputies^ from each department on a general ticket^ the difference beinof the same that exists between our method of elect- ing congressmen each in a separate district, and our method of choosing presidential electors on a single ticket for the whole State. The scrutin d^arrondissement or single district system prevailed from 1876 to 1885, when ihe scrutin de liste was revived;^ partly, no doubt, in order to swamp the reactionary minority, but also with the hope of withdrawing the deputies from the pressure of petty local interests, which had become lamentably strong, of getting a Chamber of broader and more national views, and of forming a Republican majority that would be more truly a great and united party. The experiment did not last long enough to produce any sensible effect of this kind ; and indeed the change seems, on the whole, to have resulted in an increase of the power of the local politicians, who formed themselves into nominating and electoral committees for the depart- ment. At the general elections of 1885 the Reaction- aries gained rather than lost seats in spite of the scrutin de liste; and the disgust of the Republicans with the device from which they had hoped so much was brought to its height two or three years later, by General Bou- langer. This singular man, who, after enjoying a mar- velous popularity, became in a short time an object of 1 Law of Juns 16, 1885. THE CHAMBER OF DEPUTIES. IT contempt, if not of ridicule, had been minister of war in one of the recent Republican cabinets. He was forced to resign on account of his enormous expenditure on the army, and the fear that he would plunge the nation into a war with Germany. He then posed as the saviour of the country, and being at the height of his reputa- tion he made use of the scrutin de liste to hold a plebiscite or pop^ular vote of Prance piecemeal. \ When- ever a seat became vacant in a department he siood as a candidate, and if elected he held the seat only until a vacancy occurred in another department, when he resigned to appear as a candidate again. After doing this in several large departments he was able to declare that a considerable part of the French people had pro- nounced themselves on his side — a proceeding which would have been impossible if the deputies had been elected in five hundred and seventy-six separate dis- tricts. His success at the by-elections had so fright- ened the Republicans that they restored the scrutin _d^arro7tdissement or single electoral districts before the .general election of 1889 took place.^ Every large body of men, not under strict military discipline, has lurking in it the traits of a mob, and 1 Law of Feb. 13, 1889. In order to frustrate more effectually Bou- langer's scheme, a law of July 17, 1889, provided that no one should be candidate in more than one district. The meaning and effects of these laws is discussed by Saleilles (Ann. Am. Acad. Pol. ScL, July, 1895, pp. 19-37). A measure providing for the restoration of the scrutin de liste with an arrangement for proportional representation passed the Chamber of Deputies in 1912. For the arguments in its favor, see " Electoral Ke- form in France," by J. W. Garner, American Political Science Review, vii, pp. 610-38 (Nov., 1913). 18 FRANCE. is liable to occasional outbreaks when the spirit of dis- The Cham- o^^ler becoHies epidemic ; but the French muituous Chamber of Deputies is especially tumultuous, ^°^^' and, in times of great excitement, sometimes breaks into a veritable uproar. Even the method of preserving order lacks the decorum and dignity that one expects in a legislative assembly. The President has power to call a refractory member to order and impose a penalty in case he persists ; but instead of relying on this alone, he often tries to enforce silence by caustic remarks. The writer remembers being in the Chamber a few years ago when M. Floquet was presiding, — the same man who fought a duel with General Boulang-er and wounded him in the throat. A deputy who had just been speaking kept interrupt- ing the member who was addressing the Chamber, and when called to order made some remark about parlia- mentary practice. The President cried out, " It is not according to parliamentary practice for one man to speak all the time." " I am not speaking all the time," said the deputy. " At this moment you are overbear- ing everybody," answered the President. This incident is related, not as being unusual or humorous, but as a fair sample of what is constantly occurring in the Chamber. Even real sarcasm does not seem to be thought improper. Thus in a recent debate a deputy, in the midst of an unusually long speech, was con- tinually interrupted, when the President, Floquet, ex- claimed, " Pray be silent, gentlemen. The member who is speaking has never before approached so near to the question."^ These sallies from the chair are an 1 Journal Officiel of Nov. 18, 1892. THE SENATE. 19 old tradition in France, although, of course, their use depends on the personal character of the President. One does not, for example, find them at all in the reports of debates during the time Casimir-Perier was presiding over the Chamber. When the confusion gets beyond all control, and the President is at his wits' end, he puts on his hat, and if this does not quell the disturbance, he suspends the sitting for an hour in order to give time for the excitement to subside. The IlfenchSenaLte consists of three hundred mem* y bers, and by the constitutional law of Feb- ruary 24, 1875, two hundred and twenty-five of these were to be elected for nine years by the depart- ments, while seventy-five were appointed for life by the same National Assembly that framed that law. The life senators were intended to be a permanent feature of the Senate, and it was provided that when any of them died his successor should be elected for life by the Sen- ate itself. A few years later, however, the Republi- cans, thinking such an institution inconsistent with democracy, passed the amendment to the constitutional laws, to which a reference has already been made.^ This, while leaving untouched the provisions relating to the existence and powers of the Senate, took away the constitutional character from those regulating the elec- tion of senators, which thus became subject to change by ordinary legislation. A statute was then passed (December 9, 1884) providing that as fast as the life senators died their seats should be distributed among the departments, so that nowadays all the senators 1 Const. Law of Aug. 14, 1884. ^.^ 20 , t . ^U« , FRANCE. alike are elected in ^he same way. There are eighty- six departments in Fiance, and the senators are appor- tioned by the act amon§ them according to population. Since the abolition of l^e senatorships, the number of seats belonging to a department varies from two up to ten, while the territory d| Belfort, each of the three departments of Algiers, and "several of the colonies are represented by one senator ap^iece.^ The senators so elected hold of&ce for nine ye^s, one_third^^tiring every three years.^ They are chjiaaes i^ each depart- ment of France by_a^ electoral college compLO&ed^,oi. the^ de^gutiesj of thd^ members of the general_cpunciV. of thfe^inembers of the councils of the arrondisaements, and of delegates chosen by the municipal councils--of- the communes of towns.^ Before 1884 each commune elected only one delegate,* but by the law of that year the number of delegates increases with the size of the communes, though much less than in proportion to the population. These communal delegates form a large majority of the electoral college, and hence the Senate was called by Gambetta the Great Council of the Com- munes of France.^ A senator must be forty years old ; and since the law of 1884 the disqualifications for this office have been the same as for that of member of the Chamber of Deputies.^ 1 Law of Dec. 9, 1884, Art. 2. 2 Id., Art. 7. 3 Id., Art. 6. 4 Const. Law of Feb. 24, 1875, Art. 4. ^ Saleilles, op. cit., p. 41. ^ Law of Dec. 9, 1884, Arts. 4, 5, and Provisions Temporaires. Law of Dec. 26, 1887. Lebon, Frankreich, pp. 63, 64, 67. THE SENATE. 21 The legislative power of the Senate and the Chamber of Deputies is the same, except that financial itsfunc- bills must originate in the latter ; ^ but while *^^°^' it is admitted that the Senate may reduce proposals for taxes and appropriations, there is a dispute whether it can increase them or not, and debates on this point are constantly recurring. In practice the Chamber has some- times accepted augmentations thus introduced, but more frequently the Senate has abandoned them.^ The Senate has two peculiar functions. First, its consent is neces- sary for a dissolution of the Chamber of Deputies,^ a provision designed as a safeguard against the President, who might otherwise dissolve the Chamber in order to attempt a coup d'etat during its absence ; and, second, the President is authorized, with the approval of the Council of Ministers, to constitute the Senate a high court to try any one for an attempt on the safety of the state.* This power was used in the case of General Boulanger, who failed to appear for trial, and was con- demned in his absence. With such an organization and powers, an American might suppose that the Senate would be a ^u actual more influential body than the Chamber of ™^^^^<^®- 1 Const. Law of Feb. 24, 1875, Art. 8. 2 Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 430-32. 3 Const. Law of Feb. 25, 1875, Art. 5. < Lebon, Frankreich, p. 73, Const. Laws of Feb. 24, 1875, Art. 9, and July 16, 1875, Art. 12. The procedure was regulated by a law of Aug. 10, 1889. By the Const. Law of July 16, 1875, Art, 12, the Chamber of Deputies can impeach the ministers, and in case of high treason the President of the Republic. The impeachments are tried by the Senate. For the interpretation put upon this clause, see Lebon, Frankreich, pp. 65^8. 22 FEANCE. Deputies ; but in reality it is by far tlie weaker body of the two, although it contains at least as much po- litical ability and experience as the other House, and, indeed, has as much dignity, and is composed of as impressive a body of men as can be found in any legislative chamber the world over. The fact is that according to the traditions of the parliamentary system the cabinet is responsible only to the more popular branch of the legislature, and in all but one of the instances where a cabinet in France has resigned on an adverse vote of the Senate, the vote was rather an excuse for the withdrawal of a discredited ministry than the cause of its resignation.^ The remaining case, which occurred during the year 1896, is the only one where the responsibility of the ministers to the Senate was fairly raised, and where anything like a real contest took place between the chambers. On this occasion the Senate did certainly force a united and vigorous cabinet to resign, but it was enabled to do so only because the ^ Dupriez (vol. ii. pp. 453-54) mentions two such cases. One in 1876, when the cabinet, disliking a bill for an amnesty passed by the Chamber of Deputies, proposed in the Senate a compromise, which the latter, averse to any amnesty, rejected. The ministers thereupon resigned, but they had really been beaten in the Chamber of Deputies, and their only hope of restoring their prestige lay in forcing through the compromise. The other case was in 1890, when the Senate by a vote condemning the economic policy of the government, brought about a cabinet crisis. But the ministry was already divided within itself, and had almost broken in pieces a few days before. There appears to have been a third instance of the same kind in 1883. In that case the Fallieres ministry resigned because the Senate rejected a bill on the expiilsion of members of families that had reigned in France, but here again the cabinet was disunited and in a feeble condition before the vote in the Senate took place. (Journal Officiel, Feb. 18 and 19, 1883.) THE SENATE. 23 majority in the Chamber of Deputies was highly pre- carious, for there can be no doubt that if the cabinet could have relied on the hearty support of the Chamber it would have defied the Senate as it had already done two months before.^ It has been only in very excep- 1 The history of this case may be summarized as follows : The Chamber of Deputies when elected contained a decided majority of Conservative Kepublicans, and for two years the successive cabinets represented their views, but by degrees the party became disintegrated, and in October, 1895, a Radical cabinet was formed, which succeeded in obtaining the support of a majority. Early in the new year the Minister of Justice, not being satisfied that the Juge d^ Instruction, who was holding the inquest on the southern railroad ffauds, was sufficiently zealous in discovering the offenders, took the case out of his hands and intrusted it to another magistrate. On February 11, the Senate, which was strongly conserva- tive, passed a vote censuring this act as an interference with the course of justice. Two days later, the Chamber of Deputies expressed its con- fidence in the government ; whereupon the Senate, on February 15, repeated its former vote. On the 20th, the matter was again brought up in the Chamber of Deputies, and M. Bourgeois, the head of the cabinet, declared that he should not resign so long as he was upheld by the Chamber, which proceeded to reaffirm its vote of the week before. A number of the senators who had been opposed to the cabinet, finding that it would not yield, read in the Senate next day a declaration protest- ing against the refusal of the ministers to hold themselves responsible to the Senate as a violation of the Constitution, but saying that while as senators they reserved their constitutional right, they did not wish to suspend the legislative life of the country. The Senate thereupon adopted an order of the day approving this declaration, and thus virtually gave up for a time the attempt to make the ministers responsible to itself. (Journal Officiel, Feb. 12, 14, 16, 21, and 22, 1896.) A little later the cabinet brought forward a bill for a progressive in- come tax, and succeeded on March 26 in getting the Chamber to adopt an order of the day approving of the general principal involved. The order, however, which was somewhat equivocal, was only carried by sixteen votes, and more than half of the deputies were believed to be opposed in their hearts to the tax. The Senate thought its opportunity had come, and again passed a vote of lack of confidence in the ministry, this time on the subject of foreign affairs. (Journal Officiel, April 4.) The result 24 FRANCE. tional cases, that the Upper House has upset the min- istry. Moreover the question at issue in the struggle of 1896 was not whether the cabinet is responsible to the Senate to the same extent that it is to the Chamber, but simply whether the Senate can insist on the removal of a ministry to which it is peculiarly hostile. No one has ever doubted that under ordinary circumstances the ministers are responsible only to the Chamber. The majority in that body alone is considered in the forma- tion of a cabinet, and an unfavorable vote there on any current matter of importance is followed by a change of ministers, while a similar vote in the Senate is not regarded as a reason for resignation.^ was no better than before, but the Senate felt the strength of its position, and was not to be ignored. On April 21, therefore, it took a bolder step by a resolution to postpone the vote on the credits asked for Madagascar "until it had before it a constitutional ministry having the confidence of the two Chambers." Instead of trying to continue the fight Bourgeois resigned, declaring to the Chamber of Deputies that as the representa- tive of universal suffrage it ought to be supreme, but that, owing to the impossibility of insuring proper military service in Madagascar after the vote of the Senate, patriotism obliged him to withdraw. The Radicals in the Chamber succeeded in carrying a vote affirming once more the preponderance of the elect of universal suffrage, and urging the need of democratic reforms ; but a few days later a purely Conservative cabinet presented itself to the Chamber, and obtained a vote of confidence by a majority of forty-three. (Journal Officiel, April 22, 24, and May 1.) The outcome of the affair justified the belief that the Chamber would not engage in a prolonged struggle to support the cabinet ; that while unwilling to turn the ministers out itself, it would not be sorry to have the Senate do so. Had the deputies been so thoroughly in earnest as to force a deadlock between the Chambers, the Senate could not have refused its consent to a dissolution, and would certainly have been obliged to give way if the elections had resulted in a victory for the cabinet. 1 Since this was written the Briand ministry resigned on a vote in the Senate in March, 1913. THE SENATE. 25 As a rule the Senate does not decide the fate of the ministries, and hence cannot control their policy. The result is that without sinking to the helplessness of the English House of Lords, it has become a body of sec- ondary importance.^ At one time it stood very low in public esteem, on account of its origin ; for it was created by the Reactionaries in the National Assembly, and was regarded as a monarchical institution ; and even after the greater part of its seats were occupied by Re- publicans, it was suspected of being only half-heartedly in favor of the republican form of government. Its condemnation of Boulanger increased its popularity by making it appear a real bulwark of the Republic against the would-be dictator; but the prejudice against it has by no means disappeared, and the ex- treme Radicals have never ceased to demand its abo- lition, although conservative feeling in France will doubtless remain strong enough to prevent such a step. How great the influence of the Senate will be in the future is not easy to foretell. Some people were of opinion that with life members gone, many of whom had been distinguished in letters, in science, or in war, it would lose a good deal of its prestige. To some extent this fear has been realized. But, on the other hand, men of mark are still elected, and now that the Senate is not afraid of being thought lukewarm or hostile to the Republic, and does not feel 1 In his Essays on Government (chap, i) the writer has tried to prove that this must necessarily be the condition of one of two chambers wher- ever the cabinet is responsible to the other ; and that the cabinet cannot in the long run be responsible to both. 26 FRANCE. its existence seriously threatened, it has acquired more boldness and energy.^ It is highly improbable, more- over, that it will become utterly powerless, so long as the deputies are divided into a number of political groups, and the ministers are not able to speak with authority as the leaders of a great and united party,. Although the Senate has little or no share in directing the policy of the cabinet, it must not be supposed that it is a useless body. On the contrary, it does very valua- ble work in correcting the over-hasty legislation of the other Chamber, and in case of disaerreement often has its own way or effects a compromise.^ The two Chambers meeting: in ioint session form what is called the National/Assembly, which, tionai as wc havc seen, has power to revise the con- Assembly. . . -'•'-.••. -.- ••• ■ ,,,,, ,.^-.., ... stitutional laws. It has one other function, that of electing the President of the Republic. This officer is chosen for seven years, and is re- dent of the eligible;^ the only limit on the choice of a candidate being" found in the constitutional law of August 14, 1884, which excludes all members of families that have ever reigned in France, —a pro- vision dictated by the fear that, like Napoleon III., a prince might use the presidency as a step to the throne. The President is at the head of the Republicy^ijt he lives and travels in a style that is almost XS^^y foi" the conception of a republic as severe, simple, ^id econom- ^ Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 382-83. The present position and the probable future of the Senate are discussed by Saleilles, op. cit., pp. 37-52. * Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 413-15. 8 Const. Law of Feb. 25, 1875, Art. 2. THE PRESIDENT. 27 ical has changed very much in France since the second Empire taught the nation extravagance/ The duties of the President, like those of evpy chief magistrate, are manifold. He is the executive Hisfunc- head of the nation, and as such executes the *'""^" laws, issues ordinances,^ and a,j)points all the officers o£ the sTOvernment.^ He has also certain functions of a legislative character, but, except for the right of initi- ative in legislation, these are not in fact very exten- sive. He has no veto upon the laws, and although he may require the Cliamhers to reconsider a bill, the right has never been exercised.* With the consent of the Senate he can dissolve ■.th£i. Chamber of Deputies/ but this power has also fallen into disuse, because the members of his cabinet are very much under the control of the deputies, who dread the risk and expense of an election ; and, in fact, a dissolution has not taken place since President MacMahon's unsuccessful attempt to use it in 1877 as a means of getting a Chamber in sym- pathy with his views. The President has power to make treaties ; but treaties of peace, of commerce, those which burden the finances, affect the persons or property of French citizens in foreign countries, or which change the territory of France (in other words, all the more im- ^ C£. G. Channes, Nos Fautes, Letter of Jan., 1885 ; Theodore Stan- ton in the Arena, Oct., 1891. ^ For the nature of this power, see pp. 42-44, infra, 8 Const. Law of Feb. 25, 1875, Art. 3. 4 Const. Law of July 16, 1875, Art. 7 ; Dupriez, vol. ii. p. 369. It is not likely to be used unless after the bill has passed the cabinet that favored it has resigned, and another hostile to it has come in. 5 Const. Law of Feb. 25, 1875, Art. 5. 28 FRANCE. portant ones), require tlie r^il^ification o£ the Chambers,! A declaration of war also requires their consent j ^ but as a matter of fact the government managed to wage war in Tunis and Tonquin without any such consent, alleging at first that the affair was not a war, and afterwards defending itself on the ground that the Par- liament by voting credits had virtually sanctioned its course.^ Unlike the President of the United States, the French President is not free to use his powers accord- His Powers • , i • • i , p • i , are reaUy lug to nis owu judgment, lor lu order to the ministers make him independent of the fate of cabi-, in his name. . nets, and at the same time to prevent his personal power from becomhig too great, the constitu- tional laws declare that he shall not be responsible for his official conduct, except in case of high treason, and that all his acts of every kind, to be valid, must be countersigned by one of the ministers ; and thus, like the British monarch, hejias been put under guardian-^^ ship and can do no wrong.* When, therefore, we speak of the p owers of the President, it must be remembered that these are really exercised by the ministers, who are responsible to the Chamber of Deputies. Tlie Presi-^ dent, indeed, is not usually present at the cabinet con- sultations {conseils de cabinet) in which the real policy of the government is discussed, and as a rule he pre- sides only over the formal meetings {conseils des mi' 1 Const. Law of July 16, 1875, Art. 8. a Id., Art. 9. ' See Lebon, Franlcreich, pp. 46, 47. * Const. Law of Feb. 25, 1875, Arts. 3 and 6. THE PRESIDENT. 29 nistres) held for certain purposes specified by law.^ He has power/it is true, to select the ministers, and in this matter he can use his own discretion to some extent, jijit^ in fact he generally intrusts some one with the forma- tion of a cabinet, ^nd appoints the ministers this man. suggests.'^ (His duty in these cases is not, how^ever, as I simple as that of the English King, because, for reasons I that will be discussed in the next chapter, there is usually 1:\ on the fall of a cabinet no leader of a victorious oppo- llsition to whom he can turn.j A good deal of tact and I skill is sometimes required at cabinet crises, and it is said that on one occasion the formation of a ministry was due to the personal influence of President Carnot.^ Sir Henry Maine makes merry over the exalted office and lack of power of the President. " There is," he says, " no living functionary who occupmg, a more pitia- ble position than a French President. (The old kings of France reigned and governed. The Constitutional King, according to M. Thiers, reigns, but does not govern. The President of the United States gov- erns, but he does not reign. It has been reserved for the President of ^he French Republic neither to reign nor yet to govern." ^ At first sight the situation does, indeed, appear some- what irrational. When the head of the state is desig- 1 Lebon, Frankreich, p. 53 ; Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 350-51 and 367- 68, states that the President is often present when important matters are discussed, but cannot influence the decision. 2 Dupriez, vol. ii. p. 340. 8 See " France under M. Constans," in Murray^s Magazine for May, 1890. * Popular Government, p. 250. 30 FRANCE. nated by the accident of birth it is not unnatural to make of him an idol, and appoint a high priest to speak in his name ; but when he is carefully selected as the man most fit for the place, it seems a trifle illo- gical to intrust the duties of the office to some one else. By the constitution of Sieyes an ornamental post of a similar character was prepared for the First Consul, but Napoleon said he had no mind to play the part of a pig kept to fatten. In government, however, the most logical system is not always the best, and the anoma- lous position of the President has saved France from the danger of his trying to make himself a dictator, while the fact that he is independent of the changing moods of the Chambers has given to the Republic a dignity and stability it had never enjoyed before. It is a curious commentary on the nature of human am- bition, that in spite of the small power actually wielded by the President in France, the presidential fever seems to have nearly as strong a hold on public men as in this country. Before proceeding to consider the ministers, there is The Conseil ^^® otlicr institution which claims attention d'Mat. ^^ account of its past rather than its present position. This is the Conseil d''Etat or Council of State,^ a body whose importance has varied a great deal 1 Aucoc, Conferences sur le Droit Adm., liv. ii. ch. i. § 3 ; Ducrocq, Cours de Droit Adm., tit. i. ch. i. sec. i. § iii. ; Bceuf, Resume' sur le Droit Adm., ed. of 1895, p. 32 et seq. ; cf. Lebon, Frankreich, pp. 96-98; Du- priez, vol. ii. pp. 285-316, passim, and pp. 481-92 ; Gooduow, Comparative Administrative Law, vol. i. pp. 107-13. See also articles entitled " Le Conseil d'Etat et les Projets de Rdforme," by Varagnac, Revue des Deux Mondes, Aug. 15 and Sept. 15, 1892. THE COUNCIL OF STATE. 31 at different times. Under Napoleon I., and again dur= ing the second Empire, in addition to the possession of executive functions, it was a real source of legislation ; while at the time of the Restoration and the Monarchy of July it became what it is to-day, a council with high attributes, but very little authority. Except as a court of administrative justice,^ it has now lost most of its influence ; for although it must be consulted before certain classes of ordinances can be issued, and may be consulted on other administrative matters, its advice need never be followed ; and in fact the habit of con- sulting it is said to have become httle more than a mere form.^ The legislative functions of the Council have faded even more completely to a shadow, as is proved by the fact that while the Government or either of the Chambers may seek its aid in the framing of statutes, the privilege is rarely exercised by the ministers, scarcely at all by the Senate, and never by the Chamber of Deputies. The members of the Council are divided into several classes, but those belonging to the most important class, and the only ones who can vote when the Council sits as a court, are appointed and dismissed at will by the President of the Republic.^ ^ For its functions of this nature, see pp. 55-61, infra. ^ "La Rdforme Administrative — La Justice," by Vicomte d'Avenel, Revue des Deux Mondes, June 1, 1889, pp. 597-98. ^ The other members are also appointed by the President subject to certain conditions, but as he can dismiss any of them, their tenure of office depends on the pleasure of the cabinet, and in fact by means of resigna- tions or removals, most of the councilors were changed in 1879 in order to make the council Republican. — " Le Conseil d'Etat," Varagnac, Uevue des Deux Mondes, Sept. 15, 1892, p. 295. 32 FRANCE. In a parliamentary system the ministers have two The minis- ^istinct functions. One of these is the same ^^'^' as that of the members of the President's Cabinet in the United States, and consists of the man* agement of the departments of the administration. The other is the duty of representing the government in the Chambers, urging the adoption of its measures, and defending its policy against the attacks of its adversa- ries. These two functions are not necessarily united, and in fact it has been a common habit in some coun- tries to appoint ministers without portfolios, as it is called, that is, without any executive duties at all, in order that they may devote their whole energy to the battles in Parliament.^ Although there is nothing to prevent such a practice in France, it is not followed to-day, each minister being at the head of a particular branch of the administration. The number of depart- ments, however, and the distribution of the public busi- ness among them is not fixed by law, but is regulated from time to time by decree of the President of the Republic. The number of ministers is, therefore, con- stantly liable to change according to the immediate needs of the public service. At present there are twelve departments or ministries : those of the Interior ; of Justice ; of Foreign Affairs ; of Finance ; of War ; of the Navy ; of Education and the Fine Arts ; of Pub- lic Works ; of Labor ; of Commerce, Industry, and ^ This practice virtually exists in England, because some of the offices held by the ministers, such as that of First Lord of the Treasury, and that of Chancellor of the Duchy of Lancaster, involve no administrative duties. THE MINISTERS. 33 Posts and Telegraphs; of Agriculture; and of tlie Colonies.^ The constitutional law of February 25, 1875 (Art. 6), declares that the ministers are collectively Their re- responsible to the Chambers for the general trtS^"^*^ policy of the government, and individually for ^™^ers. their personal acts. The object of this clause was, of course, to establish the parliamentary system, and in fact the French ministry is responsible to the Chamber of Deputies, as the English is to the House of Com- mons, and resigns on a hostile vote on any matter of importance. Except, indeed, for the Ministers of War and of the Navy, who are usually military men, the cabinet officers are almost always selected from among the members of Parliament,^ although the reason for this practice in England does not apply in France, because the ministers have a right to be present and speak in either Chamber, whether members of it or not.^ But in order to understand fully the position of the French ministers, and their relation to the m. • Parliament, it is necessary to realize their ^d"itr^^^ enormous power, and this is due largely to *'^"^®^- three causes, — the paternal nature of the government, the centralization of the state, and the possession by the executive of authority that in an Anglo-Saxon 1 Boeuf, Resume, ed. of 1895, pp. 22, 23. The last ministry, that of the Colonies, was, however, created by statute in 1894, and as Boeuf remarks, the Chambers can always prevent the creation of a ministry by refusing to make the necessary appropriations. 2 Dupriez, vol. ii. p. 336. ^ Const. Law of July 16, 1875, Art. 6. In practice this privilege is also accorded to their under-seeretaries. Lebon, Frankreich, p. 52. VOL, I. 84 FRANCE. country would be lodged with the legislature or the courts of law. On the first of these matters, the paternal nature of the government, there is no need to dwell Paternal na- i ,i An ture of the at length. Aii governments are growing more paternal at the present day, for a re- action has set in against the extreme laissez-faire doctrines preached by Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, and the English political economists of the earlier school. There is a general tendency to restrain the liberty of the individual and subject him to govern- mental supervision and control. Such control and supervision are traditional in France, and far exceed anything to which we are accustomed in this country. All trades and occupations are there subject to a great deal more police inspection than with us. They require more generally to be licensed, and are regulated and prohibited by the administrative officials with a much freer hand. And although the liberty of the press and the right of holding public meetings are now sub- stantially realized, the right of association is still very limited, for no society of more than twenty persons, except business companies, and associations of persons pursuing the same profession or trade, can be formed without the permission of the Minister of the Interior or the prefect of the department.^ It is easy to see how much power all this paternalism places in the hands of the administration. An explanation of the centralization of the state entails a brief survey of local government; and here * Lebon, Frankreich, pp. 32-39 ; Ducrocq, tit. ii. ch. iii. ; ch. iv. sec. iii. LOCAL GOVERNMENT. 35 we meet with a deeply rooted French tradition, for cen- tralization was already great under the old re- Centraiiza- gime, and although the first effect of the Rev- *^°"- olution was to place the, administration of local affairs under the control of independent elected bodies, the pressure of foreign war, and the necessity of maintain- ing order at home, soon threw despotic power into the hands of the national government. Under Napoleon this power became crystallized in a permanent form, and an administrative system was established, more perfect, more effective, and at the same time more centralized than that which had existed under the monarchy.^ The outward form of the Napoleonic system has been continuously preserved with surprisingly little change, but since 1830 its spirit has been modified in two dis- tinct ways : first, by means of what the French call deconcentration, that is, by giving to the local agents of the central government a greater right of independ- ent action, so that they are more free from the direct tutelage of the ministers ; second, by a process of true decentralization, or the introduction of the elective principle into local government, and the extension of the powers of the local representative bodies. But although the successive rulers of France have pursued this policy pretty steadily, the progress of local self- government has been far from rapid. ^ One reason for ^ For a short but vigorous comment on Napoleon's system, see G. L. Dickinson, Revolution and Reaction in Modern France, eh. ii. 2 On the subject of local government, I have used Aucoe, Conferences, 3d ed. ; Bceuf, Resume, ed. of 1895 ; Leroy-Beaulieu, A dm. Locale en France et en Angleterre ; Lebon's two works on France ; Goodnow, Comp. Adm. Law. There is a popular account in Block, Entretiens familiers sur I'Adrn. de notre pays. 36 FRANCE. this is the habit of looking to the central authorities for guidance in all matters. Another is a fear on the part of the government of furnishing its enemies with rallying-points which might be used to organize an op- position, — a fear that takes shape to-day in provisions forbidding the local elected councils to express any opinions on general politics, or to communicate with each other except about certain matters specified by law. A third cause of the feeble state of local self- government is to be found in the fact that the Kevolu- tion of 1789 destroyed all the existing local divisions except the commune, and replaced them by artificial districts which have never developed any real vitality, so that the commune is the only true centre of local life in the republic.^ A fourth, and perhaps the most potent cause of all, is the dread of disorder which is constantly present in the minds of Frenchmen, and makes them crave a master strong enough to cope with any outbreak. France is divided into eighty-six departments, at the Local gov- head of each of which is a prefect, appointed The depart- and rcmovcd at pleasure by the President of the prefect, the Rcpublic, but in reality nominated by the Minister of the Interior. The office is, indeed, regarded as distinctly political, and the incumbent is often re- placed when the minister changes. The prefect, who is by far the most important of the local officials, occu- pies a double position, for he is the agent of the central government in regard to those matters of general administration which are thought to concern ^ Most of the existing communes were in fact created in 1789. LOCAL GOVERNMENT. 37 the whole country, and at the same time he is the executive officer of the department for local affairs. In the former capacity he is in theory the immediate subordinate of the Minister of the Interior, but since his duties extend to all branches of the administration, he corresponds in practice directly with any minister in whose sphere of action the matter with which he is called upon to deal may lie. His authority as the agent of the central government is not, however, the same in all cases. Sometimes he is absolutely subject to the orders of the ministers. This is true when he executes general laws and ordinances ; but when, for example, he directs the police of the department, or supervises the subordinate local bodies, he proceeds on his own responsibility, and his acts can be overruled by the central government only in case they are con- trary to law, or give rise to complaints on the part of the persons affected by them. In pursuance of the policy of deconcentration, the prefect has been given an independent authority of this kind over a large number of subjects, and he was intended to exercise his own judgment in regard to them, but the influence and pressure of the deputies has, it is said, induced him to shirk responsibility as much as possible by refer- ring doubtful questions to the ministers, and hence the centralization has not been diminished as much as was expected.^ In matters of general administration, the prefect is assisted by a prefectoral council of three or four members appointed by the President of the Re- public ; but, except when it sits as an administrative 1 Channes, Letter of October 1, 1884. 38 FRANCE. court; the functions of this body are almost altogether advisory, and their use has become scarcely more than a form.^ As the executive officer for local a:ffairs, the prefect The General carrics out tlic rcsolutious of the General Council. Council. This is the representative assembly of the department, and is elected by universal suffrage, one of the members being chosen in each canton for six years, and half of them being renewed every three years. The authority of the body is jealously hmited. Its competence is almost entirely confined to affairs that are deemed to have a strictly local interest,^ and even in regard to these its powers are not absolute, for its votes on certain matters can be annulled by the President of the Republic, and its budget, that is the annual tax levy and list of appropriations, is not vahd without his approval. Although the Council has the right of final decision in a considerable class of sub- jects, its actual power over them is curtailed in a variety of ways. In the first place it does not carry out its own votes, but their execution is intrusted to an agent of the central government, the prefect, who appoints all the officials, manages the public institutions, and signs the orders for all payments of money ; the direct control of the council over his performance of these duties extending only to the election of a standing commission which has little more than a right of inspec- ^ Vicomte d'Avenel, "La E^forme Administrative," Revue des Deux Mondes, June 1, 1889, p. 596. ^ Its functions in relation to the general administration consist in ap- portioning certain direct taxes, in giving its advice when asked, and in expressing its wishes on matters not connected with general politics. LOCAL GOVERNMENT. 39 tion.^ In the second place, the prefect has an opportu- nity to exert a great deal of influence over the action of the Council, for not only has he a right to address it, but he prepares the budget and all other business, and in fact it is not allowed to act on any matter until it has heard his report.^ Moreover the Council is only permitted to sit a very short time. It has two regular sessions a year, whose duration is Hmited one to a month, the other to a fortnight, and although extra sessions can be held they must not exceed one week apiece. Finally its very existence is insecure, for it can be dissolved by the chief of the state. In general it may be said that in matters falling within its province the General Council cannot do everything it wants, but can prevent almost anything it does not want. Its financial resources are not large,^ and its attention is confined for the most part to the construction of roads, subventions to railroads, and the care of schools, insane asylums, and other institutions of a similar character. At one time a hope was entertained that politics might be kept out of the general councils, but it has not been fulfilled, the departmental elections being regularly conducted on party lines.* It has therefore ^ The Council can delegate to the commission a somewhat indefinite class of functions, but it is not in fact a body of much importance. Du- priez, vol. ii. pp. 467-68. 2 Aucoc, p. 282. 8 Almost its only source of revenue is the addition of a limited sum to the direct state taxes. * Boz^rian, in his Etude sur la Revision de la Constitution (pp. 89-90), attributes this to the fact that the local assemblies take part in the elec- tion of senators. 40 FRANCE. been thought best to intrust the supervision of the communes largely to the central government and its representative the prefect, rather than to the councils with their partisan bias, and this, of course, deprives the latter of a part of the importance they would other- wise possess.^ The next local division is the arrondissement. This The arron- ^^ ^ mcrc administrative district without cor- dissement. porato personality, with no property, revenues^, or expenses of its own, and although it has a sub-pre- fect and an elected council, neither of them has much power. In fact it has been proposed to abolish the arrondissement altogether. The canton, which is the next subdivision, is really a The can- judicial and military rather than an admin- ^^^' istrative district, and therefore does not con- cern us here. We now come to the communes, which are the small- The com- ®^^ local entities, but differ enormously in '^^®" area and population. They vary in size from twenty acres to over a quarter of a million, and they run all the way from a hamlet with a dozen inhabitants to large cities ; yet with the exception of Paris and Lyons they are all governed on one plan. The officer in the commune whose position corresponds e mayor. ^^ ^^^^^ ^^ ^j^^ prefect in the department is the mayor. He acts in the same way both as agent of the central government, and as the executive head of the 1 By the law of 1884 on municipalities, part of the supervision over these bodies, which had previously been in the hands of the general councils, was withdrawn and given to the prefect. LOCAL GOVERNMENT. 41 district, but whereas in the prefect the former character predominates, the mayor is chiefly occupied with local matters. It is largely for this reason that, unlike the prefect, he is not appointed by the President, but since 1884 has been elected by and from the communal coun- cil for the length of its own term.^ The mayor is, however, by no means free from control. So far as he acts as agent of the central government, he is abso- lutely under the orders of the prefect. Nor is this all. The subject of communal poHce, which includes the public health and other matters of a kindred nature, is considered a part of "the local administration, but the acts of the mayor in regard to it can be annulled by the prefect, who has also power in many cases to issue direct orders of his own. Moreover the police officials require to be confirmed by the prefect,^ and can be removed only by him.^ But even these extensive pow- ers of control are not deemed enough, and it is provided that the mayor can be suspended from office for a month by the prefect, or for three months by the Min- ister of the Interior, and can be removed altogether by the President of the Republic. The deliberative organ of the commune is the com- munal council, which varies in size from ten to thirty- six members, and is elected by universal suffrage for four years. Its authority extends to all communal ^ The office is an honorary one, as the mayor receives no salary. ^ Or sub-prefect. ^ The mayor is not free from control in regard to other matters of local interest, for his accounts must be submitted for approval to the pre- fect, who can order the payment of any expense properly authorized if the mayor neglects to make it. 42 FEANCE. affairs, except that it has nothing to do with the broad subject of police, although that is regarded for other purposes as a local matter. The general statute on municipal government lays down the general princi- ple that the decisions of the council on local affairs, when legally made, are conclusive without the approval of any superior administrative official, but in a subse- quent section all the most important matters are spe- cially excepted from the rule. The Hst of exceptions includes almost every financial measure, the construction of roads and buildings, and the sale of communal prop- erty.^ The council has, therefore, very much less power than might at first sight be supposed ; and in order to guard against any attempt on its part to exceed these slender privileges, the prefect is given a discretionary authority to suspend it for a month, while the President of the Republic can dissolve it entirely, and appoint a commission with Hmited powers to rule the commune for two months, when a new election must take place. The general laws of local government already de- scribed do not, however, cover the whole field, because a dread of the explosive char- acter and communistic tendencies of the democracy of Paris has prevented the capital from enjoying even the measure of liberty granted to other towns. The city has, indeed, a municipal council composed of eighty elected members and endowed with most of the usual powers, and a general council for the department with limited powers, composed of these same eighty rein- 1 The official who has power to approve the budget can also inscribe therein certain obligatory expenses. PAEIS. 43 forced by eight suburban members ; but the executive authority is entirely in the hands of the central govern- ment. It is lodged in part with the mayors of the twenty arrondissements, who are appointed directly by the President of the Republic ; but chiefly with two prefects appointed in the same way. One of these, the Prefect of the Seine, has most of the functions of the ordinary prefect, together with those of a central mayor ; while the other, the Prefect of Police, has charge of the police, and is directly responsible to the Minister of the Interior.^ This sketch of local government in France shows how centralized the state still remains, what extensive supervision and control the administration keeps in its own hands, and how slight is the measure of real local autonomy if measured by an Anglo-Saxon standard. In fact, the central government still makes itself contin- ually and actively felt in local affairs, and this is for the ministers a great source of power, but also, as we shall see later, a cause of weakness. A third source of the enormous power of the minis- ters in France is the possession by the execu- tive of authority that in an Anglo-Saxon and judicial country would be lodged with the legislature the execu- or the courts of law. This requires an expla- nation, for it involves some of the most strange and ^ In Lyons the control of the police is still intrusted to the Prefect of the Rhone ; in Marseilles it is in charge of the Prefect of Bonches-du- Rhone. In all cities of over 40,000 people the organization of the police is fixed by decree of the chief of the state, although the members of the force are appointed as in other communes. 44 FRANCE. interesting peculiarities of French, and, indeed, of con- tinental political ideas. Let us take first the legislative authority of the execu- tive in France. When an English or an Ameri- Legialative i • i i p i • decrees and cau legislator draits a statute lie tries to cover ordinances. . ., ^ . all questions that can possibly arise. He goes into details and describes minutely the operation of the act, in order that every conceivable case may be expressly and distinctly provided for. He does this because there is no one who has pOwer to remedy defects that may subsequently appear. If the law is vague or obscure, it can receive an authoritative inter- pretation only from the courts by the slow process of litigation. If it is incomplete, it must remain so until amended by a subsequent enactment. In some cases, it is true, an officer or board is given by statute power to make regulations. The Local Government Board and our boards of health furnish examples of this ; but such cases are exceptional, and most Anglo-Saxons feel that the power is in its nature arbitrary, and ought not to be extended farther than is necessary. And here it is important to distinguish between rules issued by the head of a department for the guidance of his subordi- nates and the regulations of which we are speaking. The former are merely directions given to the officials for the purpose of instructing them in their duties, and are binding on no one else. The right to issue them must belong, to some extent, to every one who has other persons under his orders, although they are used much more systematically in France than in the United States. The regulations with which we are concerned here are THE ORDINANCE POWER. , 45 of quite a different kind, for they are binding on all citizens who may be affected by them, and have, in fact, the character of laws. In America the authority to make regulations is de- legated by the legislature cautiously, and apart from such an express delegation no of&cer of the govern- ment has power to issue any ordinances with the force of law. But in France all this is very different. Stat- utes that do not concern the rights of a man against his neighbor, that do not, in other words, form a part of the Civil Code, are often couched in general terms, and enunciate a principle which the Executive is to carry out in detail.^ Sometimes the President of the Republic is expressly given power to make regulations, but even without any special authority he has a general power to make them for the purpose of completing the statutes, by virtue of his general duty to execute the laws.^ Such regulations in France are called acts of secondary legislation, and the ordinances of the Presi- dent in which they are contained are termed decrets. The power to make them is not, however, confined to the chief of the state. For matters of inferior grav- ity the laws often confer a similar authority on the min- isters, the prefects, and even the mayors, and in this ^ Dupriez (vol. ii. p. 377), after remarking this difference between English and French legislation, expresses a regret that the French Parlia» ment has shown a tendency of late years to go more into details. ^ On the power to issue ordinances in France, see Aucoc, Conferences, §§ 52-57, 66, 91, 170 ; Ducrocq, Cours, §§ 61-66, 72-73, 109-10, 210-14 ; Goodnow, vol. i. pp. 85-87. Before issuing certain classes of ordinances the President must consult the Council of State, but he is not obliged to follow its advice. 46 FRANCE. case the edicts are termed arretes, to distinguish them from the more solemn ordinances of the President.^ The regulations cannot, of course, be contrary to law, or in excess of the authority of the official who issues them. If they are so and infringe private rights, a process to have them annulled may be instituted before the administrative courts, and in certain limited cases the ordinary courts can also refuse to apply them.^ So much for the power of the executive to make law, Appropria- ^^* ^^^^ ^^^^ ^^^ cxliaust its eucroachmcnts tions. Qj^ what we have learned to regrard as the province of the legislature, for it is less strictly held to the appropriations voted by the Chambers than is the case with us. The virements (that is to say, the use for one purpose of approj)riations voted for another), which were an abuse under the Empire, have, indeed, been abolished, except as between different items in the same chapter of the annual budget ; but certain chapters are designated each year to which additions can be made by decree of the President issued with the con- sent of the council of ministers. Moreover, in urgent and unforeseen cases arising- when Parliament is not in session, the government has power by means of such a decree, not only to incur the expenses called for by the emergency, but also to open an extraordinary credit on its own authority and borrow the money that it needs.^ ^ Lebon, Frankreich, p. 23 ; Aucoc, Ducrocq, ubi cit. 2 Laferri^re, Traite de la Jur. Adm., liv. iii. ch. i. see. Ii. ; liv. vi. ; liv. vii. ch. i. sec. iv. 8 In both cases notice of the decree must be laid before the Chambers within fourteen days from their next meeting. (Lebon, Frankreich, p. 162.) It is worth while, moreover, to note in passing that there is ENGLISH AND FRENCH HISTORY. 47 One may, perhaps, be pardoned for dwelling at some- what greater length on the judicial powers of j^^iiciai the executive in France, both because they thnxecu- are so Httle understood by English-speaking *^^®" people, and because their origin may be traced to a tradition which has its roots far back in the past. The characteristic difference between the political history of England and that of France is to character- be found in the fact that the English, though eneebefween influenced by each new spirit of the age, frlilchhis- have never yielded entirely to its guidance, ^°^^' while the French have always thrown themselves into the current, and, adopting completely the dominant ideas of the time, have carried them to their logical results. Thus, in the Middle Ages, the feudal system never became fully developed in England as it did in France. Again, when absolute monarchy came into vogue, the British sovereign was not able to acquire the arbitrary power of the Bourbons. And, lastly, democracy made its way neither so rapidly nor so thoroughly on the north as on the south of the Chan- nel. The result is that in France the institutions of any period have been adapted almost exclusively to the wants of the time in which they were produced, and in the succeeding age it has been thought necessary to destroy them and devise new ones more in harmony no effective process for bringing to account a minister who exceeds the appropriations. He can, indeed, be impeached, but except in times of great excitement this would not be done if the money had been expended for public purposes ; and as regards civil liability, there is no court that has power to compel him to refund the suras which he has spent illegally. 48 FRANCE. with the new conditions j ^ whereas in England there has been no need of such sweeping changes, and it has been possible to preserve in a modified form many of the most important features of the government. Hence the permanence and continuity of the political system.^ Let us inquire how these facts have affected the deveh opment of judicial and administrative institutions in the two countries. The Norman kings of England strove deliberately to check the growth of the feudal system, and veiopment tlicir succcssors coustautly followed the same power in policy. Now the csscncc of the feudal sys- tem consisted in the blending of public and private law by making all political relations depend on the tenure of land ; and, in fact, according to the strict feudal theory, no man had direct relations with any superior except his immediate overlord. Every great vassal of the crown, therefore, had jurisdiction over all the tenants on his estate, which he exercised by holding a court of his own for the administration of justice among them. The English kings resisted this principle, and tried to bring their power to bear directly on all The iidieiai ^^^® pcoplc of the realm. For this purpose system. sheriffs were appointed to represent the crown in the counties, and what was of more permanent im- portance, the gravest crimes, actions for the possession 1 This Is the more striking because the French are in some ways more conservative than the English, as, for example, in their retention to the present day of public executions. M. Lebon truly remarks (France as It Is, p. 86) : " People have no idea of the spirit of routiue and conser- vatism which prevails in France." * Cf. Freeman, Groivth of the English Constitution, pp. 63-66. ENGLISH CENTKALIZATION JUDICIAL. 49 of land, and subsequently other matters, were brought within the jurisdiction of the Curia Regis} As early as the reign of Henry I., moreover, royal officers were commissioned to travel about the country holding court, a practice which was renewed in a more systematic form by Henry II., and has continued with short in- terruptions to the present day.^ The chief object of the early kings in sending out the itinerant justices, as they were called, was no doubt financial; for their duties consisted in assessing taxes, collecting fines for violation of the law, and administering justice, which was in itself a source of no small profit in the Middle Ages.^ The functions of the justices in the collection of revenue grew, however, less and less prominent, but their administration of justice became of permanent importance, and in regard to this two tendencies were at work. In the first place, the royal judges adopted new methods of procedure and gradually developed the trial by jury, while the baronial courts clung to the ordeal and other barbaric forms of trial.* " The glad- some light of jurisprudence," as Coke called it, came ^ See Pollock & Maitland, History of English Law, vol. i, pp. 85-87 and chs. V. and vi. ^ The institution of traveling judges was not new. It had been used by Charlemagne (Hallam, Middle Ages, ch. ii. part ii. 5), and a similar practice was employed by Alfred, Edgar, and Canute (Stubbs, History of England, xi. §§ 127, 134). On the itinerant justices, see Stubbs, lb. xi. 127 ; xii. 141, 145, 150 ; xiii. 163 ; xv. 235 ; Gneist, Englische Ver~ fassungsgeschichte, pp. 148, 224-28, 305 (note), 318-19, 447. Pollock & Maitland, vol. i. pp. 134, 149, 179 ; Franqueville, Le Systeme Judiciaire de ta Grande Bretagne, vol. i. pp. 149 et seq. The royal duty of sending the justices in eyre is one of those insisted upon in Magna Charta, § 18. 3 Stubbs, lb. xi. 127. 4 Cf. Stubbs, lb. xiii. 164 ; Gneist, lb. p. 142. VOL. I. 50 FRANCE. ■with the king's courts, and hence it is not surprising that they supplanted the baronial courts, and in time drew before themselves all the important lawsuits. In the second place, the commissions which had at first been issued to high officials, barons, and knights, be- came confined to regular judges, and about the time of Edward I. were given only to the members of the royal courts at Westminster.^ The same body of judges, therefore, expounded the law in all parts of the realm, and hence England, alone among the countries of Europe, developed a uniform national justice called the common law.^ The people naturally became attached to this law and boasted of the rights of Englishmen, while the courts that were the creators and guardians of the law became strong and respected. The very fact that the judicial branch of the govern- ment became so highly developed made the istrative Centralization of the administration unneces- sary. At the time when the itinerant justices first went on circuit, administration in the modern sense was of course unknown, and such local affairs as needed attention were regulated by the shire moots and other local meetings.^ The sheriff, indeed, repre- sented the crown, but his powers were curtailed more and more, until, apart from his command of the mili- tary forces of the county, he became little more than an officer of the courts.* When the local administra- ^ Gneist, Englische Verfassungsgeschichte, p. 318 ; Stubbs, History of England, xv. 235. 2 Cf. Hallam, Middle Ages, cb. viii. part ii. 3. » Stubbs, lb. XV. 205. 4 On the powers of the sheriff, see Stubbs, lb. xiii. 163, xv. 204:-7i Gneist, lb. pp. 115-20, 297. FRANCE CENTRALIZED LATER. 51 tion grew more important, it was confided not to him, but to justices of the peace, who, though nominally selected by the king, were never strictly under his orders, and in time became almost completely inde- pendent, except for the purely judicial control exercised by the Court of King's Bencli.^ In England, therefore, the royal power came early into contact with the people all over the kingdom by means of the courts of law, mentofthe .,.., , I'll direct royal and the judicial system became highly cen- power in tralized; while the local administrative insti- tutions developed slowly, and through them the king's authority was little felt. In France, on the other hand, the course of events was very different, for the royal power came into direct contact with the people at a much later date, and therefore in quite another form. When the feudal system became established, the The judicial great vassals set up their own courts and sue- ^y^*^"^- ceeded in excluding the royal judges from their fiefs, so that the direct jurisdiction of the crown became confined to the comparatively small part of the country which was included in the royal domain. Gradually, indeed, as the feudal system began to lose its strength, the king's jurisdiction encroached upon that of the vassals, — a process which was carried on both by insisting on the right of appeal to the royal tribu- nals, and by reserving for the exclusive cognizance of the king's courts a somewhat indefinite class of cases ^ Gneist, Englische Verfassungsgeschichte, pp. 298 et seq., 468 et seq.} and see the note at the end of this chapter. 52 FRANCE. known by the name of cas royaux} But this process aroused serious resistance on the part of the territorial lords, and it was not until the sixteenth century that the crown judges possessed the universal authority they had obtained in England more than three hundred years earlier. So strong, in fact, did the local jealousy of the Parliament of Paris (the king's high court of justice) remain, that after the great fiefs fell into the hands of the crown, they were not placed under the jurisdiction of that tribunal, but were given independ- ent parliaments of their own.^ At the outbreak of the Revolution there were thirteen separate parliaments, so that every considerable province had a distinct body of magistrates.^ Under these circumstances, the courts could not create a uniform national justice like the English common law, and although since the revolution such a uniform system has been provided by the Code, this does not strengthen the hands of the judges, but has rather the opposite tendency. In the first place, it is not their work, and hence does not redound to their glory; and secondly, by weakening the force of prece- dent, it diminishes the importance of judicial decisions. This review of the history of the courts of law shows 1 Aubert, Le Parlement de Paris de Pliillippe le Bel a Charles VII., ch. i. sec. I. ; Hist, du Pari, de Paris, 1250-1515, liv. ii. ch. i.; Du Bois, Hist, du Droit Criminel de la France, part i. ch. i. ; Esmein, Hist, du Droit Franqais, part i. tit. ii. ch. i.; Hist, de la Proc. Crim., part i. tit. i. ch. i. sec. II.; ch. ii. sec. I.; Hallam, Middle Ages, ch. ii. part ii. 5. ^ Du Bois, part i. ch. ii. § 2 ; Bastard d'Estang, Les Parlements de France^ vol. i. pp. 36-38 ; Esmein, Hist, du Droit Franqais, tit. ii. ch. i. sec. I. § 2, v. ^ For the dates of the creation of the provincial parliaments, which run from 1444 to 1775, see Bastard d'Estang, vol. i. p. 189, note, and Esmein, ubi supra. HER CENTRALIZATION ADMINISTRATIVE. 53 clearly why they have not attained in France the same power and authority as in Anglo-Saxon countries.^ The French courts of law were weak because the royal authority did not come into direct con- tact with the people at the time when public istrative and private law were everywhere blended, when the tone of thought was peculiarly legal, and when political power was chiefly exercised in a judicial or semi-judicial form.^ It made itself felt at a later date, and especially as the restorer of order after the anarchy caused by the hundred years' war. Its presence brought peace and prosperity, and naturally enough the organs which it employed acquired a high degree of vigor. Now, at this period, administration, in the modern sense, was becoming important, and as the royal authority came to be exercised by commissioners or intendants who had, indeed, certain judicial powers, but whose functions were chiefly administrative,^ the administration developed an influence and a strength which the courts have never attained. The administra- tive system became centralized, and grew to be the most important factor in the government.^ All classes of the people looked to it for protection ; ^ in fact, it took, 1 Since the Revolution, the courts have, of course, been reorganized on a centralized basis. ^ On the relative importance attributed to law in the Middle Ages, and in later times, see Stubbs's chapters on the Characteristic Differences between Mediaeval and Modern History, in his Lectures on Med. and Mod. Hist. s Ch^ruel, Die. des Inst, de la France, " Intendants des Provinces ; " Esmein, Hist, du Droit Fran^ais, tit. ii. ch. v. § 2. * Cf. De Tocqueville, An. Reg. et la Rev., liv. ii. chs. ii. iii. ^ De Tocqueville speaks of all classes as looking on the government as a special providence. Id., ch. vi. (7th ed. pp. 100-103). 54 FRANCE. to a great extent, the place which the judiciary filled in Enoland, and in those countries which had inherited the English principles. This difference in the relative authority of the courts and the administration was intensified, so far as doctrine of the United States and France were concerned, tion of by the poHtical philosophy of the last century. powers. . .,. ^.. PIT j> Montesquieu, m his " fepint oi the Laws, pro- claimed the importance of separating the executive, legislative, and judicial powers, and the maxim was eagerly accepted on both sides of the Atlantic, though in very different senses. Our ancestors, anxious to maintain the independence of the courts and the sacred- ness of private rights, took the principle to signify the necessity of so protecting the courts from the control or influence of the other branches of the government that they might be free to administer justice without regard to the official position of the litigants or the nature of the questions involved. They meant to preserve the Enghsh tradition that there is only one law of the land to which every one is subject, from the humblest citizen to the highest officer. The French, on the other hand, had acquired no great passion for law, or for the rights of the individual, and did not admit a claim on the part of any one to delay or overturn the public interests in order to get his own grievances redressed. Moreover, they had seen the Parliament of Paris interfere with the government by refusing to register the edicts of the King ; for although this tribunal had failed to acquire judicial supremacy, it had retained a good deal of politi- cal power, which it used during the years preceding the THE SEPARATION OF POWERS. 55 Kevolution to resist innovations.^ Such a power might not be dishked as a means of opposing an unpopular court party, but it could not be tolerated for a moment when the reins of government were seized by men who believed themselves commissioned to reform the world. The French statesmen, therefore, took Montesquieu's doctrine in the sense that the administration ousfht to be free to act for the public weal without let or hin- drance from the courts of law. The Declaration of the Rights of Man proclaimed in 1789 that a community in which the separation of powers was not established had no constitution ; and a statute of the next year, on the organization of the tribunals, gave effect to the maxim as it was understood in France by providing that the judges should not interfere in any way with the work of administrative authorities, or proceed against the officers of the government on account of their official acts.^ The American and French applications of the doctrine of the separation of powers are both per- fectly logical, but are based on different conceptions of the nature of law. The Anglo-Saxon draws no distinc- tion between public and private law. To him all legal rights and duties of every kind form part of one univer- sal system of positive law, and so far as the functions of pubhc officials are not regulated by that law, they are purely matters of discretion. It follows that every legal question, whether it involves the power of a public officer or the construction of a private contract, comes 1 Cf. Edward J. Lowell, The Eve of the French Revolution, p. 105. 2 Aucoc, Conferences, part i. liv. i. cb. i. ; Bceuf, Resume, part iv- sec. u. 56 FRANCE. before the ordinary courts.^ In France, on the other hand, private law, or the regulation of the rights and duties of individuals among themselves, is treated as only one branch of jurisprudence; while public law, which deals with the principles of government and the relations of individuals to the state, is regarded as something of an entirely different kind. Of course every civilized government must strive to treat all its subjects fairly, and hence, in the course of administra- tion, questions of justice must arise ; but as these do not concern the rights of a man against his neighbor, they are not classed in France with private law. It is felt that, unlike questions of private law, they ought not to be decided solely by the application of abstract principles of justice between man and man, but must be considered from the broad standpoint of public policy. Now the domain of the ordinary French courts is pri- vate law alone, and it is quite logical to regard any attempt on their part to judge administrative acts and thus pass on questions of public policy, as an attempt to go beyond their proper sphere of action and invade the province of the executive.^ The principle of withdrawing questions of public law from the ordinary courts was not new. It existed in ^ This principle, like all others in Anglo-Saxon countries, is not carried out with absolute consistency. Thus the various commissions in America on railroads, interstate commerce, etc., partake of the nature of the French administrative tribunals. '■^ The French, like tbe Americans, have not applied their principles quite strictly, for Criminal Law ought to be a branch of Public Law (Aueoc, Introd. § 1), but it has been put into the charge of the ordinary courts. THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS. 57 practice under tlie old regime/ but was extended and systematized after the Revolution. The protection of officials from suit or prosecution was formally incorpo- rated into the Constitution of the year VIII. (1799), and remained in force until after the fall of Napo- leon III., when it was repealed by a decree of the Government of the National Defense.^ This decree was intended to remove all hindrances in the way of bringing government officials before the ordinary courts, but it had very little effect, because the Tri- bunal of Conflicts held that it applied only to the personal protection of officials, and did not affect the principle of the separation of powers, which, as un- derstood in France, forbids the ordinary judges to pass upon the legality of official acts.^ Ques- tions of this kind, therefore, are still reserved istrative exclusively for the administrative courts, — tribunals created especially for this purpose, and com- posed of officials in the service of the government. Criminal cases are, indeed, an exception to the rule,* but this is of no great practical importance, because as force is pretty sure to be on the side of the police, it is no real protection to the individual to know that he can- ^ See Laferriere, Traite, llv. i. ; De Tocqueville, An. Reg. et la Rev., book ii. ch. iv. ; Varagnac, " Le Conseil cl'Etat," Revue des Deux Mondes, Aug. 15, 1892. 2 Decree of Sept. 19, 1870. 3 Arret, 30 JuiUet, 1873, " Affaire P^l^tier," Dalloz, Jur. Gen., 1874, part iii. p. 5 ; Leferriere, Traite, liv. iii. ch. vii. ; Aucoc, Conf., liv. v. ch. ii. ; Goodnow, Comp. Adm. Law, vol. ii. pp. 172-76. * Laferrifere, Traite, liv. iii. ch. vi. But even this exception is not absolute. See, also, a discussion of the subject in Dalloz, 1881, part iii p. 17, note. 58 FRANCE. not be condemned for resistance ; and on the other hand the officials concerned run no risk of punishment for illegal acts committed in obedience to orders, because the government can easily manage to prevent their being brought to trial, and can pardon them if con- victed. In France, therefore, there is one law for the citizen and another for the public official, and thus the executive is really independent of the judiciary, for the government has always a free hand, and can violate the law if it wants to do so without having any- thing to fear from the ordinary courts. Nor is the danger of interference on the part of the administrative tribunals as great as it would be in the case of the ordinary judges, because the former can be controlled absolutely in case of necessity ; and, in fact, they are so much a part of the administration itself that they fall into the province of the Interior and not that of Justice.^ The independence of the ordinary judges is secured by a provision which prevents their removal or transfer to another court, without the approval of the Court of Cassation, the final court of error. But the ^ It would be absurd to suppose that the government always extorts a favorable judgment. This was clearly shown in 1895, in a once famous case, which illustrates at the same time the degree of respect entertained for the decisions of the administrative courts. The Minister of the Interior and the railroads disagreed about the interpretation of a statute relating to the state guarantee of interest on the securities of the roads. The matter was brought before the Council of State, which decided in favor of the railroad. Thereupon the Minister of the Interior resigned, but the rest of the cabinet felt bound to abide by the decision. A discussion was, however, raised in the Chamber of Deputies, which in effect censured the ministers for submitting the matter to the Council of State, and thereby caused the cabinet to resign. THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS. 69 . . . ' judges of tlie administrative courts enjoy no such pro- tection, and can be removed by the President at any time.^ The result is that, although a great mass of administrative law has slowly grown up from the deci- sions of these courts,^ and personal liberty is much more respected than under the Empire, yet the courts themselves cannot be considered entirely judicial bodies, and are far from providing the rights of the citizen with a complete guarantee, at least where political questions are involved.^ 1 Aucoe, Conf., vol. i. pp. 156-57; Bceuf, iiesume,pp. 39-40. The mem- bers of the Council of State who are qualified to sit as administrative judges are said to be always selected from the political friends of the government (Dupriez, Les Ministres, vol. ii. pp. 482-83). 2 Unlike the civil law, the administrative law has never been codified, and indeed it could not be without destroying the element of discretion which is the reason for its existence. So far as it is not contained in statutes and ordinances, it has developed, like the English Common Law, by decision and precedent, and hence the sources for studying it are the reported cases and the writings of jurists such as those heretofore cited. ^ Lebon, France as It Is, pp. 101-2; Goodnow {Comp. Administrative Law, vol. ii. pp. 220-21, 231) remarks that the administrative courts have shown themselves more favorable to private rights than the ordinary courts, and in some ways that is certainly true. In English-speaking countries a public official can be prosecuted criminally or sued for dam- ages in the ordinary courts for any acts done without legal authority, whether his action was in the public interest or not. But he is not, as a rule, liable for acts authorized by law although his actual motives were bad or his discretionary powers misused. Nor is he usually liable for negligence in the performance of his duties. The state, on the other hand, cannot in theory be sued at all. In practice some means of main- taining claims against the state is almost always provided; but only for breaches of contract or to recover property, not for torts committed by officials. In France acts of officials are classified in quite another way with very different results. First, there are personal acts, which involve grave per- 60 FRANCE. It Is evident that with two sets of courts, neither of The Court which is superlor to the other, disputes about of Conflicts, jurisdiction must constantly arise. Such is in sonal iiiisconduet or gross negligence on the part of the official, whether beyond or within his legal authority. For these, and these alone, he is liable in damages in the ordinary courts. Whatever he does in good faith for the public interest, whether within or beyond his legal authority, is an act of administration for which a remedy, if any, can be sought only against the state, and as a rule only in the administrative courts. Acts of this kind fall into three classes, called, actes de gestion, actes d'authorite and actes de gouvernement. Broadly speaking, actes de gestion are acts done in the course of the business administration of the public ser- vices, and the administrative courts tend to award compensation against the state for acts of this nature, not only when done wholly without legal authority, but also when there has been an abuse of that author- ity for improper purposes, or even negligence, as, for example, where a merchantman has been damaged by collision with a warship. (See a discussion of this whole subject in Hauriou La Gestion Administra- tive). Actes d'authorite are done in the exercise of the right of the state to issue commands to its citizens; and if such commands, orders or regu- lations are issued without legal authority, or involve an abuse of power, they can be annulled by a special procedure in the Council of State, which may incidentally award compensation. Finally actes de gouvernement, that is acts done for reasons of state with a view to the public safety, whether within the legal power of the government or not, lie beyond the juris- diction both of the ordinary and the administrative courts; but there is a distinct tendency to restrict this principle to an ever-narrowing field. It is obvious that while the French system does not hold the official to a rigid conformity with law, it often gives compensation from the public treasury for tortious acts of officials when in England or America there would be no redress, or only an action against an official who might be unable to pay the damages. It is somewhat curious in this connection to observe that French writers often assert the inability of an ordinary court to protect the pub- lic against illegal ordinances, because it can only decide the case at bar, whereas an administrative court has power to annul the ordinance alto- gether; a remark which shows an entire failure to comprehend the force of precedent in a judicial system like that of England. (See, for example, THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS. 61 fact the case, and a special tribunal has been appointed to determine these disputes, or conflicts as they are called.^ It is composed of the Minister of Justice, of three members of the highest court of law, the Court of Cassation, of three members of the highest administra- tive court, the Council of State (each of these sets being selected by their own court), and of two other persons elected by the foregoing seven. All the members are chosen for three years, except the Minister of Justice. This officer has the right to preside, and thus his pres- ence gives to the administration a majority in the tri- bunal. A striking example of the working of the sys- tem was presented in 1880, when the government issued decrees for the suppression of all monastic orders not authorized by law. There seems to have been grave doubt about the legality of the decrees, and the victims brought suits in the ordinary courts in several parts of France. Most of these courts held that they were authorized to entertain the suits, and in some cases they went so far as to order the persons who had been ex- pelled from their establishments to be restored to pos- session pending the trial ; ^ but the government raised the question of jurisdiction, and the Tribunal of Con- Varagnac, " Le Conseil d'Etat," Revue des Deux Mondes, Sept. 15, 1892, pp. 290-91.) An admirable comparison of the English and French systems may be found in Professor Dicey's Law of the Constitution, and especially iu chapter xii. 1 Aucoc, Con/., vol. i. § 406; Boeuf, Resume, 15th ed. pp. 542-43. 2 Some of the decisions to this efPect may be found in Dalloz, Jurispru- dence Generale, 1880, part iii. pp. 57-62, and 80. In the note to page 57 there is a list of some of the other similar decisions and a discussion of the law. 62 FRANCE. flicts decided that the ordinary courts were not compe= tent to deal with the matter.^ It is a significant fact, which seems to show a lack of confidence in the impar- tiality of the administrative courts, that the persons inJTired did not bring the question of the legality of the decrees before the Council of State.^ When an ordinary court has assumed jurisdiction of a case, the question of competence can be raised only by the prefect, and not by a party, for the principle that the ordinary courts cannot determine the legality of official acts is intended solely as a protection to the administration .^ It is not quite accurate to say that the ordinary Jurisdiction courts cau cousider the validity of no official minktn^ive ^^^} ^1^^? iudccd, the line between the juris- courts. diction of the ordinary and the administrative courts does not follow any strictly logical principle.^ Questions of indirect taxes, for example, and those relating to the lesser highways (petite voirie), come before the ordinary courts, while those arising under the direct taxes, or relating to the greater highways (grande voirie), come before the administrative tribu- nals. The competence of the various administrative 1 Arrets de Nov. 4, 5, 13, 17, and 20 ; Dalloz, 1880, part iii. pp. 121- 32. These cases are reported with unusual fullness. 2 At least I can find no decision on the subject by the Council of State reported in Dalloz. For criticisms on the conduct of the government, see Jules Simon, Dieu, Patrie, Liberie, ch, vi. ; and Chaunes, Nos Fautes, letters of July 12 and Oct. 27, 1880. 3 Aucoc, Con/., vol. i. § 404; Bceuf, Resume, 15th ed. p. 547. * On this subject, see Laferri^re's great work, Traite de la Jurisdiction Administrative. THE ADMINISTRATIVE COURTS. 63 courts is no less complicated. The prefect and the mayor have each a very limited jurisdiction. That of the prefectorial councils, on the other hand, is very con- siderable, although as a matter of fact these councils are occupied almost altogether with questions of taxes, and in these, as a rule, they follow the advice of the assessors.^ But by far the most important administra- tive court is the Council of State, which has a special section or committee to attend to the contentieux, as this class of litigation is called. The Council not only hears appeals from the lower administrative tribunals, but has also original jurisdiction in many important cases, and in fact recent practice is tending to estabhsh the principle that the Council of State is the judge of all administrative matters in the absence of special pro- visions of law. The number of cases brought before it is very large, and has increased so rapidly that the section for the contentieux is badly in arrears, and it has been proposed to create a second section to relieve the pressure.^ Such is the legal position of the administration in ordinary times, but in case of war or insurrec- -jj^g ^^^^^ ^^ tion it can be given far greater powers, by a ^^^^®' proclamation of the state of siege. This can be made by statute, or if ParHament is not in session, it can be made by the President ; but in that case, in order to meet the danger of a coup d'etat, which is ever present ^ Vicomte d'Avenel, " La Rdf orme Administrative — La Justice," Revue des Deux Mondes, June 1, 1889, p. 596. 2 For the number of cases decided by the administrative courts, see the tables (through 1886) in Laferriere, liv. i. ch. v. 64 FRANCE. to the eyes of Frenchmen^ it is provided tliat the Cham= bars shall meet as of right in two days.^ Within the district covered by the state of siege, the military courts can be given criminal jurisdiction, and can punish any offenses against the safety of the Republic or the general peace. They can search houses by day or night, expel from the district any non-residents, seize all arms, and forbid any publications or meetings which are liable to disturb the public order.^ I have dwelt at some length on what, from an Effect of the Auglo-Saxou poiut of view, may well be called tem^onthe' ^^^^ legislative and judicial powers of the the^exeeu- exccutive in France, because these things are ^^^' entirely foreign to our own political ideas and experience, and because they exist in some form in almost every country on the continent of Europe. When we consider the paternal character of the government, the centralization of the state, and the large share of authority vested in the executive depart- ment, we cannot fail to see that the ministers in whose hands this vast power is lodged must be either very strong or very weak. If they are able to wield it as they please, and are really free to carry out their own policy, they must be far stronger than any officer or body in Great Britain, and immeasurably stronger than any in our federal republic. But, on the other hand, the very immensity and pervasiveness of their power, the fact that it touches closely every interest in the country, renders them liable to pressure from all sides. 1 Law of April 3, 1878, Poudra et Pierre, § 79. 2 Poudra et Pierre, § 76, gives the text of the law. . EFFECT OF THE FRENCH SYSTEM. 65 It becomes important for every one to influence their action, provided lie can get a standpoint from which to bring a pressure to bear. This standpoint is fur- nished by the Chamber of Deputies, for the existence of the ministry depends on the votes of that body. The greater, therefore, the power of the minister, and the more numerous the favors he is able to bestow, the fiercer will be the struggle for them, and the less will he be free to pursue his own policy, untrammeled by deputies, whose votes he must win if he would remain in office. A Frenchman, who is eminent as a student of political philosophy, and has at the same time great practical experience in politics, once remarked to the author, " We have the organization of an empire with the forms of a republic." ^ The French administrative system is, indeed, designed for an empire, and would work admirably in the hands of a wise and benevolent autocrat who had no motive but the common weal ; but when arbitrary power falls under the control of popular leaders, it can hardly fail to be used for personal and party ends ; for, as a keen observer has truly said, the defect of democracy lies in the fact that it is nobody's business to look after the interests of the public.^ ^ Gneist expresses the same idea : " Es entsteht der unvermittelte Gegen- satz einer repuUikanisch gedachten Verfassung mit einer absolutistisch orga- nisirten Verwaltung." (Die Preussiscke Kreisordnung, p. 7.) ^ The late Professor Gneist, perhaps the most profound student of the comparative history of England and the continent, from the point of view of the working of parliamentary government, demonstrated that the success of the system in England has been due to certain underlying institutions which have made that country a commonwealth based upon law (Rechtsstaat). His chief works on the subject are his Englische Verwaltungsrecht j Self-government, etc., in England; Der Rechtsstaat, and VOL. I. 66 FRANCE. Verwaltung, Justiz, RecJitsweg. In tlie opening words of the preface to the last of these, the keynote of the whole theory is struck when he says, " Die parlamentarische Regierung Englands ist eine Regierung nach Gesetzen und durch Gesetze." His views may be briefly summarized as follows : In England alone, among the countries of Europe, the royal power became consolidated early, for the Norman kings broke down the resistance of the great vassals and made their authority effective over the whole realm, drawing military, judicial, and police matters into their own hands. By this process, the antagonism and jealousy of the dift'erent classes was crushed ; while the land-owning nobility found their only chance of political activity in exerting a restraint upon the crown by means of judicial action and statutes. Their first great achievement was Magna Charta, with which the parliamentary era begins. The struggle was continued in the Barons' war, and resulted in the evolution of the House of Commons. From time to time Parliament enacted statutes which supplemented the customary law, and furnished a solid basis for the decisions of the courts. The existence of permanent statutes, as distinguished from royal edicts in their nature changeable, is one of the chief foundations of the reign of law in England, for the statutes in ever increasing quantity regu- lated the administration rigorously and uniformly throughout the land. Another factor that contributed to the same result was the method in which the statutes were executed, and this in turn may be traced to the early extension of the royal power. The administrative laws were carried out by means of a large number of officers, of whom the most important were the justices of the peace. These were appointed by the king, and hence acted in behalf of the state instead of local or class interests ; but, on the other hand, they were in fact the greater land- owners of the county, not professional officials bound to do the bidding of the court. They conducted the local administration according to judicial forms, subject on purely legal questions to the control of the King's Bench by means of writs of Certiorari, Mandamus, etc., the effect being to prevent arbitrary abuse of power, and to insure legality in the execution of the law. In short, as Gneist expresses it, the English developed an elaborate and effective system of administrative justice. The method of administration also produced self-government, by which Gneist means not the control of local matters by bodies elected to repre- sent local interests, but an organization of the whole community for the service of the state, so arranged that the classes most capable by their wealth and position for government bore the burdens and administered the affairs of their neighborhood. The result was brought about in NOTE OF THE VIEWS OF GNEIST. 67 England cliiefly by means of the office of justice of the peace, which gradually became both an honor and a duty attached to the ownership of land. Thus the gentry carried on the local government ; but this was no mere privilege which they enjoyed for their own benefit, because they also paid the taxes and ruled, not for the profit of their own class, but as officers of the state for the common good and in strict accordance with fixed laws. Hence, instead of the hostility of classes that existed all over the continent, there developed harmonious local communities with true public opinions on political questions. Moreover, the habit of sitting as justices gave to the gentry a sense of public duty and a love for law. Now the House of Commons was virtually composed of the representa- tives of the gentry, who carried into it their sentiments. The members of Parliament, therefore, understood law, and had a deep sense of its importance, while their training caused them to act for the good of the whole state rather than the benefit of their own class. This rendered possible the formation of real national parties, based on differences of opinion, not on class interests ; parties whose action in Parliament v/as restricted by a respect for law. Gneist points out how different has been the history of France. Feudalism there was at first too strong for the royal power to overcome, and hence the community, instead of being consolidated, split into hostile classes. The king found himself at the head of a state whose organiza- tion was so loose and inefficient as to be incapable of natural develop- ment. As soon as he was able, he began to create in the royal domains better military, financial, police, and judicial systems. The old institutions having gained no strength in the mean while were unable to stand against the new and more effective ones, which gradually spread over the whole of France. The new ones, however, were not combined with the old, but substituted for them ; and thus the power both of the vassals and of the estates was crushed by the royal supremacy. In fact, the political and social organization of the country became entirely unlike. Socially, the nation was still divided into the classes whose selfish antagonism had made possible the triumph of the crown. Politically, absolute power had become vested in the king, who ruled by means of a paid corps of officials without ties with the local communities, unrestrained by perma- nent statutes, and dependent solely on his pleasure. The French Revolu- tion did not essentially change this state of things. It did not create a new organic political structure of the community, but merely transferred the royal power to the people, or rather to those partigular interests among the people that were able to acquire ascendency for the moment, and these were no more inclined to place restraints on their own omnipo- 68 FRANCE. tehee than the king had been before. While, therefore, private law was just and strong, public law was weak and unstable ; and as public law is the foundation of political society, Gneist regards France as the very negation of a commonwealth based upon law- German history followed very much the same course during the Middle Ages, but at their close the central power was not strong enough to enforce obedience and consolidate the empire. Hence the supremacy of the crown developed at a still later time, after the centrifugal forces had grown so powerful that the principalities had become well-nigh independent. Then the princes overcame within their territories the resistance of the estates as the king had done in France. In Germany, however, and especially in Prussia, the bureaucracy was so ordered as to furnish a better protection to individual rights and a firmer maintenance of law. But this broke down with the spread of French ideas after 1848, when the antagonistic interests in the state, taking advantage of the parliamentary system, abused the administrative power and introduced a veritable party tyranny. Gneist considered the subsidiary framework of the English institutions, and especially the justices of the peace, as the foundation of the legal character of the government, and hence of the success of the parlia- mentary system. But he did not realize that the keystone of the whole structure is the ultimate decision by the courts at Westminster of all questions of law that arise in the course of the administration. He did aot see that the legal spirit pervading the system is the result of giving to public law the sacredness and inflexibility that pertains to private law, and that this end is reached by fusing the two together, and confiding them both in the last resort to the same courts. On the contrary, he believed that public and private law ought to be kept distinct, and he approved of the practice of placing the former in the hands of special administrative tribunals. The germs of such a system appeared for a moment in England when the Star Chamber began to act as a supreme administrative court ; but one cannot help feeling that if this procedure had become permanent, public law would have been much less rigidly interpreted than it was by the King's Bench, that the administration would have become more discretionary, and that the strict, rigorous, legal spirit of the system would have been lost. It may be added that Gneist considered the English government at its highest perfection under George III. In his opinion, the reform bill of 1832, the extension of the franchise in 1867, and still more the recent changes in local government, have been a departure from historic prin- ciples, and have tended by disorganizing the state to bring about a strife of parties and reduce England to the condition of other nations. CHAPTER n. FRANCE : PARTIES. For more tlian a hundred years it has been the habit to talk of government by the people, and the 1 Pill T^^Q influ- expression is, perhaps, more ireeiy used to-day ence of par- 1 IP p • 1 1 *^^^ ^" popu- than ever before, yet a superficial glance at largovem- the history of democracy ought to be enough to convince us that in a great nation the joeople as a whole do not and cannot really govern. The fact is that we are ruled by parties, whose action is more or less modified, but never completely directed, by public opinion. Rousseau, indeed, shadowed forth a great truth, when he declared that no community could be capable of a general will — or as we should express it, of a true public opinion — where parties or sects pre- vailed;^ and our own experience of popular government will quite justify us in saying that public opinion is always more or less warped by the existence of party ties. A study of the nature and development of parties is, therefore, the most important one that can occupy the student of political philosophy to-day. Asa rule Among Anglo-Saxon peoples, who have had oniy^two^ a far longer experience in self-government Angkf-™ ,1 j_ j^i j_i n j^ Saxon coun- than most other races, there are usually two tries, but . ,• I'lT jp j -jI several else- great parties which dispute tor mastery m the where. ^ Contrat Social, liv. ii. ch. iii. 70 FRANCE. state. But in the countries on the continent of Europe this is not usually true. We there find a number of parties or groups which are independent of each other to a greater or less extent, and form coalitions, some- times of a most unnatural kind, to support or oppose the Pfovernment of the hour. Now the existence of several distinct political groups has a decisive influence on the working of the parliamentary system. Let us consider this question a moment. When a country with a parliamentary form of gov- ernment is divided into two hostile parties, parliament- tlic miuistors who lead the majority of the ary system iii p ii n there are popular cliamber must 01 course belong all to normally only two one of tliose parties, or all to the other, and parties. they are forced by circumstances to work in harmony. But even when party strife is less bitter, and parties have begun to break up, experience has proved that the best policy for the ministers is to sup- port each other and stand or fall together. Lord Mel- bourne is reported to have exclaimed at a cabinet meet- ing, after a discussion on the question of changing the duty on corn, " Now is it to lower the price of corn, or is n't it ? It is not much matter which we say, but mind, we must all say the same." ^ The statesmanship implied by this remark may not have been of the high= est kind, but the politics were sound, and showed a knowledge of the great secret of success. It is, indeed, an axiom in politics that, except under very peculiar circumstances, coalition ministries are short-lived com- pared with homogeneous ones, whose members are in BageLot, English Constitution, p. 16, note. PARTIES IN THE PAELIAMENTARY SYSTEM. 71 cordial sympathy with each other. Now so long as the ministers cling together, every member of the House must consider the cabinet and its policy as a whole, and make up his mind whether he will support it, or help to turn it out and put in an entirely different set of ministers with another poHcy. He cannot support the cabinet on certain questions and oppose it on others. jHe must sacrifice details to the general question. The result is that the members either group themselves about the ministers, and vote with them through thick and thin, or else they attach themselves to an opposi- tion party, whose object is to turn out the cabinet, and then take of&ce itself and carry on a different policy. The normal condition of the parliamentary system, therefore, among a people sufficiently free from preju- dices to group themselves naturally, and possessing enough experience to know that the practical and attainable, and not the ideal, is the true aim in politics, is a division into two parties, each of which is ready to take of&ce whenever the other loses its majority. This has been true in England in ordinary times, and although of late years it has been frequently asserted that the two great parties in the House of Commons are destined to come to an end, and be repla,ced by a number of independent groups, the prophecy does not accord with experience. It is based on the state of the Parliament of 1892, and seems to arise from mistaking a temporary poHtical condition for a permanent one. The sudden interjection of the question of Home Rule into English politics caused a new party division on fresh lines, which necessarily broke up the traditional associ' 72 FRANCE. ations of public life, and threw both parties into a state of confusion that has not yet disappeared. On one side, the opponents of the measure were composed of men whose habits of thought had been most diverse ; while the followers of Mr. Gladstone, on the other side, included many Liberals who were forced, against their will, to subordinate to Home Rule other matters which they deemed more important. In short, the introduc- tion of a new issue shattered the old basis of cleavage; and it is not surprising that new, solidified parties were not formed in an instant. Moreover it may be noticed that although the Liberal groups in the late House of Commons talked freely of their dissensions, they acted as a single party, and supported the cabinet by their votes with astonishing fidelity. A division into two parties is not only the normal result of the parliamentary system, but also It cannot . , ,. . „ . „ work well an essential condition oi its success, feup- pose, for example, that a third party, like that of the Irish Home Rulers under Parnell, is formed, and places some one specific issue above all others, with the determination of voting against any cabinet that does not yield to its demands on that point; and suppose this body becomes large enough to hold the balance of power. If, in such a case, the two old parties do not make a coalition, or one of them does not absorb the new group by making concessions, no ministry will be able to secure a majority. Every cabinet will be overthrown as soon as it is formed, and parliamentary government will be an impossibility. Now suppose that the third party, instead of being implacably hostile to TWO PARTIES ESSE5TTIAL. 73 both the others, is willing for a time to tolerate a cabi- net from one of them, — is willing, in short, to allow the ministers to retain office provided they give no offensCc Under these circumstances parliamentary government is not impossible, but it is extremely difficult. The ministers are compelled to ride two horses at once. They must try to conciliate two inharmonious bodies of men, on pain of defeat if either of them becomes hos- tile ; and hence their tenure is unstable and their course necessarily timid. Now the larger the number of dis- cordant groups that form the majority, the harder the task of pleasing them all, and the more feeble and unstable the position of the cabinet. Nor is the diffi- culty removed by giving portfolios to the members of the several groups ; for even if this reduces the labor of satisfying the parties, it adds that of maintaining an accord among the ministers themselves, and entails the proverbial weakness of coalition governments. A cab- inet which depends for its existence on the votes of the Chamber can pursue a consistent policy with firm- ness and effect only when it can rely for support on a compact and faithful majority; and therefore the par- liamentary system will give the country a strong and efficient government only in case the majority consists of a single party. But this is not all. The opposition must also be united. So long as the ministry stands, the composition of the minority is, indeed, of little con- sequence ; but when that minority becomes a majority, it must in turn be a single party, or the weakness of a coalition ministry cannot be avoided. It follows that a division of the Chamber into two parties, and two par 74 FRANCE. ties only, is necessary in order that the parliamentary form of government should permanently produce good results. In France the parliamentary system has not worked well, because this condition has not been ful- tionhasnot filled.^ The various groups of Monarchists filled in and Bonapartists have toerether formed in the France. ^ ® . . Chambers the party of the Reactionaries, or as it is more commonly called, the Right.^ The rest of ^ This is recognized by many French writers, e. g., Lamy, La Repub- lique en 1883 ; Paul Laffitte, Le Suffrage Universel et la Re'gime Parlementaire, pt. i. ch. iii. ; Saleilles, in the Annals of the American Academy of Political Science, July, 1895, pp. 57, 64, 65. But the reason for the existence of a number of groups in France seems to be only partially understood. The most clear-sighted writer on this subject is Dupriez. (See Les Ministres, vol. ii. pp. 363-65, 370-71, and 386-95.) ^ For readers unfamiliar with European politics it may perhaps be necessary to explain the meaning of the terms Right and Left, as they are used all over the Continent. In England a broad aisle runs from the Speaker's desk through the middle of the House of Commons to the main entrance opposite, and the benches of the members are arranged parallel to this aisle and facing it. The Ministry sit on the front bench at the right of the Speaker (the so-called Treasury Bench), their supporters taking seats behind and alongside of them, while the opposition sit on the left side of the House. The Liberals and Conservatives, therefore, are each to be found sometimes on one side of the House and sometimes on the other, according as their party is in power or not. But on the Conti- nent the seats are arranged, as a rule, like those of a theatre, as in our legislative bodies, the ministers usually sitting immediately in front of the Speaker or President, on a bench which sometimes faces him and sometimes looks the other way, while the conservative members sit on the President's right, the more liberal next to these, and the radical on his left. As this arrangement is permanent, the words Right and Left have come to be generally used for Conservative and Liberal ; and the diiferent groups are often designated by their position in the Chamber, as the Right, the Centre, and the Left Centre, the Left, or the Extreme Left. _ MANY GROUPS IN FRANCE. 75 the members have been supporters of the Republic, and have formed nominally a single party, but they have really been held together only by a desire to maintain the existing form of government, and have seldom acted in concert except when they thought that threat- ened. They have always comprised men of every shade of opinion, from conservatives to radicals and even sociahsts, and would speedily have broken up into com- pletely hostile parties, if it had not been for the fear of the Reactionaries. Even under the pressure of this fear their cohesion has been very slight, for they have been divided into a number of groups with organiza- tions which, though never either complete or durable, have been quite separate ; and again, these groups have often been subdivided into still smaller groups, whose members were loosely held together by similarity of opinions or desire for advancement, usually under the standard of some chief, who held, or hoped to win, a place in the cabinet. In fact, the parties in the Cham- ber of Deputies have presented such a series of dissolv- ing views that it is very difficult to draw an intelligible picture of them.^ 1 The line of cleavage between the monarchists and republicans has now ceased to be of much importance. All the larger factions now profess to be republican. These factions are constantly gaining or losing members so that it is almost impossible to state their exact numerical strength at any- one time. Sometimes it happens, indeed, that a member of the Chamber may profess to belong to two political groups at the same time. No single faction ever forms a majority of the Chamber so that a coalition or Hoc is necessary. The following groups at present make up the Chamber of Deputies but their names afford, for the most part, no indication of the principles to which they give allegiance : Conservatives (or members of the extreme Right) ; Nationalists (members of the Action Libdrale 76 FRANCE. During ttie struggle with MacMahon, the Republicans had been solidly united, but the danger had not passed very long before the Radicals began to show themselves independent. They soon became quite ready to upset any ministry that offended them, and in fact cabinet after cabinet was overthrown by the votes of the Right and the Extreme Left. Even Gambetta, who had striven to keep the Republicans together, did not escape this fate, in spite of his immense popularity both in the country and in the Parliament. He did not consent to form a ministry until November, 1881 ; and after holding office only two months and a half, he was forced to resign by the refusal of the Chamber to introduce the scrutin de liste for the election of deputies. He lived only till the end of the year, and his death deprived France of her only great popular leader. After his fall, politics followed the old course, and there passed across the stage a series of short-lived ministries. During the last few years there has indeed been a nearer approach to a division of the deputies into two great parties — one Conservative and the other Rad- ical — than at any other time since the birth of the Republic; and yet the history of the successive minis- tries during the life of the later Chambers makes it clear with how little sharpness the lines are drawn, and how little the members of the various groups populaire) ; Progressives ; Republicans (or Moderates) ; Radicals ; Radical-Socialists ; Independent Socialists ; and Independents. The first three groups make ixp the Right ; the last five usually make up the Left; but some of the smaller groups keep shifting from side to side. CAUSES OF THE STATE OF PARTIES. 77 that compose the majority can be relied upon to be faithful to the cabinet. In short, there has been an approach to the system of two parties, but as yet not a very near approach, and the numerous de- tached groups still remain the basis of parliamentary life. Let us now consider the reasons for the subdivi- sions of the Chamber into a number of ^ Causes of groups. And first we must look at a source the existence of political dissensions with which we are parties in not familiar at home, but which is to be found in almost every nation in Europe. Few persons ever ask themselves why the bodies of men who assemble every year at the State The lack of House or the Capitol have power to make apouticai consensus laws. It is not because they have more per- sonal force or wisdom or virtue than any one else. A congress of scientific men may contain all these quali- ties in greater abundance, but it cannot change a single line in the statute-book. Is it because they represent the people? But we all know that they occasionally pass laws which the people do not want, and yet we obey those laws without hesitation. Moreover, this answer only pushes the question one step further back, for why should we obey the people ? A few centuries ago nobody recognized any right on the part of the people to govern or misgovern themselves as they chose, or rather on the part of the majority to impose their wiU on the minority ; and in many countries of the world no such right is recognized to-day. How does it happen that there is not a class of men among us who 78 FRANCE. think tliat the legislature does not fairly represent the people, or who think that the right to vote ought to be limited by a certain educational or property qualifica- tion, or by the profession of a certain creed ; and why does not some such class of men get up a rival legisla- ture ? The fact is that, while we may differ in regard to the ideal form of government, we are all of one mind on the question of what government is entitled to our actual allegiance, and we are all determined to yield to that government our obedience and support. In short, a common understanding or consensus in regard to the basis and form of the government is so universal here that we feel as if it were natural and inevitable; but in all countries this is not so. Such a consensus is the foundation of all political authority, of all law and order ; and it is easy to see that if it were seriously questioned, the position of the government would be shaken, that if it were destroyed, the country would be plunged into a state of anarchy. Now persons who do not "^ accept the consensus on which the political authority of the day is based are termed in France Irreconcilables. Men of this sort do not admit the rightfulness of the existing government, and although they may submit to it for the moment, their object is to effect a revolution by peaceful if not by violent means. Hence their position is essentially different from that of all other parties, for these aim only at directing the policy of the government within constitu- tional limits, and can be intrusted with power without danger to the fundamental institutions of the nation, while the Irreconcilables, on the contrary, would use LACK OF A CONSENSUS. 79 their power to upset those institutions, and therefore cannot be suffered to get control of the state. They form an opposition that is incapable of taking office, and so present a disturbing element, which in a parUa- mentary form of government throws the whole system out of gear.^ Another thing to be noticed about a consensus is that it cannot be created artificially, but must ^ consensus be the result of a slow growth and long tra- ^6^^^ ditions. Its essence lies in the fact that it is ^^p^^^^- unconscious. The people of the United States, for example, could not, by agreement, give to a dictator the power the Czar wields in Russia, for except in the pres- ence of imminent danger he would have no authority unless the people believed in his inherent right to rule, and the people cannot make themselves believe in any such right simply by agreeing to do so. The r^j^^ French foundation of government is faith, not rea- dettroyed'^ son, and the faith of a people is not vital clfconsen-^" unless they have been born with it.^ Now, ^'^^^ * It is impossible to draw a sharp line between what is revolutionary and what is not ; or to define exactly an Irreconcilable. The matter depends in fact upon the opinion of the community. Thus, before 1886, Home Rule might fairly be said to have been revolutionary, and the Irish Home Rulers to have been Irreconcilables ; but after Mr. Gladstone made Home Rule a practical question in English politics, it would have been absurd to call Parnell's followers Irreconcilables. 2 Curiously enough an exception to this principle, and almost a solitary one, is to be found in the history of the United States. The generation that framed the Constitution looked upon that document as very imper- fect, but they clung to it tenaciously as the only defense against national dismemberment, and in order to make it popular, they praised it beyond their own belief in its merits. This efEort to force themselves to ad- mire the Constitution was marvelously successful, and resulted, in the 80 FRANCE. in France, tlie Revolution of 1789 destroyed all faith in the political institutions of the past, and was unable to substitute anything else. It did, indeed, give birth to a code of law, and to an administrative system, both of which have taken a strong hold on the nation, and have survived every change in the government. These are the permanent elements in France, and the only ones that have acquired the blind force of tradition. They supply a machinery that is unshaken by political up- heavals, and it is this that has made it possible for the country to pass through so many revolutions without falling into a state of anarchy.^ But in regard to in- stitutions of a purely pohtical character, the nation has not been so fortunate, for the governments that followed the Revolution were not sufficiently durable to lay even a foundation for a general consensus, and the lack of continuity has so thoroughly prevented the steady growth of opinion that the people have not succeeded in acquiring a political creed. The The effect t • ^ p r> i of tins on result IS that every lorm oi government that parties. . . . has existed m J^ ranee has its partisans, who are irreconcilable under every other ; while the great mass of the middle classes and the peasants have no strong political convictions, and are ready to support any government that maintains order. Thus the two Empires bequeathed to the Republic the group of Bona- partists, while the Monarchists are a legacy from the old regime and the reign of Louis Philippe. At pres- next generation, in a worship of the Constitution, of which its framera never dreamed. 1 Cf. Laffitte, pp. 208, 209. POLITICAL OPINIONS THEORETICAL. 81 ent it seems altogether probable that, if no great European crisis occurs, the Right will end by accept- ing the Republic, and if so the irreconcilable elements will disappear or become insignificant, and one of the chief obstacles to the formation of two great parties, one Conservative and the other Radical, will be removed. But this is only one of several obstacles, and the others are so great that it will probably be a other causes long time before the system of groups breaks dhfsfonof down in France, or is replaced by that of two p*^^*^®^- political parties. In the first place, the Frenchman is theoretical rather than practical in politics. He is incHned to . 1 1 . . 1 . , . Theoretical pursue an ideal, striving to realize nis concep- character of tion of a perfect form of society, and is re- political „.„,-, opinions. luctant to give up any part of it for the sake of attaining so much as hes within his reach. Such a tendency naturally gives rise to a number of groups, each with a separate ideal, and each unwilling to make the sacrifice that is necessary for a fusion into a great party. In short, the intensity of political sentiment prevents the development of real political issues. To the Frenchman, public questions have an absolute rather than a relative or practical bearing, and there- fore he cares more for principles and opinions than for facts. This tendency is shown in the programmes of the candidates, which are apt to be philosophic docu- ments instead of statements of concrete policy, and, although published at great length, often give a com- paratively small idea of the position of the author on 82 FRANCE. the immediate questions of the day.^ It is shown also in the newspapers, and the use that is made of them. An Anglo-Saxon reads the newspapers chiefly for infor- mation about current events, and as all the papers contain very much the same news, he habitually reads only one. But the French papers contain far less news, and as the Frenchman reads them largely for the sake of the editorials, he commonly reads several in order to compare the opinions they express. It is partly on account of this mental attitude, and partly owing to the absence of the habit of do not self-government, and the lack of sympathy readily in bctwcen different parts of the country, that the French do not organize readily in politics. This is the more curious because in mihtary matters they organize more easily than any other people in the world ; and it is no doubt the military instinct, as well as the want of confidence in their own power of po- litical organization, that disposes them to seek a leader and follow him blindly after he has won their confi- ^ Lebon, France as It Is, p. 85. Abstracts of all the electoral programmes issued by the successful candidates for the Chamber of Deputies at the elections of 1889 and 1893, together with the results of the ballots, have been published by Duguet, under the title Les Deputes et les Cahiers Electoraux. These volumes are very instructive ; and a perusal of them shows that the programmes of the Radicals are much longer and less vague than the others, but often demand measures which lie out of the domain of practical politics, such as revision of the Constitution, abolition of the Senate, abolition of state aid to the churches, confiscation of all ecclesiastical property, elective judiciary, etc. The programmes give a very good idea of the candidate's general turn of mind ; and those of the Radicals may be said to contain their conception of the ideal state of polities or of society. The Radicals are, indeed, the only group among PARTIES LITTLE ORGANIZED. 83 dence.^ The inability to organize readily in politics has this striking result, that vehement as some of the groups are, and passionate as is their attachment to their creeds, they make little effort to realize their aims, by associating together their supporters in all parts of the country for concerted action. In fact, there may be said to be no national party organizations in France.^ The various groups into which the deputies are divided have, as a rule, no existence whatever outside of Par- liament, the candidates for seats merely calHng them- selves in general terms. Moderates, Radicals, Socialists, or simply Republicans without further qualification, and attaching themselves to a particular group after the Chamber has met. Moreover, the programmes, which are drawn up by each candidate for himself, are only individual confessions of faith, and are all different, so that there is no policy which any party as a whole is pledged to support. Before the opening of the cam paign, indeed, party gatherings or banquets take place, and speeches are made, but until recent elections, no common platform of principles has been issued except by the Socialists.^ It is after the campaign has begun, however, that the absence of party organization is most clearly seen. Then the struggle is conducted in each the Republicans that can be said to have anything like a positive pro-, gramme, and this is the source both of their strength and their weakness. 1 Cf. Channes, Letter of Aug. 22, 1885. 2 Cf. Lebon, France as It Is, p. 75 ; Theodore Stanton in the North American Rev., vol. 155, p. 471. This contrasts strangely with the United States, where the machinery of a party has sometimes shown more vitality than its principles. 8 Daniel, UAnnee Politique, 1893, pp. 254r-80. 84 ^FRANCE. electoral district with very little regard to the rest o£ the country, and in fact each district appears like a separate nation engaged in a distinct contest of its own.^ Political effort becomes localized, and except for the candidates themselves, who confine their labors to their constituencies, scarcely a man of prominence opens his mouth. One might suppose that, under a parliamentary form of sfovernment, party ore^anization would French hardly be required, and that, as in England, mechanism the uccd of poHtical cohcsiou would be to a in splitting tit • • up the great extent supphed by a strong mmistry that really led Parliament and the nation. But here we meet with some of the other causes that tend to produce a multiplicity of groups, — causes that spring from certain of the minor French institu- tions which were referred to in the beginning of the first chapter as inconsistent with the parliamentary system. Three of these are especially important, — the method of electing deputies, the system of committees in the Chambers, and the practice of interpellations. In France the scrutin de liste, or the election of all the deputies from a department on one ticket, of elating'' and the scrutin d' arrondissement, or the use eputies. ^^ single electoral districts, have prevailed alternately, the latter being in force at the present day.^ But under both systems an absolute majority of all the votes cast is required for election. If there are more than two candidates in the field, and no one of them 1 Comte de Chaudordy, La France en 1889, p. 89. 2 See, however, note on p. 17, ante. METHOD OF CHOOSING DEPUTIES. 85 gets such a majority, a second vote, called the hallotage, is taken two weeks later, and at this a plurality is enough to elect.^ Now it is clear that such a procedure encourages each political group to nominate a separate candidate for the first ballot. Suppose, for example, that there are Reactionary and Moderate Kepubhcan candidates in the field, and that the Radicals prefer the Republican to the Reactionary, still they have nothing to lose by running a candidate of their own on the first ballot, for if the Reactionary can poll more votes than both his rivals combined, he will be elected in any event; if he cannot, he will not be elected whether the Radicals put up a candidate of their own or not. In this last case, the first ballot will have counted for nothing, and the Radicals will be able to vote for the Moderate Republican at the hallotage, and elect him then. They are Hkely, indeed, to gain a positive advan- tage by nominating a separate candidate, for if they succeed in polKng a large vote on the first ballot, they are in an excellent position to wring concessions from the Moderates as a price of their support. ^ Law of June 16, 1885, Art. 5. (This article was not repealed by the Law of Feb. 13, 1889.) By the same article a quarter as many votes as there are voters registered is required for election on the first ballot. According to strict parliamentary usage, the term ballotage is applied only to cases where, at the final trial, the voting is confined by law to the two names highest on the poll at the preceding ballot, but the word is popularly used for any final ballot where a plurality is decisive. For the choice of a senator by the electoral college of a department, the votes of a quarter of the college, and a majority of all the votes actually cast, are required on the first two ballots, while on the third a plurality is enough. Law of August 2, 1875, Art. 15. The election of delegates . to the college by the municipal councils is conducted in the same manner. Law of Dec. 9, 1884, Art. 8. 86 FRANCE. Cumbrous as it is, this system of voting dates back to the election of the States General in 1789, and, with a couple of short breaks, has been maintained in France ever since.^ The idea that a representative ought to be the choice of a majority of the people seems, indeed, to be natural in democracies, for we find it put in practice elsewhere. Thus, in the United States, a majority vote was formerly very commonly required for election, but it is instructive to notice that it was found to hinder the smooth working of two political parties, and has been generally though not quite universally abandoned.^ The fact that election by majority did not give rise to a multiplicity of parties in America shows that by itself it does not produce that result, where the other influences favor the development of two parties ; but it is nevertheless clear that where a number of groups exist, it tends to foster them, and prevent their fusing into larger bodies.^ The French system has been praised on the ground that it saves the people from the yoke of huge party machines, and ^ Poudra et Pierre, liv. ii. ch. vii. ^ Stimson, Am. Statute Law, § 232. In Massachusetts, election by plu- rality was introduced in 1855. Const, of Mass., Amendments, Art. xiv. For the previous law, see Const, pt. ii. ch. i. sec. n. Art. iv. ; ch. ii. sec. I. Art. iii. ; sec. n. Art. i. ; Rev. Stats, ch. iv. sec. xui. 8 At the elections of 1885, which were held under the system of tcrutin de liste, there were two Republican lists of candidates in almost all the departments. G. Channes, Letter of Oct. 30, 1885. At the elections of 1889 and 1893, held under the scrutin d'arrondissement, there were two Republican candidates in a large proportion of the districts, the total number of candidates for a single seat running as high as ten. Duguet, Les Deputes et les Cahiers Electoraux en 1889 ; Id., 1893. And see Tableau des Elections a la Chambre des Deputes, dresse aux Archives de la Chambre. THE SYSTEM OF COMMITTEES. 87 enables them to select their candidates more freely.^ This is true, and it is a great advantage. But the converse is also true ; the system tends to prevent the formation of great consolidated parties, and that is the evil from which parliamentary government suffers in France to-day.^ The system of committees in the Chambers is a still more important matter. Each of the French rj^^ system chambers is divided into sections called Bu- tferinThe reaux, of which there are nine in the Senate ^°^ ^^^' and eleven in the Chamber of Deputies.^ The Bureaux are of equal size, and every member of the Chamber belongs to one and only one of them, the division being made afresh every month by lot. This is a very old institution in France, a relic of a time before parliament- ary government had been thought of ; for not only do we find it in the Assembly of Notables and the States General that met on the eve of the Revolution,* but it 1 Alfred Naquet, "The French Electoral System," in the North Am. Rev., vol. 155, pp. 467-68. 2 It is not a little curious that just at this time, when the English system of two parties is thought by many people to be in danger of breaking up, a motion should be made in the House of Commons to introduce election by majority vote and second ballot. Such a motion was made by Mr. Dalziel on April 5, 1895. ^ For the constitution of the Bureaux and the election of the commit- tees, see Poudra et Pierre, liv. v. chs. ii. and iii. ; Reginald Dickinson, Summary of the Constitution and Procedure of Foreign Parliaments, 2d ed. pp. 363-66. These Bureaux must not be confounded with the Bureau of the Cham- ber, which consists of the President, the Vice-Presidents, and the Sec- retaries. The habit in France of using the same word with different meanings is liable to be the source of no little confusion to the students of her institutions. 4 Poudra et Pierre, § 976. 88 FRANCE. existed in the ecclesiastical assemblieSj and to some extent in tlie States General, at a mucli earlier date.^ The use of the lot is, indeed, a survival from the Mid- dle Ages, when it was a common method of selecting officials.^ The Bureaux meet separately and have three functions. The first is that of making a preHminary examination of the credentials of members of the Cham- ber, which are divided among them for the purpose. The second is that of holding a preHminary discussion on bills brought into the Chamber, before they are referred to a committee ; but as a matter of fact this discussion is perfunctory, and is lunited to finding out in a general way what members of the Bureau favor or oppose the bill.^ The third and most important function of the Bureaux is the election of committees, for with rare exceptions all the committees of both Chambers are selected in the same way. Each of the Bureaux chooses one of its own members, and the per- sons so elected together constitute the committee. In the case of the more important committees it is some- times desirable to have a larger number of members, and if so the Bureaux choose in like manner two or even three members apiece, — the Chamber in each case ^ Sciout, Histoire de la Constitution Civile du Clerge, p. 36. While writing, a friend has pointed out to me that the States General which met at Tours in 1484 was divided into six sections by provinces. See a jour- nal of this body by Jehan Masselin, in the Collection de Documents inedits sur V Histoire de France puhlies par ordre du Roi, Paris, 1835, pp. 66-73. ^ The chief relic of the lot left in Anglo-Saxon institutions is, of course, its use in the selection of the jury, — a survival which is due to the fact already pointed out, that the English royal justice developed at an early period. ® Dupriez, vol. ii. p. 404. THE SYSTEM OF COMMITTEES. 89 directing, by its rules or by special vote, the number of members to be elected. Thus the committee on the budget, which is the most important one of the year, consists of three members chosen by each of the Bureaux in the Chamber of Deputies, and contains, therefore, thirty-three members ; while the correspond- ing committee in the Senate contains eighteen members, or two from each Bureau. The committee on the budget and the one appointed to audit the accounts of the government are permanent, and remain unchanged for a year. A few of the others (those on local affairs, on petitions, on leave of absence, and on granting permission to members of parliament to introduce bills) serve for a month and then are chosen afresh. With these exceptions every measure is in theory referred to a special committee elected by the Bureaux for the purpose ; but as there are certain to be in every session a number of bills that cover very much the same ground, a rigid application of this princij^le would result in inconsistent reports on the same matter by different committees, and would throw the work of the Chamber into utter confusion. A prac- tice has, therefore, grown up of treating certain com- mittees — such as those on the army, on labor, and on railroads — as virtually permanent, and referring to them all bills on their respective subjects.^ We have seen that with rare exceptions all committees, whether permanent, temporary, or special, are elected by the Bureaux, but these last, being created anew every month, acquire no corporate feeling, and hence have 1 Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 385-86. VOL. I. 90 FRANCE. no real leaders. Owing partly to this fact they do not choose freely, and the chief of the parliamentary groups meet and barter away the places on the important com- mittees, which are thus cut and dried beforehand.* But whether the choice of committee-men is really made by the Bureaux or dictated by the chiefs of the groups, the main point to notice is that the system is entirely inconsistent with the parliamentary form of government. The cabinet cannot exert the same influence over an election conducted in this way that it could over one made by the Chamber in open session. In the latter case it might insist on the choice of a majority of the committee from among its own friends, and make of the matter a cabinet question; but it cannot treat the failure of several irresponsible sections of the Chamber to act in accordance with its wishes as an expression of want of confidence by the Chamber as a whole. The result is that the committees are not nominated by the cabinet, or necessarily in sympathy with it ; and yet all measures, including those proposed by the government, are referred to them to revise as they think best. Now if the ministers are to be responsible for directing the work of the Chamber, they ought to have a policy of their own and stand or fall on that. They ought to be at liberty to determine their own course of action, and to present their measures to Parliament in a form that they entirely approve. But if a committee has power to amend government bills, the ministers must either assume the burden of trying to persuade the Chamber to reverse the amendments, with all the influence of the ^ C£. Simon, Nos Hommes d'Etat, pp. 41, 241. THE SYSTEM OF COMMITTEES. 91 committee against tliem; or they must take tlie risk of opposing the bill as reported, although they still approve of many of its features ; or finally they must accept the bill as it stands, and become responsible for a measure with which they are not themselves fully satisfied. The committees in fact use their power with- out shrinking, and the annual budget, for example, has been compared to a tennis-ball sent backward and forward between the minister and the committee until a compromise can be reached.^ M. Dupriez, in his excellent work on the ministers in the principal countries of Europe and America, paints in very strong colors the evils of the French committee system. He points out how little influence the ministers have with the committees, who often regard them almost as the representatives of a hos- tile power in the state .^ He shows that while the ministers have no right to be present at committee meetings, and are invited to attend only when they wish to express their views, the committees claim a right to examine the administrative offices, insist on seeing books and papers, and volunteer advice.^ So little respect, indeed, do the committees pay to the opinions of the cabinet, and so freely do they amend its bills, that, as M. Dupriez sarcastically remarks, the government and the committee are never in perfect accord except when the former submits to the latter.* He says, moreover, that when a bill comes up for ^ Simon, Souviens toi du Deux Decembre, p. 314. 2 Vol. ii. pp. 406-7. 8 Id., pp. 395, 405, 423-24, 438-39. * Id., pp. 405-6, 412. 92 FRANCE. debate the reporter of the committee is a rival who has great influence with the Chamber, while the depu- ties are inclined to regard the ministers with jealousy and defiance.^ Nor do the woes of the cabinet end here, for its authority is reduced to so low a point that its biUs are quite freely amended during the debate on the motion of individual deputies.^ Of all the committees, the most domineering and vex- atious is that on the budget. This committee seems to take pride in criticising the estimates and making them over, both as regards income and expenditures, while each member exerts himself to add appropriations for the benefit of his own constituents, so that when the report is finally made the government can hardly recog- nize its own work.^ In strong contrast with all this is Dupriez's description of the procedure on the budget in England.* There the authority of the ministers is expressly protected by a standing order of the House of Commons to the effect that no petition or motion for the expenditure of the public revenue shall be enter- tained except on the recommendation of the Crown ; and in accordance with a firmly established practice proposals for national taxes originate only with the government. In regard to amendments of the budget, members of the House may move to diminish, but not to increase an appropriation, and as a matter of fact the budget is rarely amended by the House at all. The comparison of the English and French methods of dealing with the budget goes far to explain the differ- 1 Dupriez, vol. ii., p. 411. « ici., pp. 425-26. 8 Id., p. 412. * Id., vol. i. pp. 110-12. INTERPELLATIONS. 93 ence in the position of the two cabinets. Such a state of things as exists in France cannot fail to lessen the authority and dignity of the ministers, and place them at the mercy of the committees. It prevents them from framing their own programme, and insisting that the deputies shall accept or reject it as it stands ; and thus, instead of compelling the majority to act solidly together under the leadership of the cabinet, it allows any deputy to use his place on a committee as a means of urging his own personal views. Hence it tends to dislocate the majority and break it into sec- tions, with policies more or less out of harmony with each other. While, therefore, the French scheme of com- mittees has good points, and some features that might be very valuable under another form of government, it is clearly incompatible with the parliamentary system.^ The habit of addressing interpellations to the min- isters has a direct bearing on the stability of interpgUa,- the cabinet and the subdivision of parties ; *^°°^" for it cannot be repeated too often that these things are inseparable. The existence of the ministry depends on the support of the majority, and if that is compact and harmonious, the ministry will be strong and durable ; if not, it will be feeble and short-lived. The converse is also true. The cohesive force that unites the majority is loyalty to the cabinet and submission to its guidance, but if the cabinets are weak, or are constantly overthrown at short intervals, they cannot 1 Lebon, U Allemagne, p. 88, remarks that the Bureaux in the French Chamber were intended to subdivide the factions, and accomplish this only too well. 94 FRANCE. acquire the autliority that is necessary to lead the majority and weld it into a single party. This is especially the case when the crises occur over matters which are not of vital consequence to the bulk of the followers of the government, and yet that is precisely the state of things that interpellations tend to create. It is of the essence of parliamentary government that the majority should support the ministers so long, and only so long, as it approves of their course, and this means their course as a whole, in administration as well as in legislation ; for parHament, having the fate of the ministers in its hands, holds them responsible for all their acts, and has gradually extended its supervision over the whole field of government. Now a parliament can judge of the legislative policy of the cabinet by the bills it introduces, but it is not so easy to get the information necessary for a sound opinion on the efficiency of the administration. It is largely to satisfy this need that a practice has grown up in the House of Commons of asking the ministers questions, which may relate to any conceivable subject, and afPord a means of putting the cabinet through a very searching examination. Of course the privilege is freely used to harass the government, but the answer is not followed by a general debate, or by a vote, except in the un- usual case where a motion to adjourn is made for the purpose of bringing the matter under discussion.^ ^ The motion to adjourn is the only one that is in order, and since 1882 its use has been carefully limited. May, Pari. Practice, 10th ed. p. 240 et seq. In this form or some other a vote is occasionally taken on a single detail of administration. The most famous instances of late years have been the affair of Miss Cass in 1887, where the House of INTERPELLATIONS. 95 A similar practice has been adopted in France, and questions are addressed to the ministers by members who really want information. But another kind of question has also developed, which is used not to get information, but to call the cabinet to account, and force the Chamber to pass judgment upon its con- duct. This is the interpellation.^ In form it is similar to the question, but the procedure in the two cases is quite different. A question can be addressed to a minister only with his consent, whereas the interpel- lation is a matter of right, which any deputy may exercise, without regard to the wishes of the cabinet. The time, moreover, when it shall be made is fixed by the Chamber itself, and except in matters relating to foreign affairs, the date cannot be set more than a month ahead. But by far the most important differ- ence consists in the fact that the author of the question can alone reply to the minister, no further . discussion being permitted, and no motion being in order ; while the interpellation is followed both by a general debate and by motions. These are in the form of motions to Commons expressed its disapproval of the government's refusal to make an inquiry by voting to adjourn, but where no member of the cabinet felt obliged to resign ; and the defeat of Lord Rosebery's ministry in 1895. In the last case a motion was made to reduce the salary of the Secretary of State for War, in order to draw attention to the lack of a sufficient supply of ammunition, and the motion was carried ; but there can be no doubt that the cabinet would not have resigned if its position had not already been hopeless. In the House of Lords questions can always be debated. May, p. 206. ^ For the rules and practice in the case of questions, see Poudra et Pierre, liv. vii. ch. iii., and Supp. 1879-80, § 1539. In the case of interpellations. Id,, liv. viL ch. iv. 96 FRANCE. pass to the order of the day, and may be orders of the day pure and simple, as they are called, which contain no expression of opinion, or they may be what are termed orders of the day with a motive, such as " the Chamber, approving the declarations of the Govern- ment, passes to the order of the day." Several orders of this kind are often moved, and they are put to the vote in succession. The ministers select one of them (usually one proposed by their friends for the purpose), and declare that they will accept that. If it is rejected by the Chamber, or if a hostile order of the day is adopted, and the matter is thought to be of sufficient im- portance, the cabinet resigns. This is a very common way of upsetting a ministry, but it is one which puts the cabinet in a position of great disadvantage, for a government would be superhuman that never made mistakes, and yet here is a method by which any of its acts can be brought before the Chamber, and a vote forced on the question whether it made a mistake or not. Moreover, members of the opposition are given a chance to employ their ingenuity in framing orders of the day so as to catch the votes of those deputies who are in sympathy with the cabinet, but cannot approve of the act in question.^ Now if adverse votes ^ A very good example of the various shades of praise or blame that may be expressed by orders of the day can be found in the Journal Officiel for July 9, 1893. There had been a riot in Paris, which had not been suppressed without violence and even bloodshed. The police were accused of wanton brutality, and an interpellation on the subject was debated in the Chamber of Deputies on July 8. The order of the day quoted in the text, " The Chamber, approving the declarations of the government, passes to the order of the day," was adopted, but the follow- iag were also moved : — INTERPELLATIONS. 97 in the Chamber are to be followed by the resignation of the cabinet and the formation of a new one, it is evi- dent that to secure the proper stability and permanence in the ministry, such votes ought to be taken only on measures of really great importance, or on questions that involve the whole poHcy and conduct of the " The Chamber, disapproving the acts of brutality of which the police have been guilty, requests the government to give to the police instruc- tions and orders more conformable to the laws of justice and humanity." " The Chamber, disapproving the proceedings of the police, passes to the order of the day." " The Chamber, approving the declarations of the government, and per- suaded that it will take measures to prevent the violence of the police officials, passes to the order of the day." " The Chamber, censuring the policy of provocation and reaction on the part of the government, passes to the order of the day." " The Chamber, hoping that the government will give a prompt and legitimate satisfaction to public opinion, passes to the order of the day." " Considering that the government has acknowledged from the tribune that its policy has caused in Paris ' sad occurrences,' ' deeds that must certainly be regretted,' and * some acts of brutality,' the Chamber takes notice of the admission of the President of the Council, demands that the exercise of power shall be inspired by the indefeasible sentiments of jus- tice, of foresight, and of humanity, and passes to the order of the day." " The Chamber, convinced that the government of the Republic ought to make the law respected and maintain order, approving the declarations of the government, passes to the order of the day." " The Chamber, regretting the acts of violence on the part of the police, and taking notice of the declarations of the government, passes to the order of the day." "The Chamber, approving the declaration whereby the government has announced its desire to put an end to the practices and habits of the police which have been pointed out, passes to the order of the day." " The Chamber, convinced of the necessity of causing the laws to be respected by all citizens, passes to the order of the day." In this case, by voting priority for the first of these motions and adopting it, the Chamber avoided the snares prepared for it by the in- genious wording of the others. 98 FRANCE. administration. It is evident also that tliey ought not to be taken hastily^ or under excitement, but only after the Chamber has deliberately made up its mind that it disapproves of the cabinet, and that the country would on the whole be benefited by a change of ministers. The reverse of all this is true of the French system of interpellations, and a cabinet which in the morning sees no danger ahead, and enjoys the confidence of the Chamber and the nation, may be upset before nightfall by a vote provoked in a moment of excitement on a matter of secondary importance. The frequency with which interpellations are used to upset the cabinet may be judged by the fact that out of the twenty-one ministries that resigned in consequence of a vote of the Chamber of Deputies during the years 1879-1896, ten went to pieces on account of orders of the day moved after an interpellation, or in the course of debate.^ Several of these orders covered, indeed, the general policy of the cabinet, but others — like the one relating to the attendance of the employees of the state railroads at a congress of labor unions, which occasioned the resignation of Casimir-Perier's min- istry in May, 1894 — had no such broad significance. Moreover, the production of actual cabinet crises is by ^ C£. Haucour, Gouvernements et ministeres de la IIP republique fran- faise {1870-1893) ; Muel, Gouvernements, ministeres et constitutions de la France depuis cent ans. Among the resignations brought about in this way, I have counted that of Rouvier's cabinet in 1887, although this was caused not by the vote of an order of the day, but by the refusal of the Chamber to postpone the debate on an interpellation, and although the cabinet continued to hold office for a few days pending the resignation of President Gr^vy. INTERPELLATIONS. 99 no means the whole evil caused by interpellations. The enfeebling of the authority of the ministers by hostile votes about affairs on which they do not feel bound to stake their office is, perhaps, an even more serious matter, for no cabinet can retain the prestige that is necessary to lead the Chambers in a parliamentary gov- ernment, if it is to be constantly censured and put in a minority even in questions of detail. The ministers are not obliged, it is true, to answer interpellations,^ but unless some reason of state can be given for refusing, such as that an answer would prejudice diplomatic negotiations, a refusal would amount to a confession of error, or would indicate a desire to conceal the fact, and would weaken very much the position of the cabinet. The large part that interpellations play in French politics is shown by the fact that they arouse more pop- ular interest than the speeches on great measures ; ^ and, indeed, the most valuable quality for a minister to possess is a ready tact and quick wit in answering them.^ The first two institutions referred to as not in har- mony with parliamentary government — that is, the method of electing deputies and the system of com- mittees in the Chambers — have real merit. Both tend to check the tyranny of party, and under a form of government where the existence of two great parties was not essential, they might be very valuable. But, except in a despotism, the interpellation followed by a motion expressing the judgment of the Chamber is a 1 Poudra et Pierre, § 1555. ^ Simon, Nos Hommes d'Etat, p. 27. ® Simon, Dieu, Patrie, Liberie, p. 379. 100 FRANCE. purely vicious institution. It furnishes the politicians with an admirable opportunity for a display of parlia- mentary fireworks ; but it is hard to see how, under any form of popular government, it could fail to be mis- chievous, or serve any useful purpose that would not be much better accomplished by a question followed by no motion and no vote. The plausible suggestion has been made that the administration, being free from supervision by the courts of law, can be brought to account for its acts only in this way ; ^ but surely the same result could be as well accomplished by the simpler process of the question, and it is hard to see any reason for imperihng the existence or the prestige of the cabinet to rectify some matter of trifling conse- ^ , quence. The practice arose from the fact Jealousy J- ■■■ and distrust that, owinp^ to the immense power of the or the nunis- ? & x mrt^of the executive in France, and the frequency with Chamber. ^hich that powcr has been used despotically, the legislature has acquired the habit of looking on the cabinet officers as natural enemies, to be attacked and harassed as much as possible.^ But such a view, which 1 See Vicomte d'Avenel, " La K^forme Administrative — La Justice," Revue des Deux Mondes, June 1, 1889, pp. 595-96. 2 M. Dupriez, in the work already cited (vol. ii. p. 253 et seq.), has explained the strength of this feeling by a most valuable study of the history of the relations between the ministers and the legislature in France. He points out that it existed at the outbreak of the Revolution, for the cahiers or statements of grievances prepared by the meetings of electors held to choose members of the States General in 1789 express a widespread dislike and distrust of all ministers as such. He then shows how the Constituent Assembly tried to curtail the power of the ministers, and reduce their functions to a simple execution of its own orders. It is unnecessary here to follow the subject in detail. It is enough to remark that a large part of the political history of France since the Revolution INTERPELLATIONS. 101 is defensible enough when the ministers are independ- ent of the Parliament, becomes irrational when they are responsible to it, and bound to resign on an adverse vote. Strange as it may seem, the development of inter- pellations has coincided very closely with that of parlia- mentary government ; ^ and, in fact, the French regard the privilege as one of the main bulwarks of political liberty. It is this same feeling of antagonism to the government that has given rise to the overweening power of the committees in the Chamber, and their desire to usurp the functions of the ministers. The extent to which this feeling is carried by the Radicals is shown by the proposal made some years ago to divide the whole Chamber into a small number of per- manent grand committees, such as existed in 1848, in order to bring the ministers even more completely under the control of the deputies ; the ideal of the Extreme Radicals being the revolutionary convention, which drew all the powers of the state as directly and absolutely as possible into its own hands.^ The less is filled with struggles for power between the executive and the legisla- ture, in which the former has twice won a complete victory, and deprived the representatives of the people of all influence in the state. Under these circumstances the suspicion and jealousy of the cabinet shown by Liberal statesmen is not surprising. ^ The practice was first regularly established at the accession of Louis Philippe, the period when cabinets became thoroughly responsible to the Chamber ; and it was freely used during the Republic of 1848. After the Coup cfEtat it was, of course, abolished ; but toward the end of his reign Napoleon III., as a part of his concessions to the demand for parliamentary institutions, gradually restored the right of intei-pellation. Finally, under the present Republic the right has been used more frequently than ever before. See Poudra et Pierre, §§ 1544-49; Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 305, 317-18. 2 Cf. De la Berge, "Les Grands Comitds Parlementaires," Revue des Deux Monies, Dec. 1, 1889. 102 FRANCE. violent Republicans are, no doubt, very far from accept- ing any such ideal, but still they cannot shake out of their minds the spirit of hostility to the administration which has been nurtured by long periods of absolute rule. They fail to realize that when the ministry becomes responsible to the deputies, the relations be- tween the executive and the legislature are radically changed. The parliamentary system requires an entire harmony, a cordial sympathy, and a close cooperation between the ministers and the Chamber ; and to the obligation on the part of the cabinet to resign when the majority withdraws its approval, there corresponds a duty on the part of the majority to support the min- isters heartily so long as they remain in office. Par- liamentary government, therefore, cannot be really successful in France until a spirit of mutual confidence between the cabinet and the Chamber replaces the jealousy and distrust that now prevail. A comparison of the political history of France and Ens'land durinp- corresponding" years shows to Companson O o i. o j of the^ what extent the French procedure interferes ?893™nrtife ^^^^ discipHne and disintegrates the parties. nrmlut oF III England the Liberals came into power after ^^^^' the elections of 1892 with a small majority in the House of Commons; and, although the sup- porters of the government were far from harmonious, were, in fact, jealous of each other and interested in quite different measures, the perfection of the parlia- mentary machinery enabled the ministers to keep their followers tosfether and maintain themselves in office for three years. In France, on the other hand, the EFFECTS OF THE STATE OF PARTIES. 103 elections of 1893 produced a majority which, if not so large, was far more homogeneous ; and indeed, if we compare the position of some of the outlying groups with that of certain sections of the English Liberal party, it is fair to say that the majority in France was both larger and more homogeneous. Yet within two years this majority suffered three cabinets which rep- resented it to be overthrown on interpellations about matters of secondary importance, and finally became so thoroughly disorganized that it lost control of the situation altogether. We have surveyed some of the causes of the condi- tion of political parties in France. Let us Results of now trace a few of its results. In the first tion'^of"*^' place, the presence of the Reactionaries de- p^^^®^- prives cabinet crises of the significance they might otherwise possess. The defeat of the min- _ . ■•■ _ Uwing to the isters does not ordinarily mean the advent presence of '' the reae- to power of a different party, because there ghrn'^Sf* is no other party capable of forming a cabi- dJ)^^^^^ net, — not the Reactionaries, for they are Singe of irreconcilable and hostile to the Republic, and ^^^^' of late years have been far too few in numbers; nor those Republicans who have helped the Right to turn out the ministers, because by themselves they do not constitute a majority of the Chamber. The new cabi- net must, therefore, seek its support mainly in the ranks of the defeated minority, and hence is usually formed from very much the same material as its prede- cessor. In fact, a number of the old ministers have 104 FRANCE. generally kept their places, at most an attempt being made Effects of ^^ gain a little more support from the Right this. Qj. j^g£^ -^j giying one or two additional port- folios to the Moderates, Radicals, or Socialists.^ When a ministry falls, the parliamentary cards are shuffled, a few that have become too unpopular or too prominent are removed, and a new deal takes place. So true is this, that out of the twenty-four ministries that succeeded each other from the time President MacMahon ap- pointed a Republican cabinet in 1877 until 1897, only three contained none of the retiring ministers, the aver- age proportion of members retained being about two fifths.^ Now, the fact that the fall of the cabinet does not involve a change of party has two important effects : by removing the fear that a hostile opposition will come to power, it destroys the chief motive for discipline among the majority;^ and by making the Chamber feel that a change of ministers is not a matter of vital conse- quence, it encourages that body to turn them out with rash indifference. The result is that the cabinets are extremely short-lived; during the thirty-seven years be- tween 1875 and 1912 — there were forty-five of them, so that the average duration of a French cabinet has been a 1 Lebon, France as It Is, p. 94. ^ Cf. Haucour, Gouv. et Min.j Muel, Gouv., Min. et Const.; Duprlez, vol. ii. pp. 338, 343. The three exceptions were the cabinets of Brisson in 1885, Bourgeois in 1895, and M^line in 1896. ^ This is very clearly pointed out by Dupriez, Les Ministres, vol. ii. p. 390. i CABINETS SHORT-LIVED AND WEAK. 105 little less than ten months.' The same fact explains, moreover, the persistence of the system of interpella- tions, for if a change of ministry does not imply a differ- ent programme, there is no self-evident impropriety in overthrowing a cabinet on a question that does not in- volve a radical condemnation of its policy. The subdivision of the Republican party into sepa- rate groups has also an important bearing on Owinerto the character of the ministry. Instead of of^epXii-^ representing a united party, the cabinet must cabmet^ls a usually rely for support on a number of these andtibere- groups, and the portfolios must be so dis- tributed as to conciliate enough of them to form a majority of the Chamber.^ As a rule, therefore, the cabinet is in reality the result of a coalition, and suffers from the evils to vrhich bodies of that kind are always subject. The members tend to become rivals rather than comrades, and each of them is a little inclined to think less of the common interests of the cabinet than of his own future prospects when the combina- tion breaks up.^ Such a government, moreover, is essentially weak, for it cannot afford to refuse the de- mands of any group whose defection may be fatal to 1 I have not counted the reappointment of the Dupuy ministry on the election of Casimir-Perier to the presidency as the formation of a new cabinet. ^ Only on two or three occasions has the cabinet been supported by a group which has contained by itself anything like a majority of the deputies. 8 Cf. Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 348-49. Lebon, France as It Is, p. 85, speaks of the never-ending struggles for mastery within the cabinet. 106 FRANCE. its existence.^ The ministers are not at the head of a great party that is bound to follow their lead, and yet they must secure the votes of the Chamber or they cannot remain in office. Hence they must seek support as best they may, and as they cannot rule the majority, they are constrained to follow and flatter it ; ^ or rather they are forced to conciliate the various groups, and, It must win ^^ *^^® members of the groups themselves ^anti^ are loosely held together, they must grant favors. favors to the individual deputies in order to secure their votes. This is not a new feature in French politics. It is said that during the reign of Louis Philippe, the government kept a regular account with each deputy, showing his votes in the Chamber on one side, and the favors he had been granted on the other, so that he could expect no indulgence if the balance were against him.^ Nor has the cause of the evil changed. It is the same under the Third Republic that it was under the Monarchy of July, for in both cases the lack of great national parties with definite pro- grammes has made the satisfaction of local and personal interests a necessity. We are, unfortunately, only too familiar in this PoUtieai use couutry with the doctrine that to the victors of offices belong the spoils. In France we find the same thing, although it is not acknowledged so openly, and is disguised under the name of epuration, or the 1 Cf. Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 347-48, 434-35. 2 Cf. Simon, Nos Hommes d'Etat, ch. vii. p. iii. ^ Hello, Du Regime Constitutionnel, quoted by Minghetti, / Partiti Politici, p. 101 ; and see G. Lowes Dickinson, Revolution and Reaction in Modern France, pp. 118-20. PATRONAGE USED TO PLEASE DEPUTIES. 107 pTirification of the administration from the enemies of the Repubhc. The practice of turning poKtical foes out of office and substituting one's friends seems to have begun during President MacMahon's contest with the Chamber, when the Reactionary party dismissed a large number of officials who had served under former cabinets.- After the Right had been overthrown in 1877, there arose a cry that the Republic ought not to be administered by men who did not sympathize with it, and would naturally throw their influence against it ; but although the fear of danger to the form of government was no doubt genuine at first, the cry became before long a transparent excuse for a hunt after office.^ In speaking of this subject, however, it must be remembered that France is not divided into two great parties which succeed each other in power, and hence a wholesale change of public servants, such as has often taken place after a presidential election in the United States, does not occur. The process is con- tinuous, but slower and less thorough. On and other the other hand, the evil in France is by p^^^^s^s- no means limited to office-seeking, for owing to the immense power vested in the government, the favors which the deputies demand and exact as the price of their votes extend over a vast field. Nor do they show any false modesty about making their desires known. 1 See Channes, pp. 18-19, 231-32. 2 See the remarkable little book by Edmond Seherer, La Democratie et la France ; Cbannes, Nos Fautes (passim) ; Simon, Nos Hommes d'Efat, pp. 114^15, and ch. vi. ii. ; Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 502-9 ; Lamy, La Repub- lique en 1883, pp. 6-8, 22 ; and see a higUy colored account by Hurlbert, " The Outlook in France," Fortnightly Rev., vol. 55, p. 347. 108 FRANCE. They do not hesitate to invade the executive offices, and meddle directly in the conduct of affairs.^ Even the prefect, who has the principal charge of local ad- ministration, is not free from their interference. He is liable to lose his place if he offends the RepubHcan deputies from his department, and is therefore obliged to pay court to them and follow their lead. In short, the prefect has become, to a great extent, the tool of these autocrats ; and his dependence is increased by the fact that nowadays he does not usually remain in office long enough to acquire a thorough knowledge of the local wants, or to exercise a strong personal influence. I do not mean that he has become corrupt ; far from it. The level of integrity among French officials appears to be extremely high, and though wedded to routine, their efficiency is great ; ^ but the discretion in their hands is enormous, and in using it they must take care not to displease his Majesty the Deputy.^ Of course the deputies do not wield this immense in- Deputies fluencc to forward their own private ends alone. Srrf'favor They are representatives, and must use their Seal com- position for the benefit of the persons they mit ees. represent. But whom do they represent? The people at large? No representative ever really does that. So far as he is actuated by purely conscien- tious motives he represents his own ideas of right, and for the rest he represents primarily the men who have 1 Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 435, 607-8 ; Channes, pp. 253-56 ; Lamy, pp. 21-26 ; Laffitte, Le Suffrage Universel, pp. 54-59. 2 Simon, " Stability of the French Republic," The Forum, vol. 10, p. 383. 3 Cf. Channes, Letter of Oct. 1, 1884 ; Laffitte, pp. 56-58 ; Dupriez, vol. ii. pp. 471-72, 506-9. POWER OF LOCAL COMMITTEES. 109 elected him, and to whom he must look for help and votes in the next campaign. In some countries this means the party, and those classes that hang on the skirts of the party and may be prevailed upon to fall into line. But in France there are no great organized parties, and hence we must consider how candidates are nominated there. The government, at the present day, does not put forward official candidates of its own, as was commonly done during the Second Empire ; ^ and, indeed, it is not supposed to take an active part in elections. This last principle is not strictly observed, for the administrative officials at times exert no little influence in important campaigns, and the government is said to have spent a good deal of money to defeat Boulanger in 1889. Still there is nothing resembhng the control of elections under Napoleon III., and es- pecially there is no interference with the selection of candidates, this matter being left to the spontaneous movement of the voters themselves. The usual method of proceeding is as foUows : a number of men in active politics in a commune, or what we should call the wire- pullers, form themselves into a self-elected committee, the members usually belonging to liberal or semi-liberal professions, and very commonly holding advanced views, which are apt to go with political activity in France. The committees or their representatives meet together to form an assembly, which prepares the programme, nominates the candidate, and proclaims him as the can- didate of the party .^ These self-constituted committees, 1 Simon, Dieu, Patrie, Liberie, p. 372. 2 Simon, Nos Hommes d'Etat, pp. 17-25 ; Scherer, La Democratie et la 110 FRANCE. therefore, have the nomniation entirely in their own hands ;^ and, except in the larger cities, a candidate owes his position largely to local influence and personal interests.^ Sometimes he has won prominence by a clever speech at a local meeting. Sometimes he has earned gratitude by services rendered in his profession, or otherwise.^ After the candidate is nominated, his first care is to issue his programme, and under the system of single electoral districts, each candidate, as has already been observed, has a separate programme, which expresses only his particular views. The active campaign is car- ried on by means of placards posted on walls and fences, which make a great show, but win few votes ; and what is far more effective, by means of newspapers and the stump."* The stump, curiously enough, is used France, pp. 22-24 ; Reinacli, La Politique Opportuniste, 186-88 ; Laffitte, op. cit., pp. 64r-69. ^ Since the system of scrutin de liste has been given up and the single electoral districts have been reestablished, the matter is said to have become somewhat more simplified. It is stated that the nominating com- mittees are now formed, at least in many cases, without any meeting of delegates from the communes ; and that their function lies not in the selection of a candidate, but rather in helping the candidate in whose behalf they have been organized, and acting as his sponsors. (See Alfred Naquet, " The French Electoral System," North American Rev., vol. 155, p. 466. But see Charles Benoist, " De I'Organization du Suffrage Uni- versel," Revue des Deux Mondes, July 1, 1895, pp. 15-20.) However this may be, the close relations between the deputy and a small self-consti- tuted clique of local politicians, which is the essential point in the French electoral system, remains very much the same. 2 Simon, Nos Hommes d'Etat, pp. 24-25. 8 Chaudordy, La France en 1889, p. 96. 4 Alfred Naquet, "The French Electoral System," North American Rev., vol. 155, pp. 468-70. POWER OF LOCAL COMMITTEES. Ill very little except by the candidates themselves/ who constantly speak at political rallies, of late years fre- quently holding joint debates.^ Far too often, unfor- tunately, they also truckle to the personal ambition of individual voters by flattery and the promise of favors, a course that deters some of the best men from political lif e.^ The wire-pullers, indeed, are not over-anxious for really strong characters, because they prefer men whom they can control, and use for their own purposes.* If they want anything they exert a pressure on the deputy, who in his turn brings a pressure to bear on the min- isters ; and hence it has been a common saying that the electoral committees rule the deputies, and the deputies rule the government.^ It is asserted that, since the re-introduction of single electoral districts, the power of the committees has sen- sibly diminished,'^ and, whether this be true or not, it is ^ Theodore Stanton, supplement to the article of Alfred Naquet, p. 473. 2 Alfred Naquet, lb. The newspapers at election time are full of accounts of these meetings for joint debate, called Reunions publiques contradictoires. ^ Cf . Scherer, La Democratie et la France, pp. 24-25, 39. Direct bribery of voters, though not unknown, seems to be rare, but the complaint that elections have been getting a good deal more expensive of late years is general. Naquet, lb. ; Reinach, pp. 189-90 ; Simon, Dieu, Patrie, Liberie, p. 373 ; Souviens toi du Deux Decembre, p. 91. 4 Channes, Nos Fautes, pp. 379-81 ; Laffitte, p. 69 et seq. ^ Channes, pp. 238-39 ; and see Scherer, La Democratie et la France, p. 27; Simon, Dieu, Patrie, Liberie, p. 378. For this reason one frequently hears it said that the deputies do not see the real people, but only their own political dependents. Channes, p. 38 ; Simon, Souviens toi du Deux Decembre, pp. 165-66. ^ Naquet, " The French Electoral System," NoriTi American Rev., vol. 155, p. 466. But see on the other side the article of Benoist in the Revue des Deux Mond.es, July 1, 1895, pp. 17-19. 112 FRANCE. certainly easy to exaggerate their influence, for the dep- The depu- ^^J must always consider other people beside theb con- ^he wirc-pullers. He must try to strengthen stituents. j^'g general popularity throughout his district. He is, indeed, expected to look after the political business of his constituents, and is a regular channel for the pre- sentation of grievances and the distribution of favors ; one of the complaints most commonly heard in France being that the deputies represent local and personal in- terests rather than national ones. But even this does not end his responsibilities. The traditions of centralization which make all France look to Paris for guidance, and the habit of paternal government that makes men turn to the state for aid, have caused many people to regard the deputy as a kind of universal business agent for his district at the capital, and burden him with all sorts of private matters in addition to his heavy public duties. Sometimes this is carried to an extent that is positively ludicrous. Some years ago a couple of deputies gave an account at a pubhc dinner of the letters they had received from their districts. Some constituents wanted their representative to go shopping for them ; others asked him to consult a physician in their behalf ; and more than one begged him to procure a wet nurse, hearing that this could be done better in Paris than in the provinces.^ Is it to be wondered that the French deputy should bend under the weight of his responsi- bilities ? If I seem to have drawn a somewhat dark picture of the position of the deputy, I do not want to be under- 1 This is quoted by Scherer in La Democratie et la France, pp. 34r-35. THE DEPUTY A CHANNEL FOK PRIVATE FAVORS. 113 stood as implying that all deputies are alike ; that many of them are not men of high character, who will not yield to the temptation and pressure with which they are surrounded. My object is simply to describe a tendency ; to point out a defect in the French poHtical system, and to show clearly the characteristic evils which that defect cannot fail to develop. The famous scandals about the bribery of deputies in connection with the Panama Canal, with which the newspapers were filled for three months, have thrown a dismal light over pubHc life in France, and, although at first the credulous Parisians no doubt exaggerated the ex- tent of the corruption, still there was fire enough under the smoke to show what balefid influences haunt the corridors of the Palais Bourbon. Before closing, let us consider for a moment the political prospects of the country. The gen- ProsT)Gcts or erous enthusiasm that greeted the Republic at the Repub- the outset has faded away, and even its most ardent advocates have found to their sorrow that it has not brought the promised millennium. Such a feeling of disappointment is not surprising. On the contrary, it might have been surely predicted, for in every form of government that has existed in France since the Revo- lution the period of enthusiasm has been followed by one of disenchantment, and to this latter stage the Re- public has come in the natural course of events. Now this period may weU be looked upon as crucial, because as yet no form of government in France has been able to live through it. After a political system has lasted about half a generation, the country has always become 114 FRANCE. disgusted with it, torn it down, and set up another, — a course that has made any steady progress in pubHc life impossible. The effect has, in fact, been very much like that which would be produced by a man who should constantly root out his crops before they came to maturity, and sow his field with new and different seed. The reason for such a state of things' is not hard to Hitherto no ^^^- Siuce the Rcvolution every form of ^arr^has govcmment in France has been the expres- Sout\ sion or outward sign of a definite set of revolution, political opiuious. So close, indeed, has the connection been between the two, that it has been impossible for men to conceive of one without the other, and therefore a fundamental change of opinion has always involved a change in the form of govern- ment. Any one who studies the history of the nation will see that there has never been a change of party without a revolution. There has often been a shifting of control from one group to another of a slightly dif- ferent coloring, but the real party in opposition has never come to power without an overturn of the whole political system. Under the Restoration, for example, the ministers were sometimes Moderate and sometimes extremely Reactionary, but were never taken from the ranks of the liberal opposition. Again, during the Monarchy of July the different groups of Liberals dis- puted fiercely for the mastery, but neither the Radicals nor the Reactionaries had the slightest chance of com- ing to power. If space permitted, this truth might be illustrated by taking up in succession each of the gov* PROSPECTS OF THE REPUBLIC. 115 ernments that have flourished since the Revolution, but perhaps it is enough to refer to the only apparent exception that has occurred. While General MacMahon was President of the Third Republic, power was cer- tainly transferred from the Reactionaries to the Repub- licans, but the circumstances of this case were very peculiar. The Republic had hardly got into working order, and the struggle of the Reactionaries may be looked upon as a final effort to prevent it from becom- ing firmly established. The French themselves have always considered the occurrence, not as a normal change of party, but as the frustration of an attempt at a C0U2J dJetat or counter-revolution. This case, there- fore, from the fact that it has been generally regarded as exceptional, may fairly be treated as the kind of exception that tends to prove the rule. A revolution in France corresponds in many ways to a change of party in other countries, but with this grave disadvan- tage, that the new administration, instead of reforming the pohtical institutions, destroys them altogether. Of course such a method puts gradual improvement out of the question, and before the nation can perfect her government she must learn that the remedy for defects is to be sought through the reform, not the overthrow, of the existing system. One would suppose that under the Republic no such difficulty could arise, because a republic means the rule of the majority, and the majority is sure to be some- times on one side and sometimes on the other. But this is not the view of most French Republicans, and especially of the Radicals. These men, recognizing 116 FRANCE. that, on account of a want of training in self-govern- ment, the people can be cajoled, or frightened, or charmed, or tricked into the expression of the most con- tradictory opinions, refuse to admit that any vote not in harmony with their own ideas can be a fair test of the popular will, and assume for themselves the exclusive privilege of declaring what the people really want. As M. Edmond Scherer has cleverly said : " Let us add that the God (universal suffrage) has his priests, whose authority has never been quite clear, but who know his wishes, speak in his name, and, if resistance occurs, confound it by an appeal to the oracle whose secrets are confided to them alone." ^ The Radicals, therefore, cannot admit a possibility that the true majority can be against them, and nothing irritates them so much as to hear the other parties claim that the people are on their own side. It has been said that the Republic will not be safe until it has been governed by the Conserva- tives,^ and the remark has a special significance in this connection : first, because, until the Conservatives come to power, it will not be clear whether the Republic has enough strength and elasticity to stand a change of party without breaking down ; and second, because the right of the majority to rule, which is the ultimate basis of the consensus on which the Republic must rest, will not be surely established until each party has submitted peaceably to a popular verdict in favor of the other. 1 La Democratie et la France, p. 18. 2 " La E^publique et les Conservateurs," Revue des Deux Mondes, March 1, 1890, pp. 120-21. This means, of course, the conservative elements among the people, and not merely the conservative Republicans. PROSPECTS OF THE REPUBLIC. 117 If the Republic proves lasting, the form of its institu- tions will no doubt be gradually modified, but, ppoi^abie whatever changes take place, one thing is prencK clear: the responsibility of the ministers to «*^*'^t^°^^- parliament must be retained. In a country like the United States, where power is split up by the federal system, where the authority in the hands of the executive is comparatively small, and, above all, where the belief in popular government and the attachment to individual liberty and the principles of the common law are ingrained in the race, there is no danger in intrusting the administration to a President who is independent of the legislature. But this would not be safe in France, because, owing to the centralization of the government and the immense power vested in the executive, such a President would be almost a dictator during his term of office ; and the temptation to pro- long his authority, from public no less than from selfish motives, would be tremendous. Nor, in view of the tendency of the mercantile classes, and even of the peasants, to crave a strong ruler, would it be difficult for him to do so, as Louis Napoleon proved long ago. A President is able to overthrow a popular assembly because the French have long been accustomed to personal government, and because an assembly is in- capable of maintaining a stable majority ; because, in short, the French know how to work personal but not representative government : and the danger will con- tinue until parliamentary institutions are perfected, and their traditions by long habit have become firmly rooted. The French President cannot, therefore, be 118 FRANCE. independent, and the only feasible alternative is to surround him with ministers who are responsible to the Chamber of Deputies. But if the parliamentary system must be retained, it is important to remove the defects that it shows to-day, and especially is it necessary, on the one hand, to diminish the autocratic power of the administration, which offers a well-nigh irresistible temptation to both minister and deputy ; and, on the other hand, to give the cabinet more stability, more dignity, and more authority ; to free it from the yoke of the groups in the Chamber, and from dependence on local interest and personal appetite ; to relieve it from the domination of irresponsible committees, and from the danger of defeat by haphazard majorities ; to enable it to exert over its followers the discipline that is required for the formation of great, compact parties ; to make it, in short, the real head of a majority in parliament and in the nation. VOL. I. ITALY CHAPTER m. ITALY: INSTITUTIONS. The perfection of its organization and the excel- Causesthat ^^^(^^ of its laws preserved the Hfe of Rome Srof*^^ long after its vital force had become ex- ^^^^' hausted ; and when the Teutonic tribes had once broken through the shell of the western empire, they overran it almost without resistance. Europe sank into a state of barbarism, from which she re- covered to find her poHtical condition completely changed. Slowly, during the Middle Ages, the nations were forming, until at last Europe became divided into separate and permanent states, each with an inde- pendent government of its own. In two countries, however, — Italy and Germany, — this process of de- velopment was delayed by the existence of the Holy Roman Empire, which claimed an authority far greater than it was able to wield, and, while too weak to consoli- date its vast dominions into a single state, was strong enough to hinder them from acquiring distinct and national governments. The condition of Italy was further complicated by the presence of the Pope ; for although the Papacy was an immense civilizing force in mediaeval Europe, yet the constant quarrels of the Pope and the Emperor, and the existence of the States of the Church, tended greatly to prevent the development FORMATION OF THE KINGDOM. 121 of Italy as a nation. The country was broken into a multitude of jarring elements, and even Dante saw no hope of union and order save under the sway of a German emperor. The north of Italy was full of flourishing cities enriched by commerce and manufac- tures and resplendent with art, but constantly fighting with each other, and, except in the case of Venice, a prey to internal feuds that brought them at last under the control of autocratic rulers.^ The south, on the other hand, fell under the dominion of a series of foreign monarchs, who were often despotic, and, by making the government seem an enemy of the gov- erned, destroyed in great measure the legal and social organization of the people. For thirteen centuries — from the reign of Theodoric the Ostrogoth to the time of Napoleon — the greater part of Italy was never united under a single head, and in both of these cases the country was ruled by foreigners. Yet short- lived and unnatural as the Napoleonic Kingdom of Italy was, it had no small effect in kindling that longing for freedom and union which was destined to be fulfilled after many disappointments. By the treaty of Vienna, in 1815, Italy was again carved into a number of principalities, most of them under the direct influence of Austria, takes the _ _ pi 1 n (1 • 1 1 ^^^"^ '^^ Italy Most 01 them, but not all, lor in the north- in the , strug-gle for western corner of the peninsula, between the Italian inde- ^ ^ pendence. mountains and the sea, lay Piedmont, ruled by a prince of the house of Savoy, with the title of King ^ Genoa was torn with factions, and was at times, though not perma* nently, subject to Milan or to France. 122 ITALY. of Sardinia. During the great popular upheaval of 1848, Charles Albert, a king of this line, granted to his people a charter called the Statuto, and in that year and the following he waged war with Austria for the Hberation of Italy. He was badly beaten, but succeeded in attracting the attention of all Italians, who now began to look on the King of Sardinia as the possible saviour of the country. After his second defeat, at Novara, on March 23, 1849, Charles Albert abdicated in favor of his son, Victor Victor Emmanuel, who refused to repeal the Emmanuel. • • o j re i i i btatuto m spite oi the oners and the threats of Austria, — an act that won for him the confi- dence of Italy and the title " II Re Galantuomo," the King Honest Man. The rehance, indeed, which Victor Emmanuel inspired was a great factor in the making of Italy; and to this is due in large part the readiness with which the ItaHan revolutionists accepted the mon- archy, although contrary to their repubhcan sentiments. In fact, the chivalrous nature of the principal character of actors makes the struggle for Itahan unity more dramatic than any other event in modern times.^ The chief characters are heroic, and stand out with a vividness that impresses the imagination, and gives to the whole history the charm of a romance. Victor Emmanuel is the model constitutional king; Cavour, the ideal of a cool, far-sighted statesman ; Garibaldi, the perfect chieftain in irregular war, dash- ing, but rash and hot-headed ; Mazzini, the typical ^ Professor Dicey speaks of this, and draws a comparison between Italian ajid Swiss politics, in a letter to The Nation of Nov. 18, 1886. FORMATION OF THE KINGDOM. 123 conspirator, ardent and fanatical ; — all of tliem full of generosity and devotion. The enthusiasm which their characters inspired went far to soften the difficulties in their path, and to help the people to bear the sacrifices entailed by the national regeneration. Over against these men stands Pius IX., who began his career as a reformer, but, terrified by the march of the revolution, became at last the bigoted champion of reaction. The purity of his character and the subtle charm of his manner fitted him to play the part of the innocent victim in the great drama. When Cavour first became prime minister of Victor Emmanuel in 1852, his plan was a confeder- cavour's ation of the Italian States under the Pope ftaUancon- Till. !_• n 1 l.^ federation. as nominal head, but practically under the lead of the King of Sardinia. Now, in order to make this plan a success, it was necessary to exclude the powerful and reactionary House of Habsburg from all influence in the peninsula, and with this object he induced Napoleon III. to declare war against Austria in 1859 ; but when the Emperor brought the war to a sudden end by a peace that required the cession of Lombardy alone, and left Venice still in the hands of the enemy, Cavour saw that so long as Austria retained a foothold in Italy, many of the principalities would remain subject to her control. He therefore changed his scheme, and aimed at a complete union changed to of Italy under the House of Savoy .^ The ^fi**''^ whole country was ready to follow the lead ^ °™* 1 Jaeini, / Conservatori e I' Evoluzione dei Partiti Politici in Italia, p. 55 et seq. 124 ITALY. of Victor Emmanuel, and, except for Venice and Rome, which were guarded by foreign troops, the march of events was rapid. The people of the northern States had already risen and expelled their rulers, and early in 1860 they declared for a union with Sardinia. Later in the same year Garibaldi landed at Marsala with a thousand men, roused the country, and quickly overran Sicily and Naples, which decided by popular vote to join the new kingdom, — a step that was soon followed by Umbria and the Marches. The rest of Italy was won more slowly. Venice was annexed in 1866, as a result of the war fought against Austria by Prussia and Italy ; and Rome was not added until 1870, after the withdrawal of the French garrison and the faU of Napoleon III., who had sent it there to protect the Pope. It is curious that Sardinia expanded into the King- Govemment dom of Italy witliout any alteration of its domofit^y. fundamental laws, for the Statuto, originally The Statuto. granted by Charles Albert in 1848, remains the constitution of the nation to-day. It has never been formally amended, and contains, indeed, no pro- vision for amendment. At first it was thought that any changes ought to be made by a constituent assembly, and in 1848 a law was passed to call one, although, on account of the disastrous results of the war, it never met. By degrees, however, an opinion gained ground that the political institutions of Italy, like those of England, could be modified by the ordi- nary process of legislation. This has actually been done, to a greater or less extent, on several occasions ; THE STATUTO. 125 and now both jurists and statesmen are agreed that unlimited sovereign power resides in the King and Parliament.^ The Statuto contains a bill of rights ; but, except for the provision forbidding censorship of the press, and perhaps that protecting the right of holding meetings,^ it was not designed to guard against oppression by the legislature, but only by the executive. The Statuto is, in fact, mainly occupied with the organization of the powers of state, and has gradually become overlaid with customs, which are now so strong that many Italian jurists consider custom itself a source of public law. They claim, for example, that the habit of selecting ministers who can command a majority in Parliament has become binding as part of the law of the land.^ Let us consider the powers of state in turn, begin- ning with the King and his ministers, then passing to the Parliament, then to the local government and the judicial system, and finally to the position of the CathoHc church. ^ Brusa, Italien, in Marquardsen's Handhuch, pp. 12-16, 181-82; Ruiz, "The Amendments to the Italian Constitution," 4nn. Amer. Acad, of Pol. Sci., Sept., 1895. It may be noted that the various contributions to Mar- quardsen's work are of very different value, and that Brusa's is one of the best. He remarks (p. 15) that, before changing any constitutional provision, it has been customary to consult the people by means of a gen- eral election, and that it is the universal opinion that Parliament has not power to undo the work of the popular votes by which the various prov- inces were annexed ; in other words, that Parliament cannot break up the kingdom. It has been suggested that the courts can consider the constitutionality of a law which involves a forced construction of the Statuto, but this view has not prevailed. (Brusa, pp. 182, note 3, 229-30.) 2 Arts. 28, 32. * See Brusa, p. 19. 126 ITALY. At the head of the nation is the King, whose crown is declared hereditary, according to the prin- ciples of the Salic law; that is, it can be inherited only by and through males.^ It sounds like Power ^ paradox to say that the King is a constitu- exerSed tional sovcrcign, but that the constitution ^ ■ does not give a correct idea of his real func- tions, and yet this is true. By the Statuto, for example, his sanction is necessary to the vaHdity of laws passed by the Parliament,^ but in point of fact he never refuses it.^ Again, the constitution provides that treaties which impose a burden on the finances or change the territory shall require the assent of the Chambers,* leaving the Crown free to conclude others as it thinks best ; but in practice all treaties, except military conventions and alHances, are submitted to Parliament for approval.^ The King is further given power to declare war, to appoint all of&cers, to make decrees and ordinances, to create Senators, to dissolve the Chamber of Deputies, and so forth ; ^ but the Statuto also provides that no act of the government shall be valid unless countersigned by a minister ; and in fact all the powers of the King are exercised in his name by the ministers, who are responsible to the popular Housed He is, indeed, seldom present at 1 Statute, Art. 2. 2 Statuto, Art. 7. 3 Brusa, pp. 105, 153 ; cf. Dupriez, vol. i. pp. 281, 292-97. * Statuto, Art. 5. « Brusa, p. 106. 6 Statuto, Arts. 5-9. ' Statuto, Art. 67 ; and see Brusa, p. 105. THE KING AND HIS MINISTERS. 127 cabinet meetings, and has little or no direct influence over current domestic politics/ although it is said that his personal opinion has a good deal of weight on the relations with foreign states.^ When, however, a cabinet crisis occurs and the ministry resigns, the King has a great deal of latitude in the appointment of its successor; for the Chamber is not divided into two parties, one of which naturally comes into power when the other goes out, but, as in France, it is split up into a number of small groups, so that every ministry is based upon a coalition. The King can, therefore, send for almost any one he pleases and allow him to attempt to form a cabinet. It often happens, moreover, that the man selected feels that he cannot get the support of a majority in the existing Chamber, but, hoping for a favorable result from a new election, is wilHng to undertake to form a cabinet if allowed to dissolve ParHament. In such cases the King exercises his own discretion, and grants permission or not as he thinks best ; for, contrary to the habit in France, dissolutions in Italy are by no means rare. Thus the Itahan King, although strictly a constitutional monarch tied up in a parHamentary system, is not quite so powerless as the French President or the English King. *^ /^' In the selection of his ministers the King is not limited by law to members of ParHament, but, r^-^^ -anma.. if a man is appointed who is not a member of *®^^' either House, he is obliged by custom to become a can- 1 Brusa, p. 108. Dupriez, vol. i. p. 289, says that he presides only when peculiarly important matters are under discussion. 2 Dupriez, vol. i. p. 296. This is a common opinion. 128 ITALY. didate for the next vacant seat in the Chamber of Deputies, unless he is created a Senator.^ As in other parHamentary governments on the Continent, however, the ministers and their under-secretaries have a right to be present and speak in either Chamber, although they can vote only in the one of which they happen to be members.^ The work of the Parliament is, indeed, chiefly directed by them ; for, while individual members have a right to introduce bills, the power is used only for matters of small importance.^ As a rule, each minister has charge of a department of the administra- tion; but it is allowable, and was at one time not uncommon, to appoint additional ministers without port- folios, whose duties consisted solely in helping to shape the policy of the government, and defending it in the Chambers.* The Italian Parliament has two branches, — ^the Senate and the Chamber of Deputies. The Senate is composed of the princes of the royal family,^ ^ Brusa, p. 108; and the same thing is true of the parliamentary under-secretaries. Id., p. 196. 2 Statute, Art. 66 ; Law of Feb, 12, 1888, Art. 2. 8 Brusa, p. 172. Dupriez (vol. i. p. 308) says that the ministers in Italy have not so complete a monopoly of initiative as in other countries, and that private members often propose measures with success. But in saying this he must not be understood to deny that the laws enacted as a result of private initiative are unimportant compared with the govern- ment measures, both as regards number and character. * Brusa, p. 197. See, also, the lists of the different ministries published in the Manual of the Deputies. This manual, by the way, is a most valua- ble production, for it contains the text of many important laws and a large amount of interesting information. For the organization and functions of the various departments, see Brusa, p. 200 et seq. ^ Statuto, Art. 34. THE SENATE. 129 and of members appointed by the King for life from certain categories of persons defined by the j^^ ^^ Statuto.^ These are : bishops ; ^ sundry high ^^^^^^ of&cials, civil, mihtary, and judicial;^ deputies who have served three terms, or six years ; * men vv^ho have been for seven years members of the Royal Academy of Science ; men who pay over three thousand lire (about six hundred dollars) in taxes ;^ and men deserving ex- ceptional honor for service to the state. Owing to the extreme severity of the Senate in recognizing such desert, there are at present only two members from this last class ; for the Senate itself has the strange privilege of deciding whether a person selected by the King belongs properly to one of these classes, and is qualified to be a Senator.^ Except for money bills, which must be presented first to the p^^®^^- Chamber of Deputies, the legislative powers of the two Houses are the same, but the Senate has also judicial functions. It can sit as a court to try ministers im- peached by the Chamber of Deputies ; to try cases of high treason and attempts on the safety of the state ; ^ 1 Statute, Art. 33. All the appointed members must be forty years old. 2 Since the quarrel with the Pope in 1870 this class has not been avail- able. Brusa, p. 119. 2 Except in the case of the highest officials, persons of this class can be appointed only after a period of service which varies from three to seven years, according to the office they hold. In 1910 there were ninety-nine Senators from this class. ^ Out of a total of about three hundred and eighty-three, there were in 1910 about one hundred and forty-seven Senators from this class. ^ There were seventy-one Senators from this class also. « Brusa, p. 119 ; and see the Statute, Art. 60. 7 Statute, Art. 36. 130 ITALY, and to try its own members, — the Italians, curiously enough, having copied in their Senate the antiquated privilege which entitles the English Peers to be tried for crime only by members of their own body.^ As a matter of fact, the Senate has very little real power, and is obliged to yield to the will of the Lower House.^ In 1878-80 it did, indeed, refuse to abolish the unpopular grist-tax for more than a year, but gave way before a newly elected Chamber of Deputies.^ It would proba- bly not venture even so far to-day, for the number of Senators is unlimited, and on several occasions a large batch of members has been created in order to change the party coloring of the body, — in 1890 as many as seventy-five having been appointed for this purpose at one time.* As in other countries where the parha- mentary system exists, the cabinet is not responsible to the Upper House ; and it is only occasionally, and as it were by accident, that a minister has resigned on account of an adverse vote in the Senate.^ The Chamber of Deputies consists of five hundred and eight members, elected on a limited fran- berof Depu- chisc. By the earher law, the suffrage was so restricted that less than two and a half per cent of the population were entitled to vote ; but this 1 Statute, Art. 37. 2 The changes made by the Senate in bills have usually a legal rather than a political importance. Dupriez, p. 313. 8 Brusa, pp. 155-56. See Petruccelli della Gattina, Storia d' Italia, 1860-1880, pp. 420-21, 558-59. •* In 1886 forty-one were appointed together, and in 1892 forty-two. See the list of Senators with their dates, in the Manual of the Deputies for 1892, p. 806 et seq., and p. 876. * Brusa, p. 158, note 3. THE CHAMBER OF DEPUTIES. 131 was felt to be too small a proportion, and in 1882 it was increased by an act whose provisions are still rpj^g ^^.^^^ in force. ^ By this statute a voter must be able ^^^^' to read and write, and must have passed an examination on the subjects comprised in the course of compulsory education,^ except that the examination is not required in the case of of&cials, professional men, graduates of ' colleges, and others who could, of course, pass it ; nor in the case of men who have received a medal for military or civil service, or who pay a direct tax of nineteen lire and four fifths (about four dollars), or who pay rents of certain amounts. The change more than tripled the quantity of voters at once;^ and, although these still include only a small part of the citizens, it is to be observed that with the spread of elementary education their number will gradually increase until the suffrage becomes substantially universal.* At first the members were chosen each in a separate district, but after the times of enthusiasm for Italian unity were over, and the generous impulse that had ^ Brusa, pp. 122-27. This law, with its amendments, recodified in 1895, may be found in full in the Manual of the Deputies for that year. 2 Education is compulsory in Italy only between the ages of six and nine. Act of July 15, 1877, Art. 2. 3 It raised the number from 627,838 to 2,049,461. Brusa, p. 127. When the law went into effect, the voters were not very unequally divided into those who passed the examination, those who paid the taxes, and the other excepted classes. Id., p. 126, notes 1-2, ^ In order to restrict the arbitrary influence of the government over elections, and to prevent the abuses which had been common before, a procedure for preparing the lists of voters and insuring the secrecy of the ballot was established by the same law (see Brusa, pp. 127-28, 130-32) ; and in this connection it is to be noticed that soldiers and sailors in active service (including subalterns and police officials) are not allowed to vote. Law of March 28, 1895, Art. 14. 132 ITALY. stirred the country began to give way before the selfish motives of e very-day life, it was found that the deputies failed to take broad views of national questions, and were largely absorbed by personal and local interests. It was found, in short, that they represented the nation too little and their particular districts too much ; ^ and it was hoped that by increasing the size of the districts they would be freed from the tyranny of local influence, and enabled to form compact parties on national issues.^ With this object the Act of 1882 distributed the five hundred and eight seats among one hundred and thirty- five districts, which elected from two to five deputies apiece;^ and, in order to give some representation to minorities, it was provided that in those districts which elected five deputies no one should vote for more than four candidates.* The new system, called the scriitinio di lista, did not produce the results that were expected from it. On the contrary, in Italy as in France, where the same remedy was applied to the same evil, the organization and power of the local wire-pullers grew with the increase in the number of deputies elected in a district, while the influence of the latter over the ministers and the provincial officers was greater than ever before.^ An Act of May 5, 1891, has therefore 1 Brusa, p. 16. 2 Minghetti, / Partiti Polidci, p. 18 ; Petruccelli della Gattina, p. 504. 8 Three districts elected two deputies, sixty-one elected three, thirty- six elected four, and thirty-five elected five. Brusa, p. 129. See Arts. 44 and 45 of the Act of 1882, and the table of districts annexed thereto. 4 Act of 1882, Art. 65. ^ Brusa, lb. ; and see Turiello, Governo e Governati in Italia, 2d ed. j Fatti, p. 326 ; Proposte, p. 171. THE CHAMBER OF DEPUTIES. 133 abolished tlie serutinio di lista and reestablislied single electoral districts.^ In accordance with the general practice in Europe, the deputies are not required to be residents „,.,.. ■, -, • T- Qualifica- 01 their districts, the only important limita- tionofthe 1 • f> T 1 1 • 1 deputies. tions on the choice oi candidates being the requirement of the age of thirty years, and the pro- vision excluding priests who have active duties, mayors and provincial counselors in their own districts, and all officials paid from the treasury of the state with the ex- ception of ministers, under-secretaries, and a few others.^ The deputies receive no pay for attendance, but are given free passes over the railroads,^ and it is no doubt partly for this reason that the small attendance in the Chamber has long been a crying evil. The Chamber is elected for five years, but so far its life has always been cut short by a dis- t ' -I ' p ^ IIP '^^^ term solution, and in lact the average length ot of the 11111 4. FTM Chamber. term has been less than three years. ihe budget and the contingent of recruits are adjusted by 1 This law is printed in the Manual of the Deputies for 1892, in place of Arts. 44, 45, of the Act of 1882. 2 Brusa, pp. 132-34 ; and see Acts of Dec, 1860 (Arts. 97, 98), July 3, 1875, May 13, 1877, July 5, 1882, March 28, 1895 (Arts. 81-89). There is a curious provision that only forty officials of all kinds (except minis- ters and under-secretaries), and among them not more than ten judges and ten professors, can be deputies at the same time, and if more are elected they are reduced to that number by lot. Law of March 28, 1895, Art. 88. On account of some scandals that occurred at one time it is further provided that no officers of companies subventioned by the state, and no government contractors, can sit in the Chamber. Brusa, p. 134 ; law of March 28, 1895, Arts. 84-85. ^ Brusa, pp. 159-60. 4 Id., p. 139. 134 ITALY. annual laws, and there would naturally be a new session every year; but in order not to interrupt the work of Parliament, and especially the consideration of the budget, which is apt to be behindhand, a curious habit has grown up of prolonging the sessions, so that three recent Parliaments have had only a single session apiece, one lasting two and a half and another three and a half years, all of them unbroken save by occasional recesses.^ The Chamber of Deputies elects its own President The Presi- ^^^ othcr officers, and the vote for President ^^^^- used to he an occasion for a trial of party strength, as in most other legislative bodies. Of late years, however, the English habit has prevailed of re- electing the same man without regard to party afifilia- tions ; ^ and this is the more striking because the President appoints the committees on rules and contested elections,^ which have, of course, no little importance. The idea that the presiding officer ought to be strictly impartial is not the only valuable suggestion the Italians have derived from England, for they have inherited Cavour's admiration for British parHamentary procedure, and in general they attempt to follow it. Unfortunately they have not done so in all cases, for, as we shall see when we come to consider the actual working of the govern- 1 Brusa, p. 139; and see the list of the sessions of the various Parlia- Snents in the Manual of the Deputies. 2 Brusa, pp. 140 and 156, note 2. Biancheri was President of the Chamber continuously from 1884 to 1892. Manual of the Deputies for 1892 (pp. 800-802). In that year he was dropped for party reasons, and in fact the practice of looking on the President as the representative of a party has unfortunately revived. s Rules of the Chamber of Deputies, Art. 12. THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM. 135 ment, tlie system of committees and of interpellations or questions has been copied mainly from the French and not the English practice. Such, briefly stated, are the position of the King and the composition of the Parliament ; but although the King and his ministers on the one hand, and the Par- liament on the other, are the great political forces whose interaction determines the character of the government, still it is impossible to appreciate the re- lations between the two, without some knowledge of the method of administration, the principles of local government, and the control exercised by the courts of law, because these matters have a direct bearing on the functions of the cabinet, and hence on the nature of the influence exerted upon it by the Parliament. The administration both of national and local affairs, and to some extent the judicial system of The admin- Italy, are modeled- on those of France, and toro7it£y they present the defects without all the ad- thSoV""'^ vantages of the original. This is particularly ^^^'^<'®- true of the administrative system, where Italy has copied the centralization, but has been unable to ac- quire the traditions which give real solidity to the body of officials. At first sight it seems strange that Cavour and his successors, with their admiration for English institutions, should have turned to the French bureaucracy as a pattern ; but there were Reasons for several reasons for their course. In the first *^' place the Napoleonic rule had already made the Italians familiar with the French form of administration. A far stronger motive came from the fact that after. Cavour VOL. I. 138 ITALY. gave up tlie idea of a confederation, and strove to create a united kingdom of Italy, it became important, in view of the possible interference of foreign powers, to consolidate the different provinces as completely and rapidly as possible. The Italian statesmen tried, there- fore, to make the people homogeneous ; to remove as far as possible all local differences ; and to destroy all possibility of local opposition.^ The country, more- over, was very backward, and a great work of regen- eration had to be undertaken, especially in the south, where society was badly disintegrated and brigandage was rife. To accomplish this a highly centralized and autocratic system, in which the government could make itself quickly and decisively felt, was thought essen- tial ; ^ and it was believed, not without reason, that until the union was accomplished, and order had been established in Naples and Sicily, it was impossible to introduce general local self-government or universal Hberty. The old territorial divisions were therefore swept away, and replaced by artificial districts devoid, of course, of real local life. A centralized form of administration was set up, and the government was given a highly arbitrary power to interfere with the freedom of the individual. Such a system might have worked very well in the hands of a wise dictator, but, as some of the Italian writers have themselves remarked, it was so entirely inconsistent with the parliamentary form of government that one of them was sure to spoil 1 See Brusa, pp. 23, 337 ; Jacini, / Conservatori, p. 55 et seq., Due Anni di Politica Italiana, pp. 93-94. 2 See Brusa, pp. 253-54. THE ADMINISTRATIVE SYSTEM. 137 the other, and experience has shown that both of them have suffered grievously from the combination.^ There is a marked contradiction in Italy between the theory and practice of government ; for Contrast in there is a strong ambition to be abreast of Jj^een^*^ the times and a general belief in the prin- prletS^of ciple of personal Hbertyj but the actual con- s^^^^^™^^"** dition of the nation has made it impossible to live up to these standards. A striking example of the con- trast between aspirations and results is furnished by the state of the criminal law, for capital punishment has been abolished, in spite of the fact that homicide is more common than in any other civilized country in Europe,^ and yet criminal procedure is in such a condi- tion that thousands of people have been arrested on sus- picion, kept in prison sometimes for years, and finally released because there was not sufficient ground for trial.^ Thus by her code Italy appears to be in ad- vance of most other nations, but in her criminal prac- tice she is really far behind them. The truth is that ^ Cf. Jacini, / Conservatori, pp. 67-68 ; Minghetti, / Partiti Politici, p. 100 ; Pareto, " L'ltalie Economique," Revue des Deux Mondes, Oct. 15, 1891 ; and see Bertolini, "I Pieui Poteri per le Eiforme Orga- niche," Nuova Antologia, June 1, 1894. 2 Turiello, Fatti, pp. 330-32. ^ See Speyer, in Unsere Zeit, 1879, vol. i. p. 576. Petruceelli della Gattina says (Storia d* Italia, p. 258) that in 1876, 93,444 persons were arrested on suspicion and let off because there was no ground for trial. This, it is true, was eleven years before the code was finally enacted ; nevertheless it illustrates the contrast between ideals and practice in criminal naatters, and in fact in that very year the abolition of the death penalty was voted by the Chamber of Deputies, but rejected by the Senate. 138 ITALY. the successive governments, in view of the unsettled state of the country, have been afraid to place re- straints on their own power, and weaken an authority thought necessary for the preservation of order. Of course the result has been a good deal of arbitrary of&- ciaHsm and disregard of the rights of the citizen,^ but while this is a misfortune for the north of Italy, ex- traordinary and autocratic power has at times been in- dispensable in Sicily and the south.^ The impossi- bility, indeed, of giving effect to the theories of hberty that are constantly proclaimed from every quarter was forcibly illustrated by the only serious attempt that has been made to do so. When CairoH and Zanardelli became ministers in 1878 they tried to carry out their principles thoroughly. They permitted the constitu- tional right of public meeting to be freely exercised, and gave up the despotic practice of preventive arrest, trusting to the courts to punish offenders against the law ; but brigandage increased so fast, and other dis- turbances became so alarming, that the cabinet was driven from office, and its policy was abandoned. Of late years Zanardelli has again held office, and has succeeded in improving the administrative and judicial system to some extent, but the progress of the reform has been extremely slow, and the arbitrary power of the government, although reduced, still conforms even in quiet times far more nearly to French than to Anglo-Saxon notions. There are two matters in connection with the admin- 1 Cf. Brusa, p. 183. 2 Cf. Speyer, in Unsere Zeit, 1879, vol. i. p. 581. LEGISLATION BY ORDINANCE. 139 istration that require special notice. One of tliem is the power of the executive officials to make ordinances. ihis is even more extensively nance 1 . power. used than in France, and there are complaints that it is sometimes carried so far as to render the provi- sions of a statute nugatory/ although the constitution expressly declares that "the King makes the decrees and regulations necessary for the execution of the laws, without suspending their observance or dispensing with them." ^ The interpretation put upon this provi- sion is in fact so broad that the government is practically allowed to suspend the law subject to responsibility to Parliament, and even to make temporary laws which are to be submitted to Parliament later, — a power that is used when a tariff bill is introduced, to prevent large importations before the tariff goes into effect.^ The Parliament has, moreover, a habit of delegating legis- lative power to the ministers in the most astonishing way. In the case of the Italian criminal code, for example, the final text was never submitted to the Chambers at all, but after the subject had been suffi- ciently debated, the government was authorized to make a complete draft of the code, and then to enact it by royal decree, harmonizing it with itself and with other statutes, and taking into account the views ex- 1 Brusa, pp. 170-72. 2 Statute, Art. 6. The courts have power to refuse to apply an ordi- nance which exceeds the authority of the government, but, in practice, this is not an effective restraint. Brusa, pp. 171-72, 175, 187. ' Brusa, pp. 186-87. In 1891 the customs duties on several articles were increased by royal decree, which was subsequently ratified by Par- liament. 140 ITALY. pressed by the Chambers. The same was true of the electoral law of 1882, of the general laws on local gov- ernment and on the Council of State, and of many- other enactments.^ It may be added that although the Statuto does not expressly provide for it, the ministers, prefects, syndics, and other of&cials are in the habit of making decrees on subjects of minor importance.^ The preference indeed for administrative regulations, which the government can change at any time, over rigid statutes is deeply implanted in the Latin races, and seems to be especially marked in Italy .^ The other matter referred to as requiring special notice is the civil service. The host of ofB.- serviceand cials, who are, unfortunately, too numerous political and too poorly paid,^ can be appointed or dis- missed very much at the pleasure of the government, for although there are royal decrees regu- lating appointments and removals in many cases, they 1 Brusa, pp. 175-76; Bertolini, "I Pieni Poteri," Nuova Antologia, June 1, 1894. Several laws of this kind may be found in the Manuals of the Deputies. They are issued in the form not of statutes, but of ordi- nances, and begin by reciting the legislative authority under which they are made. It is a curious fact that Italian statutes vary a great deal, sometimes containing only general principles, and leaving to the govern- ment the task of completing them by supplementary regulations, and sometimes going into minute details (Bi^usa, p. 171). Dupriez, who looks at the matter from a French standpoint, says (vol. i. p. 336) that in the struggle between the government and the Parliament over the limits of the ordinance power, the government has tried to extend its authority beyond measure, and the Parliament to dispute it even in the matter oi organizing the administrative service. 2 Brusa, pp. 188-90. 3 Minghetti, pp. 293-94. ■* Brusa, p. 260. THE ABUSE OF PATRONAGE. 141 do not appear to furnish a satisfactory guarantee.^ Here, then, is a great mass of spoils, in the distribu- tion of which the pohticians take an active part.^ Such decrees, providing for competitive examinations for admission to the service, are indeed common ; and in 1890 a statute,^ affecting the officers in the department of public safety, was passed with provisions for such examinations, and for preventing removal without the consent of a standing commission. But civil service laws, like all others, depend for much of their effective- ness on the persons who execute them.* Let us look for a moment at the local government. 1 Dupriez, vol. i. pp. 337^0 ; Brusa, pp. 252-55. For the scope of these decrees, see p. 261 et seq. 2 Brusa, pp. 152-53 ; and see Dupriez, vol. i. pp. 340-42. 3 Law of Dec. 21, 1890. * There are two bodies that exercise a considerable control over the government. One of these is the Council of State, which has, however, only an advisory power, except in matters of administrative justice, and in the case of provincial and communal officials whom it protects from arbitrary removal. On this subject see Brusa, p. 212 et seq. The laws of June 2, 1889, which regulate this body, may be found in the Manual of the Deputies for 1892, p. 357. The other is the Courts of Accounts (Corte del Conti), whose members can be removed only with the consent of a commission composed of the Presidents and Vice-Presidents of both Chambers. It has a limited supervision over the collection of the revenue, and passes finally on pensions and on the accounts of officials, provinces, and communes. It also makes a yearly report to Parliament on the accounts of each ministry ; but its most extraordinary function consists in the fact that all decrees and orders which involve the payment of more than 2,000 lire must be submitted to it for registration, and if it thinks them contrary to the laws or regulations it can refuse to register them. It is, indeed, obliged to register them if the Council of Ministers insists upon it, but in that case they must be transmitted to the Presidents of the Chambers together with the opinion of the Corte del Conti. Law of Aug. 14, 1862, Arts. 14, 18, 19 ; and see Brusa, pp. 219-24. 142 ITALY. The Italian statesmen had at first a general belief in r 1 decentralization,^ but the force of circum- Liocal gov- ^ ernment. stanccs and a repugnance to the idea of fed- eration were so strong that the old territorial divi- sions, which could alone have furnished a solid basis for a decentralized system, were abandoned, and the whole country was cut up into a series of brand-new districts. These are the provinces, the circondari, the mandamenti, and the communes,^ of which the first and the last are the only ones of great importance. Until the Act of 1888, the powers conferred on the local bodies were extremely small, and even now they are far from extensive, for the whole system is copied from that of France, and, with some variations in de- tail, the organization and powers of the French local officers and councils have been followed very closely.^ A general description of the local government would therefore consist very largely in a repetition of what has been already said in the first chapter on France ; and hence it is only necessary to touch on a few sahent points, begging the reader to remember how great a power and how large a share of political patronage this ^ In 1868 the Chamber actually voted an order of the day in favor of decentralization. Petruccelli della Gattina, pp. 192-95. 2 In the provinces of Mantua and Venice the division is somewhat different, but is being brought into accord with the general plan. Brusa, p. 339. ^ For a description of the local government see Brusa, p. 337 et seq. The full text of the law on the subject was fixed by royal ordinance on Feb. 10, 1889, in accordance with the Act of Dec. 30, 1888. It was followed by an elaborate ordinance regulating its execution, and on July 7, 1889, and July 11, 1894, by acts amending the law. Manual of Deps., 1895, pp. 301-94. LOCAL GOVERNMENT. 143 system places in tlie hands of the central authorities.' At the head of each province, which corresponds to the French department, is a prefect appointed by the King, and directly subject to the Minister of the In- terior. Like his French prototype, he is regarded as a political officer, and uses his influence more or less openly at elections.^ The chief executive magistrate of the commune is the syndic ; who is chosen, like the mayor in France, by the communal council from its own members, if the commune has more than ten thousand inhabitants or is the capital of a province or circondaro ; and in other cases is selected by the King from among the members of the council.* As in France, both the provinces and the communes possess elected councils. In Italy they are chosen for six years, one half being renewed every three years ; but the suffrage for these bodies was exceedingly restricted, until by the Act of 1888 it was extended so as to be somewhat wider, especially as applied to the peasants, than the suffrage for the elec- tion of deputies.^ The abuse of local machinery for * In practice the administration appears to be, if anything, even more centralized than in France, owing to the habit on the part of the officials of referring everything to the central government. Jacinl, / Conser- vatori, p. 130 ; Minghetti, / Partiti Politici, pp. 240-41. 2 Brusa, pp. 225, 277. On the eve of the elections in 1892, forty-six out of the sixty-nine prefects were dismissed or transferred to other provinces, in order to help the government to carry the country. * By a law of July 7, 1896, all the syndics are now elected. 8 The other communal and provincial bodies are the municipal giunta, which is elected by the communal council, and has executive powers ; the provincial deputation, which occupies a similar position in the prov- ince, and is elected by the provincial council ; the prefectoral council, appointed by the central government to assist the prefect ; and the pro- vincial administrative giunta, partly appointed and partly elected, which 144 ITALY. political purposes, and the results on the public life of the nation, will be discussed later ; but it is proper to remark here that the resources of the local bodies are not adequate for the fulfillment of their duties, and this, combined with a love of municipal display, has been the cause of heavy debts, especially in the case of the larger cities, many of which have long been on the verge of bankruptcy/ There is one branch of the Itahan government which The "udiciai ^^^ ^^* bccu Centralized, and that is the ju- system. dicial systcm. The lower courts are, indeed, new creations, organized on a symmetrical plan very much resembHng the French ; but, in order apparently itsdecen- ^^* ^^ offcud the bcncli and bar of the old trahzation. principalities, the highest courts have been suffered to remain in the more important capitals, so that there are now five independent Courts of Cassa- tion, those of Turin, Florence, Naples, Palermo, and Rome, each of which has final and supreme authority, within its own district, on all questions of ordinary civil law.^ The Court of Cassation at Rome has, it is true, been given little by little exclusive jurisdiction over certain special matters ; ^ but the ordinary civil has a certain share in administrative justice, and whose approval is neces- sary for the validity of some of the most important acts of the local councils. For a list of these acts see the Local Government Law of Feb. 10, 1889, Arts. 142, 166-71, 173, and 223. 1 See Brusa, pp. 365-67 ; Turiello, Proposte, pp. 56, 63-65. 2 A Court of Cassation is a court of last resort, which considers only errors in law in the decisions of inferior tribunals. 3 These are, conflicts of competence between different courts, or be- tween the courts and the administration ; the transfer of suits from one court to another ; disciplinary matters ; and writs of error in criminal THE JUDICIAL SYSTEM. 145 jurisdiction is still divided among the five Courts of Cassation, which bear the same relation to each other as the hig-hest state courts in America/ There is no appeal from one to another, and no one of them feels bound to accept the decisions of the others, or to follow them as precedents. One cannot help thinking that this is an unfortunate condition, because there is nothing that tends more completely to consolidate a people, without crushing out local life, than a uniform admin- istration of justice. Italy has, indeed, a series of codes enacted at various times from 1865 to 1889, and cover- ing civil law, civil procedure, commercial law, criminal law, and criminal procedure ; but a code alone will not produce uniformity, because there is still room for differences of interpretation, and in fact the Italian Courts of Cassation often disagree, and there is no tri- bunal empowered to harmonize their decisions.^ As we have already seen in the case of France, the decision of civil and criminal questions forms . „ . , . . . „ , . . The courts only a part oi the admmistration oi lustice m and the . , T^ o 1 T ■ officials. continental xLurope, on account oi the distinc- tion drawn between public and private law.^ In order, therefore, to form a correct estimate of the position of cases, in complaints for violation of election laws, in civil suits against judges, and in questions of taxes and of church property. ^ For the organization and jurisdiction of the courts, see Brusa, pp. 231-38. 2 Cf. Speyer, in U'7isere Zeit, 1879, vol. i. p. 576. ^ Belgium presents an exception, for there the officials can be sued, and the acts of the government can be reviewed by the courts, as in an Anglo-Saxon country. Cf. Kerchove de Denterghem, De la Responsabilite des Ministres dans le Droit Public Beige. For Switzerland, see chap. xi. infra. 146 ITALY. the courts, we must consider their relation to the gov- ernment, and their power to determine the legaHty of the acts of pubHc officers. In Italy the prefects, sub- prefects, syndics, and their subordinates still enjoy the so-called administrative protection, that is, they cannot be sued or prosecuted for their official conduct with- out the royal consent.^ This privilege is generally un- popular, and will no doubt be abolished when the pro- posed bill on the tenure of office is passed. Meanwhile the benefit of it is claimed more and more frequently, although the permission to proceed appears to be usually granted.^ But even when this protection has been taken away, the courts will not have as much authority as in England or America. The reader will remember that the officers of the French government formerly possessed a similar privilege, and were deprived of it after the fall of the Second Empire. He will remember also that the change made very little practical difference, because it was held that the ordinary courts had no power to pass on the legality of official acts, such ques- tions being reserved exclusively for the administrative courts. The result of abohshing the privilege will not be precisely the same on the other side of the Alps, because the problem has been worked out on somewhat different lines, a curious attempt having been made to establish a compromise between the English and the French systems. 1 Law of Feb. 10, 1889, Arts. 8, 139. 2 Brusa, p. 282 ; Turiello, Fatti, pp. 210-11. The permission to prose- cute is not necessary in the case of offenses against the election laws. Law of Feb. 10, 1889, Art. 100 et seq. ; Brusa, pp. 73, 130, note 1. ADMINISTRATIVE LAW. 147 The subject of administrative law is, indeed, very confused in Italy, and a few years asfo it was . , . . in a thoroughly unsatisfactory condition, t^ativeiaw. When the union was formed, several of the component states possessed administrative courts of their own -, but in order to produce uniformity, and also with a view of furnishing the rights of the citizen the ordinary with a better guarantee, an act of March 20, 1865, abolished all these tribunals, and provided that the ordinary courts should have exclusive jurisdiction of all criminal prosecutions, and of all civil cases in which a civil or political right was involved, the Council of State being empowered to decide whether such a right was involved or not.^ It was not clearly foreseen that this last provision would place in the hands of the government an effective means of tyranny ; ^ but such proved to be the case, for the Council of State, com- posed, as it was at that time, of members who could be removed at pleasure,^ showed little incHnation in dis- puted cases to recognize that any private rights were involved, and, there being no administrative courts at all, the government had an absolutely free hand as soon as the jurisdiction of the ordinary courts was ousted.* The attempt to place the rights of the citizen ^ Legge sul Contenzioso Administrativo (March 20, 1865). See, espe- cially. Arts. 1, 2, 3, 13. 2 Perhaps it would be more correct to say that it was not foreseen how this power would be used for party purposes. Minghetti, / Partiti Politici, p. 270 et seq. ^ See Legge sul Consiglio di Stato of March 20, 1865, Art. 4. * See Brusa, pp. 212-13, 247 ; Minghetti, / Partiti Politici, p. 147 et seq. 148 ITALY. more fully under the protection of the ordinary courts than in France had resulted in freeing the officials more completely from all control ; for, except when strong political motives come into play, arbitrary conduct on the part of the French officials is restrained by the administrative courts. This state of the law in Italy gave rise to bitter complaints, but it lasted until 1877, when the decision of conflicts, as they are called, or Administra-