LAND AND ITS RENT W I 7 FRANC I S A. WALKER Cop/2 DEPARTMENT OF STATE. Alcove, Shelf,.. BEET BeALL, Her and Stationer, LAND AND ITS RENT. BY }v^,^ '' FRANCIS A. WALKER, Ph.D., LL.D., PRESIDENT OP THE MASSACHUSETTS ESTSTITUTE OP TECHNOLOGY; AUTHOR OP "the WAGES QUESTION;" " MONEY ; " " MONEY, TRADE, AND industry;" POLITICAL ECONOMY:" ETC. BOSTON: LITTLE, BROWN, AND COMPANY. 1883. !C >^ H3^^i (0 /•' Entered according to Act of Congress, in the year 1883, By Little, Beown, and Company, In the Office of the Librarian of Congress, at Washington. Camfiritfse *♦ PRINTED BY JOHN WILSON AND SON, UNIVERSITY PRESS. PEEFACE. ^ I ^HIS volume contains the substance of four lectures, delivered in Harvard University in May, 1883. The lecture-form, and also, so far as possible, the lecture-tone, have been dropped in preparing the work for the press, while some matters of detail have been added, which neither time nor the conditions of oral delivery allowed to be introduced on the former occasion. The author is aware that he is regarded by his American brethren as somewhat heretical in the view he takes of the relations of wages to the interest of capital and to the profits of business management, which view may be summed up in two propositions, namely: — iv PREFACE. 1st. Under perfect competition, the laborer would become the residual claimant upon the product of industry ,1 the amount to be deducted on account of rent, interest, and business profits being subject to definite principles, and, conse- quently, all gains in productive power would, upon this condition, inure directly to the benefit of the laborer. 2d. With imperfect and unequal competition, the economic harmonies do not pre- vail, the laborer surely losing his interest if he does not himself seek his interest. All economic injuries inflicted in the distribution of wealth tend, moreover, to abide and to deepen, while industrial society itself, as a whole, suffers in the ultimate result, through the reaction of dis- tribution upon production. But while the author of the present treatise thus fails to satisfy the requirements of eco- nomic orthodoxy, in regard to the relation of wages to the interest of capital and to the prof- its of business management, he is, in his view 1 For tlie elaboration of tliis proposition, the author would refer to pp. 265, 266, of his Political Economy. PEEFACE. V of tlie origin of rent and its influence upon the distribution of wealth, a Eicardian of the Eicardians, holding that the great thinker who has given his name to the economic doctrine of rent left little for those who should follow him to do ; and that any wide departure from the lines laid down by him can only result in con- fusion and error. The author is well aware that the tone of his allusions to Frederic Bastiat will grieve many of the American admirers of that most ingeni- ous, eloquent, and sentimental essayist ; but it seems full time that the plain truth regarding Bastiat's theory of value, whether as applied to land or to commercial products, should be spoken out on this side the water, as it was long ago, in England, by Professor Cairnes. In his power of raillery and sarcasm, in the gracious charm of his narrative, in the purity and ear- nestness of his philanthropic purpose, Bastiat cannot sufficiently be admired; but as a con- structive economist he made a dead failure, while his views regarding the land are espe- cially erroneous. Vi PREFACE. For the spirit in whicli he discusses the views of a writer who deliberately proposes that Gov- ernment shall confiscate the entire value of landed property, without compensation to those who, under the express sanction and encourage- ment of Government itself, have inherited or bought their estates, the author has no apol- ogy to offer. Every honest man will resent such a proposition as an insult. Boston, October, 1883. CONTENTS. o Chapter Page I. The Economic Doctrine of Rent . 5 II. Attacks upon the Doctrine of Rent 57 III. Recent Attacks upon Landed Prop- erty 121 IV. The Best Holding of the Land . 183 Index 221 3 -n LAND AND ITS EENT. CHAPTEE I THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF EENT. ^ I ^HE immediate reason for the publication -■- of this work is found in the course of economic discussion during the few months now passing. Altogether unexpectedly, and, so far as one can see, without any cause exist- ing in the economic relations of society, the questions of the rightfulness and the expe- diency of private property in land, and of the influence of rent upon the distribution of wealth, have been precipitated upon us, almost as if they were new questions. Whatever may be true of France and Germany, it must be said that never in England has the discussion of the equities and the economics of landed property been so active and earnest as now; while in the United States, where practically, the ques- b LAND AND ITS EENT. tion of the private ownership of the soil has not heretofore even been raised, we find popu- lar attention bestowed in a remarkable degree upon a book, now perhaps in its hundredth edition, the fundamental proposition of which is that " the recognition of exclusive property in land is necessarily a denial of the right of property in the products of labor," and whose practical proposals embrace the virtual abolition of private property in land through the confis- cation of rents by the State, — the author of this work ax3pearing as a welcome contributor to influential journals and reviews, and receiv- ing the greeting of crowded assemblies as the apostle of great sociological and economical reforms. It will be said : " The publication of such a work is certainly a curious phenomenon of the times, and a very disagreeable phenomenon; but surely the work itself cannot call for any serious consideration. ISTo intelligent person will read far in a book in which such gross incapacity for economical thinking is exhibited, in which a scheme so mad and anarchical is brought forward. Surely, society must long since have passed the point where it was nec- essary to discuss propositions like these, or to THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF EENT. 7 refute a writer who gives snch ample warning of the dangerous nature of his doctrines." But I think we cannot deal quite in this spirit with Mr. Henry George's " Progress and Poverty." As the London Quarterly Eeview remarks : " False theories, when they bear directly upon action, do not claim our atten- tion in proportion to the talent they are sup- ported by, but in proportion to the extent to which action is likely to be influenced by them ; and since action in modern politics so largely depends on the people, the wildest errors are grave, if they are only sufficiently popu- lar. . . . How they strike the wise is a matter of small moment; the great question is how they will strike the ignorant. . . . For practical purposes no proposals are ridiculous unless they are ridiculous to the mass of those who may act upon them. In any question in which the people are powerful no fallacy is refuted if the people still believe in it." ^ Unfortunately there is too much evidence of a profound popu- lar effect produced by this work upon the public mind of Great Britain, and, though more tardily, upon the public mind of the United States. The work was, in fact, published in 1879 ; 1 Quarterly Review, January, 1883. 8 LAND AND ITS RENT. but tliough it had a ready sale and attracted not a little attention, and even elicited some heed- less commendation by reason of the eloquence and picturesqueness of its style, it created its first sensation when reprinted abroad. In Great Britain the success of this book has been truly remarkable. " It is not the poor/' says the Eeview just cited, " it is not the seditious, only, who have been- thus affected by Mr. George's doctrines. They have received a welcome, which is even more singular, amongst certain sections of the really instructed classes. They have been gravely listened to by a conclave of English clergymen. Scotch ministers and non-conform- ist professors have done more than listen ; they have received them with marked approval; they have even held meetings and given lec- tures to disseminate them. Finally, certain trained economic thinkers, or men who pass for such, in at least one of our imiversities, are reported to have said that they see no means of refuting them, and that they probably mark the beginning of a new political epoch." Such a reception could hardly be accorded an American book abroad, without awakening new interest and stimulating a wider demand THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 9 at home. It is said that "Progress and Pov- erty " has reached an enormous circulation. The author has certainly come to be one of the lions of the hour. There is no reason to suppose that his doctrines have yet deeply in- fected the public mind of this country ; yet the ingenuity and eloquence of this writer must produce no uiconsiderable effect upon any reader, however intelligent, and however forti- fied by economic study. It is in view of this fresh discussion of the tenure of land and of rent in its relations to the distribution of wealth, that it has seemed best to take occasion to go over the field, step by step, through its whole extent. I shall there- fore deA^ote this the present chapter to an ele- mentary statement of the economic law of rent. In the second chapter I shall discuss the at- tacks made by Messrs. Bastiat, Carey, and Leroy-Beaulieu upon that doctrine. In the third chapter I shall undertake to deal with attacks upon the individual ownership of land, as made, not by those who denounce all species of property, but by those who admit private property in the products of labor, of which they deem private property in land an invasion. In 10 LAND AND ITS RENT. this connection attention will be invited to tlie later essays and sioeeches of Mr. Mill and to Mr. Henry George's work. In the fourth and last chapter I shall present some considera- tions related to the question. What, conceding the individual ownership of land, is that use of the soil which is most conducive to social and industrial welfare ? In pursuance of this scheme, let us now in- quire into the origin of rent. We will begin by assuming the existence of an isolated community occupying a territory of varying fertility. Let it, however, for sim- plicity of illustration, be conceded that, instead of an infinite diversity in this respect, each acre having its own rate of productiveness, the territory is divided into four tracts, each dis- tinctly defined. Thus, we might suppose that one tract would, with the application of a given amount of labor and capital, yield to the acre 24 bushels of wheat; the second, 22 bushels; the third, 20 bushels ; the fourth, 18 bushels. Such a supposition does not transcend the limits of a reasonable assumption for the pur- poses of argument. The differences of fertility existing among the cultivated lands of any con- THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 11 siderable district are not only as great as those indicated, but often very much greater. Thus, Mr. McCuUoch, the author of the '' Statistical Account of the British Empire," says : "A quar- ter of wheat may be raised in Kent, or Essex, or in the Carse of Gowrie, for a fourth or a fifth part, perhaps, of the expense necessary to raise it on the worst soils under cultivation." The range of productiveness among lands oc- cupied for the purposes of pasturage is very much wider still. Thus Sir James Caird, in his admirable work, " The Landed Interest and the Supply of Food," says : " The maximum of fertility, in the natural state, is a rich pasture capable of fattening an ox and two sheep an acre. Such soils are exceptional, though in most counties they are to be met with. . . . The minimum of fertility may be exemplified by a bleak mountain pasture where ten acres will barely maintain a small sheep." Now, in the case of the community under view, let us first take the stage where the pop- ulation yet remains so small that it can be sup- plied with food by the cultivation of only a por- tion of the most fertile of the four tracts of land. In this case, if the land in question be held by a number of competmg owners, either no 12 LAND AND ITS EENT. rent at all will be paid, or else a rent so small that, for purposes of economic reasoning, we may treat it as no rent at all, the principle de minimis non curatur applying with not less force in economics than in law. The above result will be reached by the sim- ple and direct operation of the principle of self-interest among the owners of the land. Inasmuch as only a part of the land of that quality (the 24-bushel tract) is required for cultivation, each proprietor will, if only he can be assured against Waste, ~ of which element we shall speak hereafter,^ — desire to have his own land occupied, even at the smallest rent, rather than derive no income whatever there- from ; and as, by the supposition, all the lots are not required for cultivation, the competi- tion of owners will reduce the compensation for the use of land to that minimum which in economics we may disregard. Let us next contemplate the community as increased in numbers until the entire tract of land of the first quality will no longer produce, under the traditional cultivation, — that is, with the farming methods employed, and with the amount of labor and capital heretofore applied 1 See post, pp. 51-53. THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF EENT. 13 to tlie soil, — enough wheat for the mamtenance of the population. In this state of things the question will arise, Shall the additional labor power, which is al- ways presumed to exist when we speak of an increase of population, and upon which the ad- ditional members of the community must rely for their subsistence, — new hands to feed new mouths, — shall this additional labor power be applied to the soil heretofore under cultivation, or shall it be applied to a portion of the tract standing next in order of fertility and hereto- fore uncultivated, — that which we may call the 2 2 -bushel tract ? The answer to this question will depend on the answer to the prior question : Has cultivation on the 24-bushel tract reached the point of diminishing returns, or not ? What do we mean by the point of " diminish- ing returns " ? This should be fully and clearly explained before any further progress is at- tempted. The explanation is as follows. In the progressive cultivation of any considerable tract of land having any appreciable degree of fertility, a continually higher and higher degree of per capita production is attained, year by year, as the amount of labor applied to the 14 LAND AND ITS EENT. soil increases, until a certain limit is readied. Thus, in the cultivation of a square mile of arable land, two laborers will produce more than twice as much as one ; four laborers will produce more than twice as much as two ; eight laborers will produce more than twice as much as four. Perhaps the eight laborers last al- luded to will produce twelve times as much as the first two, forty times as much as the first one. Such increase in productive power is due, first, to the opportunity afforded for co-opera- tion in labor, as, for instance, when two men do easily and rapidly something to which the strength of a single man would be utterly inadequate; and, secondly, to the division of labor and the organization of industry, which yield very great advantages as compared with an earlier industrial state. Now, the condition of agricultural develop- ment, in the course of which, by virtue of the mechanical advantages adverted to, the per capita product becomes greater and greater through the addition of new laborers, may be called the condition of "increasing returns." Just as surely, however, as the earth revolves around the sun, if labor continue to be applied THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF KENT. 15 in increasing amount to the cultivation of any piece of land, a point will be reached — sooner on this piece, later on that, but at some time for every piece, according to the character of the soil — ■ after which more labor applied to the soil will, the art of agriculture and other conditions remaining constant, meet a less than proportional return. Some return the new labor applied to the land will undoubtedly secure. We can hardly imagine a situation where more labor judi- ciously applied to any tract ^ would not increase the crop more or less. But, as has been said, the return declines proportionally. From that point forward, additional labor can only be em- ployed in cultivation upon the condition of a smaller and still smaller per capita product. The point we have indicated marks the stage of " diminishing returns " in agriculture. "Where 1 "It might be ploughed or harrowed twice instead of once, or three times instead of twice ; it might be dug instead of being ploughed. ; after ploughing, it might be gone over with a hoe, instead of a harrow, and the soil more com- pletely pulverized ; it might be oftener and more thoroughly weeded ; the implements used might be of a higher finish and more elaborate construction ; a greater quantity or more expensive kinds of manure might be applied, or, when ap- plied, they might be more carefully mixed and incorporated with the soil." — /. S. 3Iill. 16 LAND AND ITS KENT. that point is, may not be easily ascertained for any single piece of land, probably never could be ascertained with absolute exactness by any series of experiments ; yet we know that such a point is there, will be reached, will in time be passed, if the application of labor and capital continue. On one side the per capita product rises, rapidly or slowly, but surely and con- stantly, under the mechanical advantages of co-operation in productive effort, the division of employments, the organization of labor. On the other side, the per capita product falls off, slowly or rapidly, but just as surely and con- stantly, under the chemical disadvantages which attend the attempt to extort a greater and still greater crop from the soil. That it does rise on the one side, that it does fall away on the other, is so manifest that no man of sound mind can question the fact. That at some point the turning takes place, reason tells us, though we may not be able to identify that point with assurance. Let us now return to the community whose experience with the land, under the condition of increasing population, we have been tracing. The whole extent of the 24-bushel tract having THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF EENT 17 been occupied, and having proved, under tlie traditional cultivation, inadequate to the needs of subsistence, the question, we see, has arisen, whether the additional labor shall be expended upon that tract, or be carried over to the tract next in order of fertility, — the 2 2 -bushel tract. The decision of that question depends, as has been said, on the decision of the prior question, whether the point of " diminishing returns " has been reached. If not, the additional labor will be applied to the familiar fields. If it have been reached, the additional labor will (subject to a slight hesitation due to that abrupt descent from one grade to another, which we assumed for convenience of illustration, the actual order of nature being an insensible gradation) be transferred to the 22-bushel tract, and thus, in the phrase of the economist, "cultivation will descend to inferior soils." That cultivation does so descend is a fact of familiar observation on every hand. There are few farms within which land is not cultivated which is poorer than the best, and it is so culti- vated because the farmer knows that it is more profitable for him to plough and plant a less fertile field than to attempt to force the yield of the more fertile up beyond a certain limit. 2 18 LAND AND ITS RENT. Cultivation, then, descending to the 22-bushel tract, Eent emerges. Under what impulse ? Why, by this simple operation of the prin- ciple of self-interest : inasmuch as some of the would-be cultivators must go upon the 22- bushel tract, every person now in occupation of a lot on the 24-bushel tract may just as well — may he not ? — pay something for the privi- lege of remaining where he is, as take up a lot of the new land for nothing ? If not, why not ? How much shall he pay ? Wliy, clearly, 2 bushels per acre, the difference between the yield of the two tracts, under the same ap- plication of labor and capital. The culti- vator of the better land, raising 24 bushels per acre, and out of this paying 2 bushels for the privilege of cultivation, which we will call Eent, will have 22 bushels left, net, which is all he could, by the supposition, raise from the new land. More than this margin, 2 bushels, he will not pay, because, otherwise, he would do better to take up a lot of the new land.^ All of this margin he will pay, because, otherwise, some would-be cultivator 1 The effects of the indisposition of the cultivator to change his place of labor and residence will be subsequently- allowed for. Bee post, pp. 42-51. THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 19 will offer to pay that rent, and thus cut him out of the occupancy. And this rental of 2 bushels per acre will apply to all the land in the 24-bushel tract, and not to a part of it only. As yet, however, no rent whatever is paid for any part of the 2 2 -bushel tract, not even for that part which is cultivated, since, inasmuch as only a portion of it is required, competition among proprietors within this tract will prevent rent rising above that minimum which we treat as niL If, now, we suppose that, in the progress of population, the numbers of the community in- crease to the point where subsistence up to the traditional standard of living cannot, by the traditional methods of cultivation, be provided from the 24- and the 2 2 -bushel tracts together, recourse will be had to the third grade of soils, comprised within the 20-bushel tract. What will then happen in the matter of rents ? Why, this : the lands of the 20-bushel tract will bear no rent, for the reason which we con- templated in connection with the 22-bushel tract, when that comprised the lowest grade of soils under cultivation ; but rent will now emerge from the land just above it on the scale of fertility, and that rent will measure the 20 LAND AND ITS RENT. excess of productiveness, as in the former case. Any actual cultivator of the 22-bushel tract may just as well pay 2 bushels rent, where he is, as go upon the new land, for nothing; any would-be cultivator may just as well settle here, paying this rent, as take up a free tract of the poorer land. And now, if we look back to the 24-bushel tract, we note a remarkable phenomenon. The soil here is no better than it was ; nothing has been done to increase its productiveness ; yet suddenly and peremptorily proprietors within this tract demand and receive 4 bushels per acre. Why is this ? Again the result is due to the simple and direct operation of the prin- ciple of self-interest in dealing with the land. Any person, actual cultivator or would-be cul- tivator, may just as well — may he not ? — pay 4 bushels here, as go upon the 22-bushel tract and pay 2 bushels rent, or " squat " upon the 20-bushel tract, paying nothing for the privilege. And if the increase of the numbers of the community requires cultivation (which, as we have seen, is always and everywhere subject to the law of " diminishing returns ") again to descend, and the soil within the 18-bushel tract THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 21 is taken up, we shall find, according to the principle already abundantly illustrated, that this land itself will bear no rent, but that the 20-bushel tract will now bear a rent of 2 bushels per acre, while the rent of the 22-bushel tract will advance to 4 bushels and that of the 24-bushel tract to 6 bushels. We state, then, the normal operation of the principle of self-interest in dealing vnth the land (that is, the Laiv of Bent), as folloivs : — Bent arises from the fact of varying degrees of productiveness in the lands actually contributing to the supp)ly of the same marhet, the least pro- ductive land paying no rent, or a rent so small that it may he treated as none. The rent of all the higher grades of land is measured upwards from this line, the rent of each piece ahsorling cdl the excess of produce above that of the no-i^ent land. Thus far we have, for simplicity of illustra- tion, spoken of fertility and productiveness indis- tinguishably, as if differences in productiveness were due solely to differences in the chemical constituents of the land, the depth of soil, its friabihty, etc., or to differences in climate, all of which are included in our conception of com- parative fertility. 22 LAND AND ITS RENT. But we have now to note that the net pro- ductiveness of a tract of land may be reduced, in comparison with another tract of equal fer- tility, by either or both of two considerable causes : — 1. The mechanical difficulties of cultivation, e. g. irregularity of surface. This consideration has been almost wholly neglected by writers on rent, and naturally enough in the past, when land was cultivated mainly with hand tools, — the hoe, the spade, the scythe, the sickle. But the rapid introduction of horse and even steam power into agricultural operations, since 1850, has made the character of the surface an impor- tant, though not the most important, element in the problem of rent. The land in a New Eng- land side-hill farm may be as fertile as that of an Illinois prairie farm, but the cost of cultivation may in the former case be enhanced thirty or fifty per cent through roughness of surface. 2. A much more important cause in the reduc- tion of the net productiveness of land, for the purposes of rent, is found in distance from mar- ket. By distance, in this connection, we should understand, not absolute distance, as measured on a great circle of the earth, but resistance to transportation. THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF EENT. 28 To illustrate the operation of tliis cause, let us return to our four tracts of arable land, sup- plying a certain market, and yielding, respec- tively, 24, 22, 20, and 18 bushels of wheat per acre, with the application of a certam amount of labor and capital. These have been assumed to be all equally near to the market in which their produce is to be sold. Now, let us suppose that some enterprising cultivators undertake to open up a large tract of very fertile land situated at a considerable distance. The productiveness of this tract might even reach 30 bushels, as compared with the four tracts described; yet it might be found that, after the grain were harvested, the cattle and the men engaged in hauling the crop to market would eat up, on the round trip, not less than 12 bushels out of the produce of each acre, — in which case this tract would stand, for the purposes of rent, not on a level with the more fertile home tracts, but exactly in the position (30 — 12 = 18) of the 18-bushel tract ; and until this last-named were all taken up, the more distant lands would either not be cultivated at all, or would be cultivated with- out paying rent. But should some improvement in the means' 24 LAND AND ITS RENT. of transportation reduce the amount of the de- duction to be made from the gross produce, on that account, very important effects might be wrought, not only as influencing the occupation and cultivation of this tract, but also as con- trolling the rent of the home tracts. Let us, first, suppose one bushel saved from the maw of the cattle and men engaged in transporting the crop to market. The net productiveness of the tract (30 — 11) would then be 19. Imme- diately the 18-bushel home tract would be thrown out of cultivation, as the labor and capital previously employed thereon could be more advantageously transferred to the new territory. And now a readjustment of rents must take place. The 19-bushel land will bear no rent. The highest grade of soils will bear a rent (24 — 19) of only 5 bushels ; the second grade, of only 3 ; the third grade, of only 1. If we assume the tracts to be of equal size, the aggregate amount of rents now received by the owners of land will be but 9 as against 12, a reduction of one fourth. Their land is just as good as it was before, yields just as much grain of unimpaired quality; but their rents have fallen, simply because the 18-bushel tract has been thrown out of cultivation, and the THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF KENT. 25 19-busliel tract substituted as furnisliing tlie poorest grade of soils contributing to the sup- ply of the market. Let us further suppose that some improve- ment in carts, or the substitution of draught- horses for oxen, shortens the tmie taken for the transport of the grain, so that only nine bushels have to be deducted from the pro- duce of an acre ; what will be the effect on the cultivation of the several tracts, and on the amounts of rent yielded by them respectively ? The net produce of the distant tract (30 — 9) has now risen to 21 bushels. The 20-bushel tract must be abandoned. No one can culti- vate it and get his outlay back, so long as there is a limitless extent of free land on which wheat can be raised with a smaller expenditure of labor and capital. The highest grade of land now yields a rent of but 3 bushels an acre (24 — 21); the second of but 1 bushel. The aggregate amount received by the owners of land, in rents, sinks from 9 to 4, as the conse- quence of the last step taken, namely, the throwing out of certain soils, the uplifting of the lower limit of cultivation. Give the name America to the remote tract in this illustration, and you have a fair explana- 26 LAND AND ITS RENT. tion of the tremendous effects produced, during the past few years, upon English and Irish rents, by the increasing severity of competition from this side the Atlantic, following the reduction in the cost of transportation. We now reach the second stage of our in- quiry. If rent arises solely as we have de- scribed, and if the amount of rent is measured by the rule that has been laid down, what is the influence of rent upon the distribution of wealth ? Who is richer and who is poorer by reason of it? In particular, how are the la- borers, on the one side, and the consumers of agricultural produce, on the other, affected thereby ? To get the clearest possible conception of the relations of the parties in interest, we will assume the English threefold organization for the purposes of agricultural production, — the landlord owning the land and leasing it to tenant farmers, who, on their part, hire those who perform the labor of cultivation, devoting their own time to the buying of tools, supplies, and work animals, to selling the produce, to superintending the progress of each part, by turns, of the work of the farm, while exercising a THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF EENT. 27 general administration of the wliole and assum- ing all the responsibilities of production. Under such an organization as is here de- scribed, the question of rent is wholly a ques- tion between landlord and tenant. It does not concern the laborer at all. It does not go fur- ther, and touch the interest of the consumer of agricultural produce.^ The laborer, on his part, gets no less wages because rent is paid; the loaf of bread would cost the consumer just as much, were all rents remitted. This is "a hard saying," and on its first statement appears incredible, but it is as sure- ly demonstrable as any theorem in geometry. Let us see. The normal price of any commodity is fixed by the cost of the production of that part of the supply which is produced under the most disadvantageous conditions. The cost of that portion, whatever that cost may be, will deter- mine the price of all other portions, no matter how much more favorable the conditions under which these may be produced. " 1 It was one of the greatest of the mistakes of Adam .Smith that he believed rent to enter into the price of agri- cultural produce. "Eent," he says, "enters into the com- position of the price of commodities in a different way from wages and profits. " The fact is, it does not enter at all. 28 LAND AND ITS KENT. Appl}dng this principle to a single agricul- tural crop, e. g. wheat, we say that the normal price of wheat will be fixed by the cost of raising it upon the least productive soils which are actually cultivated for the supply of the market. This cost must be covered by the price, or else wheat will not continue to be grown on those soils, while yet the fact that it is grown there now proves that this wheat constitutes a necessary part of the supply of the market. Whatever be the price of the wheat grown on the least productive soils, that price will — quality being assumed constant, or allowance being made for differences in quality — be paid for the wheat grown on more productive soils. This is clear, since, if dealers are to attempt to exact a higher price for one lot of wheat than for others, simply because it was raised at a greater cost, no one would buy from that lot. But if the price of the whole crop of wheat is to be fixed by the cost of raising it on the least productive soils actually cultivated, then rent is not a part of the price of agricul- tural produce, since the least productive soils pay no rent; and therefore rent cannot be a part of the price of the wheat raised there- THE ECONOMIC DOCTEIXE OF EENT. 29 from; and if not of this wheat, then of no wheat/ since, as we have seen, the price of the whole crop is fixed by the cost of that portion which is raised on the no-rent land. Let us look at it from another point of view. Suppose a landlord to hold the opinion that rent somehow, after all, in spite of all your fine-spun theories, must swell the price of the baker's loaf, and, in consequence of this con- viction, to remit, in an access of philanthropy, all his rents for the year. What will be the effect on the price of wheat ? I answer, None ; the tenants raising the wheat at the same cost, otherwise, as before, and selling it at a price determined by the cost of raising wheat on lands which pay no rent, would simply pocket the sums they would have paid in rent but for the landlord's bad political economy. But, it may be asked, will not the farmers, thus enriched, pay higher wages to their laborers ? No. Why should they ? They have been pay- ing wages at the usual rates, — rates determined by the demand for and the supply of labor. Noth- ing has happened to affect that demand or that supply. Moreover, why, even in equity, should 1 " Corn is not high because a rent is paid ; but a rent is paid because corn is high." — Ricardo. 30 LAND AND ITS RENT. tliey pay higher wages ? They have been paying the same wages as the farmers who cultivate the no-rent lands. Why should laborers work- ing on rich fields receive more than those whose lot it is to work on poor fields ? Where would be the justice of that ? The one set of laborers work as industriously and as effi- ciently as the other. In the matter of desert they are equal ; what should make discrimina- tion between them in the matter of wages ? But even though there were the strongest reason, in equity, why tenant farmers should hand over to their laborers the whole or a part of the rents remitted by the landlord, it will be seen that we have no assurance, human nature being what it is, that they would do so. They would pay wages at the old rates, sell their wheat at the old price, and put the difference into their own pockets. No economic force can be invoked which would carry the remitted rents, or any part of them, past the tenant farm- er's door. The landlord would be poorer for his mistake, the farmer richer ; but neither the agricultural laborer nor the consumer of agri- cultural produce would profit by it in the smallest degree. We conclude then that, the price of agricul- THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF EENT. 31 tural produce being fixed by the cost of raising it on the least productive soils actually con- tributing to the supply of the market, there remains, on all more productive fields, an excess of value above the cost of p)'i'oduction, a surplus, which, so far as the normal operation of the principle of self-interest is concerned, must become the property of the owner of the soil. The owner can give it away, as he can give away anything else that is his, or it can be taken from him by violence, as anything else may be taken ; but no economic force can en- ter to carry rent' to any point where it will either raise the price of labor or lower the price of produce. Such, in its simplest elements, is the normal operation of the principle of self-interest in dealing with the land. As formulated by Ei- cardo, this is known as the Economic, or Eicar- dian, doctrine of rent. Surely, no one who has followed me with care will hesitate to say that the doctrine, upon its assumptions, is incon- testably true, and that whoever denies it puts himself on the level of the man who denies that things which are equal to the same thing are equal to each other. 32 LAND AND ITS EENT. I spoke of the doctrine as formulated by Eicardo. That illustrious economist was not, indeed, the first to announce the law of rent, which had been correctly and clearly stated by Andersen, a Scotch writer, in 1777. As by him declared, however, the doctrine failed to attract attention. Forty years later, it was, according to the usual statement, " simultane- ously rediscovered," in the early pari? of this century, by Mr. Malthus, Sir Edward West, and Mr. Eicardo. The cogency with which the arguments of the last-named writer were put, the stringency with which the principle in- volved was applied in stating the theory of value and in tracing the effects of taxation upon the distribution of wealth, have served to affix his name permanently to the doctrine, alike in England, in America, and on the con- tinent of Europe. We now come to a distinction which is most important in the theory of our subject. The principles thus far laid down relate only to the natural advantages of the land, productively, being such as are derived from fertility, from accessibility for the purposes of cultivation, or from nearness to the market where the produce THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 33 is to be sold. From this point of view land is contemplated as unimproved. The return that shall be made to productive advantages acquired hy the land through the applications of capital, in the nature of permanent improvements, whether above or beneath the surface, is gov- erned by a law altogether different from that which we have thus far discovered. The law of capital differs from the law of rent in this : there is not theoretically any no- interest capital. We have seen that the exist- ence of a body of no-rent lands is essentially involved in the theory of rent. There is noth- ing corresponding to this m the law of capital. Practically it is doubtless true that some capi- tal bears a high interest ; other portions, a low interest; still other portions bring no returns to their owners, while, in cases not infrequent, the capital sum invested may even be itself lost, in whole or in part. But this is not at all involved in the nature of capital. Such a result would be due to the greater or less wis- dom displayed by investors in dealing with the portions of capital placed m their hands. In regard to land, on the contrary, the securing of rent by the owner does not depend on the greater or less wisdom of the proprietor, but is 3 34 LAND AND ITS RENT. determined by the conditions of the land itself. There is a reason, in the nature of the case, why one piece of land should bring a high rent, an- other a low rent, a third no rent at all. But in regard to two portions of capital, as yet unin- vested, there is no reason why one should bear a higher rate of interest than the other. And so, in theory, not only is there no no-interest capital, but all portions of capital bear an equal rate of interest, the divergences of actual from theoreti- cal interest being due to mistakes of calcula- tion, to misadventures beyond the power of the investor to foresee, to fraud, or other cause alto- gether outside the nature of the capital itself. The applications of capital to land are deter- mined by the same force which directs capital to other uses, namely, the expectation of a profit to the investor. If capital be applied to land, it is because the owner looks, wisely or weakly, to obtain, on the whole and in the long run, a return equal (the degree of security being taken fairly into account) to that which could be ob- tained through its application to any of the various purposes of manufacture, transporta- tion, or commerce. The main difference between capital invested in agriculture and that invested in other depart- THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 35 ments of productive effort is found in tlie im- movability of such property. This is, however, a difference not of kind, but of degree only, since capital invested in many other ways becomes immovable, or movable only upon the condition of a heavy charge for transpor- tation, or a great loss of value in adapting it to other uses. We note, then, that what shall be paid for the use of land may consist of two parts, — rent proper, the remuneration for what Eicardo called the original and indestructible powers of the soil ; and fictitious rent, which is, in truth, nothing but interest upon capital invested. It is only to the former that the economic doc- trine of rent applies. When I speak of rent, without qualification, I beg to be understood to mean rent proper; though I shall sometimes express the adjective at critical points, as a fresh assurance against misconception. It has been said that capital would not be invested in agricultural improvements but for the expectation of a return equal to that de- rived from investments in other directions. But agricultural investments, being in a very high degree immovable, are, of course, subject 36 LAND AND ITS RENT. to great or even total loss in case the operation prove to have been made ill-advisedly. Now let us further note here, that, in such a case as that just indicated, the loss is not borne in any degree by the proprietor of the soil, as such, be he, in fact, also the owner of the capi- tal invested in the soil, or not, but by the owner of the capital, as such. The loss arising from the failure of capital invested in agricultural improvements is not divided between the rent proper and the interest which together make up what is popularly called rent. Such loss falls wholly upon the interest part of this composite payment. Rent proper takes care of itself. Under the normal operation of the principle of self-interest, rent gets its own in- variably, indefeasibly. Let us illustrate. Suppose a field of which the economic rent, meaning thereby the pro- ductive advantages of that field over the poor- est or most distant field under cultivation for the supply of the market, is 50 bushels of wheat a year. Now let an investment of capi- tal take place, in the form of trenches, fences, buildings, or what not, of which the proper annual returns, according to the usual rate of interest, would be 50 bushels. THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 37 Were the produce of the field to be so in- creased thereby that, after repaying the cost of cultivation, a surplus of 120 bushels should remain, the economist does not contemplate this amount as divided equally between rent proper and interest, each receiving 60 bushels. On the contrary, the economist regards the rent of the land as still 50 bushels only, the remainder, 70 bushels, being interest on the investment. But if, in the opposite case, the produce remainmg, after repaying the cost of cultivation, should be but 80 bushels, the economist would regard not 40, but only 30, bushels as compensation for the sum invested in improvements, the amount of rent remain- ing, in any philosophical view, unaffected by the partial failure of that investment. The distinction to which attention is here invited is not a mere matter of finesse. It is of vital and vast importance in dealing with the question of the value of land, whether for rental or for sale, as we shall see ^ when we come to consider the attacks made upon the doctrine of rent by Mr. Carey and others. It has been said that, upon its assumptions, See^os^, i:)p. 76-85, 111, 112. 38 LAND AND ITS RENT. that doctrine must be admitted by every person who is capable of understanding the terms in which it is stated. It has, however, frequently been alleged that those assumptions are so wide of the facts of human society, that the so-called economic law of rent is of no practical importance in the theory of the distribution of wealth. Let us, then, carefully consider the several successive assumptions which underlie this doc- trine. 1. The doctrine assumes the private owner- ship of land, with real and active competition among proprietors, as contrasted with monop- oly secured by a combination of proprietors, or by a single proprietor ; for instance, the State. Thus, to return to the illustration which we pursued so much at length, we said that when the community was yet so small that all the members could be maintained by the cultivation of a portion only of the tract having the highest degree of productiveness, no rent whatsoever would be paid for any portion of that tract, even the portion actually cultivated, or, in any event, only a rent so small that, for pur- poses of economic reasoning, it could safely be disregarded. THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF RENT. 39 But if we suppose that all the proprietors of this tract firmly unite to demand a rent, what will be the result? Competition being de- stroyed, a rent may conceivably be exacted. How large a rent ? What will be its upward limit ? I answer, Two bushels an acre for the whole amount actually cultivated. More than this cannot be secured by any combination among the proprietors within this tract, since, if a higher rent were demanded, it would be- come the interest of every cultivator to resort to lands of the next grade of productiveness, namely, those within the 22-bushel tract, which could be had without rent. This rent of two bushels will not, it should be observed, be paid for all the land (say a acres) within the first-described tract, but only for so much of it as is actually required for cultivation (say x acres) to meet the existing demand for wheat. All the persons in the combination, those whose lands are cultivated and those whose lands are not, will have to divide among themselves the aggregate sum (2 X bushels) so obtained, no single proprietor securing so much as two bushels an acre for all of his individual estate. Each individual pro- prietor will then receive for each acre of liis 40 LAND AND ITS RENT. land the following rent : i^i^n^M! Should one owner try to overreach the others by rentmg his own land privately, in contravention of the agreement, the combination would at once be broken, competition would set in, and rents would fall to the minimum. Such a combination is, of course, conceiv- able ; yet it would be wholly impracticable if any considerable number of proprietors were concerned. That the combination should be extended downwards, to include not only the proprietors of the next grade of land, the 22-bushel tract, but also those of the 20- bushel tract, and even of the lowest grade, the 18-bushel tract, for which otherwise no rent would be paid, but which, in the attempt to escape competition, would have to be brought within the combination, their owners becoming entitled to a share of the profits, and that thus a monopoly should be established governing the price of wheat, would mani- festly involve a thousand-fold the difficulties which would attend the formation of a com- bination to control the rent of lands all of the same grade. I am not aware that in the his- tory of mankind such a combination has ever anywhere been made and maintained; and THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF RENT. 41 there seems little reason for appreliending such a combination in the future. But what individual owners could not do, Government may. There are instances of rents paid in new countries, as in Australia, while yet all even of the best lands were not taken up. This phenomenon, which several writers have mistakenly adduced as if it were in con- tradiction of Eicardo's law of rent, has been due to the fact that all available lands were held by the Government, which was thus able to fix a monopoly price. Now, under monopoly, price is wholly cut away from cost of production. It becomes purely a question of demand. What price shall be paid, — for Avheat, for example, — whether one dollar, or five, or fifty, will depend on how much consumers, who must get it, have with which to purchase it. Up to the limit of the absolute exhaustion of the resources of pur- chasers, price may be carried by the force of monopoly, and into that price, as Professor Cairnes has so well shown,^ rent does enter. 1 **In the ordinary case of agi'icultural rent, the relation of rent to price is not that of cause to effect, but of effect to cause ; rent, that is to say, is the consequence, not the cause, of the high price of agricultural products. ... On the other 42 LAND AND ITS EENT. Such would be tlie effect upon rent, and upon the price of produce, of universal land monop- oly. The matter is not, however, of great prac- tical interest, inasmuch as a monopoly of land, in any proper sense of the term, rarely exists over any considerable territory ; and were it to be established, even over large regions, its ef- fects would be kept down within narrow limits unless the importation of food were forbidden. 2. The doctrine of rent, as we have stated it, assumes not only an active competition among land-owners, but also an active com- petition between land owners and cultivators as classes, and, still further, an active competi- tion throughout the cultivating class itself, each cultivator seeking his own interests as against those of any and every other. It is implied that the landlord, on his part, will unflinchingly demand all the rent which the excess of produce over that of the no-rent lands will allow the cultivators to pay ; and that he will exact this, if need be, at the cost hand, in the special cases of rent referred to, in the case, e. g., of the unoccupied Lands of a colony, — rent is, not the effect, but the cause of price. " The price of corn rises here because the Government de- mands a rent. In the ordinary case the landlord demands a rent because the price of corn is high." THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF EENT. 43 of driving old tenants from the soil, not even giving favor to age, infirmity, or ajBfliction. On the part of the cultivator, it is implied that he will pursue his interest with unfailmg intelligence and unflagging zeal, hesitating not to raise the rent upon his fellows by overbid- ding them ; hesitating not to crowd himself into the place of any other cultivator, should a gain appear therein ; hesitating not, for any senti- mental reason, to abandon his own farm, his own home, his native country even, and seek his interest elsewhere, with absolute indiffer- ence to everything but an economic benefit. The barest statement of these conditions shows that Eicardo's law does not furnish a formula by which the compensation to be paid for the cultivation of any given piece of land can be determined in advance. The law is only true hypothetically, and the conditions taken for the purpose nowhere exist, in their theoretical completeness. The United States and Ireland are probably the only two con- siderable countries in which rents closely ap- proximating true competitive rents have been habitually paid. This fact does not deprive the economic law of rent of its significance and value. No projectile describes a perfect 44 LAND AND ITS EENT. parabola ; yet tlie artillerist never fails to have reference to the law of the projectile, while pointing his piece. I have said that the United States and Ire- land are probably the only considerable coun- tries ^ in which true competitive rents have been habitually paid. The similarity of action, in this respect, in these two countries, has been due to altogether different causes, and has, through affecting widely different material in the two cases, produced altogether different re- sults. In the United States, the mobility of the population, their quick intelligence, their almost Ishmaelitish proclivity to change of place; the utter absence of popular notions regarding favors to be given in trade, or con- cessions to be made to classes supposed to be helpless and dependent ; the cheapness of lands within the area of settlement, and the standing offer, by the Government, of boundless tracts of good land along the frontier, free of charge, 1 Professor de Laveleye speaks of the rents exacted by the small owners of land in certain districts of Belgium from those who are so unfortunate as to become their tenants, as true "rack rents," characterized by a severity of extortion rarely known elsewhere. But the area to which this state of things applies does not require a qualification of the already guarded statement in the text. THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 45 upon the sole condition of actual personal occu- pation and cultivation; and, lastly, the tradi- tional character of American agriculture, which up to this point in our history has been of a very superficial character,^ involving comparatively 1 In an article in the " Princeton Review" of 1882, I ven- tured on the following vindication of that system of cultivation which has elicited so many expressions of disapproval from European tourists in America, and even from the self-consti- tuted guardians of our agricultural interests at home. " The American people, finding themselves on a continent containing an almost limitless breadth of arable land, of fair average fertility, having little accumulated capital and many urgent occasions for every unit of labor power they could exert, have elected — and in doing so they are, I make bold to say, fully justified, on sound economical principles — to regard the land as practically of no value, and labor as of high value ; have, in pursuance of this theory of the case, syste- matically cropped their fields on the principle of obtaining the largest crops with the least expenditure of labor, limiting their improvements to what was required for the immediate purpose specified, and caring little about returning to the soil any equivalent for the properties taken from it by the crops of each successive year. What has been returned has been only the manure generated incidentally to the support of the live stock needed to work the farm. In that which is for the time the great wheat and corn region of the United States, the fields are, as a rule, cropped continuously, with- out fertilization, year after year, decade after decade, until their fertility sensibly declines. "Decline under this regimen it must, sooner or later, later or sooner, according to the crop and according to the degree 46 LAND AND ITS KENT. little expenditure for the benefit of tlie soil beyond the requirements of the annual crop, of original strength in tlie soil. Resort must then be had to new fields of virgin freshness, which, with us in the United States, has always meant ' The West.' When Profes- sor Johnston published his ' ISTotes on North America, ' in 1851, the granary of the continent had already moved from the flats of the lower St. Lawrence to the Mississippi Yalley, the north and south line which divided the wheat product of the United States into two equal parts being approximately the line of the 82d meridian. In 1860, it was the 85th ; in 1870, the 88th ; in 1880, the 89th. " Meanwhile, what becomes of the regions over Avhich this shadow of partial exhaustion passes, like an eclipse, in its westward movement ? The answer is to be read in the con- dition of New England to-day. A part of the agricultural population is maintained in raising upon limited soils the smaller crops, garden vegetables and orchard fruits, and pro- ducing butter, milk, poultry, and eggs for the supply of the cities and manufacturing towns which had their origin in the flourishing days of agriculture, which have grown with the age of the communities in which they were planted, and which, having been well founded when the decadence of agriculture begins, flourish the more on this account, inas- much as a second part of the agricultural population, not choosing to follow the westward movement of the grain cul- ture, are ready with their rising sons and daughters to enter the mill and factory. Still another part of the agricultural population gradually becomes occupied in the higher and more careful culture of the cereal crops on the better portion of the former breadth of arable land, the less eligible fields being allowed to spring up in brush and woods ; deeper ploughing and better drainage are resorted to ; fertilizers are THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 47 except as to expenditures of a constructive or mechanical nature, thus leaving the question of "unexhausted improvements," between tenant and landlord, a very simple one, — all these causes have combined in the United States to bring actual and theoretical rent close together. No landlord here would hesitate to demand the utmost rent which he thought the tenant would pay; nor would any degree of popular odium attend a change of tenants, made solely on the ground that the new-comer offered more for the privilege of cultivation. It would be held that it was the landlord's right to get the full value of his land and to do whatever should be necessary to that end; while in a country where nine and a half millions of the native population live in other States than those in which they were born, any effort to now employed to "bring up and to keep up the pristine fer- tility of the soil. And thus begins the systematic agricul- ture of an old State. . . . "It is in the way described that Americans have dealt with the soil opened to them by treaty or by purchase. And I have no hesitation in saying that posterity will decide, first, that it was both economically justifiable and politically for- tunate that this should be done ; and, secondly, that what has been done was accomplished with singular enterprise, prudence, patience, intelligence, and skill," 48 LAND AND ITS RENT. arouse indignation, or even pity, at the specta- cle of an evicted family would be ludicrously futile. Here, then, we have competitive rents nearly in their fulness, the normal operation of the principle of self-interest being only re- strained by that degree of ignorance and inertia which may be found among the most enlight- ened and enterprising peoples. In England, however, the very country of Bicardo, competitive rents have never been generally exacted. Here we find sentiments of mutual obligation between landlord and tenant, sentiments having a political or a social origin, entering to modify profoundly the operation of purely economic forces. " The rent of agri- cultural land," says Professor Thorold Eogers, " is seldom the maximum annual value of the occupancy ; in many cases, is considerably be- low such an amount." Not only are the land- lord's own instincts of acquisition in general tempered by personal good-will between himself and his tenant, but an imperious public senti- ment would protect the tenant against an un- duly exacting landlord, to the extent of the social proscription of the offending party. 'No English gentleman could crowd an industrious tenant, who had been long upon the estate, out THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 49 of liis holding, to admit a stranger, without having the whole parish or the whole county crying shame upon him. By the force of sentiments like these, the normal operation of the principle of self-inter- est in dealing with the land is, in England, so far restrained that no inconsiderable part of what might, by Kicardo's law, be exacted in rent, remains unclaimed in the hands of the occupier, the tenant farmer. Upon the Conti- nent of Europe, competitive rents are not even the rule, to which exception is made by virtue of such causes as have been indicated. In general, custom determines the amount of rent ; and while custom has always a certain refer- ence to the comparative productive advantages of land, it is the universal admission of all writers, whether liberal or conservative, upon this subject, that it has the effect, supported, as it is, by feelings of personal good- will and by a public sentiment which recognizes and is pre- pared to enforce the obligation of the noble and wealthy classes to be considerate and mer- ciful in dealing with the peasantry, to cause a divergence, often a very wide divergence, from competitive rents, always in favor of the culti- vator. So strong is custom, in controlling the 4 50 LAND AND ITS RENT. actions of men in dealing with the land, that over large portions of Continental Europe, the rents, consisting generally of a share of the produce, are not changed ^ from generation to generation, notwithstanding the growth of pop- ulation, sending cultivation down to soils of lower and still lower fertility. It is true that the landlord gains through the enhanced value of his share of the produce ; but it is also true that the cultivator realizes a large gain (of which by the Eicardian law he would have been deprived) through the enhanced value of so much of the produce as remains to himself. It is not necessary at this time to enter, merely for illustration of our principle, upon so large and so difficult a question as that of rents in Ireland. Here in the past have been seen the full effects of competition, — competition, not, as in the United States, between classes sub- stantially equal in intelligence and freedom of 1 Indeed, it is, as Sir Henry Maine remarks, "all but certain that the idea of taking the highest obtainable rent for land is relatively of very modern origin. The rent of land corresponds to the price of goods ; but doubtless was infi- nitely slower in corresponding to economical law, since the impression of a brotherhood in the ownership of land still survived, when goods had long since become the subject of individual property." — Village Communities, p. 198. THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 51 movement; competition, not, as in England, restrained by kindly sentiments and conserva- tive usages ; ^ but a competition between a land- lord class, few in numbers, rich in accumulated means, thoroughly united among themselves as the result of generations of suppressed warfare, and cherishing towards the peasantry, not the feelings natural to the lord of the soil, but the fears, the jealousies, the hatreds, that are born of race and religious antagonisms, and, on the other part, a tenant class, whose numbers were largely in excess of the capabilities of the land to support, and who were, in character, ignorant, superstitious, and improvident, their very vir- tues of generosity and hopefulness contributing to further disqualify them for the competition which they were compelled to enter upon for the occupation of the soil. Two minor assumptions, involved in Eicardo's law, are : (1.) The indifference of the landlord to the possibility of waste being committed by the tenant, and (2.) The indifference of the 1 "The three rents are : Eack-rent from a person of a strange tribe ; a fair rent, frmn one of the tribe ; and the stipulated rent, which is paid equally by the tribe and the strange tribe." — Senchus Mor, quoted by Maine, Village Communities, p. 187. 52 LAND AND ITS EENT. tenant towards the value of tlie improvements he may have incorporated with the soil. Of course, neither of these assumptions is even supposed to correspond to the facts. They are made merely for convenience of reasoning and simplicity of illustration. Inasmuch as wanton malice, greed, or mere neglect, on the part of the tenant may impair, in a greater or smaller degree and more or less permanently, the fertility of land, it might readily happen that, contrary to the supposition made, the proprietor of land of the highest grade would prefer to have his land remain unoccupied rather than admit a distrusted ten- ant on a minimum rent. In this way the actual operation of the principle of self-interest might be made to differ in some degree from what we have described as the normal operation of that principle. Lands of this class might be held out of cultivation until the accumulating stress of the principle of "diminishing returns " upon the cultivators of the higher-grade lands led to the offer of a rent for these lands which, though low, could not yet properly be called a mini- mum rent (to be treated as nil), being substan- tial enough to constitute a sort of guarantee to the proprietor, or, to put it in another form, THE ECONOMIC DOCTEINE OF KENT. 53 being so far considerable as to make him think it worth while to take some risk regarding waste. On the other hand, the tenant is never likely to be so free to move to other land as is assumed in the economic doctrine of rent, inasmuch as the existence of " unexhausted improvements " wrought by him in the soil is likely to hold him in his place, with a greater or less degree of tenacity, inducing him to remain where he is, even though obtaining somewhat less annu- ally by present exertions than he might in another locality, rather than permanently sac- rifice the benefit of his improvements by a removal. I do not know that any other qualification of the Eicardian doctrine of rent, arising from the nature of the assumptions which underlie it, needs to be expressed in order to place us in a position to examine the views of recent writers regarding the actual influence of rent on the distribution of wealth. It will be observed that the degree of this influence must depend, primarily, on the lower limit of cultivation, what economists commonly call the margin of cultivation. If the range of 64 LAND AND ITS KENT. net productiveness between the soils actually under cultivation at the same time, for the supply of the same market, be narrow, no matter how great the average productiveness of the whole body of lands, the amount paid in rent will be small. As that range increases, even though the average net productiveness should decline, and decline greatly, the amount paid in rents would increase. Suppose six lots of land, of 1,000 acres each, supplying a given market, to produce, severally, 40, 39, 38, 37, 36, and 35 bushels per acre, the amount of rent realized therefrom, according to the formula of Eicardo, will be 15,000 bush- els, out of a total production of 225,000 bushels, or tV Now suppose that the same lots produce, severally, but 30, 28, 26, 24, 22, and 20 bushels. Here we should have an aggregate production of but 150,000 bushels, and yet the amount of -rent would rise to 30,000 bushels, reaching -| of the produce. If, again, we were to assume that the lots produced, severally, 30, 27, 24, 21, 18, and 15 bushels, we should find the aggre- gate product sinking to 135,000 bushels ; but of this not less than 45,000 bushels, or J the crop, would go as rent. THE ECONOMIC DOCTRINE OF RENT. 55 '' Eent is always," said Mr. Eicardo, " tlie difference between the produce obtained by the employment of two equal quantities of capital and labor. . . . "Whatever diminishes the inequality of produce obtained from successive portions of capital employed on the same or on new land, tends to lower rent ; and whatever increases that inequality necessarily produces an oppo- site effect and tends to raise it." The range tetween the higher and the lower limit of cultivation we see, therefore, is of prime importance in the discussion of the influence of rent upon the distribution of wealth, as it determines the actual amount of the produce which, under the Eicardian formula, will go into the hands of the landlord simply for the privilege of applying labor and capital to the land. Upon what we shall ascertain as to the ex- isting facts and the manifest tendencies of economical forces in this matter of the margin of cultivation, so called, will depend our decision whether M. Leroy-Beaulieu is right in declaring that rent has ceased to be of any importance in the distribution of wealth; or Mr. George is right in declaring that rent is a deadly evil. 56 LAND AND ITS KENT. which is every day drawing nearer and nearer to the vital organs of the State ; or, thirdly, whether both these gentlemen are not wrong, the one in unduly disparaging, the other in unduly magnifying, the importance of rent in the distribution of wealth, under modern eco- nomic conditions. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF EENT. 57 CHAPTEE II. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF EENT. I SHALL not attempt even to name all those writers who have, at one time or another, from one quarter or another, assailed the economic doctrine of rent, as it was stated and illustrated in the last chapter. I shall ask the reader's attention to the arguments of but three writers, M. Bastiat, Mr. Henry C. Carey, of our own country, and M. Leroy-Beaulieu, the present editor of the " Economiste Eranqais " and the successor of Michel Chevalier, as professor of political economy in the College de France. BASTIAT. It may be assumed that the reader is familiar with the essays and popular tracts of that in- genious and eloquent socio-economical writer, Frederic Bastiat. His argument against the accepted doctrine of rent will be found in 58 LAND AND ITS EENT. chapters viii. and ix. of his "Harmonies of Political Economy." Bastiat's argument against the doctrine of rent is supplemental to his attempted demon- stration of the proposition that, not the gifts of nature, such as are found in soil and climate, not even the high mental or muscular endow- ments of individuals, but human efforts, are the creative cause of value. Bastiat wrote especially in opposition to the communistic orators and pamphleteers of his day, that is, of the period of the Eevolution of 1848. He wrote with a strong political intention, and discussed economical principles always with a side glance at the existing social situation. Could he have satisfactorily demon- strated the proposition just stated, it is evi- dent he would have achieved an easy triumph over his antagonists. Wealth, the substance of which value is the attribute, would be found only in the hands of those who had created it ; than which what could be more reasonable and righteous ? But against the view that human effort is the sole and sufficient creative cause of value, Bastiat found arrayed not only the compact opinion of all economists of reputation, but also ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF EENT. 59 a great number and variety of familiar in- stances in which the possession of value is seen to be either irrespective of, or altogether out of proportion to, the human effort bestowed. Blocked thus in his attempted progress in this direction, Bastiat broke through a passage for himself, and secured at least a seeming^ and temporary triumph by introducing into the dis- cussion of value the equivocal word " service." ^ Now the word " service " may signify either personal exertions made in another's behalf, or acts, not necessarily onerous, by which another person is served or benefited. In other words, service may mean either the taking of 'pains by a person rendering the service, or the samng of pains to the person receiving the service. This equivocal word admirably suited Bas- tiat's controversial exigencies. It was easy enough to prove that value depended upon ser- vice, in the sense of saving pains to the person purchasing, because, clearly, no one would pur- chase an article unless pains were saved to him thereby, — that is, unless he obtained the article with less pains to himself, with less of effort and 1 On Bastiat's use of this word, Professor Cairnes has commented with great and not undeserved severity. See his Essay on Bastiat. 60 LAND AND ITS RENT. sacrifice, than would be necessary in producing it for himself. On the other hand, Bastiat, having thus established his proposition that value originates in service, and that the quan- tum of value is proportional to the quantum of service, turned about to his popular constitu- ency only to use this juggling word, " service," in the sense of the taking of pains by the person selling. If a man, he would ask, only gets for his product that which is proportioned to the exertions he has made, what more could be asked ? Who will challenge the equity of such an exchange ? It seems astonishing that a mere equiwque, like that which runs through Bastiat's whole theory of value, should have completely im- posed on American economists, one of the most meritorious of whom has written : "I had scarcely read a dozen pages in that remarkable book when, closing it and giving myself to an hour's reflection, the field of political economy, in all its outlines and landmarks, lay before my mind, just as it does to-day. . . . From that hour political economy has been to me a new science." And this author elsewhere at- tributes especial influence over his mind to Bastiat's views on Value and Land, on each of ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 61 which the witty, subtile, eloquent rrenchman was about as far wrong as it is possible for an eloquent, subtile, and witty Frenchman to be. At home, certainly, Bastiat never took rank as a constructive economist, though nowhere were the delicacy of the wit and the pungency of the satire with which he discussed many false and dangerous social and industrial theo- ries so fully appreciated or so highly relished as in his native country. But while, as a serious contribution to the theory of value, Bastiat' s conception of eco- nomic " services " — which, as we have said, in some places he defines as the saving of pains to the person receiving, as distinguished from the taking of pains by the person rendering, so that the term in this use becomes almost equiv- alent to the ordinary meaning of the word " demand " — is utterly without significance, it is perhaps even more surprising that his writ- ings on this theme should have had the slight- est degree even of present popular influence in quieting disaffection regarding the rights of property. For let it be conceded that value is exactly according to the " service " rendered, that is, the pains saved to the person receiv- ing the service, has not the proUtaire wit 62 LAND AND ITS EENT. enough, when that wit is quickened by the sense of wrong or the feeling of hardship, to ask, Ah ! but how comes it that this man is in a position to render me so easily a service which I must repay at so great a cost to me ? It is indeed true that the man who sells me anything renders me, in one sense, a service. I should not buy that thing unless I wanted it ; unless it were more useful to me than that I part with in exchange for it. That I buy of this person, and not of another, is a proof, or at least creates a strong presumption, that I buy at a lower price, or with a smaller ex- penditure of time and trouble in purchasing, or think I do so, than if I had bought of another. So far he has rendered me a service. Yet, if there is to be question respecting the equitableness of existing social arrangements, it is still possible, and reasonable as well, for me to go behind the situation, in which it is ad- mitted there is a fair and free exchange of equivalent " services," and inquire how it hap- pened that the two parties came severally into the positions in which that exchange finds them. A receiver of stolen goods sells me something that I stand greatly in need of, at a very low ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 63 price. Strictly as between liim and me, as trading persons, lie doubtless renders me a ser- vice, the full equivalent of the money I pay to him ; but as between society and him, and even between him and me as a member of society, there is an account still open that has to be adjusted. A highwayman points a pistol at my head, but offers to spare me if I shall give him $500, which I proceed to do with the greatest alacrity. In sparing my life he renders me the highest possible service, one for which I would gladly, were it needful, pay many times $500. Indeed, on no equal payment during my hfe do I so much felicitate myself. Still the question will arise, How came the highwayman to be in a position to do me such a vital service, and, after all, what right has he to what was my $500 ? In like manner, while the owner of land who at a certain rent leases to me a few acres on which I may work to raise food for myself and family, undoubtedly does me a great service, as compared with not giving me leave to cultivate it upon any terms whatever, it will still be ra- tional and pertinent for me to inquire, at least under my breath, what business he has with the land, more than I or any one else. Why 64 LAND AND ITS EENT. sliould I not have the whole produce of my ten-acre lot without deduction, although I freely confess that I would rather submit to the de- duction than not have it at all ; in other words, that a service, in Bastiat's sense, has been re- ceived by me. It will appear that while Bastiat uses the fact of service rendered as, of itself, sufficiently establishing the equitableness of property, the capability of rendering a service, in the ex- tended use which at times he gives to that term, may reside in a man by virtue of possessions most inequitably or even iniqui- tously obtained or retained. Yet Bastiat was so far satisfied with his demonstration of what seemed to him the perfect and indefeasible har- mony of property and justice, that, addressing the owners of property, he exclaims : " You have not intercepted the gifts of God. You have received them gratuitously, it is true, at the hands of nature; but you have also gratuitously transferred them to your brethren without receiving anything. They have also acted in the same way towards you ; and the only things which have been reciprocally com- pensated are physical and intellectual efforts, toils undergone, dangers braved, skill exercised, ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 65 privations submitted to, pains taken, services rendered and received;" and lie states, with especial emphasis and distinctness, the proposi- tion that "Every man enjoys gratuitously all the utilities furnished or created by nature, on condition of taking the trouble to appropriate them, or of returning an equivalent service to those who render him the service of taking that trouble for him." "Taking the trouble to appropriate them," is good. One can imagine the sardonic smile with which Mr. Jay Gould would receive and accept the congratulations of the eloquent optimist, upon the benefits he had conferred upon mankind by "taking the trouble to ap- propriate" the utilities furnished or created by nature to the extent of a cool hundred millions. I have said that M. Bastiat's argument against the economic doctrine of rent is sup- plemental to his attempted demonstration that all the gifts of nature, of every kind, are abso- lutely gratuitous. In dealing with the special case of landed property, he still relies upon the potency of the word " services " to establish the righteousness of the institution. " It is," he says, " rigorously exact to say that the proprietor of 5 66 LAND AND ITS KENT. land is, after all, the proprietor only of a value which he has created, of services which he has rendered ; and what property can be more legitimate ? It is property created at no one's expense, and neither intercepts nor taxes the gifts of God." The exceptional difficulty, however, of meet- ing manifest facts regarding the rent of land, and the universal consent of economists that there is, on all but the lowest grade of soils, an excess of produce, a clear surplus, above the cost of production, seemed to require of M. Bastiat that he should here make a distinct and special demonstration of his proposition con- cerning the relation of services to value. Con- sequently, we have, in the chapter on Landed Property, a laborious attempt to vindicate that species of property on the ground of natural right, in opposition to the view of nearly all publicists, founded on the current economic doctrine, that private property in land is a privilege conferring unearned advantages upon individuals, only to be justified by the public benefits resulting from the private cultivation and improvement of the soil. M. Bastiat enters upon his task with zeal and courage. He denounces the statement of ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF EENT. 67 Eicardo, McCuUocli, and Senior, of Say, Gamier, and Blanqui, that rent is paid for the use of the original and indestructible powers of the soil, declaring that if rent have this origin, then, indeed, in the language of Proudhon, property is robbery, — a dangerous admission in the land of Frenchmen ! M. Bastiat, however, entertains no doubt of his own competency to establish a wholly independent basis for rent, which shall make its payment consist with his glowing theory of the Mutuality of Services. The main argument of this chapter of the Economic Harmonies we shall meet hereafter, in better form, when reviewing Mr. Carey's discussion of the same subject It is directed to the demonstration of the proposition that the actual value of land does not exceed the accu- mulated labor that has been spent in giving it value ; the inference being that, therefore, noth- ing but labor can have entered to give land any portion of its value. We shall see how delusive is this mode of demonstration. What is especially noticeable in Bastiat's reasoning is that, in enumerating the forms of human effort which have given value to the land, he does not confine himself to the labors of indi- vidual proprietors upon their respective estates, 68 LAND AND ITS EENT. but is continually adducing the efforts of the community, what M. Leroy-Beaulieu calls " so- cial labor," that is, labor expended in building bridges and roads, labor expended in rearing towns for manufacture and trade which shall furnish a market for the produce of the farms, labor expended in promoting general interests and in preserving the public peace. Now, so far as it is the labor of the commu- nity, social labor, which has given value to the land, the individual proprietor is in possession of wealth which he has not created. That wealth, being in so far due to the exertions of the community, should, on M. Bastiat's princi- ple, be common to all. And thus the outcome of this labored defence of landed property on grounds of natural right is to exhibit the owner of land in the exclusive enjoyment of a value derived from the labor of others ! In a vain effort to avert this conclusion, M. Bastiat falls back upon an argument which may be cited to show the utter incompetence of this brilliant pamphleteer to deal with questions relating to land and its rent. " There is here," he says, " no injustice, no exception in favor of landed property. No species of labor, from that of the banker to ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 69 that of tlie (lay laborer, fails to exhibit the same phenomenon. No one fails to see his remuneration improved by the improvement of the society in which his work is carried on. This action and reaction of the prosperity of each upon the prosperity of all, and vice versa, is the very law of value. . . . The lawyer, the physician, the professor, the artist, the poet, receive a higher remuneration for an equal amount of labor, in proportion as the town or country in which they belong increases in wealth and prosperity." E'ow this is specious : it looks solid; but let us touch it witii a pin. M. Bastiat here represents the owner of the land as working on it, and deriving increased wealth with the increased prosperity and grow- ing numbers of the community ; as, for that matter, do the banker, the lawyer, and the phy- sician. Where, he asks, is the injustice of this ? But suppose the owner of land does not cultivate it. Suppose he is himself a banker, lawyer, or physician, and lets his land to be cultivated by others. Do we not find him, then, receiving two shares, instead of one, out of the general increase of wealth, — one, as banker, lawyer, or physician, through his en- hanced fees or profits ; the other, as landlord, 70 LAND AND ITS RENT. through the enhancement of the price of agri- cultural produce ? What right has he, on M. Bastiat's principles, as but one man, to more than one share ? But is it said, he receives the second share as the proprietor of the productive power of the labor of the past ; had he invested his means — saved by himself, or derived from some frugal ancestor — in other forms of wealth besides land, he would still, under the conditions as- sumed, receive an equal benefit from the gen- eral prosperity ? No, no ! that will not do. M. Bastiat, if, in his own judgment, he has demonstrated anything, has proven conclu- sively that the power of the labor of the past to purchase present labor is continuously on the declme. With great emphasis and much iteration he lays down the general proposition that '' one of the effects of progress is to di- minish the value of all existing instruments." Under this law, the reward or return to the landlord should, if it be true that land owes its value solely to capitahzed labor, continually decline. That it does not decline, is due to the fact established by Eicardo, that, on all but the lowest grade of soils, there is a surplus above the cost of cultivation, which, through ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF RENT. 71 the progress of society and the multiplication of the numbers of the community, tends to increase, and which, so far as economic forces alone are concerned, goes into the hands of the proprietor, as compensation for the use of the natural advantages of the land. But it is in his " Brother Jonathan " illus- tration, so often quoted or referred to, that we are made most painfully to realize this gifted writer's incapacity for dealing with questions relating to land. In this somewhat protracted study, he supposes Brother Jonathan, " a labo- rious water-carrier of JSTew York," to emigrate to Arkansas, where he buys land from the Gov- ernment at a dollar an acre. This price, how- ever, M. Bastiat tells us, as if anxious to shut himself off from any possible explanation of his subsequent misconceptions, represents only the value of the improvements which Grovern- ment has already made, of the security it is prepared to afford to occupants, and of the mail facilities it has provided. M. Bastiat proceeds to represent Brother Jonathan as taking his first crop to market and demanding for it something more than the recompense of his present and former labor, upon the express ground that "English and 72 LAND AND ITS EENT. Frencli economists had assured him " that, in the character of a proprietor of land, he was entitled to derive a profit from the productive and indestructible powers of the soil. But here he fails, the merchant declining to pay more than the cost of producing the crop. M. Bastiat next represents Brother Jona- than as negotiating with a would-be cultivator as to the rent of his farm. Again Brother Jonathan claims something for the use of his farm over and above the proper interest of the sum which would be necessary to bring another lot of Arkansas land into as good condition as his own, alleging that he is authorized to do so "according to the principles of Eicardo and Proudhon;" and again he meets with failure, the tenant offering him a rent which only cor- responds to interest at current rates, upon the capital actually invested in the soil. Still, a third time, M. Bastiat depicts Brother Jonathan, when trying not to lease but to sell his farm, encountering the disappointment of the expectations which had been inspired in him by the economists. " It is needless to say," goes the story, " that no one would give him more for it than it cost himself. In vain he cited Eicardo, and repre- ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTKINE OF RENT. 73 sented the inherent value of the indestructible powers of the soil. The answer always was, * There are other lands close by ; ' and these few words put an extinguisher on his exactions and his illusions." Now, can one readily believe that a writer so thoroughly honest in purpose as M. Bastiat could so egregiously misrepresent and misstate the doctrine he had chosen to combat ? It is of the very essence of the Eicardian law of rent that there is a body of no-rent lands which, by reason of their low fertility or their distance from market, only return the cost of cultivation, leaving no surplus ^ whatever to go i Adam Smith says : " The most desert moors in Norway and Scotland produce some sort of pasture for cattle, of which the milk and the increase are always more than suffi- cient, not only to maintain all the labor necessary for tend- ing them and to pay the ordinary profit to the farmer or owner of the herd or flock, but to afford some small rent to the landlord." Eicardo doubts this, believing that "in every country, from the rudest to the most refined, there is land of such a quality that it cannot yield a produce more than sufficiently valuable to replace the stock employed upon it, together with the profits ordinary and usual in that country." Eicardo is probably right, though the matter is of no consequence, any way, inasmuch as the rent of Scottish or Norwegian "desert moors" is so small, per acre, as to constitute the economical minimum. 74 LAND AND ITS EENT. to the proprietor of the land as rent. You can only make an intelligible statement of Eicardo's doctrine by starting with the existence of no- rent lands, since the Eicardian formula measures rent upwards from the no-rent line. Yet here M. Bastiat sends Brother Jonathan out to Arkansas, — a region which forty years ago stood in the relation to the markets of the world in which Montana and Idaho now stand, — a region where, by his own supposition, un- cultivated and unappropriated lands lie on every side ; and here, in this very position, on lands which are precisely the no-rent lands of the Eicardian formula, he makes Brother Jonathan claim a price for his produce above the cost of production, on the ground that the English and French economists have assured him that he is entitled to it on account of the original and indestructible properties of the soil. Again, he makes Brother Jonathan claim a rent above the interest of his investment, upon the author- ity of " Eicardo and Proudhon," and still again makes the Arkansas settler claim, for the same reason, a selling price in excess of the value of his improvements ; and all this, while the sim- ple, unmistakable fact is that, according to the doctrine which he is misrepresenting, the lands ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 75 in question bear neither rent nor price, aside from the condition of an actual investment of capital, and the produce raised thereon must be sold to repay only the cost of production. Such is M. Bastiat's contribution to the philosophy of land and its rent ! CAEEY. The economic doctrine of rent encountered a more formidable antagonist in Mr. Henry C. Carey, of Philadelphia, who in his work enti- tled ''Political Economy," published m 1837, attacked Eicardo with arguments which he sub- sequently elaborated in his work entitled " The Past, Present, and Future," published in 1848. I shall quote indiscriminately from Mr. Carey's two works, the only difference between the au- thor's views, as developed in the interval of the two publications, being, as stated by himself,^ that in 1837 he was convinced that the theory of Eicardo was "not universally true," while, at the later date, he felt assured that it was "universally false." Let us proceed to test the validity of argu- ments which lead to a conclusion so mo- mentous. 1 In the " Unity of Law." 76 LAND AND ITS RENT. Mr. Carey's first argument is founded on a "comparison of the cost and value of existing landed capital/' to use liis own phraseology; and will be found in the chapter of that title in his " Political Economy," and in his chapter, "Man and Land," in the work of 1848. "There is not," he asserts, "throughout the United States, a county, township, town, or city, that would sell for cost; or one whose rents are equal to the interest upon the labor and capital expended." ^ And he elsewhere draws what he regards as the logical inference from this alleged fact: "If we show that the land heretofore appropriated is not only not worth as much labor as it has cost to produce it in its present condition, but that it could not be reproduced by the labor that its present value would purchase, it will be obvious to the reader that its whole value is due to that which has been applied to its improvement." ^ Now, it appears to me that not only is this not "obvious," but that something very like an Irish bull is contained in this demonstration of a great " law " by which the harmony of all human interests is proposed to be established. 1 Past, Present, and Future, p. 60. 2 Political Economy, vol. i. p. 102. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 77 The trouble with Mr. Carey's argument is its superabundance of proof. The effect is much the same as that which sometimes results from the superabundance of powder in charging a gun. Had Mr. Carey been able to show that, in any case taken, a county, township, town, or city was worth exactly as much in labor as it had cost, the coincidence of amounts could at least have suggested, if it did not create a proper presumption to that effect, that the labor expended was the cause of the value ex- isting; but when Mr. Carey, with a view to proving his very important proposition, asserts that any farm and any collection of farms has cost more, often far more, than it is worth, he simply affords another instance of that "Vaulting ambition which o'erleaps itself, And falls on the other side." Suppose the present value of a piece of land to be represented by 100 units, while the value of the labor it has cost to " produce " the farms found thereon, is represented hf 125. Now, says Mr. Carey, inasmuch as the land is not worth more than 100, while the labor invested in it was worth 125, it is clear that nothing but the labor has entered to give value to the land ! 78 LAND AND ITS RENT. But how SO ? What has become of the 25 which was in excess of the 100 ? Lost, says Mr. Carey, since, " as labor is improved in its quality by the aid of improved instruments, all previously accumulated capital tends to fall below its cost, in labor." ^ Ah ! but if that 25 can be lost and has been lost, how can you show that another 25 has not been lost, and still another 25, through the operation of the same cause ? How can you prove that the 100 of the present value of the land is due, in any part whatever, to the 125 of the value of the labor in the past? John Smith's barn has been broken into, over night, by a burglar who sawed a hole through the door to effect his entrance. Mr. Henry Carey, in the interest of justice, appears next morning among the excited throng of neigh- bors, and produces a board taken from James Brown's woodshed, which, though not corre- sponding to the guilty hole in size or shape, is yet large enough, as he explains, to allow just such a piece "to be cut out of it, thus conclu- sively proving James Brown to have been the robber of John Smith's barn ! Mr. Eicardo, upon a statement of reasons 1 Political Economy, vol. 1. p. 35. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 79 which in their cogency and vigor exact an almost painful assent from every well-ordered mind, demonstrates that the value, at any time, of any piece of improved land is made up of two elements, — one representing, in capitalized form, the sum of its natural advantages, for pro- ductive purposes, over the least favored piece of land (whether less favored by reason of natural infertility, difficulty of cultivation, or distance) contributing to the supply of the same market at the same time; the other representing the present advantages, for productive purposes, acquired by the land in view, through applica- tions of labor and capital in the past. Mr. Carey, having established statistically, to his own satisfaction, that the value of the labor and capital so applied exceeds, even greatly exceeds, the present value of all culti- vated lands, deems that he has demonstrated that the first element of Eicardo cannot enter at all into the value of such lands. How, indeed, can it, when there is no room for it, when the subject is already full and more than fitlW^ 1 Let me reproduce Mr. Carey's words, already quoted : "There is not, throughout the United States, a county, township, town, or city that would sell for cost ; or one whose rents are equal to the interest upon the labor and capital expended." 80 LAND AND ITS EENT, More than full : all, there is the rub ! Noth- ing can be more than full, and if there is a surplus in the value of the labor and capi- tal applied to the land, above the present value of the land itself, it follows inevitably that some of that labor and capital have, so far as the present value of the land is concerned, been lost ; but if so much has been lost, why not more ? and if more, why may not Mr. Ei- cardo's first element enter, after all ? And this is the vaunted refutation of Eicar- do's law of rent ! An argument that breaks down thus, under the slightest strain of hostile pressure, cannot be worth further notice on its own account; yet we may find matter of not a little economi- cal interest in following out the question here raised, as to the relation between what Mr. Carey calls the cost of producing farms and the value of farms when " produced." 1st. To begin with, all the statements which are made regarding the amount so invested in any country or district are based on compara- tively little information. The statistical data are few and meagre, even for making estimates. Accomplished statisticians, long accustomed to ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 81 deal with computations relating to agriculture, like Mr. Frederick Purdy,. Mr. Eobert Giffen, Professor Thorold Kogers, or Sir James Caird, would scarcely presume to claim even approxi- mate accuracy for any estimates they might make regarding the amount of labor involved in bringing even a limited agricultural region into its present state of productiveness. 2d. Again, wholly in addition to the difficulty encountered in estimating the amount of labor involved in bringing a district to its present state of productiveness, would be the difficulty of computing the money value of that labor. While some great works of improvement are effected by bodies of hired laborers working through the year or through the agricultural season, most farm improvements are effected in the off season, when the wages of hired labor are very low, — perhaps only one half what they would be at another period of the year ; and probably the greater part are effected by the labor of the owner or occupier of the land and his family, in fragments of the day which would not otherwise be utilized, or in portions of the year when little or nothing of the current work of the farm can be done. Tn a word, much, very much, of the agri- 6 82 LAND AND ITS RENT. cultural improvements of a country like the United States, at least, represents no cost at all, in the sense that if the labor power exerted had not been expended in this way, it would not have been put to any economic use. 3d. It goes almost without saying that the element of interest can properly be introduced into such computations only in respect to a very small proportion of the agricultural in- vestments of capital. In general, where capital is applied to agri- culture, it is in the expectation of an immedi- ate improvement of the productive power of the land, the annual increase of the produce being relied upon to furnish, at least the annual interest upon the investment, so that, speaking broadly, in any comparison between the cost and the value of landed property, only the first cost of the improvements effected should be set against the ultimate value added thereby. There are cases, of course, where capital is applied to the land in the view alone of a dis- tant increase of value. Here, within moderate limits of time, the inclusion of interest in the computation is not unreasonable. But even here, and even within comparatively brief ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 83 periods, the application of the principle of geometric progression in the form of com- pound interest is of very doubtful propriety. Geometrical increase is rarely attained and never long maintained in things human. Con- templating an actual instance of geometrical increase within the field of industry, the most unreasonable expectation which can be formed concerning it, is that it will continue. That it should continue long, is not so much unlikely as impossible. Sir Archibald Alison, in his discussion of the British Sinking Fund, states that " a penny laid out at compound interest at the birth of our Saviour would in the year 1775 have amounted to a solid mass of gold eighteen hundred times the whole weight of the globe." So, doubtless, it might be shown that the value of Adam's first day's work in the Gar- den, properly compounded during six thousand years, would amount to more than the present value of all the lands of the world, and conse- quently that all the work that has been done since, in bringing the soil under cultivation, has merely been thrown away ! The incredibility of geometric increase through any considerable period of time can- 84 LAND AND ITS KENT. not be too strongly impressed upon the stu- dent of economics. The produce of a single acre of wheat, sown over and over, for four- teen years, would cover all the solid land on this planet. The spawn of certain fish would suffice in even fewer years, if reproduction went on in geometrical progression, to fill to the brim the basin of every pond, lake, river, sea, and ocean. Hence we see the utter inconsequence of computations relating to human afi'airs into which compound interest is allowed to enter, except in strict subordination to common- sense. Probably there is no way in which a man can so quickly and so conclusively show himself unfit to be listened to, as by appeal- ing to geometrical progression for the proof of an economical or social theory. 4th. But the consideration of greatest impor- tance in computing the cost of ''producing" farms is that, in general, agricultural improve- ments are compensated, and are expected to be compensated, in great measure, upon the prin- ciple of those annuities in which a certain number of annual payments both yield due in- terest on the purchase money and extinguish the capital itself, as when a man for $1,000 (on ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF RENT. 85 which the normal interest would be $50 or $60) purchases the right to receive $120 a year for a certain term, with no claim on the principal thereafter. Now, is this so, or is it not ? Let us satisfy our minds on this point ; for if the proposition just now stated is correct, it disposes effectu- ally of the argument against the economic doctrine of rent derived from the fact of ex- penditures in " producing " farms. That this proposition is correct is, I think, proved conclusively by the fact that there are few classes of improvements known to agricul- ture which a tenant for 33 years will not make at his own expense, notwithstanding the cer- tainty that he will cease to enjoy the benefit of them at the expiry of his lease. Even a very much shorter period of enjoyment, as 21 years, or, as so commonly in Scotland, 19 years, may give the tenant time enough to get back the value of the most expensive improvements, if judiciously made. Do not the several considerations adduced, and especially the last, take away all the force of this labored argument against the doctrine of rent ? Indeed, I must say that it appears to me 86 LAND AND ITS EENT. that the proper effect of the facts relating to the extent of land improvements in the past, instead of impairing the validity of the general body of orthodox economic doctrines, is really, when properly understood, to confirm them. Political economists have been wont to allege that two elements enter into the rental or the selling price of land, — one, rent proper, being compensation for the original and indestructi- ble properties of the soil ; the other, interest, being compensation for capital invested. Of these two, the economists have been wont to allege that the first, rent proper, tends to in- crease with the general advance of wealth and prosperity; the other, interest on landed improvements, like all forms of interest, tends to diminish under the same conditions. Now, of the two elements thus entering into nominal rents, one, we hiov:, is there, and we have something like a measure of its amount. If, of two fields equally near the market and equally accessible to cultivation, one will yield 30 bushels of wheat per acre to the same appli- cation of labor and capital which from the other will produce but 20, then there is a nor- mal rent of 10 bushels an acre for the more fertile as compared with the less fertile field ; ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 87 and any American would consider tlie proprie- tor as little better than a fool if, in leasing tlie former field, he did not get something near that amomit of rent for it. In the same way, if, of two equally fertile fields, each producing 30 bushels to the acre, one is situated close by the market, while the other lies at a distance so great that the cost of transportation consumes one third the produce, then, again, there will be a normal rent of 10 bushels per acre for the nearer as compared with the more distant field ; and any American would have his own opmion of a landlord who, in leasing such a field, should not get pretty nearly that price for the advantages of its location. In some degree, greater or less according to the character and uistitutions of the people concerned, law, or custom, or personal good feeling may enter to cause some portion of the normal rent of land to be remitted by landlord to tenant;^ but none the less truly is it a fact, constant, certain, inexpugnable, that real rent, strictly economic rent, does enter into the actual rent or selling price of land in every community where self- interest is even the general principle which governs human actions. 1 See pp. 48-51. 0« LAND AND ITS RENT. Now, as it is a fact beyond question or cavil, that rents, composed of these two elements, in one or another proportion, have increased greatly and almost steadily in nearly all civil- ized communities throughout the past seventy- five years, at the least, the more the cavillers at Eicardo's doctrine adduce to show the mag- nitude of the amounts of labor and capital which have been in the past expended upon land, the more, as it strikes me, do they afford corroboration of the view of the economists that it is the tendency of interest to fall with the general advance of wealth and prosperity. But Mr. Carey was not satisfied with one refutation of Eicardo's law. He attempted and, to the satisfaction of his disciples, achieved, a second demonstration of its falsity. That this subsidiary argument against the doctrine of rent should have been for a moment admitted ; that, indeed, it was not exploded at once amid general ridicule, — affords a striking proof of the weakness and vagueness with which economic questions, especially those affecting the land, have been discussed. It is a great pity, from the point of view of one who enjoys contro- versy, that Mr. Eicardo had not lived long ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF EENT. 89 enough to deal with this audacious assailant of his law of rent. A very pretty case of dissec- tion was lost through Mr. Eicardo's untimely death. I give Mr. Carey's argument in his own language. " It will," he says/ " be perceived that the whole system is based upon the assertion of the existence of a single fact, namely, that, in the commencement of cultivation, when population is small and land consequently abundant, the soils capable of yielding the largest return to any given quantity of labor alone are cultivated. "' That fact exists, or it does not. If it has no existence, the system falls to the ground. That it does not exist, that it never has existed in any country whatsoever, and that it is contrary to the nature of things that it should have existed, or can exist, we propose noiu to show. " We shall commence," he says, " our ex- amination with the United States. Their first settlement is recent ; and, the work being still in progress, we can readily trace the settler and mark his course of operation. If we find him invariably occupying the high and thin lands requiring little clearing and no drainage, those which can yield but a small return to labor, 1 Past, Present, and Future, p. 23. 90 LAND AND ITS EENT. and as invariably travelling down the hills and clearing and draining the lower and richer lands, as population and wealth increase, then will the theory we have offered be confirmed by practice, — American practice, at least. "If, however, we can thence follow him into Mexico and through South America, into Britain, and through France, Germany, Italy, Greece, and Egypt, into Asia and Australia, and show that such has been his invariable course of action, then may it be believed that when pop- ulation is small and land consequently abun- dant, the work of cultivation is, and always must be, commenced upon the poorer soils; that, with the growth of population and wealth, other soils, yielding a larger return to labor, are always brought into activity, with a con- stantly increasing return to the labor expended upon them." I will not say, with Koscher, that Mr. Carey's lengthy exposition is "rank with inexact sci- ence and unhistorical history." It does not matter a particle, so far as the validity of Eicardo's doctrine is concerned, whether Mr. Carey has correctly apprehended or grossly misapprehended the facts of human history, in the respect under consideration. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTPJNE OF EENT. 91 Let it be conceded that the order of settle- ment in all new countries is that which Mr. Carey has indicated, — the new-comers taking up light, dry, sandy soils, which will yield a quick return to the labor of the colonists, aided by their scanty capitals ; and that it is only when wealth has been in some measure accumulated, after the first severe struggle to maintam ex- istence, that deeper and richer, but cold and wet soils are opened, the forests cleared, the swamps, rich with the vegetable mould of cen- turies, dramed. What, pray, does all this prove, so far as the doctrme under consideration is concerned ? It is absolutely indifferent to the matter at issue. It is true that Eicardo assumed, for the pur- pose of illustrating his doctrine, that the soils first cultivated, within any considerable coun- try, were those most productive. It also ap- pears from the context, that Mr. Eicardo really supposed that this was the historical order of occupation. Yet the economic law of rent has reference alone to the lands under cultivation at the same time ; and would have precisely as much validity if everything which ]\Ir. Carey has contended for, regarding the actual order of settlement and cultivation, were conceded, 92 LAND AND ITS EENT. as if the hypothesis of Eicardo had been histori- cally accurate. Thus, let us revert for a moment to the illus- tration offered, in the preceding chapter, of the origin of rent. We there assumed the existence of four tracts of different degrees of fertility, with population so increasing as to send culti- vation down from the 24-bushel tract to the 22-bushel tract, thence down to the 20-bushel tract, and so on ; showing how rent emerged at the first descent of cultivation, and how rents were readjusted at every rise or fall of the margin, or, as I prefer to call it, the lower limit, of cultivation. But the operation of the principle of self-interest in dealing with the land would be precisely the same, if, instead of a community, small at first, growing slowly in numbers and thus coming to occupy the four tracts successively, we were to suppose that a tribe numerous enough to require the cultivation of all four tracts at once, were to move upon the land. It would still be true that any member of the tribe could as well afford to pay 6 bush- els rent for the 24-bushel tract as occupy a lot of the 18-bushel land for nothing, or cultivate a portion of the 22-bushel tract at a rent of 4 bushels. All the incidents we have described ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 93 would occur upon one hypothesis exactly as upon the other. But you will ask : Is it really possible that Mr. Carey could have made so great a blunder ? Is there not some mistake about this ? Are you fairly representing him ? I answer : I have represented Mr. Carey with perfect fairness ; have repeated his own words, and commented upon them in the very mean- ing which a hundred repetitions show that Mr. Carey intended they should bear. The fact is, while Mr. Carey claimed to have, by this argument, refuted Eicardo's law of rent, and while that claim has been echoed from every side by his admirers, what Mr. Carey is here attacking is not Eicardo's law of rent, at all, but a deduction, true or false, from Eicardo's law of rent taken in conjunction with Malthus's law of population. Mr. Malthus attempted to prove, positively, that mankind will increase, even to their own hurt. Mr. Eicardo showed, purely hypothetic cally, what must happen if by increase of popu- lation cultivation be driven down to inferior soils. Hereupon the economists, generally, who ac- cept the doctrines both of Eicardo and of Mai- 94 LAND AND ITS RENT. thus, have asserted that there is, in all com- munities, a practically irresistible tendency to an increase of population which will surely drive cultivation down to lower and still lower soils, with the result of a smaller and still smaller per capita product, yielding a scantier and still scantier subsistence to the members of the community. But this is not Eicardo's law of rent, which would hold true of a com- munity slowly diminishing in numbers from generation to generation (contrary to Malthus's law of population), and, by consequence, with- drawing, little by little, from the worst lands under cultivation, and thus increasing the per capita product. I have said that the complete establishment of Carey's historical order would not affect the validity of Eicardo's law of rent; and that, therefore, one might, for argument's sake, con- cede the accuracy of the narrative concerning the early settlement of Europe, Asia, and America, which occupies so large a portion of Mr. Carey's treatises, without surrendering even an outwork of the Eicardian doctrine. But while the historical order of settlement is thus of no consequence as affecting the eco- ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF EENT. 95 nomic law of rent, it must be admitted that very important economic consequences would follow the establishment of Mr. Carey's propo- sition that " the work of cultivation is and always must be commenced upon the poorer soils ; that, with the growth of population and wealth, other soils yielding a larger return to labor are always brought into activity ; " or, as he elsewhere expresses it, that the settler in- variaUy travels down the hills, clearing and draining the lower and richer lands, as popula- tion and wealth increase. l^Tow, as we are about to hold Mr. Carey accountable for this sweeping proposition, let there be no question that these expressions fairly represent the general drift of his argu- ment. Of this, no one familiar with his volumi- nous writings will entertain a doubt. Mr. Carey asserts not only the unreality, but the impossi- bihty, of the assumed fact that the increase of population sends cultivation down to inferior soils, in terms no less strong than these : It does not exist ; it never has existed in any country whatsoever ; it is contrary to the nature of things that it should have existed or can exist. What are the economic consequences which. 96 LAND AND ITS KENT. as we have said, would follow the establish- ment of Mr. Carey's proposition ? These : that, instead of the increase of population lowering the margin of cultivation, and thus enhancing the aggregate body of rents,^ it would be shown to have the effect, by stimulat- ing the cultivation of better lands, to throw out the poorer (the first cultivated soils), and thus to raise the lower limit of cultivation, and thus at once to diminish the share of the produce going as rent to the landlord, and to increase the average produce, per capita, of the com- munity. Eents will still be determined by the Ricardian formula ; but the importance of rent as a factor in the distribution of wealth will be diminished. In view of the importance of these conse- quences, let us proceed to examine Mr. Carey's sweeping assertions regarding the actual order of settlement and occupation, for the purposes of agriculture. Let us see whether this history be indeed historical or not. In the first place, we note that Mr. Carey's detailed accounts relate, in the main, either to the settlement and cultivation of countries in ages when military necessities were a con- 1 See pp. 53-55. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF EENT. 97 trolling force, or else to the very earliest stages of settlement and cultivation of the land, under circumstances which make the needs of im- mediate subsistence peculiarly urgent, as in the new States of the American Union, eighty, sixty, forty years ago. It would take more time than we have at command, even were the game worth the can- dle, to go through the history of the settlement of Britain, Italy, Greece, Germany, and other ancient countries, and attempt to analyze the influences which determined the selection of lands for habitation and cultivation. When we contrast the sites of nearly all ancient and mediseval cities, built upon the towering rock, with the utterly indefensible sites of our mod- ern cities, we can well understand that not economical but political and military exigencies may have given a strong preference to high and rugged ground, even for agriculture, in the days of almost universal warfare. The crops, in- deed, raised on such ground would neither be so ample, nor obtained with so little effort and sacrifice, as those which might have been raised in the fertile valleys below, but they would have been in a less degree subject to be swept away by the forays of armed bands. 7 98 LAND AND ITS RENT. Fortunately, we do not need to enter into an analysis involving so much time and labor, and perplexed by so many uncertainties regarding the facts with which we should have to deal. If the forces which in those days determined pop- ulation to high and poor soils were exclusively or even predominantly economic forces, we shall not fail to find them operating to control the occupation of new countries in these piping times of general peace. Let us then consider the course of settlement in the United States. Mr. Carey himself expresses his preference for investigation in this field. " Their first settle- ment," he says, "is recent, and, the work being still in progress, we can readily trace the settler, and mark his course of operation." ^ And, to further narrow the field, let us con- fine our view to the State of Ohio. This State is as favorable as any to Mr. Carey's theory. "The early settlers," he says, "of Ohio, In- diana, and Illinois uniformly selected the higher grounds, leaving the richer lands for their suc- cessors." 2 1 Past, Present, and Future, p. 24. 2 Past, Present, and Future, p. 32. Indeed, Ohio affords a much better opportunity for exhibiting the operation of economic forces than either of the other States named, inas- much as it is more generally wooded, has a greater diversity ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 99 Now let US take this case up and push it. If Mr. Carey has justly generalized the facts of the settlement of this great free State, he is entitled to much praise. The settlement of Ohio may be said to have been in progress all the time between 1802, when its inhabitants were fewer than 50,000, and 1832, when its population had reached 1,000,000 ; in progress in this sense, that not until the latter date had settlers found their way into every corner and county of the new State beyond the AUeghanies. Now let it be conceded that throughout this period Mr. Carey's statement regarding the course of occupation holds good, substantially. I say, substantially, because to justify the as- sertion that the settlers "uniformly" selected the higher grounds would require a vastly greater amount of particular and local knowl- edge regarding the territory of Ohio than any one man ever possessed. How much, then, would there be in this fact, admitted for the sake of argument, which should be in contravention of the economic doctrine of of surface, and a larger proportion of rocky ground, than either Indiana or Illinois, which are purely prairie States, of great uniformity of surface and of soil. 100 LAND AND ITS RENT. rent ? These early settlers of Ohio were, in the first instance, necessarily controlled in their " lo- cation " by considerations relating to the trans- portation of their products and to communication with the settlements they had left behind. Now, advantages of situation, as we have be- fore seen, enter just as fully into the net pro- ductiveness of any tract of land, according to Eicardo's doctrine, as advantages arising from superior fertility. Even in illustrating the ori- gin of rent, in our first chapter, we assumed the existence of a, very productive tract, situated at so great a distance that it would not be oc- cupied until cultivation had been driven to descend through several successive stages with- in the territory immediately surrounding the market. But, secondly, the early settlers of Ohio were largely compelled by the immediate exigencies of pioneer life to do something different from that which would have been the most economi- cal had they possessed an ample store of neces- saries and of the utensils and materials of industry. New-comers must needs do, not what they would, but what they can ; they must raise a quick crop, by little labor ; and it is natural enough that they should generally seek ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 101 the side-hill, which is self-drained, and the open country, which does not require clearing, and the thin, dry soil, which gives a speedy, though not a large return. They still seek that land which will be most productive under the circumstances in which they find themselves placed ; for, as Professor Johnston has well said, that which would be rich land for a rich man may be poor land for a poor man. But the question I wish now to raise is, whether, when the first exigencies of pioneer life were passed, when some store had been accumulated, when population had become sufficiently dense to allow a reasonable degree of co-operation in labor, when time had been afforded to lay out roads and bridges and to perfect the means of transportation, when the capabilities and resources of the land had be- come thoroughly known, — whether then it remained true that cultivators in Ohio neg- lected the best soils for those of an inferior quality ? If not, the fabric so laboriously reared for assaulting the stronghold of the economists tumbles to the ground, of its own weight. How much does it matter that the people of 102 LAND AND ITS EENT. Ohio, while they were first spreading loosely over the State, took up lands as Mr. Carey says they did, unless it can be proved, or at least a strong presumption can be established, that they continued to take up poorer soils, in preference to the best ? Mr. Carey asserts that the hypothetical order of settlement is " uni- versally false ; " that is, it is false as applied not to one but to all stages of the history of any community. As this matter is important, let us formulate it somewhat rigidly. Let us suppose the possibly cultivable lands of Ohio to form seven distinct grades, 1 to 7, 'No. 1 being the poorest, No. 7 the richest. Let us divide the economic life of Ohio, be- ginning in 1802 and ending — when? into seven generations, with continually increasing population. Now, unless Mr. Carey is grossly mistaken, generation No. 1, the first settlers, will take up lands No. 1, the poorest of all ; generation No. 2 will take up lands No. 2, the next to the poorest; generation No. 3 will take up lands No. 3, and so on. This, or something very like it, must take place, or Mr. Carey's " law " breaks down ; for should generation No. 3, say, have the pre- ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 103 sumption to take up lands No. 6, and genera- tion No. 4 be thereby encouraged to take up lands No. 1, why then generation No. 5 will perforce be compelled to take up lands No. 5, that is, lands poorer than those which had been brought m by the two generations preceding, while generation No. 6 will be driven to take up lands No. 4, far down on the scale of fer- tility ; and generation No. 7, the flower of civi- lization, will actually have to " decline upon " lands No. 3, which, according to Mr. Carey, generation No. 3 should, in conscience, have taken up. In other words, we should have cultivation driven down to inferior soils, a state of things respecting which Mr. Carey declares that it not only never has existed in any country whatsoever, but that it is contrary to the nature of things that it should have existed or can exist. In view of such possible results, what an appalling responsibility rests upon the people of any generation in the matter of not taking up any better land than they ought ! In the first place, think what a degree of virtue it requires, that they should deliberately deny themselves the enjoyment of the really best land around them, in order that the coming 104 LAND AND ITS RENT. generations, with increasing numbers, slionld have the privilege of first occupying these, as Mr. Carey says they must do ! Even more remarkable than this, think of the degree of intelligence that is required to point out to the men of any generation just the share of the lands of the State which Mr. Carey's theory will permit them to occupy, they being neces- sarily ignorant as to what the future popula- tion of the State is to be, or through how many generations or centuries the increase of popu- lation upon the territory is to be continued ! But let us return to Ohio. We have seen what is required to make Mr. Carey's " his- torical law " true. How far do the probabili- ties of the case favor the rigid application of that law throughout the settlement of this State ? We may believe that there were, in Ohio, in 1832, when the population was 1,000,000, about 4,000,000 acres of improved land in farms. By 1850, when the population had risen to 2,000,000, these 4,000,000 acres had.be- come 10,000,000. Did the addition thus made to the enclosed and improved lands of the State include a fair proportion of the best lands within its limits, or were the new lands, also, ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF KENT. 105 tliin, dry, sandy soils, only not quite so poor as those brought in between 1802 and 1832, — soils giving little root to grasses or to grain, but raising a small crop easily and quickly ? Unless the latter was the case, Mr. Carey's great historical law becomes little better than arrant nonsense. There is a popular belief throughout the Eastern States of this Union, that, in the eigh- teen years covered by this period, — 1832-50, — there was an immense amount of "clearing" done in Ohio; and the virtues of the "pio- neer's axe" have been celebrated in song and story. Is this all a mistake ? Or, if the peo- ple of Ohio really did cut down the prime- val timber over thousands of square miles, did they, as they ought, take pains to cut down only timber which grew over comparatively poor soils, so as not to interfere with the rights vested in unborn generations by Mr. Carey's "law"? Imagine Abraham Garfield, after reading Mr. Carey's " Political Economy," going into the woods, with his stalwart sons, axe on shoulder. He stoops down, gathers a sample of the soil, and after a patient examination rises with a sigh, and exclaims : " No, boys, it won't do for 106 LA.ND AND ITS RENT. US to cut down this bit of timber. The land underneath is too good for the like of us. The population of the county will not, you know, attain its maximum until 2184, and if we should, now that it is only the year of grace 1847, open this ground for cultivation, those who come after us might be obliged to resort to soils which would not be of as good a quality, and this Mr. Carey assures us can never be. So let us move on. We will strike into that lot across the ridge, where we know the soil is just thin and dry and mean enough for you and me." Between 1850 and 1880, again, the popula- tion of Ohio has increased to 3,000,000, and the number of acres of improved lands has risen to 18,000,000. Are the 8,000,000 acres improved for the first time during this period, all, or substantially all, of a quality next above those previously brought in, but still below the best ? Has this added territory embraced lands only a little less thin, a little less shal- low, a little less dry, than those occupied in 1850 ? Has this vast annexation still left the really good lands of the State uncultivated, only to be improved when the population shall reach 5,000,000 or 10,000,000 ? ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF KENT. 107 I do not care to contest Mr. Carey's theory that the first generation of settlers in any American State have spread themselves loosely over the soil, picking out the spots which offered the greatest facilities for the transportation of produce and for communication with the older settlements, perhaps giving a certain preference to naturally cleared, self-drained land. But that the second generation, in any American State, north of Mason and Dixon's line at least, have shrunk from the real problem of their economic life, have failed to grapple with the obstacles which withstood their acquisition of the richest resources of nature, have neglected to subdue the soil, the best soil they could find, with axe and spade, strenuously, manfully, with incessant toil, with unflinchinoj courage, T, for one, do not believe ; and Mr. Carey has not adduced a scintilla of evidence to prove a proposition so contrary to all we have ever learned of the character and life of the West- ern people. It would require a detailed local knowledge of at least 50,000 farms, including the time and manner in which every field therein came to be enclosed and cultivated, to establish such a proposition regarding the State of Ohio alone. In the absence of any such sta- 108 LAND AND ITS RENT. tistical demonstration, common fame and com- mon sense give the flattest contradiction to this monstrous hypothesis. With this we may leave Mr. Carey's argu- ment against the Eicardian doctrine of rent. The person who denies the truth of the Eicar- dian law in effect declares that men habitually rent highly fertile and comparatively infertile fields, rich corn lands and mountain pastures, at the same price ; that men habitually rent lands near a market at the same price with lands the most distant from the market. If he does not mean to assert this, he does not in the smallest degree traverse the path of Eicardo's majestic argument. If he does mean to assert this, he puts himself on the level of the person who should assert that men habitually sell 2 bushels or 10 bushels of wheat at one and the same price. In a word, Eicardo's doctrine can no more be impugned than the sun in heaven, and those who mouth at it simply show that they do not know what it was Eicardo taught. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF EENT. 109 LEROY-BEAULIEU. The latest attack on the economic doctrine of rent, that of M. Leroy-Beaulieu,i need not detain us long. I say, attack upon the economic doctrine of rent ; and yet M. Leroy-Beaulieu does not in terms attack that doctrine. Indeed, this distinguished economist and statistician is not capable of denying the theoretical truth of the doctrine of Eicardo. He admits that the fact of differences in natural advantages, whether of fertility or of situation, among the fields con- tributing to the supply of the market, must leave a surplus above the cost of production in the hands of the cultivators of all but the lowest grade of soils. M. Leroy-Beaulieu's attack upon the doc- trine of rent takes the form, not of questioning its theoretical validity, but of disparaging its present and prospective importance in the dis- tribution of wealth. Did M. Leroy-Beaulieu confine himself to a careful statistical measure- ment of that part of the rents actually paid by tenants to landlords which is due to the natural advantages of the soil, whether of climate or 1 La Repartition des Pdchesses. Paris, 1882. 110 LAND AND ITS RENT. location ; and were the effect of his investiga- tion merely to reduce somewhat, or even to reduce very considerably, the importance gen- erally assigned to rent proper as a factor in the distribution of wealth, — I should not presume to speak of him as making an attack upon the Eicardian doctrine. But inasmuch as M. Leroy- Beaulieu, while admittmg the theoretical valid- ity of that doctrine, carries his disparagement of its practical importance to such an extreme as to lead him to declare that rent — real economic rent — has ceased to have any significance in the modern distribution of wealth, having already sunk to an economical minimum, and is on the point of disappearing altogether, I conceive that we cannot regard his discussion of the subject as anything less, or anything other, than an attack upon the economic doctrine of rent. " Subjected," says this writer, " to an atten- tive examination, the doctrine of Eicardo ap- pears to us to have, to-day, almost no practical importance." ^ Elsewhere he says that, of the produce of the soil, it is only a parcelle infime ^ which goes to the proprietor. The English school of economists, he declares, have exagger- 1 La Repartition des Eicliesses, p. 103. 2 i^i(j^ p, 113, ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. Ill ated singidierement the pretended privilege of the rural proprietor; "to speak the 'truth, it is not even an exaggeration, hut a veritable trav- esty of facts." ^ For the support of his views regarding the narrowness of the influence exerted by rent upon the distribution of wealth, this writer relies chiefly upon the argument derived from what Mr. Carey calls the cost of producing farms. The French economist is not only much more moderate in his assertions than the American economist, whom he follows on this line, but he brings to the discussion a far higher degree of statistical ability, and draws upon a much wider range of statistical data. He does not, indeed, reach any such sweeping conclu- sion as that there is no township or parish the present value of whose lands would repay the labor which has been expended upon them ; yet, after a wide-reaching discussion of all the facts at his command, he issues with this result, that the enhancement of rents in England, France, and Belgium during the last seventy- five years — or, say, since the peace of 1815 — has not amounted to a sum greatly in excess of a fair interest return upon the expenditures 1 La Eepartition des Richesses, pp. 115, 116. 112 LAND AND ITS RENT. directed towards the improvement of the soil within the same period. Now, the force of this argument has already been sufficiently discussed while we were deal- ing with Mr. Carey's attack on Eicardo. I have sought to show that expenditures upon land are, in very large part, made in the expec- tation that they will be compensated by the increased yield of a comparatively short term of years. It might have been difficult to prove this, were the cultivator of the soil always the- proprietor ; but when we find by far the greater part of the lands of England, and no inconsid- erable part of those of France and Belgium, in the hands of tenants, and when we see that those tenants, holding under leases for 11, 19, 21, or possibly 33 years, as a maximum, freely make, in their own interest, nearly every class of improvements known to agriculture,^ we have what seems to me a sufficient refutation of the argument by which it is sought to disparage the importance of rent, — real economic rent, — the compensation that is paid for the natural 1 Even in cities, costly residences, stores, and warehouses are often built upon leased land, to go entire to the proprie- tor of the soil at the expiry of the lease, the tenant looking to secure his own interest by the profits of occupation during the brief interval. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTEINE OF RENT. 113 advantages of the soil, through magnifying the vokime of expenditures made for its im^Drove- ment. But M. Leroy-Beaulieu is not content with the indirect method of establishing the insig- nificance of rent, — the method, that is, which seeks to show that, of the two elements enter- ing into the compensation for the use of land, rent must be little because interest is so great. He undertakes to establish the same conclusion, directly and affirmatively, by showing that mod- ern facilities of transportation have reduced the tax or toll levied upon the aggregate pro- duce of the land in favor of the proprietor class, to the extent of practically extinguishing rent, — rent proper. His line of argument is this : Modern facili- ties of transportation have substituted, for the distinction between cultivated lands as more or less fertile, the distinction between cultivated lands as more or less remote from market. No community is now confined, in obtainmg its subsistence, to the lands surrounding it, as was formerly the case in a high degree. The Eo- mans and the Athenians, indeed, brought grain from the Black Sea, Egypt, and Africa; but they would have starved had they depended 8 114 LAND AND ITS EENT. for any essential part of their supply upon lands as distant as Australia or America. Any Englishman may now eat the wheat of Min- nesota or Dakota ; any German may, if Bis- marck will let him, eat the hams of Cincinnati or Chicacfo. Steam navis^ation has enabled the whole world to resort to the world's best soils, and eat of the produce thereof at the cost of raising it plus only the cost of transport, and this cost of transport is steadily diminishing under the force of invention and discovery. M. Leroy-Beaulieu's discussion of this sub- ject is very interesting, and, except as he deals with questions of degree, is sound and just. The principle he adduces is incontestable. In our statement and illustration of the origin of rent, we purposely placed one of the tracts dealt with at a great distance, and inquired as to the effects of successive reductions in the cost of transportation, not only upon the culti- vation of that tract itself, but upon the cultiva- tion of the home tracts, and upon the rentals they would severally bear. But when M. Leroy-Beauheu declares that the cost of transportation has already been reduced so low that rent has become nearly if not quite a genuine economic minimum, he ATTACKS UPOX THE DOCTEINE OF RENT. 115 utterly transcends the limits of toleration and deservedly forfeits the confidence of his reader. Fortunately we need no elaborate or extended argument to prove him hopelessly in the wrong. Turn we to England. Here we find a steady increase in the price of animal food throughout the last thirty or forty years, notwithstanding free trade and improved navigation ; that price " rising," as Sir James Caird states, " in a few years from fivepence to sevenpence, ninepence, and even a shilling, a pound." ^ Under any cii^cumstances. Sir James remarks, the English producer has the advantage of at least a penny, in the pound of live meat, arising from the cost and risk of transporta- tion, over his transatlantic competitor, an ad- vantage equal to £4 on an average ox.^ " Of this natural advantage nothing can deprive him ; and with this he may rest content." " Fresh meat from America," he continues, '' from the costly methods necessary to pre- serve it, will, on the produce of an acre, cost 1 The Landed Interest and tlie Price of Land, pp. 2, 3. 2 Mr. Alfred Pell states the average freight of live cattle from America at £7 per head. "I have heard," he writes, " that the price has since been reduced to £5. It was as high as £12 in the first instance, and they have carried cat- tle, I believe, as low as 50 shillings." 116 LAND AND ITS RENT. equal to 40 sliillings, for transport to tliis country." JsTow, 40 shillings an acre is equiv- alent to the average rent of land in England, — a rent with which, Sir James remarks, the British land-owner may well rest content. In regard to the cereal and other vegetable crops, the same high authority testifies that the cost of transporting from California, the Black Sea, or India, the chief sources of supply, a quan- tity of wheat equal to the produce of an acre, "is seldom less, and often more than 40 shil- lings. " ^ " Hay and straw," he adds, " are so bulky that they can only bear the cost of carriage from near Continental ports." Certainly this does not look like a statistical minimum. Forty shillings ($12) an acre is a very pretty rent, neither to be despised by the landlord nor to be neglected by the economist in dis- cussing the distribution of wealth. And if we inquire how the selling price of land has been affected by modern facilities for transport and intercommunication, we have this remarkable statement from tlje same writer, certainly the most capable agricultural observer 1 See, also, the address of Sir James Caird, as President of the Statistical Society, 1881, in the Journal of the So- ciety. % ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 117 in Great Britain, where since 1851 his authority has been undisputed, namely, that the capital wealth of the owners of landed property has been increased, in Great Britain and Ireland, by £331,000,000 in 20 years, "at a cost to them which probably has not exceeded £60,000,000." Here we have, according to this eminent economist, a net increase of the selling price of the lands of Great Britain and Ireland, after deduction of the cost of improvements, of not less than £270,000,000, or $1,350,000,000. It is true that during the five years since Sir James Caird wrote these words, the in- creasing severity of American competition ^ has very considerably reduced the rental value of the lands of the United Kingdom ; but there is no reason to suppose that this effect has proceeded far enough to neutralize the gain of the twenty years preceding, notwithstanding all those improvements in the means and agen- cies of transport and intercommunication upon which M. Leroy-Beaulieu dwells with so much emphasis and eloquence. I do npt know that I could give a better idea, in a single line, of the strained way in which M. Leroy-Beaulieu pursues his object of 1 See ante, pp. 23-26. 118 LAND AND ITS EENT. demonstrating that economic rent has ceased to be a factor in the distribution of wealth, than by saying that he seriously refers to the lamentable exx^eriences of Mr. Martin Chuzzle- wit, of the late firm of Chuzzlewit and Tapley, Architects and Land Surveyors, as an instance in point to prove the native valuelessness of land and the greatness of the pains and perils which attend its occupation and cultivation ! Many a hundred thousand of American agri- culturists, who, ten, fifteen, or twenty years ago, " went West," taking up government land un- der the Homestead Act, who, every year since, have lived with their families on the land, con- suming at least twice as much of animal and vegetable food as falls to the lot of the English, French, or German peasant, and whose lands are now worth, through the mere growth of the country, $10, $30, or $50 an acre, could reassure the philanthropic heart of M. Leroy- Beaulieu. In like manner, this really admirable econo- mist and statistician, turning his eyes upon Europe, disparages the natural advantages of the proprietor of the soil in that region by reference to the pests and plagues which beset the vuie, the growing wheat, the fruiting tree. ATTACKS UPON THE DOCTRINE OF RENT. 119 After dwelling with profound commiseration upon the ravages of the infamous phylloxera, the malignant rotrytis mfestans, and the al- together pernicious doriphera, he exclaims, with what some might mistake for bathos : " Were Eicardo to return to earth, would he, in the presence of these evils which afflict the agricul- ture of the elder communities, still hisist that the proprietor of land is a privileged being, the favorite of civilization, who sees his own profits continually increase without his efforts, and who gathers the larger share of the fruits of social progress." ^ If I might venture to reply for Mr. Eicardo, in his absence, I would say : Were that very clear-sighted and hard-headed person to revisit the glimpses of the moon, and take a survey of modern industrial society, it is probable that, in view of the fact that fair wheat lands are worth $300 in England, $50 in Illinois, and $5 in Dakota, he would still be disposed to hold that the possession of land near the cen- tres of civilization and the marts of trade, if not v/holly without drawbacks, is, on the whole, phylloxera, doriphera, and rotrytis infestans to the contrary notwithstanding, a decidedly 1 La Eepartition des Eicliesses, p. 102. 120 LAND AND ITS RENT. good thing. With M. Leroy-Beaulieu's vatici- nations respecting the advances to be hereafter made in the arts and agencies of transportation, we are not called to concern ourselves. All this may come to pass, and, with Keeley Motor stock at par, rents may sink to zero. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 121 CHAPTER III. RECENT ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. As stated in the opening chapter, I shall not, in this connection, take note of works which attack property in general, but shall confine myself to those writers who admit property in the products of labor, of which they deem the individual appropriation of land to be an invasion. MILL. The later essays and speeches of Mr. Stuart Mill, dealing with the land, are well known to students of economics. In 1870 Mr. Mill became President of the Land Tenure Reform Association. As its title indicates, and as its published programme announced, the purpose of the As- sociation was to secure a reform, and not the abolition, of landed property ; but inasmuch 122 LAND AND ITS EENT. as tlie reform which the Association deemed imperative cut off so much of the incidents of ownership as fairly to raise the question whether enough would be left to make owner- ship itself thereafter desirable, and, indeed, whether the result would not be to bring the greater part of the land into the hands of the State as owner, through the relinquishment of the land by its former owners, upon the terms contained in the programme of the Associa- tion, this movement is fairly to be ranked among the Attacks upon Landed Property made in our day. Although, as a measure of so-called reform, Mr. Mill took up this question so late in life^ all the principles, whether of economics or of political equity, to which he appealed at this period, are distinctly laid down in his work of 1848. " The essential principle of property being to assure to all persons what they have pro- duced by their labor and accumulated by their abstinence, this principle cannot apply to what is not the produce of labor, the raw material of the earth. If the land derived its produc- tive power wholly from nature and not at all from industry, or if there were any means of ATTACKS UPON LANDED PEOPEETY. 123 discriminating what is derived from each source, it not only would not be necessary, but it would be the height of injustice, to let the gift of nature be engrossed by a few. . . . "But, though land is not the produce of industry, most of its valuable qualities are so. Labor is not only requisite for using, but almost equally so for fashioning, the instru- ment. In many cases, even when cleared, its productiveness is wholly the effect of labor and art. . . . " These are the reasons which form the justi- fication, in an economical point of view, of property in land. It is seen that they are only valid in so far as the proprietor of land is its improver. . . . " When the sacredness of property is talked of, it should always be remembered that this sacredness does not belong in the same degree to landed property. No* man made the land. It is the original inheritance of the whole species. Public reasons exist for its being ap- propriated. But if those reasons lost their force, the thing would be unjust. . . . " Landed property is felt, even by those most tenacious of its rights, to be a different thing from other property ; and where the bulk of the 124 LAND AND ITS EENT. community have been disinlierited of tlieir share of it, and it has become the exclusive attribute of a small minority, men have generally tried to reconcile it, at least in theory, to their sense of justice, by endeavoring to attach duties to it, and erecting it into a sort of magistracy, either moral or legal. But if the State is at liberty to treat the possessors of land as public functionaries, it is only going one step further to say that it is at liberty to discard them. The claim of the land-owners to the land is altogether subordinate to the general policy of the State. The principle of property gives them no right to the land, but only a right to compensation for whatever portion of their in- terest in land it may be the policy of the State to deprive them of. To that their claim is in- defeasible!' In 1870, as stated, Mr. Mill had so far ad- vanced in his views regarding the private own- ership of land, that he became President of the Land Tenure Eeform Association, one " of whose proposed objects was : " To claim for the benefit of the State the Interception by Taxation of the Future Unearned Increase of the Eent of Land (so far as the same can be ascertained), or a great part of that increase, ATTACKS UPON LANDED PEOPERTY. 125 which is continually taking place, without any effort or outlay by the proprietors, merely through the growth of population and wealth ; reserving to owners the option of relinquish- ing their property to the State at the market value which it may have acquired at the time when this principle may be adopted by the Legislature." This project was advocated by Mr. Mill in arguments of which the following paragraphs contain the essence : — " There are some things, which, if allowed to be articles of commerce at all, cannot be pre- vented from being monopolized articles. On all such the State has an acknowledged right to limit the profits. . . . Now, land is one of these natural monopolies. The demand for it in every prosperous country is constantly rising, while the land itself is susceptible of but little increase. All such articles, when indispensa- ble to human existence, tend irresistibly to rise in price, with the progress of wealth and popu- lation. The rise of the value of land and of the incomes of land-owners during the present century has been enormous. Part of it, un- doubtedly, has been due to agricultural improve- ments and the expenditure of capital on the 126 LAND AND ITS KENT. soil. Mucli of it, however, is merely tlie result of the increased demand for agricultural pro- ducts and for building land, and would have taken place even though no money had been laid out in increasing the productive powers of the soil. Such outlay, moreover, as there has been, was made, in a great proportion of cases, not by the landlord, but by the tenant,^ who may or may not have been indemnified by a temporary enjoyment of the profits ; but, sooner or later, the increased return produced by the tenant's capital, has become an unearned addi- tion to the income of the landlord. " The Society are of opinion that, in allowing the land to become private property, the State ought to have reserved to itself this accession of income; and that lapse of time does not extinguish this right, whatever claim to com- pensation it may establish in favor of the land- owners. . . . " The Society do not propose to disturb the land-owners in their past acquisitions ; but they assert the right of the State to all such accessions in the future. "Whatever value the land may have ac- quired at the time when the principle they 1 See ante, pp. 84, 85. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPEETY. 127 contend for sliall obtain the assent of Parlia- ment, tliey do not propose to interfere with. If, rather than submit to be specially taxed on the future increase of his rent, the land-owner prefer to relinquish his land to the State, the Society are willing that the State should pay for it at its selling value. "In this manner, that increase of wealth which now flows into the coffers of private persons from the mere progress of society, and not from their own merits or sacrifices, will be gradually, and in an increasing proportion, diverted from them to the nation as a whole, from whose collective exertions and sacrifices it really proceeds." For the carrying out of this scheme, Mr. Mill says: "A valuation of all the land in the country would be made in the first instance, and a registration estab- lished of subsequent improvements made by the landlord." Looking at this statement of principles in the light of our previous discussions, what do we find here asserted ? 1st. There is the fullest recognition of Ei- cardo's law of rent. It is asserted, in direct contradiction of Messrs. Carey and Bastiat, that the rental or sellmg price of land, in general, 128 LAND AND ITS RENT. consists of two elements, — one being the own- er's compensation for tlie capital invested in improvements, whether above or below the sur- face; the other being a remuneration exacted for the use of a natural agent of production, the inherent properties of the soil. 2d. It is asserted that the actual amount of wealth, if not the share of the aggregate pro- duct of land, labor, and capital, thus going, as economic rent, to the landlord, is not only of enormous importance in the existing state of society, but tends strongly to increase with increase of wealth and population. This view of the present and prospective consequence of rent, in the distribution of wealth, which differs toto cmlo from that of M. Leroy-Beaulieu, leads Mr. Mill to inquire into the nature of the claim of the land-owner, with the result which we have read. That individual ownership of land is of com- paratively recent institution, the soil having formerly been deemed the common possession of cultivating communities, held together by a real or constructive tie of kinship ; that, even when the private ownership of land was insti- tuted, rights of property were coupled with political and military duties and fiscal obliga- ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. . 129 tions, which constituted no inconsiderable com- pensation to the comumnity for the loss of its interest in the land ; and, finally, that these political and mihtary duties and fiscal obliga- tions have been thrown off by the land-owning class, through the exertion of their superior power and influence in the formation of public policies and in the enactment of laws, with- out any adequate commutation thereof, — these things appear to me too well established to admit of question. From the point of view of political equity, I know of no answer which can successfully be made to Mr. Mill's argu- ment. In my judgment it stands, on that side, inexpugnable. It is from the point of view, however, of political expediency — using that term in its largest sense, to include consideration of the economic effects of the proposed change — that the programme of the Land Tenure Keform Association must be approved or condemned. Mr. Mill himself, in his work of 1848, pro- fessed, as in the paragraphs which have been quoted, amenability to this rule ; nor do I un- derstand him as seeking, in his later publica- tions on the land question, to escape therefrom. On the contrary, while the primal motive of 9 130 LAND AND ITS RENT. the proposed reform is to secure a more equi- table apportionment of the products of land, capital, and labor, he argues not only that the change will, in the first instance, bring no shock to production, but that, instead of dimin- ishing in any direction the impulse towards the creation of values, it will, in its ultimate re- sult, secure a more harmonious distribution, a wiser consumption, and by consequence, in the next economic generation, an increased produc- tion of wealth. What, then, should be said of Mr. Mill's proposition, as a scheme of practical reform ? In the first place, we note that, in saving the rights of existing property-holders, Mr. Mill, in common honesty, relinquishes the claim of the community upon all that increase in the rental or selling price of land which shall have accompanied the increase of population and the development of industry, up to the time when the scheme shall be definitely adopted by legal authority. Of all the probable mischief attrib- utable to what Mr. Mill regards as an ill-advised surrender of land to individuals, a large part possibly, not improbably the larger part, has already been irreparably done. It is, then. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 131 only to future increase in the value of land that this scheme would apply. Such a limita- tion of its scope would not only greatly reduce the benefits to be derived by the State, benefits for the sake of which great perils are to be risked, but would wholly deprive the scheme of all significance whatever, for good at least, in many communities where rent has already reached its maximum and tends rather to de- cline than to increase, under the severity of competition from newer or more fortunate lands. But, secondly, governments could not under this scheme realize by any means the whole even of the future mcrease of rents. This is admitted by Mr. Mill, in his defence of the programme of the Land Tenure Eeform Associa- tion. " A large margin," he says, " should be allowed for possible miscalculation." Yet such an allowance would by just so much dimmish the inducement for the State to assert its rights to the lands now held by individuals. And that this margin must, as Mr. Mill says, be large, that it must be very large indeed, I think we shall see, if we take into consid- eration the difficulties which attend the valua- tion of improvements effected in the soil. I 132 LAND AND ITS EENT. endeavored in the last chapter to convey an impression of the difficulties attending this val- uation. ^ Here we have Mr. Carey declaring that there is not a county, a township, a town, or a city in the United States of his day, which was worth what it had cost to produce it. Here we have a statistician of eminence, like M. Leroy-Beaulieu, prepared to prove that the present rental of land in England, France, or Belgium constitutes no more than a fair interest on the investment made by the owners. I trust I showed to the reader's satisfaction that a mistaken principle underlies all compu- tations of " the cost of producing farms ; " and that many, if not most, agricultural improve- ments are made in the expectation of an in- crease of the produce, the enjoyment of which for a term of years, greater or less, answers both for interest on the investment and for the principal of the investment itself ; but how improvements should be classified for this pur- pose, what should be the term of years for any one class of investments, how the first cost should be computed, how the State should check and prove the owner's accounts of work 1 See ante,, pp. 80-82. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 133 done, how secure that the work charged should be real, effective work, such as would be given to the plantmg and harvestmg of the annual crop, of which the State would take no account, — it must appear, on the first suggestion, that these questions would involve infinite perplex- ity,^ with one of two results certain to ensue : either, with just and fair-minded assessors, the State would, in the readjustment of values for the purposes of Mr. Mill's scheme, lose every time and at every point, since the assessors could not know the facts upon which to base a confident decision, while the owner would be in a position to represent the circumstances in such a way as always to leave a balance in his own favor ; or else, with assessors not anx- iously desirous to do right, perhaps even dis- posed to assert the interests of the State to extremity, owners would, in great numbers, avail themselves of their right to rehnquish their lands to the State, at its first registered valuation, with consequences which we shall consider hereafter. 3d. But we have not yet enumerated all 1 On the difficulty of distinguishing and classifying agri- cultural improvements, see Mr. Newmarch's paper, in the Journal of the Statistical Society, for 1871, p. 488. 134 LAND AND ITS RENT. the difficulties which would attend the exe- cution of this system of "Nationalizing the Land." Were every change of value in land, through- out the most extensive community, certain to be in the direction of a rise, some estates rising perhaps rapidly, others slowly, and oth- ers not at all, but none losing any part of their present value with the lapse of time, all the perplexities we have indicated would be en- countered by the State in asserting for itself the benefits of the "unearned increment of land." But a further and a still greater difficulty would stand in the way of this scheme, namely, the fact of declining values in landed property. That the amount going to the owner of the soil in rent has, taking all progressive countries together, risen greatly through the past gener- ation, the past century, the past three centu- ries, or five, seems too clear to require proof. That it is still rising, I believe, in spite of M. Leroy-Beaulieu's attempted disproof. That it is likely, most likely, to rise through a con- siderable future, though no one can conjecture how fast or how far, I entertain no doubt. But this general rise of rents has always been in ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 135 tlie past, and is morally certain to be in tlie future, accompanied by the phenomenon of values falling over considerable areas. This is seen on every hand, even throughout flour- ishing communities. Now it is evident, beyond challenge or ques- tion by any honest man, that in a readjustment of the relations of land, made primarily to meet the demands of political equity, the State, if it will claim the benefit of all gain resulting from general causes affecting the numbers and pro- ductive power of the community, and thus due neither to the merits nor to the sacrifices of own- ers, is bound to make good all losses resulting from a decline of demand due to causes which are of a general nature, and are thus attributable to no fault or neglect on the part of owners. If he who remains, in name, the proprietor of land is not to be allowed to reap any gain not brought about by his own exertions, he has a good claim to be saved harmless from loss which no effort of his could have averted. Heads, I win ; tails, you lose, is no fair game ; it is not a game at which the State can in safety or decency play with its own citizens. 4th. And now we have to note still another source of loss to the State in its effort to re- 136 LAND AND ITS EENT. sume the virtual owersliip of land, namely, that, in appraising the losses to owners occur- ring in the case of depreciating property, the State would be bound to allow " a large mar- gin for miscalculation," corresponding to that adopted in the valuation of property rising in value. This would constitute another deduc- tion from the theoretical advantages of this project. Whether, after the State had indemnified all owners of depreciating property, after it had conceded all the deductions which might be necessary to prevent large bodies of land from coming upon its hands, at the official valuation, there would be enough left, as a source of rev- enue, to make it worth while to undertake a measure so revolutionary and perilous in its nature, may well be doubted. That, in the event the public interest in the matter of landed property were to be asserted in such a way as to bring large numbers of estates into the hands of public officials, the treasury paying the owners therefor the original registered valuation, the State could so manage such properties, either by occupation, by rental, or by sale, as to get its money back, even with- out interest, even after much delay and great ATTACKS UPON LANDED PIIOPERTY. 137 fiscal embarrassment, what man, who knows anything of the history of State property, beheves ? Professor Emile de Laveleye has indeed, in this connection, referred to the experience of the early Village Communities of Europe as proof that successful cultivation without abuse of the soil is possible under collective ownership. But consider the vast differences in the conditions ! The agriculture of those days was wonderfully simple and rude. The communities were small, highly localized, thor- oughly integrated bodies. Each man cultivated his temporary allotment under the eyes of his real or constructive kinsmen, subject to their daily and hourly criticism and control. Any- thing like abuse of the soil or neglect of the punctilious prescriptions relating to the enjoy- ment of the common property was a direct inva- sion of the rights of every other member of the community, who was in a position to know it and to resent it. Could the five hundred thou- sand residents of Manchester, the five million residents of London, exert any corresponding control of their individual interests in the farms of Kent, Hampshire, Lincoln, and the Lothians ? When, as by Mr. Mill's scheme, you make the 138 LAND AND ITS RENT. unit of possession, not a village or a parish, but a nation ; when the actual cultivators be- come but a fraction of the community, the remaining members knowing little and caring less about the cultivation of the soil; when, instead of a population spread evenly over the land, you gather half the subjects of the realm into cities and towns ; when, moreover, the crops cultivated become numerous, and the methods of cultivation infinitely various and complicated, — then the conditions which made the occupation of the soil in common even tol- erable disappear. Indeed, Sir Henry Maine has shown reason for believing that, even with the simple agriculture of those early days, even under the very limited demands then made upon the soil, the organization of society into village communities was ineffective for produc- tive purposes ; and that it was from its lack of adaptation to the wants of an increasing popu- lation, that it was replaced by autocratically governed manorial groups of cultivators. The objection to common ownership of land, which arises from the liability to abuse and waste, disappears, of course, when building-lands and town sites are brought under considera- tion ; and so greatly is the problem simplified ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPEETY. 139 that Dr. Adolpli Wagner, the illustrious Profes- sor of Political Economy in the University of Berlin, has proposed that the municipalities should purchase all town property ,i in order to realize therefrom the progressive increase of values. I shall, however, assume that the disadvan- tages of the State or of a municipality turning itself into a great real-estate company will be sufficiently obvious not to require any extended discussion. Think what the civil service of a city like Boston, a State like Massachusetts, a nation like the United States, would become, if, instead of an annual pay-roll of a half mil- lion, or two millions, or thirty milhons, the control and manipulation of income to the amount of tens or hundreds of millions, of wealth to the amount of hundreds or thousands of millions, were to become the object of politi- cal intrigue, the spoil of political victory ! 1 It is perhaps worth noting, that Professor Wagner's scheme, if practicable, would fail to satisfy all the equities of the case, since the growth of towns and cities is largely due to the "exertions and sacrifices" of the rural communities by which they are surrounded, and which would have a strong claim to be admitted to a participation in the "un- earned increment of land" situated in the towns and cities to which they thus contribute. 140 LAND AND ITS EENT. The beginning of our national career found us in possession of a vast public domain, on which our earlier financiers looked as an important fiscal resource. A wiser policy, however, pre- vailed ; and although that original domain has been multiplied fourfold as the result of war or purchase, it has been almost as rapidly re- duced by alienations, all wise and patriotic statesmen agreeing, with almost perfect una- nimity, that no fiscal advantage that might accrue from holding the public lands as a source of revenue could be weighed against the interests to be secured by those lands becommg the individual property of actual cultivators. That a nation which deliberately adopted the policy of selling at a minimum price, and even of giving away to actual settlers, the lands which were already unqualifiedly public prop- erty, and which has never hesitated for a mo- ment in the pursuit of this policy, men of all classes and all parties agreeing thereto with sub- stantial unanimity, should undertake a scheme that at least borders upon confiscation, for the purpose of bringing under the control of the treasury lands which had become a private possession before the nation had an existence, ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 141 is SO -unlikely that we need not waste time in arraying arguments against tlie proposition. GEORGE. We come now to the work of Mr. Henry George, entitled "Progress and Poverty," to which allusion was made in our opening chapter. Mr. George's attack upon Landed Property is twofold, — from the side of natural rights, and from the side of the economic interests of society. Let those who feel competent to the task answer Mr. George's eloquent plea in behalf of the natural and inalienable right of all indi- vidual members of the human race indiscrimi- nately to enter and enjoy at will each and every lot and parcel of land upon the globe, and every building which may have been or may hereafter be erected thereupon. ^ I profess no qualifications for the work, never having lived in a state of nature myself, but having 1 " There is on earth no power which can rightfully make a grant of exclusive ownership in land. . . . Let the parch- ments be ever so many, or possession ever so long, natural jus- tice can recognize no right in one man to the possession and enjoyment of land, that is not equally the right of all his fellows." — Progress and Poverty. 142 LAND AND ITS KENT. resided all my life in communities more or less civilized. In my humble judgment, only con- siderations of political expediency or of politi- cal equity are pertinent to discussions relating to the arrangements of human society. I shall therefore, venture to apply to Mr. George's assertions and proposals regarding the occupa- tion of the land purely economic tests, just as if all this fine talk about the rights of man ^ had been left out of his book. And this sub- jection of the question of the ownership of land to economic principles is, after all, not something to which Mr. George can consistently make objection : for he claims to write as an economist; he professes to be able to give a strictly economic reason for the faith that is in him ; he founds his system upon the economic doctrine of rent, as he understands it ; and he is severe upon writers who have preceded him, on 1 " Though his titles have been acquiesced in by genera- tion after generation, to the landed estates of the Duke of "Westminster the poorest child that is born in London to- day has just as much right as has his eldest son. Though the sovereign people of the State of New York consent to the landed possessions of the Astors, the puniest infant that comes wailing into the world, in the squalidest room of the most miserable tenement house, becomes at that moment seized of an equal right with the millionnaires. " — Progress and Poverty. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 143 account of their slips and lapses in the appli- cation of economic principles. First and fore- most, Mr. George is, if he knows himself, an economist. Let us, then, proceed to consider " Progress and Poverty," on this side. In the first place, it will not be needful ^ to enter into the arguments by which Mr. George seeks to establish the proposition that " wages are produced by the labor for which they are paid." Were this proposition false, we could 1 Neither needful nor desirable. Nearly all of Mr. George's assailants have wasted their strength and breath in attacking the proposition expressed in the text, or in discussing the arguments Mr. George puts forward in refutation of the Mal- thusian doctrine of population. Witness the labored arti- cles in the January number of the Edinburgh and of the Quarterly Eeview. The fact is, neither Mr. George's view regarding the origin of wages nor his anti-Malthusianism is, in the slightest degree, of the essence of his doctrine. By placing these in his front, and procuring his enemies to assault them, Mr. George has evaded a direct attack upon his vital point, namely, his position regarding the impor- tance of rent as a factor in the distribution of wealth. To reach this it is not necessary to cross the quagmire into which Mr. George has drawn his heedless assailants, who have been completely " blown " before they reached the posi- tion upon which alone his system stands. Any one who will avoid this error may raid Mr. George's camp to his heart's content. 144 LAND AND ITS RENT. concede him all the benefit to be derived from its use, and still disprove the main positions of his book ; but the proposition that " wages are produced by the labor for which they are paid," contains much truth, although the author's attempts to disparage the importance of the contributions to current production made by capital accumulated in the past involve a fear- ful straining of economic facts and economic conditions.^ So far, however, as this proposi- tion contains any truth, it is not, in the least degree, original with Mr. George. Professor Stanley Jevons in 1871 announced the doctrine that ''the wages of a working man are ulti- mately coincident with what he produces, after the deduction of rent, taxes, and the interest of 1 As, for example, when in treating the function of cap- ital in production, he says, "Accumulated wealth seems to play just about such a part in relation to the social organ- ism as accumulated nutriment does to the physical organism," and adds, in illustration, "Some accumulated wealth is nec- essary, and to a certain extent it may be drawn upon in exigencies ; but the wealth produced by past generations can no more account for the consumption of the present, than the dinners he ate last year can supply a man with present strength.'' This work abounds in statements of an equal degree of extravagance, and doubtless herein lies the secret of the attraction it exerts upon ill- balanced minds. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 145 capital," while in my own work of 1876 it was said that " wages are, in any philosophical view of the subject, paid out of the product of present industry, and hence production fur- nishes the true measure of wages." ^ Nor is it necessary to take time, as many of Mr. George's critics have done, for a discussion of Mr. George's attempted refutation of Mal- thus's doctrine of population. Here, again, we might concede to this writer all he claims, true or false, without giving him ground on which to establish the subsequent truly monstrous propositions of his book. There is absolutely nothing original in Mr. George's attack on Mal- thusianism, — the doctrine, namely, that popula- tion strongly tends to increase to its own hurt ; and we should use time that might be more prof- itably employed, were we to recite the thread- bare arguments of the opponents of that doctrine for no other reason than that Mr. George has chosen to make them a preface to his doctrine of rent. What is original in Mr. George's work is the enormous importance assigned^ to rent as an 1 The same doctrine was contained in an article by the present writer in the North American Review of January, 1875, and in an Address at Amherst College in 1874. 10 146 LAND AND ITS KENT. element in the distribution of wealth. Here Mr. George's admirers may rightfully claim for him all the credit of first discovery. No other writer, so far as I am aware, ever attributed to rent anything approaching ' the same degree of importance. We have seen Mr. Mill, weighed down by a sense of the injustice of allowing the large an- nual increment of the land to pass, unearned, to the landlord, propose that the State should assert the right of the community, as a whole, to this body of wealth; but Mr. Mill never dreamed of advancing the theory that rent nec- essarily, in the progress of society, absorbs the entire gain in productive power, and even more than that gain, leaving the laboring classes ac- tually worse off by reason of every succes- sive improvement in the arts or in the social order.i 1 Mr. Mill does, indeed, assert that the working classes have failed to reap the greater part of the gain which should have accrued to them from the improvements and inventions of the past century ; but he attributes this mainly to their own improvidence, ignorance, or heedlessness, or to the un- due increase of population, or to social and legal wrongs, outside the tenure of land. Mr. George asserts that the private ownership of land deprives the laboring class of all share whatsoever in the fruits of social progress, altogether irrespective of increase of numbers, or of any failure to meet ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 147 On the other hand, we have heard M. Leroy- Beaulieu, an economist and statistician of emi- nence, declare that rent — real, economic rent, as distinguished from the returns made to cap- ital invested in the soil — has actually ceased to be a factor in the distribution of wealth, has already sunk to an economic minimum, and will soon disappear altogether. If I may resort to a somewhat unpleasant physiological illustration, M. Leroy-Beaulieu declares that rent is no more than the merest mole upon the industrial body; Mr. Mill re- gards it as an open sore, a real, appreciable, and considerable drain upon the vitality of the state, which should be checked by stringent surgery and cautery. Mr. George looks upon rent as a cancerous evil, which, growing by what it feeds upon, draws into itself all the vital forces of the community, extending its deadly influence further and further every day, every day drawing nearer and nearer to the seat of life, with only one possible result, and that in no distant future. Eeduce rent, as an element in the distribu- the requirements of a true competition. He declares that this inheres, naturally, necessarily, and inevitably, in the economic conditions of the private ownership of the soil. 148 LAND AND ITS RENT. tion of wealth, to the importance assigned it by M. Leroy-Beaulieu, and Mr. George's practical proposals would become simply ridiculous ; and probably Mr. George himself would see them to be so. Eeduce rent, as an element in the distribu- tion of wealth, to the importance assigned it by Mr. Mill, and Mr. George's work would be emptied of all novel significance. It would remain merely a passionate tract in advocacy of the proposals for nationalizing the land which were put forth by Mr. Mill and the Land Eeform Tenure Association in 1870. Here, then, right here, in the highly magni- fied importance assigned to rent as a factor in the distribution of wealth, we find all there is of Mr. George's work which has either original- ity or novelty. This is literally all the new matter there is in the book, in the view of any economic investigator. But this is Mr. George's own, in every sense of the term. If Mr. George is right here, he has discovered a principle of su- preme importance, the neglect of which should put every professional economist to the blush. Let us, then, confine ourselves to this view of the subject. In stating and discussing the views of Mr. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPEETY. 149 George, I shall seek to exercise the utmost fair- ness. I shall, as far as possible, give him the benefit of his own forms of expression, even at the expense of much space. I shall sometimes quote two, three, or even more statements of the same principle, in order that it may appear that I am not taking a controversial advantage of any inadvertence or extravagance in expres- sion. This is the more desirable, since some of Mr. George's assertions are so astonishing that a few repetitions really assist one in rising to the height of the occasion. I shall, however, take the liberty to introduce italics into my quotations from Mr. George, at my own dis- cretion. In the first place, I remark, negatively, that Mr. George does not attack property in general. He does not rail at capital, or impeach its claim to recompense. On the contrary, he vigorously asserts the "natural right" of the producer to the fruits of his exertions and sacrifices, whether he be laborer or capitalist ; and it is partly because, as he esteems it, private property in land constitutes an invasion of property in the product of labor, that he would bring about the state ownership, or common ownership, of land. 150 LAND AND ITS RENT. In the second place, and also negatively, Mr. George is not an opponent of the Eicardian doctrine. The law of rent is, he says, "cor- rectly apprehended by the current political economy." Indeed, so far is he from being an opponent of the Eicardian doctrine, that it is in the un- heard-of and unthought-of extension which he gives to the scope of the principle of rent, that the essence of his teaching consists. Let us now proceed to state Mr. George's position affirmatively. As we have agreed, for the purposes of the present discussion,^ to con- cede the sufficiency of his refutation of the doctrine of Malthus, we will, for simplicity, follow Mr. George only through his analysis of the effects of rent acting upon stationary populations. This cannot fail to receive his assent, since he declares that "land, being held as private property, would produce in a stationary pop- ulation all the eifects attributed by the Mal- thusian doctrine to pressure of population." What, then, is Mr. George's position ? Just 1 Only for the sake of the discussion. The writer is a thorough believer in the validity of the doctrine of Malthus as restated by Mr. Mill. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 151 this : " Irrespective of the increase of population^ the effect of improvements in methods of produc- tion and exchange is to increase rent!' The proof of this proposition is as follows, in his own words : — "Demand is not a fixed quantity that in- creases only as population increases. In each individual it rises with his power of getting the things demanded. . . . "The amount of wealth produced is nowhere commensurate with the desire for wealth; and desire mounts with every additional opportu- nity for gratification. " This being the case, the effect of labor-saving improvements will be to increase the produc- tion of wealth. Now, for the production of wealth, two things are required, labor and land. Therefore the effect of labor-saving im- provements will be to extend the demand for land, and wherever the limit of the quality of land in use is reached, to bring into cultivation lands of less natural productiveness, or to extend cultivation on the same lands to a point of lower natural productiveness. And thus, while the primary effect of labor-saving improvements is to increase the power of labor, the secondary effect is to extend cultivation, and, where this 152 LAND AND ITS EENT. lowers the margin of cultivation, to increase rent. . . . " Thus, where land is entirely appropriated, as in England, or where it is either appropriated or is capable of appropriation as rapidly as it is needed for use, as in the United States, the ultimate effect of labor-saving machinery or improvements is to increase rent, without in- creasing wages or interest. "It is important that this be fully under- stood, for it shows that effects attributed by current theories to increase of population are really due to the progress of invention, and explains the otherwise perplexing fact that labor-saving machinery everywhere fails to benefit laborers." And he concludes, after repeating and further illustrating this view of the effect of produc- tive improvements and inventions, with the following italicized proposition: "Wealth, in all its forms, being the product of labor applied to land, or the products of land, any increase in the power of labor, the demand for wealth being unsatisfied, will be utilized in procuring more wealth, and thus increase the demand for land." And so, to use his own phrase, labor cannot reap the benefits which advancing civi- ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPEETY. 153 lization brings, because they are " intercepted," ^ that is, intercepted by rent. 1 Mr. George draws what he apparently deems a very ap- palling picture of the conceivable, if not possible, conse- quences of this subjection of labor and capital to the land. " As," he says, 'Sve can assign no limits to the progress of invention, neither can we assign any limits to the increase of rent, short of the whole produce. For, if labor-saving inventions went on until perfection ' was attained, and the necessity of labor in the production of wealth was entirely done away with, then everything that the earth could yield could be obtained without labor, and the margin of cultiva- tion would be extended to zero. Wages would be nothing, and interest would be nothing, while rent would take every- thing. For, the owners of the land being enabled without labor to obtain all the wealth that could be procured from nature, there would be no use for either labor or capital, and no possible way in which either could compel any share of the wealth produced." All this is said seriously, as if it were of some consequence. Yet one cannot help asking ; Well, what of it ? Why should there be any wages, if there were no labor? What are wages? Mr. George himself de- fines both labor and wages as follows : ' ' The term ' labor ' includes all human exertion in the production of wealth ; and wages, being that part of the produce which goes to labor, includes all reward for such exertion." Very good, as it is very familiar. But if a state of things were reached such as Mr. George contemplates, in which there were no labor, no exertion of human powers or facul- ties in the production of wealth, why, in the name of equity, should there be any wages, the reward for such exertion ? And if there were no capital, why should there be any in- terest, the recompense of capital ? What is capital ? Accord- 154 LAND AND ITS RENT. That it may not be supposed that I am in any way misrepresenting Mr. George, or omit- ting any qualification of his propositions, I quote another extended paragraph, in his own words. " Land being necessary to labor, and being re- duced to private ownership, every increase in the productive power of labor but increases reiit, — the price that labor must pay for the opportu- nity to utilize its powers ; and thus all the ad- vantages gained by the march of progress go to the owners of land and luages do not increase. Wages cannot increase; for, the greater the earnings of labor, the greater the price that labor must pay out of its earnings for the op- portunity to make any earnings at all. The mere laborer has thus no more interest in the general advance of productive power than the Cuban slave has in advance in the price of sugar. And just as an advance in the price of sugar may make the condition of the slave worse, by inducing the master to drive him ing to Mr. George it is " only a part of wealth, — that part, namely, which is devoted to the aid of production." But if no wealth were to be devoted to production, as on Mr. George's supposition, then there would be no capital. If no capital, why any interest ? ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 155 harder, so may the condition of the free laborer be povsitively, as well as relatively, changed for the worse by the increase in the productive power of his labor. For, begotten of the con- tinuous advance of rents, arises a speculative tendency which discounts the effect of future improvements by a still further advance of rent." The last sentence introduces Mr. George's second count in his arraignment of rent, as the great social criminal. Please carefully to note the point. The im- mediate and direct effect of any addition, from whatever source, to the productive power of labor, is to increase rents by just the same amount, so that nothing is left to go either into enhanced wages or enhanced profits, the landlord taking the entire increase, whatever that may be. But now another force enters, actually to deplete the already starving laborer. This is the speculative advance in land, owing to the expectation of further increments of value at the expense of the community. " We have," says Mr. George, " hitherto as- sumed, as is generally assumed in elucidations of the theory of rent, that the acUml margin of 156 LAND AND ITS RENT. cultivation always coincides with what may be termed the necessary margin of cultivation, — that is to say, we have assumed that cultivation extends to less productive points only as it becomes necessary from the fact that natural opportunities are at the more productive points fully utilized. This, probably, is the case in stationary or very slowly progressing commu- nities ; but in rapidly progressing communities, where the swift and steady increase of rent gives confidence to calculations of further in- crease, it is not the case. In such commu- nities, the confident expectation of increased prices produces, to a greater or less extent, the effects of a combination among land-holders, and tends to the withholding of land from use, in expectation of higher prices, thus forcing the margin of cultivation farther than required by the necessities of production." But this is not the end of the mischief at- tending the private ownership of land. We have now the third and final count in this arraignment. The speculative holding of land, just described, becomes, in turn, the cause of incessant industrial disturbance, and of those great periodic convulsions of production and trade which involve the labormg classes, poor. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 157 inert, and unapt to travel or to change of occu- pation, in the deepest distress. How can this be ? Mr. George is equal to the occasion. " Production," he says, in explanation of an assumed industrial crisis, " has somewhere been checked, and this reduction in the supply of some things has shown itself in cessation of de- mand for others, the check propagating itself through the whole framework of industry and exchange. Now, the industrial pyramid mani- festly rests on the land. " The primary and fundamental occupations, which create a demand for all others, are evi- dently those which extract wealth from nature, and hence, if v/e trace from one exchange point to another, and from one occupation to another, this check to production, which shows itself in decreased purchasing power, we must ultimately find it in some obstacle which checks labor in expending itself on land. " And that obstacle, it is clear, is the specu- lative advance in rent, or the value of land, whicli produces the same effects as (in fact, it is) a lock-out of labor and capital by land-own- ers. This check to production, beginning at the basis of interlaced industry, propagates it- self from exchange point to exchange point. 158 LAND AND ITS RENT. cessation of supply becoming failure of demand, until, so to speak, the whole machine is thrown out of gear, and the spectacle is everywhere presented of labor going to waste while laborers suffer from want." This concludes Mr. George's arraignment of private property in land. If these successive counts can be sustained, he is fully borne out in his conclusion that " the necessary result of ma- terial progress — land being private property — is, no matter luliat the increase in loopulation, to force laborers to wages which give but a bare living;" or, as he elsewhere expresses it, that " material progress does not merely fail to re- lieve poverty, it actually produces it ; " or, again, that, " whatever be the increase of productive power, rent steadily tends to swallow up the gain and more than the gain ; " or, agam, that " the ownership of the land on which and from which a man must live, is virtually the owner- ship of the man himself, and in acknowledging the right of some individuals to the exclusive use and enjoyment of the earth, we condemn other individuals to slavery, as fully and as completely as though we had formally made them chattels." To a man who believed but a small fraction ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 159 of this, the conclusion which Mr. George an- nounces at the close of the following paragraph would appear irresistible : — "As long as this institution exists, no in- crease in productive power can permanently benefit the masses, but, on the contrary, must tend to still further depress their condition. . . . Poverty deepens as wealth increases, and wages are forced down while productive power grows, because land, which is the source of all wealth and the field of all labor, is monopolized. To extirpate poverty, to make wages what justice commands they should be, the full earnings of the laborer, we must therefore substitute for the individual ownership of land a common ownership." I believe I have presented, in the foregoing extracts, every essential feature of Mr. George's economic system, without suppression or per- version. His practical recommendations for the carrying out of his proposal for the na- tionalization of the land cannot be politically very important, since matters of this sort are generally left to statesmen, not to economists ; and even should the abolition of private prop- erty be decreed at the approaching session of Congress, there is too much reason to fear that 160 LAND AND ITS RENT. Mr. George would not be called in to adjust the details of the scheme. Those recommenda- tions are, however, if not politically important, psychologically interesting, and serve to give an idea as to the kind of person this apostle of a regenerated humanity may be, and as to the sort of society in which he has been bred. " I do not," he says, " propose either to pur- chase or to confiscate private property in land. . . . Let the individuals who now hold it, still retain, if they want to, possession of what they are pleased to call their land. Let them con- tinue to call it tlieir land. Let them buy and sell and bequeath and devise it. We may safely leave them the shell, if we take the kernel. It is not necessary to confiscate land; it is only necessary to confiscate rent." "What I propose," he exclaims, in a fine glow of enthusiasm, " as the simple yet sov- ereign remedy, which will raise wages, increase the earnings of capital, extirpate pauperism, abolish poverty, give remunerative employment to whoever wishes it, afford free scope to hu- man powers, lessen crime, elevate morals and taste and intelligence, purify government, and carry civilization to yet nobler heights, is — to appropriate rent by taxation." ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 161 Of course, the present owners of the land — many, perhaps most, of whom have, under the ex- press sanction and encouragement of the State, bought it, perhaps even from the State itself, paying the price into the treasury — will be compensated when their property or the entire value thereof shall thus be "confiscated" for public uses. Mr. George rejects the suggestion with indignation. He even pities Mr. Mill for having had the weakness to admit ^ the land- owner's claim to compensation : " Great as he was, and pure as he was, warm heart and noble mind, he never yet saw the true harmony of economic laws." But there are the improvements, urges Mr. George's reader, which have become blended with and inseparable from the soil. ''Very well," he cheerfully replies ; " then the title to the improvements becomes blended with the title to the land, the individual right is lost in the common right. . . . Nature does not pro- ceed from man, but man from nature ; and it is into the bosom of nature that he and all his works must return again." What a thing it is to be a philosopher, and see " the true harmony of economic laws " ! 1 See ante, p. 24. 11 162 LAND AND ITS RENT. Since such consequences, not only destructive of the established order of industrial society, but subversive also, it would seem, of ordinary honesty, are to be drawn from Mr. George's discovery of the enormous and previously un- suspected importance of rent as a factor in the distribution of wealth, let us somewhat care- fully analyze the arguments by which his prop- ositions under this head are established. Let us take up, in their inverse order, Mr. George's three capital propositions.^ And, first, how much is there in the view that commercial disturbance and industrial depression are due chiefly to the speculative holding of land ? That land, in its own degree, shares with other species of property in the speculative impulses of exchange, is a matter of course. Everybody knows it; no one ever thought of denying it. Mr. George makes no point against private property in land, however, unless he can show that it is, of all species of property, 1 I do not insist upon the consideration, though, both rele- vant and important, in this connection, that whereas Mr. George's argument assumes that the rents paid by the mem- bers of society are the full economic rents under the Ricar- dian formula, those rents are, in fact, in most communities, greatly reduced by the operation of the forces indicated on pp. 42-51. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 163 peculiarly the subject of speculative impulses. Now, this is so far from being either self-evi- dent or established by adequate induction, that the contrary is the general opinion of eco- nomic writers. Of all species of property, land, especially agricultural land, starts latest and stops earliest in any upward movement of prices, as induced, for instance, by a paper- money inflation, which perhaps affords the best opportunity for the study of purely speculative impulses. Of course, there are circumstances under which those impulses may especially attack land, and a wild " rig " may be run in the mar- ket for this commodity, as, at other times, in the market for government stocks, or mines, or railways, or Dutch tulips, or what not. A very striking instance of the possibilities of speculation in this direction is afforded by the history of land in California. The opening of the Pacific railways in 1868 aroused the most extravagant expectations of a rise in the value of land. Mr. George says, and perhaps truly, that lots in the outskirts of San Francisco " rose hundreds and thousands per cent," and a period of wild speculation ensued. Mr. George ap- pears to have been profoundly affected by his 164 LAND AND ITS EENT. observation of this episode. What was purely local and accidental, he has magnified into a universal cause of speculation. " What," he remarks, " thus went on in Cali- fornia, went on in every progressive section of the Union ; " and this land speculation he makes the primary and principal cause of the panic of 1873. It is difficult to say what Mr. George, with his peculiar ideas, may regard as the progres- sive and what as the retrogressive or stationary sections of the Union; but throughout the regions which, between 1868 and 1873, com- prised more than two thirds of the accumu- lated wealth of the country, and did more than three fourths of its trading and more than five sixths of its manufacturing, agricultural land was not the subject of a speculative enhance- ment of values. On the contrary, the value of farms was, on the whole, depressed relatively to other objects of exchange, throughout the period when the catastrophe of 1873 was preparing. We now come to Mr. George's second count. The allegation that the enhancement of the value of land, above what should be regarded as the capitalized value of its present productive or income-yielding power, withdraws large bodies ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 165 of land from cultivation, thus driving labor and capital to poorer and more distant soils, in order to secure the needed subsistence of the community can only be characterized, so far as all the agricultural ^ uses of land are con- cerned, as a baseless assumption, for which not a particle of proper statistical proof can be adduced, and which is directly contrary to the reason of the case. Because, forsooth, a man is holding a tract of land in the hope of a rise in its value years hence, does that constitute any reason why he should refuse to rent it, this year or next, and get from it what he can, were it no more than enough to pay his taxes and a part of the in- terest on the money borrowed to "carry" the property ? Every financier knows how difficult it is to secure a loan on the mortgage of unimproved property, at anything approaching the value at which the owner holds it. What is this but testimony to the unwillingness of most men, cu'cumstanced as they find themselves, to put their wealth into forms which imply that there is to be, for a number of years, all outgo 1 It will be observed that in the extracts quoted it is cultivation which is spoken of. 166 LAND AND ITS EENT. and no income, however great the final profit anticijDated ? How unreasonable, then, to as- sume that men owning good productive land will refuse to allow it to be cultivated now, simply because they cannot get for it a rent which corresponds to what they look forward ultimately to realize as its capital price ! Undoubtedly the speculative treatment of building lots does cause a certain amount of city real estate to be held out of use. Nobody needed Mr. George to tell him this ; but that the amount of land so reserved is such as seri- ously to retard the development of population, trade, or manufactures, except in a craze like that which seized the people of San Francisco in 1868, seems highly improbable. Let us now proceed to deal with Mr. George's main proposition, the proposition to which the others are subsidiary. If this be established, it really does not matter much whether the others be true or not, for the condition of humanity under the grinding pressure of this main force will be about as bad as it could be ; while, if this be disproved, Mr. George's whole system must break down ridiculously, leaving it to matter little whether the minor evils attributed to the private ownership of land be found to ATTACKS UPON LANDED PEOPERTY. 167 have any real existence or not. This it is which constitutes the original feature of Mr. George's book, that upon which the value of his mission as a public teacher depends, that by which he must stand or fall, — the proposition, namely, that, " irrespective of the increase of population, the effect of improvements in methods of pro- duction and exchange is to increase rent ; " this effect being carried so far that " all the advan- tages gained by the march of progress go to the owners of land, and wages do not increase," the laboring man having " no more interest in the general advance of productive power than the Cuban slave has in advance in the price of sugar," capital also, in its turn, suffering, and to an equal extent, since, as Mr. George states, the effect of labor-saving machinery or im- provements is to increase rent without increas- ing either wages or interest. Now this is not only false, but ridiculously false, blunder being piled on blunder, to reach a conclusion so monstrous. In the first place, the proposition is contra- dicted by plain facts of common observation and by unimpeachable testimony of industrial statistics. The laborer has gained in wages through the labor-saving inventions and im- 168 LAND AND ITS KENT. provements of modern times. Speaking of England, Sir James Caird says : " The laborer's earning power in procuring the staff of life cost him five days' work to pay for a bushel of wheat in 1770, four days' in 1840, and two and a half days' in 1870." So much for bread. " Thirty years ago," says Sir James, " probably not one third of the people of this country con- sumed animal food more than once a week. Now, nearly all of them eat it in meat or cheese or butter, once a day." The same high authority adds : " The laborer is better lodged than he ever was before." We need no one to tell us that the laborer's power to purchase manufactured articles has increased, since 1770, much more rapidly than his power to pur- chase agricultural produce, whether animal or vegetable. To the assertion of Mr. George that even the capitalist gains nothing by inventions and improvements in the agencies of trade or man- ufactures, because the landlord usurps and absorbs all possible increase of productive power, what better answer can we give than that of Professor Emile de Laveleye, himself a qualified advocate of the state ownership of land? ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 169 "Who occupy the pretty houses and villas which are springing up in every direction in all prosperous towns ? Certainly, more than two thirds of these occupants are fresh capitalists. The value of capital engaged in industrial enterprise exceeds that of land itself, and its power of accumulation is far greater than that of ground rents. The immense fortunes amassed so rapidly in the United States, like those of Mr. Gould and Mr. Vanderbilt, were the results of railway speculation, and not of the greater value of land. "We see, then, that the increase of profits and of interest takes a much larger proportion of the total value of labor, and is a more general and powerful cause of inequality, than the increase of rent."^ So much for industrial statistics and facts of common observation. Let us now turn to the reason" of the case. And, first, let us recite Mr. George's own argument. " The effect," he says, " of labor-saving improvements will be to increase the production of wealth. Now, for the production of wealth, two things are re- quired, — labor and land. Therefore the effect of labor-saving improvements will be to extend the demand for land." 1 Contemporary Eeview, November, 1882. 170 LAND AND ITS KENT. A pretty piece of reasoning this ! A mono- graph by Mr. George upon the significance of the word "therefore" is really a desideratum of systematic logic. Two things are needed for the production of wealth, land and labor; therefore an increase of production will increase the demand for land, forsooth ! But luliy not also for labor, since both are concerned in pro- duction ? Was there ever a more senseless blunder ? But Mr. George is further in error, even, than would so far appear. He has got the thing exactly wrong. It is not only true that an increased production of wealth may involve an enhanced demand for labor as well as for land, but it is also incontestably true that the increased production of wealth rarely if ever causes an increased demand for land without a corresponding demand for labor, while, on the contrary, an increased production of wealth may cause an enormous increase in the demand for labor without enhancing the demand for the products of the soil in any degree whatsoever. Here is a pound of raw cotton, the production of which makes a certain demand, or drain, upon the land. To that cotton may be applied the labor of one operative for half an hour, worth, ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPEETY. 171 say, 5 cents. Successive demands for the pro- duction of wealth may lead to the application of, first, a full hour's labor, then of two hours', then of three, four, or five ; finer and finer fab- rics being successively produced, until at last the pound of cotton has been wrought into the most exquisite articles. Mr. George says that the whole effect of any increase in the pro- duction of wealth is to enhance the demand for land. Here is a large increase of produc- tion, twofold, threefold, tenfold, perhaps, with no additional demand, or drain, upon the soil. But I go further, and assert, without fear of contradiction, that not only is no increase in the demand for land necessarily involved in an increased production of wealth, but that the enhancement of the demand for land, in the progress of society, habitually falls short of the enhancement of the demand for labor, the increase of production taking two great forms, — one which involves no increase whatever in the materials derived from the soil : the other in which the increased demand for land falls short, generally far short, often almost infinitely short, of the increased demand for labor. Let us look around. I have cited one in- 172 LAND AND ITS KENT. stance, that of the use made in the mill of a pound of cotton, manufactured successively into fabrics worth, perhaps, 20 cents a pound, then 30, then 50, then $1.00. This is not an extreme case. Here is the rude furniture of a laborer's cot- tage, worth perhaps S30. The same amount of wood may be made into furniture worth $200 for the home of the clerk, or into furni- ture worth $2,000 for the home of the banker. The steel that would be needed to make a cheap scythe worth 80 cents may be rendered into watch-springs, or surgical or philosophical in- struments worth $100 or $200. The actual ma- terial derived from the soil which would go into a picture by a master, worth thousands, makes a smaller draught upon the productive essences of the soil than a chromo of the Prodigal's Eeturn, sold from a cart for $2, frame included. These are, of course, extreme cases, taken purposely, with a view to show briefly and graphically the range of values that may be produced in dealing with the same quantity of material drawn from the soil. That range, however, is always great as applied to almost any class of expenditures. A gentleman of means goes to Delmonico's, and pays $2, $3, or $5 for a dinner which makes no ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 17o heavier drain upon the productive essences of the soil than a dinner of corned beef and cab- bage for which a laborer pays 25 cents. A part of the difference between the prices of the two dinnerS; to be sure, represents the cost of an expensive business "stand" on Fifth Avenue ; but by far the greater part represents service of one kind or another, at one stage or another, in making the dishes exquisite in appearance and flavor, in serving them neatly and elegantly with all the appliances of taste and fashion. Our gentleman, before dining, had perhaps been measured for a pair of boots, for which he was to pay $12 or $15, yet con- taining no more leather, and so making no more draught upon the productive essences of the soil, in the way of nourishing the animal from which the leather was cut, than the laborer's $3 pair of " stogies ; " he had also ordered a suit of clothes for $60 or $75, at his tailor's, no thicker, no warmer, containing no more fibre, than the laborer's $15 tweeds. In all these cases (and they fairly represent the facts of personal con- sumption in modern society) the main cause for the excess of value in products of higher price is not the use of a larger quantity of material, involving a greater demand or drain upon the 174 LAND AND ITS RENT. productive essences of the soil, but the appli- cation of more labor to the same quantity of material. In contradiction, then, of Mr. George's propo- sition that the entire effect of an increase of production is expended in raising rents, neither wages nor the interest of capital deriving any gain whatsoever therefrom, rent indeed absorb- ing the entire gain, " and more than the gain," we have seen, — 1. That an increase of production onay en- hance the demand for labor equally with the demand for land. 2. That, in fact, in those forms of production which especially characterize modern society, the rate of enhancement of the demand for labor tends to far exceed the rate of enhance- ment of the demand for land. 3. That an increased demand for the produc- tion of wealth may, and in a vast body of in- stances does, enhance the demand for labor without enhancing the demand for land in any, the slightest degree, the whole effect being ex- pended in the elaboration of the same amount of material. 4. We have now only to show, in the fourth place, that, instead of all improvements and in- ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 175 ventions increasing the demand for land, as Mr. George declares, some very extensive classes of improvements and inventions actually operate powerfully, directly, and exclusively in reduc- ing tlie demand for land, — we have, I say, only to show this, to convict this would-be apostle of a new political economy and a regenerated humanity, of the grossest incompetence for eco- nomic reasoning. This it will be easy to do. By far the larger proportion of all improve- ments and inventions fall naturally under one or another of three great classes, — first, those which affect manufacturing industry; second, those which affect transportation; third, those which affect the cultivation of the soil. Of these three classes it has always been admitted by economists that the first tends to enhance the demand for land, and thus to raise rents, although not necessarily, or indeed usu- ally, without also enhancing the demand for labor and capital, and 'thus raising wages and interest. The two remaining classes of im- provements and inventions tend directly, and indeed operate exclusively, ^ to reduce the de- mand for land, leaving, thus, the whole advan- 1 "Irrespective of the increase of population," to use Mr. George's own voluntary qualification. 176 LAND AND ITS EENT. tage of such improvements and inventions to be acquired by either labor or capital, or, in one proportion or another, by both labor and capi- tal, in enhanced wages or interest. And, first, of improvements in transporta- tion. I need not waste time in calling to mind the mighty strides which invention has made, during the past fifty years, in this direction, substituting for the sailing vessel of 400 tons, which carried its petty cargo of wheat in forty or sixty days from New York to Liverpool, the steamship of 5,000 tons, which makes the pas- sage in nine days or twelve ; substituting for the tedious wagon carriage which in forty or fifty miles, perhaps in twenty or thirty only, ate up the whole value of the freight,^ carriage by steam cars, drawn on steel rails, which, allowing for transport from Dakota to New York, leaves enough of the value of the freight to pay for the ocean passage and for the sup- port of the producer upon those distant plains. Add the telegraph and the fast mail, for trans- 1 The enormous and speedily destructive cost of wagon carriage may be seen in the fact, recited by Professor Eoscher, that, according to the instructions of the Koyal Saxon Com- mission, the cost of hauling manure is assumed to be 10 per cent higher for a distance of 250 rods, and 20 per cent higher for a distance of 500 rods. ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 177 mitting orders and transacting sales, and one will hardly question the assertion that the greatest of all the classes of improvements and inventions effected within the last half-century, has been that which relates to transportation. Is it the effect of improvements of this class to enhance rents ? Absolutely and exclusively the reverse. Whatever quickens and cheapens transport, acts directly in the reduction of rents,^ and cannot act in any other way, since it throws out of cultivation the poorer lands previously in use for the supply of the market, enabling the better soils at a distance to take their place, thus raising the lower limit, or, as it is called, the "margin" of cultivation, and thus reducing rents. But, secondly, take the case of agricultural improvements and inventions. Here the effect upon rents is not so simple or direct ; but it is not the less certain in the result. The case cannot be better stated than in the language of Mr. Mill, which I will quote at length. After premising that improved processes of agriculture are of two kinds, — one consisting of those which do not increase the produce, but diminish the labor and expense by which that 1 See ante, pp. 23-26. 12 178 LAND AND ITS RENT. produce is obtained, such as the improved con- struction of tools or the introduction of new instruments which spare manual labor, like the winnowing and threshing machines ; the other class consisting of those improvements which enable the land to yield a greater absolute pro- duce without an equivalent increase of labor, such as the disuse of fallows by means of the rotation of crops, — the introduction of new veg- etable species, either of a nature to "rest the land," in alternation, by calling upon the soil for different properties, or of a nature which enables them to afford a greater amount of sub- sistence for men or animals in proportion to the draught made upon the land, — the introduction of new and more powerful fertilizing agents or a better application of familiar manures, — inven- tions, too, like subsoil ploughing or tile-drain- ing, etc., — Mr. Mill says, "By the former OF THE TWO KINDS OF IMPROVEMENT, RENT WOULD BE DIMINISHED J BY THE SECOND, IT WOULD BE DIMINISHED STILL MORE." The following is Mr. Mill's demonstration of these propositions : '' Suppose that the demand for food requires the cultivation of three quali- ties of land, yielding, on an equal surface, and at an equal expense, 100, 80, and 60 bushels of ATTACKS UPON LANDED PROPERTY. 179 wheat. The price of wheat will, on the aver- age, be just sufficient to enable the third qual- ity to be cultivated with the ordinary profit. The first quality, therefore, will yield 40 and the second 20 bushels of extra profit, consti- tuting the rent of the landlord. " And, first, let an improvement be made, which, without enabling more corn to be grown, enables the same corn to be grown with one fourth less labor. The price of wheat will fall one fourth, and 80 bushels will be sold for the price for which 60 were sold before. But the produce of the land which produces 60 bushels is still required, and, the expenses being as much reduced as the price, the land can still be cultivated with the ordinary profit. The first and second qualities will, therefore, con- tinue to yield a surplus of 40 and 20 bushels, and corn-rent will remain the same as before. But, corn having fallen in price one fourth, the same corn-rent is equivalent to a fourth less of money, and of all other commodities. "If the improvement is of the other kind, rent will fall in a still greater ratio. Suppose that the amount of produce which the mar- ket requires, can be grown not only with a fourth less of labor, but on a fourth less of land. 180 LAND AND ITS EENT. If all the land already in cnltivation continued to be cultivated, it would yield a produce much larger than necessary. Land equivalent to a fourth of the produce must now be abandoned ; and as the third quality yielded exactly one fourth (being 60 out of 240), that quality will go out of cultivation. The 240 bushels can now be grown on land of the first and second qualities only ; being, on the first, 100 bushels plus one third, or 133 J bushels ; on the second, 80 bushels plus one third, or 106f bushels; together, 240. The second quality of land, instead of the third, is now the lowest, and regulates the price. Instead of 60, it is suffi- cient if 106f bushels repay the capital with the ordinary profit. The price of wheat will consequently fall, not in the ratio of 60 to 80, as in the other case, but in the ratio of 60 to 106f . Even this gives an insufficient idea of the degree in which rent will be affected. The whole produce of the second quality of land will now be required to repay the expenses of production. That land, being the worst in culti- vation, will pay no rent. And the first quality will only yield the difference between 133 J bushels and 106f, being 26f bushels instead of 40. The landlords collectively will have lost ATTACKS UPOX LANDED PEOPERTY. 181 33J out of 60 bushels in corn-rent alone, while the value and price of what is left will have been diminished in the ratio of 60 to 106 1." Surely there can be no need to pursue the subject. I think we may conclude that we have nothing to learn from Mr. George about either land or rent, but that we may safely go back to our old teachers, Eicardo, Senior, and Mill. The true economic law of rent was correctly apprehended, fully stated, and clearly illus- trated by the great economist who has given his name thereto. The attempts of Messrs. Bas- tiat^ and Carey ^ to overthrow that doctrine have completely failed to shake a single pillar in the majestic structure of Eicardo's argument. The application of that principle, with how- ever much of laxity or severity,^ to the various grades of soil contributing to the supply of any market, will always make rent a most impor- tant element in the distribution of wealth. The labored efforts of M. Leroy-Beaulieu * to disparage rent, by provmg that the landlord's share is destined soon to disappear as an ele- ment in the distribution of wealth, can com- 1 See ante, pp. 57-75. ^ See pp. 42-51. 2 See pp. 75-108. * gee pp. 109-120. 182 LAND AND ITS RENT. mand little conviction in the face of the fact stated by Sir James Caird, that the cost of im- portation from the American wheat-fields, in spite of all the vast inventions and discoveries of the past fifty years in the arts of transport, still affords a natural protection to English corn-lands equal, on the average, to 40 shil- lings an acre. On the other hand, the extravagant asser- tions and passionate declamations of Mr. GJ-eorge avail just as little to establish his view of the overwhelming importance of rent, as a factor in the distribution of the joint produce of land, labor, and capital, among the several classes taking part in its production. The relations of the land to labor and to cap- ital, in the distribution of wealth, are very nearly what we have heretofore been accus- tomed to consider them to be, — • what our old masters taught us they were. Thus far, at least, there has been little to learn from the prophets of a new economic dispensation. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 183 I CHAPTEE IV. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. N tlie present chapter I propose to offer some suggestions regarding that tenure of the land which is best suited to advance the interests of society as a whole. The first question which arises is this : Shall land be regarded solely as an instrument of production, or shall other aspects of the land be considered by the economist in writing of the tenure of the soil, and by the statesman in dealing with the land as it comes within the scope of legislation ? The answer to this ques- tion is all-important. Economists generally, though not without many and unportant ex- ceptions, have been disposed to hold that land should be regarded merely as an instrument of production. Let the soil, they have said, be cultivated in that way, under that system, which will secure the largest aggregate pro- duce for a given amount of labor and capital, 184 LAND AND ITS EENT. or will secure tlie required quantity of produce with tlie least application of labor and capital ; and let us trust to the natural operation of economic forces to bring about the proper di- vision of the produce among individuals and classes. If one system will, as contrasted with any and all other systems, yield a larger amount of vegetable and animal food, of fibre for clothing, and of fuel for warmth, the presump- tion must be that, by adoptiag that system, each individual and each class of producers will be the better off, since there is a larger amount in the aggregate to be divided, while the natural operation of the principle of self- interest will effect a distribution at least approximating, in reasonableness and natural justice, that which would be effected under any other, the most favorable, system of produc- tion. In a word, no matter what the position of the individual member of the industrial so- ciety is, as producer, he will, as consumer, find his true interest in the largest production of wealth. The reader will recall the similar debate which has long been held over the same ques- tion in its application to mechanical industry, especially as developed into what we call a THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 185 manufacturing system. Here the English and American economists, ahnost without excep- tion, — and perhaps we may say also the econo- mists of the Continent, though not without numerous and important exceptions, — have held that the general interest was to be found in the largest production of wealth. Let labor be divided and still subdivided ; let occupations become diversified, and industries specialized and localized, as fully as may be involved in the largest possible application of machinery and elemental power, and in the realization of the highest amount of productive efficiency from the mass of productive agents ; have no care concerning the position which the mass of laborers shall occupy in the industrial order, whether they shall be hired or self-employed, whether they shall or shall not be individually accomplished in any art which could enable them to earn a livelihood by exertions outside that industrial order; indeed, let it be frankly assumed that they will, in the vast majority of cases, know but a fraction of a trade, being kept at work, for the sake of the highest effi- ciency, in performmg, year after year, but a single operation, involving perhaps but a single motion ; have no thought regarding the influ- 186 LAND AND ITS EENT. ence of sucli an organization of industry upon the physical, intellectual, or moral condition of the laborer ; let him take his place wherever the interests of the largest production assign him, without any reference to the question whether his duties and his surroundings there will tend to the symmetrical development of his powers and faculties, or otherwise. In a word, accept cheerfully all the incidents of that organization of industrial society which has been described. Doubtless much evil will ensue ; but four considerations should suffice to reconcile the social philosopher to this condi- tion, — first, that much of the evil would occur under any organization of industrial society ; secondly, that, thanks to the economic harmo- nies, industrial evils are self-limited and tend to disappear ; thirdly, that the gain in produc- tive power, accomplished by the means recited, furnishes a fund with which the individual industrial agent may purchase the means of physical, intellectual, and moral culture which would have been unattainable with a smaller production of wealth, which means of culture, including leisure for social enjoyment and for study, should compensate, and far more than compensate, for the tendency to an incomplete THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 187 or one-sided development of the individual ; fourthly, that there is a certain virtue in that discipline^ which is the condition of highly organized industry, enforcing punctuality and precision; that there is a certain virtue in sub- jection to the authority of an official superior, on the one side, and to the public sentiment of a class or a corps, on the other, which acts most powerfully upon even the most inconstant mind ; that there is a certain virtue in direct competition with one's fellows, and in the com- parison and criticism of the methods and re- sults of work, which stimulates and quickens even the dullest and least apprehensive. However much one may take exception, at points, to the arguments by which the modern industrial order of extended and constantly extending competition is defended, the econo- mists generally have, as was said, accepted the principle that, so far as mechanical labor is con- cerned, society should be organized to accom- 1 In tliis connection I should do injustice to the reader, did I not refer to the very striking comparison between the Domestic and the Factory systems of industry, in their re- spective effects upon the laboring populations engaged, which is conducted by Colonel C. D. Wright in his report on the Factory System, embodied in the Manufacturing Volume of the Tenth Census. 188 LAND AND ITS EENT. plish tlie largest production of wealth, without any care respecting the industrial position of individuals, leaving each to seek his own inter- ests as a consumer of wealth, — to recover, that is, through the greater quantities and lower prices of the comforts, decencies, and luxuries of life, whatever he may have lost through the sacrifice of his independence and self -sufficiency as a producer. Two great classes, however, dissent from this conclusion. The socialists declare that the concentration of manufacturing industry, the minute subdivision, and, by consequence, the extreme specialization of labor, under com- mercial freedom and unlimited competition; the principle of association, which, if it do not benefit the great capitalists alone, benefits them in a far higher proportion than persons of small means ; and, lastly, speculation, whose power to engross the wealth of the community in- creases with the extent and complexity of the industrial system, — that these causes yoke pov- erty and progress together ; force wages down as production rises ; exaggerate the natural dis- tinctions of society, ever making the rich richer and the poor poorer, and fixing an impassable barrier between classes and orders of men. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 189 The protectionists, also, take exception to the proposition that it is the largest production of wealth which, on the whole, best subserves the public interest. The doctrine of protection has no other logical significance than that pro- duction should be crossed along certain lines — the lines of nationality — for the purpose of checking the otherwise irresistible tendency to the division of labor, the diversification of oc- cupations, the specialization and localization of mechanical industry. The protectionist entertains, in common with the socialist, a profound distrust of competition, as an agent for returning to the individual mem- ber of society, in his capacity as consumer, what- ever henefits he may lose through the sacrifice of his advantages as a loroducer, believing that, on the contrary, competition tends to exert a very unequal pressure upon the several classes of the community, and that unequal competition is a highly pernicious and possibly destructive force. The protectionist rejects, also, the doctrine of the economic harmonies, holding, instead, the theory that economic injuries, once suffered, tend to remain and to deepen, rather than to be removed by the natural operation of the prin- ciple of self-interest. 19.Q LAND AND ITS EENT. To prevent, therefore, the undue extension of the prmciple of competition, the protection- ist proposes, as has been stated, to erect barriers along the boundary lines of nationality.^ For myself, I accept the principle of com- petition, in its application to all branches of mechanical labor, without any hesitation and without any reserve except as to that class of restrictions which come fairly within the two titles of Factory Acts and Sanitary Eegula- tions, respecting which I cannot but esteem the 1 Conceding, for the sake of argument, that the advan- tages of the world-wide extension of the principle of division of labor are more than outweighed by the resulting evils, it will be noted that the theory of protection is palpably weak in the respect that never has anything approaching a serious reason been offered for making industrial units out of exist- ing political units ; allowing production and trade to follow the impulses of competition not only without restraint, but actually under encouragement, to the extreme boundaries of empire, however widely these may be spread, though it were from ocean to ocean or pole to pole, yet forbidding them to cross those boundaries, even in the case of the narrowest State No shadow of a reason has ever yet been given by any pro tectionist for this equivalency, or, rather, conterminateness, of political and industrial entities, while the antecedent im probability of a sufficient reason being found therefor must. in view of the almost infinite range of conditions under which nations exist, in the respects of area, soil, extension in latitude and in longitude, climate and civilization, be con- ceded to be little, if anything, less than hopeless. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 191 attitude of tlie English and even the Ameri- can economists in the past, and to some extent in the present, as most unfortunate, not only as having been mistaken in point of theory, but as having been the cause of a great part of the jealousy and hostility which the working classes have cherished towards political economy. But while I accept freedom of production, with all its consequences, throughout the length and breadth of mechanical industry, with the exception indicated, I cannot but feel that there is a great deal of truth in the descriptions which the socialists and the protectionists give of the deleterious effects of extended competi- tion ; and that the economists — or free-traders, if one chooses to regard the terms as inter- convertible — have committed a controversial error, to put it on the lowest ground, in dis- paraging these evils and even denying their existence. The economic harmonies do not prevail ex- cept among populations rarely gifted with intel- ligence and enterprise. Economic injuries do not tend to diminish and to disappear, but to abide and to deepen, imder the natural opera- tion of the principle of self-interest. The rule 192 LAND AND ITS EENT. "To liim that hatli shall be given," expresses a law of wide extent and stringent application throughout the sphere of industry. Competi- tion may become a crushing and destructive force, when it is so far unequal that one class, alert and aggressive, wielding large capitals, and acting m concert or with a common understand- ing, exerts a continuous, unremitting pressure upon another class, whose members cannot ade- quately respond to the demand made upon them, in a prompt assertion of their own interests, through change of place or occupation. This is so clear in principle, and it is so manifest that the working classes have suffered enormous injuries, enduring injuries, through the operation of unequal competition, in that unceasing struggle for economical vantage- ground which is involved in the highly intense organization of modern industry, as it has been described, that the economists have committed a palpable controversial error in disparaging the importance of these considerations, and even denying them any validity whatever. Had they taken upon themselves the task of investigating the effects of imperfect competi- tion, in frank recognition of the too palpable facts of modern industrial society ; had they THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 193 undertaken to trace the curve, so to speak, which the principle of self-interest describes, under varying conditions, upon the ground of the general good, showing under what circum- stances the public and the private interest are coincident, under what circumstances the oper- ation of the principle of self-interest, unre- strained, may become, in a higher or lower degree, prejudicial ; and had they been willing to inquire, or even to tolerate the inquiries of others, concerning the means, if any, by which the pressure of an unequal competition may be relieved, — they might have retained the con- fidence of the working classes, whom they have alienated almost beyond the possibility of rec- onciliation by their uncompromismg reiteration of the dogma of Laissez faire. Our American economists have been the great- est sinners in this respect. Even after Cairnes, the ablest English economist who survived Mill, had frankly confessed that since "human beings know and follow their interests, accord- ing to their lights and dispositions, but not necessarily, nor in practice always, in that sense in which the interest of the individual is coincident with that of others or of the whole, . . . there is no security that the economic 13 194 LAND AND ITS EENT. phenomena of society, as at present constituted, will arrange themselves spontaneously in the way which is most for the common good ; " and even after Jevons, the ablest English economist who survived Cairnes, had declared, in reference to this very subject, that it is futile to attempt to uphold any theory of eternal fixed principles or abstract rights re- garding what is simply a question of proba- bility and degree, — our American economists have continued monotonously to repeat the doctrine of the economic harmonies, as if it contained the sum of all truth, and have dealt with every one who presumed to seek to define that part of the field of the general good which fails to be covered by the operation of the prin- ciple of self-interest, almost as an economic outlaw. I do not know that a better instance could be given of the unfortunate efi'ects of the con- troversial error (looking at it still from the lowest point of view) which the economists have committed in dealing with this question, than by referring again, for a moment, to Mr. George's work.^ The keynote of that work is found in its 1 See ante, p. 141. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 195 title, "Progress and Poverty." The author, with extraordinary rhetorical skill, grasps all the facts which establish a seeming connection between these two phenomena. To his own satisfaction he finds that " where the conditions to which material progress everywhere tends are most fully realized, — that is to say, where population is densest, wealth greatest, and the machinery of production and exchange most highly developed, — we find the deepest pov- erty, the sharpest struggle for existence, and the most enforced idleness. . . . The tramp comes with the locomotive, and almshouses and prisons are as surely the marks of mate- rial progress as are costly dwellings, rich ware- houses, and magnificent churches. Upon streets lighted with gas and patrolled by uniformed policemen, beggars wait for the passer-by ; and in the shadow of college and library and museum, are gathering the more hideous Huns and fiercer Yandals of whom Macaulay prophesied." The cause of this close conjunction of Pov- erty with Progress is the object of Mr. George's research. Obvious, close at hand, is the influ- ence of the modern organization of industry, — the concentration of capitals, the speciaHzation 196 LAND AND ITS EENT. of occupations, tlie localization of manufactures, the intense and unremitting competition of world-wide exchanges. But the professional economists assure Mr. George that it is not this cause which produces the effect he seeks to explain ; that, through economic harmonies, never to be sufficiently ad- mired, the individual industrial agent is pro- tected from all possibility of harm amid the operation of these tremendous forces, and that the laborer will surely recover, as consumer, whatever he may lose as producer. Shut off, then, by the economists themselves, from finding here the cause of " the association of Poverty with Progress," Mr. George turns to rent as the source of the economic evils he describes ; and it is difficult to see how he can be answered by those who stand committed to the dogma of the economic harmonies. He has arrived at his demonstration through a logical process of exclusion ; and it is the econ- omists themselves who have thrown out, for his behoof if not on his behalf, the only cause, other than rent, which could reasonably be adduced in explanation of the phenomenon. To return from this long excursion, the prime question regarding the land, which addresses it- THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 197 self alike to economist and to statesman, is this : Shall land he regarded simply as an instrument of production, as we have agreed to consider the organized system of mechanical industry ? Shall we say that it does not matter how much those who actually work upon the soil may lose, of individuality or independence, in their economical position, since they will be sure, as consumers, to make themselves good for any disadvantage which they may immediately suf- fer, as producers ? Shall we consent to trust to competition alone to effect the distribution of the produce of agricultural labor, as we have, with whatever of misgiving or reserve, accepted it as the agent for the distribution of the pro- ducts of mechanical labor ? ^ Or must we take some further bond for securing the interests of the producer who works upon the land ? Or, again, are there considerations addressing them- selves to the economist or the statesman, which claim priority to the questions relating either to 1 This view is expressed by Sir James Caird, in speaking of English agi-iculture : " Our agriculture is no longer in- fluenced hy considerations of the means of finding employment for surplus labor, but is now being developed on the prin- ciple of obtaining the largest produce at the least cost, — the same principle by which the power-loom has supplanted the hand-loom." 198 LAND AND ITS EENT. the production or the distribution of wealth, — considerations, for example, relating to the con- sumption of wealth or to the relation of subsist- ence to population, or considerations relating to good citizenship and the security of the State ? That great numbers of intelligent economists, who willingly accept all the consequences of competition acting upon the most extended sys- tem of production in mechanical industry, either hesitate or altogether refuse to regard land as a mere instrument of production, is well known to all students of economics. ISTor do these men occupy an illogical position. In the first place, looking to what are called the rights of property, it is admitted by all sound writers on public policy, that property in land differs markedly and materially from property in capital or in the products of labor. If both species of property are "sacred," to use a familiar phrase, landed property, by almost universal consent, stands lower, much lower, in the hierarchy than property in capi- tal. It would be easy to quote from writers of every school in support of this assertion, but doubtless the statement of Professor Eoscher will be accepted as a just summary of the views of the body of publicists : — THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 199 " The appropriation of ' original and indestruc- tible natural forces' lias its basis not so much in justice as in the general good ; and the state has always considered itself entitled to attach to the ' monopoly of land ' which it accorded to the first possessor all kinds of limitations and conditions, in the interest of the common good, and sometimes to consider private property in land in the light of a semi-public function." ^ If, therefore, the proprietor of land owns it in a somewhat different and a somewhat lower sense than that in which the proprietor of chattels owns them, one class of valid objec- tions to interference by authority with the use of property in chattels may not apply with equal force, or indeed may perhaps not apply at all, to property in land. This distinction is vigorously asserted by Professor Cairnes, in his essay entitled ''Politi- cal Economy and Land." " Sustained," he says, "by some of the greatest names, — I will say, by every name of the first rank in Political Economy, from Turgot and Adam Smith to Mill, — I hold that the land of a country presents conditions which separate it economically from the great mass of the other 1 See Mr. Mill's remark, ante, p. 124. 200 LAND AND ITS RENT. objects of wealtli, — conditions which, if they do not absolutely and under all circumstances impose upon the state the obligation of con- trolling private enterprise in dealing with land, at least explain why this control is, in certain stages of social progress, indispensable, and why, in fact, it has been constantly put in force whenever public opinion or custom^ has not been strong enough to do without it. "And not merely does economic science, as expounded by its ablest teachers, dispose of cv priori objections to a policy of intervention with regard to land, it even furnishes princi- ples fitted to inform and guide such a policy in a positive sense. Far from being the irrec- oncilable foe, it is the natural ally, of those who engage in this course, at once justifying the principle of their undertaking, and lending itself as a minister to the elaboration of the constructive design." But, again, a wide difference in the degree of advantage which may be expected to result from the application of the subdivision of labor and the aggregation of capitals in agri- culture, as compared with manufactures, enters 1 On the power of public opinion or custom over rent, see ante, pp. 47-51. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 201 to justify a very different view of tlie two cases. It would be wholly reasonable to admit that the enormous gain in productive power which results from the modern organization of me- chanical labor must be accepted as outweighing all the evils incidental to that system, while denying emphatically that the productive power of land in large estates under a single manage- ment shows any such excess over the produc- tive power of land when cut up into small farms cultivated by their respective owners, as to compensa.te for the disadvantages that might be held to result from a less equable distribu- tion of wealth, through the discouragement of frugality, through a more wanton increase of population, or through the merely political loss resulting to the State from the destruction of an independent and self-reliant yeomanry. That the excess of advantages, productively considered, upon the side of large estates, as compared with what are usually called peasant properties, cannot be very great, is shown by the fact that the existence of such an excess in any degree has been disputed by writers so in- telligent and candid as Messrs. Mill, Thornton, and Hippolyte Passy. 202 LAND AND ITS RENT. Yet, for one, I am willing to accept tlie con- clusion of Sir James Caird, as stated in the following paragraphs : — " A system is best tested by its fruits. Com- pared with all other countries, our threefold plan of landlord, farmer, and laborer, appears to yield larger returns, with fewer laborers and from an equal extent of land. " Our average produce of wheat is 28 bushels an acre, against 16 in France, 16 in Germany, and 13 in Eussia and the United States.^ We show a similar advantage in live-stock, both in quantity and quality. We have far more horses, cattle, and sheep in proportion to acreage than any other country, and in all these kinds there is a general superiority. Our most famous breeders of live-stock are the tenant farmers. The best examples of farming are found in the same class. The improved breeds of cattle, the Leicester and Southdown sheep, and the ex- 1 The reader will, of course, understand that these figures do not represent the comparative fertility of the lands of the several countries named, or the comparative profits of agri- culture. The English product is obtained, as Sir James Caird states in the sentences following, through the applica- tion of more labor, the employment of more cattle (furnishing both power and manure), and the use of more machinery, the cost of all which has to come out of the value of the product. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 203 tended use of macliinery, manures, and artificial foods are chiefly due to them. ''And the neatness of the cultivation, the straight furrow and the beautiful lines of drilled corn, the well-built ricks and docile horses, ex- hibit at once the strength and the skill of the laborers. " If that mode of husbandry which lessens the exchangeable value of bread and meat by an increase of production and supply, is the best for the community, from whom a smaller propor- tion of their labor is required for the purchase of their food, then our system of subdivision of labor by landlord, farmer, and laborer, the three interests engaged in its production, will stand a favorable comparison with that of any other country." ^ The reason why the division of labor and the concentration of capital accomplish so much less, relatively, in agriculture than in manu- factures, is twofold. On the one hand, the nature of agricultural operations, the extent of the field over which they are carried on, the varying necessities of the seasons in their order, and the limited ap- plicability of machinery and elemental power, 1 The Landed Interest and the Supply of Food, pp. 68-70. 204 LAND AND ITS RENT. preclude tlie possibility of achieving a gain in tills department of activity which shall be at all comparable to that which is attained where hundreds and thousands of workmen are gath- ered upon a few acres of ground, where ma- chinery the most delicate and the most powerful may be applied successively to every minute operation, and where the force of steam or grav- ity may be invoked to multiply many fold the efficiency of the unaided man. On the other hand, there is a virtue in the mere ownership of land by the actual laborer, which goes far, very far, to outweigh the ad- vantages which great capitals bring to the cul- tivation of the soil. The " magic of property " in transmuting the bleak rock into the bloom- ing garden, the barren sand of the seashore into the richest mould, has been told by a hundred travellers and economists since Arthur Young's day. In his tireless activity, "from the rising of the lark to the lodging of the lamb ; " in his unceasing vigilance against every form of waste ; in his sympathetic care of the drooping vine, the broken bough, the tender young of the flock and the herd; in his inti- mate knowledge of the character and capabili- ties of every field, and of every corner of every THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 205 field, within his narrow domain ; in his passion- ate devotion to the land which is all his own, which was his father's before him, which will be his son's after him, the peasant, the small proprietor, holds the secret of an economic vir- tue which even the power of machinery can scarcely overcome. Americans are perhaps likely to overrate the degree in which operations on a vast scale, un- der a single management, may be advanta- geously carried on. The stories of the great farms of Illinois and California, and, even more prodigious, of the Dalrymple farms along the line of the Northern Pacific Eailroad, are likely to create the impression on the mind of the reader that there is almost no limit to the success of great, even of gigantic, agricul- ture. Such cases, are, however, highly exceptional, even in the cultivation of the staple cereal crops and of cotton ; while, as we reach the numberless minor crops, which in their aggre- gate constitute a large part of the agriculture of the world, the advantages of aggregated capitals diminish rapidly or disappear alto- gether. On this point M. Leroy-Beaulieu remarks : — 206 LAND AND ITS EENT. "The more agriculture develops, the more the exceptional advantage of great operations diminishes. When we have only to do with simple processes, like gathering the wild fruits of the earth, burning or cutting trees and brush to clear the soil, opening the land with im- proved ploughs, harvesting with machines which in a high degree economize hand-labor ; or when, indeed, it is merely necessary to fence in large tracts, leaving the flocks to roam there untended, care alone being taken that they do not stray and that the animals are duly sheared or slaughtered, — under these circum- stances large capitals have doubtless a signal advantage. The principle of combination, by avoiding the dissipation of human energy, gives much greater results than a multitude of sepa- rate and independent efforts. "But these conditions are met only in an early stage. They soon disappear. There are scarcely more than two agricultural products which succeed very well in large operations, — the cereals and the raising of cattle.^ It is 1 M. Leroy-Bcaulieu might perhaps have added cotton ; yet the results of Mr, Edward Atkinson's investigations strongly tend to prove that, with free labor, small cotton plantations have an actual advantage. THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 207 said, these are the principal products ; but even with these the small and medium can very easily hold their own against the great culture, when once the period of clearing and peopling the ground has passed, while, on the contrary, the great culture, at least the giant culture, can hardly hold its own against the small, as respects all the accessory products of agricul- ture, the importance of which is continually on the increase. The finer products, with- out exception, — vegetables, fruits, wine, poul- try, butter, cheese, — are better suited to small or medium than to large operations. The im- portance of the eye of the master upon all the details of production becomes much greater as the cultivatmg of the soil becomes more intensive and more varied." Thirdly, in addition to the question of gross production, we have considerations relating to the distribution of the produce, which may properly enter to affect the mind of the econ- omist or the statesman when dealing with the tenure of the soil. That the industrial position of the individual agent, — as, for instance, whether producing in his own right and name, by permission of no one, a merchantable product, regarding which 208 LAND AND ITS EENT. he lias only to take the risks of a fortunate or unfortunate exchange, or, in the opposite case, as a candidate for employment at the hands of another, through whose consent only can he ob- tain the opportunity to take a part in produc- tion, and with whom, consequently, he has to make terms in advance of production and as a condition precedent to production, — that the industrial position of the individual agent may powerfully affect the distribution of the produce among those who take part in production ; that the injuries suffered in that distribution by the economically weak should result, more or less extensively, in permanent industrial disability, through loss of health and strength, through loss of constitutional energy or corruption of the blood, through loss of self-respect and social ambition, such disability being as real and as lasting as the disabilities incurred in a railway accident, the laborer, in consequence thereof, sinking to a lower industrial grade, beyond the reach of any reparative or restorative forces of a purely economical origin ; and, lastly, that in the reaction of distribution upon production, the whole community and all classes should suffer, both economically and socially ; — how any one can deny these things, I cannot con- THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 209 ceive, although it has mysteriously pleased the economists almost wholly to omit considera- tion of causes of this nature. That the system of small holdings reduces to a minimum the difficulties and the economic dangers attending the distribution of wealth, is implied in the very statement of the case. The great majority of those who work upon the land being self-employed, and the produce being their own, without deduction, the question what they shall receive as the fruit of their labor becomes a question of their own indus- try and prudence, subject alone to the kindness or unkindness of nature in giving the sunshine and the rain in their due season and measure, or the reverse. The reduction of the mass of those who work upon the land to the condition of hired labor- ers brings upon each the necessity of finding a master with whom he must make terms prece- dent to production ; of entering into a compe- tition at once with his fellows as to priority of employment, and with the members of the em- ploying class as to rates of wages and forms of payment, for which competition he may be more or less disqualified by poverty, ignorance, and mental inertia, by distrust of himself or by 14 210 LAND AND ITS RENT. jealousy of others. The condition of the agri- cultural laborers of England during the past hundred years shows that the evils portrayed are not merely imaginary. Fourthly, even more important than the con- siderations relating to the production and the distribution of wealth, bearing upon the tenure of land, which have been indicated, are certain considerations connected with the Consumption of Wealth. Under which system of holdings are the forces which determine the uses to be made of wealth likely to be most favorable to the strength and prosperity of the community? That the ownership of land, in the main, by the cultivating class, promotes frugality and a wiser application of the existing body of wealth, is too manifest to require discussion. The true savings-bank, says Sismondi, is the soil. There is never a time when the owner of land is not painfully conscious of improvements which he desires to make upon his farm, of additions which he desires to make to his stock. For every shilling of money, as for every hour of time, he knows an immediate use. He has not to carry his earnings past a drinking-saloon to find an opportunity to invest them. The THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 211 hungry land is, even at the moment, crying aloud for them. " Day-laborers," says Mr. Mill, " where the laboring class mainly consists of them, are usu- ally improvident ; they spend carelessly to the full extent of their means, and let the future shift for itself. "This is so notorious that many persons, otherwise well affected to the labormg classes, hold it as a fixed opinion that an increase of wages would do them little good, unless accom- panied by at least a corresponding improvement in their tastes and habits. The tendency of peasant proprietors, and of those who hope to become proprietors, is to the contrary extreme, — to take even too much thought for the mor- row. They are oftener accused of penuriousness than of prodigality. They deny themselves reasonable indulgences, and live wretchedly, in order to economize. " In Switzerland almost everybody saves, who has any means of saving ; among the French, though a pleasure-loving and reputed to be a self-indulgent people, the spirit of thrift is dif- fused through the rural population in a manner most gratifying as a whole, and which in in- dividual instances errs rather on the side of excess than defect. .... 212 LAND AND ITS RENT. " But some excess in this direction is a small and passing evil compared with recklessness and improvidence in the laboring classes, and a cheap price to pay for the inestimable worth of the virtue of self-dependence, as the general characteristic of a people, — a virtue which is one of the first conditions of excellence in a hu- man character ; the stock on which, if the other virtues are not grafted, they have seldom any firm root ; a quality indispensable in the case of a laboring class, even to any tolerable degree of physical comfort, and by which the peasantry of France and of most European countries of peasant proprietors are distinguished beyond any other laboring population." Fifthly, the influence upon population of a widely popular tenure of the soil was once mat- ter of dispute ; but the entire effect of European experience during the past generation has been to corroborate the view that no other state of agricultural economy tends, on the whole, so much to discourage an improvident increase of numbers. The reasons herefor cannot be better stated than they have been by M. Sismondi : — " In the countries in which cultivation by small proprietors still continues, population THE BEST HOLDIXG OF THE LAND. 213 increases regularly and rapidly, until it has at- tained its natural limits ; tliat is to say, inheri- tances continue to be divided and subdivided among several sons as long as, by an increase of labor, each family can extract an equal income from a smaller portion of land.^ A father who possessed a vast extent of natural pasture divides it among his sons, and they turn it mto fields and meadows ; his sons divide it among their sons, who abolish fallows ; each improvement in agricultural knowledge admits of another step in the subdivision of property. " But there is no danger that the proprietor will bring up children to make beggars of them. He knows exactly what inheritance he has to leave them ; he knows that the law ^ will divide it equally among them; he sees the limits beyond which partition would make them descend from the rank which he himself has filled ; and a just family pride, common to the peasant and the prmce, makes hhn abstain from summoning into life children for whom he cannot properly provide. If more are born, 1 See ante, pp. 13-16. 2 This has reference to the principle of "Partible Suc- cession," widely incorporated into the law of Continental Europe. 214 LAND AND ITS EENT. at least they do not marry, or they agree among themselves which of several brothers shall per- petuate the family." The power of population strictly to limit itself, under the impulse to preserve family estates from undue subdivision, by the means adverted to in the closing sentence of the paragraph quoted, is strikingly illustrated by Professor Cliffe Leslie, in the facts which he adduces regarding the population of Au- vergne. In the mountains, it appears, the people cling with remarkable tenacity to the conservation of the inheritance unbroken. The daughters willingly consent to take vows and renounce the patrimony of their parents; or, if they con- tract marriage, agree to leave to the head of the family their individual shares of the inheri- tance. It is the same with the sons, of whom some become priests ; others emigrate, consent- ing never to claim any part of the property. One of the sons remains at home, working with the father and mother, and becomes in time the proprietor of the ancestral estate. Thus the principle of equal partition, established by law, is eluded by the connivance of the family, it seldom occurring that the other children assert THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 215 their claims, so fullj accepted is this usage in the manners of the mountains. Professor Leslie, after giving the foregoing as the substance of an official report, adds : " The renunciation by the emigrants of their share in the family property certainly shows, if not an extraordinary imperviousness to new ideas, an extraordinary tenacity of old ones ; and, in par- ticular, of two ideas which are among the old- est in human society, — subordination to the male head of the family, and conservation of the family property unbroken." From the '' London Times," ^ I take the fol- lowing remarkable testimony to the influence of an extensive ownership of land in antago- nizing the procreative force, and in winning for improved living, comfort, luxury, and security of condition, what otherwise would be usurped and wasted upon increase of population, with resulting squalor and poverty : — " Over the greater part of France the standard of comfort and well-being has been increasing ever since the termination of the great war in 1815. The country had been so drained and impoverished by the great wars of Napoleon and by a century and a half of bad government, 1 January 25, 1883. 216 LAND AND ITS EENT. that the general misery of the population was indescribable, and the poverty even of the landed proprietors and middle classes was very great. . . . For many years comfort and well- being, and even luxury, have made their way into the households of all classes in France. The standard of living has risen enormously. The habits of saving and thrift have not been neg- lected. In the art of managing and regularizing their lives, the French people are unrivalled, and the object of every family is to live and to save, at the same time, so as to be able to leave their sons and daughters in as good a position as themselves, at all events, and in a better, if possible. . . . " Among people with such habits and such views of life, the risk and expenditure attend- ant upon a large family are naturally regarded with horror. ' Since two or three children give us sufficient enjoyment of the pleasures of paternity, why,' the greater number of French- men argue, ' should we have more ? With two or three children, we can live comfortably, and save sufficient to leave our children as well off as ourselves; a greater number would in- volve curtailment of enjoyments both for our- selves and our children/ " THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 217 "VVitliout confining myself at all points within strictly economic lines of thought, I have grouped the considerations which lead me to dissent from the opinion of M. Leroy-Beaulieu that if the economic interest which demands the greatest possible production of wealth be found irreconcilable with the moral interest which claims that the greatest number of persons shall be proprietors of land, it is the former which should by all means prevail, the latter which should in all cases give way. Beyond the considerations which I have felt at liberty to adduce, is the interest of the com- munity in the development of the manhood of its citizens, through the individuality and independence of character which spring from working upon the soil that you own. "I believe," wrote Emerson,^ "in the spade and an acre of good ground. Whoso cuts a straight path to his own bread, by the help of God in the sun and rain and sprouting of the grain, seems to me an universal workman. He solves the problem of life, not for one, but for all men of sound body." Still, in addition to this, is the political in- terest which the State has, that as many as may 1 To Carlyle, March 18, 1840. 218 LAND AND ITS EENT. be of its citizens shall be directly interested in the land. Especially with popular institutions is there a strong assurance of peace, order, purity, and liberty, where those who are to make the laws, to pay the taxes, to rally to the support of the Government against foreign invasion or do- mestic violence, are the proprietors of the soil. I would by no means argue in favor of a dull uniformity of petty holdings. Probably Professor Eoscher is right in saying that a mingling of large, medium, and small proper- ties, in which those of medium size predomi- nate, forms the most wholesome of national and economical organizations. In such an organization each class of estates is a help and strength to every other. The great estates afford adequate field and ample capital for advanced experimental agriculture, by the results of which all will, in turn, profit. They set the standard of " the straight furrow, the well-built ricks, and the beautiful lines of drilled corn," to use the enthusiastic phrase of Sir James Caird. The multitude of small proprietors, on the other hand, as Professor Emile de Lave! eye has well expressed it, serve as a kind of political rampart and safeguard for the holders of large THE BEST HOLDING OF THE LAND. 219 estates ; tliey offer the laborer a ready resort to the land, a sort of economical " escape/' in the failure of mechanical employment; and they provide the nation with a solid body of yeo- men, not easily bought or bullied or cajoled by demagogues. In the medium-sized farms, again, may be found united no small measure of the advan- tages of both the large estate and the petty holding, the three degrees together forming the ideal distribution of the soil of any country, where both economical and social considera- tions are taken into account. What, if anything, should be done by the State to promote the right holding of land ? Mr. Thornton's reply to this question is the reply of Diogenes to Alexander : " Get out of my light ! " And, indeed, in a country like our own, with vast unoccupied tracts still available for settlement, with a population active, alert, aggressive, both industrially and socially, and with no vicious traditions, no old abuses, per- verting the natural operation of economic forces to ends injurious to the general interest, it is only needful that the State should keep off its hand, and allow the soil to be parted as the 220 LAND AND ITS RENT. unhelped and unMndered course of sale and bequest may determine. But wherever there is a peasantry unfitted for competition, upon purely commercial principles, with a powerful and wealthy class, under a painful pressure of population, there the regulation of the holding of land becomes a proper matter of State concern.