. JK 421 16 no48 B 1,674,150 The Inter-University Case Program ¡ Corinne Silverman The President's Economic Advisers Published for the ICP by UNIVERSITY OF ALABAMA PRESS University, Alabama b THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN JUN 7 1961 F LIBRARY #48 : 1 THE INTER-UNIVERSITY CASE PROGRAM Cases in Public Administration and Policy Formation The Inter-University Case Program was organized to stimulate the use and writing of case studies as aids to the teaching and practice of public administration and policy formation. By en- couraging the writing and distribution of case studies which depict the work of the executive branch in the governmental process at all levels from local to international, the ICP aims to: 1. 2. explore the manner in which the insights developed by the various social sciences and disciplines can be marshaled in administrative policy making; 3. enlarge the existing basis for realistic generalizations about administrative organization and behavior; 4. make generally available a body of varied case materials useful for teaching purposes, for scholarly inquiry, and for analysis by practitioners in the field of public administra- tion; and secure widespread acceptance of the case study technique as a scholarly tool of research and reporting for use in theses, dissertations, and learned articles. Membership in the ICP is open to all colleges, universities and other institutions concerned with public administration and policy formation; some fifty schools and institutions are now affiliated. The Program is supported by annual subscription-membership fees from participating institutions and by a grant from the Ford Foundation of New York. ICP members receive copies of all ICP publications when issued. ICP publications are listed on the back cover of this pamphlet. The ICP furthers case writing and teaching at universities and allied public administration research centers by publishing selected case studies of high quality written by students, faculty members and other scholars under the auspices of the ICP; by furnishing advisory and editorial services through its Executive Board and central staff; by acting as a clearing house for informa- tion on case development and use; and by allocating funds to assist in the development and writing of case projects proposed by interested persons and approved by the Executive Board. Queries and proposals on membership and on future case studies are welcomed by ICP and should be addressed to Inter-University Case Program, Edwin A. Bock, Staff Director, 45 East 65th Street, New York 21, New York. ICP CASE SERIES: NUMBER 48 The President's Economic Advisers COPYRIGHT 1959 BY THE INTER-UNIVERSITY CASE Program PUBLISHED BY UNIVERSITY OF ALABAMA PRESS, UNIVERSITY, Alabama The Inter-University Case Program The President's Economic Advisers Corinne Silverman Published for the ICP by UNIVERSITY OF ALABAMA PRESS University, Alabama net .35 5-1 #48 JK 421 16 no.48 CORINNE SILVERMAN, author of The Little Rock Story, is a member of the ICP editorial staff and is also the author of The Office of Education Library for the Committee on Public Administration Cases, the forerunner to ICP. Her other works include "The Legislative Process in Massachusetts: The Legislators' View," Public Opinion Quarterly (Summer, 1954); “A Pressure Group and the Pressured," with Oliver Garceau, American Political Science Review (September, 1954); and "Party and the Separation of Power," with V. O. Key, Jr., in Public Policy, ed. by Freidrich and Galbraith (Harvard University Press, 1954). Before joining the ICP staff she was chief assistant to Samuel Lubell. 237-24657 The President's Economic Advisers IN 1946, in accordance with the Employment Act passed that year, three economists were named members of the Council of Economic Advisers and installed in the Executive Office of the President. Their principal duty was to advise President Truman on economic matters and to prepare reports which the President would consider in drawing up his annual eco- nomic message to the Congress now required by the new act. As the CEA began its work, there were many who hoped it would strengthen the quality and rationality of economic decision-making in the government by injecting at the White House level the advice of three professional economists. The three men who were appointed to inaugu- rate the CEA had similar hopes, but they soon found themselves confronted with procedural problems which raised questions about the ex- tent to which, and the manner by which, profes- sional expertise can be effectively incorporated in the making of major policy decisions in a political democracy. The three economists differed on some major economic policy matters. This made it harder for them to resolve their difference on one of the important procedural problems they con- fronted. This was the question of whether the three CEA members should testify before con- gressional committees on economic matters after they had rendered advice privately to the Presi- dent. Was their role solely that of privy adviser to the chief executive or should they also serve as advocates of the policies he finally decided to pursue? If the President ignored his advice, was à CEA member nevertheless obliged to support White House policies at congressional hearings at the expense of his professional conscience? How neutral and confidential could a profes- sional adviser of the President be and still exercise effective influence on policy-making within the executive branch and in the govern- mental process as a whole? The three economists who faced these issues were Edwin G. Nourse, Leon H. Keyserling, and John B. Clark.¹ As the first members of the CEA they were conscious that their actions would set precedents for their successors. This case study describes their actions and then goes on to show how their first successor under the Eisenhower administration-Arthur F. Burns- attempted to resolve the same problems in 1953-1954. The Employment Act of 1946 As the Second World War drew to a close, many economists of all types-government of- mists, bank advisers, and academicians—issued ficials, labor union and trade association econo- predictions of a postwar depression. The general tenor of their analyses, which were accepted in the main by government officials, was that the layoffs from defense plants, disappearance of overtime wages, and the unemployment of re- turning veterans, would result in a sharp fall in personal incomes. This in turn would restrict consumer purchasing power and result in a business spiral into depression. Predictions of unemployment ranged from 8,000,000 to the Federal Reserve Bulletin's 20,000,000.2 It was in this atmosphere that the Employment Act was debated and passed, becoming law on February 20, 1946. The congressmen sponsoring the bill saw it as a means of asserting the re- sponsibility of government to promote full employment. They hoped that one of the long- run results of the Act would be an unprece- dented peacetime total of 60,000,000 jobs. 1 This case was reviewed by the three members of the first Council of Economic Advisers. Some of their com- ments appear as footnotes to the text. 2 Keyserling comments: "I think you should add that there were some economists who did not expect large unemployment after World War II, and that I was among them." 2 Inter- University University Case Program Apart from the underlying thesis that the federal government was to assume some kind of responsibility for the economic health of the country, this declaration of policy was all things to all people—and indeed the Employment Act passed the Senate unanimously. Those interested in fostering government planning read in loud tones the phrase which enjoined the govern- ment to "coordinate and utilize all its plans, functions and resources. . . .” Those who tended more to laissez-faire saw in italics the phrase in a manner calculated to foster and pro- mote free competitive enterprise. What the role of the government was to be under the Act would emerge only from the way in which the purposes of the new legislation were carried CC "J out. However, the economists' predictions soon. proved wrong. There was an unexpectedly smooth transition from wartime to peacetime production. By May 1946 total employment had risen to 55,000,000 from the war-end level of 52,000,000. Only 2,000,000 were unemployed. Consumers rushed to buy the cars, houses, and washing machines they had been waiting for. It appeared that a major postwar economic problem was not to be unemployment but inflation. But the Employment Act was by no means obsolete. The Act had been cast in a larger frame than guaranteeing full or maximum em- ployment. It had been conceived fundamentally as an expression of a new consensus about government responsibility for the economy-a consensus achieved after the debates and trials- and-errors of the thirties. The Act had received much of its support in Congress because few disagreed with its basic premises: first, that the country could not af ford, nor would public opinion accept, another great depression; and second, that positive gov- ernment action could and should prevent extended periods of economic distress. Debate in Congress had centered on the more difficult questions of when the government should take action, how much government action was pos- sible or desirable, and what kinds of policies. would be effective in which situations. The final declaration of policy of the Em- ployment Act was a cumbersome sentence of over 100 words, riddled with many qualifica- tions resulting from legislative compromises: The Congress hereby declares that it is the con- tinuing policy and responsibility of the Federal Gov- crnment to use all practicable means consistent with its needs and obligations and other essential con- siderations of national policy, with the assistance and cooperation of industry, agriculture, labor, and state and local governments to coordinate and utilize all its plans, functions, and resources for the pur- pose of creating and maintaining, in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitive enterprise and the general welfare, conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment op- portunities, including self-employment for those able, willing, and seeking to work, and to promote maxi- mum employment, production, and purchasing power. (Public Law 304, 79th Congress, Sec. 2) The New Obligations of the Federal Government Although the Act was ambiguous as to the scope and nature of the new policy obligations of the government, it was clear about the ma- chinery to be established. The Act called upon the President to present an annual Economic Report to Congress in addition to the traditional State of the Union and Budget messages. It also established the Council of Economic Advisers in the Executive Office of the President, and a Joint Committee on the Economic Report in the Congress. The Joint Committee was to re- ceive the President's economic message and to report to the House and Senate its own recom- mendations on each of the major proposals in the President's message. The Council's principal tasks were to assist the President in drawing up his new annual message, to advise him on economic trends, to appraise current economic policies, and to de- velop and to recommend to the President national economic policies. The Council was also to collect from existing governmental agencies statistical information on economic developments and trends. There had been considerable debate in Con- gress on whether a separate Council was de- sirable. The Treasury The Treasury Department already reported directly to the President on the state of the economy and recommended fiscal policies. The Bureau of the Budget also reported to the The President's Economic Advisers President on the effect of current and proposed economic policies, including the impact on the economy of the total federal budget. However, neither of the two agencies wished the other to be designated as the top adviser and co- ordinator of economic policies, and so a separate Council of Economic Advisers was established. In the next year or two the Executive Office of the President was to be expanded further by the creation, for example, of the National Se- curity Council and the re-location in the Execu- tive Office of the Joint Chiefs of Staff. But the Council of Economic Advisers had to break new ground in deciding whether it would act solely as privy adviser to the President with no deal- ings with Congress on policy issues, or whether it would follow the example of the Bureau of the Budget. The Bureau was also part of the Executive Office, but it had a single head and its director had always worked closely with congressional committees and testified at con- gressional hearings in support of presidential policies. 3 The Members of the Council The Employment Act was passed in February 1946. President Truman offered positions on the Council to a number of economists, but it was not until July 25, 1946 that he received three acceptances. Edwin G. Nourse accepted the position of Chairman, Leon H. Keyserling became Vice Chairman, and John D. Clark filled the third place. The Act did not specifically invest the Chairman with any extra powers or duties. None of the three had met before being nominated to the Council. Edwin G. Nourse was then 63. He had taught at a number of universities until 1923 when he became associated with The Brookings Institu- tion, a non-profit research foundation in Wash- ington. He became director of Brookings' of Brookings' 3 The Executive Office of the President may be divided into (1) the President and his personal staff, and (2) the other more formal agencies such as the Bureau of the Budget and the CEA. Traditionally, there is a con- fidential relationship between the President and his personal staff. Unlike CEA appointments, the President's appointments of his personal staff aides and of the Director of the Bureau of the Budget do not require Senate confirmation. من 3 Institute of Economics in 1929, and was vice president of The Brookings Institution at the time his appointment to CEA was announced. He had served as president of the American Farm Economic Association in 1924 and of the American Economic Association in 1942, and he had been chairman of the Social Science Re- search Council from 1942 to 1945. He was generally regarded as middle-of-the-road to con- servative. Politically, Nourse claimed he was "non-political" and "non-partisan.” His father had been a member of the Prohibition Party, and Nourse himself had voted only twice in presidential elections, once for a Republican and once for a Democrat. (Since the 1920s, as a resident of the District of Columbia, he had been unable to vote.) John D. Clark, then 62, was generally con- sidered to be the most conservative of the three. He had had a rather unusual career, starting as a lawyer, at one time serving as counsel for the Midwest Refining Company. Then he be- came vice president of Standard Oil of Indiana. Successful in business, he decided to turn to teaching. He resigned from Standard Oil, re- turned to college, and received a Ph.D. in economics in 1931. He taught economics for ten years at the University of Denver and at the University of Nebraska, and then he became dean of the College of Business Administration at the University of Nebraska. Sandwiched be- tween these academic posts was a short stint Legislature. During the 1940s he was appointed as a Democratic representative in the Wyoming sions. His political activities in Wyoming had to a number of political committees or commis- brought him close to Wyoming's Democratic Senator Joseph O'Mahoney, one of the co- sponsors of the Employment Act, and he was regarded by some as the Senator's protegé. Clark did not consider himself a "conservative” econo- mist, and his position on questions pondered by the Council of Economic Advisers seemed to confirm this estimate of himself. Leon H. Keyserling, only 38 when he was appointed to the Council, had a reputation as one of Washington's "boy wonders." His pro- fessional training had been in both law and economics. He had received a degree from Har- vard Law School, and he had also completed 4 two years of graduate courses in economics at Columbia University. He entered government service as a lawyer for the Agricultural Adjust- ment Administration in 1933 and almost im- mediately became legislative assistant to New York's Democratic Senator Robert F. Wagner. He remained associated with Wagner until 1937 when he became general counsel of the U. S. Housing Authority. He rose to be acting ad- ministrator of the Authority and then general counsel of the National Housing Agency. Dur- ing this period Keyserling had his fingers in almost every pie baking in the New Deal ovens. He became involved in the drafting of the Na- tional Industrial Recovery Act, various public works, farm, and banking acts, the Social Se- curity Act, and the National Labor Relations Act. He also did staff work on economic ques- tions for a number of congressional committees. As direct qualifications for nomination to the Council of Economic Advisers, Keyserling had assisted in drafting the bill which ultimately became the Employment Act of 1946; and he had maintained close connections with Senator Wagner, one of the co-sponsors of the original bill. Also, Keyserling had attracted attention when he won the second prize of $10,000 in the Pabst Brewing Company's postwar employ- ment essay contest in 1944.4 Inter-University These background sketches do not shed any light on the personalities of the three men, nor on how they fit together. There were people who had the opportunity to assess the members: the Council had a professional staff of twenty or so economists; also there were liaison per- sonnel between the Council and the White House, the Bureau of the Budget, the Federal Reserve Board, and the Treasury Department. This case will draw on the recollections of four such persons. Commentator A described the Council mem- bers this way: Nourse's reputation with us was that he was a Case Program wise man with scholarly achievements. His views on policy were limited: he had been in agricultural eco- nomics most of his life. He was relatively conserva- tive-not when viewed on the spectrum of economists, but when viewed as an appointee of a Democratic administration. He was personally liked and re- spected. He was also known as relatively inflexible on sub- stantive economic matters. This was the major reason why there were difficulties. He was willing to recog- nize political realities-for example, the Democratic platform might have said something about price supports which Nourse was not in favor of, but he was willing to go along. However, he chafed under it. He was not used to the kind of policy-making where there is discussion and dissension over policy, then a decision is made, and thereafter the ranks close behind the decision. 4 One of Keyserling's theses in this essay was that plan- ning and the development of economic policies should be a joint executive-legislative function. He suggested the establishment of a continuing American Economic Committee. This committee, Keyserling wrote, should be composed of representatives from the Senate, House, Cabinet, industry, labor, and agriculture. Keyserling had no difficulty with this problem, partly because his views were nearer the President's, partly because he was by training a lawyer and gov- ernment official. Keyserling was regarded as a hard working man with a somewhat abrupt and sometimes abrasive manner. Clark was the dark horse. He turned out to be a man who had spent most of his life in business and had just about retired. He had a vigorous mind and unorthodox ideas. He suffered from the narrowness of his background. He was the easiest personality of the three. On administrative policy issues the Council often split with Keyserling and Clark against Nourse. But it is very important to remember that on economic questions they agreed about eighty percent of the time. Commentator B observed: Nourse was a formalistic thinker. That's one reason why he and Keyserling didn't get along very well. Keyserling didn't have a Ph.D. in economics so Nourse sometimes acted as though he didn't know anything about economics. Of course Keyserling resented this attitude. This latter observation was repeated in sub- stance by several persons close to the Council. It may or may not have been accurate. But the fact that others placed this interpretation on Nourse's opinion of Keyserling made for strain between the two. Relations with the White House The Council members were formally ap- pointed in August 1946. By October a staff had been recruited, and CEA offices were set up The President's Economic Economic Advisers in the Executive Office Building, near the White House. The Bureau of the Budget is also located in this building. The Council's first substantive task was preparing the draft of the President's first eco- nomic message to Congress-the draft con- taining the Council's analysis of "foreseeable economic trends" and its suggestions for national economic policy and program. Here, the newness of the Council presented difficulties. The CEA had no regular channels for co-ordinating its proposed recommendations with those in the drafts of the other two mes- sages which were to be presented to Congress in the first week of January—the State of the Union and the Budget messages. The procedure this first year was somewhat disorganized, with co-ordination coming only the last two weeks in December through the joint efforts of the Council and members of the staff of John Steel- man, the Assistant to the President. There was nothing in this half-hour interview which in any way suggested that the President was in- terested in the content of the work our staff was doing or in the conclusions toward which we were moving. the White House staff. In 1953, quoting from a diary which he kept during his Council years, Nourse referred to an interview he had had with the President in November 1946, during the preparation of the first draft of the eco- nomic message: • While he has accepted the material which we have presented to him for use in the Economic Reports and passed it on without material change and with only minor omissions, there is no clear evidence that at any juncture we have had any tangible influence on the formation of policy or the adoption of any course of action or feature of a program.5 And, Nourse wrote: When it came to using the Council as an in- tellectual staff arm of the Presidency . . the Presi- dent was quite evidently at sea. 20 Writing in his diary in 1947, Nourse again expressed dissatisfaction: • 5 In the following years a rift developed within the White House staff between John Steelman and Clark Clifford, the President's legal coun- sel. In time, each of the CEA members, along with many other government officials, found he was relying on a different person to serve as a channel of communication with the President. Nourse felt Steelman was more receptive to his way of thinking; Keyserling had more of a bond with Clifford. Clark found easier access through influential members of Congress. On economic questions to be discussed in presidential mes- sages co-ordination was effected by the establish- ment of work groups comprised of staff members from the White House office, the Bureau of the Budget, and the CEA. Many of these staff people had been trained in the Bureau of the Budget. The work groups, forming a network of people by a disgruntled former official on record. Dr. Nourse who knew each other and had worked together, not only bridged the cleavage between Steelman and Clifford, but connected the Bureau of the Budget, the Treasury, the CEA, and the White House, as well as any department concerned with a major economic matter that would be mentioned in a presidential message. 5 Keyserling comments: "Dr. Nourse's habitual assertions that he was not accorded the utmost considerate treat- ment by President Truman is in my opinion one of the most extreme cases of unfair treatment of a President could see the President whenever he wanted to. The President gave him a great deal of time. . . . Dr. Nourse was simply unable to adjust himself to the nature and the problems of the Presidency. He could never under- stand that the President of the United States has too many things to do to engage in long bull sessions on economics of the kind that take place at The Brookings Institution. He could never understand that the President must delegate, must have confidence in his principal of- ficers, and that these officers have no just cause for com- plaint when the President not only remains accessible to them but also accepts practically everything that they recommend to him." Keyserling and Clark had no difficulty with. this system. Nourse, however, had been dis- turbed by the extent to which responsibility for the draft of the first economic message had been delegated by the President to members of There was really no basis for Nourse's feeling that the Council was rejected by the President. The White House took the Council members very seriously. Their views were sought and listened to on every occasion they should have been. But Nourse may have wished the Council was something it was not and couldn't These relationships between the Council members and the President were seen by Com- mentator A in this way: 6 Inter - University Case Program Relations with Congress The Employment Act had provided that the Joint Committee on the Economic Report, aided by a professional staff, should review the President's economic message and present a report of its own to Congress. The Joint Com- mittee was composed of seven senators appointed by the president of the Senate, and seven repre- sentatives appointed by the speaker of the House. The party composition reflected roughly the party division in each of the two houses. The first Joint Committee included many of the senators and representatives who had played an active role in the debate and passage of the Employment Act. Democratic Senator Joseph O'Mahoney, who had been one of the co-sponsors of the bill, was expected to be the Committee's first chairman. However, the Republicans gained a majority in Congress in the 1946 elections, and Senator Robert A. Taft became chairman. hope to be. It was set up as a separate, advisory agency with no control or power.6 It was not part of a regular flow of procedures and documents. The Council had to make new connections or else wait until people came to consult it-things did not flow across its path in the same way as things routed through the Bureau of the Budget. One of the origi- nal ideas had been to give the responsibility to the Bureau of the Budget, making the Council a special section within the Bureau. If that had been done, the Council would have had a more direct way of having its views made effective through influencing the budget. However, the Council did have the initiative when it came to the draft of the economic message. That was a device for approaching issues on the Council's terms. There the Council didn't have to wait to see whether it was invited in. The real question in determining whether anyone paid proper attention to the Council is whether it was consulted in time to have its views considered, and whether it had access to the information it needed to formulate its views. On these scores the Council had no complaints. Commentator C saw the relationship between them this way: It was all a matter of temperament. The President was a man who knew his limitations. He knew he was not a scholar. He was a politician. He was some- what awed by expertise. He just couldn't sit down and jaw with a man with the scholarly reputation and mien of Dr. Nourse. Nourse, on the other hand, wanted to sit down and "ponder" problems with the President. And Commentator D observed: That's the way Truman worked. You had to work through his subordinates. Nourse never really ac- cepted this, so the other members of the Council were sometimes able to outflank him by using White House staff channels more effectively. 6 Nourse comments: "I did wish for the Council to be something it was not-that is, a purely advisory agency of the highest professional competence and political de- tachment. But the implication of this passage that I wished it to be an agency of 'control or power' is com- pletely erroneous, as is abundantly shown in other parts of this document." Clark comments: “Mr. Keyserling and I wanted the Council to be a powerful influence in devising and securing the understanding and acceptance of sound economic policies to save prosperity." The President delivered his first economic message in January 1947, but the members of the Joint Committee were occupied primarily with problems attendant on the shift of party control. They did not hold extensive hearings on the 1947 message or prepare more than a mimeographed report of a few pages. Although the Joint Committee began to hold hearings during 1947 on a variety of subjects, the issue of the relationship of the Council of Economic Advisers to congressional committees arose first with the Senate Foreign Relations Committee. In June 1947, Secretary of State George C. Marshall delivered his famous Commencement Address at Harvard, suggesting a program of economic aid to Europe. That same month President Truman set in motion three studies on the impact of a foreign aid program upon the domestic economy. One of these studies was made by the Council of Economic Advisers, which submitted its report to the President in October of that year. The next month the Foreign Relations Com- mittee scheduled hearings on the European Recovery Plan and tentatively scheduled ap- pearances before the Committee by the Chair- man of the CEA. When Nourse was advised by the Committee secretary of the proposed invita- tion, he explained that he would be "embar- rassed by a formal invitation to testify" and that Economic Advisers The President's Economic he had taken the position that Council members should not appear, even before the Joint Com- mittee on the Economic Report. Nourse stated that he had taken this position to protect the relationship between Council members and the President. He had explained his position to his colleagues and to the Presi- dent: the Joint Committee on the Economic Report might try to draw Council members into a discussion of policy positions taken by the President in his economic message. Some of these policy positions might not have followed the drafted recommendations of the Council. Or, the Council members might disagree among themselves as to the advisability of some of the President's positions. To date, there had been no major divergence between the Council and the President, and only minor disagreements among Council members, but, Nourse explained, either situation might arise in the future and cause embarrassment both to the President and the Council members. It would be wise, he felt, to establish precedents to prevent such mutual embarrassment. The President indicated to Nourse, when the subject was first raised, that he agreed that the Council should protect itself against such situa- tions, but he added that at the same time the Council should not remain aloof from the work of the Joint Committee. Neither of Nourse's two colleagues were happy with the Chairman's position. Clark, for one, argued that a "policy of aloofness from congressional committees" such as Nourse sug- gested would impede "the machinery set up by the Employment Act of 1946 to secure congres- sional approval of economic policies recom- mended by the President upon the advice of the Council of Economic Advisers." When the issue arose on the question of testifying be- fore the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, Nourse's point of view was accepted by the Committee. Keyserling and Clark deferred to this view although they disagreed with it. From time to time, the members of the CEA were invited by various congressional commit- tees to testify on economic matters, and in each instance Nourse's view prevailed, and invitations were declined. By 1948 the issue of testifying or not had become a source of considerable tension among the Council members. 7 The President Recalls Congress This was an election year. Harry Truman, regarded by many as a "caretaker" and Presi- dent only by accident, was almost alone in feeling he had any chance of being re-elected. In July, President Truman, when accepting the Democratic nomination, made a surprise an- nouncement to the convention: he was going to call back into session the Republican-controlled 80th Congress to consider his eight-point emer- gency program for inflation control. Inflation was still a serious problem, and Truman seized on this tactic to dramatize his idea that respon- sibility lay with Congress. Keyserling and Clark were firmly convinced Council members should testify before congres- sional committees at the special session. Clark felt the Council was on probation, since the House Appropriations Committee had just cut the Council budget sharply. Clark still had ringing in his ears the words of the report of the Appropriations subcommittee: The testimony of this agency was lamentably weak. There was strong sentiment in the committee for the complete elimination of all funds for the agency. There is little evidence of any important results from its work of interpretation, and it takes the po- sition that its views and recommendations are confi- dential except to the President, unless released by him. Nourse did not agree with Keyserling and Clark that their reduced budget was a result of their refusal to testify. He interpreted it as a reflection of the Republican majority's antago- nism to President Truman and his advisers, and its dislike of the Employment Act. The issue of Council members testifying was finally resolved. Nourse described the decision process this way: "After numerous telephone conversations with Mr. Steelman, Mr. Clifford, Mr. [Paul] Porter and Mr. [Robert] Turner,8 7 Paul Porter had been the last head of the wartime Office of Price Administration. He was at that time one of Truman's principal campaign advisers and was co- ordinating presentations to congressional committees at the special sessions. 8 Robert Turner had been director of the Foreign Divi- sion of the War Production Board during World War II, had been a staff member of the Office of War Mo- bilization and Reconversion, and was then assistant to John Steelman. He was one of the principal liaison men between the White House staff and the CEA. 8 and with lengthy conferences on the Williams- burg [the President's yacht] between the Presi- dent, the White House aides, and Mr. Porter, and after positions had been taken and reversed, as I recall it, four times within the week, the President's final decision was given me in his letter of August 13." The letter read: Inter-University Case Pro gr a m you would want an entirely different kind of chairman, and I would want to be relieved of the position at once. . . ." In the second draft— the one the President received in December 1948-Nourse said principally that in view of his age and the hard work and tensions in- volved in the job, he hoped he could be relieved soon. Dear Dr. Nourse, Mr. Paul Porter has raised with me the question of whether I would regard it as appropriate for mem- bers of the Council of Economic Advisers to testify before Congressional committees concerning the anti- inflation program I have recommended to the Con- gress. As you know, I have considered from time to time in the past the question. . . . I am aware of the difference between your views on this subject and the views held by your colleagues on the Council. I respect these varying views, which I am sure all of you hold most conscientiously. Under these circumstances, it seems that the wisest course in the present instance is to permit the mem- bers of the Council to be guided by their own con- victions. Accordingly, I do not wish to induce any member of the Council to testify if he feels it in- appropriate for him to do so; nor do I wish to restrain any member from testifying if he feels that to be an appropriate part of his duties. I am informing Mr. Porter of this letter, with the expectation that he will make arrangements for tes- timony by the members of the Council if any testi- mony is to be presented by them. Sincerely, /s/ Harry S. Truman Keyserling appeared before the Senate Bank- ing and Currency Committee a few days later. Nourse was invited to appear but was excused by the Committee chairman. This became the practice during the rest of 1948, and in 1949. Keyserling and Clark appeared before several committees; Nourse was invited, but he declined and was excused.9 Nourse's Letter of Resignation Immediately after the election of 1948 Nourse submitted his resignation to President Truman. He wrote two drafts of his resignation. The first draft, which he never sent to the President, included the thought that if the Council was "in any way to be assigned a political role or to be allowed to stray over into political activi- ties or lay itself open to political influences, The President did not respond to the letter of resignation, and Nourse did not actually re- sign until a year later. However, during the year the issue became more and more a source of bitter argument among the Council mem- bers. Nourse clung to his view that any appear- ances before Congress meant that the Council was taking on a political role. Keyserling and Clark were convinced that it was the duty of the Council to be the President's economic ambassadors to and tutors of Congress. Tensions grew, also, over the kinds of public speeches both Nourse and Keyserling were making. Nourse had taken the position that he did not want to be forced into criticizing the President before congressional committees. Yet, Keyserling pointed out, Nourse did not seem to hesitate to criticize the President's position in public speeches. Nourse's reply was that he 9 Keyserling comments: "The important thing is that I refrained from appearing before Congressional commit- tees during the first year of the Council operations, and thus made the concession to Dr. Nourse of being bound by his views, although they were the minority view. I would have been willing to do this throughout the period of our joint service on the Council. But even though I made this concession, Dr. Nourse persisted in making a public issue of it, which was entirely inappropriate on a matter of Council procedure, and which violated his own profession of desire to avoid public controversy. He made a speech on this subject to the National Planning Asso- ciation before I had ever testified. He carried stories on the disagreement into the public press. He imputed po- litical motivation to his colleagues. I frequently pointed out to him how entirely unreasonable and inconsiderate this was, in view of the concession which the other mem- bers of the Council at that time were making to his views. But he persisted in this course of personal attack and disparagement in public forums, and it was this which led me ultimately to the view that nothing was to be gained by refraining further from appearing be- fore Congressional committees, a position which I be- lieved to be correct in substance, and which in fact was held by a majority of the Council." 9 Council members began to be felt during 1949 when production, employment, and prices all declined. By mid-June 1949 unemployment was over 3,000,000. The government policy Nourse favored was allowing the recession to find its own bottom. He opposed expansion of the gov- ernment expenditures as a means of pumping buying power into the economy. Inflationary deficit spending by the government, he be- lieved, was not the way to cope with the recession. Keyserling favored more aggressive anti-slump policies.10 In his mid-year economic message to Congress, President Truman said, "We cannot have prosperity by getting adjusted to the idea of a depression." The President went on to repeat his January requests including improved supports for farm income, an increase in the minimum wage, more unemployment and old age assistance. He specifically rejected any increase in taxation. This program of increased benefits with no additional revenue portended a budget deficit for the coming year. The President's Economic Advisers could choose his own ground in making speeches, but he could not choose which questions to answer in congressional hearings. In turn, he criticized Keyserling for appearing before such partisan groups as the Americans for Demo- cratic Action. Public appearances, Nourse felt, should be limited to academic, civic, business, labor, or agricultural organizations. (The or- ganizations before which Nourse had appeared included such groups as the Controllers Insti- tute of America, the U. S. Chamber of Com- merce, the Executives Club of Chicago, and the Illinois Tech Alumni Association.) For his part, Keyserling felt the audience was less im- portant than the content of the speech. Early in 1949 Nourse received considerable press at- tention for his public criticism of a pending presidential proposal. Keyserling wrote Nourse a memorandum pointing out that his own ac- tions had never drawn attention for such a reason. Nourse replied that on several occasions in the past he had been "deeply concerned" when Keyserling or Clark had made speeches conveying the impression that their personal professional views were in fact the positions of the Council. A Single Head? In January 1949 the first of the Hoover Com- mission reports appeared-the Report on Gen- eral Management of the Executive Branch. (Un- der the chairmanship of former President Her- bert Hoover, the non-partisan Commission prepared a series of reports aimed at improving the administrative efficiency of government de- partments. It recommended specific reorganiza- tion plans.) The Hoover Commission's comments and recommendations concerning the CEA re- flected much of the general feeling that the Council's problems were at least partly tied to its organizational structure. The Report recom- Economic Differences The separate economic orientations of the two men also made for difficulties. These pro- fessional differences began to be felt late in 1948 and during 1949. A split first developed over the moot question of how much the na- tion could spend on national defense without increasing inflationary pressures to a dangerous extent. Nourse took the position that a thirteen billion dollar defense program was close to the outer limit of safety-presumably a safety de- fined in terms of economic stability. Keyserling argued that the economy could stand a sub- stantial increase in the defense effort if this should prove necessary for national security. President Truman asserted his desire for a fifteen billion dollar ceiling on defense spend- ing-much closer to Nourse's position than to Keyserling's—and the defense budget was held under that limit until the outbreak of the Ko- rean War shot defense expenditures to $22 billion in 1951 and $45 billion in 1952. Another source of disagreement among the larged national income. This is standard economics." Keyserling comments: "An increase in expenditures without an increase in tax rates does not necessarily portend a budget deficit if it produces sufficient eco- nomic recovery to enlarge tax receipts through an en- 10 Nourse comments: "There is a faulty implication of laissez faire in saying: 'Nourse favored allowing the re- cession to find its own bottom. . . .' The fact was that I was urging on both labor and management that they had a responsibility for working out sound wage and price adjustments for checking recession and quickening recovery rather than looking to the government for the inflationary devices of deficit spending." 10 Inter-University Case Pro gr a m Keyserling felt they were arms of the President. Like other agencies, they were established by Con- gress to do a certain job and were confirmed in their positions by Congress. They were, he felt, account- able to Congress. mended that the CEA be replaced by an Office of the Economic Adviser and that it have a single head: ... at least potentially it is handicapped by being a multiheaded body, with the requirement that its members be confirmed by the Senate. To put a full-time board at the head of a staff agency is to run the risk of inviting public disagree- ments among its members and of transplanting within the President's Office the disagreements on policy issues that grow up in the executive depart- ments or in Congress. It also makes cooperation with related staff agencies more difficult.11 In 1949 the Council broke with another prac- tice. Previously, in its quarterly reports to the President on economic policies, or in its annual and mid-year drafts of presidential economic messages, the Council members had attempted to reconcile differences of opinion and present a single viewpoint to the President. However, in the preparation of the draft of the President's mid-year report in 1949, Nourse found he dif- fered with his colleagues to such an extent that he wrote a minority report. Finally, on September 9, 1949 Nourse wrote Truman that "if the work of the Council is to be kept from serious demoralization," he felt he should tell his colleagues that he wished to retire so that they could get on with the job of preparing the draft of the 1950 economic message. This time Nourse's resignation was accepted, and he left the Council on November 1. Leon Keyserling became Acting Chairman and subsequently was appointed the second Chairman. Commentator C said of Nourse's resignation: Nourse wanted to avoid a possible difficult situation which actually never was a real situation. Nourse, so far as I could tell, diverged from the President's position only on very minor points. But Nourse felt the Council members were confidential advisers. • 11 Keyserling comments: "It is significant that the Hoover Commission's recommendation was preceded by discus- sions between representatives of that Commission and Dr. Nourse, but no effort was made to obtain the views of the other members of the Council. Further, Dr. Nourse never informed the other members of the Council of his discussions on this point, which is to my mind one example of his improper concept of the relationships among the three members of the Council." But behind those positions was another factor- the personalities of the two. Nourse didn't like the limelight. Keyserling loved it. Many public sources attributed Nourse's resig- nation more to a combination of reasons. The influential British weekly, The Economist, re- ported on October 29: The open split in the Council between Dr. Nourse on the one hand, and Mr. Keyserling and Dr. Clark on the other, has for over a year made it likely that Dr. Nourse would resign. Their disagreement is merely the latest of a series over economic policy and practice which has plagued Washington since the scope and responsibilities of government began to grow under the impact of the great depression nearly twenty years ago. It was in a speech last week that Dr. Nourse most bluntly outlined the reasons for his determination to press his resignation and made it inevitable that the President should accept it . . . his bitterest criticism was reserved for the apparent willingness to accept deficit financing as a "way of life." That [the CEA] should split was perhaps in- evitable, but is nevertheless regrettable. Dr. Nourse is far from a proponent of laissez faire, but he has a caution as to the extent of government activity which is not shared by the other two members. . . . He likewise holds the conviction that a council appointed to advise the President should do exactly that and no more, while the other two believe its functions should include open advocacy . . . [of] policies felt to be appropriate. The proper character of the new organization has therefore also been an issue. The Washington Post sympathized editorially with Nourse's view that the Council should be politically neutral. But, the Post went on, • we think that Dr. Nourse seriously impaired his influence with the President by delivering speeches in which he openly criticized some Administration policies and made it quite plain that he did not agree with the views of his colleagues on various important issues. If he had stuck to his thesis that a presidential adviser should reserve his opinions for the council table, it is our belief that he would have been more effective as a dissenter, and might still be in a position to render useful service as a member of the Advisory Council. • • The President's Economic Advisers As Keyserling Saw It In 1952 Leon Keyserling, then Chairman of the CEA, was testifying before a subcommittee of the Joint Committee on the Economic Re- port. He was asked by Senator Paul Douglas to explain exactly what his position was on this issue: was not the Council primarily an adviser to the President, Douglas asked, and if this was true could Council members be frank with Con- gress? Keyserling answered with this statement: It is .. clear that the members of the Council are employees of and advisers to the President, and that they are not employees of and advisers to the Congress in the same sense. But this does not mean, in my opinion, that the members of the Council cannot or should not testify before, cooperate and consult with, and in a sense give advice to, committees of the Congress, just as this is done by heads of other agencies in the execu- tive branch, and even other agencies in the Executive Office of the President. · • In all of these cases. . . none of these officials, except in rare instances, makes available to the pub- lic or to the Congress the nature of the advice he gives to the President while he is assisting and ad- vising the President in the preparation of such Presidential messages and the recommendations con- tained therein; and likewise, it is only in rare in- stances that such officials make it known to the public or even to the Congress if there is a variance between the advice they give to the President and the extent to which the President follows that ad- vice. . . . Nonetheless after the Presidential message in question and the recommendations contained therein are sent to the Congress . . . it has been practically the universal custom and is entirely ap- propriate for those officials whose statutory respon- sibility makes it clear that they have been advisers to the President in the field covered by such Presi- dential message and recommendations to appear be- fore such congressional committees, to discuss and analyze the matters involved, and in fact to amplify and support the recommendations made by the President and the analysis underlying it. In addition, it has been the almost universal custom and entirely appropriate for such officials to appear before con- gressional committees and to make analyses and give advice in the fields in which they operate under statute, even when this has not been preceded by a Presidential message. In appearing before committees of the Congress in this role, I cannot see where the Council of Eco- nomic Advisers is doing any different or appearing • • 11 in any different light from what is done by heads of other agencies working in different fields. Certainly, the distinction cannot be that members of the Council deal with economic problems, because many heads of many other agencies deal with eco- nomic problems, or even predominantly with eco- nomic problems. • That this construction of the Council's role is cor- rect is supported by the legislative history of the Employment Act, by the expressed views of some of the legislative sponsors of the Act, by the fact that the Joint Committee on the Economic Report and other congressional committees have frequently invited the members of the Council to appear be- fore them for this purpose, and by the fact that doing so is in accord with the Council's responsi- bilities as defined by the President. More important, it is in accord with the whole tenor of the American system of government, and I believe it a good and healthy thing that public officials should be sub- jected to the questioning and testing of their views by congressional committees, particularly when these public officials have been appointed and confirmed under acts of Congress to deal with the very subject matters which these committees are considering and to help in the preparation of the very reports and recommendations which the President sends to these committees. The next phase of the question is whether the members of the Council are in a position to express themselves frankly and fully to congressional com- mittees, in view of the fact that they are advisers to the President, and in view of the fact that the advice and recommendations that they give to the President may at times not be exactly the same as the advice and recommendations which the President transmits to the Congress. There has been considerable in- terest in this subject, and I am glad of this op- portunity to express my views. I believe that members of the Council of Economic Advisers are in exactly the same position, with re- spect to expressing themselves frankly and fully be- fore congressional committees, as any other agency heads of integrity who had advised the President in important fields in which the President makes recom- mendations to the Congress. Under our system, no responsible official in such a position, while working for the President, parades before the public or be- fore congressional committees the differences of view- point that there may be between himself and the President on matters under consideration by the Congress. If these differences are minor in character, the responsible public official does not feel entitled to the luxury of self-satisfaction of having the Presi- dent agree with him in every detail; government 12 Inter - University Case Program subcommittee to assume what is in fact the truth, that the analyses and recommendations which I make to it are consistent with the analyses and recommen- dations which I make to the President. So long as the recommendations made by the President to the Congress conform in the main to the recommenda- tions which I have given him, I feel privileged and duty-bound in appearing before a congressional com- mittee to give my reasons for supporting those recom- mendations. If the President were to fundamentally repudiate my views as to what is in the nation's economic interest, and were to send recommendations to the Congress in basic conflict with them, then I would resign. That situation has not arisen. At all times, consequently, I hope this subcommittee will feel that the analyses and recommendations I present to it represent my honest convictions. I would not present them if they did not. could not function if that were expected. But if the President, in his recommendations to the Congress, were to depart from the analysis and advice given him by the official in question to the extent that it could be regarded as a fundamental repudiation of that official's views, the official of integrity should resign where under all the circumstances he believes it in the national interest to do so. But it seems to me incorrect to say that a public official in this kind of job can place himself in open conflict with the President for whom he works, and at the same time stay on the job. Obviously, also, a man of integrity should resign if the President for whom he works should ask him to go before a congressional com- mittee or anywhere else and stultify himself by mak- ing analyses or supporting policies which this official believes to be against the national interest. The view has been expressed in some quarters, that members of the Council of Economic Advisers, in order never to be faced with a choice based upon the situation described above, should solve the prob- lem by advising the President but by refusing to appear before congressional committees to analyze and support those recommendations by the President to the Congress which are in accord with the advice they have given him. I can see no more reason why the members of the Council should duck their basic responsibilities by so doing than why other officials should thus avoid their responsibilities. Under our system, if it is to function and if congressional com- mittees are intelligently to process reports and recom- mendations sent to them by the President, there must be and there always has been someone from the executive branch available and ready to come before the congressional committees and to work with them in the customary fashion. With respect to analyses and recommendations sent by the President to the Congress in those areas of economic policy which are the province of the Council as defined by statute, if the members of the Council are not the proper persons to come before the congressional committees for this purpose, then who are the proper persons? If my analysis is at all correct, it seems to me that for a member of a congressional committee to raise a question about my freedom to be frank, or whether I agree with the recommendations made by the Presi- dent, or whether after the President has sent up recommendations I am estopped from expressing my own views, is the same as asking that question of the head of some other statutory agency of govern- ment appearing before a congressional committee. My own answer to the question is as follows: I always have and always will try to speak frankly and deal fairly with congressional committees. I ask the As Nourse Saw It Nourse explained his point of view this way:12 One of the most important considerations, I felt, was for us to build the precedents properly. The Executive Office was only seven years old, and the Council was a completely new agency. I felt I should think ahead carefully. I was impressed that other people would have to sleep in the bed I was making. I felt there were, theoretically, three levels on which the Council could operate. The first would be for us to draw up abstract economic analyses. The second would be for us to make our analyses, taking into consideration the impact on the various institutional structures of the country-the labor in- stitutions, the banking setup, and so forth. This I considered to be economically realistic, and this is what I attempted to do. The third level would be to make analyses taking into account the different pressure groups which bear on an issue and try to make analyses which would be accepted by them. This, I felt, was none of our business. This was the role of the politician. Keyserling and Clark disagreed with me.13 12 Based on a transcript of a recorded interview, July 1958. 13 Keyserling comments: "No evidence can be brought to bear to support the allegation that either Clark or I took positions in which we did not substantively believe. .. Dr. Clark and I did, of course, take account of the practicality of policy recommendations from the viewpoint of their institutional acceptability, and this is within the proper scope of economics in the public service. Dr. Nourse's statement . that Keyserling and Clark wanted to be policy makers is also categorically false. • • • The President's Economic Economic The sharpest difference between me and my col- leagues was that I differentiated clearly between economic analysis and political synthesis. Keyserling and Clark wanted to be policy makers. But I saw the Council as an apex of economic thought, with us processing problems for the President's consideration. Our role was to give the President a notion of how professional economic thought was dividing on a question, and then give him our best judgment on it. If the President, for political considerations, for- mulated a policy that led to bad economic policy, the role of the Council was then to show him the least bad way to apply bad policy. I made this point in my speech before the American Philosophical Society. I said “.. the economist must be spiritually capable of bringing the choicest pearls of scientific work to cast before the politically motivated and politically con- ditioned policy makers of the executive branch. He must be prepared to see these carefully fabricated materials rejected or distorted, and still carry on the same process of preparation and submission again tomorrow, unperturbed and unabashed. He must all the while be aware that his professional brethren and the public will hold him accountable for the final compromised product while he, by virtue of his relationship with the Executive Office, is estopped from saying anything in explanation or vindication of his own workmanship."14 Now that is where the problem came in testifying before Congress. If we were all in agreement-we three and the President-we could go up and ex- plain to Congress what the economic needs were and how the decisions had been arrived at. But you'd be establishing a precedent. What happens when a policy comes up which you don't think is good eco- nomics-and they're bound to come because the President can't be expected always to follow the advice of the Council when he takes into account We recognized that policy had to be determined by the President. We, of course, sought to urge him to adopt the policies in which we believed, but so did Dr. Nourse, and so would anyone else in our position. Further, Dr. Nourse went all around the country making speeches to all kinds of groups, urging upon them the policies in which he believed. Sometimes he did this before the President had made a determination of policy, and some- times, after the President had made a determination of policy, Dr. Nourse made speeches to the contrary. Clark and I believed this to be inappropriate for reasons fully set forth in your quotation of my views." 14 Edwin G. Nourse, Proceedings of the American Philo- sophical Society (R.A.F. Penrose, Jr., Memorial Lecture), Vol. 94, No. 4, 1950. Advisers all factors in the political decision-making process. What would I do then? That was the question I was asking. Do I go ahead as a professional economist and argue for the President's position? That came up and I said, “I can't do that.” That, in my judg- ment, was an entirely different role from the one I envisioned as a member of the President's Council. Take my situation. Suppose the President took a position for, say, selective price or wage controls and that I have to go before Congress and defend it. Then some smart senator on the Joint Commit- tee like O'Mahoney, Douglas, Sparkman—there were plenty of them-says, "That's a very interesting case you make for this policy, Dr. Nourse. Now I notice that on page 486 of your book, America's Capacity to Produce, you deplore government controls in these words. Now, do you think the situation has changed?" What am I going to do? Someone else might make a forty-minute speech showing how conditions had changed. I couldn't operate on that basis. 13 I felt, as I read the Act, that the Congress had provided for dual implementation-we were to ad- vise the President and the Joint Committee was to advise Congress. There was no necessity for us to go before Congress. Congress had its own advisers with their own staff. Mr. Keyserling, though, felt we were responsible in a sense to Congress, partly because we had had senatorial confirmation, partly because as the Presi- dent's advisers we should speak for him, and partly because he wanted to wield that influence. On the first score, I had always felt that the situation would be clarified if we did not need senatorial confirma- tion. We weren't presiding over any action programs. On the second score, although we were the Presi- dent's advisers he didn't always follow our advice. Our advice was only one factor he took into account. On the third score, I was content being "schulmeister” to the White House. I didn't feel I needed the larger class on the Hill also. Of course, I wasn't completely happy with the re- lations we did have with the President. There was never a time when I called Matt Connally, the Presi- dent's appointment secretary, when there was the slightest difficulty in getting an appointment. He would say, "Will fifteen minutes be all right?" And I would say, "No, I need a half hour." Then Con- nally would say, "Well, we've got a lot of cash customers this morning; we'll have to move some of them around." And they were moved. There was never more than a day's lapse before I was sitting at the President's desk, and that was excellent. But when I got there, the President was always very gracious, friendly and nice-too nice, in fact. He wasn't busi- 14 Inter-University Case Program it in as objective a manner as my basic attitudes permit. However, a definite recommendation on expenditures, it seems to me, is advice that I can more properly give to the Executive than to Con- gress. ness-like enough. He'd tell me what happened on his walk that morning, or tell me chit-chat about his family-wasting minutes of this precious appoint- ment. As I think back, I can honestly say that I think I never had a real intellectual exchange with the President, that I was opening my mind to analysis with him, that he was following me. And the situa tion wasn't much better when I sent him reports. On the occasion when we turned in a majority and minority report the President took them and said, "Thank you for making this report. I'll study it with great care." But the next day he saw Clark Clifford in the morning and he said, "Well, I asked these guys for a report, and they gave me two reports. You take them and see if you can make anything out of them." You see, that was the frustrating part of it. I felt there was little opportunity to become more effective. But the important thing was to establish the Council as a professional body immune from po- litical influence. And, in fact, if the Council could pass from one administration to the next with some continuity of personnel, I felt that would firmly es- tablish the precedent. As I said once or twice before, "It will take time for successive Presidents to learn how to use a nonpolitical advisory staff agency ef- fectively. It will take time for successive Council members to learn how to bring the most competent and realistic analysis of economic problems simply and effectively to the President's aid." Blough's View After Keyserling became Chairman, Council members appeared frequently at congressional hearings. The new Council member appointed to fill the vacancy left by Nourse's resignation was Dr. Roy Blough, then professor of economics and political science at the University of Chi- cago. Blough joined in these appearances but differed from Keyserling on the kinds of testi- mony a Council member should give. This emerged publicly at the 1952 subcommittee hearing referred to above, when Senator Douglas asked Blough whether he advised Congress to cut expenditures by five billion dollars or whether he preferred not to answer. In reply Blough stated: I consider myself completely at liberty to dis- cuss with Congress economic trends and develop- ments, the effects and implications of governmental policies, and the different ways in which various policy objectives can be achieved. I am very pleased to have an opportunity to do this, and I try to do • Blough subsequently enlarged on this state- ment to the effect that the advisory relationship to the President clearly precludes the Council member from openly expressing views adverse to the President's recommendations. Accordingly, Blough felt, it is unwise for a Council member to serve as an advocate of administration pro- grams. Congressmen will not receive his frank opinion on matters of policy, but they should be able to rely on the objectivity of his state- ments as an economist. The CEA Under Eisenhower In January 1953, when Republican President Dwight Eisenhower took office, he inherited an unusual situation. In 1952 the Congress, un- certain whether the Council should be con- tinued, had provided it only enough money to function for nine months. Thus, Council funds were due to run out in March 1953. In February 1953 Sherman Adams, the Assistant to the Presi- dent, advised the Chairman of the House Ap- propriations Committee that President Eisen- hower considered it important that the Council continue to function, and asked that the Com- mittee consider a supplemental appropriation to carry the Council through the rest of the fiscal year. At the same time, President Eisenhower asked Dr. Arthur F. Burns if he would serve as Chair- man of the Council of Economic Advisers. Burns was at that time professor of economics at Co- lumbia University and director of research of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Burns thought back over some of the difficul- ties in CEA operations during the Truman administration and looked ahead to the kind of CEA on which he would be serving if he accepted the appointment. He advised the White House that he would accept the nomination provided he had the right to review the other two appointments. His condition was met. Early in March his nomination was presented to the Senate, which confirmed it on March 18. A few days later Congress approved the Supplementary Appropriation Act which provided only for the The President's Economic Advisers establishment of one Economic Adviser to the President and appropriated $50,000 for this Adviser and a small staff. The CEA's forty-member economic and cleri- cal staff was almost entirely dispersed. Only two or three economists remained. Burns considered his first task to be an evalu- ation of the structure of the Council as it had functioned in the Truman administration. In the course of his evaluation he concluded that many of the CEA's difficulties had resulted from defects in the legislation. He agreed with the Hoover Commission finding that the Coun- cil had been handicapped "by being a multi- headed body" whose three members had held identical powers and responsibilities. The Chair- man, as such, had no added powers at all. All administrative problems had to be decided by all three members. The second defect which Burns detected in the basic legislation was the absence of estab- lished channels between the Council and other agencies within the government. This deficiency had caused at least two problems: (1) It had been difficult for the Council to influence the making of economic policy throughout the gov- ernment. (2) There had been many accusations of "intrigue" between Council members and officials of other agencies. Burns felt that if there had been any "intriguing," one reason was the necessity to by-pass the blocks in the institutional arrangements. He therefore pro- posed a reorganization of the Council, which was approved by the President and which be- came Reorganization Plan Number 9, approved by Congress on August 1, 1953. This plan placed administrative responsibility for the CEA in the Council Chairman, who also had the sole re- sponsibility for reporting to the President. The position of Vice Chairman was abolished. In his letter transmitting the Reorganization Plan to Congress, President Eisenhower indi- cated that he was also asking the heads of several departments and agencies, or their rep- resentatives, to serve as an Advisory Board on Economic Growth and Stability under the chair- manship of the Chairman of the CEA. This was in line with Burns' notion that regular channels of communication between government agencies should be institutionalized. Burns' original idea had been to have an economic 15 cabinet. This cabinet, under the chairmanship of the CEA Chairman, would have been com- posed of the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, the Secretary of the Treasury, and other Cabinet-level officials with major responsibility in the economic field. However, Burns recom- mended that rather than leap directly to this high-level economic cabinet, it might be well to try the idea first with an advisory board composed of officials from the policy-making level immediately below that of Secretary. In June 1953 the Advisory Board on Eco- nomic Growth and Stability was set up with Burns as Chairman. The other seven members were under-secretaries, assistant secretaries, and officials of similar rank from the departments of the Treasury, Agriculture, Commerce, and Labor, and the Bureau of the Budget and the Federal Reserve Board. The White House was represented by Gabriel Hauge, an Administra- tive Assistant to the President with responsibility for briefing the President on details of economic matters. Burns now had a Council reconstituted on his terms: administrative responsibility was cen tralized in the chairman; there was an inter- agency board for co-ordinating economic policy under CEA direction; the two other members of the Council were men specifically approved by Burns. (In September 1953 Burns was joined on the Council by Dr. Neil H. Jacoby, Dean of the School of Business Administration at the University of California at Los Angeles, and in December by Dr. Walter W. Stewart of the Institute for Advanced Study in Princeton.) Burns also had strong backing from the Presi- dent. Eisenhower repeatedly told his Cabinet members that he wished them to consult the CEA Chairman on all important economic mat- ters and policies. While this did not give Burns veto power, of course, it lent weight to his posi- tion and provided him with another channel for putting forward his views. Besides consulting with the heads of departments and agencies individually, Burns attended Cabinet meetings regularly and participated in debates on eco- nomic issues. Under the Reorganization Plan Burns alone was responsible for reporting to the President on the workings of the CEA and on economic policy recommendations. Burns had a scheduled Inter- University Case Program Secondly, a congressional committee might wish testimony on some technical problem, such as an analysis of the statistical units of all govern- ment departments. This too would be a legiti- mate request which should be honored. Third, Council members certainly should appear be- fore the Appropriations Committee to defend budget requests for the Council itself.15 The difficulty arose when an invitation was proffered by a congressional committee dealing with economic conditions and policy. Here, Burns felt, there were at least two major dangers in testifying. 16 weekly meeting with Eisenhower, generally at- tended also by Hauge. Burns made it clear to his two colleagues, however, that although he had sole administrative responsibility for pro- cedural matters, he considered that all three members of the CEA shared equally the respon- sibility for advising on substantive economic problems. Burns also discontinued the practice of having the Council issue separate annual economic sur- veys. These were now made part of the Presi- dent's economic messages. The problem of the relationship of the CEA to Congress arose immediately. During the hear- ings before the Senate Banking and Currency Committee on the confirmation of Burns as CEA Chairman in March 1953, Senator John Sparkman put a question to Burns: "Is it your feeling that you should testify before a con- gressional committee, or will you keep yourself aloof from congressional committees?" Burns replied: "Senator Sparkman, it is per- fectly plain to me that the Congress has the full right to call upon any citizen within or outside the Government to testify at any time. ... My own personal . . . inclination would be to stay out of the limelight, make my recom- mendations to the President, indicate to him what the basis for the recommendation is and then having done that, to remain eternally quiet.” • Burns' Position Burns later gave considerable thought to the position he should take. To a large extent he agreed with Nourse's feeling that it would be difficult for an economic adviser to maintain his usefulness to the President if he had to answer all questions put to him by a political group. However, he felt Nourse had carried this position too far. There were several cate- gories of aid which could be given without interfering with his advisory relationship to the President. First, there might be a request for the CEA to aid the Congress in understanding the Employment Act of 1946. Such a request would call upon Council members in their function as administrators of an Act passed by Congress, and it would be completely appro- priate for Council members to testify freely. First, in some cases the President had to adopt policies that he didn't like and that I didn't like. He had to do it for reasons of overall political policy, but his heart was bleeding over it. What should I do before a committee of Congress in such a case? Should I criticize the President when I hap- pen to know that he shares my views? Would that be fair? In any case, how could I criticize the Presi- dent publicly and still remain a useful member of his administration? On the other hand, how could I say to a congressional committee that something is sound when I believed otherwise? The other major danger in testifying is that once an adviser takes a strong position in public, he is apt to become a prisoner of that position. I wanted to give the President the fullest benefit of my knowl- 15 Nourse comments: "With these three propositions I am, of course, in complete agreement. I only wish I had been smart enough to differentiate these cases as explicitly as Burns has done from the fourth issue-the one on which I took my stand. Naturally, I appeared before Senate and House committees to defend the Council's budget. When, in May 1947, Senator Taft, as chairman of the Joint Economic Committee, extended us an invitation to meet with that committee to discuss interpretation of the Employment Act and, in a broad way, means for its implementation, I unhesitatingly ac- cepted. The Committee's report had been made several months before. The session was well along on the legis- lative program, and our discussion was entirely free of debate over policy recommendations of the President or specific issues then involved in Congressional debate. We cooperated fully on the staff level in inquiries in- itiated by the Joint Economic Committee as to 'statistical gaps' and if, at any time, we had been invited to join with the committee in mutual conferences within this field, I am sure I would have been glad to participate. Not having the statistical competence that Burns had, I was not in a position to exercise the leadership in this important area which he subsequently contributed." 1 The President's Economic edge and thought. Hence I wanted to be free to advise the President one way one day, and yet be able if necessary to go in the next day and say, "I've been thinking it over. What I told you yester- day was wrong. I overlooked some important points. What really ought to be done is thus and so." Burns decided that he ought to testify de- spite these dangers, because good citizenship required it. He also decided that he would express to the congressional committee, if it dealt with economic policy, a preference as to the method of testifying. Burns preferred that he be permitted to testify in executive session with no transcript made of the remarks. But if the congressional committee would not agree to this method, Burns decided, he would testify anyway. "Maybe I'd have to resign after I got off the stand, but that would be one of the chances I knew I would be taking." In 1954 the Joint Committee on the Economic Report called upon Burns to testify. At that time the Republicans controlled Congress, and Republican Jesse Wolcott was Chairman of the Joint Committee. Wolcott and the Committee with its majority of Republicans acceded to Burns' request that the testimony be taken in executive session with no transcript. The election of 1954 resulted in the Demo- crats gaining control of Congress, and in 1955 Democrat Paul Douglas was Chairman of the Joint Committee with its new Democratic ma- jority. Again, Burns was asked to testif and again he expressed his preference. Douglas re- plied that although he would agree to an ex- ecutive session, he would want a transcript made of the testimony. However, Douglas we on, this transcript would not be part of the public record. Burns replied that if a transcript were to be made at all, he would want the script made public. So in 1955 the testimony was given in executive session, and the transcript was made a part of the printed record man, The next year Douglas was still and Burns again expressed his origin prefer- ence. This time some Democrats on Committee voted with the Republic Burns' testimony was taken in executi with no transcript made. Joint and ession So Burns established his policy. Hwould clearly express his preference to the ongres- sional committees dealing with economic issues. Advisers 17 If the committee in question accepted his pref- erence, that was all to the good. However, if the Committee insisted on different terms, Burns would accept those terms. There was another major change in the work- ings of the Employment Act in the first years of the Eisenhower administration. The Joint Congressional Committee, which up to this time usually issued partisan majority and minority reports, issued a unanimous report in 1954 and again in 1955. By 1956 there were those who felt that the Joint Committee was no longer "a fifth wheel" and that its hearings and reports were as significant as those of the CEA. Burns resigned from the Council in December 1956 and returned to his post as professor of economics at Columbia University, becoming at the same time president of the National Bureau of Economic Research. In 1958, look- ing back over his years as Chairman, and eval- uating his policy against that of the first Council members, Burns said: Keyserling took an extreme position and in the process ignored a vital distinction. Cabinet officers are directly responsible to Congress. Their responsi- bilities are largely defined by Congress. But the Council is not an administrative agency. It is ad- visory only-advisory to the President by law, and advisory to the Presidency by practice. Nourse also took a rigid position. To the extent that the Council had duties defined by law it is responsible to Congress and must answer to it-that is why I placed no conditions on my testifying on proposed changes of the Employment Act or on the statistical gathering functions of the government or on the defense of the Council's budget. But I want to add this: if there had only been the type of Council that Keyserling envisaged, I never would have accepted the appointment. I would have taken it for granted Council Chairman must, as a practical matter, support the President's views at public hearings, and I would not place myself in that position. But because there had been a Nourse I could conceive of there being a practical alternative and could try to find it. So Nourse did more than make my job easier by taking the posi- tion he did; because there had been a Nourse my job was possible. VAN TURK Not everyone agreed that Burns had solved the problems. Harvard economist Alvin H. Han- sen, for one, considered that Burns' solution had been to sidestep the dilemma Nourse had feared 18 by restricting his activities "more nearly, though not quite exclusively" to assisting and advising the President. Hansen felt that Burns had not really met the question (raised earlier by Keyser- ling) that the Democratic members of the Joint Committee posed in this manner in the com- mittee's Supplementary Report of March 1955: “A sound and consistent position for the Coun- Inter University Case Program cil must be agreed upon, either it acts solely as an anonymous professional body advising the President or as the spokesmen before Congress and the public for the President's economic analyses and programs. If the first alternative is adopted, then some other spokesman for the President's overall economic position must be established." PRINTED IN U.S.A - DO NOT REMOVE OR MUTILATE CARD 28-520-002 J { :. 7 1 • 蹿 ​• 5 ¿ • 11SARULE green gree ܚ ܂܂ J -- ཁ, ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ ་ .. CPAC CASE STUDIES, 1948-1951 *Air Search and Rescue Program, The. 1950. W. Scott Payne. $1.25. *Attack on the Cost of Living Index, The. 1951. Kathryn Smul Arnow. $1.35. Inter-University Case Program *Cambridge City Manager, The. 1951. Frank C. Abbot. $1.50. Consumers' Counsel, The. 1949, revised 1950. Kathryn Smul Arnow. $1.75. *Defense Plant Corporation, The. 1950. Clifford J. Durr. $.75. *Disposal of the Aluminum Plants, The. 1948, revised 1952. Harold Stein. $.75. *FBI Retirement Bill, The. 1949. Joseph F. Marsh, Jr. $.50. Feasibility Dispute, The. 1950. John Brigante. $1.75. *Foreign Service Act of 1946, The. 1949, revised 1952. Harold Stein. $1.75. *Gotham in the Air Age. 1950, revised 1952. Herbert Kaufman. $1.00. *Indonesian Assignment. 1950. Charles Wolf, Jr. $.20. *Kings River Project, The. 1949, revised 1950. Arthur A. Maass. $.70. Latin American Proceeding, The. 1949. W. Scott Payne. $1.75. *Natural Cement Issue, The. 1950. Paul N. Ylvisaker. $1.00. *National Labor Relations Board Field Examiner, The. 1951. William H. Riker. $.50. *Office of Education Library, The. 1950. Corinne Silverman. $.40. • *Reconversion Controversy, The. 1950. Jack W. Peltason. $1.75. *Sale of the Tankers, The. 1950, revised 1952. Louis W. Koenig. $1.75. *Self-Insurance in the Treasury. 1949, revised 1952. Kathryn Smul Arnow. $.25. Smith and the OPA. 1950. Robert L. Gold. $.75. *Transfer of the Children's Bureau, The. 1949, revised 1952. E. Drexel Godfrey, Jr. $.45. *TVA Ammonia Plant, The. 1950. Ellen St. Sure. $.75. ICP CASE SERIES, 1951- 1. Firing of Pat Jackson, The. 1951. William H. Riker. $.25. *2. Cancelation of the Ration Stamps. 1952. Martin Kriesberg. $.20. *3. Emergency Rubber Project, The. 1952. Martin Kriesberg. $.25. *4. Glavis-Ballinger Dispute, The. 1952. Winifred McCulloch. $.20. *5. Regional Director and the Press, The. 1952. $.20. *6. Production Planning in the Patent Office. 1952. Arch Dotson. $.20. *7. Rural Electrification Administration Personnel Report, The. 1952. Winifred McCulloch. $.20. *8. Veterans' Gas Ration, The. 1952. William H. Riker. $.20. 9. New York City Health Centers, The. Rev. ed. 1959. Herbert Kaufman. $.50. 10. Displaced Career Employee Program, The. 1952. James E. Drury. $.65. 11. UN Publications Board, The. 1952. Herbert Kaufman. $.75. 12. New York Farm Labor Camps, The. 1953. Ronald M. Stout. $1.40. 13. Wilderness Sanctuary. 1953, revised 1954. Russell P. Andrews. $.25. UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 14. Reorganizing the Massachusetts Department of Conservation. 1953. Thomas H. Eliot. $.70. 3 9015 06792 8666 15. Gainesville School Problem, The. 1953. Frank T. Adams, Jr. $.30. 16. Three Cases in Field Administration. 1953. P. B. Crooks, H. D. Lakin, F. J. Pratt. $.50. 17. Whittier Narrows Dam, The. 1953. Donald E. Pearson. $.60. 18. Taxing the Southern Railroad in Alabama. 1953. Valerie A. and Chester B. Earle. $.75. 19. Regional Information Officer, The. 1953. Martin Kriesberg. $.20. 20. Promotion of Lem Merrill, The. 1954. Valerie A. and Chester B. Earle. $.90. 21. Department of Commerce Field Service, The. 1954. Kathryn Smul Arnow. $.50. 22. Van Waters Case, The. 1954. Thomas H. Eliot. $.60. 23. Michigan State Director of Elections, The. 1954. Glendon A. Schubert, Jr. $.70. 24. Army Flies the Mails, The. 1954. Paul D. Tillett. $1.40. 25. Battle of Blue Earth County, The. Rev. ed. 1955. Paul N. Ylvisaker. $.50. 26. Defending "The Hill" Against Metal Houses. 1955. William K. Muir, Jr. $.50. 27. Closing of Newark Airport, The. 1955. Paul Tillett and Myron Weiner. $1.00. 28. Impounding of Funds by the Bureau of the Budget, The. 1955. J. D. Williams. $.50. 29. Michigan Athletic Awards Rule, The. 1955. 1955. Glendon A. Schubert, Jr., Helenan Sonnenburg, George Kantrowitz. $.35. 30. Public Advisory Board and the Tariff Study, The. 1956. David S. Brown. $.50. 31. Transfer of the Kansas State Civil Service Department, The. 1956. Peter Bart and Milton Cummings, Jr. $.35. 32. Reorganization of the California State Personnel Board, The. 1956. F. C. Mosher. $.90. 33. Coterminous Boundaries Dispute, The. 1956. Edwin A. Read. $.20. 34. (Resources Case) From Forest to Front Page. 1956. Roscoe C. Martin. $1.25. 35. General Accounting Office: Two Glimpses, The. 1956. Gerald G. Schulsinger. $1.00. 36. Appointed by the Mayor. 1956. William N. Kinnard, Jr. $.30. 37. Flagstaff Federal Sustained Yield Unit, The. 1957. Paul W. Bedard and Paul N. Ylvisaker. $.35. 38. New Bedford Manpower Incident, The. 1957. Kathryn Smul Arnow. $.85. 39. 'Lonesome Train' in Levittown, The. 1958. Joseph F. Maloney. $.35. 40. Decentralization of Business Services in the Agricultural Re- search Service, The. 1958. Lynn W. Eley. $.50. 41. Little Rock Story, The. Rev. ed. 1959. Corinne Silverman. $.50. 42. Commuters vs. the Black Ball Line. 1959. William J. Gore and Evelyn Shipman. $.80. 43. Mayor and the Fire Chief, The. 1959. Frank P. Sherwood and Beatrice Markey. $.60. 44. Personnel Problems in Converting to Automation. 1959. James R. Bell and Lynwood B. Steedman. $.45. 45. Moses on the Green. 1959. John B. Keeley. $.25. 46. Echo Park Controversy, The. 1959. Owen Stratton and Phillip Sirotkin. $1.85. Reorganization of Philadelphia General Hospital, The. 1959. Marianna Robinson and Corinne Silverman. $.75. President's Economic Advisers, The. Corinne Silverman. $.35. 47. 48. These ICP cases emphasize government, but they impinge on such fields as agriculture, aviation, business admin- istration, conservation, economics, education, engineering, international affairs, labor relations, law, personnel, journalism, public health, public relations, social service, sociology and anthropology, and planning. Write Univer- sity of Alabama Press, Drawer 2877, University, Alabama, for a descriptive catalog. Discounts are allowed on quantity orders. Titles marked with an asterisk were also published in a case book, Public Administration and Policy De- velopment, edited by Harold Stein, published by Harcourt, Brace and Company, Inc.