HE MAY 29 1918 < -- 1009 P18 Commerce Stuot y (ADVANCE SHEETS) EDUCATIONAL PREPARA- TION FOR FOREIGN SERVICE > BY GLEN LEVIN SWIGGETT Specialist in Commercial Education, U. S. Bureau of Education; Chairman Committee of Fifteen on Educational Preparation for Foreign Service AN ADDRESS DELIVERED AT THE FIFTH NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE CONVENTION CINCINNATI, OHIO APRIL 18, 1918 1 NOTICE TO DELEGATES. This paper is sent IN CON- FIDENCE for the convenience of delegates who wish to prepare for discussion. It is to be delivered at the group session on Commercial Education for Foreign Trade, and no publication, in whole or in part, is permitted prior to the morning papers of Friday, April 19. NOTICE TO PRESS. This paper is distributed IN CONFI- DENCE in advance of delivery. Release for morning papers of Friday, April 19, or thereafter. O. K. DAVIS, Secretary National Foreign Trade Council, 1 Hanover Square, New York City. to burn esatuan Miquel V . A و مات EDUCATIONAL PREPARATION FOR FOREIGN SERVICE By GLEN LEVIN SWIGGETT Specialist in Commercial Education, U. S. Bureau of Education; Chairman Committee of Fifteen on Educational Preparation for Foreign Service Training for foreign service has in view not only foreign careers in the service of government and business, the diplomatic and consular service and foreign trade, but should prepare one to successfully accomplish any special or permanent mission abroad in the general fields of industrial, intellectual, social and religious. effort. Students of foreign relations have seen the merely diplo- matic character of foreign missions increasingly modified by the participation of nation after nation in the commerce of the world, and by the more practical interest of all international social and re- ligious welfare work. This has led in some countries to a partial modification of the course of study considered essential in prepara- tion for the diplomatic service and in others to the complete reor- ganization of the school system or to the establishment of entirely new study courses in order to meet the novel and changing aspects of diplomacy or to prepare adequately for the pursuit of foreign com- merce. England and France, I presume, may be taken as examples of the former method, and Germany of the latter. Since August, 1914, we have observed the increasing practice. of the belligerent and neutral nations to appoint specialists in econ- omics and finance to supplement foreign chiefs of missions and even to supplant them momentarily in the accomplishment of some work of particular importance. Practical men of affairs have assumed in recent months in the solution of international problems positions of prominence rather unusual for the Old World. I merely speak of this in passing as a sign of a somewhat novel condition only hastened by the war and for which all nations must prepare with the advent of peace. Training for foreign service is to assume a preponderant position in national preparedness. International reorganization or reconstruction demands the commercial diplomat and the diplomatic man of commerce. 3 FIRST Conference on TrAINING FOR Foreign ServICE. December 31, 1915, there was held in Washington, a conference on training for foreign service, the first conference of the kind as far as I know ever held in the United States. A report of this con- ference has been prepared and published as Bulletin 1917, No. 37, of the Bureau of Education.* The conference was convoked by the Commissioner of Education and was addressed by the Chairman of the National Foreign Trade Council and the Director of the Con- sular Service. Mr. Carr stated that the subjects for examination into the con- sular service are as follows: International, maritime and com- mercial law; political and commercial geography; arithmetic; mod- ern languages (French, German or Spanish and in addition any others that the candidates desire to submit); natural, industrial, and commercial resources and commerce of the United States; political economy; American history, government and institutions; modern history (since 1850) of Europe, South America and the Far East. He stated that the applicant's "business experience and ability are considered upon his own statements and other information before the board of examiners." The subjects considered by Mr. Farrell as requisite in training for foreign trade include English, arithmetic. and commercial law, subjects specified by Mr. Carr; he places emphasis on commerce rather than history in the study of the United States and foreign nations, and adds business-office routine, manu- facturing, and ocean-borne transportation. With the exception of international and maritime law and modern history of South America and the Far East, the subjects demanded in examination for the consular service are offered in the high schools of our larger cities. The high schools of most of these cities, particularly the commercial high school, offer the subjects suggested by Mr. Farrell with the exception of manufac- turing and ocean transportation. We must, however, keep strictly in mind that the subjects mentioned by Mr. Farrell and Mr. Carr are rarely taught in the high school from the standpoint of foreign relations or foreign trade. *Copies may be obtained at ten cents per copy from the Superin- tendent of Documents, Washington. 4 SPECIFIC CHARACTER OF TRAINING. It is commonly believed that training for foreign trade differs but little, perhaps only in subject matter, from that for domestic trade. Mr. Farrell has himself stated in the above mentioned address that "the problem of training for foreign trade is inseparable, so far as concerns common school or secondary education, from that of training for domestic business." I hesitate to differ with such an au- thority as Mr. Farrell but it seems to me, particularly at this time when no moment is to be lost in the vigorous prosecution of a pro- gram of educational preparation for foreign trade, that not only in the colleges and universities but in the secondary schools as well there must be kept constantly in mind an essential difference in the technique of foreign and domestic trade; and this is especially true in the personal attitude of student and instructor with respect to the end in view in the study of foreign relations courses on diplomacy and trade. I shall not emphasize that point further since it may be, I admit, merely the writer's personal opinion. We all agree, however, that an adequate course in commercial education is fundamental as preparation for foreign service. This course should not only include the usual business training subjects, now to be taught with the view of foreign service, but all related academic subjects like language, history, mathematics and science should be presented from an inter- national point of view. This point of view is an essential factor of success in foreign distribution of manufactured products. It is not only essential in production from the manufacturer's standpoint but to the salesman and to all who are concerned with each successive step in transportation and in financing trade transactions. The mar- gin of success in the foreign trade of any nation lies, it seems to me, in that nation's patience in familiarizing itself with a foreign point of view, in its tolerance and catholicity. I marvel sometimes at what the future prosperity of our country through foreign trade will be when we, as a nation, have learned to make real catholicity, not apathy, the handmaid of our deservedly valued virtues of inde- pendence and initiative. << GENERAL STATEMENT CONCERNING COLLEGES AND UNIVERSITIES In the report of the Commissioner of Education for 1917, 575 universities, colleges and technical schools are listed. Some of these schools are not really more advanced than the better secondary 5 schools, although they do afford greater opportunities for the study of languages and cultural subjects; others are of the junior college type, while a comparatively small number represent the standard higher institutions of learning. There were 11,651 students enrolled in commercial studies in 1915-16 in 70 of these colleges that reported departments, schools, - or courses in commerce to the Bureau of Education. At the end of that school year 789 degrees in commerce were conferred. These figures, however, represent by no means the number of men with either interest in or training for foreign service. As a matter of fact, most of the college men recruited for this service may be found in the department of arts and science and even in some of the engineering departments. In fact the commercial engineering course of a few of our advanced technical institutions is now pre- paring a type of man that is particularly valuable for service in the foreign field. An examination of the courses of study for 1917 of these 575 higher institutions reveals the fact that with rare exception our colleges are not prepared as yet to train for foreign service. The courses in history, economics, and political science do not subdivide the subject matter sufficiently nor is it so presented as to equip the student with the essential body of knowledge or to create in him a desire to engage in some foreign career. The viewpoint is still local and provincial, and the results indicate too largely a concern with the traditional facts of history, the principles of economics, and the theories of government. This observation is not true, I admit, for some of our larger State or municipal universities or some five or six of our privately endowed universities, although there is ample oppor- tunity here for improvement in the way of developing these three important university departments of study by such subdivision as will permit adequate treatment of the foreign relations of the leading governments of the world and the placing of proper emphasis upon the distribution in the foreign field of the nation's raw and finished products. Our favorable balance of trade, the building of the Panama Canal, the enlightened propaganda of the National Foreign Trade Council, the establishment of the National Chamber of Commerce, with member organizations in several foreign countries, the con- structive legislation of Congress leading to the enlargement of execu- tive branches of the government and above all the present war, have led no doubt, to some effort on the part of the universities to meet 6 1 the demand for trained men and women to engage in foreign service by the introduction of courses of study largely on foreign trade. These courses were first given by business men actually engaged in the conduct of foreign trade. The success of this plan, together with the lack of business experience of the regular faculty members has led to the adoption of a permanent policy of cooperation of this na- ture in many universities for the teaching of their foreign trade courses. The necessity for this cooperation may be paralleled in the successful foreign trade instruction of some of the corporation. schools, business training corporations, correspondence schools, mer- cantile associations, banking institutes, and of the Y. M. C. A. I do not for a moment question the wisdom of instruction of this character. If we judge the results by the character of the business men engaged in lecturing or in the preparation of private study courses, or 'even by the student product, we shall readily admit that the means are justified. I can not but feel, however, that the meas- ure is one of compromise and should not be looked upon as perma- nent. There has been unquestionably great gain. But this will be in time offset by the loss in educational value, to be met only by the proper assumption by the teaching faculty of the universities of the subjects of trade and commerce in a manner similar to the subjects of law, medicine, and engineering. I make no plea for special priv- ilege of the full-time instructor. I do not believe as a general policy that even our larger universities will be able to give for some time adequate foreign service training without this extra-mural co- operation. There is being prepared just now a body of men particularly subject to draft by the universities for part-time teaching service. I refer to the university men who have recently resigned their positions. or been given leave of absence to enter upon foreign trade careers. in the service of government or business firms. These men have the teaching habit-by no means a negligible virtue. They are able to present their subject in due relation to the many semi-related sub- jects into which the general subject of foreign trade subdivides itself; and possess above all that sense of proportion which insures unity of purpose and effort. When these virtues are now added to the prac- tical knowledge and a sympathetic understanding of the subject gained by actual participation in the conduct of foreign trade, these men will become the ideal teachers of foreign trade and foreign re- lations. It is the lack of the latter experience that has lessened some- what the value of foreign trade instruction in those institutions that 7 have not developed to any great degree the policy of cooperative teaching through business men. And it is for this reason that I have urged for some time our smaller institutions to encourage the mod- ern language departments, particularly in the field of Spanish, to offer some simple study courses on the commerce of the country or coun- tries where the spoken language is that taught by the language de- partment. There has not been, perhaps, great gain and the policy of offering foreign trade courses in this manner can be only a tem- porary makeshift. I am, however, prepared to defend the courses on Latin America now offered by the department of Spanish, especially in some of our smaller institutions, as these courses are universally presented by men who have a sympathetic understanding of the peo- ple and have been led through this to learn enough about foreign trade policies and technique to make the subject intelligible to the students and to stimulate them to pursue the subject further or to undertake it as a career. THE ROLE OF SPANISH. There is unquestionably for the moment an asset of real value in training for foreign trade in the marvelous increase of oppor- tunity for the study of Spanish in our colleges and universities. In 1910 the study of this language in our high schools and colleges was negligible, less than one-half per cent of the students enrolled for its study. By 1915 there was an increase to two per cent. Statistics are not yet available for the school year of 1917-18. Three hundred and sixty colleges, however, of the above mentioned list of 575 are now offering Spanish. If the increased interest for Spanish in the summer schools of 1917 may be taken as an index to the number now enrolled in the regular college year, we can safely predicate an attendance in our larger institutions equal; or nearly equal, to its two principal rivals, French and German. We have in this language, how- ever, a nucleus for the development of a foreign relations course relating to commerce, just as we have in international law for diplomacy. In passing, I may state that in this list of 575 institutions, only 168 offer a course on international law; 165 offer commercial or business law; and only 1 offers a separate or special course on mari- time law. Specific courses on international or foreign relations are offered by 38 of these institutions; on foreign trade by 24; on foreign exchange or banking by 10; and only 4 present the subject of ocean transportation as a special subject. Sta T 8 It is to be regretted that the large number of institutions teaching Spanish does not indicate a corresponding interest of these univer- sities for trade and commerce with the Spanish-speaking nations. The course in Spanish in many of the institutions is still undeveloped and presented solely from the standpoint of culture. And this is especially true of the languages of other commercial nations. Not only are these languages presented with a similar object in view, but with the exception of French and German-almost universally offered there is only meagre opportunity for their study in our colleges. For example, only 13 institutions offer Portuguese; 13 Swedish; 15 Dano-Norwegian; 4 Chinese; 2 Dutch; 2 Japanese; and 10 Russian. THE TEACHING OF RUSSIAN. From the list of 575 colleges to which reference has been made, I have made a select list of 512 institutions wherein one finds one or more subjects, including Spanish, that serve, or may be made to serve, as a basis for the establishment of a course of study, the object of which is to train for commerce, domestic and foreign. Surely in some of these institutions the necessity of teaching Russian from the commercial point of view has been seen! And of these, still more surely some possess the means and courage to introduce it and at once! And yet in these 10 institutions the courses in Russian are elective and are, with the possible exception of three, not offered from `the spoken language viewpoint. Interesting to note, further, that of the 10 institutions, three are situated, one each, in Iowa, Kansas, and Nebraska—and one of these, a denominational school, where the subject is first offered this year to a class of seven students. This gain, however, is lost if paired with one of the largest and most pro- gressive institutions in the South, with three courses offered this session, where I am informed officially that "queerly enough, not enough students registered for any one of the courses to justify giv- ing any." And two of the largest institutions in the United States, situated in great trade centers, report a combined enrollment of four students in Russian. How different the story reads for England, and even Scotland! With the very beginning of this present war signs of preparation for a more intimate intercourse with Russia may be seen in the propa- ganda of their chambers of commerce and in the reports of their County Education Committees. This early zeal with wise direction has borne fruit, as will testify the following statement taken from the 9 memoranda adopted by the General Committee of the Modern Lan- guage Association and published in the English review, Modern Language Teaching, for June 1917: In November to December an inquiry was sent to (a) English universities; (b) to schools; and (c) to schools, colleges, and institutes under jurisdiction of education committees. Of the 12 universities reporting--including those usually mentioned-9 report the teaching of Russian with an attendance of 239; of the 41 schools of the type of Eton, Rugby, Harrow—10 offer Russian with an enrollment of 172; and of the Education Com- mittee Schools of 15 cities reporting-including 26 schools in Lon- don-all offer Russian with an attendance of 1,551-totaling 1,862 for England. Scotland likewise has felt this quickened demand and is sharing the general interest of the United Kingdom. Certain insti- tutions like the commercial colleges of Glasgow, Dundee, Aberdeen, and continuation classes-all under inspection of the Scottish Educa- tion Department-report 566 students of Russian. SOME TRADITIONAL DIFFICULTIES. It is the practice of the American colleges and universities to require for unconditioned entrance into the Freshman class certain units in history, science, language and mathematics. The customary articulation between preparatory school and college together with the usual grouping of college subjects, with or without the privilege of election, has failed to give opportunity in the college for the pursuit of many of the subjects suggested by Mr. Carr and Mr. Farrell save in the case of a small group of our larger universities that have been stimulated in recent years to offer on the elective basis one or more subjects in preparation for the consular service or for foreign trade. Foreign service training courses have developed, however, within the departments of history, political science, and economics; and occasionally, through the travel interest of some member of the faculty, one or more pertinent courses are taught, particularly in the smaller institutions, in a department only remotely related, as for example modern languages, geology, anthropology, etc. Strictly speaking, all foreign relations courses should be offered, except those that relate narrowly to diplomacy or diplomatic customs, in the de- partment of economics or in the school of commerce or business administration. Lacking until recently any unified and vigorous nation-wide propaganda for, or Federal or State patronage of, com- mercial education in the higher institutions, this subject has not yet 10 been systematically organized nor properly coordinated for treatmen in a separate department or school. Many of the small institutions maintain a separate school of business with a course of study similar to that of the better private business schools, but do not attempt to relate the regular collegiate instruction in economics, etc., to this course of study. In consequence of this, there is only unrelated theory and inferior practice. At the other extreme, we have the gradually evolving school of commerce in the larger universities, with the unique Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration at the top. Some of the ESSENTIAL SUBJECTS. In view of the fact that the colleges and universities in the United States are yet far from being standardized as they are in the commercial nations of Europe, it will likely be some time before all of the States will have adequate educational facilities in their higher institutions for the study of foreign trade. There must, however, be brought to bear in the early future concerted and insistent pressure upon the executives of these institutions. As a nation we must be prepared to anticipate export needs by a larger opportunity for the study of adequate courses on foreign trade. Certain studies must be offered and all of these must be taught with some understanding of the problems of business and some sympathy for the higher aims of international commerce. The basis of election of these subjects must be made satisfactory to the students and ample oppor- tunity given for the greatest possible contact of students with the actual processes of business through some mutually advantageous plan of co-operation between business and the educational insti- tution. Among the leading subjects that should receive treat- ment in the college course are the following: Ample opportunity to acquire a conversational use of two or more modern commercial languages; accounting applied to export problems; the history and geography of commerce with special and separate treatment of the five main geographical divisions; commercial products; organization of home factory and office for export trade; export policies; foreign advertising and salesmanship; foreign commerce and commercial development and commercial policies; trade relations of the United States; international banking and foreign exchange; credits; trade mark and patent laws; foreign investments; foreign transportation systems; ocean transportation; port and terminal facilities; marine insurance; international, mercantile, and maritime law; industrial, 11 1 fiscal and customs legislation; comparative government; tropical hygiene. Fully conscious of the criticism that may be invited I shall presume to offer for the purpose of discussion a four-year course of study in preparation for foreign trade and the consular and diplo- matic service that can, with but slight modification and adjustment of the present college course, be offered in the typical American college. Many of these subjects are now offered in the larger institutions and even receive more advanced treatment than the course of study herewith submitted would seem to imply. The real difficulty lies, in my opinion, in the acceptance by our colleges of the subjects men- tioned in the first year which are, however, worthy of college treat- ment and are fundamental and essential in any course of training for foreign trade. Until our cities have more generally established high schools of commerce, with natural articulation with the department of commerce of our higher institutions, it is absolutely necessary that the latter, in planning for an adequate course of instruction on foreign trade, substitute, on an elective basis, the customary first year group of studies with subjects similar to those mentioned in the following course of study: A SUGGESTED FOUR-YEAR COLLEGE COURSE IN PREPARA- TION FOR FOREIGN SERVICE.* First Year. First Semester: Advanced Business Arithmetic and Rapid Calculation. Advanced Commercial Correspond- ence. History of Commerce (Ethno- graphic and Historical Back- ground). First Modern Language. Stenography and Typewriting, or Commercial Chemistry. Second Semester: Advanced Business Arithmetic and Rapid Calculation. Trade Documents and Office Prac- tice. History of Commerce (Ethno- graphic and Historical Back- ground). Principles of Accounting. Salesmanship and Advertising. History of Commerce, (Products, markets and trade movements). First Modern Language. Economic, Industrial and Political History of the United States. Second Year. First Modern Language. Stenography and Typewriting, or Commercial Chemistry. Commercial Law. Public Speaking and Publicity. History of Commerce, (Products, markets and trade movements). First Modern Language. Economic, Industrial and Political History of the United States. 12 Third Year. Economics, (Transportation, money and banking). Representative Biographies of International Leaders and Pub- licists. International Law, or Organization and Management of Factory and Home Office. First Modern Language. Second Modern Language. Civics, (Social legislation and cit- izenship laws), Representative Biographies of International Leaders and Pub- licists. Maritime Law, or Foreign Trade Problems. Second Modern Language. Third Modern Language. Current Political History of Eu- rope and Near East, or Foreign Trade with Europe and Near East. Comparative Government or For- eign Investments. American Diplomacy, Treaties and Foreign Policy, or Industrial and Customs Legislation. First Modern Language. Second Modern Language. Fourth Year. Second Modern Language. Third Modern Language. Current Political History of Latin- America and Far East, or For- eign Trade with Latin-America and Far East. Tropical Hygiene. Diplomatic and Consular Practices, or Fiscal Legislation and Foreign Exchange. *Wherever alternative subjects are given, it is intended that one should be pursued by the student of foreign trade and the other by the student of diplomatic or consular service. COURSES OF STUDY AT SPECIFIC UNIVERSITIES.¹ The Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration offers a study group in foreign trade that includes the three following one- half courses: foreign trade methods, European trade, and Latin-Amer- ican trade problems. Related courses in banking, management, mar- keting, and transportation will naturally give some treatment to the foreign aspects of trade. Special supplementary courses are offered in the departments of economics, history, and government. In the depart- ment of history, the Eastern question and the Far East are given to undergraduates as one-half courses in alternate years; four one-half courses are offered on Latin America, one dealing with the recent commercial history of these republics. In economics, there is a special course on international trade and tariff problems. In the departments of government and international law, there are no special subjects relat- "The data herewith-given is taken from the college catalogs of 1916- 1917, most of which contain the announcements of new courses for the present college year of 1917-1918. 13 ing to such geographical divisions as Asia, Australasia, Africa, and Latin-America. International law offers two courses only for under- graduates: elements of international law; and American diplomacy. theories, and foreign policy. The latter subject is usually given in altern- ate years. Chicago University has a special school of commerce and adminis- tration. There are four main divisions of study. The first .or business. division prepares for all business pursuits, including foreign trade. In the fourth year the following special subjects are offered: commercial organization—foreign trade; commerce of South America; commerce of Europe; commerce of the Orient. The departments of economics, his- tory, political science, and geography, the latter in particular, offer supplementary courses. The economic and commercial resources of foreign countries receive regional treatment in this institution in the department of geography. Economics offers a course on foreign ex- change in alternate years. Political science offers two courses in inter- national law and diplomacy, one on elements of international law and one on diplomatic history of the United States. In history there are the following courses: history of Southeastern Europe and the history of South America. The University of Illinois has a special course on foreign commerce in its recently established college of commerce and business administra- tion. Only the following required courses, given in the third and fourth years, relate to foreign service: foreign commerce; organization of for- eign commerce; international law; and American diplomacy. The univer- sity offers, however, in the department of economics, courses on foreign commerce and commercial politics, a graduate course on foreign com- merce of the United States and a summer session course on theory and policies of international trade, in addition to the usual course or courses. dealing with economic resources of the principal countries. History offers undergraduate courses, one each, on Latin America, the Far East, and the Near East, and special summer session courses on the foreign policy of Great Britain and the history of France since 1815. Ohio State University offers a study group on domestic and for- eign marketing in the third and fourth years of the college of commerce and journalism. The subjects that relate specifically to foreign trade are foreign exchange, international commercial policies, exporting and importing, and the geography and resources of South America. The department of history offers a course in American diplomacy and the history of Latin American republics. Political science offers problems in international politics and international law. In the recently organized college of commerce of the University of California, courses covering five years have been outlined as preparation for the consular service. The current catalogue, with 1917-1918 an- nouncements, offers in the department of economics, in addition to the usual courses on economic history, the geography and statistics of international trade, foreign exchange, economic geography of South America, commerce of the Orient. Oriental languages offers commerce and industry of Japan and the economic conditions of China. Political 14 science offers two undergraduate courses in international relations, one on Spanish America and one on the Far East, and the usual course in comparative government. History offers the following special under- graduate courses: history of Latin American institutions; history of Latin America. International law is offered in the department of jurisprudence. New York University offers in the school of commerce, accounts, and finance: foreign exchange, accounting, export selling, foreign bank- ing practices, foreign exchange, economic geography of Europe, com- parative government, consular service of the United States, diplomatic protection of citizens abroad, international law developed by diplomacy, commercial law of Spanish America, export traffic and ocean shipping, European trade and industry and Latin American republics (history, geography, resources, commerce, banking, and transportation.) The School of Business of Columbia University offers the following courses: foreign salesmanship, international banking, and foreign ex- change, Latin America (the people, government, and resources; indus- try, transportation and commerce), international trade, ocean trans- portation, ports and terminal facilities, commerce in South America, commerce and commercial policy and Latin American commercial law. The following studies are offered in the international law group: history of diplomacy; history of American diplomacy; rights, duties, etc., of consular and diplomatic officers; international cooperation; treaties; nationality; extradition; and international law. In the history depart- ment the following special courses are offered: Australia and islands of the Pacific Ocean, modern Turkey and Egypt (modern Turkish is also taught at Columbia University), history of Central and South America. In addition to most of these subjects the Extension Teaching Depart- ment offers courses on the Eastern question, modern European and American diplomacy, history of Russia, history of the Balkan States, history and growth of international relations, political constitution of Mexico. The Wharton School of Finance and Commerce of the University of Pennsylvania offers: business of American commerce; foreign trade methods; ocean transportation; banking (includes foreign exchange); monetary and banking problems; geography and industry of Europe, Far East, and South America; marine insurance; diplomatic and consular procedure and practices; international law; American diplomacy in Eu- rope and the Orient; United States and Latin America; comparative government; and current international politics. The School of Economics of the University of Pittsburgh offers: foreign exchange; resources and trade of South America; commercial history and policy; foreign trade relations; American diplomacy; inter- national law. Tulane University offers: foreign trade; international payments; marine insurance. The College of Commerce of the University of Cincinnati offers: foreign trade; banking (includes foreign exchange). 15 SECONDARY AND SPECIAL SCHOOLS. In 1913 there was, according to the statistics of the Federal Bureau of Education an enrollment of 330,539 students in the com- mercial course of public and private high schools and in the com- mercial or private business colleges of the United States; in 1914 this number had increased to 346,770; in 1915, to 409,597; and, in 1916, to 452,801. If these figures included the students of all schools. that failed to register, as well as the students of the excellent Y. M. C. A. commercial course, of corporation schools, and of business training corporations, I am quite sure that the total would not be far from one million, less than one-quarter of whom perhaps are pursuing this course with other than the vocational aim of imme- diate service as stenographer, typist, clerk, etc. A study of local trade needs, of foreign trade opportunities, on the part of the secon- dary schools, with immediate readjustment and reorganization of the course of study to meet these needs, will help to create the man force necessary for the organization of the home office or factory of any industry engaged or about to engage in foreign trade, a factor of supreme importance. There is everywhere apparent the adoption of a policy of continuation work as a basis of cooperation between business and education. It is imperative, therefore, that the commer- cial course in our high schools be planned with some emphasis upon foreign trade in order that there be opportunity for the proper pro- motion of the foreign trade interest of our five hundred or more cities in excess of 10,000 population. Not that this need actually exists in all of these cities but in order to be prepared to stimulate as well as to meet the demand of business for foreign trade, in the pursuit of which we shall soon enter as a nation with a well-defined, rational, and consistent economic policy. The necessity for adequate treatment in the public high schools of the simple processes of foreign trade becomes apparent with the realization that the private business college and the Y. M. C. A. have failed to meet-perhaps in this single case-a real demand in their respective communities for some special type of instruction. With the possible exception of one school in New York City, one in Phila- delphia, and in the affiliated Y. M. C. A. of San Francisco, the many hundreds of schools of this great teaching institution offered in 1916-1917 no specific course in foreign trade beyond such passing and occasional treatment as the subject would receive in their classes in modern languages or on Latin America. ag 16 This lack is even more apparent with the private business schools. I have failed to find a single special course on foreign trade in the course of study of the better schools in Boston, Springfield, New York, Philadelphia, New Orleans, San Francisco, Cincinnati, St. Louis, Cleveland, or Detroit. With the exception of the Boston High School of Commerce, which offers an elective foreign trade course, two periods per week in the third and fourth years, no specific course on foreign trade was offered in 1916-1917 in the high schools of Boston, Springfield, New York, Brooklyn, Philadelphia, Cleveland, St. Louis, New Orleans, or San Francisco. The lack of interest in foreign trade in these three types of schools, the public high, the Y. M. C. A., and the private business college, in the larger cities of the United States can well be taken as a measure of our school interest and of the apathy of our busi- ness men and commercial organizations for training for foreign trade. APPENDIX: A SURVEY OF THE STATUS OF TRAINING FOR FOREIGN TRADE. In order to confirm a well-established inference, I requested the secretaries of the leading trade organizations of the largest cities in the United States, member organizations of the United States Chamber of Commerce, to furnish me, if possible, with the following information: 1, approximate number of mills or factories that manufacture for foreign markets; 2, nature and destination of the articles of export; 3, school opportunities for the study of domestic and foreign commerce¹. A questionnaire was sent to 408 cities. It is very gratifying to state that only 58 failed to furnish. the information, and of this number only 16 belong to the list of major cities. I regret to state that it is impossible at this writing to publish in detail the information furnished, since it was stated to the secretaries of these organizations that the data with respect to particular cities would not now be published. The results of this questionnaire are given by states listed according to the five main divisions of the U. S. Bureau of Education. Paragraph (a) ¹It is assumed that reference to school opportunity refers to public schools. The number of cities reporting adequate opportunity for instruction in foreign trade is doubtless greatly exaggerated owing to the natural tendency to confuse training for foreign trade with training for domestic trade. 17 gives the names of the higher institutions in each state not previ- ously mentioned which offer some opportunity for the study of foreign trade; paragraph (b) contains the information furnished by the secretaries of commercial organizations-lack of school instruction refers only to the cities reporting. 2All colleges are omitted from this list that do not offer, according to their latest catalog, one or more specific courses relating to foreign trade. THE STORY BY STATES. NORTH ATLANTIC DIVISION. Percentage of total number public high school students in commer- cial courses. Increase from 1910-11 to 1915-16: Maine, 16.7 to 25.0; New Hampshire, 19.7 to 33.8; Vermont, 8.0 to 21.5; Massachusetts, 30.8 to 36.1; Rhode Island, 25.8 to 34.2; Connecticut, 22.4 to 29.3; New York, 13.0 to 20.8; New Jersey, 23.0 to 30.6; Pennsylvania, 11.2 to 20.8. Maine: (a) Bowdoin College offers one one-half course in commerce and commercial policy in alternate years. The University of Maine offers a course two hours per week in American commerce-Spanish America is treated in the first half year. (b) Four cities out of seven reported 15 export manufacturing plants; destination,* Asia, Europe, and Latin America; no city reported adequate instruction in foreign trade in the schools. *Destination omitted in the remaining reports by states. New Hampshire: (a) Amos Tuck School of Administration and Finance of Dart- mouth College offers courses on foreign commerce of the United States, commerce of foreign countries, including Latin America, and foreign exchange. New Hampshire College offers a half-year course, three hours per week, in geography of commerce. (b) Four cities reported 17 export manufacturing plants; no city with adequate school instruction in foreign trade. Vermont: (a) Middlebury College offers a course in transportation and trade with treatment of ocean transportation and international trade. (b) Four out of five cities reported 11 export manufacturing plants; no city with adequate foreign trade instruction. Massachusetts: (a) Mention has been made, page 13, of the foreign trade in- struction in Harvard University. Boston University has a course on commercial development and one on foreign trade, each two hours per week for one one-half year. Simmons College has a course on economic conditions in South America. 18 " (b) Thirteen out of twenty cities reported 339 export manufactur- ing plants-five unable to state number; only four of the eighteen cities reporting stated that there was some attention paid in the schools to training for foreign trade. Rhode Island: (a) Brown University offers courses on international trade. (b) Three out of four cities reported 1202 export manufacturing plants; two reported no school instruction in foreign trade. Connecticut: (a). Wesleyan University offers courses in international trade. Yale University offers courses on commercial and banking relations of the United States. (b) Nine out of thirteen cities report 152 export manufacturing plants-two unable to furnish number; five cities report adequate in- struction in foreign trade. New York: (a) Mention has been made, page 15, of the foreign trade instruc- tion in Columbia University and New York University. The College of the City of New York has courses on foreign trade, foreign exchange, and South American markets. Attention is also paid to the subject of foreign trade at Syracuse University. (b) Twenty-one cities out of thirty-two reported 370 export manufac- turing plants-two cities unable to give the exact number. New York City and Brooklyn are among the cities not reporting; twenty-one of the twenty-three cities reporting stated that there was no educational oppor- tunity for the study of foreign trade in the schools of these cities- one stated that there was as much instruction as the demand warranted. New Jersey: (b) Nine out of the eleven cities reported 104 export manufacturing plants-three of this number of cities, including Jersey City and Trenton, unable to state the number of factories; only one of the cities reported that there was adequate school opportunity for instruction in foreign trade. Pennsylvania: (a) Mention has been made, page 15, of the foreign trade instruc- tion in the University of Pennsylvania and the University of Pittsburgh. Bucknell University and Lafayette College have a brief course on trans- portation and commerce with some emphasis upon foreign trade and for- eign exchange. Duquesne University of Pittsburgh has a course on Latin American commerce. Pennsylvania State College has courses on foreign exchange, and trade and resources of the United States and South America. The commercial engineering course of Carnegie In- stitute of Technology includes export trade and foreign banking and transportation. Temple University has courses on foreign exchange, 19 and trade and transportation. Lehigh University offers courses on the commercial relations of the United States with Latin America and with the Eastern Hemisphere. (b) Seventeen cities out of twenty-five reported 568 export manu- facturing plants-five unable to give number; only three cities reported school instruction in foreign trade. NORTH CENTRAL DIVISION. Percentage of total number of public high school students in com- mercial courses. Increase from 1910-11 to 1915-16: Ohio, 8.0 to 14.8; Indiana, 4.6 to 8.4; Illinois, 9.0 to 17.7; Michigan, 13.5 to 13.8; Wisconsin, 12.2 to 18.0; Minnesota, 11.3 to 15.3; Iowa, 5.8 to 9.9; Missouri, 8.8 to 10.4; North Dakota, 8.4 to 10.2; South Dakota, 4.4 to 8.9; Nebraska, 4.1 to 8.9; Kansas, 8.1 to 9.6. Ohio: (a) The course in foreign trade of Ohio State University and of the University of Cincinnati has been mentioned on pages 14-15. Miami University offers a course on the consular service and places special emphasis upon commercial relations between the United States and Latin America. Ohio Northern University has a course on Latin American trade. Toledo University has courses on traffic geography and movements, and foreign exchange. (b) Nineteen out of twenty-six cities reported 877 export manu- facturing plants-three unable to give number; only three cities reported school instruction in foreign trade. Indiana¹: (a) Notre Dame University has a course on foreign commerce. (b) Twenty-seven out of thirty-four cities reported 1,312 export manufacturing plants (1,200 of which are in Indianapolis)-three cities unable to give number; only five cities reported satisfactory school instruction in foreign trade. "The Department of Economics and Sociology has a new course dealing with foreign trade. Indiana University News-Letter, February, 1918. Illinois: (a) Mention has been made on page 14, of foreign trade instruction in the University of Chicago and the University of Illinois. North- western University offers several courses on foreign trade. James Milli- kin University offers one course in foreign commerce. (b) Seventeen out of twenty-four cities reported 875 export manu- facturing plants (800 in Chicago)-six cities unable to give number; five cities report school instruction in foreign trade and one city reports enough to meet local needs. Michigan: (a) The University of Michigan offers methods of foreign trade and a special course in commercial geography for foreign service. 20 Kalamazoo College offers a course in foreign trade. The University of Detroit offers courses on foreign commerce and foreign exchange. (b) Thirteen out of seventeen cities reported 246 export manufac- turing plants-three cities unable to give number; only two cities report school instruction in foreign trade. Wisconsin: (a) Marquette University offers courses in foreign trade, foreign exchange, and South American markets. The University of Wisconsin offers courses on international commercial policies, money markets, and American foreign service. (b) Nine out of eleven cities reported 340 export manufacturing plants; one city reported satisfactory instruction in foreign trade. Minnesota: (a) Carleton College offers courses on foreign banking and com- merce. The University of Minnesota offers commercial policies and economic geography of foreign countries. (b) No large manufacturing cities reported. Iowa: (a) Drake University offers courses on foreign exchange and South American markets. The University of Iowa offers courses on foreign commerce of the United States, business methods in foreign trade, and foreign exchange. (b) Eleven out of twelve cities reported 50 export manufacturing plants; three cities reported instruction in foreign trade. Missouri: (a) The University of Missouri offers courses on foreign exchange and trade. St. Louis University offers courses on international trade and foreign exchange. Washington University, in addition to the usual courses on economic geography, offers commercial development and markets of foreign countries. (b) Five out of seven cities reported 1 export manufacturing plant (St. Louis not included). The export statistics of this State unsatisfac- tory. Four of the five cities reporting state that the foreign trade instruc- tion in the schools is satisfactory. North Dakota: (b) All five cities reported no export manufacturing plants and no instruction in foreign trade. South Dakota: (a) The University of South Dakota offers one course in business barometers. (b) Three out of four cities reported no export manufacturing plants and no instruction in foreign trade. Nebraska: (a) The University of Nebraska in its school of commerce endeavors to stimulate an interest in consular service and foreign trade; foreign A 21 exchange and foreign commerce are offered. Several of the smaller insti- tutions in this State offer college courses on the history and geography of commerce. (b) All three cities reported 17 export manufacturing plants; one city reported instruction in foreign trade. Kansas: (b) Seven cities reported nineteen export manufacturing plants; no city reported instruction in foreign trade. SOUTH ATLANTIC DIVISION. Percentage of total number of public high school students in com- mercial courses. Increase from 1910-11 to 1915-16: Delaware, 1.8 to 17.5; Maryland, 14.2 to 17.6; Virginia, 4.9 to 10.0; West Virginia, 7.4 to 10.0; North Carolina, 1.0 to 4.1; South Carolina, 1.7 to 3.9; Georgia, 6.9 to 7.9; Florida, 2.3 to 5.3. Delaware: (b) The City of Wilmington reported only destination of its export products; failed to report the number of export manufacturing plants and the status of school instruction for foreign trade. Maryland: (b) Two cities reported-Baltimore unable to give number of export manufacturing plants; neither city reported satisfactory school instruc- tion in foreign trade. Virginia: (a) The University of Virginia offers a course on economic geography of Latin America. Washington and Lee University has a course on foreign trade. (b) Four out of six cities reported no export manufacturing plants; one city reported several plants, but unable to state number; five cities reported inadequate facilities for school instruction in foreign trade. West Virginia: (a) The University of West Virginia offers courses on foreign ex- change, international trade policies, and materials of commerce. (b) Three out of six cities reported 29 export manufacturing plants; two of these reported school instruction in foreign trade. North Carolina: (b) Seven cities reported twenty export manufacturing plants; no city reported educational opportunities for instruction in foreign trade. South Carolina: (b) Five out of six cities reported; three cities reported eleven export manufacturing plants and one unable to state number. One city reported school opportunity for foreign trade instruction. 22 Georgia: (a) University of Georgia offers courses in foreign trade organiza- tion and methods, and foreign trade of the United States; Georgia School of Technology offers courses on foreign trade and exchange, and Latin American resources and markets. (b) Four out of six cities reported 16 export manufacturing plants; no city reported opportunity for instruction in foreign trade. Florida: (b) One city reported no export manufacturing plants and no school opportunity for instruction in foreign trade. SOUTH CENTRAL DIVISION. Percentage of total number of public high school students in com- mercial courses. Increase from 1910-11 to 1915-16: Kentucky, 5.4 to 9.3; Tennessee, 4.1 to 9.0; Alabama, 2.0 to 4.8; Mississippi, 2.1 to 5.1; Louisiana, 8.8 to 12.4; Texas, 1.9 to 5.3; Arkansas 1.3 to 2.9; Oklahoma 6.6 to 8.5. Kentucky: (b) Three cities reported 17 export manufacturing plants; one city reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Tennesse: (b) Five cities reported 77 export manufacturing plants; one city reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Alabama: (b) Four out of six cities reported 20 export manufacturing plants— Birmingham not reporting; no city reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Mississippi: (b) One city reported no export manufacturing plants and no opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Louisiana: (a) The course of instruction in foreign trade at Tulane University has been mentioned on page 15. (b) Three cities reported 169 export manufacturing plants; no city reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Texas: (a) The University of Texas offers courses on foreign trade and foreign exchange. (b) Ten out of thirteen cities reported 38 export manufacturing plants; three cities unable to state number; four cities reported oppor- tunity for school instruction in foreign trade. 23 Arkansas: (b) Three out of four cities reported three export manufacturing plants; no city reported adequate opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Oklahoma: (a) A course in foreign trade is offered at the Western University of Oklahoma and at the Oklahoma Agricultural and Mechanical College. (b) Three out of four cities reported 5 export manufacturing plants and no opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. WESTERN DIVISION. Percentage of total number of public high school students in com- mercial courses. Increase from 1910-11 to 1915-16: Montana 13.7 to 19.6; Wyoming, 22.2 to 19.9; Colorado, 8.9 to 13.8; New Mexico, 2.0 to 8.1; Arizona 18.4 to 25.9; Utah, 10.1 to 20.5; Nevada, 9.7 to 17.2; Idaho, 10.1 to 13.7; Washington, 11.1 to 16.6; Oregon, 10.2 to 15.0; California, 16.1 to 18.9. Montana: (a) The University of Montana offers courses in commerce and com- mercial policy, and in foreign exchange. (b) Six out of seven cities reported 8 export manufacturing plants; one city reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Wyoming: (b) Two cities reported no export manufacturing plants; one city reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Colorado: (a) The University of Colorado offers a course on consular and diplomatic service. Colorado College offers courses on commercial development, foreign commerce, ocean transportation and foreign bank- ing practice. The University of Denver offers a course in foreign trade. (b) Nine cities reported 8 export manufacturing plants; two of these cities reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. New Mexico: (a) The University of New Mexico offers a course on Latin Amer- ican commerce. (b) Two out of three cities reported no export manufacturing plants; one of these cities reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Arizona: (a) The University of Arizona offers courses on trade resources and policies and on Latin American commerce. (b) Three cities reported no export manufacturing plants and no opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. 24 Utah: (a) The University of Utah offers courses on Latin American trade and American Asiatic relations. (b) No report from this State. Nevada: (a) The University of Nevada offers a course on international trade. (b) One city reported no export manufacturing plants and no school instruction in foreign trade. Idaho: (b) Three out of four cities reported no export manufacturing plants and no opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Washington: (a) The University of Washington offers courses on foreign trade and ocean transportation; foreign exchange and credits; tariff systems; and commercial policies. The State College of Washington offers courses on international exchange and technique of foreign trade, marine insurance, and the Far East. (b) Five out of eight cities reported 310 export manufacturing plants-three cities unable to state number; four cities reported oppor- tunity for school instruction in foreign trade. Oregon: (a) The University of Oregon offers courses on foreign commerce, practical exporting and foreign exchange. (b) Five cities reported 59.export manufacturing plants-1 unable to state number; two cities reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. California: (a) Reference has been made, page 14, to the foreign trade instruc- tion at the University of California. The University of Southern Cali- fornia offers courses on trade relations with Latin America and the Far East. The Leland Stanford Junior University offers courses on foreign exchange, ocean transportation and trade relations with Latin America and the Far East. (b) Seven out of thirteen cities reported 150 export manufacturing plants-6 unable to state number; four cities reported opportunity for school instruction in foreign trade. TOTALS North Atlantic Division: 84 cities reported 2778 plants that manufacture for export; 17 cities unable to state number of plants; 15 cities reported adequate school instruction for foreign trade. 25 North Central Division: 120 cities reported 3737 export manufacturing plants; 15 cities unable to state number; 25 cities reported adequate school instruc- tion for foreign trade. South Atlantic Division: 25 cities reported 76 export manufacturing plants; 4 cities unable to state number; 8 cities reported adequate instruction for foreign trade. South Central Division: 32 cities reported 329 export manufacturing plants; 3 cities unable to state number; 6 cities reported adequate instruction for foreign trade. Western Division: 43 cities reported 535 export manufacturing plants; 10 cities unable to state number; 15 cities reported adequate instruction for foreign trade. For the United States: 304 cities reported 7455 export manufacturing plants; 49 cities unable to give number; 69 cities reported adequate instruction for foreign trade. the 1 26 HE I { 1009 .P18 AL NOV 9 1918 PLATINUM DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR U.S. BUREAU OF MINES HO RTM RULES AND REGULATIONS UNDER THE ACT OF OCTOBER 6, 1917 (40 STAT. 385), AS AMENDED BY THE ACT OF JULY 1, 1918 (PUB. 181) LIMITING THE SALE, POS- SESSION AND USE OF PLATINUM, IRIDIUM, AND PALLADIUM AND COMPOUNDS THEREOF Platinum Section War Industries Board Washington, D. C. OF ENT Platele All communications regarding applications, licenses, inventories or other matters per- taining to the following regulations should be addressed to MO wesome in a FRED THE 이 WASHINGTON ܼܕ GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE CARAC 1 1918 FOREWORD. - - - - - - 2 Reclass Congress, under the Sundry Civil Act of July 1, 1918, made plati- num, iridium, and palladium, and compounds thereof, subject to the terms, conditions, and limitations of the Explosives Act, and the Director of the Bureau of Mines was authorized, under rules and regulations approved by the Secretary of the Interior, to limit the sale, possession, and use of said materials. In order effectively to carry out the act the following rules and regulations have been ap- proved by the Secretary of the Interior. Under these the Platinum Section of the War Industries Board is created an agency for the doing of those acts provided in the regulations. On this Section the Bureau of Mines is represented. The following rules and regulations have been prepared with much care and labor by a committee consisting of Messrs. Hennen Jennings, Bureau of Mines, chairman; C. L. Parsons, Bureau of Mines; C. H. Conner, War Industries Board; J. M. Hill, United States Geological Survey; and W. F. Hillebrand, Bureau of Stand- ards. It is desired that the trade shall be disturbed as little as possible. The main object of this legislation, however, and of the regulations thereunder, is to assist the Government in developing an adequate supply of these necessary metals. The cooperation of all citizens in the enforcement of these regulations is earnestly requested. REGULATIONS. The following regulations are hereby promulgated under the pro- visions of the act of October 6, 1917 (40 Stat., 385), as amended by the act of July 1, 1918 (Public, No. 181), authorizing the Director of the Bureau of Mines, under rules and regulations approved by the Secretary of the Interior, to limit, during the period of the war, the sale, possession, and use of platinum, iridium, and palladium, and compounds thereof: SECTION I. The War Industries Board is hereby designated under section 21 of the act of October 6, 1917, and the President's proclama- tion of October 26, 1917, as the agent of the Director of the Bureau of Mines in the execution of the regulations as hereinafter indicated. SEC. II. From and after the date of these regulations, under the penalties prescribed by section 19 of the act of October 6, 1917, no person shall: a b PAR. a. Use any platinum or platinum scrap, iridium, or iridium scrap, palladium or palladium scrap, and/or compounds thereof, in a Section 19 of the act of Oct. 6, 1917, is as follows: "That any person violating any of the provisions of this act, or any rules or regula- tions made thereunder, shall be guilty of misdemeanor, and shall be punished by a fine of not more than $5,000, or by imprisonment not more than one year, or by both such fine and imprisonment." v The word "person," for the purposes of these regulations, shall be construed in ac- cordance with the definition contained in section 4 of the act of Oct. 6. 1917, which is as follows: "That the word person' when used herein shall include States, Territories, the Dis- trict of Columbia, Alaska, and other dependencies of the United States, and municipal subdivisions thereof, individual citizens, firms, associations, societies, and corporations of the United States and of other countries at peace with the United States.' 78312°-18 (3) "" 4 the manufacture, alteration, or repair of any ornament or article of jewelry. PAR. b. Manufacture for use in dentistry any metal, metal parts, or alloys containing more than 20 per cent by weight of platinum or 40 per cent by weight of platinum, iridium, and/or palladium com- bined, or manufacture supplies therefrom. SEC. III. From and after the date of these regulations, under the penalties prescribed by section 19 of the act of October 6, 1917, no person shall without a license- PAR. a. Purchase, sell, barter, or deal in unmanufactured platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof (including crude, scrap, filings, polishings, or sweeps), except that sales may be made without a license to an authorized agent of the United States or to a licensee authorized to purchase the same; or possess for more than 90 days after the date of these regulations one ounce troy, or more, of such unmanufactured platinum, iridium, palladium, or compounds thereof. PAR. b. Possess, use, sell, purchase, or barter, for purposes con- nected with his business, platinum, iridium, palladium, or compounds thereof (except that sales may be made without license to an author- ized agent of the United States, or to a licensee authorized to pur- chase the same), if such person be engaged in— No. 1. Producing platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof, by mining. No. 2. Producing sulphuric acid, nitric acid, or other chemical products where platinum, iridium, palladium, or compounds thereof are used in such production. No. 3. Importing or exporting platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. WA No. 4. Producing platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof, either as a primary product or as a by-product of smelting or refining. No. 5. Manufacturing electrical appliances and/or parts thereof containing platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. No. 6. Manufacturing surgical appliances and X-ray apparatus containing platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. No. 7. Manufacturing chemical apparatus and reagents of all kinds containing platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. No. 8. Conducting or operating chemical laboratories in which platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof, are used. No. 9. Manufacturing scientific instruments containing platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. No. 10. Manufacturing and/or distributing dental supplies con- taining platinum, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. No. 11. Manufacturing and/or dealing in jewelry containing plati- num, iridium, or palladium or compounds thereof. No. 12. Manufacturing or producing any article or product not mentioned above where such business requires more than one ounce troy per month of platinum, iridium, or palladium or compounds thereof. dej SEC. IV. Applications for licenses shall be made under oath to any licensing agent duly authorized under the act of October 6, 1917, as provided in the regulations issued under this act. 5 SEC. V. Every applicant for a license will be required to submit with his application a sworn inventory of all platinum, iridium or palladium or compounds thereof in his possession or control; and every licensee will be required to submit at such times as may be designated by the War Industries Board a sworn inventory of his holdings of platinum, iridium, or palladium or compounds thereof in whatever form they may be. The Director of the Bureau of Mines, at the request of the War Industries Board, may at any time require from any user or possessor a detailed sworn inventory of any and all materials held by him containing platinum, iridium, palladium or compounds thereof, and such inventory must be furnished promptly upon receipt of such requirement. SEC. VI. All licenses shall be issued in the name of the Director of the Bureau of Mines and countersigned and delivered by the War Industries Board, and shall be, and remain subject to the follow- ing conditions: PAR. a. Each license shall contain such appropriate conditions as the Bureau of Mines, through the War Industries Board, may impose. PAR. b. The Bureau of Mines through the War Industries Board may change the conditions of the license from time to time, as it may deem necessary. -- PAR. C. Records shall be kept by each licensee of all his sales, pur- chases and other transfers of platinum, iridium or palladium or compounds thereof, and of articles containing platinum, iridium, or palladium or compounds thereof, with the names and addresses of the purchasers, sellers, and/or transferees, and the quantities in- volved, which records shall be open at all reasonable times to the duly authorized representative of the Director of the Bureau of Mines. PAR. d. Any and all platinum, iridium, or palladium, or com- pounds thereof, acquired under the authority of such license shall be used strictly for the purposes and in the manner stated in such license. PAR. e. Upon request of the War Industries Board, the licensee shall report the prices at which sales of his products containing plati- num, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof, are being made, and the right to prohibit further sale of such articles at prices deemed exorbitant by it is reserved to the War Industries Board. SEC. VII. Any licenses issued hereunder may be revoked for viola- tion of any of these regulations, or for violation of any of the condi- tions contained in such license, or if such revocation is deemed neces- sary or advisable for purposes of the national security and common. defense. SEC. VIII. The War Industries Board will, upon request, furnish a list of Government agents or licensees authorized to purchase plati- num, iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof. Neither the United States nor its representatives will assume any responsibility, financial or otherwise, where sales are made to licensees. SEC. IX. The prices at which platinum, iridium, or palladium will be purchased by a duly authorized agent of the United States or by such licensee as may be authorized to purchase or sell platinum, + 6 iridium, or palladium, or compounds thereof, will be such prices as may be determined by the proper governmental agency authorized to determine such prices. SEC. X. Whenever such Government agents and such licensees as may be authorized to purchase platinum, iridium, or palladium or compounds thereof, shall refuse to purchase the same from any per- son who is compelled by these regulations to sell the same, or is for- bidden by these regulations to possess or use the same, then such per- son shall promptly notify the Platinum Section, War Industries Board, Washington, D. C. SEC. XI. These regulations shall not operate to relieve any person upon whom an order requisitioning platinum, iridium, or palladium or compounds thereof may have been or may hereafter be served, from any obligation imposed upon him by such order. SEC. XII. These regulations are supplemental and amendatory to the regulations heretofore issued under the Explosives Act of October 6, 1917. Approved, August 17, 1918. VAN. H. MANNING, Director of Bureau of Mines. FRANKLIN K. LANE, Secretary of the Interior. X. : LICENSE CLASSIFICATIONS. PLATINUM, IRIDIUM, AND PALLADIUM, OR COMPOUNDS THEREOF. No. 1. To produce and possess for a reasonable time, platinum, iridium, and palladium, or compounds thereof, by mining. (See section III, par. a, of Rules and Regulations regarding Sale.) No. 2. To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium, or compounds thereof, for the production of nitric acid, sulphuric acid, or other chemical products, in a sufficient amount to cover their current requirements. K No. 3. To importa and possess, for a reasonable time, platinum, iridium and palladium, or compounds thereof. (See section III, par. a, of Rules and Regulations regarding Sale.) No. 4. To purchase in any form which requires refining or smelt- ing, and to possess for a reasonable time, the platinum, iridium and palladium produced as a primary product or as a by-product of the smelting or refining. (See section III, par. A, of Rules and Regula- tions regarding Sale.) No. 5. To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof, for the purpose of manufactur- ing electrical appliances and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (a) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof, in an amount equivalent to their known 30-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing elec- trical appliances, and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (b) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium, and/or compounds thereof, in an amount equivalent to their known 60-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing elec- trical appliances and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (c) To purchase, possess, and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium, and/or compounds thereof, in an amount equivalent to their known 90-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing elec- trical appliances and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. No. 6. To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium, and/or compounds thereof, for the purpose of manufactur- ing surgical appliances and X-ray apparatus and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced there- from. (a) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof, in an amount equivalent to their known 30-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing sur- gical appliances and X-ray apparatus and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. a Export licenses will be issued by the War Trade Board. ་ (7) 8 (b) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 60-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing sur- gical appliances and X-ray apparatus and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. A (c) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 90-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing sur- gical appliances and X-ray apparatus and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. No. 7. To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof for the purpose of manufacturing and repairing chemical apparatus and/or parts thereof and manu- facturing reagents of all kinds, and to possess and sell such manu- factured articles produced therefrom. - - (a) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 30-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing and repairing chemical apparatus and/or parts thereof and manufactur- ing reagents of all kinds, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (b) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 60-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing and repairing chemical apparatus and/or parts thereof and manufactur- ing reagents of all kinds, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (c) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 90-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing and repairing chemical apparatus and/or parts thereof and manufactur- ing reagents of all kinds, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. No. 8. To purchase, possess and use chemical apparatus of all kinds containing platinum, iridium and palladium and/or compounds thereof. (See section III, par. a, of Rules and Regulations regard- ing Sale.) No. 9. To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof for the purpose of manufacturing scientific instruments and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. T (a) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 30-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing scien- tific instruments and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (b) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palla- dium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 60-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing scien- tific instruments and/or parts thereof, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (c) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and palladium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 9 90-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing scientific instruments and/or parts thereof and to possess and sell such manu- factured articles produced therefrom. No. 10. To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof for the purpose of manufacturing dental supplies and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (a) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 30-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing dental supplies and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (b) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 60-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing dental supplies and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. (c) To purchase, possess and use platinum, iridium and pal- ladium and/or compounds thereof in an amount equivalent to their known 90-day requirements for the purpose of manufacturing dental supplies, and to possess and sell such manufactured articles produced therefrom. No. 10-x. To purchase and possess and to sell to dentists (upon their certification that they will not possess more than a 30-day re- quirement, excepting artificial teeth), dental supplies containing platinum, iridium and palladium and/or compounds thereof. (a) To purchase and possess in an amount equivalent to their known 30-day requirements and to sell to dentists (upon their certification that they will not possess more than a 30-day require- ment, excepting artificial teeth), dental supplies containing platinum, iridium and palladium and/or compounds thereof. (b) To purchase and possess in an amount equivalent to their known 60-day requirements and to sell to dentists (upon their certification that they will not possess more than a 60-day require- ment, excepting artificial teeth), dental supplies containing platinum, iridium and palladium and/or compounds thereof. (c) To purchase and possess in an amount equivalent to their known 90-day requirements and to sell to dentists (upon their cer- tification that they will not possess more than a 90-day requirement, excepting artificial teeth), dental supplies containing platinum, iridium and palladium and/or compounds thereof. No. 11. To purchase, possess and sell articles of jewelry and orna- ments containing platinum, iridium and/or palladium not manu- factured in violation of the regulations governing these classifica- tions. No. 12. Special cases. No. 13. To purchase and possess scrap, filings, polishings and sweeps containing platinum, iridium or palladium for resale to the United States Government or to licensees authorized to purchase same. APPENDIX. [PUBLIC-No. 68-65TH CONGRESS.] [H. R. 3932.] An Act To prohibit the manufacture, distribution, storage, use, and possession in time of war of explosives, providing regulations for the safe manufacture, distribution, storage, use, and possession of the same, and for other purposes. Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives of the United States of America in Congress assembled, That when the United States is at war it shall be unlawful to manufacture, distrib- ute, store, use, or possess powder, explosives, blasting supplies, or ingredients thereof, in such manner as to be detrimental to the public safety, except as in this act provided. SEC. 2. That the words "explosive" and "explosives" when used herein shall mean gunpowders, powders used for blasting, all forms of high explosives, blasting materials, fuses, detonators, and other detonating agents, smokeless powders, and any chemical compound or mechanical mixture that contains any oxidizing and combustible units, or other ingredients, in such proportions, quantities, or packing that ignition by fire, by friction, by concussion, by percussion, or by detonation of, or any part of the compound or mixture may cause such a sudden generation of highly heated gases that the resultant gaseous pressures are capable of producing destructive effects on con- tiguous objects, or of destroying life or limb, but shall not include small arms or shotgun cartridges: Provided, That nothing herein contained shall be construed to prevent the manufacture, under the authority of the Government, of explosives for, their sale to, or their possession by the military or naval service of the United States of America. SEC. 3. That the word "ingredients" when used herein shall mean the materials and substances capable by combination of producing one or more of the explosives mentioned in section one hereof. www SEC. 4. That the word "person" when used herein shall include States, Territories, the District of Columbia, Alaska, and other de- pendencies of the United States, and municipal subdivisions thereof, individual citizens, firms, associations, societies, and corporations of the United States and of other countries at peace with the United States. SEC. 5. That from and after forty days after the passage and approval of this act no person shall have in his possession or pur- chase, accept, receive, sell, give, barter, or otherwise dispose of or procure explosives, or ingredients, except as provided in this act: Provided, That the purchase or possession of said ingredients when purchased or held in small quantities and not used or intended to be used in the manufacture of explosives are not subject to the provi- sions of this act: Provided further, That the superintendent, fore- (10) 11 man, or other duly authorized employee at a mine, quarry, or other work may, when licensed so to do, sell or issue to any workman under him such an amount of explosives or ingredients as may be required. by that workman in the performance of his duties, and the workman may purchase or accept the explosives or ingredients so sold or issued, but the person so selling or issuing same shall see that any unused explosives or ingredients are returned, and that no explosives or ingredients are taken by the workman to any point not necessary to the carrying on of his duties. SEC. 6. That nothing contained herein shall apply to explosives or ingredients while being transported upon vessels or railroad cars in conformity with statutory law or Interstate Commerce Commission rules. SEC. 7. That from and after forty days after the passage of this act no person shall manufacture explosives unless licensed so to do, as hereinafter provided. SEC. 8. That any licensee or applicant for license hereunder shall furnish such information regarding himself and his business, so far as such business relates to or is connected with explosives or ingredients at such time and in such manner as the Director of the Bureau of Mines, or his authorized representative, may request, excepting that those who have been or are at the time of the passage of this act regularly engaged in the manufacture of explosives shall not be com- pelled to disclose secret processes, costs, or other data unrelated to the distribution of explosives. SEC. 9. That from and after forty days after the passage and ap- proval of this act every person authorized to sell. issue, or dispose of explosives shall keep a complete itemized and accurate record, showing each person to whom explosives are sold, given, bartered, or to whom or how otherwise disposed of, and the quantity and kind of explosives, and the date of each such sale, gift, barter, or other disposition; and this record shall be sworn to and furnished to the Director of the Bureau of Mines, or his authorized representatives, whenever requested. SEC. 10. That the Director of the Bureau of Mines is hereby author- ized to issue licenses as follows: (a) Manufacturer's license, authorizing the manufacture, posses- sion, and sale of explosives and ingredients. (b) Vendor's license, authorizing the purchase, possession, and sale of explosives or ingredients. (c) Purchaser's license, authorizing the purchase and possession of explosives and ingredients. (d) Foreman's license, authorizing the purchase and possession of explosives and ingredients, and the sale and issuance of explosives and ingredients to workmen under the proviso to section five above. (e) Exporter's license, authorizing the licensee to export explo- sives, but no such license shall authorize exportation in violation of any proclamation of the President issued under any act of Congress. (f) Importer's license, authorizing the licensee to import explo- sives. (g) Analyst's, educator's, inventor's, and investigator's licenses authorizing the purchase, manufacture, possession, testing, and dis- posal of explosives and ingredients. 12 SEC. 11. That the Director of the Bureau of Mines shall issue licenses, upon application duly made, but only to citizens of the United States of America, and to the subjects or citizens of nations that are at peace with them, and to corporations, firms, and asso- ciations thereof, and he may, in his discretion, refuse to issue a license, when he has reason to believe, from facts of which he has knowledge or reliable information, that the applicant is disloyal or hostile to the United States of America, or that, if the applicant is a firm, association, society, or corporation, its controlling stockholders or members are disloyal or hostile to the United States of America. The director may, when he has reason to believe on like grounds that any licensee is so disloyal or hostile, revoke any license issued to him. Any applicant to whom a license is refused or any licensee whose license is revoked by the said director may, at any time within thirty days after notification of the rejection of his application or revocation of his license, apply for such license or the cancellation of such revo- cation to the Council of National Defense, which shall make its order upon the director either to grant or to withhold the license. SEC. 12. That any person desiring to manufacture, sell, export, import, store, or purchase explosives or ingredients, or to keep explo- sives or ingredients in his possession, shall make application for a license, which application shall state, under oath, the name of the applicant; the place of birth; whether native born or naturalized citizen of the United States of America; if a naturalized citizen, the date and place of naturalization; business in which engaged; the amount and kind of explosives or ingredients which during the past six months have been purchased, disposed of, or used by him; the amount and kind of explosives or ingredients now on hand; whether sales, if any, have been made to jobbers, wholesalers, retailers, or consumers; the kind of license to be issued, and the kind and amount of explosives or ingredients to be authorized by the license; and such further information as the Director of the Bureau of Mines may, by rule, from time to time require. Applications for vendor's, purchaser's, or foreman's licenses shall be made to such officers of the State, Territory, or dependency having jurisdiction in the district within which the explosives or ingredients are to be sold or used, and having the power to administer oaths as may be designated by the Director of the Bureau of Mines, who shall issue the same in the name of such director. Such officers shall be entitled to receive from the applicant a fee of 25 cents for each license issued. They shall keep an accurate record of all licenses issued in manner and form to be prescribed by the Director of the Bureau of Mines, to whom they shall make reports from time to time as may be by rule issued by the director required. The necessary blanks and blank records shall be furnished to such officers by the said director. Licensing officers shall be subject to removal for cause by the Director of the Bureau of Mines, and all licenses issued by them shall be subject to revocation by the director as provided in section eleven. SEC. 13. That the President, by and with the advice and consent of the Senate, may appoint in each State and in Alaska an explosives inspector, whose duty it shall be, under the direction of the Director of the Bureau of Mines, to see that this act is faithfully executed and 13 observed. Each such inspector shall receive a salary of $2,400 per annum. He may at any time be detailed for service by said director in the District of Columbia or in any State, Territory, or dependency of the United States. All additional employees required in carrying out the provisions of this act shall be appointed by the Director of the Bureau of Mines, subject to the approval of the Secretary of the Interior. SEC. 14. That it shall be unlawful for any person to represent him- self as having a license issued under this act, when he has not such a license, or as having a license different in form or in conditions from the one which he in fact has, or without proper authority make, cause to be made, issue, or exhibit anything purporting or pretending to be such license, or intended to mislead any person into believing it is such a license, or to refuse to exhibit his license to any peace officer, Federal or State, or representative of the Bureau of Mines. SEC. 15. That no inspector or other employee of the Bureau of Mines shall divulge any information obtained in the course of his duties under this act regarding the business of any licensee, or appli- cant for license, without authority from the applicant for license or from the Director of the Bureau of Mines. SEC. 16. That every person authorized under this act to manufac- ture or store explosives or ingredients shall clearly mark and define the premises on which his plant or magazine may be and shall con- spicuously display thereon the words “ Explosives Keep Off.” 66 SEC. 17. That no person, without the consent of the owner or his authorized agents, except peace officers, the Director of the Bureau of Mines and persons designated by him in writing, shall be in or upon any plant or premises on which explosives are manufactured or stored, or be in or upon any magazine premises on which explosives are stored; nor shall any person discharge any firearms or throw or place any explosives or inflammable bombs at, on, or against any such plant or magazine premises, or cause the same to be done. SEC. 18. That the Director of the Bureau of Mines is hereby au- thorized to make rules and regulations for carrying into effect this act, subject to the approval of the Secretary of the Interior. SEC. 19. That any person violating any of the provisions of this act, or any rules or regulations made thereunder, shall be guilty of a misdemeanor and shall be punished by a fine of not more than $5,000 or by imprisonment not more than one year, or by both such fine and imprisonment. SEC. 20. That the Director of the Bureau of Mines is hereby au- thorized to investigate all explosions and fires which may occur in mines, quarries, factories, warehouses, magazines, houses, cars, boats, conveyances, and all places in which explosives or the ingredients thereof are manufactured, transported, stored, or used, and shall, in his discretion, report his findings, in such manner as he may deem fit, to the proper Federal or State authorities, to the end that if such explosion has been brought about by a willful act the person or per- sons causing such act may be proceeded against and brought to jus- tice; or, if said explosion has been brought about by accidental means, that precautions may be taken to prevent similar accidents from occurring. In the prosecution of such investigations the employees of the Bureau of Mines are hereby granted the authority to enter the : 20 14 premises where such explosion or fire has occurred, to examine plans, books, and papers, to administer oaths to, and to examine all wit- nesses and persons concerned, without let or hindrance on the part of the owner, lessee, operator, or agent thereof. SEC. 21. That the Director of the Bureau of Mines, with the ap- proval of the President, is hereby authorized to utilize such agents, agencies, and all officers of the United States and of the several States, Territories, dependencies, and municipalities thereof, and the District of Columbia, in the execution of this act, and all agents, agencies, and all officers of the United States and of the several States and Territories, dependencies, and municipalities thereof, and the District of Columbia, shall hereby have full authority for all acts done by them in the execution of this act when acting by the direction of the Bureau of Mines. SEC. 2. That for the enforcement of the provisions of this act, including personal services in the District of Columbia and else- where, and including supplies, equipment, expenses of traveling and subsistence, and for the purchase and hire of animal-drawn or motor-propelled passenger-carrying vehicles, and upkeep of same, and for every other expense incident to the enforcement of the pro- visions of this act, there is hereby appropriated, out of any money in the Treasury not otherwise appropriated, the sum of $300,000, or so much thereof as may be necessary: Provided, That not to exceed $10,000 shall be expended in the purchase of motor-propelled passenger-carrying vehicles. Approved, October 6, 1917. The above act was amended by the sundry civil appropriation act, approved July 1, 1918 (Pub. 181) as follows: Provided, That any license issued under the act of October sixth, nineteen hundred and seventeen, may be canceled by the Director of the Bureau of Mines if the person to whom such license was issued shall, after notice and an opportunity to be heard, be found to have violated any of the provisions of the act. Provided further, That platinum, iridium, and palla- dium and compounds thereof are hereby made subject to the terms, conditions, and limitations of said act of October sixth, nineteen hundred and seventeen, and the Director of the Bureau of Mines is hereby authorized, under rules and regulations approved by the Secretary of the Interior, to limit the sale, possession, and the use of said material. THE PRESIDENT'S PROCLAMATION. - Whereas, under and by virtue of an act of Congress entitled "An act to prohibit the manufacture, distribution, storage, use, and pos- session in time of war of explosives, providing regulations for the safe manufacture, distribution, storage, use, and possession of the same, and for other purposes," approved by the President on the 6th day of October, 1917, it is provided among other things that from and after forty days after the passage and approval of said act no person shall manufacture, distribute, store, use, or possess ex- plosives or ingredients thereof, not including explosives for the military or naval service of the United States of America under the authority of the Government or ingredients in small quantities not used or intended to be used in the manufacture of explosives, and not including small-arms or shotgun cartridges, unless such person shall obtain a license issued in the name of the Director of the Bureau of Mines, except that any workman may purchase or accept explosives or ingredients thereof under prescribed conditions from a licensed superintendent or foreman. And whereas, it is further provided in said act as follows: "That the Director of the Bureau of Mines, with the approval of the President, is hereby authorized to utilize such agents, agencies, and all officers of the United States and of the several States. Terri- tories, dependencies, and municipalities thereof, and the District of Columbia, in the execution of this act, and all agents, agencies, and all officers of the United States and of the several States and Terri- tories, dependencies, and municipalities thereof, and the District of Columbia, shall hereby have full authority for all acts done by them in the execution of this act when acting by the direction of the Bureau of Mines." Now, therefore, I, Woodrow Wilson, President of the United States of America, by this proclamation do announce the follow- ing: That from and after the 15th day of November, 1917, and during the present war with Germany, it will be unlawful to manufacture, distribute, store, use, or possess explosives or ingredients thereof, except as provided in said act. That the Director of the Bureau of Mines is hereby authorized to utilize, where necessary for the proper administration of said act, the services of all officers of the United States and of the several States, Territories, dependencies, and municipalities thereof, and of the District of Columbia, and such other agents and agencies as he may designate, who shall have full authority for all acts done by them in the execution of the said act when acting under his direction. In witness whereof, I have hereunto set my hand and caused the seal of the United States to be affixed. (15) 1 16 Done in the District of Columbia, this twenty-sixth day of October, in the year of our Lord one thousand nine hundred and seventeen, and of the independence of the United States of America, the one hundred and forty-second. [SEAL.] : By the President: ROBERT LANSING, Secretary of State. ! WOODROW WILSON. ގތ : HF 1009 P18 sty Organiſation Egg des Berliner Eiergroßhandels. madeerto der Inaugural-Diſſertation zur Erlangung der Doktorwürde hohen Philoſophiſchen Fakultät der A Friedrich-Alexanders-Univerſität Erlangen vorgelegt Don Anton Rolf aus Haſte 1 Barline WWV 11 Tag der mündlichen Prüfung: 27. Februar 1912 Berlin Gedruckt bei Julius Sittenfeld 1912. { 272 9. E.R Reclass,12-18-2I. Meiner lieben Mutter! Egg Resou industry $ al Quellenverzeichnis. Sonndorfer: „Der internationale Eierhandel". Zeitschrift: „Die Eierbörse“. Berliner Markthallenzeitung". "} „Die Kolonialwaren-Woche". Jahrbücher für Handel und Induſtrie“ (Jahresbericht der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin). " Dr. Trumpler: Artikel Vinfulation" in Monatsschrift für Handelsrecht und Bankwesen“ 1903. Gutachten der Handelskammer zu Breslau über Vinkulation in „Monats- ſchrift für Handelsrecht und Bankwesen“ 1899. Gutachten der Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin über Usancen im Berliner Eierhandel „Berlin und seine Eisenbahnen" 1896, von der Regierung herausgegeben. Fr. Prall: Ueber Eierkonservierung". Enqueten bei Interessenten des Berliner Eiergroßhandels und eigne Beob- achtungen. Im Text angegebene Quellen. OARTO Inhaltsangabe. Einleitung Einiges über den internationalen Eiergroßhandel Berliner Eiergroßhandel im allgemeinen. 9 18 25 Die Träger des Berliner Eiergroßhandels und die Formen des Geschäfts 29 Die Bank im Dienste des Eierhandels 34 Der Eierſpezialmarkt . 38 Die Interessenvertretung des Eiergroßhandels 47 Das Schiedsgericht 49 Das Sachverständigenamt 51 Die Geschäftsbedingungen 53 Faktoren der Preisbildung am Berliner Markte 57 • • Einleitung. Deutschland hat neben England von allen Staaten Europas den größten Import von Eiern. Gegenüber dieſer Einfuhr, die noch im steten Wachsen begriffen ist, hat die Ausfuhr eine sehr geringe Bedeutung. Deutschlands Ein- und Ausfuhr im Spezialhandel von Eiern (bis 1906 inklusive von Eiern und Eigelb) betrug: Einfuhr 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 • • • 1900 . 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 • 118 169 700 kg Br. 116 486 500 128 153 800 124 776 900 123 991 700 130 737 100 149 642 800 149 455 200 - 139 292 800 s 137 009 800 • = 11 ***** = · ព * 900 400 = 659 700 594 900 491 200 Ausfuhr 613 100 kg Br. 698 800 - 968 900 1 035 500 1 097 800 1 231 200 *** 11 11 "1 = 0 0 }} }} }} 0 11 103 227 000 M. 104 773 000 115 071 000 108 377 000 114 651 000 121 350 000 144 557 000 = 149 707 000 136 990 000 156 559 000 บ 597 000 M. 699 000 969 000 1 036 000 1 098 000 1 354 000 991 000 726 000 654 000 564 000 = 11 W = 11 WI AI Aus diesen anwachsenden Zahlen des Imports kann man nicht zugleich den Schluß ziehen, daß die inländische Produktion zurückgeht. Dem steht nämlich die Tatsache ent- gegen, daß bei der zweiten Geflügelzählung im Jahre 1900 Deutschland einen Geflügelbestand von 64 573 242 Stück hatte, im Jahre 1907 dagegen 77 103 045 Stück. Dieser Annahme ſteht ferner entgegen, daß seit den lezten Jahrzehnten in den Geflügelzuchtvereinen, Geflügelausstellungen usw. Bestrebungen sich geltend machen, das deutsche Geflügel zu vermehren und zu veredeln, und nicht zum letzten auch die Gründungen zahl= reicher Absaßgenossenschaften, die infolge einer guten Verkaufs- organisation thren Mitgliedern höhere Preise für die Eier bezah= len können, als diese beim Absaß an ländliche Auffäufer erzielen würden, und so das Interesse für die Geflügelzucht beleben. 10 Wenn man nun fragt, wo genügt dem Bedarf an Eiern die inländische Produktion nicht, wo wird also die vom Aus- lande importierte Ware in den Konsum gebracht, ſo iſt die Antwort: in den größten und größeren Städten. Zahlen- mäßig läßt sich das schwer nachweisen, denn außer in Berlin, Hamburg, Frankfurt a. M. konnte man mir auf meine Anfrage in den Städten, die als größere Importpläge für aus- ländische Eier bekannt sind, keinerlei statistische Angaben über den Eingang von Eiern geben. (Die Zahlen von Hamburg lassen hauptsächlich nur den Import vom Auslande, die von Frankfurt a. M. nur die Mengen der dort verzollten Ware erkennen.) Nach Sonndorfer betrug die Einfuhr Hamburgs 1906: 36 520 930 kg 1907: 39 265 997 kg 1906: 26 346 876 - 1907: 27 382 622 I die Ausfuhr ſo daß in den Kon- fum übergingen 1906: 10 174 054 kg 1907: 11 883 375 kg Die in Frankfurt a. M. verzollten Eier betrugen nach den Berichten der dortigen Handelskammer 10 265 000 kg 1906 1907 9 167 700 7 737 400 1908 1909 6 771 200 1910 9 823 300 1885 1886 1887 1888 1889 • 1890 1891 1892 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 • . Uebergehend zur Betrachtung des Berliner Eierimports seien. zunächst die Zahlen der Ein- und Ausfuhr der legten Jahrzehnte wiedergegeben, die den Jahresberichten der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft über den Berliner Eierhandel entnommen sind: Einfuhr Ausfuhr 13 269 446 kg Br. 14 681 433 17 873 804 20 865 676 19 491 510 21 285 044 24 109 208 23 120 547 22 983 710 24 744 112 25 914 126 26 496 151 27 975 780 27 642 840 29 179 660 30 280 620 30 243 132 29 986 958 28 897 172 31 071 271 33 388 301 39 627 837 42 772 281 39 595 915 41 798 071 42 161 690 U W W 11 **** = 11 = 11 " 11 11 11 = 1 " 11 = C = - W W = M " n W 11 "1 11 " 11 W n W U n n 11 18 = ***** 11 1 325 204 kg Br. 1 724 630 1 924 206 2 742 024 2 319 064 2 765 765 3 429 122 3 316 961 3 492 952 3 347 426 3 668 087 2 410 347 2 292 661 2 018 967 2 301 306 2 582 087 2 611 848 2 299 640 1 793 963 2 197 415 2 043 140 2 317 111 3 255 101 2 683 530 2 411 736 2 924 382 n n 11 = 18 11 11 n S C ล 11 = 0 W ****** 1}] W " The - - 11 W 0 11 1101111011111111111A = = = u un = 11 11 11 Die Ein- und Ausfuhr repräsentierte in den lezten zehn Jahren, umgerechnet zum jeweiligen Durchschnittspreis für normale Eier, in Berlin folgenden Wert: 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 Wert der Einfuhr Mm. 25 299 389 25 564 881 24 643 506 27 296 518 32 328 775 37 560 514 42 384 480 40 408 952 43 893 546 Wert der Ausfuhr M. 2 184 900 1 960 518 1 529 891 1 930 208 2 367 861 2 190 441 2 225 588 2 738 629 2 532 646 Die Zahlen der Ein- und Ausfuhr sind Zusammen- stellungen der Ein- und Ausgänge von Eiern bei den ver- schiedenen Güterbahnhöfen Berlins. Sie bilden die einzig vorhandene Statistik der Ein- und Ausfuhr dieser Ware nach und von dem Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiet, d. h. Berlin und feinen Vororten. Geben uns diese Zahlen nun ein richtiges Bild von der Größe des Berliner Eierhandels? Dazu iſt folgendes zu sagen. Der allergrößte Teil der eingeführten Eier wird mit der Eisenbahn nach Berlin transportiert, die Ausfuhr erfolgt lediglich auf diesem Wege. Ein geringer Teil der Ankünfte entzieht sich der Statistik in den Sendungen, die mit der Post an einige Butterdetailgeschäfte und an Konſu- menten direkt geschicht werden. Ferner fehlen in den Zahlen die Sendungen Eier, die auf Wagen nach Berlin transportiert werden. Dieser Teil der Ankünfte dürfte aber noch geringer ſein als der durch die Post beförderte, denn es kommen hier nur Eier aus der allernächsten Umgebung der Hauptstadt in Betracht. Auf dem Wasserwege kommen feine Eier direkt nach Berlin. Die Statistik dürfte also fast die ganze Einfuhr, ſicher aber die ganze Ausfuhr erfassen. Sie ist genauer als andere statistische Ausweisungen der Bahnverwaltungen, da die Gepflogenheit der preußischen Eisenbahn, Stückgüter unter 500 kg statistisch nicht zu verzeichnen, hier keinen Eingang ge- funden hat; vielmehr enthält die Statistik auch die Stückgüter bis zu 20 kg. Ein Uebelstand dieser Statiſtil iſt der, daß sie keinen Unterschied macht zwischen der Zufuhr von Eiern aus dem Inlande und der aus dem Auslande. Es läßt sich aber auf Grund der spezialisierten Zahlen der einzelnen Bahnhöfe eine ungefähre Schäßung von der Größe der inländiſchen und der der ausländischen Zufuhr anstellen. Eierladungen aus Rußland und aus Desterreich-Ungarn (diese beiden Länder find die Bezugsquellen, aus denen Berlin, wie noch zu zeigen ſein wird, faſt ſeinen ganzen Bedarf an ausländischen Eiern dect) kommen nur am Schlesischen und am Anhalter Bahn- hof an. Der Anhalter Güterbahnhof erhält ausländische Eier nur in den Frühjahrs- und Sommermonaten, und zwar nur die. welche zur Konservierung im Kühlhause bestimmt sind, weil von dort aus ein Anschlußgleis nach dem Grundstück der „Gesellschaft für Markt- und Kühlhallen“ führt. Von den 12 anderen Berliner Güterbahnhöfen erhalten ausländische Eier- sendungen im geringen Umfange nur noch der Stettiner und der Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof und zwar der Stettiner geringe Mengen dänischer, der Hamburg-Lehrter holländische Ware; doch bilden dieſe ausländischen Eingänge nur einen verhältnis- mäßig geringen Bruchteil des gesamten Eierempfanges dieser Bahnhöfe. Wenn wir davon absehen, so können wir die Eingänge am Schlesischen und Anhalter Bahnhof einerseits und die am Hamburg-Lehrter, Görlizer, Potsdamer, Ost-, Nord, Stettiner Bahnhof andererseits gegenüberstellen und behaupten: die Eingänge der ersten Gruppe tommen aus dem östlich und südöstlich von Berlin aus gelegenen Auslande, die der leßteren Gruppe aus dem Inlande. Wir müssen uns aber dabei der beiden Fehler bewußt bleiben, daß auch der Schlesische und der Anhalter Bahnhof inländische Eiersendungen haben und daß andererseits auch bei den Bahnhöfen der zweiten Gruppe geringe Mengen von Eiern aus dem Auslande eintreffen. Es ist aber nicht zu verkennen, daß die beiden Fehler sich teil- weise kompensieren; ein Saldo dürfte nur zugunsten der Zufuhr vom Inlande bleiben. Ein- und Ausgänge bei den einzelnen Güterbahnhöfen betrugen : Schlesischer Bahnhof . Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof . Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ditbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof • Schlesischer Bahnhof . Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof · • Schlesischer Bahnhof Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof . Görlizer Bahnhof Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof . · 1904 • 1905 1906 Eingang 29 207 944 47 840 45 190 15 103 460 062 91 380 375 110 732 642 Eingang 31 514 106 55 966 38 310 13 070 496 333 26 470 379 100 714 946 Eingang 37 536 451 54 744 12 700 43 961 649 495 19 560 435 760 785 168 Ausgang 333 210 39 753 80 590 416 943 85 693 350 380 934 946 Ausgang 318 755 64 393 71 660 364 585 54 794 5 000 353 550 840 403 Ausgang 582 740 27 629 81 330 539 183 59 390 356 590 670 743 S P 13 Schlesischer Bahnhof . Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof. Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof · Schlesischer Bahnhof Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görliger Bahnhof. Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof • • Schlesischer Bahnhof Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof . · Schlesischer Bahnhof . Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof . Görlizer Bahnhof. · • Schlesischer Bahn- hof Anhalt - Dresdner Bahnhof • · 1907 1908 1909 1910 29 207 944 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof . In der oben besprochenen Weise gruppiert Eingänge an Eiern der einzelnen Bahnhöfe: 1904 29 940 586 Eingang 40 054 500 85 256 18 380 113 522 607 954 5 600 497 820 1 488 779 Eingang 36 912 000 80 982 20 020 69 430 618 020 17 210 509 584 1 348 639 Eingang 39 449 911 84 315 29 340 43 884 468 979 91 397 417 493 1 212 752 Eingang 39 515 000 148 202 17 360 76 645 618 102 96 059 407 120 1 272 892 Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof 732 642 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof . Stettiner Bahnhof Ausgang 493 860 25 007 75 060 768 149 109 937 480 930 852 158 Ausgang 895 910 16 128 79 310 619 942 126 428 5 000 330 289 610 523 Ausgang 889 980 33 438 86 970 720 160 111 478 3 605 346 621 209 604 Ausgang 680 890 45 254 88 180 721 539 200 188 530 770 647 561 betrugen die 47 840 45 190 15 103 460 062 91 380 375 110 1 034 685 14 Schlesischer Bahn- hof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof Schlesischer Bahn= hof Anhalt- Dresdner Bahnhof Schlesischer Bahn- hof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof • • Schlesischer Bahn- hof Anhalt- Dresdner Bahnhof • 1905 Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof 714 946 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof. Stettiner Bahnhof 31 514 106 32 229 052 1906 Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof. 785 168 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof. Stettiner Bahnhof 37 536 451 38 321 619 1907 40 054 500 Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof 1 488 779 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof. Stettiner Bahnhof 41 543 279 Schlesischer Bahn- hof Anhalt - Dresdner Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof Bahnhof . . 1 348 639 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof 1908 36 912 000 38 260 639 1909 40 662 663 Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görlizer Bahnhof 39 449 911 1 212 752 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof . Stettiner Bahnhof • • • 55 966 38 310 13 070 496 333 26 470 379 100 1 009 249 54 744 12 700 43 961 649 495 19 560 435 760 1 216 220 85 256 18 380 113 522 607 954 5 600 497 820 1 328 532 80 982 20 020 69 430 618 020 17 210 509 584 1 315 246 84 315 29 340 43 884 468 979 91 397 417 493 1 135 408 15 Schlesischer Bahn- hof Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof • 1910 39 515 000 Hamburg-Lehrter Bahnhof Görliger Bahnhof 1 272 892 Berlin-Potsdamer Bahnhof Ostbahnhof Nordbahnhof Stettiner Bahnhof 148 202 17 360 76 645 618 102 96 059 407 120 *) 1 363 488 40 787 892 Nach den wie oben ermittelten Schäßungen trägt die inländische Produktion zur Befriedigung des Berliner Eier- konsums zirka 3% bei, ist also für die Versorgung Berlins mit Eiern herzlich unbedeutend**). Für diese Erscheinung fann ich nur folgende Erklärung finden. Mit dem Wachs- tum der Stadt und mit dem mit dem Entstehen eines wahren Massenkonsums mußte sich der städtische Nahrungsmittel= handel nach einer Zufuhr von Eiern umsehen, die der Nach- frage genügte und die auch im Herbst und Winter nicht aussette. In der inländischen Produktion_fand der Bedarf Berlins einerseits wegen der Spärlichkeit derselben, andererseits wegen der neu aufkommenden Konkurrenz der Nachfrage seitens der anwachsenden Provinzstädte teine genügende Befriedigung. Dieser Mangel mußte sich besonders im Herbst und Winter fühlbar machen. Die so entstandene Lücke in der Versorgung Berlins füllte ein neu aufkommender Eiergroßhandel aus, der ausländische Ware importierte, die in den Produktions- ländern bedeutend billiger war als die inländiſche, ſo daß ſie unter Berücksichtigung aller Transport- und Handelsſpeſen mit Gewinn am Berliner Markt abgeſeßt werden konnte, und die zugleich so reichlich vorhanden war, daß sie den Berliner Bedarf zu feiner Jahreszeit im Stich ließ. In der Gegen- wart, wo die inländischen Eier durch den gewaltig ange- stiegenen Import vom Auslande fast vom Berliner Markt verdrängt sind, spielt sich ein Konkurrenzkampf zwischen in- ländischer und ausländischer Ware nur noch auf folgenden Gebieten ab: Zufuhren von inländischen Eiern haben in Berlin hauptsächlich Detailgeschäfte, aber auch der Engros- handel hat einen geringen Umsak in dieser Ware. Detailgeschäfte halten inländische Eier als Nebenartikel zum Verkauf. Es sind Buttergeschäfte, ferner Delikateßwarenges ſchäfte, aber auch Gemüsekram- und Vorkoſthandlungen sowie Milchwirtschaften, ferner zeitweise Wildbret- und Geflügel- handlungen. Die Beziehungen, die diesen Detailgeschäften inländische Eier zuführen, sind recht mannigfache. Die wenigen Die *) Die Summen dieser Zahlen differieren mit den oben an- gegebenen, den Berichten der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin entnommenen, welcher Umstand wohl auf Schreib- fehler zurückzuführen ist. **) In „Berlin und ſeine Eiſenbahnen“ findet sich für das Jahr 1896 eine schäßungsweise Teilung der Zufuhr in 90% ausländische und 10% inländische; bei den Verhandlungen der Zolltariffommiſſion im Jahre 1902 wurde eine solche von 95% ausländischer und 5% inländischer genannt. 16 großen Firmen, die in Berlin das Buttergeschäft in Händen haben und durch ein weit ausgebreitetes Neß von Verkaufs- stellen den Absag im fleinen an die Konsumenten organisiert haben, haben teils Verträge mit Geflügelzuchtvereinen und Eierabsaßgenossenschaften auf Lieferung von Etern, teils be- kommen sie die Ware von eigenen Gütern und Molkereien, die auch Geflügelzucht betreiben. Gemüsekram- und Wildhändler erhalten inländische Eier von den ländlichen Aufkäufern, die ihnen auch die andere Ware liefern. Diesem Detailhandel steht der Großhandel mit inländischen Eiern weit nach. Ein Engroshandel mit inländischen Eiern besteht unter den berufs- mäßigen Berliner Eiergroßhändlern, die sich sonst nur mit dem Import und Absaß der ausländischen Ware befassen. Einige Importeure und wenige Eiergroßhändler kaufen zur Zeit der größten Produktion in den Monaten März bis Juni geringe Mengen inländischer Ware auf. Seit zwei Jahren haben diese Importeure den Versuch unternommen, auch am Berliner Eierspezialmarkt den Handel mit inländischer Ware einzuführen. Die Umfäße waren bisher jedoch sehr gering. Der Preis, den die Ware bei diesen Geschäften erzielte, war im Durchschnitt der Monate: - März April 4,01 3,59 per Schock netto, ohne den usancemäßigen Rabatt von 2 Schock per Riste à 1440 Stück. Ferner findet ein Engrosverkehr mit inländischen Eiern in der Zentralmarkthalle statt; hier wird diese Ware wie jede andere von städtischen Verkaufsvermittlern im Wege der Verauftionierung verkauft. Eine wie geringe Ausdehnung aber die dort erzielten Umfäße haben, läßt sich aus einer von beteiligter Seite gemachten Schäßung entnehmen, die die jährlichen Ümsäße auf noch nicht 200 Schod an= nimmt. Das inländische Et gilt als eine „Delikatesse“. Der größte Teil der nach Berlin aus dem Inlande kommenden Eier werden als „Trinteier" verkauft, worunter man große und völlig friſche Eier versteht, die zum persönlichen Genuß, meist nicht zur Zubereitung von Speisen verbraucht werden. Der Preis inländischer Eier ist das ganze Jahr hindurch höher als der der ausländischen Ware; zu ihren Käufern ge- hören Krankenhäuser, bessere Hotels, die wohlhabenderen Schichten der Bevölkerung. Die größte Menge inländischer Eier gelangt in den Frühjahrs- und ersten Sommermonaten auf den Markt, d. h. zu einer Zeit, wo die Zufuhr aus dem Aus- lande fast ausnahmslos friſch und in guter Qualität in Berlin anlangt. In dieser Zeit steht ein russisches und öster= reichisches Ei einem inländischen an Güte kaum nach. Die Folge ist, daß die Käufer wegen des billigeren Preiſes dem ausländischen Ei den Vorzug geben. Im Herbst und Winter liegen die Verhältnisse für den Abſaß der inländischen Eier bedeutend günstiger, "weil dann ein Teil der Zufuhr aus den russischen und österreichischen Produktionsländern in schlechterer Qualität nach Berlin kommt. Diese Erscheinung findet ihren Grund in dem Hang aller am Eierhandel im Pro- duktionslande Beteiligten, den Vorrat an Eiern in der Hoffnung auf Steigen der Preise eine Zeitlang zurückzuhalten. In diesen Zeiten unterscheidet der Berliner Eierhandel die 1909 1910 Mai 3,80 8,75 Juni # 3,90 4,- M. 17 K für vollfr. ausl. Eier normale Eter ausländische Zufuhr auch in vollfrische und in normale Ware. Daß für vollfrische aber dann eine große Nachfrage besteht, das ergibt sich aus der bedeutenden Preisdifferenz der beiden Sorten. Am Berliner Eierſpezialmarkt ſtellte sich der Preis im Durchschnitt der Monate - • Juni Juli Aug. Sept. Okt. Nov. Dez. 1909 3,82 3,80 3,93 4,19 4,65 5,76 5,94 3,37 3,37 8,39 3,72 4,01 4,68 4,62 1910 für vollfr. ausl. Eier 3,60 3,59 3,51 4,41 5,39 5,51 5,31 normale Eier 3,15 3,24 3,30 3,99 4,54 4,72 4,56 Die hohen Preiſe, die alſo in dieser Zeit für frische Eier zu erzielen sind, kommen der inländischen Produktion in nur ganz geringem Maße zugute, denn die Zufuhr aus dem In- Lande geht dann auf ein Minimum zurück. Die Nachfrage nach frischen Eiern muß dann größtenteils mit ausländiſcher Ware, mit dänischer und holländischer und in den Monaten Januar und Februar mit ungarischer Produktion befriedigt werden. Da inländische Eier in Berlin teinen eigentlichen Groß- verkehr haben, so haben sie auch mit Ausnahme der ſporadi- schen Preisnotiz am Eierſpezialmarkt in den Monaten März bis Juni teine eigene Pretsbildung. Ihr Preis hängt von dem der ausländischen Ware ab. In den großen Butter- geschäften wird der Preis für inländische Eier so bestimmt, daß unter Berücksichtigung der Notiz für ausländische Eier am Spezialmarkt und unter Berücksichtigung des Einkauf- preises ein angemessener Preis für den Detailverkauf ange= fegt wird. Aus allen diesen Ausführungen geht hervor, daß bei einer Betrachtung des Berliner Eiergroßhandels nur der Handel mit ausländischen Eiern in Frage kommen kann. 2 Einiges über den internationalen Eiergroßhandel. Der Berliner Eiergroßhandel ist ein Stück des internatio- nalen Eiergroßhandels, dessen Aufgabe es ist, den Ueberschuß der Eierproduktion der einen Gruppe von Ländern einer andern Gruppe von Ländern, deren Eierkonsum größer ist als die eigene Produktion, zu übermitteln. Ueber den internationalen Eiergroßhandel ist hier das zum Verſtändnis des Berliner Eiergroßhandels Notwendige zu sagen. Von der Größe des internationalen Eiergroßhandels entwirft folgende von Professor Sonndorfer ¹) aufgestellte Statistik ein Bild: Import der europäischen Staaten im Jahre 1906. England. Deutschland Frankreich Belgien. Schweiz Spanien. Schweden * Norwegen Finnland Holland Griechenland 170 355 000 177 600 000 14 425 000 6 960 000 18 670 000 3 150 000 1 839 000 92 400 1 635 000 1 265 000 106 600 Summe | 325,890 | 5888,- 391 098 000 Dieser Import wurde durch folgende Staaten gedect: Rußland Desterreich-Ungarn Dänemark Balkanstaaten Italien Aegypten Marokko Canada Portugal • • In In Millionen Millionen kg Brutto Stück 138,110 2265 149,643 2454 12,496 205 5,854 96 11,401 188 42 34 • 2,534 2,073 0,084 1,805 1,067 0,323 In In Millionen Millionen kg Brutto Stüc 172,744 59,004 17,927 35,366 31,116 3,780 4,268 1,4 29,6 17,5 5,5 Summe 1) „Der internationale Eterhandel." 2833 966 294 580 511 62 70 28 12 1,707 0,732 326,644 5356 Amtlich festgesteα= ter Einfuhrwert in Kronen ö. W. umgerechnet Amtlich festgeste¤- ter Einfuhrwert in Kronen ö. W. umgerechnet 140 941 000 62 757 000 25 269 000 31 683 000 51 900 000 2 591 000 4 200 000 2 553 000 900 000 322 794 000 19 Bei dieser Tabelle ist zu beachten, daß bei den Export- ländern die Größe des Exports abzüglich des Imports, bei den Importländern die Größe des Imports abzüglich des Exports eingesezt ist. Zur Ermittelung der Stückzahl ist als Nettogewicht 82% des Bruttogewichts angenommen und auf 1 kg netto sind 20 Stück Eier gerechnet. Im einzelnen betrug der Import Deutschlands in den lekten vier Jahren (im Spezialhandel)· Belgien Bulgarien Dänemark Frankreich Italien Niederlande Desterreich-Ungarn Rumänien Rußland in Europa. Schweiz Serbien Türkei in Europa. Aegypten. • Belgien Bulgarien Dänemart Frankreich Italien Niederlande Desterreich-Ungarn Rumänien Rußland in Europa Schweiz Serbien Türkei in Europa Aegypten • 1907 268 000 kg 6 316 000 62 400 148 300 4 914 800 4 134 500 58 975 100 3 929 400 66 097 200 445 100 1 899 600 2 067 400 11 11 4 370 400 0 11 · D n 143 800 1909 216 800 kg - 222 500 253 300 4 592 200 5 431 400 53 924 200 = 2 883 900 62 447 000 206 000 995 900 11 179 900 204 300 *** - = = n = 1908 294 800 kg 3 850 300 138 800 133 900 5 951 800 4 484 300 61 303 200 3 312 900 = 57 435 500 330 700 1 214 400 615 200 50 300 104 400 n 4 154 900 430 700 153 800 4 104 800 7 677 600 56 701 400 2 614 500 71 583 200 155 200 1 755 600 1 096 400 138 500 *** **** 0 1910 265 600 kg - 11 น Eier sind zu einem Welthandelsartikel geworden wie Getreide. Es haben sich durch jahrzehntelangem Gebrauch ganz einheitliche Regeln für die Verpackung und Sortierung Herausgebildet: Eier werden für den Export verpact in Kiſten à 1440 Stück. Die Kisten haben alle eine einheitliche Form und Größe, sie sind 180 cm lang, 60 cm breit und 30 cm tief, sie haben dickere Kopfbretter und dünnere Seiten= bretter, die Lücken von Zweifingergröße lassen. Jede Kiste ist durch eine doppelte Mittelwand in zwei gleiche Hälften geteilt, so daß sie leicht in zwei Halbkiſten auseinander gesägt werden kann. Zum Export gelangen meistens nur die besten und größten Eier eines Distrikts, die minderwertige Ware bleibt im Lande. Daher bedarf die im Exportlande an den Markt kommende Ware einer Sortierung nach Größe und Qualität. Bezüglich der Größe sind die üblichen Klassen: extragroße, mittelgroße und kleine Eier. Leßtere sind solche, die durch den 38 mm-Ring gehen. Auf die Qualität hin werden die Eier im Großhandel allgemein mittels des Eier- Dorm 2* 20 spiegels geprüft. Der Eierspiegel ist eine Lampe, dessen Zylinder eine undurchsichtige Umkleidung trägt mit nur einer eigroßen, runden Deffnung, durch die der Lichtstrahl bricht. Wenn in einem verdunkelten Raume ein Ei vor dieſe Deffnung gebracht wird, so ist sein Inhalt durchscheinend und kann auf Alter und Gesundheit untersucht werden. Bezüglich der Qualität unterscheidet man erste, zweite und dritte Sorte. In den Monaten März bis Junt werden die Eier auf ihre Qualität gewöhnlich nicht geprüft, weil dann alle Eier, die in den Produktionsländern an den Markt kommen, frisch sind. Einer Waggonladung Eier, die 100 Kisten enthält, find je nach der Jahreszeit 10 bis 25 Kisten zweiter Sorte beigegeben und 2 bis 3 Kisten mit nur fleinen und angeſchmußten Eiern. Diese Kisten mit den „Nebensorten" sind durch Signierung kenntlich gemacht. Das Auftaufen der Eier in den Produktions- ländern liegt in den Händen der Exporteure. Diese haben ländliche Aufkäufer an der Hand, die ihnen die Ware zu- führen und denen sie meistens auf die zu liefernde Ware Vorschuß geben müssen. Die Mehrzahl der Exporteure find kleine, wirtschaftlich schwache Existenzen, die nur mit Hilfe eines vom Bankter gewährten Kredits eine Wagenladung Eier auftaufen können. Es gibt unter ihnen aber auch große Firmen, die an vielen Stellen des Landes Auftaufstellen unterhalten. Auflaufstellen sind Zweigniederlassungen des Hauptgeschäftes in den Produktionsdistrikten. Sie haben nur die Aufgabe, Eier aufzukaufen, und zwar entweder nach einem wöchentlichen Limit oder auf jedesmaligen Auftrag des Haupt- geschäftes, das übrigens auch den Verlauf der an der Ein- kaufstelle gesammelten und dort exportfertig sortierten und ver- packten Eier in den Händen behält. Eine wichtige Rolle spielen im internationalen Eierhandel Konnossement und Frachtbrief duplikat. Das Konnossement besizt im Eterhandel dieselbe Bedeutung wie im Getreide- handel. Das Frachtbriefduplitat, das auch im internationalen Eiſenbahnübereinkommen vorgeschrieben ist, ist rechtlich zwar dem Konnossement nicht identisch, doch ist es dem Importeur ein sicherer Beweis dafür, daß die Ware abgegangen ist, auch ist dem Absender ohne Vorlegung des Duplikats die weitere Verfügung über die verladene Ware genommen. Die nach Deutschland importierten Eier unterliegen jeßt einem Einfuhr- zoll von 2 M. per 100 kg bei Export aus Vertragsstaaten, von 6 M. per 100 kg bei Export aus Nichtvertragsstaaten. Dem Transport der Eier nach Deutschland stehen der Landweg und der Wasserweg zur Verfügung. Der Wasserweg wird wegen seiner Billigkeit gewählt für den Transport russischer Eier über Petersburg und Riga nach den deutschen Küstenstädten Stettin, Lübeck, Hamburg, Bremen uſw. ſowie via Antwerpen nach der Rheinprovinz und auch wohl nach Süd- deutschland. Bei weitem aber die größere Menge der Ware wird auf dem Landwege nach Deutschland befördert. Für den Verkehr zwischen den hauptsächlichſten Abladestationen Galiziens und der Bukowina und den größeren Städten Deutschlands, so auch Berlin, besteht der Ausnahmetarif 42, sofern die Ver- ladung der Eier in halben Waggonladungen à 5000 kg oder in ganzen à 10 000 kg geschieht. Dieser Tarif bestimmt für jeden Importplag Deutschlands eine besondere, feste, von der Entfernung unabhängige Fracht. Dem Verkehr zwischen den 21 russischen Produktionsländern und Deutschland werden die Verbandtarife zugrunde gelegt. Nur für Waggonladungen à 10 000 kg, die von Rußland nach den deutschen Hafenſtädten rollen und zum Export nach außerdeutschen Ländern bestimmt sind, sind Frachtermäßigungen vorgesehen, um der Konkurrenz der russischen Ostseehäfen in der Verladung von Eiern be= sonders nach England entgegenzuwirken. An vorstehende Ausführungen ist noch einiges über die Konservierung von Eiern anzuschließen wegen ihrer großen Bedeutung für die Preisbildung im Eierhandel. Die Preise von Eiern erfahren mit dem Wechsel von Sommer und Winter und mit dem Steigen und Nachlassen der Produktion große Schwankungen. Im allgemeinen kann man sagen, daß Eier zwischen Ostern und Pfingsten am billigsten und um Weih- nachten am teuersten sind. Dieser natürliche, große, jährlich wiederkehrende Preisunterschied hat das Konservieren von Eiern hervorgerufen. Von den vielen verschiedenen Konser- vierungsverfahren haben in den Eiergroßhandel hauptsächlich nur zwei Eingang gefunden: das Einlegen in Kaltwasser und das Konservieren in Kühlräumen. Die Konservierung der Eier in Kaltwasser ist das ältere und technisch unvoll- kommenere Verfahren; das Einlagern in Kühlräumen ist seit einem Jahrzehnt bekannt, hat aber in der kurzen Zeit eine mächtige Ausdehnung erfahren. Ihm ist eine ungeahnte Ver- mehrung der vom internationalen Eierhandel, sowohl von Importeuren wie Exporteuren, jährlich konservierten Mengen zuzuschreiben, da es nicht so sehr an Stelle der Konservierung in Kaltwasser als neben dieſe getreten ist. Zur Durchführung der Konservierung in Kalkwasser gehören größere Kellereien. Die Eier werden eingelagert in große Bottiche aus Beton oder Holz, die bis zu 100 000 Eier faſſen können. Nach Fr. Prall „Die Eierkonservierung" wird als Kalkwasser ent- weder eine klare Lösung von Calciumhydroxyd benußt oder es wird ein Ueberschuß von frisch gelöschtem Kalk in Waſſer getan und damit zu einer dünnen Kalkmilch verrührt. Durch einen Zusaß von Kochsalz läßt sich zum Teil verhindern, daß merkliche Mengen von Calciumhydroryd durch die Schale in das Innere des Eies dringen. Eier, die in Kalkwasser ton- ſerviert werden, verlieren nicht an Gewicht, da sie nicht ab- trocknen, ihre Genußfähigkeit ist beeinträchtigt durch einen Beigeschmack von Kaltwasser. Werden Kalleier zum Kochen gebracht, so plagt meistens die Schale; ihr Eiweiß läßt sich kaum noch zu Schaum schlagen. Ein Kalkei läßt sich sofort als solches an der glanzlosen Schale erkennen. Statt Kalk- wasser wird bei Maſſenkonservierungen auch zuweilen Waſſer- glaslösung oder Garantol" verwandt. Bei Konservierung in Kühlräumen muß die Temperatur dauernd von bis +1° gehalten werden, die Luft muß eine Feuchtigkeit von 80% besigen. Die Eier werden in den üblichen Exportkisten verpackt eingelagert, und zwar hauptsächlich nur Ware russischer und österreichischer Provenienz. Als Einlage- rungsräume tommen wegen der techniſchen Schwierigkeit nur Kühlhäuſer in Betracht, in denen die Abkühlung der Räume mit Kältemaschinen bewirkt wird. In den meisten Kühl- häusern wird die Temperatur im Lagerraum für Eier durch Kühlröhren hergestellt, das Zuführen frischer Luft mit vorge= schriebener Temperatur und Feuchtigkeit geschieht so, daß die " -10 0 ― 22 Luft außerhalb des Lagerraumes abgefühlt und getrocknet und dann durch Ventilatoren in den Kühlraum getrieben wird. Die Eier lagern gewöhnlich fünf bis sieben Monate im Kühlhause. Bei dem Herausnehmen ist es nötig, daß die Eier, bevor sie der Außenluft mit einer andern Feuchtigkeit und Temperatur ausgesetzt werden, zuvor eine Zeitlang in einem Vorraume in einer nach patentiertem Verfahren ge= trockneten Luft verweilen, da sonst die Feuchtigkeit der Außen- luft sich auf das talte Ei niederschlägt und dasselbe zum schnellen Verderben führt. Wie findet nun die Ueberlegenheit der Konservierung in Kühlräumen vor der in Kaltwasser ihre Erklärung, troßdem die Kosten des ersteren Verfahrens die des letteren um ein vielfaches übertreffen? Dafür sind zwei Gründe ausschlaggebend. Einmal ist das Konservieren in Kühlräumen das technisch beſte Verfahren, es erhält das Ei am vollkom- mensten. Das Ei wird im Geschmack wenig verändert, ſo daß etwa ein fünf Monate altes Kühlhausei den Geschmack eines etwa drei Wochen alten nicht konservierten haben kann. Der Prozentsag der verdorbenen Eier ist verhältnismäßig ſehr gering. Zum Kochen lassen sich Kühlhauseier gut verwenden, ihr Eiweiß läßt sich noch zu Schaum schlagen. An der Schale ist ein Kühlhausei von einem frischen nicht zu unterscheiden. Gerade dieser Umstand iſt nicht zum geringsten Teil ausschlag- gebend für den Erfolg der Kühlhauskonservierungsmethode. Kühlhauseier gelangen nämlich sehr oft, und zwar nicht nur in Deutschland, sondern auch in andern Ländern als frische in den Handel. Das ist auch von den nicht unbeträchtlichen Mengen Kühlhausetern zu sagen, die in Berlin in den Handel tommen. In den Berliner Detailgeschäften werden Kühlhaus- eier fast nie als solche deklariert, sie werden durchgehends als frische, d. h. als nicht konservierte verkauft. Der Verdienst, der durch den Verkauf dieser konservierten Ware als frische gemacht wird, ist ein großer, denn der Preisunterschied der beiden Sorten beträgt 0,50 bis 1, M. per Schock. Der zweite Grund für den Steg der Kühlhauskonservierungs- methode ist der, daß sie dem Eierhandel ein viel besseres Mittel zur Durchführung seiner Spekulation ist, als Keller- anlagen zum Konservieren in Kaltwasser es je sein können. Das Konservieren von Eiern stellt sich vom Standpunkte des Handels als eine Spekulation dar: der Händler nimmt in den Zeiten, wo die Produktion reichlich und der Preis niedrig ist, Ware. aus dem Markte, um sie im Herbst und Winter, wenn die Produktion spärlicher geworden und der Preis dementsprechend gestiegen ist, zu verkaufen. Dieser spekulativen Natur der Konservierungen sind auch die Schwankungen der konservierten Mengen von Jahr zu Jahr zuzuschreiben. Nach den Jahren, in denen die Spekulation Verluste erlitten hat, weil einerseits im Frühjahr die Preise zu hoch waren infolge geringer Produktion oder lebhafter Nachfrage zu Konservierungszwecken und andererseits die Preise im Herbst und Winter niedrig, weil das Angebot der kon- servierten Ware auf den Markt drückte oder eine milde Tem- peratur die Produktion begünstigte, bemerkt man ſtets, wie die Spekulation mit dem Einkauf zu Konservierungszwecken Zurückhaltung übt, um später, wenn durch eine solche Ge- fundung des Marktes die Spannung zwischen Sommer- und Winterpreisen wieder eine natürliche geworden ist, abermals ***** p 23 Januar Februar März April Mai in den alten Fehler zu verfallen, nämlich zu viel Ware und zu teuren Preisen für Konservierungszwecke aufzukaufen. Bei dtefer Spekulation bietet aber das Kühlhaus dem Eierhandel bessere Dienste als das Kaltbassin. Bei Einlagerungen in ein Kühlhaus braucht der Eierhändler wegen räumlicher Be= schränkung seiner Spekulation feine Grenzen zu seßen, auch die finanzielle Beschränkung_schwindet fast; denn es wird ihm leicht gelingen, die in ein Kühlhaus eingelagerte Ware bis zu 75% des Wertes meist von der Kühlhausgesellschaft selbst beleihen zu lassen. Kühlhäuser gibt es außer in den west= lichen Kulturstaaten noch in Rußland, das mehrere ganz große, moderne Kühlhäuser beſigt. In den österreichischen Produktionsländern ist die Kühlhaustonservierungsmethode noch wenig verbreitet, dort herrscht noch die Konservierung in Kaltwasser vor. Von den zwei großen Kühlhäusern, die Berlin besitt, hatte bis 1909 nur das eine, das der „Gesell- schaft für Markt- und Kühlhallen" an der Trebbiner Straße Räume zur Einlagerung von Eiern eingerichtet, seitdem auch, aber in sehr geringem Maße, das der „Norddeutschen Eis- werke" an der Köpenicker Straße. Die Zahlen der jährlichen Einlagerungen bei der Gesellschaft für Markt- und Kühl- hallen" will die Direktion des Werkes aus naheliegenden Gründen nicht veröffentlichen. Es läßt sich aber ein Bild von der Größe dieser Einlagerungen und somit von der Aus= dehnung der Konservierung in Berlin überhaupt gewinnen aus dem Anschwellen der Empfangszahlen des Anhalter Bahnhofs in den Frühjahrs- und Sommermonaten. Eingang von Eiern am Anhalt-Dresdner Bahnhof: • Juni. Juli August September Oktober . November Dezember • Januar Februar März. April Mai. • Juni Juli. August · September. Oftober. November Dezember · • 1903 1065 kg 6 340 = 7 891 15 704 22 529 32 735 58 268 16 686 21 276 17 913 1 915 2 009 15 180 17 987 3 875 25 304 147 161 376 797 118 982 60 578 1 607 8 520 - n N 11 = M 1906 4 370 kg 4 807 n 1904 8875 kg 13 412 12 291 20 210 27 750 216 748 23 551 256 031 52 989 73 055 26 280 1 450 11 26 002 5 748 225 276 382 231 542 286 39 428 41 786 170 664 35 435 11 655 2 D 11 11 1907 6 925 kg 1 343 11 n W 11 n 11 11 = 1905 5 742 kg 1 920 13 814 3 149 63 170 202 784 241 248 56 331 94 450 15 955 7 136 9 244 = 4 809 14 483 **** ( = - = **** = 1908 1 135 kg 3160 3 981 4 929 2468 616 305 476 879 112 631 42 970 64 889 = 0 24 1 Januar Februar März April Mai • Juni Juli August September Oktober November Dezember 1909 5 719 kg 6 298 49 330 6 169 388 617 517 040 245 122 3 407 22 092 1 638 1 132 16 188 - 1910 4 045 kg 12 716 10 930 2416 317 792 778 844 47 424 49 058 14 830 7 485 2 597 24 755 - - = - Die Konservierungsmethode in Kalkwasser wird in Berlin nicht angewandt. Die in Berliner Kühlhäusern eingelagerten Eier find aber nicht die einzigen Mengen konservierter Ware, die hier in den Handel kommen, vielmehr ist im Herbst und Winter ein großer Teil des Imports Kall- und Kühlhaus- eier, die in den Produktionsländern konserviert wurden. Der Berliner Eiergroßhandel im allgemeinen. nommen "} Die Stellung Berlins im internationalen Eiergroßhandel ist die eines der größten Konſumpläge. Es wird ange- aus Mangel an Aufzeichnungen an andern Import- plägen ist es statistisch nicht zu beweisen daß Berlin nach London für Eier der größte Konsumplag Europas ist. Welchen Einfluß Berlin in dieser Eigenschaft auf die inter- nationale Preisgestaltung ausübt, ist später zu untersuchen, an dieser Stelle ist zunächst nur zu besprechen, aus welchen Pro- duktionsländern Berlins Einfuhr an Etern stammt. Die früher gebrachte Einfuhrstatistik gibt darüber keinen Aufschluß. Angaben über die in Berlin verzollten Eier werden nicht ver- öffentlicht. Einigermaßen richtige Auskunft können die regel- mäßigen Besucher des Eierspezialmarktes geben, die erfahren, in welchen Provenienzen" Geschäfte abgeschlossen werden. Da stellt sich dann erstaunlicherweise heraus, daß von den vielen Staaten, die Eier nach Deutschland einführen, nur ganz wenige nach Berlin exportieren. Fast den ganzen Be- darf Berlins an Eiern decken wohl zu gleichen Teilen Deſter- reich-Ungarn und Rußland. Von andern ausländischen Eiern kommen nur noch geringe Mengen rumänischer, holländischer und dänischer an den Markt. Bei dem Import aus andern Produktionsländern läßt sich von einer regelmäßigen Wieder- tehr nicht sprechen. Es ist mir gelungen, leider nur für eine Reihe von Monaten des Jahres 1911, die Abgangsstationen der am Schlesischen Bahnhof´ anlangenden Eierladungen fest= zustellen. Der so gewonnene statistische Einblick in das Ver- hältnis der Bezugsländer zu einander dürfte deshalb nicht ganz ohne Wert sein, da der Schlesische Bahnhof, wie die frühere Eingangstabelle zeigt, den überwiegend größten Teil der ausländischen Zufuhren bekommt. Die nachfolgenden Zahlen können keinen Anspruch auf Vollständigkeit machen, da einige Tage fehlen, wodurch das Gesamtbild aber wohl faum verändert wird. Eingänge am Schlesischen Bahnhof. Zahl der Kisten à 1440 Stück Eier aus: Mandala Vom 27. Januar bis 31. Januar 1911 Februar 1911 März April Mai. Juni Juli August Vom 1. September bis 22. September Desterreich- Ungarn 3 656 13 277 34 814 19 932 16 828 8 169 8 985 13 653 12 053 → Rußland 927 2 317 6 982 18 162 32 787 35 436 17 580 16 642 12 351 Rumänien und teilweise aus andern Ländern 175 240 1 26 Auch diese Zahlen bestätigen, daß der Berliner Bedarf an Eiern fast ganz mit österreichischer und russischer Ware befriedigt wird. Die Bedeutung, die Berlin als Stapelplag für den Artikel Eier hat, erreicht diejenige, die es als Konſumplag einnimmt, bei weitem nicht. Daß aber Berlin als Stapel- play in Betracht kommt, das zeigen die Zahlen der Ausfuhr. Das Jahrbuch für Handel und Industrie" und teilweiſe eigene Untersuchungen lehren, daß die Ausfuhrzahlen zum einen Teil kleinere Stückgutsendungen von einer halben bis zu einigen Kisten Eier betreffen, deren Absender Berliner Eier- importeure sowohl wie Großhändler und deren Empfänger Lebensmittelgeschäfte in den ferner gelegenen Vororten Berlins, z. B. in Potsdam, Spandau usw., aber auch in weiter gelegenen Städten und Städtchen der Provinz Branden- burg und der benachbarten Provinzen sind. Dieser Teil der Ausfuhr stellt also den Verkehr zwischen Großhändlern und Kleinhändlern dar. Der andere Teil der Ausfuhr entsteht durch die Weiterverladung ganzer Waggonladungen Eier nach weiter gelegenen Importplähen Deutschlands oder nach dem Auslande, nach England und Frankreich. Dieser Teil der Ausfuhr stellt also den Zwischenhandel der Berliner Eier- importeure dar. Die Jahresberichte über den Eierhandel im „Jahrbuch für Handel und Industrie" konstatieren seit mehr als einem Jahrzehnt eine Abnahme dieses Zwischenhandels. Der Statistit nach steigt die Ausfuhr bis zum Jahre 1895, und zwar im Verhältnis schneller als die Einfuhr. In diesem Jahre erreicht die Ausfuhr ihren höchsten Punkt mit 3 668 087 kg Brutto. Von da an ist ein Zurückgehen der Ausfuhr zu bemerken, obwohl die Einfuhr weiter steigt. Dieser Rückgang der Ausfuhr ist nach dem Jahrbuch für Handel und Industrie" in erster Linie dem Rückgang des Zwischenhandels zuzuschreiben, dem eine ungünstige Entwick- lung der Verkehrsverhältnisse geschadet hat. Es sind drei Momente, die hier offensichtlich auf eine Verminderung der Ausfuhr hingewirkt haben: 1. Die Ausdehnung der direkten Tarifverbände durch Einrichtung durchgehender russisch-französischer Tarife sowie der Umstand, daß der Ausnahmetarif 42 im Verkehr mit Galizien und der Bukowina auch für andere Importpläge Deutschlands in Ansatz tam, speziell auch für Hamburg, das so im Wettbewerb um den Zwischenhandel nach England vor Berlin einen Vorsprung erhielt. Aus der geographischen Lage Berlins, die bedingte, daß einige der direkten Tarife des Aus- nahmetarifs 42 über die deutsche Metropole führen, konnten die Importeure einen Nußen nicht ziehen wegen des Fehlens von Reexpeditionstarifen, da eben wegen des Fehlens der- ſelben bei einer vorläufigen Zurlagernahme der Ware am Orte und späteren Weiterversendung nach den Bestimmungs- plägen für den Rest des Transports die reguläre Fracht zu bezahlen ist. Welche Frachtunterschiede hier in Betracht kommen, zeigen einige in einem Schreiben vom Jahre 1903 der Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft an die Eisenbahndirektion angeführten Beispeile: - 27 Fracht für Eier per 100 kg 1. Swatowa-Hamburg seewärts a) direkt • b) Umexpedition in Berlin Swatoma- Berlin Berlin-Hamburg • 2. Huſiatyn-Hamburg seewärts a) direkt . b) Umexpedition in Berlin Hufiatyn-Berlin Berlin-Hamburg 3. Podmoloczyska-Hamburg seewärts a) direkt b) Umexpedition in Berlin Bodwoloczysta-Berlin Berlin-Hamburg 7,10 M. 1,88 = • 5,46 M. 1,88 ✓ 4,72 M. 1,88 8,05 M. 8,98 0,93 m. 6,29 M. = 7,34 1,05 m. 5,55 M. 6,60 1,05 m. Es bedarf teiner weiteren Ausführung“, ſo heißt es in dem Schreiben weiter, daß bei solchen Frachtdifferenzen eine Transportunterbrechung in Berlin im Interesse des hiesigen Zwischenhandels geradezu ausgeschlossen ist." " 2. Die Verteuerung des Lagergeldes. Bis Ende 1897 hatten die Berliner Eierimporteure eine Vereinbarung mit der Eisenbahndirektion auf eine Ermäßigung des tarifmäßigen Lagergeldes bei Lagerung im Eierschuppen am Schlesischen Bahnhof. Anfang 1898 wurde den Importeuren diese Ver- günstigung genommen und der gewöhnliche Lagertarif wieder in Ansah gebracht. Dadurch entstand eine Verteuerung des Lagergeldes um das Vierzehnfache für die erste Woche, um das Siebenfache für die weitere Zeit. 3. Die stetig fallenden Seefrachten. Die Verbilligung der Seefrachten hat den Zwischenhandel nach England, der Rheinproving usw. von Berlin auf die Küstenpläße abgelenkt. Vergrößert wird der Vorsprung der Importpläge an der Küste im Wettbewerb mit Berlin um diesen Zwischenhandel noch durch die differenzielle Tarifierung der Eierladungen, die von Rußland nach den Küstenplägen gehen und zum Export nach außerdeutschen Ländern bestimmt sind. Die Tendenz in der Entwicklung des Berliner Eierhandels geht jezt also dahin, ſich zum größten Teil auf die Ver- ſorgung des Berliner Plazes mit Eiern zu beschränken. Es entspricht der Bedeutung Berlins, als des größten Importplates Deutschlands, daß der Berliner Eiergroßhandel sich vor denen anderer Städte auch dadurch auszeichnet, daß er die Formen des Handels und seine öffentlichen Institutionen am meisten ausgebildet hat. Eine turze Uebersicht über die Institutionen ist hier vorwegzunehmen, da sie dem besseren Verständnis des folgenden dient. Das Verdienst, die Insti- tutionen ins Leben gerufen zu haben, fällt den öffentlichen kaufmännischen Korporationen und mit ihnen den Berliner Eierhändlern selbst zu, die als Mitglieder von Fachausschüssen dieser Korporationen für die gemeinsamen Interessen des Handels gesorgt haben. Diese öffentlichen Institutionen ſind folgende: 28 Einen Konzentrationspunkt erhält der ganze Handel durch den Eierspezialmarkt. Um die rechtliche Lage aller Geschäfte sowohl am Plage wie im Verkehr mit dem Auslande zu flären und zu sichern, sind die gewohnheitsmäßig sich bilden- den Geschäftsbedingungen fodifiziert. Um die Entscheidung von Rechtsstreitigkeiten zu verbilligen und zu beschleunigen, ist ein Schiedsgericht geschaffen worden. Die unvermeidlichen Reklamationen der Qualität der Ware sowie das Bedürfnis, in solchen Fällen ein unanfechtbares Gutachten über die Be- schaffenheit der Ware zu erlangen, haben zur Bestellung von ständigen, von der Handelskammer vereidigten Sachverständi- gen geführt. Die Träger des Berliner Eiergroßhandels und die Formen des Geschäftes. Wenn nun im nachstehenden gesprochen werden soll von den Trägern des Berliner Eiergroßhandels und von den Formen des Geschäftes, so ist zuvor die Frage zu beantworten, inwiefern das vom Berliner Handel zu entwerfende Bild typisch ist für das des Etergroßhandels in anderen Import- pläßen Deutschlands. Die Schilderung der Berliner Verhält nisse könnte typisch sein für die in anderen Städten Deutsch- lands, wenn nicht ein Umstand da wäre, der in seinen Folgen das Bild des Berliner Handels von dem jeder andern Stadt abweichen läßt; das ist die Teilung des Handels in Impor= teure, die die Ware im Auslande auftaufen, und in Eiergroß- Händler, die die Ware an Detaillisten weitergeben. Die Ent- stehung dieser Trennung ist nur zu verstehen, wenn man weiß, daß der Berliner Eierimport anfangs nur Kommiſſions= handel war. Der Kommiſſionär, der die Ware vom Auslande zum Verkauf erhielt, konnte sie nicht selbst übernehmen; da waren ihm wenige Großabnehmer an Stelle vieler Kleinab- nehmer ſehr willkommen. Jezt geben die Exporteure nur noch einen ganz geringen Teil ihrer Ware in Kommiſſion, den größeren Teil überlassen ste den Importeuren nur gegen festen Kauf. So wurde der Kommiſſionär notgedrungen zu einem Importeur. Zu diesem Umschwung in der Handelsfitte hat wohl die neu aufkommende Konkurrenz auf dem Markte ausländischer Eter seitens englischer und französischer Jm= porteure die Veranlassung gegeben. Das Jahrbuch für Handel und Induſtrie“ konstatiert eine Abnahme der Kom= missionsgeschäfte seit der Einführung des deutschen Einfuhr- zolles im Jahre 1879 und führt als Grund für die Erschei- nung an, daß Deutschland als Einkäufer auf dem Markte ausländischer Eier durch den Zoll seinen Konkurrenten, befon- ders England, gegenüber in Nachteil geraten sei. "/ Der Ankauf der Ware vollzieht sich jest in folgenden Formen: 1. Kauf „ab Station des Verkäufers" gegen sofortige Zahlung des Kaufpreises. Das Geschäft kommt hauptsächlich im Verkehr mit ruſſiſchen Exporteuren vor. Der Importeur muß durch die Vermittlung seiner Bant gegen Uebergabe des Frachtbriefduplikats über die verladene Ware dem Exporteur den Kaufpreis an seinem Domizile zahlen lassen. In manchen Fällen wird der Importeur nicht den ganzen Kaufpreis über- mitteln lassen, sondern einen Rücklaß“, d. h. eine Summe, an der er sich bei einem etwaigen schlechten Ausfall der Ware schadlos halten kann, bis zur völligen Abwicklung des Geschäfts zurückbehalten. "} 30 2. Kauf frei Berlin" gegen Einlösung des Duplikats mit der Zahlung des Kaufpreises in Berlin. Diese Art des Kaufes ist die häufigste im Verkehr mit den galizischen und russisch-polnischen Exporteuren. In diesem Falle trägt der Verkäufer alle Spesen, Zoll, Fracht und die Gefahr des Transports bis Berlin. Das Duplikat schickt der Exporteur oder, falls die Ware von einem Bankier beliehen war, dessen „Vorschußgeber" an eine Berliner Bank zum Inkasso des Kaufpreises. Auch bei diesem Kauf wird der Importeur meiſt einen „Rücklaß" verlangen, denn wenn er das Duplikat ein- löst, hat er die Ware noch nicht gesehen, da ihm nur im Besize des Duplikats das Verfügungsrecht über die Ware zu- steht. Dieses Geschäft tommt zwischen den oben erwähnten Exporteuren und den Importeuren anderer deutscher Städte mit einer fleinen Modifikation vor. Dort schickt der Expor- teur dem Käufer das Duplikat zur freien Verfügung ein und zieht auf ihn eine etwa drei Wochen nach Ankunft der Ware fällige Tratte in Höhe des Kaufpreises. Bei einem schlechten Ausfall der Ware fürzt der Bezogene die Tratte um eine entsprechende Summe. Bei den unter 1 und 2 beschriebenen Geschäften ist es Sitte, wegen der Preisschwankungen den Tag des Abganges der Ware vorzuschreiben. 3. Kommissionsgeschäft. Dasselbe ist, wie schon erwähnt, sehr zurückgegangen. Seine Abwicklung ist folgende: Der Exporteur schickt die Ware zu bestmöglichem Verkauf oder unter Preislimitierung an einen Importeur. Er schickt die Ware entweder „frei", d. h. er übergibt das Duplikat und damit das Verfügungsrecht über die Ladung dem Kom- missionär ohne jede Anzahlung, oder er läßt sich die Ware von ihm „bevorschussen“, indem er das Duplikat durch eine Berliner Bank gegen Nachnahme des ungefähren Wertes der Ladung ausliefern läßt. 4. Bezug von eigenen Einkaufstellen, die der Importeur in den Produktionsländern eingerichtet hat. Diese Einkauf- ſtellen, die sehr oft von Verwandten des Importeurs geleitet werden, kaufen und verpacken die Ware wie jeder Exporteur. Die Zahl der Einkaufstellen des Berliner Eiergroßhandels ist zurückgegangen, gegenwärtig haben nur noch vier Importeure Einkaufstellen in Rußland und Galizien. Als Vorteil einer Einkaufstelle wird genannt gute, zuverlässige Sortierung der Ware, als Nachteil teures Arbeiten. Der Exporteur soll mit ſeinen wohlfeilen Arbeitskräften eine Ladung Eier billiger aufkaufen und verpacken können, als eine Einkaufstelle. Eine weitere Folge der Einrichtung von Einkaufstellen iſt die, daß sich das Geschäft des Importeurs nicht mehr auf den Absaß am Berliner Plage beschränken kann, sondern seine Verlaufs- beziehungen auch auf andere Importpläße ausdehnen muß; denn in Zeiten, in denen die Preise in Berlin fallen, kann er einen im Produktionslande teuer eingekauften Waggon Eier nicht ohne Verlust nach Berlin verladen laſſen, ſondern muß ihn nach einem Plage senden, wo der Markt zurzeit ein festeres Gepräge zeigt. Und wirklich stehen diejenigen Jm= porteure, die Einkaufstellen in den Produktionsländern be= sigen, in regen Geschäftsverbindungen auch mit anderen Ex- portplägen Europas. Die Ware, die sie nach fremden Plägen = 31 verkauft haben, wird meistens nicht zuvor nach Berlin ver= laden, ſondern rollt direkt von der Abgangsstation nach dem Orte der Bestimmung aus Gründen der Frachtersparnis. Die Entwicklung dieses Berliner Zwischenhandels wird also von der früher angeführten Ausführstatistil nicht kontrolliert. Die nach Berlin eingeführte Ware verkauft der Importeur listenweise an die Eiergroßhändler. Die Abnahme der Ware erfolgt vielfach durch die Eiergroßhändler mit eigenem Ge= spann, und zwar am Ankunftsbahnhof selbst, wo die antom- mende Wagenladung Eier meist noch am Tage des Verkaufs an die Großhändler verteilt wird. Die Importeure nehmen alſo wie in den Zeiten des reinen Kommiſſionshandels´ die Ware nicht auf Lager, sie haben daher mit wenigen Aus- nahmen weder Fuhrwert noch Speicher. Das Risiko des Importgeschäftes ist, abgesehen von den Gefahren, die aus der Kreditgewährung an die Abnehmer, die Eiergroßhändler, entſpringen, ein doppeltes. Es entsteht 1. aus den Preisschwankungen der Ware, 2. aus der Art des Kaufes, die den Importeur zwingt, die Ware ungesehen zu übernehmen. Das erstere Riſiko iſt bei weitem das größere, weil enorme Preisschwankungen in kurzer Zeit nicht zu den Selten- heiten gehören. Es trifft sowohl Importeure wie Exporteure. Vergrößert wird das Risiko noch dadurch, daß manche, denen ein Schaden aus demselben droht, denselben abzuwälzen ſuchen, indem sie bei einer Preissteigerung nach Verlauf der Ware die Wagenladung unter einem Scheinvorwande nicht liefern oder bei einem Preisfall nach Kauf derselben auf die- ſelbe Weise die Ware nicht abnehmen. Das zweite Risiko ist dort ausgeschaltet, wo die Ware einem Kommissionsgeschäft entstammt oder von einer eigenen Einkaufstelle bezogen ist. Es läßt sich aber auch in den andern Fällen beschränken da- durch, daß der Importeur die Ware nicht „ab Station des Verkäufers", sondern „frei Berlin" übernimmt und bei jedem Kauf bis zur Abwicklung des Geschäfts einen genügend großen Rücklaß“ zurückbehält. " Den Berliner Eiergroßhändlern ist der Name keineswegs unbestritten; sie werden auch Eierdetaillisten genannt. Ich möchte sie zum Großhandel rechnen, denn sie verlaufen die Ware an Detaillisten, wie Kolonialwarenhändler, Butter detail- geschäfte usw., sowie an Großkonsumenten, wie Bäckereien, Konditoreien, Restaurateure. Der Absaß an Kleinkonsumenten spielt der Menge nach eine untergeordnete Rolle. Es gibt allerdings auch einige Eierzwischenhändler, die sicher als Detaillisten zu bezeichnen sind. Das sind die Eindringlinge des Geschäftszweiges, wirtschaftlich schwache Existenzen, deren ganzes Geschäftskapital kaum zur Beschaffung eines fleinen Kellers, eines Karrens und ein oder zwei Kisten Eier aus- reicht, mit denen sie die Kunden in der Stadt aufsuchen und ſo geradezu Hauſierhandel treiben. Von ihnen ist noch später zu reden. Nicht der ganze Import ausländischer Eier geht durch die Hände der Eiergroßhändler, vielmehr kaufen einige große Butterfirmen den für den Detailverkauf in den Verkaufstellen nötigen Vorrat direkt vom Importeur. Die Eiergroßhändler unterhalten einen Verkaufsraum, der meist zugleich als Lager 32 dient; etwa drei Viertel aller Geschäfte haben eigenes Gespann. Sie nehmen die Ware auf Lager und untersuchen sie durch Prüfen mit der Eierlampe. Hat die Ware einen größeren Ausfall als den usancemäßigen Rabatt von zwei Schock per Kiste, so wird sie reklamiert. § 5 der Berliner Geschäftsbedingungen sagt zwar, daß der Verkäufer nur zur Lieferung der Ware gegen Barzahlung verpflichtet ist; es ist aber durchweg üblich, daß der Eiergroß- händler den Kaufpreis zwei bis drei Wochen schuldet; auch eine vierwöchentliche, in einzelnen Fällen noch längere Frist wird ihm zur Zahlung gewährt. Der Umsatz eines Eiergroßgeschäftes ist ein bedeutender, selbst kleinere Geschäfte erreichen einen Jahresumsag von 50 000 M. Der Gewinn soll sich gewöhnlich nur auf 2¹½-3% vom Umsatz stellen. Die Berliner Etergroßhändler klagen sehr über die in den lezten Jahrzehnten unter ihnen entstandene übermäßige Konkurrenz, die durch das Eindringen völlig ungeeigneter und wirtschaftlich schwacher Elemente verursacht ist. Der Zu- zug eingewanderter Desterreicher und Ruffen, die den Handel in den seltensten Fällen mit genügenden Mitteln beginnen, ist für den Geschäftszweig zu einer wahren Not geworden. Es ist durch Prozesse und mannigfache Feststellungen in der Fachpresse genügend erwiesen, daß viele von ihnen den Handel auch betrügerisch betreiben. Die betrügerischen Machi- nationen gehen nach zwei Seiten hin: Sie schädigen den Ab- nehmer durch Verkauf schlechter Ware. So ſortieren sie aus russischen und galizischen Eiern die besten heraus, drücken den Stempel Trintei" darauf und verkaufen sie als inländische Trinketer. Sie verkaufen Kühlhauseier als frische. Fleckeier, die von der Berliner Polizei als verdorbene angesehen werden und deren Verkauf demnach verboten ist, knicken sie in der Schale etwas ein und verlaufen sie zu einem billigen Preise als Knickeier. - In zweiter Hinsicht richten sich die betrügerischen Mani- pulationen in Form von ungerechtfertigten Reklamationen der Ware gegen den Verkäufer. Es gibt in Berlin mehrere Eier- großhändler, die notoriſch vertragsmäßige Ware reklamieren und daraus ein regelmäßiges gewinnbringendes Geschäft machen. Es ist offensichtlich, daß dieser Uebelstand erst durch die merkwürdige Teilung des Berliner Handels sowie dadurch ermöglicht wird, daß der Importeur aus Mangel an Fuhr- werk und Speicher die Ware ungesehen dem Großhändler an- vertrauen muß. Um den Sachverständigen, der bei Reklama- tionen vom Verkäufer mit der Begutachtung der Ware be- traut wird, zu täuschen, verschlechtern diese Großhändler die Ware, indem sie gesunde Eier aus der Kiste nehmen und durch verdorbene erseßen oder gar ganze Kisten verdorbener Eier einer Sendung unterschieben oder Eier aus der Kiste entwenden, um das „Manko“ zu reklamieren. Durch Ver- wandtschaft miteinander verbunden, helfen sie sich zu ihren betrügerischen Manipulationen oft gegenseitig, so daß es schwer wird, gegen solche Vorkommnisse Front zu machen. Es leuchtet ein, daß diejenigen Händler, die durch derartige betrügerische Maßnahmen einen Ertragewinn an der Ware haben, ihren Konkurrenten überlegen sind. Das Vorgehen 33 des Vereins Berliner Eierimporteure, welcher seinen Mit- gliedern die Pflicht auferlegt, mit den als Betrüger festge= stellten Großhändlern nur noch Geſchäfte unter Ausschluß des Reklamationsrechtes abzuschließen, ferner das Vorgehen des Vereins Berliner Eiergroßhändler, sich mit Hilfe polizeilicher Verordnungen gegen diese Elemente zu wehren, ist bisher ohne endgültigen Erfolg gewesen. Solche Handelssitten ein- zelner Großhändler haben den ganzen Geſchäftszweig in Verruf gebracht, und zwar in den Exportländern sowohl als in Berlin selbst. Das wird erklärlich, wenn man die Art der Abwicklung der Reklamationen betrachtet. Der Impor- teur muß zwar den Schaden, der aus der Reklamation ent- steht, zunächst auf sich nehmen, stammt aber die Ware aus einem Kommissionsgeschäfte oder aus einem Kauf, der zu den Bedingungen frei Berlin" abgeschlossen ist, so wird er ihn auf den Exporteur abwälzen. Neben den Importeuren und Eiergroßhändlern unter- ſtüßt den Handel noch eine dritte Gruppe von Kaufleuten, das sind die Eieragenten. Sie vermitteln Geschäfte zwischen Exporteuren und Importeuren, wofür sie vom Exporteur und manchmal auch vom Importeur eine Provision erhalten. Einige Agenten am Berliner Plaze machen auch Kommissions- geschäfte. 3 Die Bank im Dienste des Eierhandels. = Die Bank leistet dem Importeur unerseßliche Dienste, ein- mal als Kreditgeberin, dann bei der Uebermittelung des Kaufpreiſes an den Exporteur. In Berlin kommen wohl nur die Importeure für einen größeren Bantkredit in Frage. Die Eiergroßhändler erhalten, wie gezeigt, von den Importeuren Kredit, auch bedürfen sie nicht der Dienste der Bank zu Zah- lungsübermittelungen, da sie nur am Berliner Markte kaufen. Die Importeure müssen dagegen in der Mehrzahl einen Bank- tredit in Anspruch nehmen; das scheint erklärlich, wenn man bedenkt, daß der Importeur die Ware sofort nach Kauf be= zahlen muß, den Gegenwert derselben aber erst erhält, nach- dem die Ware schon dem Konsum übergeben ist. Der Kredit, den ihm die Bank zur Durchführung seiner Geschäfte gewährt, ist zumeist ein Blankokredit. Im einzelnen gestaltet sich der Verkehr mit der Bank so: Hat der Importeur im Auslande, in Rußland, Ungarn oder Rumänien, Ware unter der Bedin- gung fofortige Zahlung gegen Dokumente" gekauft, so gibt er seiner Bank den Auftrag, durch ihren Korrespondenten am Orte des Verkäufers gegen eisenbahnamtlich abgestempeltes Duplikat des Frachtbriefs über die abgegangene Ladung den Kaufpreis in der Währung des Landes zahlen zu lassen. Um die Möglichkeit der Uebervorteilung seitens des Verkäufers möglichst zu begrenzen, wird im Zahlungsaufirag genau vor- geschrieben, welche Angaben das Duplikat über Anzahl der Risten Eier, Datum der Absendung, Bestimmungsort usw. enthalten muß. Während die Ware dem Plage des Käufers zurollt, wird das Duplikat von dem Korrespondenten im Orte des Verkäufers an die Bant weitergegeben. Diese stellt dem Importeur den ausgezahlten Betrag in Rechnung in deutscher Währung und berechnet für die Transaktion eine Auszahlungsproviſion, auch berechnet sie zumeist im Umrech= nungsturs noch einen kleinen Gewinn. Um ihre Kunden bei jedem Geschäft mit ihren Dienſten unterſtüßen zu können, muß die Bank in vielen, auch ganz kleinen Orten in den Produk- tionsländern ihre Verbindungen unterhalten. Bezahlung durch Akkreditive ist im Verkehr mit den Ex- porteuren Galiztens und Ruſſiſch-Polens selten; diese Expor- teure schicken gewöhnlich das Duplikat über die abgesandte Ware an eine Berliner Bank mit der Weiſung, es dem Käufer gegen Zahlung des Kaufpreises auszuliefern. Da der Käufer mit der Bank meist in Kontokorrentverbindung steht, so löst die Bank das Duplikat zu seinen Lasten ein und schickt dem Verkäufer den Inkassobetrag in der Währung seines Landes, den sie noch um eine minimale Inkaſſoproviſion kürzt. Ihrem Kunden dagegen stellt die Bank den Betrag in deutscher Währung in Rechnung und legt der Umrechnung einen etwas höheren als den Tageskurs zugrunde. Dieser Gewinn stellt eine angemessene Provision für Besorgung der fremden Geld- 35 ſorten dar. Die Rückzahlung des durch die oben beschriebe- nen Transaktionen in Anspruch genommenen Kredits erfolgt durch Bareinzahlung an der Kasse der Bank. Als ein Geschäft der Bant im Verkehr mit dem Eiergroßhandel ist ferner noch zu nennen das Lombardieren von Eiern, die zwecks Konſer- vierung in ein Kühlhaus eingelagert sind. Das Kühlhaus spielt in diesem Falle die Rolle eines öffentlichen Lagerhauses. Sie stellt über die eingelagerte Ware einen Warrant aus, der anstatt der Ware selbst der Bank als Faustpfand dient. In manchen Fällen begnügt sich die Bant nicht mit der einfachen Uebergabe des Warrant, sie teilt auch dem Kühlhausbeſizer mit, daß sie als Eigentümerin der Ware allein über diese verfügen kann, und läßt sich die Kenntnisnahme von dieſer Mitteilung bestätigen. Das Geschäft der Beleihung von Eiern, die ins Kühlhaus eingelagert sind, ist bei den Banken keineswegs ein bedeutendes, wie man das bei den großen Mengen der durch das Kühlverfahren jährlich konservierten Eier vermuten sollte. Das erklärt sich daraus, daß die Kühl- häuser selbst das Kreditbedürfnis der Einlagerer von Eiern befriedigen, indem sie ihre eigenen Lagerscheine beleihen. Der größte Teil der in den Berliner Kühlhäusern eingelagerten Eier ist nicht von Banken, sondern von den Kühlhausgesell- schaften beliehen. Für den llebergang dieses bankmäßigen Geschäftes an die Kühlhausgesellschaften ist wohl die Zurück- haltung der Banten, leicht verderbliche Lebensmittel zu be- leihen, entscheidend geweſen; die Kühlhäuſer glauben das Risiko der Verderblichkeit der Ware genau abschäßen zu können, da ſie die zur Einlagerung gelangenden Eier unter= suchen können und die Zuverlässigkeit ihres Konservierungs- verfahrens genau kennen. Von den Berliner Banffirmen, die sich mit der Finan- zierung des Eiergroßhandels befassen, hat die Nationalbant für Deutschland diesem Gebiete von jeher eine große Auf- merksamkeit gewidmet und steht unter ihnen an erster Stelle. Durch ihren weit ausgedehnten Kundenkreis, der nicht nur Importfirmen Berlins, ſondern auch anderer deutschen Pläße, auch in England und Frankreich, ferner Exportfirmen in Ruß- land und Desterreich-Ungarn umfaßt, ist sie zu einem Mittelpunkte der Beziehungen der Importeure und Exporteure geworden. Hier ist noch einer juristisch merkwürdigen Institution zu gedenken, die aus der engen Verbindung der Banken mit dem Fiergroßhandel, genauer gesagt aus der Kreditbedürftigkeit einiger Exporteure hervorgegangen ist, nämlich der sogenann- ten Vinkulation. Die Vinkulation, die auch im Getreide. und Futtermittelhandel Eingang gefunden hat, kommt im Verkehr der galizischen Exporteure mit deutschen und so auch Berliner Importeuren vor. Das wirtschaftliche Verhältnis, welches die Vinfulation geboren hat, ist folgendes: Der fleine Ex- porteur, der zum Aufkauf ſelbſt geringer Mengen von Eiern Kredit bei einem Bankier in Anspruch nehmen muß, ist ver- pflichtet, dieſem zur Sicherung seiner Forderung die Ware zu übereignen; das geschieht durch Uebergabe des Frachtbrief- duplikats. Im Besize dieses Dokuments dient der Bankier dem ihm vom Exporteur bezeichneten Käufer der Wagenladung die Ware an, indem er ihm das Duplikat übersendet, zusam= men mit einem sich als Vinkulation bezeichnenden Schreiben, welches etwa folgenden Wortlaut hat: 3* 36 B. B. „Hierdurch teile ich Ihnen mit, daß die Ihnen von Herrn H. verkauften 105 Kisten Eier von mir bevorschußt und mein Eigentum geworden sind. Ich überreiche Ihnen einliegend das Frachtbriefduplikat Nr. 20 340 und räume Ihnen das Verfügungsrecht über die Ware nur unter der Bedingung ein, daß Sie den Erlös der Ware zur vollen Deckung meiner auf Sie gezogenen Tratte von M. 7280 pr. 15./10. verwenden wollen. Anderen Falles bitte ich die Ware zu meiner Verfügung zu halten.“ War beim Kauf der Ware die Andienung derselben seitens des Bantiers nicht vorgesehen, so hat laut Gutachten der Handelskammer zu Breslau sowie der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin der Empfänger des Briefes nach dem Handelsgebrauch, der sich mit diesem Geſchäft in Deutſch= land gebildet hat, zwei Möglichkeiten: er fann die unter Vinkulation erfolgende Lieferung der Ware als nicht vertrags- mäßig abweisen, er kann sie auch annehmen. Im leßten Falle muß er aber den vollen „vintulierten“ Kaufpreis an den Bankier zahlen. Er kann sich also dem Vintulanten gegen- über nicht auf den schlechten Ausfall der Ware berufen. Auch alle andern Einreden, die sonst zu einer Kürzung des Kauf- preiſes oder zur Verweigerung der Zahlung desselben be- rechtigen würden, sind durch die Annahme der Vinkulation ausgeschlossen. Wegen dieser Ansprüche muß er sich mit dem Verkäufer selbst auseinanderseßen. Die Vinkulation iſt den deutschen Geseßen unbekannt, sie hat aber in der Praxis unserer Gerichte rechtliche Kraft angenommen. Maßgebend hierfür ist die Entscheidung des Reichsgerichts vom 31. März 1903 (7. Zivilsenat; Reichsgerichtsentscheidungen, Band 54, : 218 ff.). Die Entscheidung des Reichsgerichts kommt zur Anerkennung der Vinkulation durch folgende juristische Er- wägung. Sie nimmt an, daß die Andienung der Ware durch den Vintulanten, die an die im Vinfulationsbriefe normierten Bedingungen geknüpft ist, ein neues Angebot an den Käufer darstellt, welches rechtlich mit dem Verkauf der Ware nichts zu tun hat. Das ist die Tür, durch die das Reichsgericht zu einer Beurteilung der Rechtslage kommt, die ganz der beab- fichtigten Wirkung der Vinkulation entspricht. Wir haben nach dem Reichsgerichtsurteile bei der Vinkulation drei ver- schiedene Rechtsbeziehungen zu unterſcheiden, die voneinander getrennt bestehen: 1. das Verhältnis des Vinfulanten zum Käufer, 2. das Verhältnis des Verkäufers zum Vintulanten, 3. das Verhältnis des Verkäufers zum Käufer. Das Ver- hältnis des Vinkulanten zum Käufer stellt sich juristisch so dar: Der Vinfulant bietet die Leistung eines Dritten, des Verkäufers, an mit der Wirkung, daß durch die Leistung des Vinkulanten der Anspruch des Käufers auf Leiſtung des Ver- läufers erlischt. Der Vinkulant bietet dem Käufer eine Ware an, über deren qualitative Beschaffenheit er teine Abmachun- gen trifft. Daher ist der Käufer verpflichtet, dem Vinkulanten den geforderten Kaufpreis ohne Rücksicht auf den Ausfall der Ware zu zahlen. Das Verhältnis des Verkäufers zum Bin- tulanten ist das des Kreditnehmers zum Kreditgeber. Das Verhältnis des Verkäufers zum Käufer ist ein doppeltes: - 37 1. War die Andienung der Ware durch den Vintulanten beim Kauf vorgesehen, so kann der Käufer das Angebot des Vintulanten nicht ablehnen. Der Verläufer ist aber zur Lieferung einer vertragsmäßigen Ware verpflichtet. Er bleibt also, obwohl die Lieferung durch den Vinkulanten bewirkt und die Zahlung des vollen Kaufpreiſes an dieſen erfolgt iſt, dem Käufer haftbar für alle Ansprüche, die sich aus etwaigen Mängeln der Ware ergeben. 2. War die Andienung der Ware durch den Vinkulanten beim Abschluß des Kaufgeschäftes nicht vorgesehen, so tann der Käufer das Angebot des Vinkulanten ablehnen; denn er hat einen Anspruch auf Lieferung von Ware frei von fremden Rechten. Der Verkäufer bleibt auch zur Lieferung der ver- tragsmäßigen Ware weiter verpflichtet. Nimmt der Käufer aber das Angebot des Vinfulanten an, so tritt er mit diesem in einen Vertrag ein, der die oben beschriebenen Folgen nach sich zieht. Wirtschaftlich bedeutet das Verhältnis des Verkäufers zum Käufer, wie aus häufigen Klagen der Importeure und aus Prozessen hervorgeht, oft folgendes: Der Importeur hat die Ware unter Bedingungen getauft, die ihn vor einem Verlust bei schlechter Beschaffenheit der Ware schüßen sollen, also gegen Zahlung des Kaufpreises mit einem Rücklaß“ oder gegen Zahlung erst nach Besichtigung oder nach Ver. wertung der Ware. Nun wird ihm die Ware zur Verfügung gestellt durch einen Vinfulanten mit der Bedingung, an ihn den Kaufpreis zu zahlen. Da der Käufer dem Vinkulanten gegenüber die Ware nicht wegen Mängel rügen kann, so sind die zu seinen Gunsten mit dem Verkäufer getroffenen Zah- lungsbedingungen hinfällig geworden. Der Ausweg, den ihm unsere Rechtsprechung gibt, nämlich das Angebot des Vintu- lanten nicht anzunehmen, ist für den Importeur oft ohne Nußen; denn in einigen Fällen wird er die gekaufte Ware zur Abwicklung seiner Geschäfte unbedingt benötigen, in andern Fällen wird die Preisentwicklung eine günstige sein, so daß ihm ein Gewinn entgehen würde. Uebernimmt der Käufer aber die vom Vinkulanten zur Verfügung gestellte Ware und rechtfertigt die Beschaffenheit derselben einen Abzug vom Kaufpreise, so steht ihm der Anspruch aus diesem Ver- lust gegen den Verkäufer zu. Dieser Rechtsanspruch erweist sich aber für den Käufer meistens als wertlos, wegen der Insolvenz des Verkäufers; denn es sind nicht die potenten Exporteure, die ihre Ware durch einen Vinkulanten andienen laffen, sondern Firmen mit wenig Kapital und oft zweifel- haftem Rufe. Es sind Fälle vorgekommen, wo die Vinkula- tion zu einem Betruge ausgenugt wurde, wo der Vinkulant die Ware keineswegs beliehen hatte, sondern eine vom Ex- porteur vorgeschobene Person war, wo die Vinkulation ledig- lich den Zweck hatte, eine schlechte Ware zu teurem Pretse unterzubringen. Der Eierspezialmarkt. Berlin besißt von allen deutschen Importpläßen allein eine börsenähnliche Organisation des Etergroßhandels im Eierspezialmarkt. Der Eierspezialmarkt hat seine jeßige Gestalt seit dem 17. Mai 1909. Vor dem Jahre 1909, und zwar von 1890 ab, war er räumlich und rechtlich dem sogenannten Frühmarkt der Produktenbörse angegliedert. Ueber diesen Frühmarkt seien folgende Bemerkungen angeknüpft. Nach dem Berichte der Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin vom 15. Dezember 18962) hat sich der Frühmarkt entwickelt aus einem öffentlichen, anfangs auf dem Gendarmenmarkte statt- findenden Markt, auf dem namentlich Getreide, Mehl, Heu und Stroh in Fuhren feilgeboten und gehandelt wurde. Als im Jahre 1863 dieser Markt von der Polizet nach dem Dranienplag verlegt wurde, folgten ihm die Getreidefonsu- menten wegen der weiten Entfernung des Marktplaßes nicht, ſondern mieteten von den Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft einige Räumlichkeiten im Börsengebäude, um darin an vier Wochen- tagen in den Morgenstunden ihre Versammlungen zu geschäft- lichen Zwecken abzuhalten. Als Mieter der Räumlichkeiten waren für alle Interessenten drei Kaufleute der Getreide- branche eingetreten; dieſe führten nun auch als Unternehmer des privaten Marktes die Verwaltung, und zwar zuerst unter der Firma „Kommiſſion für die Frühbörse“, dann die für den Frühmarkt gewählte Kommission". Sie hatten die Ver- pflichtung übernommen, jedem Getreide- und Mehlhändler, sowie auch anderen Personen, welche die Versammlung be- suchen wollten, den Zutritt zu derselben zu gestatten. Sie konnten jedoch und das geschah auch wirklich den Zu- tritt von der Lösung einer gegen ein Eintrittsgeld auszu- händigenden Legitimationskarte abhängig machen. 1890 er- neuerten die Mieter den Vertrag mit der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft nicht. Es traten nun zwei andere Mieter als Unternehmer des Marktes ein, das waren der Getreidehändler Herr Hugo Heilmann und der Eierkommissionär Herr Her- mann Hausen. Herr Hausen gerierte sich als Vertreter der Berliner Eiergroßhändler, die ebenfalls am Frühmarkt ihre Geschäfte abschließen wollten. 1896 erstreckte sich nach dem obengenannten Bericht der Handel am Frühmarkt auf Getreide, namentlich Hafer und Gerste, auf Mehl, auf Fourage (Heu und Stroh) und schließlich auf Eier. Besucht wurden die Versammlungen von etwa dreihundert Kaufleuten, Matlern, Müllern und Bäckern, von ungefähr hundertzwanzig Fourage= händlern, von etwa fünfzehn Fuhrherren und von annähernd zweihundertfünfzig Eierhändlern und Eierhändlerinnen (Wit- wen von verstorbenen Eierhändlern, die das Geschäft des = * 2) Korrespondenz der Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin 1896, Nr. 10. 39 // Mannes weiterführten). In Getreide und Mehl wurden vor- wiegend Effektivgeschäfte, lolo", "rollend" und „auf Abla= dung" geschlossen, und zwar zum Teil nach den von den Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft für den Berliner Getreidehandel festgeseßten Bedingungen, größtenteils aber unter ausdrüc- lichem Ausschluß derselben. In geringem Maße fand auch in Getreide und zwar meistens zwischen solchen Händlern, die auch die Hauptbörse besuchten ein Abschluß von Termin. geschäften unter Börsenbedingungen statt. Eine Kursnotie= rung bestand nur für Eier, für die eine Deputation aus den Kreiſen der Interessenten die Preisnotierung vornahm Die am Frühmarkt abgeschlossenen Geschäfte betrafen³) nicht zur Stelle gebrachte Waren; Kauf und Verkauf vollzogen sich nämlich nach Proben. Der Marktverkehr diente zum größten Teil dem Konsumbedürfnis der Stadt Berlin und seiner Vor- orte, erzielte aber dementsprechend große Umsäge. Anfang 1900 erhielt dieser Privatmarkt eine öffentlich-rechtliche Quali- filation: er wurde vom Polizeipräsidium auf Grund der Reichs-Gewerbeordnung als Markt organisiert. Er erhielt nun den Namen Spezialmarkt für Waren, eine Marktordnung und eine Marktkommission. M Meg glad "1 Der Engroshandel mit Eiern vollzog sich an diesem Markte Montags und Donnerstags, und zwar während der lezten Jahre in den Vormittagsstunden von 10-12 Uhr. Nach privaten Mitteilungen genügte die kurze offizielle Markt- zeit dem Etergroßhandel mit der Zeit, etwa seit dem Jahre 1905, nicht mehr. Daher fanden Nachmärkte statt, und zwar vor dem Börsengebäude auf offener Straße. Die Polizei hielt es für nötig, die Menschenansammlungen, die dabei natürlich nicht zu vermeiden waren, zu zerstreuen. Auch Siſtierungen famen gelegentlich dabei vor. Um dieſem unwürdigen Zu- stande ein Ende zu machen, mietete der Verein der Berliner Eierimporteure" einen Saal, worin die Interessenten nun zur Abwicklung ihrer Geschäfte zusammenkamen. Dieser private. Markt erlangte bald eine größere Bedeutung als der offizielle. Die Verhältnisse entwickelten sich bald so, daß die offizielle Marktzeit fast nur der Vorbesprechung der Geschäfte diente und daß der größte Teil der Umsäße am privaten Markte zu= ſtande kam. Durch einen Zufall erhielt das Polizeipräsidium hiervon Kunde. Es trat alsbald mit Bestrebungen hervor, den gesamten Eierhandel an einem offiziellen Markte zu kon- zentrieren und kam mit diesen Bestrebungen dem gleichen Wunsche der Interessenten entgegen. Man begnügte sich nun nicht mehr damit, die Marktzeiten zu verlängern, sondern schritt nach Verhandlungen mit dem Fachausschuß für den Berliner Eierhandel" bei der Handelskammer zur Neuorgani- ſation des Eiermarktes. Durch einen Erlaß des Miniſters für Handel und Gewerbe vom 16. April 1909 wurde be- stimmt, daß zu den Gegenständen des Verkehrs auf dem Spezialmarkt für Waren Eier nicht mehr gehören sollten, daß für diesen Artikel vom 17. Mai 1909 ab ein Spezialmarkt einzurichten sei, für den auf Grund des § 70 der Gewerbe- ordnung das Polizeipräsidium die Marktordnung erlassen 3) Bericht des Staatskommissars an der Berliner Börse in der Korrespondenz der Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft 1897, Nr. 3. 40 solle. Durch die unter dem 6. Mai 1909 gegebene Markt- ordnung hat der Eiermarkt seine jezige Gestalt erhalten, deren Hauptmerkmale folgende find. // "1 Der Markt für Eier ist ein Spezialmarkt, d. h. er ist nur für den Großhandel mit Eiern bestimmt. Die Deffentlichkeit und Freiheit des Marktes wird dadurch dokumentiert, daßz der Zutritt zu ihm jedem Interessenten des Eiergroßhandels erlaubt ist. Es wird aber von den Besuchern ein jährliches Eintrittsgeld erhoben. Der Marktverkehr findet statt Montags, Dienstags, Donnerstags und Freitags mit Ausnahme der anerkannten Feiertage sowie der beiden jüdischen Neujahrs- tage und des Versöhnungstages in der Zeit von 10 Uhr vormittags bis 1 Uhr nachmittags. 3 Der Hauptverkehr wickelt sich jedoch am Montag und Donnerstag ab. Das Marktlokal ist ein vom Verein der Berliner Eierimporteure" zusammen mit dem Verband der vereinigten Berliner Eier- großhändler-Vereine" von der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft gemieteter, in der ersten Etage des Börsengebäudes gelegener Saal. Eine aus den Kreisen der Marktbesucher vom Polizei- präsidium ernannte Markttommiſſion von dreizehn Mitgliedern, einem Vorsißenden und einem stellvertretenden Vorsitzenden wacht über die Ordnung des Marktes und nimmt die Preis- notierung vor. Die Kommiſſion iſt zusammengeseßt aus sechs Mitgliedern aus den Kreiſen der Importeure, sechs aus den Kreiſen der Eiergroßhändler, das dreizehnte Mitglied und ein Stellvertreter desselben wird vom Landes-Dekonomiekollegium vorgeschlagen. Aus der so zusammengeseßten Marktkommission schält sich die Notierungskommission in folgender Weise heraus. Es gehören ihr an neben dem Vorsißenden und dem stellver- tretenden Vorsitzenden und ſoweit anwesend dem Dele- gierten des Landes-Dekonomiekollegiums je zwei Mitglieder aus den Kreiſen der Eierimporteure und denen der Eiergroß= händler, die monatlich nach einem von der Marktkommission festgescßten Turnus wechseln. Die Beschlüsse sowohl der Markt- wie auch der Notterungskommission werden durch Stimmenmehrheit gefaßt. Bet Stimmengleichheit gibt die Stimme des Vorstzenden, wenn er abwesend ist, des stellver- tretenden Vorsitzenden den Ausschlag. M *** Die Handelsgeschäfte am Eterspezialmarkte haben zur Grundlage die Bestimmungen der allgemeinen Geschäftsbedin- gungen für den Berliner Eierhandel. Besondere Verein- barungen, die die Anwendung dieser Bestimmungen aus- schließen, kommen nur vor bei Geschäften in vollfrischen in- ländischen Eiern und in Kühlhausetern. Der größte Teil der Umfäße in der leßteren Sorte vollzieht sich auch nicht an der Börse, sondern von Kontor zu Kontor, was dadurch bedingt ist, daß die Etergroßhändler mit den Importeuren Lieferungs- verträge für Kühlhauseier abzuschließen pflegen, eine Gewohn= heit, die sonst dem Eiergroßhandel, wie aus früheren Dar- legungen hervorgeht, fremd ist. Die Ware, die am Markte gehandelt wird, ist nicht gegenwärtig aus dem einfachen Grunde der technischen Unmöglichkeit. Der Handel vollzieht sich auch nicht nach Proben, sondern nach „Provenienzen“, d. h. Abgangsstationen. Die Abgangsstationen zeigen den Distritt an, in dem die Eier gesammelt sind. Da nun erfahrungs- gemäß Eier eines und desselben Distrikts eine gewisse Gleich- mäßigkeit an Größe und Güte zeigen, so verbindet man mit - afy Veget 41 dem Begriff ciner bestimmten Provenienz auch den einer be- stimmten Größe und Güte der Eier. Diese Bestimmung der Ware nach Provenienzen wird noch durch eine genauere Unterscheidung ergänzt, indem der Verkäufer dem Käufer den Namen des Exporteurs nennt, von dem die Eier tommen. Den Käufern am Berliner Markte sind die Namen der Ex- porteure und die durchschnittliche Qualität der von ihnen verkauften Ware wohlbekannt, so daß Eier derselben Pro- venienz, aber von verschiedenen Exporteuren, oft einen ver- schiedenen Preis erzielen. Schlußbriefe über den Verkauf werden. nicht ausgewechselt; es genügt dem Handel zur Fixierung und Dokumentierung der gemachten Abschlüsse die Bleistift= notiz des Verkäufers. Der Handel ist immer nur ein Effektiv- geschäft, Termingeschäfte tommen nicht vor. Die verkaufte Ware lagert entweder schon in Berlin (Lokogeschäft) oder befindet sich noch auf dem Eisenbahntransporte (Abschluß in rollender Ware). Die Preisfestseßung erfolgt Montags und Donnerstags. Die Ermittlung des Marktpreises geschieht in der Weise, daß die Marktkommission durch Erfragen bei den Interessenten die wirklich erzielten Breise festzustellen sucht. Hierbei dürfen nur solche Geschäftsabschlüsse berücksichtigt werden, die nach Berliner Usancen abgeschlossen sind. Die Notierung muß den jeweilig höchsten und niedrigsten Preis der in den einzelnen Warenforten gemachten Abschlüsse erkennen lassen. Die Notiz lautet per Schock und versteht sich, abgesehen von inländischen Eiern, für Abschlüsse in Kisten à 1440 Stüd. Der Marktbericht unterscheidet zehn verschiedene Sorten. Der Bericht vom 29. Dezember 1910 lautet 3. B.: Eier im Großhandelsverkehr 1. Gestempelte vollfrische in- ländische netto ohne Rabatt per Schoď Sämtliche folgenden Sor- ten mit uſancemäßigcm Rabatt von 2 Schod per Hiſte von 24 Schock. 2. Vollfrische ausländische . 3. Südruſſen erster Sorte 4. In- und ausländ. beſſere Sorten 5. In- und ausländ. geringere Sorten 6. Zweite Sorte 7. Abweichende Sorten 8. Kühlhauseier 9. Kalleier . 10. Aussortierte fleine Eier u. dergl. "} "I "! " " " "} " " " 99 " // " D011 5,00 M. 11 "/ // 4,50 4,80 4,35 4,45 " n "I bis "/ 5,50 4,20 4,30 4,10 3,40, // 3,50 M. // "/ "/ " "} "I " Tendenz: fest. Wetter: kalt. Die Veröffentlichung dieses Kurszettels, der außer in den Berliner Fachzeitungen auch in einigen Berliner Tageblättern regelmäßig wiedergegeben wird, erfolgt durch Anschlag, und zwar mittags um 1214 Uhr. Man kann die Beobachtung machen, daß diese frühe Veröffentlichung beſonders in Zeiten schwacher 42 oder schwankender Tendenz einen gewiſſen Einfluß auf die Preise ausübt; denn dann zögern die Käufer, ungewiß, zu welchen Preisen sie handeln sollen, mit ihren Abschlüssen bis zur Veröffentlichung der Kursnotiz. Der Eierspezialmarkt bildet den natürlichen Konzentra- tionspunkt des gesamten Berliner Eierhandels. Durch den regen Besuch des Marktes seitens der beteiligten Geschäftsleute und die dadurch herbeigeführte persönliche Fühlung wird die Abwicklung der Geschäfte sehr erleichtert. Die Höhe der am Eierspezialmarkte erzielten Umsäße wird auf 90% der ge= samten Berliner Einfuhr geschäßt. Es ist offensichtlich, daß bei einer solchen Konzentration des Handels an diesem Markte die dort gebildeten Preise maßgebend find für den ganzen Eierhandel im Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiet. Nachdem wir so den Eierspezialmarkt kennen gelernt haben, drängt sich uns die Frage auf: ist dieser Markt nicht seinem Wesen nach eine Börse, liegt hier nicht eine kaufmän- nische Versammlung vor, die nicht der Gewerbeordnung, son- dern dem Reichsbörsengeset vom 22. Juni 1896 zu unter- ſtellen ist? Bevor auf diese Frage näher eingegangen wird, ſei erwähnt, daß sie für den Frühmarkt der Produktenbörse und somit auch für den damaligen Marktverkehr mit Eiern schon im Jahre 1897 aufgeworfen ist. Damals war der Frühmarkt, wie aus dem oben angeführten Berichte zu er= sehen ist, noch nicht als Markt im Sinne des § 70 der Ge= werbeordnung organisiert worden, er war noch ein freier Privatmarkt. Bei der Einführung des Reichsbörsengefeßes erhob sich Zweifel, ob dieses Marktgebilde unter das erwähnte Gesez falle. Der Staatskommissar an der Berliner Börſe entschied sich in einem Berichte vom 25. Januar 18974) für die Ansicht, daß der Frühmarkt eine Börse im Sinne des Gefeßes sei, weil er den Anforderungen der Definition der Börse in Konrads Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften genüge, die „eine regelmäßig sich wiederholende Zusammen- kunft von Kaufleuten und Handelsvermittlern zum Zwecke des geschäftlichen Verkehrs, des Kaufes und Verkaufes von Waren" verlangt, und weil er ferner den Anforderungen der Wermuth. schen Definition (Wermuth-Brendels Ausgabe des Börsen- geseges) entspreche, die als charakteristisches und ausschlag= gebendes Merkmal ansieht: die wirtschaftliche Bedeutung der Zusammenfünfte, namentlich in ihrer Einwirkung auf die Preisbildung in einem weiteren Wirtschaftsgebiete, über den engeren Kreis der Teilnehmer hinaus". Der Staatskommissar führt dann noch weitere Gründe zum Beweise seiner Behaup= tung an, die aber teils nicht ausschlaggebend, teils sachlich falsch sind. Dieser Auffassung des Staatskommissars traten die Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft in einem Berichte vom 15. März 18975) entgegen, indem sie geltend machten, daß das Vorhandensein der wirtschaftlichen Bedeutung des Früh- marktes besonders in seiner Einwirkung auf die Preisbildung in einem weiteren Wirtschaftsgebiete noch kein Beweis für das Vorhandensein einer Börſe ſei, daß vielmehr nach dem Sinne des Gesetzes zu einer Börse eine den bestehenden und 4) Korrespondenz der Aeltesten der Kaufmannschaft 1897, Nr. 3. 5) Korrespondenz der Kaufmannschaft 1897, Nr. 3. 43 im technischen Sinne unbestrittenen Börsen ähnliche Organi- sation und Technik des Handels gehöre, die aber dem Früh- markt völlig fehle. Die Frage, ob Börse oder Markt, be= schäftigte auch die Literatur. Unter andern unterzog Dr. Wiener in der Deutschen Juriſtenzeitung vom 15. April 1897 den Frühmarkt einer Unterſuchung, in welcher er zu dem Schluß kommt, daß man es hier nicht mit einer Börſe zu tun habe, daß dagegen das Vorliegen eines besonderen Mietverhältnisses und die starke Beteiligung der Konjumenten spreche. E. Tischer sagt in den „Annalen des Deutschen Reichs" 1899, Seite 42, über den Frühmarkt: „Es kann von einer Charakterisierung des Frühmarkts als einer Börſe nicht die Rede sein; es ist ein von Privaten veranstalteter Markt, welcher sich infolge der besonderen Bedürfnisse und Verhält- nisse der Großstadt in einzelnen Merkmalen seines Verkehrs von einem gewöhnlichen Martte unterscheidet." Auch im Ab- geordnetenhause kam die Frage, ob der Frühmarkt als Börje oder als Markt zu organisieren sei, zur Behandlung. Der Miniſter für Handel und Gewerbe erklärte) auf eine diesbe- zügliche Interpellation in der Sizung vom 25. Juni 1897, er habe Bedenten, den Frühmarkt für eine Börse im Sinne des Gesetzes zu erklären; es sei ein Privatmarkt. Anfänge zur Entwicklung als Börse seien allerdings vorhanden. Dieſe Ansichten über die rechtliche Natur des Frühmarktes und implicite über die des Eiermarktes kann man nicht ohne weiteres auf die rechtliche Natur des jezigen Eierſpezial- marktes ausdehnen, da derfelbe vom Frühmarkt abge= trennt, doch in mancher Hinsicht von jenem verschieden ist. Die Untersuchung der Frage, der Frage, ob der Eierspezialmarkt unter das Börsengeset fällt, wird darauf hinauslaufen, zu untersuchen, ob der Eierspezialmarkt den Erforderniſſen einer einwandfreien Definition der Börse entspricht. Das Börsengeset ſelbſt ſieht von einer Definition ab, da, wie es in der Begründung zum Entwurfe heißt, „eine solche kaum erschöpfend zu geben ist". Von den Definitionen, die die Nationalökonomie uns an die Hand gibt, heißt die, welche Pfleger in einem Artikel „Börsenrecht" im Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften aufstellt: „Börsen sind regelmäßig an einem bestimmten Orte zu einer bestimmten Tageszeit statt= findende Zusammenfünfte von Großlaufleuten eines Handels- plages und Hilfspersonen des Großhandels zum Zwecke des Abschlusses von Handelsgeschäften in bestimmten Mengenein- heiten generell bestimmter Wertpapiere oder typenmäßig be= stimmter Waren." = Die Definition von G. Schanz im Wörterbuch der Volks- wirtschaft lautet: „Die Börse ist eine an einem bestimmten Orte zu einer bestimmten Zeit regelmäßig stattfindende Ver- ſammlung von Personen, welche in der Hauptsache den Kauf und Verkauf von nicht präsenten vertretbaren Tauschgütern (Geldſorten, Wechsel, kurze Darlehen oder „tägliches Geld“, fungible oder fungibel gemachte Ware) bezweckt." Wie aus den weiteren Ausführungen Schanz' hervor- geht, ist mit dieſer Definition, und das gleiche ist auch von der Pflegers zu sagen, nur eine Börse im volkswirtschaftlichen 6) E. Tischer in den „Annalen des Deutschen Reichs" 1899, Seite 41. 44 "/ Sinne gemeint; von dem deutschen Börsengeseße ist anzu- nehmen, daß es von einem engeren Begriffe ausgeht, das geht aus der Begründung zum Entwurfe des Geseßes sowie aus verschiedenen Bestimmungen über technische Einrichtungen. der Börse hervor. Von den Definitionen einer Börse im Sinne des Gesetzes sei zunächst die von Dr. Wiener in der Deutschen Juristenzeitung") aufgestellte angeführt, welche be- fagt: Man wird eine Börse als vorhanden ansehen dürfen, wenn an einem Plaße des Großhandels an bestimmter Stelle eine sich regelmäßig an jedem Wochentage oder in anderen furzen Zeitabschnitten wiederholende Zusammenkunft einer Vielheit von Händlern und Handelsvermittlern eines bestimm ten Geschäftszweiges zum Zwecke des Abschlusses von Handels- geschäften in fungibler, nicht zur Stelle gebrachter Ware statt- findet, wenn die Angebote und Nachfragen hauptsächlich an dieser Stelle stattfinden und wenn die Gestaltung der Preise, die hier erfolgt, innerhalb eines weiten Gebietes bestimmend ist für die Preise oder doch den Ausgangspunkt bildet." Wiener hält also das Vorhandensein von Usancen, ferner die seitens der Börsenversammlung vorzunehmende amiliche Preis- feststellung nicht für unerläßlich zum Begriff einer Börse. Dem steht aber entgegen, daß es in der Begründung zum Entwurf des Geseßes heißt, daß die tatsächliche Gestaltung der vorhandenen und als solche im technischen Sinne unbe- ſtritten anerkannten Börsen genügenden Anhalt bietet, um zu entscheiden, ob eine kaufmännische Versammlung als Börse im Sinne des Gesezes anzusehen sei oder nicht". Amtliche Preisfest= stellung ist aber nach der Börsenenquete Eigentümlichkeit aller deutschen Börsen, mit Ausnahme der in Hamburg und einiger kleinen Börsen, deren Börseneigenschaften bestritten sind. Es ist ferner nicht einzusehen, wie sich ein börsenmäßiger Verlehr ohne Usancen abwickeln tann. " Das Erfordernis dieſer techniſchen Merkmale betont auch Kahn in seiner Ausgabe des Reichs-Börsengeseßes, indem er ſagt, daß von einer Börse im Sinne des gegenwärtigen Geseßes wohl nur dann wird gesprochen werden können, wenn diese Zusammenkünfte regelmäßig und stetig stattfinden, durch bestimmte Statuten geregelt, und dabet gewisse Ein- richtungen und Gebräuche als dauernde Institutionen maß- gebend find". Liebmann will in der amtlichen Preisfeststellung das alleinige Merkmal der Börse erblicken; seine Definition heißt: Als Börse im Sinne des Gefeßes sind diejenigen Bereini- gungen von Kaufleuten zu erachten, welche auf Grund der von den Teilnehmern geschlossenen Geschäfte einen im Wege der Selbstverwaltung der Vereinigung festgesezten Kurs oder Preis verlautbaren." Allein dieſe Definition iſt nicht voll- ständig, denn sie enthält u. a. nicht diejenigen Merkmale, die die Börse mit dem Markte gemeinſam hat. Fürst) sezt bei einer Börse folgende Merkmale voraus: 1. amtliche Preisfeststellung über vorgekommene Preise, 2. tatsächliche Bildung eines Börsenpreiſes, über den Kurszettel ausgegeben werden oder der sonst auf mechanischem Wege verbreitet wird, "! B 7) Vom 15. April 1897. 8) Abendblatt der Frankfurter Zeitung", 12. Febr. 1897. 45 3. Vermittlung der Geschäfte durch Kursmakler, 4. sonstige Börseneinrichtungen zur Benuzung des Börjen- handels, als da sind Usancen und die durch dieſe geſchaffenen Regeln und Institute, 5. Ausstellung gewisser Geschäftsbedingungen und Formen für die Termingeschäfte. Das unter 3 gebrachte Erfordernis der Vermittlung der Geschäfte durch einen Kursmakler hält Fürst in seinen weiteren Ausführungen nicht unbedingt aufrecht. Die Börsenenquete hat auch gezeigt, daß dieses Merkmal nicht bei allen Börsen vorfommt, vor allem nicht bei jenen, deren Geschäftsverkehr sich über ein Effektivgeschäft noch nicht hinaus entwickelt hat. Schließlich sei noch die Definition von E. Tischer") an= geführt, die alle in den vorhergehenden Definitionen aufge- ſtellten Merkmale einer Börſe, ſoweit ihre Richtigkeit nicht oben in Zweifel gezogen ist, in sich aufgenommen hat mit Ausnahme der zwei von Wiener aufgestellten Erforderniſſe, daß eine Börse an einem Plaße des Großhandels stattfinden und daß ihre Preisbildung innerhalb eines weiten Gebietes für die Preiſe beſtimmend sein müsse. Die Definition heißt: Eine Börse ist eine in regelmäßiger zeitlicher Folge sich wiederholende Versammlung von Kaufleuten, Handelsvermitt lern und anderen am Handel unmittelbar oder mittelbar be- teiligten Personen, welche an einem bestimmten Orte zum Zwecke des Abschlusses von Handelsgeschäften in nicht zur Stelle gebrachten vertretbaren Waren des Großhandels ſtatt- findet, wobei die Geschäfte unter Beobachtung gewisser fest- stehender Geschäftsgebräuche" (Usancen) abgeschlossen zu werden. pflegen und die aus den Geschäftsabschlüssen sich ergebenden Preise durch Organe der Versammlung festgestellt und ver- öffentlicht werden". " = * Hat nun der Eierspezialmarkt alle hier angegebenen Merk- male einer Börse? Ohne allen Zweifel hat der Eierspezial- markt neben dem Merkmale der regelmäßigen Wiederkehr in furzen Zeitabschnitten an einem bestimmten Orte, das eine Eigentümlichkeit der Börsen in ihrer Eigenschaft als Abarten der Märkte ist, auch noch die speziell börsenmäßigen, daß er hauptsächlich besucht wird von Kaufleuten, nicht von Konsu- menten und Produzenien. Auch das Vorliegen von Usancen kann beim Eierspezialmarkt nicht geleugnet werden; denn die allgemeinen Geschäftsbedingungen bilden zugleich die Regeln, die dem Handel am Markte zugrunde gelegt werden. Ferner findet eine amtliche Notierung sowie eine Veröffentlichung der erzielten Preise statt. Des weiteren steht fest, daß die am Markt erzielten Preise für die Preisgestaltung im Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiet und, wie im legten Kapitel noch zu zeigen sein wird, auch darüber hinaus bestimmend sind. Auch ist die Ware, die gehandelt wird, nicht zur Stelle gebracht; aber iſt ſie vertretbar? Vertretbar nennen wir eine Ware, wenn bet Handelsgeschäften das Interesse an ihrer individuellen Beschaffenheit erloschen ist, wenn die Ware einen Gattungs- wert besißt. Durch die Vertretbarkeit wird erst jene Leichtig= teit in Geschäften erreicht, welche den Börsenverkehr auszeich= net. Eine nicht vertretbare Ware muß beim Geschäftsabschluß zur Stelle gebracht sein, mindestens aber müssen Proben von 9) „Annalen des Deutschen Reichs“ 1899. 46 der Ware vorliegen. Wie wir gesehen haben, vollzieht sich der Eierhandel nicht nach Proben; aber troßdem bilden Eier nach meiner Ansicht kein vertretbares Gut. Die genaue Be- zeichnung der Ware durch die Provenienz und Nennung des Exporteurs, von dem sie kommt, weist darauf hin, daß das individuelle Intereſſe an der Ware keineswegs erloschen ist, daß es sich vielmehr immer nur um Kisten Eier einer ganz beſtimmten, auf dem Ankunftsbahnhof lagernden oder auf dem Transport befindlichen Wagenladung handelt. Das Geschäft am Eterſpezialmarkt iſt nicht, obschon die Eier vor- her einer Besichtigung nicht unterzogen werden, ein solches in generell bestimmten Waren, sondern es ist nur ein blindes Geſchäft und hat, wie Fachleute zugeben, auch alle Schwächen eines solchen, die nur durch das Recht der Reklamation nach Nebernahme der Ware einigermaßen gemildert werden. Der Eierspezialmarkt ist also dem Wesen nach teine Börse, sondern ein Mittelding zwischen Börse und Markt. leber den reinen Marktverkehr ist er hinausgewachsen, das zeigt sich in seiner dem Bedürfnis entsprechenden börsentech- nischen Einrichtung. Die jeßige Organisation des Eierspezialmarktes scheint den Bedürfnissen nicht zu genügen. Die Interessenten er- streben in jüngster Zeit ein dem Börsenchrengericht ähnliches Institut, wodurch sie die Möglichkeit erhalten würden, unwürdige Elemente vom Marktverkehr auszuschließen. Bei der jezigen Organisation ist ein solches Institut undenkbar, denn es ist unvereinbar mit der Marktfreiheit. Die Interessenvertretung des Eiergroßz- handels. Die Vertretung der allgemeinen Interessen des Berliner Siergroßhandels wurde im Jahre 1884 in die Hände einer Ständigen Deputation für den Berliner Eierhandel“ bei der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft gelegt. Seit dem Jahre 1903 hat auch die Berliner Handelskammer einen besonderen „Fachausschuß für den Eierhandel" eingerichtet, einem Antrage einiger vom Auslande eingewanderter und noch nicht natu- ralisterter Gierhändler Folge gebend, denen auf Grund des § 11 des Statuts der Korporation der Kaufmannschaft der Zutritt zur „Ständigen Deputation" verwehrt war. = "} Die Ständige Deputation für den Eierhandel" seßt sich) zusammen aus einem Deputierten der Weltesten der Kauf- mannschaft und augenblicklich aus sechzehn_Korporations- mitgliedern, die vom Aeltestenkollegium auf drei Jahre be- rufen werden. Der „Fachausschuß für den Eierhandel“ be= ſteht aus einem Delegierten der Handelskammer und aus vierzehn Mitgliedern aus den Kreisen der Eiergroßhändler, von denen sieben Eierimporteure und sieben Eiergroßhändler ſein müſſen. Die Wahl erfolgt auf drei Jahre für die Ab- teilungen der Ladungsimporteure und Eiergroßhändler durch die Angehörigen jeder Gruppe gesondert. Das aktive und passive Wahlrecht haben nur Inhaber einer eingetragenen Firma, welche zur Ausübung des Wahlrechts zur Handels- kammer befähigt sind. Der Fachausschuß kann sich durch Zu- wahl von höchstens drei Mitgliedern ergänzen; einer der Zu- gewählten muß ein Agent ſein. Zum Teil ſind die Mitglieder der Ständigen Deputation" zugleich Mitglieder des Fach- ausschusses. Die Aufgabe und das Wirken beider Interessen- vertretungen geht dahin, die gemeinsamen Interessen des Sierhandels bei den Behörden, den Eisenbahnverwaltungen uſw. zu vertreten, über die innere Entwicklung des Handels zu wachen, die für sein Wohl geschaffenen Institutionen zu er- halten und weiterzubilden. Beide Fachausschüsse wirken in friedlicher Konkurrenz nebeneinander. Doch bleibt es das dauernde Verdienst der Ständigen Deputation", speziell dessen Mitgliedes, des Herrn Hermann Hausen, der als der spiritus rector der für den Eierhandel geschaffenen Organisation ge= nannt wird, schon in den 1880er Jahren die drei bleibenden Institutionen, nämlich die des Schiedsgerichts, des Sachver- ständigenamts und der Kodifizierung der Geschäftsbedingun- gen ins Leben gerufen zu haben. Der „Fachausschuß für den Sterhandel" hat die Berufung und leberwachung der ver- cidigten Sachverständigen allein übernommen. Die Wahl der Schiedsrichter erfolgt in einer gemeinsamen Versammlung der Mitglieder der Ständigen Deputation" und des „Fachaus- schusses für den Eierhandel"; auch die revidierte Fassung der "1 // }} = 48 Geschäftsbedingungen vom 31. Dezember 1906 ist von beiden Interessenvertretungen gemeinsam herausgegeben. "} "} Als Interessenvertretungen des Eiergroßhandels kommen ferner noch die Vereine in Betracht. Gemäß der Scheidung der Branche in zwei sich gegenüberstehende Interessengruppen sind auch zwei Vereine entstanden. Für die Eierimporteure besteht der Verein der Berliner Eiertmporteure" (gegründet am 10. Januar 1905), für die Eiergroßhändler der Berein der Berliner Eiergroßhändler" (gegründet am 24. Mai 1905). Aus dem letteren Verein sind einige ältere Firmen ausge- schieden und haben den Verein Deutscher Eiergroßhändler" gegründet; fie glaubten ihre Interessenvertretung von der der zugewanderten Eierhändler trennen zu sollen. In Kardinal- fragen gehen aber beide Vereine der Eiergroßhändler zu= sammen und haben für diese den Verband der vereinigten Berliner Eiergroßhändlervereine" gegründet. " Maou H Das Schiedsgericht. Das Schiedsgericht für den Eierhandel hat wie jene Schiedsgerichte, die die Kaufmannschaft zu Berlin auch für andere Warenhandelszweige eingerichtet hat, den schon früher genannten Zweck der Beschleunigung, Vereinfachung und Ver- billigung des Rechtsverfahrens. Es wird gebildet von drei Schiedsrichtern, die aus der Zahl von fünfzehn zu diesem Amte Gewählten von deren Obmann für jeden einzelnen Streitfall besonders beſtimmt werden. Die Wahl der fünf- zehn Schiedsrichter erfolgt in einer gemeinsamen Versamm- lung der Mitglieder der Ständigen Deputation" und des „Fachausschusses für den Eierhandel“. Ueber die Zuſammen- segung ihrer Zahl bestimmt die Schiedsgerichtsordnung, daß zehn von ihnen Ladungsimporteure, fünf Eiergroßhändler ſein müſſen. Die drei für den einzelnen Streitfall ernannten Schiedsrichter sollen nicht ausschließlich der Gruppe der Jm- porteure oder der Gruppe der Großhändler angehören. Dem Schiedsgericht zur Seite steht ein juristisch gebildeter Syndikus. Die Parteien können sich vor dem Schiedsgerichte vertreten laſſen. Zur Eröffnung des Verfahrens hat der Kläger eine Klageschrift einzureichen. Das Verfahren ist geheim und an keine Normen gebunden; die Art seiner Führung unterliegt dem freien Ermessen der Schiedsrichter. Ein Protokoll über die Verhandlungen braucht nur insoweit geführt zu werden, als es für die Beeidigung eines Zeugen oder Sachverständi- gen für erforderlich erklärt wird. Das Gericht kann in jeder Lage des Verfahrens die Fällung eines Schiedsspruches ab- lehnen. Das gefällte Urteil wird ins Protokollbuch einge= tragen und nach Rechtskraft beim Amtsgericht Berlin-Mitte oder beim Landgericht I niedergelegt. Will die unterliegende Partei dem Urteil keine Folge leisten, so kann die andere Partei bei dem ordentlichen Gerichte das Vollstreckungsurteil des Schiedsspruches erlangen. Ueber die Zuständigkeit des Schiedsgerichts besagen verschiedene Gutachten der Kauf- mannschaft zu Berlin sowie § 4 der Berliner Geschäftsbedin- gungen, daß das Schiedsgericht zu entscheiden hat über alle Streitigkeiten, die aus einem nach Berliner Usancen unter Großhändlern geschlossenen Kauf entstehen, sofern betde Par= teten im Deutschen Reiche eine gewerbliche Niederlassung haben. Das Schiedsgericht ist obligatorisch, d. h. die Strett- sache kann nicht eher vor ein ordentliches Gericht gebracht werden, bevor nicht das Schiedsgericht die Entscheidung ab- gelehnt hat. Der § 7 der Schiedsgerichtsordnung bestimmt die zu erhebenden Gebühren. Sie betragen bei einem Strett= gegenstande bis zur Höhe von "} 50 M. ohne Ausfertigung des Schiedsspruches 1,50 M. mit " "} # 3,00 3,00 5,00 " 100, ohne mit "} " }} "} 17 " "I " 4 50 von " !! " " 200 M. ohne Ausfertigung des Schiedsspruches 5,00 M. mit 7,50 " "/ "/ 300 "I 500 ohne Unterschied 1000 1500 2000 über 2000 "I "1 "/ ohne mit "1 "/ "! " "/ " " " " "1 "I " • 7,50 10,00 12,00 17,00 20,00 25,00 30,00 " " " " "' " " "1 "1 " Wird die Klage vor oder in dem ersten Termine zurück- genommen oder lehnt das Schiedsgericht die Fällung des Schiedsspruches ab, ſo wird nur die Hälfte der Gebühren er- hoben. Die Gebühren sind fällig, wenn das Verfahren be- endet ist oder ruht. Ferner werden noch bei Hinzuziehung von Sachverständigen sowie für Stempel, Porto usw. die Auslagen erhoben. Schuldner der Gebühren und Auslagen ist der Kläger, nach Fällung eines Schiedsspruches haftet der unterliegende Teil nach Maßgabe desselben neben dem Kläger als Gesamtschuldner. Der Vorsitzende des Schiedsgerichts fann angemessenen Vorschuß fordern. " Das Sachverständigenamt. ศ Zur Begutachtung von Eiern beruft die Handelskammer zu Berlin auf Vorschlag des „Fachausschusses für den Eier- handel" und auf Grund des § 36 der Gewerbeordnung_ſowie des § 42 des Handelskammergefeßes auf jederzeitigen Wider= ruf und für die Dauer eines Jahres Fachleute, sowohl Im- porteure wie Großhändler, als Sachverständige und beeidigt fie. Der Sachverständige erhält von der Handelskammer eine Bestallungsurkunde; er führt ein Siegel, welches seinen Namen enthält mit dem Zusaß: „Von der Handelskammer zu Berlin beeidigter Sachverständiger zur Untersuchung und Begut- achtung von Eiern." Die Zahl der Sachverständigen fann auf Antrag des Fachausschusses mit Rücksicht auf ein vor- liegendes Bedürfnis beliebig vergrößert werden. Die Sach- verständigen unterstehen der Aufsicht der Handelskammer. Anträge auf Erstattung von Gutachten sind an das Bureau der Handelskammer zu richten, welche nach einer beſtimmten Reihenfolge einen oder mehrere Sachverständige bestellt. Ueber die Art, wie der Sachverständige prüfen soll, enthalten die §§ 10-15 der Vorschriften genaue Angaben: Der Sachver= ständige soll sich spätestens vierundzwanzig Stunden nach Erhalt des Auftrages zweds Besichtigung zum Lagerplaß der reflamierten Ware meist ist es der Keller des Großhänd- Iers begeben, nachdem er zuvor den Antragsteller und, wenn tunlich, auch die Gegenpartei von dem Zeitpunkt der Besichti- gung benachrichtigt hat. Um ein möglichst unparteiisches Urteil zu garantieren, find die Bestimmungen getroffen, daß die streitenden Parteien das Recht haben, der Besichtigung beizuwohnen, daß der Sachverständige aber ihre Beihilfe beim Auspacken verbieten kann und daß dagegen der Sachverstän- dige selbst einen Antrag auf Besichtigung nicht annehmen darf, wenn er an der Ware ein persönliches Interesse hat. Falls nicht besondere Vereinbarungen entgegenstehen, sind bei der Prüfung die Berliner Geschäftsbedingungen maßgebend, der Sachverständige kann demnach nur dann das Vorliegen einer nicht vertragsmäßigen Ware konstatieren, wenn der Ausfall den usancemäßigen Rabatt von zwei Schock pro Kiste übersteigt. Was als Ausfall zu betrachten ist, bestimmt der § 10 der Berliner Geschäftsbedingungen, welcher lautet: „Der Käufer hat faule, fleckige Eier und vollständigen Bruch nicht zu bezahlen. Knickeier, durch Frost aufgeplaßte und leicht angelegte Eier, die nicht als Fleckeier bezeichnet werden können, sind nur mit der Hälfte, kleine Eier, die durch den 38 mm- -Ring gehen, mit zwei Dritteln des Kaufpreises zu bezahlen." Die Begutachtung stüßt sich nicht auf die Unter- suchung der ganzen Ware, vielmehr ist der Sachverständige nur verpflichtet, ein Viertel des Inhalts einer jeden Kiste auszupacken und mit dem Eierspiegel zu untersuchen, den übrigen Inhalt aber, wie es in den Vorschriften heißt, „sach- 4* | 52 gemäß zu prüfen". Praktisch werden von dem Sachverstän- digen sechs bis acht Schock von jeder Kiſte untersucht. Der dabei ermittelte Ausfall von wertlosen und minderwertigen Eiern wird als Grundlage einer schäßungsweisen Ermittlung des Ausfalls der ganzen Kiste genommen. Ergibt die Ware allerdings bei der Prüfung des erſten Viertels einen ungleich- mäßigen Ausfall, ſo ſoll die Kiste mindestens bis zur Hälfte des Inhalts ausgepackt werden. Auf jeden Fall beruht also das Urteil zum großen Teil auf Schäzung. Wenn man be- denkt, daß durch das Gutachten über relativ große Summen entschieden wird und daß es vor Gericht volle Beweiskraft besißt, ſo läßt sich bezweifeln, ob es auf genügend zuverlässiger Grundlage aufgebaut ist. Der § 16 der Vorschriften bestimmt die Gebühren. Sie betragen zwei Mark als Grundtage für jeden Sachverständigen. Außerdem wird für jede zur Unter- suchung aufgegebene Kiste, gleich viel ob die Begutachtung durch einen oder mehrere Sachverständige erfolgt, eine Unter- suchungsgebühr von fünfzig Pfennigen berechnet. Der Höchst= betrag dieser Gebühr einschließlich der Grundtaxe darf für jeden einzelnen Sachverständigen fünfzehn Mark nicht über- steigen. Bei Begutachtungen außerhalb Berlins erhöht sich die Grundtare um fünfzig Pfennig respektive eine Mark, wozu dann noch gegebenenfalls die Reisekosten beansprucht werden können. Die Geschäftsbedingungen. Im Jahre 1884 wurden die Geschäftsgebräuche, die ſich im Berliner Etergroßhandel herausgebildet hatten, zum ersten= mal von der „Ständigen Deputation“ kodifiziert. Sie wurden abgeändert im Jahre 1896 und zum lehtenmal 1906. Die jezt gültige Fassung der Geschäftsbedingungen lautet: 1. Allgemeine Bestimmungen. § 1. Die Bedingungen gelten für alle Kauf-, Verkaufs- und Kommiſſionsgeschäfte mit Eierhändlern, die im Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiet ihre Niederlassung haben. Sie gelten nur insoweit, als eine anderweitige Vereinbarung nicht getroffen wird. § 2. Für alle Verpflichtungen ist Berlin, und zwar der Bezirk des Amtsgerichts Berlin-Mitte, Erfüllungsort. § 3. Den Sonntagen und gesetzlichen Feiertagen werden die beiden jüdischen Neujahrstage und das Versöhnungsfest gleichgeachtet. § 4. Die Entscheidung von Streitigkeiten aus Geschäften, die nach diesen Bedingungen geschlossen sind, erfolgt, sofern beide Parteien im Deutschen Reich eine gewerbliche Nieder- lassung haben, durch ein Schiedsgericht, dessen Verfassung und Verfahren in der Schiedsgerichtsordnung bestimmt ist. Für Streitigkeiten mit Personen, die im Deutschen Reiche keine gewerbliche Niederlassung haben, ist das Amtsgericht Berlin- Mitte und das Landgericht I Berlin zuständig. 2. Lieferungen innerhalb des Berliner Wirtschafts- gebiets. § 5. Der Verkäufer ist nur zur Lieferung gegen Bar- zahlung (per Kasse) verpflichtet. § 6. Als handelsüblich gilt die Verpackung in Kiſten zu je 24 Schock. § 7. Liefert der Verkäufer die Ware in die Geschäfts- räume des Käufers, so hat er 25 Pf. für die Anfuhr jeder Kiste zu fordern. § 8. Für etwaigen Bruch sowie fehlerhafte und ver- dorbene Eier werden dem Käufer zwei Schod Eier für die Kiste, und zwar jede Kiſte für sich berechnet, vergütet. Bei Vereinbarung einer höheren Vergütung ist der Käufer nur für die gesamte Sendung zu dem Abzuge der vereinbarten Mengen berechtigt. Die Sendung ist vertragsmäßig, wenn der Gesamtverlust an Bruch, fehlerhaften und verdorbenen Eiern die vereinbarte Vergütung nicht übersteigt Die gleichen Bestimmungen gelten für Kalleier sowie fleine, mittelgroße, schmuzige, abgetrocknete und Kühlhauseter. 54 § 9. Der Käufer ist berechtigt zur Untersuchung bei Lieferung von 1 Kiste 2 Lagen zu je 3 Schock auf einer Seite 6 Schock, " "} N " "I "/ von 2-3 Kisten 1/2 Kiste, und zwar entweder die linke oder die rechte Hälfte einer Kiste, 4-6 Kisten 1. Kiste, von 2 Kiſten, 7-10 11-20 3 Kisten, " "1 "/ "} " "1 bei mehr als 20 Kisten für je weitere 10 Kisten eine weitere Kiste auszupacken. § 10. Der Käufer hat faule, fleckige Eier und voll- ständigen Bruch nicht zu bezahlen.nideier, durch Frost aufgeplakte und leicht angelegte Eier, die nicht als Flecketer bezeichnet werden können, sind nur mit der Hälfte, kleine Eier, die durch den 38-mm-Ring gehen, mit zwei Dritteln des Kaufpreises zu bezahlen. § 11. Mängel der Ware sind spätestens am ersten Ge- schäftstage nach Ankunft der Lieferung, und zwar bis 6 Uhr nachmittags, dem Verkäufer anzuzeigen. Uebersteigt die Liefe rung die Zahl von 6 Kiſten, so kann die Anzeige für die 6 Kisten übersteigende Zahl spätestens am folgenden Ge schäftstage bis 6 Uhr nachmittags erfolgen. Ist die vertrags- mäßige Zahl von Eiern in der Kiste nicht enthalten, so muß die Anzeige bei Lieferung bis zu 6 Kisten innerhalb dreier Geschäftstage, bis zu 15 Kisten innerhalb vier Geschäftstagen, bei größeren Lieferungen innerhalb sechs Geschäftstagen schriftlich erfolgen. Die Anzeigen müssen bis zum Ablaufe der Fristen in den Geschäftsräumen des Verkäufers ein- gegangen sein. ศ § 12. Nach Eingang der Mängelanzeige ist der Ver- fäufer berechtigt, bis um 6 Uhr des nächstfolgenden Geschäfts- tages einen von der Handelskammer zu Berlin öffentlich an- gestellten Sachverständigen für die Untersuchung und Begut- achtung von Eiern, und wenn mehr als 15 Kisten geliefert worden sind, zwei Sachverständige mit der Feststellung der Beschaffenheit der Ware zu beauftragen. Der Verkäufer hat auf Verlangen den Käufer von dem Auftrage zu benach- richtigen. Unterläßt es der Verkäufer, die Feststellung der Beschaffenheit rechtzeitig zu beantragen oder die vom Käufer geforderte Nachricht zu geben, so ist der Käufer berechtigt, am folgenden Geschäftstage spätestens bis 6 Uhr nachmittags einen Sachverständigen oder bei Lieferung von mehr als 15 Kisten zwet Sachverständige zu beauftragen und den Ver- fäufer vom Auftrage gleichzeitig zu benachrichtigen; andern- falls gilt die Ware als genehmigt. Die Ware gilt ferner als genehmigt, wenn der Käufer sie an einen Dritten abgeliefert hat, ohne ihren Zuſtand feſtſtellen zu laſſen. I § 13. Der Käufer ist verpflichtet, die gekaufte Ware ab- zunehmen, auch wenn sie mangelhaft ist. Er ist in dieſem Falle berechtigt, für die vom Sachverständigen untersuchten Kisten den dem Minderwert entsprechenden Abzug und für die vom Käufer ausgepackten Kisten denjenigen Abzug zu machen, der sich als Durchschnitt aus den Abzügen für die unter- ſuchten Kisten und nach § 8 Abs. 1 Saz 1 für die Kiſten er- gibt, über die der Käufer bereits verfügt hat. Stark ab- weichende Kisten werden bei Ermittlung des Durchschnitts 55 nicht berücksichtigt. Die Abzüge kann der Käufer auch dann machen, wenn die ihm nach § 8 Abs. 1 Sat 2 gestatteten Abzüge niedriger sind. Die Entscheidung des Sachverständigen über die Höhe des Abzugs, der für jede untersuchte Kiste zu machen ist, ist für die Parteien bindend. 3. Lieferungen von auswärts nach dem Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiet. § 14. Kommissionsgeschäfte und Käufe. Bei allen Kommiſſionsgeschäften und Käufen, bei denen frei Berlin" zu liefern ist, kann der Kommissionär oder Käufer als Vergütung für die zum Empfange der Ware auf- gewandte Mühe 20 Pf. für jede Kiste fordern. § 15. Die Bestimmungen der §§ 8 und 10 und die Be- stimmungen des § 13 über die Höhe der Abzüge finden für Lieferungen nach dem Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiet Anwendung. § 16. Kommissionsgeschäfte. Werden Eier kommissionsweise geliefert, so hat der Kom- missionär etwaige Mängel spätestens an dem auf die Ab= sendung der Verkaufsanzeige folgenden Markttage (Montag und Donnerstag) seinem Kommittenten anzuzeigen. Die An- zeige ist rechtzeitig, wenn sie bis zu diesem Tage bei der Post aufgegeben ist. Ist die Ware zur Zeit der Absendung der Verkaufsanzeige noch nicht empfangsbereit oder der Empfänger durch die Bahn von der Ankunft noch nicht benachrichtigt, so hat die Anzeige erst an dem folgenden Markttage zu ge= schehen. § 17. Käufe. Der Käufer kann die Ware auf dem Eingangs- eiſenbahnhof oder in ſeinen Geschäftsräumen untersuchen, gleichviel, ob „fret Berlin“ oder „ab Versandort“ zu liefern ist. Er hat etwaige Mängel dem Verkäufer vor Ablauf dreier voller Geschäftstage nach Eintritt der Empfangsmöglichkeit durch eingeschriebenen Brief oder telegraphisch anzuzeigen. Ist die Ware von der Bahn Abnehmern des Käufers zu= gerollt, so kann die Untersuchung auch beim Abnehmer er- folgen. Will der Käufer die Ware wegen Mängel zur Ver- fügung stellen, so muß er dies bei der Anzeige erklären. Unterläßt er es, so ist er nur zum Abzuge des von den Sach- verständigen festgestellten Minderwerts berechtigt. § 18. Die Abrechnung des Empfängers gilt als an- erkannt, sofern nicht der Lieferer innerhalb zweier Wochen nach Eingang der Abrechnung widerspricht und den Wider- spruch auf bestimmte Tatsachen ſtüßt. 4. Lieferungen vom Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiete nach auswärts. $ 19. Der Lieferer ist berechtigt, nach erfolgter Anzeige von Mängeln einen oder bei Lieferung von mehr als 15 Kisten zwei öffentlich angestellte Sachverständige mit der Begut- achtung der Ware zu beauftragen. Das Gutachten ist für die Parteien bindend. Zu den einzelne Paragraphen ist folgendes zu be- merten: § 8 bestimmt, daß bei Verkäufen der Importeure an die Eiergroßhändler ein Rabatt von zwei Schoďk per Kiste ver- 56 rechnet wird. Dieser Rabatt wird vom Eiergroßhändler auch Abnehmern gewährt bei Verkäufen von größeren Mengen Eier bis herab zu einer halben Kiste. Laut § 15 finden dieſe Bestimmungen über den Rabatt ſowie jene der §§ 10 und 13 über den Abzug auch im Verkehr mit den Exporteuren der Produktionsländer Anwendung. Durch die Höhe des Rabatts nimmt Berlin unter allen Importpläßen Deutschlands eine Sonderstellung ein; denn die andern Importpläße verrechnen entweder überhaupt keinen Rabatt oder einen solchen von nur einem Schock per Kiste. Der hohe Rabatt dürfte daher auch die Stellung der Berliner Importeure beim Einkauf in den Produktionsländern beeinfluſſen. Der Exporteur wird den Rabatt in der Preis offerte berücksichtigen, er wird also die Ware nach Berlin teurer anbieten, als z. B. nach Hamburg, wo ihm nur ein Schock per Kiste abgezogen wird. Mancher Exporteur wird aber auch geneigt ſein, die nach Berlin_ver= taufte Ware so zu ſortieren, daß sie am Bestimmungsort einen Ausfall von nicht viel weniger als 120 Stück per Kiste hat, da sie in diesem Falle noch nicht mit Erfolg rellamiert werden kann. Der § 8 fagt ferner, daß der gleiche Rabatt gewährt wird beim Verlaufe von fleinen Eiern und von Kühlhauseiern. Bei Geschäften in diesen beiden Sorten sind jedoch anderweitige Abmachungen sehr häufig: Kleine Eier werden mit 2½ Schock Rabatt per Kiste gehandelt, bei Ge- schäften mit Eiern zweiter Sorte wird gewöhnlich ein solcher von 4 Schock per Kiſte ausbedungen. Der Preis für Kühl= Hauseier versteht sich meistens nicht per Schock, sondern per Kiste à 1440 Stück ohne jeden Rabatt und unter Ausschluß des Rechtes der Reklamation. § 13 verpflichtet den Käufer bei Geschäften innerhalb des Berliner Wirtschaftsgebiets, die Ware abzunehmen, auch wenn sie nicht vertragsmäßig ist. Der Käufer hat in diesem Falle nur das Recht, den Kaufpreis um den Minderwert der Ware zu kürzen. Durch diese Bestimmung soll verhindert werden, daß der Käufer bei einem Rückgange der Preise unter dem Vorwande der Mangelhaftigkeit der Ware diese zur Ver- fügung des Verkäufers stellen und so den aus der Preis- schwankung entstehenden Schaden abwälzen kann. Dagegen haben die Berliner Importeure im Verkehr mit den Er- porteuren sich durch den § 17 das Recht, die Annahme mangelhafter Ware zu verweigern, vorbehalten. Schließlich ist noch auf die im § 17 Sat 3 enthaltene Bestimmung hinzuweisen, daß die Untersuchung der Ware nicht auf der Bahn oder in den Geschäftsräumen des Im- porteurs zu erfolgen braucht, daß die Ware auch bei den Ab- nehmern des Importeurs besichtigt werden kann; durch diese Bestimmung wird eine durch die Organiſation des Berliner Eierhandels bedingte Eigentümlichkeit sanktioniert, die nicht zum Vorteil der Exporteure ist und die bei dieſen zu leb- haften Klagen Veranlassung gibt. Faktoren der Preisbildung am Berliner Markte. Früher wurde gezeigt, daß die Versorgung Berlins mit Eiern zum größten Teil auf der Produktion Rußlands und Desterreich-Ungarns beruht. Nun ist Berlin aber nicht der einzige Abnehmer der ruſſiſchen und österreichtſchen Produktion, ſondern es fommen neben ihm noch das übrige Deutschland, ferner England und Frankreich in Betracht. Der Bedarf Berlins ist also für die Stipulierung des Einkaufspreiſes, den die Berliner Importeure für die Ware zahlen müssen, wohl mitbestimmend, aber nicht ausschlaggebend; mit andern Worten: Die Preisentwicklung am Berliner Markt ist in erster Linie von derjenigen des international-europäiſchen ab- hängig, womit hier und im folgenden jener ideelle Markt be- zeichnet werden soll, der gebildet wird von dem gesamten Angebot der etwa oft- und südöstlich-europäischen Produktion und der westeuropäischen Nachfrage. Auf diesen Markt iſt also zuerst ein Blick zu werfen. - Zuvor muß noch auf zwei natürliche Eigenschaften des Artikels Eier hingewiesen werden, die die Preisbildung be- einfluſſen. Die leichte Verderblichkeit der Ware bedingt die Unmöglichkeit, sie ohne Konservierungsmittel längere Zeit lagern zu lassen und so einen zeitlichen Ausgleich zwischen den Schwankungen des Angebots und der Nachfrage zu be- wirken. Der augenblicklich verfügbaren Produktion steht also die augenblickliche Nachfrage gegenüber. Deswegen sind Preisschwankungen bei Eiern relativ häufig. In der ent- gegengesetzten Richtung wirkt der Umstand, daß der Konsum die Fähigkeit besißt, sich der Größe der Produktion resp. der Höhe des Preiſes derselben anzupassen. Eier sind zwar ein wertvolles und bei steigendem Wohlstande immer mehr ver- wandtes, aber immerhin ein entbehrliches Nahrungsmittel. Deshalb fallen mit den Zeiten der geringsten Produktion und des höchsten Preisstandes auch die des schwächsten Konsums zuſammen, während im Sommer mit der Produktion auch der Konsum zunimmt. Die Produktion unterliegt den natürlichen, vom Wechsel der Jahreszeiten bedingten und von den Schwankungen der Temperatur beeinflußten Veränderungen. Schlechte Ernten in den Exportländern und in deren Gefolge Dezimierung der Hühner bringen einen unvorhergesehenen Produktionsausfall. So tommt in die Preisbildung das erste unsichere Element. Was die Nachfrage betrifft, ſo ſind die Konsumländer Deutsch- land, England und Frankreich nicht auf Rußland und Dester- reich-Ungarn als Bezugsländer allein angewiesen, ſondern ſie haben auch eine beträchtliche eigne Produktion und noch Zu- fuhr aus andern Exportländern (Jtalten, Dänemark, Irland usw.). Da nun in einem Konsumlande das Angebot einer - 58 feiner Bezugsquellen zu bestimmten Zeiten besonders maffen- haft aufzutreten pflegt, also z. B. in den englischen Städten in dem einen Monat das Angebot irischer, in dem andern das dänischer Ware, so tann auf diese Weise die Nachfrage eines großen Abnehmers eine Zeitlang von dem Markte russischer und österreichischer Eier ferngehalten werden, um sich später wieder mit großer Dringlichkeit geltend zu machen. Da nun die Produktion in den Exportländern diesen Schwan- fungen der Nachfrage nicht folgen tann, so find Preis- fluttuationen unvermeidlich. Als weiterer Faktor der Preisbildung am internationalen Markte kommt die Spekulation hinzu. Man kann zwei Arten der Spekulation unterscheiden: Die eine versucht aus dem natürlichen Unterschiede der Sommer- und Winterpreise einen Gewinn zu ziehen und bedient sich zu diesem Zwecke der Kon- ſervierung, die andere will durch Zurückhalten der vor= handenen Vorräte einen künstlichen Einfluß auf die Preise ausüben. Obwohl die erste Art der Spekulation eine Ein- wirkung auf die Preise nicht zum Zweck hat, so hat sie doch eine solche zur Folge, und zwar eine für die Spekulanten selbst unliebsame; denn zur Zeit des Einkaufs vergrößert fie die durch den augenblicklichen Konsum bedingte Nachfrage und zur Zeit des Verkaufs das durch die augenblickliche Pro- duktion bedingte Angebot. Die Wirkung auf den Preis tann so weit gehen, daß (wie z. B. im Jahre 1909) die konservierte Ware im Winter billiger verkauft werden muß, als sie im Sommer eingekauft war. Volkswirtschaftlich betrachtet, hat diese Spekulation aber ihre guten Seiten; denn sie gleicht die Schwankungen in der Größe des Warenangebots bis zu einem beſtimmten Grade aus. Die zweite Art der Spekulation, die den bewußten Zwed hat, die Preise künstlich zu beeinfluſſen, hält die Warenvorräte eine Zeitlang zurück, ohne sich dabei der Konservierung zu bedienen. Sie kann daher mit Erfolg nur für turze Zeit und in großen Mengen von wenigen potenten Großhändlern in- fzeniert werden. Sie ist wegen der unter den Exporteuren und Importeuren herrschenden Konturrenz schwer durchzu= führen und kommt daher selten vor. "} Eier erfahren im Großhandel eine zweimalige Preis- bildung, nämlich im Produktionslande, wenn ſie in die Hand des Importeurs übergehen, und am Konſumplage, wenn sie an den Kleinhandel abgegeben werden. Die lettere Preisbildung vollzieht sich in Berlin auf der Grundlage einer marktmäßigen Organisation. Es ist selbstverständlich, daß die hier erzielten Preise nicht mit den im Produktionslande, am internatio nalen Markte" erzielten identisch sind, wenn auch die Kon= kurrenz unter den Importeuren eine allzugroße Spannung zwischen den Ein- und Verkaufspreisen für die Dauer nicht aufkommen läßt. Eine andere Frage aber ist es, ob die Tendenz des Marktes an den Konfumplage derjenigen des internationalen Marktes“ unbedingt folgen muß: Durch das Zusammenwirken von Exporteuren und Importeuren erfolgt bis zu einem gewissen Grade eine internationale Preisaus- gleichung; denn die Exporteure, die über die Preise an den hauptsächlichen Importpläßen unterrichtet sind, bieten ihre verfügbare Ware nach dem Plage an, wo der Markt festesten" ist, und die Importeure kaufen in dem Produktions- am "I "I 59 distrikt, wo die Ware am billigsten ist. Die Preisausgleichung ist aber keine vollkommene. Die örtlichen Differenzen find so groß, daß zeitweise z. B. in Berlin Eier zweiter Sorte den- selben Preis bedingen, wie in Hamburg Eier erster Sorte. Es sprechen hier lolale Verhältnisse mit, vor allem auch der Umstand, ob der Importplah eine bedeutende Zufuhr von Eiern aus seiner nächsten Umgebung hat. "} Obwohl die Berliner Importeure mit einer erheblichen Zufuhr aus dem Inlande nicht zu rechnen haben, geht doch die Preisentwicklung am Berliner Markte nicht immer der jenigen des internationalen Marktes" parallel. Am Berliner Markte steht der Nachfrage der Eiergroßhändler das Angebot der am Plaze vorhandenen und dorthin auf dem Transport befindlichen Warenmengen der Importeure gegenüber. Es kommt vor, daß zu einer Zeit, wo eine dringende Nachfrage der Konsumländer auf dem „internationalen Markte" den Preis in die Höhe treibt, in Berlin das Angebot der verfüg- baren Ware die Nachfrage übersteigt. Ein solcher Gegensaß in der Tendenz der beiden Märkte kann ſo weit gehen, daß die Importeure gezwungen sind, die Ware am Plage mit Verlust zu verkaufen, falls sie nicht vorziehen, dieselbe bis zum Winter zu konservieren, um den augenblidlichen Verlust zu vermeiden. Umgekehrt zeigt auch der Berliner Markt zu= weilen ein festes Gepräge, während am „internationalen Markte" die Tendenz eine weichende geworden ist. Dieser Fall tritt meistens nach den Zeiten ein, wo die Berliner Eier- großhändler sich in der Hoffnung auf einen baldigen Preis- rückgang im Einkauf Zurückhaltung auferlegt hatten und wo als Folge davon das Angebot vom Berliner Plaze sich fort= gewöhnt hatte, d. h. von den Importeuren möglichst wenig Ware aufgekauft und nach Berlin verladen wurde. Das Er- gebnis einer solchen Stockung ist ein am Plage eintretender Warenmangel, der, sobald er auf den Handel einen fühlbaren Druck ausübt, die Veranlassung wird zu einer unvermittelt und dringend hervortretenden Nachfrage, die auch zu erhöhten Preisen Befriedigung sucht. Dieser plögliche Umschwung in der Tendenz des Marktes pflanzt sich dann bei der Größe des Berliner Bedarfs, wenn auch im abgeschwächten Maße, auf den „internationalen Markt" fort. Lebenslauf des Verfassers. Ich, Anton Heinrich Rolf, wurde geboren am 24. Februar 1887 zu Haste bei Dsnabrück. Ich bin preußischer Staats- angehörigkeit und katholischer Konfession. Meine Eltern find der verstorbene Kaufmann Heinrich Rolf und dessen Ehefrau Anna geborene Roelker. Ich besuchte zunächst die Volksschule zu Haste und wurde Ostern 1901 in die Untertertia des Gymnasium Carolinum zu Osnabrück aufgenommen. Ostern 1907 beſtand ich an derselben Anstalt die Reifeprüfung. Dann bezog ich die Universität Berlin und widmete mich national- ökonomischen und juristischen Studien; unterbrach aber mein Studium, um zunächst eine Ausbildung in der Praxis zu er- langen. Zu diesem Zweck war ich zuerst als Lehrling, dann als Beamter im Bankweſen tätig. Im Winterſemeſter 1911/12 ſeßte ich meine Studien an der Universität Erlangen fort und beſtand dort Ende Februar 1912 vor der hohen philoſophiſchen Fakultät die Promotionsprüfung. DEC 18 170 Kelay 22 FOB FAS C&F CIF LCL elling Products to the World. atch ? HE I 1009 P18 ! To the Manufacturer, Exporter and Importer: We are presenting in this pamphlet a reprint of "Ameri- can Foreign Trade Definitions" adopted at a Conference held in the India House, New York, N. Y., on December 16, 1919, and participated in by committees representing the National Foreign Trade Council Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America National Association of Manufacturers American Manufacturers' Export Association Philadelphia Commercial Museum American Exporters' and Importers' Association Chamber of Commerce of the State of New York New York Produce Exchange New York Merchants' Association As the most certain means of insuring unmistakable clar- ity in terms and conditions of sale, the Conference voted to recommend to manufacturers and exporters that all use of abbreviated forms of export price quotations be abandoned, and that such terms be written out in full. The Conference recognized, however, that this recommen- dation is not likely to be accepted generally at once; and therefore, in the hope of effecting a simplification and stan- dardization of American practice, it adopted the within men- tioned statement of definitions of the abbreviated forms in more common and general use in the export trade. The Con- ference strongly recommends to manufacturers and exporters that whatever abbreviated forms of export quotations are em- ployed, the forms herein defined be used, as far as possible, to the exclusion of other forms. We are happy for the opportunity to bring this important information to the attention of merchants interested in over- seas trade and wish to express our grateful acknowledgment to the National Foreign Trade Council for the permission which they have so readily accorded us to make use of this timely data, in this way enabling us to lend what co-opera- tion we can in the admirable work being done by that organi- zation in the promotion of our foreign trade. THE UNION NATIONAL BANK OF SEATTLE JOHN CLAUSEN, Seattle, Wash. October 26, 1920. Vice-President To meet the many requests for copies of this booklet, we have been pleased to issue a SECOND EDITION. UNION SEATTLE OVERSEAS TRADE SERVICE We offer the facilities of a FOREIGN DEPARTMENT NATIONAL BANK fully equipped to meet every requirement. Our direct connections in all parts of the world provide an efficient banking service to care for the needs of MANUFACTURERS EXPORTERS AND IMPORTERS We invite correspondence G. F. CLARK Vice-President J. D. LOWMAN Vice-President JAMES D. HOGE Chairman of the Board J. A. SWALWELL President FORREST I. GILL Cashier JOHN CLAUSEN Vice-President A. B. STEWART Vice-President DEFINITIONS OF EXPORT QUOTATIONS EXPLANATIONS OF ABBREVIATIONS FREE ON BOARD FREE ALONGSIDE F. O. B...... F. A. S.... C. & F. COST AND FREIGHT C. I. F...COST, INSURANCE AND FREIGHT L. C. L......... LESS THAN CARLOAD LOT These are, in their order, the normal situations on which an export manufacturer or shipper may desire to quote prices. It is understood that unless a particular railroad is specified, the property will be delivered to the carrier most conveniently located to the shipper. If the buyer, for the purpose of delivery, or in order to obtain lower transportation charges, desires that the goods be delivered to a carrier further removed from the shipper and en- tailing a greater cost than delivery to the carrier most favorably situated, the carrier to which the buyer desires delivery of the goods should be named in the quotation. The term "cars or lighters" as used herein, is intended to include River, Lake or Coastwise ships, canal boats, barges, or other means of transportation, when so specified in the quotation. 4 1. When the price quoted applies only at inland shipping point and the seller merely undertakes to load the goods on or in cars or lighters furnished by the railroad company serving the industry, or most conveniently located to the industry, without other designation as to routing, the proper term is: "F. O. B. (named point)" Under this quotation : A. Seller must (1) place goods on or in cars or lighters (2) secure railroad bill of lading (3) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have been placed in or on cars or lighters at forwarding point, and clean bill of lading has been furnished by the railroad company. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage in- curred thereafter (2) pay all transportation charges including taxes, if any (3) handle all subsequent movement of the goods. LO 5 2. When the seller quotes a price including trans- portation charges to the port of exportation without assuming responsibility for the goods after obtaining a clean bill of lading at point of origin, the proper term is: “F. O. B. (named point) Freight Prepaid to (named point on the seaboard)" Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) place goods on or in cars or lighters (2) secure railroad bill of lading (3) pay freight to named port (4) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have been placed in or on cars or lighters at forwarding point, and clean bill of lading has been furnished by the railroad company. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage in- curred thereafter (2) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (3) unload goods from cars (4) transport goods to vessels (5) pay all demurrage and/or storage charges (6) arrange for storage in warehouse or on wharf where necessary. 6 3. Where the seller wishes to quote a price, from which the buyer may deduct the cost of transporta- tion to a given point on the seaboard, without the seller assuming responsibility for the goods after ob- taining a clean bill of lading at point of origin, the proper term is: “F. O. B. (named point) Freight Allowed to (named point on the seaboard) "" Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) place goods on or in cars or lighters (2) secure railroad bill of lading (3) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have been placed in or on cars or lighters at forwarding point, and clean bill of lading has been furnished by the railroad company. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage in- curred thereafter (2) pay all transportation charges (buyer is then entitled to deduct from the amount of the invoice the freight paid from pri- mary point to named port) (3) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (4) unload goods from cars (5) transport goods to vessel (6) pay all demurrage and/or storage charges (7) arrange for storage in warehouse or on wharf where necessary. 7 4. The seller may desire to quote a price covering the transportation of the goods to seaboard, assum- ing responsibility for loss and/or damage up to that point. In this case, the proper term is: "F. O. B. Cars (named point on seaboard)" Under this quotation : A. Seller must (1) place goods on or in cars (2) secure railroad bill of lading (3) pay all freight charges from forwarding point to port on seaboard (4) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have arrived in or on cars at the named port. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage in- curred thereafter (2) unload goods from cars (3) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (4) transport goods to vessel (5) pay all demurrage and/or storage charges (6) arrange for storage in warehouse or on wharf where necessary. 5. It may be that the goods, on which a price is quoted covering the transportation of the goods to the seaboard, constitute less than a carload lot. In this case, the proper term is: "F. O. B. Cars (named port) L. C. L." Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) deliver goods to the initial carrier (2) secure railroad bill of lading (3) pay all freight charges from forwarding point to port on seaboard (4) be responsible for loss and/or damage until goods have arrived on cars at the named port. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage in- curred thereafter (2) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (3) accept goods from the carrier (4) transport goods to vessel (5) pay all storage charges (6) arrange for storage in warehouse or on wharf where necessary. 9 6. Seller may quote a price which will include the expense of transportation of the goods by rail to the seaboard, including lighterage. In this case, the proper term is: "F. O. B. Cars (named port) Lighterage Free" Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) place goods on or in cars (2) secure railroad bill of lading (3) pay all transportation charges to, includ- ing lighterage at, the port named (4) be responsible for loss and/or damage until goods have arrived on cars at the named port. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage in- curred thereafter (2) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (3) take out the insurance necessary to the safety of the goods after arrival on the cars (4) pay the cost of hoisting goods into vessel where weight of goods is too great for ship's tackle (5) pay all demurrage and other charges, ex- cept lighterage charges. 10 7. The seller may desire to quote a price covering delivery of the goods alongside overseas vessel and within reach of its loading tackle. In this case, the proper term is: "F. A. S. vessel (named port)" Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) transport goods to seaboard (2) store goods in warehouse or on wharf if necessary, unless buyer's obligation in- cludes provision of shipping facilities (3) place goods alongside vessel either in a lighter or on the wharf (4) provide the usual dock or ship's receipt (5) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have been delivered alongside the ship or on wharf. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage thereafter, and for insurance (2) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (3) pay cost of hoisting goods into vessel where weight of goods is too great for ship's tackle. 11 8. The seller may desire to quote a price covering all expenses up to and including delivery of the goods upon the overseas vessel at a named port. In this case, the proper term is: "F. O. B. vessel (named port)" Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) meet all charges incurred in placing goods actually on board the vessel (2) provide the usual dock or ship's receipt (3) be responsible for all loss and/or damage until goods have been placed on board the vessel. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage thereafter (2) handle all subsequent movement of the goods. 12 9. The seller may be ready to go farther than the delivery of his goods upon the overseas vessel and be willing to pay transportation to a foreign point of delivery. In this case, the proper term is: "C. & F. (named foreign port)" Under this quotation : A. Seller must (1) make freight contract and pay transpor- tation charges sufficient to carry goods to agreed destination (2) deliver to buyer or his agent clean bills of lading to the agreed destination (3) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have been delivered alongside the ship and clean ocean bill of lading obtained (seller is not responsible for de- livery of goods at destination). B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage thereafter and must take out all neces- sary insurance (2) handle all subsequent movement of the goods (3) take delivery and pay costs of discharge, lighterage and landing at foreign port of destination in accordance with bill of lad- ing clauses (4) pay foreign customs duties and wharfage charges, if any. 13 10. The seller may desire to quote a price covering the cost of the goods, the marine insurance on the goods, and all transportation charges to the foreign point of delivery. In this case, the proper term is: "C. I. F. (named foreign port)" Under this quotation: A. Seller must (1) make freight contract and pay freight charges sufficient to carry goods to agreed destination (2) take out and pay for necessary marine insurance (3) deliver to buyer or his agent clean bills of lading to the agreed destination, and insurance policy and/or negotiable insur- ance certificate (4) be responsible for loss and/or damage un- til goods have been delivered alongside the ship, and clean ocean bill of lading and insurance policy and/or negotiable insur- ance certificate have been delivered to the buyer, or his agent. (Seller is not re- sponsible for the delivery of goods at des- tination, nor for payment by the under- writers of insurance claims) (5) provide war risk insurance, where neces- sary, for buyer's account. B. Buyer must (1) be responsible for loss and/or damage thereafter, and must make all claims to which he may be entitled under the insur- ance directly on the underwriters (2) take delivery and pay costs of discharge, lighterage and landing at foreign port of destination in accordance with bill of lading clauses (3) pay foreign customs duties and wharfage charges, if any. 14 GENERAL RECOMMENDATIONS W In reaching the conclusions set forth in this statement the Conference considered the fact that there are, in more or less common use by manufac- turers in different parts of the United States, numer- ous variations of these abbreviations, practically all of which are employed to convey meanings substan- tially synonymous with those here defined For in- stance, there are manufacturers who quote “F. O. B. Cars," "F. O. B. Works," "F. O. B. Mill" or "F. O. B. Factory" meaning that the seller and buyer have the same responsibilities as those set forth in section I. The Conference considered all those variations and determined to recommend the use of “F. O. B. (named point," as "F. O. B. Detroit," "F. 0. B. Pittsburgh," etc. Of the considerable number of these abbreviations which are used in the United States, the Conference felt that the form "F. O. B. (named point)" is most widely used and understood, and therefore should be adopted as the standard of practice. The chief purpose of the Conference is to simplify and standardize American practice, and to that end it urges manufacturers and exporters to cease the use of synonymous abbreviations and quote habitual- ly in the terms here recommended, just as far as these terms will cover the price conditions which it is desired to arrange with the buyer. Variations of the abbreviations recommended in other sections also are in more or less common use throughout the United States. The recommenda- tions of the Conference set forth above apply to them with the same force as to those cited under section 1. Manufacturers and exporters are urged to bear in mind that the confusion and controversies which 15 have arisen have sprung in part from the use of an excessive number of abbreviated forms with sub- stantially similar meanings, as well as from the use of abbreviations in a sense different from their orig- inal meanings, or in an application not originally given them and different from the sense or applica- tion understood by foreign buyers. In simplified and standardized practice lies the best hope of reducing confusion and avoiding con- troversy. The Conference urges upon manufacturers and exporters the very great importance at all times of making their intention in whatever quotation they employ so thoroughly clear as to be impossible of misunderstanding or misinterpretation. It is much better to take the time and space at the outset to make the quotation clearly undersood, than to be compelled in the end to go through vexatious con- troversy or litigation, which costs not only time and expense but customers as well. Misunderstandings can best be avoided if the seller will formulate a written statement of the general conditions under which his sales are to be made, and will see that the foreign buyer possesses these terms of sale when considering a quotation. The items which may be included in such a statement, deal with: delivery, delays, partial shipments, shipping instructions, in- spection, claims, damage, and payment. If all con- tingencies are thus covered by carefully considered conditions of sale, disputes will largely be prevented. The quotation "F. O. B. (named port)" as "F. O. B. New York," "F. O. B. New Orleans," "F. O. B. San Francisco," is often used by inland producers and distributors to mean merely delivery of the goods at railway terminal at the port named. This abbreviation originated as an export quotation and 16 had no application to inland shipments. It was used only to mean delivery of the goods upon an overseas vessel at the port named. That, in fact, is the mean- ing universally given to the phrase among foreign- ers, and is the meaning which the best practice among exporters requires it invariably to have. But because of the confusion which has arisen through the use of that form with a different meaning by inland producers and distributors, and in the inter- est of unmistakable clarity, the Conference most strongly urges the invariable use by American man- ufacturers and exporters of the form “F. O. B. Vessel (named port)." This adds only one word to the abbreviated form and has the great advantage that it cannot be misunderstood. It also avoids the difficulty which might arise among foreigners not always well versed in American geography, through confusing an inland forwarding point with a ship- ping port at seaboard. - The Conference calls attention to the fact that in selling "F. A. S. Vessel" manufacturers and ex- porters should be careful to have their agreements with buyers cover explicitly the question of responsi- bility for loss after goods have been delivered on the wharf or alongside the vessel and before they are actually loaded on the ship. There is no generally established practice on this point. The recommenda- tion of the Conference in the definitions of responsi- bility under section 7, sets up a rule which it is hoped will lead to the establishment of a standard practice. It is understood that he provision of lighterage covered in several of these recommendations is only within the usual free lighterage limits of the part, and that where lighterage outside such limits is re- quired, it is for buyers' account. 17 In order to avoid confusion in another particu- lar, attention is called to the care which must be exercised in all cases in making weight quotations. The net ton, the gross ton and the metric ton, all differ in weight. Similarly there is a variation in the use of the term "hundred-weight" to mean either 100 pounds or 112 pounds. It is, therefore, not sufficient to quote a price per "ton" or per "hundred- weight." Instead the Conference recommends the use of the terms "ton of 2,000 lbs.," "ton of 2,240 lbs.," or "ton of 2,204 lbs.,” etc., whichever is in- tended. It is also important to note that a carload lot in the United States means the quantity of the par- ticular commodity in question necessary to obtain the carload freight rate for transportation on Amer- ican railways. This quantity varies according to the commodity and also varies in different parts of the country. Certain commodities being more bulky than others, the minimum carload for them is less than for heavier products occupying less space. The load required may range anywhere from 12,000 to 90,000 pounds. Consequently it is important, when quoting prices applicable to carload lots, to so state and to specify the minimum weight necessary to make a carload lot of the particular commodity for the particular shipment in question. The Conference points out that in quoting "C. & F" or "C. I. F." manufacturers and exporters mov- ing large quantities of material by one vessel should be careful to ascertain in advance the buyer's capa- city to take delivery. This because, under these terms and as a condition of making the freight rate, transportation companies may require a certain rate of discharge per day, and that rate of discharge might be in excess of the buyer's capacity to take 18 delivery. In such event an adjustment with the transportation company would be necessary, which might affect the freight rate and consequently the price to be quoted. The Conference also strongly urges shippers clearly to understand the provisions of their insur- ance protection on all foreign sales, irrespective of the general terms used thereon. In almost all cases it should be possible, when making shipments by steamer, to obtain insurance cover giving full pro- tection from primary shipping point to designated sea port delivery, and/or foreign port delivery. As ordinary marine insurance under F. P. A. conditions, i. e. free of particular average, gives no protection against deterioration and/or damage to the merchan- dise itself while in transit, when caused by the recog nized hazards attending such risks, shippers should endeavor in all cases to obtain insurance under W. P. A. (S. P. A.) conditions, i. e. with particular average subject to particular average), when in excess of the customary franchise of 3% to 5%. Under such form of insurance, underwriters will be called upon to pay claims for damages when these exceed the stipulated franchise. The Conference points out that inasmuch as fees for consular invoices and similar items are arbitrary charges fixed by foreign governments, they are not included in the terms of C. & F. or C. I. F. quota- tions, and it is part of the duty of the buyer to meet them. Finally, the Conference strongly recommends, as a most effective measure of simplification, the gen- eral practice of quoting for export, as far as possible, either "F. A. S. Vessel," "F. O. B. Vessel" or "C. I. F." Concentration on this small list, all of which terms 19 are readily understood abroad and are difficult of misinterpretation, will, it is felt, be markedly influ- ential in avoiding confusion and controversy. The conclusions and definitions set forth above are the recommendations of a Conference which was composed of representatives of nine of the great commercial organizations of the United States inter- ested in foreign trade. Not all have as yet the force of law or long established practice; but it is the hope and expectation of the Conference that these recom- mendations will receive such adherence on the part of American producers and distributors, as to make them in fact the standard American practice. And it is, therefore, expected that in due time they will receive the sanction of legal authority. 20 PRESS OF LUMBERMEN'S PRINTING CO. SEATTLE THE UNION NATIONAL OF SEATTLE KONFERE DET ERFASENTAANPASSATZZZRAELA: THE UNION NATIONAL BANK OF SEATTLE WASHINGTON SUCCESSORS TO Union Savings & Trust Company ESTABLISHED 1903 BRANCHES AT BALLARD BAATAREA AND GEORGETOWN AB KALANSZENIERIAL KERESE PARTY FANNO SABRENIE NAUNGERERAS, VA PERSONENBENGALIRLINE PRODUK BURGARE LE MANS LES LAP ⠀⠀⠀⠀LLLØTE || || ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||EMALJUNZATURATLETIKALENTERI KA|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||| (4122]|||||||||||||||||| WOLENIANGU ……………ÆNDAMAN ANDER DIRECTORS G. F. CLARK JOHN CLAUSEN VICE-PRESIDENT VICE-PRESIDENT JAMES D. HOGE CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD J. D. LOWMAN L. B. PEEPLES SEATTLE MANAGER CRANE & CO. A. B. STEWART PRESIDENT STEWART & HOLMES DRUG CO.. WHOLESALE DRUGGISTS J. A. SWALWELL PRESIDENT ELMER E. TODD DONWORTH, TODD & HIGGINS, ATTORNEYS AT LAW [] = {} }} — n OFFICERS J. D. LOWMAN JAMES D. HOGE, CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD J. A. SWALWELL, PRESIDENT G, F, CLARK, VICE, President JOHN CLAUSEN, Vice, PresIDENT VICE-PRESIDENT CAPITALIST [… E. J. WHITTY, CHAS. A. SCRUBY, FORREST I. GILL, CASHIER A. B. STEWART VICE-PRESIDENT ASSISTANT CASHIERS TUMLELERTALETHAL O. W. TUPPER, ASST. CASHIER AND AUDITOR BRANCH AT BALLARD C. W. CASLER, ASST. CASHIER IN CHARGE BRANCH AT GEORGETOWN MAX G. SCHMIDT, ASST. CASHIER IN CHARGE BOND DEPARTMENT DIETRICH G, SCHMITZ, MANAGER JAS. D. FARMER E. B. ANSLEY ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||| BUZ Q……………………………………………||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||| ………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………… ………/…//////////////////////…………………………………………………………………………………… ///////////////////////|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||| CONDENSED REPORT TO COMPTROLLER OF THE CURRENCY of The Union National Bank of SEATTLE Close of Business, September 8th, 1920 2 Loans and Discounts Overdrafts Interest Earned, not collected Customers' Liability under Letters of Credit and Acceptances U. S. Govt. Bonds and Certificates of Indebtedness Other Bonds, Warrants and Securities Real Estate Owned Furniture and Fixtures Cash and Exchange RESOURCES LIABILITIES Capital Surplus and Profits Interest Collected, not earned Reserved for Taxes ………/…/////////////////////////////}}} Reserved for Interest Reserved for Canadian Exchange Dividends Unpaid Letters of Credit and Acceptances Deposits ……………||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||| $5,813,716.61 36,002.41 30,404.03 926,551.90 1,117,288.18 642,684.28 109,660.62 83,306.90 2,451,885.01 $11,211,499.94 $ 600,000.00 143,678.27 29,013.93 7,616.43 16,913.87 299.53 20.50 926,551.90 9,487,405.51 $11,211,499.94 ||||||||||||||||| //////////////////////////////////////////////////////||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||⠀⠀⠀⠀⠀⠀⠀ " Belmar Di Carlylead to a pl SPEA THE UNION NATIONAL BANK OF SEATTLE IS EQUIPPED WITH COMMERCIAL, SAVINGS, TRUST, BOND AND FOREIGN DEPARTMENTS BANKS, BANKERS, FIRMS, CORPORATIONS, AND INDIVIDUALS ARE INVITED TO AVAIL THEMSELVES OF THE FACILITIES AND SERVICES OF THIS BANK THE FOREIGN DEPARTMENT UNDERTAKES OVERSEAS BANKING TRANSACTIONS OF EVERY DESCRIPTION, ACCEPTS DRAFTS FOR THE PURPOSE OF FINANCING SHIPMENTS TO OR FROM THE UNITED STATES, ISSUES COMMERCIAL AND TRAVELERS' LETTERS OF CREDIT, BUYS AND SELLS FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND FOREIGN MONEYS. INFORMATION REGARDING EVERY PHASE OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE IS AVAILABLE TO OUR FRIENDS AND CLIENTS PRINTE FREE FORRES KANCAFE ANY RACE CEN JENES Flo FIRST TEYCLE GIFTUKEA FIFEREELD: KIDELER Ph 1/22 188 HOGE BUILDING HOME OF THE UNION NATIONAL BANK N, P BANK NOTE CO.3 LATTUE IN THE HEART OF THE FINANCIAL DISTRICT 191 P18 HE 1009 Your attention is earnestly called to the following report. CHAMBER OF COMMERCE }: OF THE STATE OF NEW YORK. COMMERCIAL ARBITRATION. At the 147th Annual Meeting of the Chamber of Commerce of the State of New York, held May 6, 1915, the following report submitted by CHARLES L. BERNHEIMER, Chairman of the Committee on Arbi- tration, was unanimously approved: To the Chamber of Commerce : The Committee on Arbitration respectfully reports the following review of its work during the past year: INTERNATIONAL ACTION. In its last annual report your Committee on Commercial Arbitra- tion recommended the adoption of a resolution instructing the Cham- ber's delegates to the Sixth International Congress of Chambers of Commerce to present the tentative plan for international arbitration of individual disputes outlined in the report submitted by this Committee and on December 4, 1913 approved by the Chamber. This reso- lution was adopted, and our delegation to the Congress, headed by MR. SAMUEL W. FAIRCHILD, of the Executive Committee, presented the plan in accordance with these instructions. The plan, translated into several languages, was distributed to all the delegates to the Congress, and in connection with other arbitration proposals from other countries, was debated at much length. While there was no agreement upon any one particular method, the principle of arbitration was received with the widest favor; and it was voted by the Congress to request the French Government to call an International Technical Conference to deliberate especially in regard to this subject and draft a definite plan. The wording of the action taken was as follows: Resolved, That the Permanent Committee of the Congress convoke a technical international conference formed by repre- sentatives of Chambers of Commerce and of Commercial and 2 Industrial Associations, to be assisted by jurists of the different countries represented at the Congress for the purpose of elaborat- ing a preliminary plan for international conventions having for their object the regulation of litigation between citizens of dif- ferent countries by means of arbitration proceedings; and that in its wake the Permanent Committee places before the Govern- ment of the French Republic its preliminary report, and petitions. it to invite the other states into a diplomatic international con- ference, the object of which is to be the establishment of an international conference on arbitration proceedings (procedure) regulating litigation between citizens of different countries, this to be done on the basis of the above preliminary report elabo- rated by the technical conference. The discussion in the Congress with regard to arbitration was pub- lished in full in the Chamber's Bulletin of August 1914. The meeting of the Congress took place on the 8th of June. Within two months the international cataclysm which we are now witnessing broke. One of the consequences of this unfortunate catastrophe was the postponement of the work of the Congress and the impossibility of calling the proposed conference. Your Committee, however, will re- vive the subject later and will then press for affirmative action. It is hopeful that this terrible experience will in the long run strengthen the cause of arbitration by dramatically revealing the costliness of the alternative. OPERATION OF THE CHAMBER'S SYSTEM. Your Committee is glad to report that it receives daily new proofs of the adaptability, flexibility and fairness of the system devised for the Chamber. The rules have now been tried so long that they work automatically and require much less personal supervision from the Committee than at first. The arbitrators chosen from the Chamber's list invariably exhibit not only the intelligence and fairness that was reasonably to be expected from the high character of men chosen, but a fidelity in the performance of their duty rising to a degree of enthu- siasm. Ordinarily the cases consumed but little time, but in others the arbitrators sat until midnight, or for several days, to square their decision with their sense of commercial equity. There has been but a single case in which the defeated party did not immediately accede to the judgment rendered: thereupon the successful disputant proceeded 1 3 under the state law, to file the judgment with the Supreme Court, where it would immediately have all the force of a decree of that court. Before this could be done, however, the defeated party upon further thought, paid the claim in full. The saving of expense in this case over court procedure was large; and indeed in every dispute there has been abundant testimony not only of quickness of action and of equity of judgment, but also of inexpensiveness. WORK OF CONCILIATION. Perhaps the most important work of your Committee has been in the way of conciliation. A large number of disputes, many of them of a serious nature have been settled without even arbitration being required, a mutual agreement through the good offices of this Com- mittee being reached. The mere bringing to the attention of dispu- tants the fact that our system is ready for action, has often helped in effecting settlement without actual recourse to it. In other instances short negotiation between them has loosened the tension: a reasonable attitude followed. A willingness has been evinced to see the merits in the standpoint of the other side, and settlement honorable to both has resulted: and with the good-will of both unbroken, business re- lations continue. Naturally many cases are brought to us in which the parties in difference have no friendship for or confidence in each other: even in such cases the good offices of the Committee's conciliatory methods are usually effective. During the past year a dispute of special interest and importance between two well-known business corporations was brought to a settlement by means of conciliation through the Arbi- tration Committee. This is especially referred to because it was a serious difference and had already been brought into the courts. where it threatened prolonged litigation, and almost complete dissi- pation of the assets of one of them. No formal arbitration was how- ever necessary, the Committee after months of negotiation, bringing the two parties together and suggesting terms of settlement which were accepted. The lawyers in the case admitted that if the dispute had been carried through the courts a total expense of from $25,000 to $50,000 would have been incurred. That entire expense was saved. Moreover, the attorney for the unsuccessful party in the dis- pute has written to the Committee with an expression of thanks for the thoughtfulness and courtesy of the investigation. Another case in which the Committee's work of conciliation was 4 sufficient to effect important results was the dispute between one of the great mercantile concerns of this city, and a very large association. Long, tedious and expensive procedure, to establish the amount of damages sustained, was avoided through your Committee's action; and a letter in appreciation of its work in this case was received by Presi- dent Low from the attorney of one side who in concluding, said: "I feel confident that the influence of the Committee on Arbitration will, if it continues as it has begun, contribute largely to relieve the congested calendar of our courts, and provide the merchants of the city, and possibly even of the country, with a reliable, economical and satisfactory tribunal for the speedy ad- justment of commercial questions." The settlements by conciliation are the invisible product of the Committee's most effective work. The methods of the Committee are adaptable even to controversies not directly in the line of their work: it may be reported that a few months ago it was able to adjust a dispute in which one of our promi- nent charitable organizations was a party, and it has upon its records the written acknowledgment by the Honorary Secretary of the organization, of the services rendered. Certain corporations and firms have inserted in their contracts with other parties, clauses providing that in case of dispute, there shall be resort to the Chamber for arbitration. There having been requests for a draft of a standard clause to be inserted in contracts, your Com- mittee has suggested the following: DRAFT FOR STANDARD CLAUSE. All disputed questions of fact that may arise and occasion controversy relating to this contract shall be submitted to arbi- tration, under the rules for the time being of the Committee on Arbitration of the Chamber of Commerce of the State of New York. In the event of the failure of the parties to agree upon arbitrators, the Committee on Arbitration of the Chamber of Commerce is hereby authorized to select three impartial persons from the " Official List" of arbitrators, with the same force and effect as if their names were herein inserted. No litigation of any kind or character shall be instituted until such arbitration shall have taken place and the arbitrators made their award thereon. J 5 In this connection, it is of interest to note that it has been provided in the Cloak and Suit Industry and in the Dress and Waist Industry, that under certain conditions the Chamber may designate one of the arbitrators to serve on the "Committee on Immediate Action." · EDUCATIONAL. Your Committee believes that an influential branch of its work may be classed under the caption "educational." Its largest opportunity, as is its most important duty is to inspire increased regard for the principle of arbitration the world over. Much is being accomplished along this line. The example of the Chamber in establishing a sys- tem of arbitration has been already instrumental in leading a number of other commercial, trade, professional and civic organizations to in- stitute arbitration committees of their own. In a number of instances the aid of your Committee has been asked by these associations in the creation of such Arbitration Systems. Amongst others, we have given assistance to the Chamber of Commerce of the United States, which has undertaken to establish arbitration systems in the different states represented in the National Chamber. Several organizations in our own city have also created tribunals of arbitration with our assistance. In this respect we have conceived our duty in the broad- est spirit, believing that the Chamber of Commerce seeks to help wherever it can. The more resort there is to arbitration in trade dis- putes, labor controversies and international differences, the better the world will be; therefore, whenever our aid has been sought we have helped and encouraged the creation of arbitration systems. Moreover, we have offered to handle arbitration cases for other associations of standing, provided they were of the sort that we could properly have taken if brought to us in the first instance. This educational work has involved a large amount of correspondence and innumerable inter- views. LEGAL PROCEDURE. In this educational work your Committee has been led to co-operate with the legal profession in its efforts to reduce the volume of unnec- essary litigation, and increase the efficiency and speed of Court pro- cedure. We have held to the principle that commercial arbitration should be promoted, not in antagonism to the Courts and the legal profession, but in co-operation with them. As was said by the Chair- man of this Committee in a recent letter which was published in the 6 "Bench and Bar": "The commercial arbitration systems established under the auspices of commercial bodies, were to act as aid to the Courts, and the law-office." Arbitration is intended to relieve the over- crowded Courts of many avoidable cases and the enlightened lawyer is recognizing its value in this respect, as in others. It was reported recently to the Bar Association of Chicago, that the Courts of that city are "swamped with sixty thousand untried cases of from eight months to three years standing." The situation in New York City is much better than this, but several years ago the congestion in the New York Courts was so great, as to cause the New York Chamber, co- operating with the legal profession, to take measures for the reform of legal procedure, and the Chamber appointed a Committee with JOSEPH H. CHOATE as its Chairman, and our ex-President, A. BARTON HEPBURN, as one of its members, to labor to that end. During two or three years that Special Committee performed an effec- tive public service. It was announced in the Law Journal of November 7th last that on October 1, 1914, 7251 new causes were added to the jury calendar of the Supreme Court, First Judicial District, and that this number is 20 per cent. greater than the number of new causes added to the same calendar on October 1, 1913. The Justices of the Court, in view of the emergency created by this unexpected addition to the calendar, formally determined to prolong the jury parts each day un- til five o'clock in the afternoon, beginning Monday, November 16th. Likewise in the City Court of New York the Justices determined to sit until five o'clock in the afternoon and are now carrying out this rule. That there is still room for improvement is clearly indicated by the public utterance of some of our most eminent jurists and lawyers, and it is to be hoped that the Constitutional Convention now in session in this State will take this subject up for consideration. In a notable pamphlet entitled "Preliminary Report on Efficiency in the Administration of Justice" prepared by CHARLES W. ELIOT, MOOREFIELD STOREY, LOUIS D. BRANDEIS, ADOLPH J. RODENBECK and ROSCOE POUND for the National Economic League, among other things, it is said: "The advantages involved in law are purchased at the expense of certain disadvantages. Chief among these is the necessarily mechanical operation of legal rules which is one of the penalties of uniformity." * * * * * * * 7 "The need is for Judges who are specialists in the class of causes with which they have to deal. This need may be met by specialized courts with specialized jurisdiction." * * * "Our procedure at law involves too many trials and too much retrial. So far as possible, all questions of fact should be dis- posed of finally upon one trial." The system of commercial arbitration for which your Committee stands, substitutes an easy trial upon questions of fact by a jury of selected experts, well trained and respected and by a simple process less. cumbersome than any process now a part of the judicial system. The attention of the Chamber is called to the following extract from the address delivered before the American Bar Association at its annual meeting in Washington, October 20, 1914, by Honorable ELIHU ROOT, who is now President of the New York Constitutional Convention and who was recently elected an honorary member of this Chamber: "American procedure ought to follow as closely as possible the methods of thought and action of American farmers and business men and workmen. The law is made, not for lawyers but for their clients, and it ought to be administered, so far as possible, along the lines of laymen's understanding and mental processes. The best practice comes the nearest to what happens when two men agree to take a neighbor's decision in a dispute, and go to him and tell their stories and accept his judgment. Of course, all practice cannot be as simple as that, but that is the standard to which we ought to try to conform, rather than the methods of an acute, subtle, logical, finely discriminating, highly-trained mind. It is that sort of thing which merchants seek when they get up committees of arbitration to decide their controversies without the intervention of lawyers. They are trying to get their questions settled in accordance with their instincts and habits of thought. That is the way in which all the great inter- national arbitrations are conducted. Fortunately for them, the judicial procedures of the nations differ so widely that there can- not be any particular rules of practice in an international case. Accordingly each country tells its story in print and then both go in and tell the arbitrators about it. Many of these cases are exceedingly complicated and difficult, but they require no com- plicated and difficult procedure." ∞ The New York State Bar Association has appointed a Committee on Prevention of Unnecessary Litigation. The preliminary report was presented at the meeting of the Association last January, and in part adopted and the Committee continued for another year for further consideration of the subject. The Chamber has been asked to co-op- erate with this Committee of the Bar Association; and as this is directly in line with the spirit of our arbitration system, your Com- mittee will, unless the Chamber otherwise directs, co-operate with the Bar Association Committee so far as seems practical. The Legislature has passed this year an amendment to the Munici- pal Court Act. This Act contains the following provisions with regard to conciliation and arbitration: "The Board of Justices may adopt and amend rules relating to the following subjects: * * * * * "5. The establishment of a system of conciliation whereby controversies may be submitted by consent of the parties to a justice of the court for informal hearing and decision without entry of judgment. ‹ 6. The establishment of a system of arbitration and the, procedure thereof." Your Committee is pleased to report that it aided in securing the enactment of this legislation. The Judges will act as arbitrators in cases brought to them and will avoid delay and expense in multitudes of controversies carried to the court by poor litigants and thus afford relief to many small tradesmen. In this court, therefore, it will be possible to secure a judicial arbitration by a trained lawyer with but very small expense to the litigant. In conclusion your Committee repeats that the mere existence of the Chamber's system actually brings about private settlements. It is the prestige and authority of this great Chamber of Commerce with its international reputation, that makes possible the work that is proving effective and valuable on the part of your Committee. ARBITRATION IN GOVERNMENT BUSINESS. Postscript. For more than two years your Committee has been quietly working for governmental acceptance of arbitration in disputes between Federal, State, and City departments and merchants with whom they may have business dealings, as for instance, in the pur- chase of supplies or in the carrying out of construction contracts. 9 Since the foregoing report was drafted, the convening of the State Constitutional Convention has seemed to your Committee to afford an opportunity for recognition of the principle of arbitration in the fundamental law of the state. Therefore, the following draft of a letter to the Honorable ELIHU ROOT, President of the Constitutional Convention, was prepared: THE HONORABLE ELIHU ROOT, President, Constitutional Convention, Albany, N. Y. MY DEAR SIR: April 27, 1915. Economy, the economy that means conservation without harmful restraint is in the air, is being sought in high and low places. Will you be so good as to give a measure of consideration to a means to this end, that we have long and earnestly tried to perfect? Our efforts have not been entirely unsuccessful. In discharging the work of the Constitutional Convention at Albany, we should like the Committee Chairmen to consider the facilities for arbitration offered by the Chamber of Commerce of the State of New York, in connection with disputes and differences that arise in the daily work of the various departments. These mean economy in financial outlay and certainly economy in time expenditure. In the same way that merchants have found it a quick and economical method, the various departments of the government should find this handling of differences a shortcut to settlement that gives better satisfaction both to contestants and their attorneys, when the latter are required. If the Government in its commercial transactions were to avail itself, in case of difference or dispute, of organized arbitration such as is offered by our Chamber, and have it known that such recourse is favored, lower costs in the running of our Government will result. The knowledge that business differences (particularly in the sale by merchants to the Government) can be adjusted equitably and satisfac- torily to both, without the alternatives of either a law suit or a rejection of merchandise upon technical grounds (merchandise which may be very perishable or not suitable for the market at large) will draw to the Government requisitions an increased number of bids, thereby insuring better prices and terms to the Government. It will eliminate the condition caused by few bids which the makers must make larger to compensate their risk of possible rejection of deliveries on technical grounds. 10 Adherence to the Code provisions for arbitration as they now exist, and reference under its provisions are encouraged. In order to facili tate this, the Committee on Arbitration of the Chamber of Commerce is ready to handle all cases that are referred to it for that purpose, provided, of course, they relate to questions of fact and are of a nature that we would ordinarily take had they been brought to us by the merchants directly. In these cases questions of law and technical points do not come up. While the law provides only for arbitration after a dispute has arisen, we recommend that merchants who seek us on this point, insert into their contracts as standard for an arbitration clause, the following: Adidas M All disputed questions of fact that may arise and occasion controversy relating to this contract shall be submitted to arbi- tration, under the rules for the time being of the Committee on Arbitration of the Chamber of Commerce of the State of New York. In the event of the failure of the parties to agree upon. arbitrators, the Committee on Arbitration of the Chamber of Commerce is hereby authorized to select three impartial persons from the "Official List" of arbitrators, with the same force and effect as if their names were herein inserted. No litigation of any kind or character shall be instituted until such arbitration shall have taken place and the arbitrators made their award thereon. We venture to quote from so eminent authority as yourself, whose views as expressed in your speech before the American Bar Associ- ation, so fully cover our aim in the work we have done and attempt to do, that we can add little except to say that to carry out this principle we have provided machinery that has proved itself efficient. You may remember your words: "American procedure ought to follow as closely as possible the methods of thought and action of American farmers and business men and workmen. The law is made not for lawyers but for their clients, and it ought to be administered as far as possible along the lines of laymen's understanding and mental processes. The best practice comes nearest to what happens when two men agree to take a neighbor's decision in a dispute and go to him and tell their stories and accept his judgment. Of course, all practice cannot be as simple as that, but that is the standard to which we ought to try to conform rather than ▸ 11 the methods of an acute, subtle, logical, finely discriminating, highly trained mind.” May we express the hope that you will yourself bring to the atten- tion of the Chairmen of the respective committees the importance of considering the methods of commercial arbitration in their relation to the handling of the business of the Government as well as in the handling of the business of private individuals? The Constitution, in our judgment, should permit parties to agree in advance to submit controversies arising between them to arbitrators and the technical rules of Law now hedged about such agreements should be abolished. Besides the State Government in its various departments should be. permitted to insert such provisions in contracts for sales of merchandise. Very truly yours, (Signed) CHARLES L. Bernheimer, Chairman, Committee on Arbitration, Chamber of Commerce of the State of New York. Before submitting this letter to the Chamber for its its approval, your Committee unofficially sent a copy of it to MR. ROOT stating that it was its intention to place it before the Chamber at its Annual Meeting, but before doing so, desired to give him an opportunity to suggest any change in form or substance, as he might think in order. MR. ROOT immediately sent us the following reply. April 28, 1915. MY DEAR MR. BERNHEIMER: I have your letter of April twenty-seventh inclosing a draft letter to me which the Committee on Arbitration of the Chamber of Com- merce propose to submit at the next meeting of the Chamber. I fully agree with the view taken in that draft and if such a letter is received by me I shall take pleasure in seeing that it is considered by the proper committee of the Constitutional Convention. There will be a serious question whether such provisions as might be advised to further the purpose expressed in the draft matter properly belong in a constitution rather than in a legislative act. Very sincerely yours, (Signed) CHARLES L. BERNHEIMER, Esq. Chamber of Commerce, New York City. ELIHU ROOT. 12 With this assurance from MR. ROOT that the letter, which we pur- pose to send to him as President of the Convention, will receive consideration by a proper committee, we ask the Chamber to give its approval. In view of MR. ROOT's commanding eminence as a lawyer and a statesman, we regard his statement, that he fully agrees with the view taken in the letter, as a declaration of the highest significance, and as giving promise of a notable expansion of arbitration methods in the settlement of commercial disputes, and thus leading up to their more general acceptance in adjusting even international differences. Respectfully submitted, CHARLES L. BERNHEIMER, ALFRED ROMER, FRANK H. Dodd, WILLIAM HARRIS DOUGLAS, J. HOWARD COWPERTHWAIT, CHARLES D. HILLES, GEORGE B. HODGMAN. NEW YORK, April 30, 1915. Committee on Arbitration. HE 1009 P18 } 霄 " 1. } 1 UNIV. OF MICHIGAN, 1 INTERNATIONAL COMMERCE } AN ADDRESS DELIVERED BEFORE THE MISSOURI BANKERS ASSOCIATION AT KANSAS CITY, MISSOURI, MAY 25, 1911 - BY WILLIAM H. BURGES OF THE EL Paso, Texas, bar EL PASO PRINTING COMPANY 1 : International Commerce ~) LA * ' C * ی یاد و چه وا نه An Address Delivered Before the MISSOURI BANKERS ASSOCIATION At Kansas City, Missouri MAY 25, 1911 BY WILLIAM H. BURGES Of the El Paso, Texas, Bar << The Constitution of the United States, which former Gov-. ernor Black, of New York, has recently described as a devenerated instrument, too old to be useful and too good to be true," provides The Congress shall have power-To regulate commerce with foreign nations, and among the several states, and with the Indian tribes. Construing this clause, the Supreme Court of the United States, through its greatest Chief Justice, early gave to the word, commerce, a definition adequate to meet the future growth and the increasing demands of a people sprung from “a race of shop keepers, as Napoleon sneer- ingly said, but sprung also from a race which had carried its flag over hearts of oak as well as bales of merchandise. into every ocean and every port. "" "" 2 In Gibbons vs. Ogden, Chief Justice Marshall said: "Commerce, undoubtedly, is traffic, but it is something more, it is intercourse. It describes the commercial inter- course between nations, and parts of nations, in all its branches, and is regulated by prescribing rules for carrying on that intercourse. The mind can scarcely conceive a system for regulating commerce between nations, which shall exclude all laws concerning navigation, which shall be silent on the admission of the vessels of the one nation into the ports of the other, and be confined to prescribing rules for the conduct of individuals, in the actual employ- ment of buying and selling, or of barter." (9 Wheaton, 1, at 189). ܕ In Pensacola Telegraph Company vs. Western Union Telegraph Company, the Supreme Court said: "Since the case of Gibbons vs. Ogden it has never been doubted that commercial intercourse is an element of commerce which comes within the regulating power of Congress. The powers thus granted are not confined to the instru- mentalities of commerce, or postal service known or in use when the constitution was adopted, but they keep pace with the progress of the country, and adapt themselves to the new developments of times and circumstances. They extend from the horse with its rider, to the stage coach, from the sailing vessel, to the steamboat, from the coach and steamboat, to the railroad, and from the railroad to the telegraph, as these new agencies are successively brought 3 into use to meet the demands of increasing population and wealth. They were intended for the government of the business to which they relate, at all times and under all circumstances. (96 U. S. 1 at 9). "" In the case of Welton vs. The State of Missouri, that same august tribunal declared: "Commerce is a term of the largest import. It comprehends intercourse for the purpose of trade in any and all its forms, including the transportation, purchase, sale and exchange of commod- ities between the citizens of our country and the citizens or subjects of other countries, and between the citizens of different states. The power to regulate it embraces all the instruments by which such commerce may be con- ducted." (91 U. S. 275, at 280). In the development of our law incident to and calling for a construction of the commerce clause of the constitu- tion, the courts have had to keep clearly in mind the dis- tinction between commerce, and aids to and the agencies of commerce, which, therefore, fall within the scope of the clause on the one hand and mere incidents to commerce, and, therefore, without the purview of the constitution on the other. Take, for example, the shipment of a car of coal from one state to another. That this is interstate commerce and subject to the regulating power of the Congress, none would deny. The car in which the shipment is made, and the railroad handling it. are the agencies of interstate com- 4 merce and equally within the control of Congress. So is the bill of lading on which the shipment is made. But the bill of exchange which pays for the coal, or that pays the railroad tariff for hauling it, is only an incident to com- merce, and, therefore, not within the power of the Congress over interstate or international trade. (Nathan vs. Louis- iana, 8 Howard, 73; Williams vs. Fears, 179 U. S. 270; Hooper vs. California, 155 U. S. 648, at 655). Now, it has uniformly been held that banking is not commerce, within the meaning of the constitution; that one dealing in foreign bills of exchange is not engaged in foreign commerce, within the meaning of the constitution, and, therefore, you, as bankers, are especially interested in interstate and international commerce only as it affords you ampler fields for your activities, and as you meet and discharge a function indispensably incident to such com- merce. I think it safely may be assumed that your primary interest is that the investment of the funds you, as bank- ers advance, be safe, the demand adequate to the supply at your disposal and the handling of the transaction reason- ably simple and expeditious. The demands of our interstate and foreign commerce, upon the financial institutions of the country, as well as upon the functions of government, have never been in- considerable. The necessity for unifying the law applicable to such commerce, and bringing the commerce of the people of the 5 several states among the states and with foreign nations under one government, more than any other one cause led to the formation of the Union and the insertion of the commerce clause in the constitution. Under the salutary workings of this constitutional power our foreign trade had begun to grow so that by 1800, the date of our earliest authentic figures, our exports were $70,971,780.00, and our imports totaled $91,252,768.00, showing a balance of more than $20,000,000.00 against us. By 1909, the latest figures available, our imports had grown to $1,311,920,224.00, and our exports reached the stupen- dous total of $1,663,011,104.00, showing a balance in our favor of more than $300,000,000.00. The march of the century but kept pace with the commercial development of the country. No appeal to figures is necessary to es- tablish this. We see it in the lives of our people. The products of every people of every country, from the frozen north to the frozen south, from farthest east to beyond the sunset enter into the consumption of daily life. The fruits and food-stuffs that were the luxuries of our childhood have become the common fare of our people. We have laughed at the statement that the cackle of the Kansas hen is heard around the world, but the jest ex- presses an important truth. So closely has the increased interchange of commodities brought the people of all the nations, so inseparably has the dependence of the indus- tries of one people on the products of another brought the 6 nations of the earth together, that we could not sunder them if we would. The attack of the cotton worm and the boll weevil on the fleecy product of our southern fields bodes more of evil to the people of England than the darkest war cloud on her international horizon. International trade, the application, on a larger scale, of the world-old law of supply and demand, has brought us most forcibly to realize that "In the gain or loss of one race, "All the rest have equal claim." The enormous figures in which the foreign commerce of our country is now stated, alone would indicate it a matter of first importance. The fact that every dollar that pays for our imports goes out through American banks, and that all that comes in from our even greater exports is bank paper at some stage of the journey from consumer to producer--in fact during most of that journey -is enough to interest American bankers in that commerce, and especially you, the bankers of a great producing and exporting state. In the Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith laid down the rule, "It is not by augumenting the capital of a country, but by rendering a greater part of that capital more active and productive than would otherwise be so, that the most judicious operations of banking can increase the industries of a country." I beg leave to suggest that this is especially true as to 7 the demands of international commerce on the banking resources of a country. The results of that trade must be secure. To that end, just and efficient treaties of corn- merce should exist between countries whose people are en- gaged largely in reciprocal commercial transactions, and the public sentiment of both should demand an enlightened comity between such countries, in the recognition of the laws of each country by the courts of the other. Take, for example, our relations with the Republic of Mexico: Our exports to Mexico for the year ending June 30, 1910, fell but a little short of sixty million dollars. We have no commercial treaty with that country. The treaty of Amity, Commerce and Navigation, entered into in 1831, was denounced by Mexico on the 30th day of November, 1881, and thereby ceased to be effective for any purpose. As a result of this state of affairs the Mexican courts now refuse to enforce contracts made in this country, unless in the very forms of their laws. Bills of exchange and other negotiable instruments are not enforcible in their country, unless made in accordance with their usages and expressly made payable in Mexico, and even the judgments of our courts are refused recognition or enforcement in theirs. In the wonderfully learned opinion of the late Mr. Justice Gray, speaking for the Supreme Court of the United States, in the case of Hilton vs. Guyot, 159 U. S. 113, the rule is announced that the courts of this country will en- 8 force the judgments of the courts of other countries operat- ing under civilized jurisprudence, to the same extent the courts of those countries recognize and enforce ours, and quoting Mr. Justice Cooley, of Michigan, he says: "True comity is equality; we should demand nothing more and concede nothing less." (38 Mich. 769). In the same opinion, Mr. Justice Gray says: "In Mexico the system of reciprocity has been adopted by the Code of 1884 as the governing principle" (page 226), but the fact is, as above stated, that the Mexican courts are refusing to enforce our contracts, or respect the judgments of our courts, and in the very recent case of Banco Minero vs. Ross and Master- son, the Court of Civil Appeals for the Fourth Supreme Judicial District of Texas, has expressly denied any effect to a judgment of a Mexican court of competent jurisdic- tion, under which the Banco Minero of Chihuahua paid out Forty Thousand Dollars, gold, deposited with it by the parties to a contract involving the sale of Mexican lands. Under the judgment of our Court of Appeals, should it not be reversed by the Supreme Court of Texas, the bank will have to refund to one of the parties to a con- tract, money paid to the other under the judgment of a court of Mexico in which the bank is situated, and where the parties had placed themselves and their money for juridical purposes. I am not criticizing the judgment of the Texas court; it may be that it is right, especially in view of the attitude 9 of the Mexican courts, but I refer to it to bring strikingly home to you the necessity of a commercial treaty that will make such conflicts in jurisdiction impossible. As Missouri bankers, you are vitally interested, and the attention of your Senators in Congress should be directed to this con- dition. No state in this Union supplies as much to Mexico as does Missouri, and Mexico's best markets of purchase are St. Louis and Kansas City. There is a reciprocity of distrust and disregard as well as of amity and respect. Those of us who have to do with Mexican courts and Mex- ican laws are frequently told that the attitude of their government is taken to force ours to enter into a satis- factory commercial treaty. This may or may not be the reason, but the result of the case of Banco Minero vs. Ross & Masterson, falling as it does heavily on one of the great financial institutions of that country, will doubtless lead to a renewed effort from that side to secure the treaty, and it should be met by a hearty and well directed effort from our people, and institutions that are interested. We have commercial treaties with many countries; we need the treaty with Mexico and we need such with all countries with which we have commercial relations. They have a pronounced tendency to increase the volume of business done, while making more amicable the relations of the peo- ple doing it. On the occasion of his visit to the City of Mexico, Mr. Root, then Secretary of State of the United States, gave expression to this thought: 10 "We are passing, undoubtedly, into a new era of inter- national communication. We have turned our backs upon the old days of armed invasion, and the people of every civilized country are constantly engaged in the peaceable invasion of every other civilized country. The science, the literature, the customs, the lessons of experience, the skill, the spirit of every country, exercise an influence upon every other." ܕ As to the policy of protection, free trade or national reciprocity, I, of course, have nothing to say on this oc- casion, but enlightened minds cannot differ on the propo- sition that our interests as individuals and as a nation lie in the upbuilding of our foreign commerce. Every product of other countries and other peoples, foreign to our own, and not intrinsically harmful, contributes its measure to the comfort and well-being of our people. Every dollar that flows in from the sale of our products abroad increases the wealth of our country. To the extent of the balance of trade in our favor do we annually add to the national wealth. This balance in our favor should be enlarged by all legitimate efforts to increase the volume as well as the quality of our exports, both by sane laws and efficient treaty provisions allowing the amplest freedom of operation of the law of supply and demand, as well as of individual and effort, by securing the just enforcement of individual and national responsibilities. 11 A wise English Judge once said: ، ، "The freedom of trade, like the liberty of the press, is one thing; the abuse of that freedom, like the licentiousness of the press, is another. God forbid that this court should do anything that should interfere with the legal freedom of trade. In support of it the law has declared, and that law has repeatedly been acted upon, that to violate the free- dom of trade by intercepting commodities in their way to market, taking them from the owner by force, or, which is the same thing, obliging him to accept a less price than he demands, and carrying them away against his will, or com- mitting a like violation upon him in the market, is a capital offense, for which men have forfeited their lives to the law; for the law so far protects the freedom of trade as to encourage men to bring their goods to the market, by pun- ishing those who, by acts of violence, deter others from so doing. But the same law that protects the proprietors of merchandise takes an interest also in the concerns of the public, by protecting the poor man against the avarice of the rich; and from all time it has been an offense against the public to commit practices to enhance the price of mer- chandise coming to market, particularly the necessaries of life, for the purpose of enriching an individual. The free- dom of trade has its limits." (The King vs. Waddington, 1 East, 141 at 163). Not only must international trade be made secure and orderly, but it must be just. 12 I am sure I do not misjudge this association when I say that the enterprises to which you lend your aid must, in a larger way, be just, as well as certain. Doubtless no member of this association could be found whose attitude towards any proposition calling for his assistance would be that of a famous Chancellor of the British Exchequer to one of the foremost educators of Colonial America. When Dr. Blair went to England to obtain money to establish a college in Virginia, and approached the Chancellor, Sir Edward Seymour, for assistance from the treasury, he met a curt refusal. "You must not forget," said Dr. Blair, "that our people in Virginia have souls to save as well as people in England." "Souls!", echoed Seymour in de- rision, "Damn your souls! Grow tobacco." No unattainable ideal is demanded. I am not unmindfu of what has been spoken on the subject by one of the great English judges of the last century--the late Chief Justice Coleridge. He said: "It must be remembered that all trade is and must be in a sense selfish; trade not being infinite, nay, the trade of a particular place or district being possibly very limited, what one man gains another loses. In the hand to hand war of commerce, as in the conflicts of public life, whether at the bar, in Parliament, in medicine, in engineering, (I give examples only,) men fight on without much thought of others, except a desire to excel or defeat them. Very lofty minds, like Sir Philip Sidney with his cup of water, 13 will not stoop to take an advantage, if they think another wants it more. Our age, in spite of high authority to the contrary, is not without its Sir Philip Sidneys; but these are counsels of perfection which it would be silly indeed to make the measure of the rough business world as pur- sued by ordinary men of business." (Mogul Steamship Company vs. McGregor, L. R. 1888, 21 Q. B. D., 544 at 553.) George Santayana, in his book "Reason in Society," says: "If a noble and civilized society is to subsist, the common citizen must be something of a saint and something of a hero." ܕ If international commerce is to be worthy of American effort, it must be secure, orderly and just, and you, who carry the purse, are the only people who can make it so. This brings us to a consideration of the most important result of international commerce-the most desirable end to be attained by enlarging the scope of its operations and increasing its volume. The people of these United States occupy a peculiarly fortunate position in this respect, that while a large foreign trade adds to our national riches, and contributes to the comforts of our homes, the diversified products of our vast domain would make us self-sustain- ing. Our breadstuffs and our cattle, not to mention the world's greatest fruit and poultry crops, would feed us. Our cotton and wool and hides would clothe us. The posi- tion of any nation so situated is secure, but the world needs our surplus of these commodities and we need the luxuries 14 to be bought with the proceeds of the sale of this surplus. The historian, Motley, once said: "Give us the luxuries of life and we can get along without the necessities." But the chief value of this enormous foreign trade, of the sup- plying to other peoples of those necessities which their countries do not produce at all, or in inadequate quantities, is the commanding position it gives us among the nations of the world, and the tremendous power it makes for in- ternational peace, something vastly more important than, and largely to be brought about by, the development of international commerce. Just as long as the balance of our foreign trade in the foodstuffs and cotton is overwhelmingly in our favor, our position is invulnerable. We may rest at home; the world must come to us, or, unclothed, go hungry. An embargo on the export of grain, meat and cotton brings to us in need and supplication every country of importance in Europe. It would make it necessary for others to bear the brunt of our battles or avert them in order to keep their people from starvation. A great army and a great navy may be objects of great pride, but a vast foreign trade in articles of prime neces- sity, is a source of supreme power in the affairs of nations. The power of an enlightened public sentiment, such as would inake you, as bankers, refuse capital or credit to enterprises wanting in honesty and fair dealing; such as makes the bankers of a country refuse credit to another 15 nation in a war of conquest or oppression, is a power never to be denied or underrated. You have that power, and you use it. America has that power and has used it wisely and well. It was that power that brought peace to Russia and Japan; that brought Russia to realize that the further maintenance of a war entailing such sacrifices would place her beyond the pale of the benefit of our friendship; that made Japan realize that the further conduct of war to secure indemnity could not be financed in this country. This enlightened opinion of the world, and especially of America, was the dove that carried the blessing of peace to the warring nations and their sorely stricken people. An intelligent critic of our affairs, Mr. Alexander G. McLellan, who has had long experience in merchant marine affairs of England, besides winning his spurs on South African battle fields, has said: "America has another power which is more efficacious than ships and guns. Brit- ain may be top-hole-man in the naval world, Germany may be top-hole-man in the military world, but America is the top-hole-man in the commercial world, which after all, passes the other two. Peace, as we all know, lasts longer than war; and a nation which can dictate to others without bullying, in times of peace and war, using only trade as a weapon, needs no other. Such a country is America. While our civilization lasts, her position is assured." (At- lantic Monthly, Jan., 1911). It must be a source of just pride to you that this, to a 16 very great extent, is the gift of the wise, patriotic and courageous bankers of America to their country and to the world. One of the most striking facts disclosed by the census of 1910, was the pronounced drift of our people from agri- culture to manufacture and foreign commerce. One result of this is the increased importance to us as a people of maintaining the peace of the world. Mr. Gladstone once said: "The ships that pass be- tween one nation and another are like the shuttle of the loom, weaving a web of concord among the nations." Lord Russell of Killowen, Chief Justice of England, gave it as his opinion that "Trade and Travel are great pacifi- cators. The more nations know of one another, the more trade relations are established between them, the more good will and mutual interests grow, and these are powerful agents working for peace.' It is a self-evident truth that the closer the commercial relationship, the more numerous the ties of common interest between two nations, the greater will be the reluctance of one to begin war upon the other, the more willingly will they listen to the appeal of reason to submit their differ- ences to impartial arbitration, and substitute for ther waste of war the conserving processes of impartial justice. The appropriations for the military establishment of the United States for the year 1910, aggregated $238,131,082.34, a sum amounting to more than one-fourth of the national 17 banking capital of the country, to be devoted exclusively to the destruction of men and property. If we add to this the $160,908,000.00 expended in pen- sions, we have the sum of $399,039,082.39, or more than a million dollars for each and every day in the year, as the toll on the industry and the necessities of the country from the substitution of blood for brains in the settlement of international controversies. Lord Russell, of Killowen, in his memorable address to the American Bar Association, declared that the fact that we had found no way to settle international disputes ex- cept through the horrors of war, its waste, its suffering, its brutality, is a standing disgrace to our civilization. War, with its harvest of "cities sacked, fields ravaged, hearths profaned, men butchered." Do you say I speak with feeling? I do. I feel strongly. This address was pre- pared in the red glare of a burning city, into which no railroad train has run in more than four months; whose prostrate commerce, whose paralyzed industries, blackened ruins and desolated homes plead in language stronger than I can command, for the coming of that time, ܕ "When the war drum shall throb no longer and the battle flags be furled, "In the Parliament of man, The Federation of a world." 18 What is the remedy? International arbitration; the sub- stitution of reason and justice for brute force between nations as between men. In this, as in many other things, the United States has furnished the world a great precedent. The Constitution of the United States provides in the second section of its third article, that the Supreme Court of the United States shall have original jurisdiction to hear and determine al! controversies between two or more states. By virtue of the power granted, as above stated, many and important controversies between the states of this Union have been settled, settled amicably and settled hon- orably, when, without such a tribunal with such a power, an appeal to arms must almost of necessity have resulted. A few illustrations will suffice: Boundary disputes, conflicting claims of territorial sov- ereignty, were heard and determined in the cases of Missouri vs. Iowa, 7 Howard, 665; Same vs. Same, 160 U. S. 688; Same vs. Same, 165 U. S. 118; Nebraska vs. Iowa, 143 U. S. 359; Missouri vs. Nebraska, 196 U. S. 23, and Louisiana vs. Mississippi, 202 U. S. 1. Jurisdiction over the disputed territory was yielded in obedience to the court's decree in every instance, without controversy: In the case of South Dakota vs. North Carolina, 192 U. S. 286, the sovereign state of North Carolina was haled be- fore the Supreme Court of the United States as a common debtor, the suit being on certain bonds issued by the State 19 of North Carolina to build a railroad, and which bonds had been given to the State of South Dakota, by an individual owning them. Judgment was rendered that the State of North Carolina pay the bonds or that the road be sold in satisfaction of the debt. From that judgment there was no appeal and against it there was no protest, although four of the nine judges who decided the case were of the opinion that the court was without constitutional authority to grant the decree. In the case of Louisiana vs. Texas, 176 U. S. 1, the State of Louisiana sought to restrain the State of Texas from enforcing her quarantine laws, to the injury of the State and the people of Louisiana, and though such enforcement was to the great, if not irreparable injury of the commerce of Louisiana, the decision of the Supreme Court that no relief could be granted was acquiesced in without a mur- mur, and the friendly relations between the sister states remained undisturbed. In Kansas vs. Colorado, 185 U. S. 125, and 206 U. S. 46, the right of the State of Kansas to the undiverted and un- diminished flow of the waters of the Arkansas River was determined against the State of Kansas, the final decree of the Supreme Court dismissing the bill with the right on the part of Kansas to bring another suit, should the facts require it, being left inviolate. The recent case of Virginia vs. West Virginia, 220 U. S. 1, is an important and instructive one in showing the spirit 20 in which such controversies are settled by the Supreme Court of the United States, and in which they will some. day be settled by a Supreme International Court. That was a suit by Virginia to compel West Virginia to pay her just proportion of the debt of the State as it was when the Old Dominion was rent and the State of West Virginia. created. The Supreme Court upheld the contention of Vir- ginia, but left the working out of the details to the good sense and good faith of the contending states. In the opinion of the court, Mr. Justice Holmes has laid down certain rules that may well be borne in mind by the tribunal yet to be created for the solution of controversies between contending nations. He says: He says: "A suit brought by one state against another, formed by its consent from its territory, to determine what proportion the latter should pay of indebtedness of the former at the time of sep- aration, is a quasi-international controversy and should be considered in an untechnical spirit. In such a controversy there is no municipal code governing the matter and this court may be called on to adjust differences that cannot be dealt with by Congress, or disposed of by the legislature of either state alone. A state is superior to the forms that it may require of its citizens. ... A suit between states to apportion debt is a quasi-international controversy involving the honor and constitutional obliga- tions of great states, which have a temper superior to that of private litigants; and, when this court has decided 21 enough, patriotism, fraternity of the Union and mutual consideration should bring the controversy to an end.' In your own great case of Missouri vs. Illinois, 200 U. S. 496, instituted to prevent the pollution of the waters of the Mississippi River by emptying into them the sewage of the City of Chicago, the Supreme Court of the United States said, again speaking through Mr. Justice Holmes: "It may be imagined that a nuisance might be created by a state upon a navigable river like the Danube, which would amount to a casus belli for a state lower down, unless re- moved. If such a nuisance were created upon the Missis- sippi, the controversy would be settled by the more peacful means of a suit in this court. > ; How infinitely better is the American way! The court has spoken. An infinitesimal part of the cost of a war is spent in establishing a purification plant. Science lays its restraining hand on contamination and consequent dis- ease. There is no waste, no bloodshed, no suffering. The contending states, side by side, in undisturbed friendship and in the security of perfect peace, are working out their splendid destinies, as the mighty river flows unvexed to the sea. As I speak an International Court of Arbitration sits in the City of El Paso to decide the dispute between the United States and Mexico as to the location of the boundary line between them, in the City of El Paso. Immense prop- erty rights and titles to the homes of thousands of people 22 will be conclusively decided by that award, but we know it will be honestly and intelligently made and all concerned, the high contracting parties and their citizens whose in- terests depend on it, will accept the result and carry out the judgment without question and without appeal. To The Hague! To The Hague! The longest guns are too short. The substitution of judicial proceedings among nations for the arbitrament of the sword will be the great achievement of the century in whose early morning light we are standing. May I be permitted to suggest that American lawyers have offered the remedy and with every effort of heart and brain are working to bring about the result? May I be permitted to suggest that its accomplishment lies largely in the hands of the American bankers? Do you ask me how? I will tell you: Do not finance a war between for- eign countries. Let but a few of the great nations of the world adopt this rule and the long struggle for peace has been won. An army, like a snake, travels on its stomach.” It cannot fight and feed itself. Withdraw your credit, let the world know that not one dollar of American billions is available to a nation with an army in the field except in the execution of the judgment and decree of a court of international arbitration, and the billion of dollars spent annually in the maintenance of military establishments of the great nations will reach the world's banks for use in developing the material resources of the nations, educating 23 the people and alleviating the suffering that centuries of war and its consequences have left upon us. Not one word of this is meant to apply to our own country, should war be made upon it. Should that time ever come when war. "The earth is full of anger, “And the seas are dark with wrath, "And the nations in their harness "Go up against our path,' 3 the bankers of America will meet the situation as they have in the past, in a spirit of loftiest patriotism; but a different question is presented when you are asked to finance an aggressive Make it known that not one dollar of American money will be invested in the bonds of a nation, issued to carry on an offensive war. Decline to deposit one dollar with any bank that handles such a bond. Let it be known of all men that not one dollar of the money you hold in trust can be had for the purpose of such war. Show the world that the bankers of Missouri live to build up, not to tear down; to develop, not to destroy. Let it be known that you have not one penny for investment in, nor commerce with any country which has not a satisfactory treaty of commerce with this country, and a treaty of universal arbitration. 24 The reward will not be pecuniary only, but you will have earned the right to feel that your efforts have contributed to usher in that day 'When the common sense of most shall hold a fret- ful realm in awe, "And the kindly earth shall slumber, lapt in universal law." ލ • HE 41.009 718 ETAT NOMINATIF des Membres DE LA SOCIÉTÉ INTERNATIONALE POUR LE développement de l'enseignement commercial. Juillet 1910. be Sociétie rutup tionale pour le crime.. de l'insignement NAMENSVERZEICHNIS der Mitglieder DER INTERNATIONALEN GESELLSCHAFT ZUR commercial Förderung des kaufmännischen Unterrichtswesens. Juli 1910. espassement • LISTE D'HONNEUR. EHRENLISTE. Gouvernements qui subventionnent la Société. Regierungen, welche die Gesellschaft subventionieren. Autriche, Baden, Belgique, Brunswick, France, Prusse, Saxe, Suisse et Wurtemberg. Membres fondateurs. Stiftungsmitglieder. (Membres qui ont fait à la Société un don d'une somme de fr. 1250 au minimum, Mitglieder, welche der Gesellschaft eine Summe von mindestens 1000 Mk. verschenkt haben.) Wirklicher Staatsrat M. von Fischer, Unterrichtsinspektor im Ministerium für Handel und Industrie, St. Petersburg, Russie. Kommerzienrat Th. Habenicht, Grosskaufmann, Mitglied des Handels- hochschulsenats; stellvertretender Präsident der Handelskammer, Leipzig, Deutschland. S Deutscher Verband für das kaufmännische Unterrichtswesen, Braunschweig, Deutschland. 4 i 3 Reclass. 12:18:09 ER, Société internationale pone le déve le développe de l'enseignement seversterful Ständige Mitglieder. Membre permanents. Mit- (Membres qui ont fait à la Société un don d'une somme de fr. 125 au moins. glieder, welche der Gesellschaft eine Summe von mindestens 100 Mk. verschenkt haben.) Börse in Kristiania, Kristiania, Norwegen. Ecole supérieure de Commerce Solvay de l'Université libre, Bruxelles. Kommerzienrat Dr. H. Schmidt, Vizepräsident der Handelskammer, Braunschweig. P. E. F. Hemelryk, Ehrenkonsul von Japan, Liverpool, England. Wallenberg, Marcus, directeur de la „Stockholms Enskilda Bank", Stockholm. Membres d'honneur, Ehrenmitglieder. 2 Geh. Regierungsrat Dr. Stegemann, Ehrenpräsident; Präsident des Deutschen Verbandes für das kaufmännische Unterrichtswesen, Braunschweig, Deutschland. G. Francotte, Président d'honneur; Ancien Ministre de l'Industrie et du Travail, Bruxelles, Belgique. E. Rombaut, Président d'honneur; Inspecteur général de l'enseigne- ment industriel et professionnel, Bruxelles, Belgique. informeret P. Wauters, Inspecteur principal au Ministère de l'Industrie et du Travail, Bruxelles, Belgique. 4 COMITÉ DIRECTEUR. A. Membres. ZENTRALVORSTAND. Mitglieder. Président: A. Junod, Secrétaire fédéral de division pour l'enseignement com- mercial; Inspecteur des écoles de commerce suisses, Berne, Suisse. 1ter Vizepräsident: Wirkl. Hofrat Eug. Gelcich, Zentralinspektor für den kommerziellen Unterricht, Präsident der österreichischen Repräsentanz der Internationalen Gesellschaft zur Förderung des kaufmäunischen Unterrichtswesens, Wien, Österreich. ― 2me Vice-Président: " Delombre, Paul, Ancien Ministre du Commerce et de l'Industrie, Rédacteur du Temps", Président de l'Union des Associations des Anciens Elèves des Ecoles supérieures de commerce de France, Paris, France. 1er Secrétaire et Trésorier. 1. Schriftführer und Schatzmeister. L. Morf, Directeur des Ecoles supérieures de commerce, d'adminis- tration et de chemins de fer, Lausanne, Suisse. 2º Secrétaire. 2ter Schriftführer. Wirklicher Staatsrat M. von Fischer, Unterrichtsinspektor für Handel und Industrie, St. Petersburg, Russie. Assistants. Beisitzer. Dr. A. Ahlström, Directeur de l'Institut commercial, Gothenburg, Suède. Dr. Bos, Präsident der Holländischen Gesellschaft für das kauf- männische Unterrichtswesen, Winschoten, Holland. E. Castelnuovo, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Venise, Italie. 5 LO B. E. Dubois, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Anvers, Belgique. James Graham, Director of Education, Education Department, Leeds, England. Kommerzienrat Habenicht, stellvertr. Vorsitzender der Handels- kammer, Leipzig. C. Polaczek, Direktor des Handelsgymnasiums, Christiania, Nor- wegen. Dr. L. Sabbatini, Rettore dell' Università commerciale Luigi Boc- coni, Milano, Italia. Dr. Bela Schack, Königlich-ungarischer Oberinspektor der höheren Handelsschulen, Budapest, Ungarn. Regierungsrat A. Schmid, Vizedirektor des k. k. Österreichischen Handelsmuseums, Leiter der Exportakademie, Wien, Österreich. Membres suppléants. Stellvertretende Mitglieder. Dr. G. Blondel, Professeur à l'Ecole des hautes études commer- ciales, Paris, France. Chanoine Fr. Van Caenegem, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure com- merciale et consulaire, Mons, Belgique. Reidar Due, Börsenkommissär, Christiania. P. E. F. Hemelryk, Vizepräsident der Handelskammer; Präsident der Handelsschule; Ehrenkonsul von Japan, Liverpool, England. Regierungsrat A. Kleibel, Direktor der Wiener Handelsakademie, Wien, Österreich. Dr. Ake W. von Munthe, Direktor des Handelsinstitutes Fr. Schartau, Stockholm, Schweden. Oberst E. Richard, Sekretär der Zürcher Handelskammer, Zürich, Schweiz. Kommerzienrat Dr. Schmidt, Vizepräsident der Handelskammer, Braunschweig. 4 6 | COMITÉ CENTRAL. ZENTRALAUSSCHUSS. Le Comité central se compose des membres nommés par les Comités des différents pays représentés dans la Société. Le Comité de chaque pays a le droit de nommer un délégué par dix membres ou fraction de 10 membres au Comité central. Cependant, aucun Etat ne peut être représenté par plus de 8 membres au sein du Comité central. Le mode d'élection des Comités nationaux est laissé aux membres des pays respectifs. Der Zentralausschuss setzt sich aus den Mitgliedern der Landesaus- schüsse der verschiedenen in der Gesellschaft vertretenen Staaten zusammen. Bei einer Mitgliederzahl bis zu 10 stimmberechtigten Mitgliedern im Landes- ausschusse ist ein Vertreter in den Zentralausschuss zu entsenden. Mit mehr als 8 Vertretern darf indes kein Staat im Zentralausschusse vertreten sein. Das bei der Wahl in den Landesausschuss zu beobachtende Verfahren ist den bezüglichen Vereinbarungen der einzelnen Länder überlassen. Il Comitato centrale si compone di membri nominati dai Comitati dei vari paesi rappresentati nella Società. Il Comitato di ogni paese ha il diritto di nominare un delegato al Comitato centrale ogni 10 soci o frazione di 10 soci. Nessuno Stato può essere rappresentato nel Comitato centrale da più di 8 delegati. Il modo di procedere alla nomina dei Comitati nazionali è lasciato ai soci dei rispettivi paesi. The Central Council consists of members nominated by the National Committees of the various countries affiliated to the Association. The National Committees have the right to name one delegate for every ten (or fraction of ten) members for the Central Council. No country, however, is allowed to be represented by more than eight representatives on the Central Council. The method of electing the National Committee is left to be decided by the members of each country concerned. Allemagne. Deutschland. Mitglieder. Dr. A. Bosenick, Frankfurt a. M., Geschäftsführer der Gesellschaft für wirtschaftliche Ausbildung. 86 membres Kaufmann W. H. Breymann, Hamburg. Kommerzienrat T. Habenicht, Leipzig, Sachsen. Landesgewerberat Dr. Kühne, Berlin. Oberbürgermeister Martin, Mannheim. 1 ? Geh. Regierungsrat Dr. Stegemann, Braunschweig. Kommerzienrat Dr. H. Schmidt, Vizepräsident der Handelskammer, Braunschweig. Stellvertreter: Oberbürgermeister Cuno, Hagen i. W. Professer Just, Dresden, Professor der öffentlichen Handelslehr- anstalt der Dresdener Kaufmannschaft. Generalsekretär Dr. Sotber, Berlin. Hotelbesitzer Otto Hoyer, Köln. Dr. Zeyss, Syndikus der Handelskammer Krefeld. 7 Angleterre. 15 membres Mitglieder. J. Graham, Director of Education, Leeds. $ England. Suppléant: P. E. F. Hemelryk, Chairman of the Commercial School, Liverpool. Autriche. Österreich. Mitglieder. 391 membres -Wirkl. Hofrat E. Geleich, Zentralinspektor für den kommerziellen Unterricht; Präsident der österreichischen Landesgruppe, Wien. Regierungsrat A. Schmid, Vizedirektor des Handelsmuseums; Leiter der Exportakademie; Vizepräsident der österr.Landesgruppe, Wien. Regierungsrat A.Kleibel, Direktor der Wiener Handelsakademie,Wien. Regierungsrat Dr. R. Sonndorfer, Direktor der Prüfungskommis- sion für das Lehramt an höhern Handelsschulen, Wien. Regierungsrat A. Pawlowski, Direktor der Handelsakademie, Lemberg. Dr. C. Glauser, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie; Schrift- führer der österr. Landesgruppe, Wien. Regierungsrat Th. Ried, Direktor der Handelsakademie, Prag. Regierungsrat J. Rezabek, Direktor der böhmischen Handelsaka- demie, Prag. Stellvertreter: Dr. R. Bergmeister, Professor an der Handels- und nautischen Akademie, Triest. J. Weyde, Direktor der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie, Wien. Dr. K. Hassack, Direktor der Handelsakademie, Graz. 1 8 Dr. K. Henner, Professor an der böhmischen Universität; Inspek- tor für den kommerziellen Unterricht, Prag. J. Ziegler, Professor an der Exportakademie; Erster Schriftführer der Landesrepräsentanz; Redaktor der, Österreichischen Handels- schul-Zeitung", Wien. K. Ottel, Landesschulinspektor, Wien. Dr. K. Ludwig, Professor an der Handelsakademie; Obmann des österreichischen Handelsschullehrervereins, Linz. Regierungsrat R. Krickl, Direktor der Gremialhandelsfachschule der Wiener Kaufmannschaft; Schatzmeister der österr. Landes- gruppe, Wien. Belgique. Belgien. 75 membres Mitglieder. E. Dubois, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Anvers. G. Francotte, Membre de la Chambre des Représentants, Bruxelles. E. Rombaut, Inspecteur général de l'enseignement industriel et professionnel, Bruxelles. Ma E. Solvay, Industriel, Bruxelles. L. Strauss, Président du Conseil supérieur de l'Industrie et du Commerce, Anvers. Chanoine Van Caenegem, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure commer- ciale et consulaire, Mons. P. Wauters, Ingénieur; Inspecteur principal au Ministère de l'In- dustrie et du Travail, Bruxelles. Suppléants: Brants, Professeur à l'Université, Louvain. Dr.F.Deschamps, Professeur à l'Institut supérieur de commerce, Anvers. E. Fagnart, Professeur à l'Université, Gand. E. Jottrand, Directeur de l'Institut commercial des industriels du Hainaut, Mons. Lecoq, Directeur de l'Ecole des hautes études commerciales et consulaires, Liège. Orban, Professeur à l'Université, Liège. Sérigiers, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce St-Ignace, Anvers. Canada. 11 membres Mitglieder. A. J. de Bray, Directeur de l'Ecole des hautes études commer- ciales, Montréal. 9 Danemark. 8 membres Dr. H. L. Möller, Inspektor der staatl. Handelsschulen, Kopenhagen. Dänemark. Mitglieder. Etats-Unis. Vereinigte Staaten. 24 membres Mitglieder. Ch. A. Herrick, Directeur de l'Institut supérieur central, Phila- delphie. K Suppléant : Dr. W. A. Scott, Directeur de l'Ecole de commerce de l'Université de Wisconsin, Madison. France. Finlande. 2 membres Dr. Lindequist, Directeur de l'Institut commercial, Abö. Finnland. Mitglieder. Frankreich. Mitglieder. 66 membres M. Delombre, Paul, ancien Ministre du Commerce et de l'Industrie, Paris. M. Parent, Louis, Ingénieur, Vice-Président de l'Association fran- çaise pour le développement de l'enseignement technique, Paris. M. Saignat, Léo, Professeur à la faculté de Droit; Président du Comité permanent des Congrès de l'enseignement technique, Bordeaux. M. Bossu, Henri, Négociant, Secrétaire de l'Association française pour le développement de l'enseignement technique, Paris. M. Pathier, Achille, Manufacturier, Membre du Comité de l'Union des Associations des anciens élèves des Ecoles supérieures de commerce, Paris. M. Renouard, Alfred, Ingénieur, Président honoraire de l'Asso- ciation des anciens élèves de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Paris. Suppleants: M. Dufourcq-Lagelouse, L., Banquier; Vice-Président de la So- ciété académique de comptabilité, Paris. M. Merckling, Fr. J., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce et d'industrie de Bordeaux, Bordeaux. Be the } M. Burnier, Sébastien-Louis, Directeur de l'Ecole des hautes études commerciales, Paris. M. Combes, Adrien, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Marseille. M. Marchal, J., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Le Havre. M. Penot, St-Cyr, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Lyon. Grèce. 10 Griechenland. 14 membres Mitglieder. C. Stephanos, Professeur à l'Université nationale; Directeur de l'Ecole publique de commerce, Athènes. Hollande. Suppleant: Dr. O. H. Rhousopoulos, Directeur de l'Académie de l'industrie et du commerce, Athènes. 10 membres Niederlande. Mitglieder. Dr. D. Bos, Mitglied der Generalstaaten; Präsident der Hollän- dischen Gesellschaft für das kaufmännische Unterrichtswesen, Winschoten. Stellvertreter : Dr. P. Tjeenk-Willink, Advokat, Haarlem. C. E. H. Boissevain, Industrielle; Präsident der Vereinigung „Houw en Trouw", Amsterdam. Hongrie. 16 membres Dr. Bela Schack, Generalinspektor der höheren Handelsschulen, Budapest. M Ungarn. Mitglieder. Italie. Italien. Mitglieder. 19 membres Prof. G. Castelli, Directeur de l'Enseignement commercial au Mini- stère du commerce, Rome. Castelnuovo, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Venise. Sabbatini, Recteur de l'Université commerciale, Milan. J Suppléant : E. Gagliardi, Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Gênes. 1 1 " Japon. 3 membres Dr. Tokuso Fukuda, Professeur à l'Université libre Keio-Gijuku, Tokio. Norvège. Stellvertreter: 20 membres C. Polazcek, Direktor des Handelsgymnasiums, Christiania. Reidar Due, Börsenkommissär, Christiania. Roumanie. 8 membres Dr. Stefan Hrubes, Bukarest. 1 E. Platon, Handelsschulinspektor, Christiania. Schnittler, C. J., Direktor des Handelsgymnasiums, Bergen. Rumänien. Mitglieder. 11 Russie. Japan. Mitglieder. Russland. Mitglieder. 29 membres S. E. Wirklicher Staatsrat M. von Fischer, Unterrichtsinspektor für Handel und Industrie, Tiflis. Stellvertreter: ― Suède. Norwegen. Mitglieder. E. Mittelsteiner, Handelsschuldirektor, Odessa. A. Ströhm, Handelsmann, Reval." Schweden. Mitglieder. 28 membres Dr. A. Ahlström, Direktor des Handelsinstituts, Gothenburg Olof Melin, Grosskaufmann, Gothenburg. Suisse. Stellvertreter: Henrik Axelson, Président de la Direction du Musée du commerce, Stockholm. Dr. Ake W. von Munthe, Handelsschuldirektor, Stockholm. 141 membres Schweiz. Mitglieder. Professor T. Bernet, Rektor der kantonalen Handelsschule, Zürich. E. Diem-Saxer, Kaufmann, St. Gallen. 12 Dr. A. Georg, Conseiller national; Secrétaire de la Chambre de commerce, Genève. Regierungsrat Dr. C. A. Gobat, Nationalrat, Bern. A. Junod, Eidgenössischer Abteilungssekretär für kaufmännisches Bildungswesen im Handelsdepartement, Bern. L. Morf, Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Lausanne. Oberst E. Richard, Mitglied der Handelskammer, Zürich. Dr. G. Schärtlin, Direktor der Schweizer. Lebensversicherungs- und Rentenanstalt, Präsident der Schweizer. Gesellschaft für kaufmännisches Bildungswesen, Zürich. Stellvertreter: J. Bolle, Professor an der kantonalen Handelsschule, Zürich. Dr. G. Bachmann, Professor der Handelswissenschaften an der Universität Zürich, Winterthur. Dr. O. Hedinger, Handelskammersekretär und Dozent der Handels- wissenschaften an der Hochschule Bern, Aarau. J. Nef-Kern, Kaufmann und Schulrat, St. Gallen. Dr. R. Rossi, Direktor der kantonalen Handelsschule, Bellinzona. F. Scheurer, Direktor der Handelsschule, Chaux-de-Fonds. J. Schurter, Rektor der städtischen Töchterhandelsschule, Zürich. W. Wick, Konrektor der kantonalen Handelsschule; Redaktor der „Schweizer. Zeitschrift für kaufmännisches Bildungswesen" Basel. MEMBRES MITGLIEDER. Allemagne Deutschland. Kollektivmitglieder: Membres collectifs BREYMANN, W., i. F. Breymann & Hübener, Hamburg, Brandstwiete 20/24. DEUTSCHER VERBAND FÜR DAS KAUFMÄNNISCHE UNTERRICHTS- 1 WESEN (Stiftendes Mitglied), Braunschweig. DEUTSCHER ESPERANTO-BUND (Dr. M. Kandt, Neuer Markt 8), Bromberg. DIREKTORIUM DER AMTHORSCHEN HÖHEREN HANDELSLEHR- ANSTALT, Humboldsstrasse, Gera, Reuss. EISSEN, Ch., Geh. Kommerzienrat, i. F. Eissen & Co., Vizepräsident der Handelskammer, Strassburg i. E. GESELLSCHAFT FÜR WIRTSCHAFTLICHE AUSBILDUNG, Frankfurt a. M, Guiollettestrasse 18. HANDELSKAMMER FÜR DAS HERZOGTUM BRAUNSCHWEIG, Braunschweig. HANDELSKAMMER FÜR DEN KREIS MANNHEIM, Mannheim. 13 ÖFFENTLICHE HANDELSLEHRANSTALT DER DRESDENER KAUF- MANNSCHAFT, Dresden. STÄDTISCHE HANDELSLEHRANSTALT, Frankfurt a. M., Junghofstr. 16. HANDELSHOCHSCHULE MANNHEIM (Oberbürgermeister Dr. Martin), Mannheim. HANDELSSCHULE DES KIELER DETAILLISTENVEREINS, Kiel. SCHIMMELPFENG, Auskunftei, Berlin W., Charlottenburgerstrasse 23. SCHUBERT, Karl, Kaufmann, Handelsrichter, Dresden, Wettinerstrasse 4. SEMINAR DER HANDELSLEHRER DER HANDELSHOCHSCHULE, STADTGEMEINDE MANNHEIM, Mannheim. STÄDTISCHE HANDELSREALSCHULE, Dessau. TEUBNER, B. G., Verlagsbuchhandlung, Leipzig, Poststrasse 3. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: ANSCHÜTZ, Prof. Dr., Handelskammer, Sonneberg S.-M. ARNHOLD, Heinrich, Dr., Waisenhausstrasse 20, Dresden. BETTELS, Senator, Hildesheim. - [Berlin. BICKEL, Stadtrat, Wiesbaden, Wilhelmstrasse 34. BOREL, Jean, i. Fa. Esperanto-Verlag Möller & Borel, Berlin. BOREL, Jules, Verlagsbuchhändler in Fa. Esperanto-Verlag Möller & Borel, BREUER, Xaver, Hamburg, Schleusenbrücke 1. [Berlin. CALMES, A., Prof. an der Handelshochschule, Mannheim. CUNO, Oberbürgermeister, Hagen i. W. DIETZE, Hugo, Dr., Oberlehrer an der Öffentlichen Handelslehranstalt zu Dresden, Redaktor der Deutschen Handelsschullehrer-Zeitung, Schiller- strasse 21, Radebeul bei Dresden. EBELING, Dr., Oberbürgermeister, Dessau. EGERER, Ernst, Handelslehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule, Johannes- strasse 63, Stuttgart. C FRENCKELL, Karl von, Dresden, Waisenhausstrasse 20. FUHRMANN, Alfred, General-Agent, Magdeburg, Friesestrasse 56 II. GESENIUS, Hermann, Verlagsbuchhandlung, Mühlweg 34, Halle a. S. GOLDSCHMIDT, Dr., Fabrikbesitzer, Essen a. d. Ruhr. GOTTETREU, P., Rundestrasse 13, Hannover. GRÆGER, Otto, Gutsbesitzer, Mitglied des Prov. Landtages pp., Magdeburg, Gr. Dielsdorferstrasse 242 I.. HABENICHT, Th., Kommerzienrat, stellv. Vorsitzender der Handelskammer Leipzig, Karl Heinestr. 20. (Stiftendes Mitglied), HAID, E., Handelslehrer, Langestrasse 5, Stuttgart. HAUG, Dr., Sekretär der Handelskammer, Strassburg i. E. HAUCK, N., Handelslehrer, Hebelstrasse 3, Mannheim. HIRSCH, Syndikus der Handelskammer, Essen a. Ruhr. HUBERT, Franz, Weingrosshändler, Bonn a. Rhein. HÜLSEMANN, A. Cl., Kommerzienrat, Altenburg. HUMMEL, E., Frankfurt a. M., Praunheimerstrasse 5 p. KANDT, M., Dr., Syndikus der Handelskammer, Neuer Markt 8, Bromberg. KARLE, Hugo, Direktor der städtischen Handelsschule, Freiburg i. B. KASTEN, A., Gewerbeschulinspektor, Hamburg. KLIEMKE, Ernst, Dr., Direktor der Ostafrikanischen Eisenbahn-Gesellschaft KLÜSSENDORF, C., Rostock i. M. [Berlin. KNÖRK, Dr., Direktor der kaufmännischen Fortbildungsschulen. Berlin C., Börse, Burgstrasse 23/26. * 14 KOHLHEPP, Professor, Inspektor für das kaufm. Unterrichtswesen, Mannheim. KUNTZ, P., Vorsteher der städt. kaufm. Fachschule, Langestrasse 42, Colmar i. Elsass. KÜHNE, Dr., Landesgewerberat, Berlin. LIEBHEIM, E., Dr., Direktor der kaufmännischen Fachschule der Handels- kammer Saarbrücken, Königin Luisenstrasse 20, Saarbrücken III. MANGELSDORF, Herm., Redaktor, Magdeburg. METZLER, Max, Obervorsteher des Vereins junger Kaufleute, Stettin. MICHAELIS, Julius, Kaufmann, Magdeburg, Breite Weg 130/132. MÖBUSS, Dir. Dr., Lübeck, Falkenstrasse 12. MUMM, von, Elisabeth, Köln a. Rh., Obermarspforten 21. MYBS, Dr., Altona/Elbe, Marktstrasse 68. RIEKEBERG, Fr., Peine. ROCKE, Dr., Syndikus, Hannover. ROCKMANN, Lehrer, Buckauerstrasse 14, Magdeburg. ROHRBACH, C., Dr. Professor und Direktor der städtischen Real- und Handelsschule, Gotha. SCHICKHARDT, Hans, Kaufmann, Stuttgart, Markt 4. SCHIFF, Ludwig, Patentanwalt, Bernburgerstrasse 18, Berlin. SCHIPPAN, Georg, Fabrikbesitzer, Freiberg i. S. SCHMEIL, Walter, Kaufmann, Magdeburg, Sternstrasse 4 II. SCHMIDT, Dr., Kommerzienrat, Vizepräsident der Handelskammer (Ständiges Mitglied), SCHNÖCKER, W., Lehrer, Thomästrasse 13, Braunschweig. SENHOLDT, Dr., Syndikus der Handelskammer, Weimar. SIMON, C., Generalkonsul, Mannheim. SPUDE, Marie, Sprachlehrerin und Lehrerin der Handelswissenschaften an der königl. Handels- und Gewerbeschule für Mädchen, Potsdam. STARK, Emil, Lehrer, Magdeburg, Kaiser Friedrichstrasse 1. STEGEMANN, Dr., Geheimer Regierungsrat, Syndikus der Handelskammer Braunschweig, Breitestrasse 9. STEMMER, L., Handelslehrer, Heinrich Lanzstrasse 22, Mannheim. THURM, Gustav, Sorau N.-L. (Ehrenpräsident), UHLITZSCH, Dr., Sekretär der Handelskammer, Bonn a. Rh. WEBER, Dr., Bernhard, Direktor der Handelsschule, Dozent an der Braunschweig. Handelsschule, Collinistrasse 18, Mannheim. WENDTLAND, Dr., Syndikus der Handelskammer, Leipzig. WERNICKE, Dr. Professor, Direktor der städt. Oberrealschule Braunschweig, Braunschweig. WIESMANN, Hüttendirektor, Brühlstrasse 9, Hannover. ·ZANDER, W., Professor, Direktor der Handelsschule, Wurzenerstrasse 24, Grimma i. S. ZEYSS, Dr., Syndikus der Handelskammer, Krefeld. ZIEGLER, Adolf, Oberlehrer an der Öffentlichen Handelslchranstalt, Re- daktor der Deutschen Handelsschullehrer-Zeitung, Ostra-Allee 9, Dresden. ZIEHEN, Stadtschulrat, Frankfurt a. M. pl Angleterre Membres individuels BARBER, W. H., Secretary of the Yorkshire Association for the Promotion of Commercial Education, Leeds. England. Einzelmitglieder: • 15 • ? BELL, Oswin, Deanstreet, 21, Newcastle. BEWSNUP, E. R., Technical College, Huddersfield. BROWNE, C. F., General Secretary of the Nord-Londona Esperanto-Institut, 53, Burghley Road, Highgate, London, N. W. DIRECTOR OF CEKBANKO ESPERANTISTA, Merton Abbey, London, S.W. DIRECTOR OF THE VIXOL, Limited, Merton Abbey, London, S. W. DIRECTOR OF THE TANDEM SMELTING, Syndicate, Limited, Merton Abbey, London, S. W. FIEDLER, H. G., Professor of the University of Birmingham, Birmingham. GOODLIFFE, F. A., Manufacturer, 46, Bridgford Road, Nottingham. GRAHAM, James, Director of Education, Education Department, Calver- leystreet, Leeds. HEMELRYK, P. E. F., Vicepresident of the Commercial School, Honorary Consul of Japon (Ständiges Mitglied), Woolton Heyes, Liverpool. HOOPER, Fredk., Secretary of the Chamber of Commerce, Bradford. KAHN, Augustus, University-College-School, Cowerstreet, London. MEYER, F. H. R., of the Firm Rabone Bros & Co., Austro Hungarian Vice- Consul, Member of the Chamber of Commerce, Broadstreet, 297, Birmingham. WEBSTER, F. E., Commercial Teacher, Office of technical Education of the County of Devon, Queen Street, 50, Exeter. Argentine t Membre individuel MONTERO, B., Consul Général de la République Argentine, 37 Via XX Settembre, Gênes (Italie). Autriche Argentinien. Einzelmitglied: Österreich. Kollektivmitglieder: Membres collectifs ANSTALT FÜR HANDEL UND GEWERBE, Bozen. ASSICURAZIONI GENERALI, Triest. IDO, DEUTSCHER PRAGER FRAUEN-ERWERBVEREIN, vertreten durch Frau Sophie Bamberger. Prag, Ferdinandstrasse 10. DIREKTIONSKOMITEE DER INTERNATIONALEN HILFSSPRACHE Halbarthstrasse, Graz. GREMIUM DER BUCHSACHVERSTÄNDIGEN, Wien VIII, Landes- gerichtstrasse 21. GREMIUM DER WIENER KAUFMANNSCHAFT, vertreten durch Herrn k. k. Regierungsrat Rudolf Krickl. Wien IV, Lothringerstrasse 10. HANDELSSEKTION DER K. K. HANDELS- UND NAUTISCHEN AKA- DEMIE in Triest, vertreten durch kaiserlichen Rat und Direktor Josef Gelcich. Triest, Piazza Lipsia. KURATORIUM DER BÖHMISCHEN HANDELSAKADEMIE in Pilsen, vertreten durch Direktor Anton Kostinec. Pilsen, Nerudagasse 12. KURATORIUM DER STÄDTISCHEN HANDELSSCHULE in Budweis, vertreten durch Direktor Friedrich Patzelt. Budweis, Parkstrasse 1. LEHRKÖRPER DER ERZHERZOG-RAINER-JUBILÄUMS HANDELS- SCHULE in Wien, vertreten durch Direktor Josef Schreiter Ritter von Schwarzenfeld. Wien V, Obere Amthausgasse 37. 16 LEHRKÖRPER DER HANDELSAKADEMIE in Gablonz a. d. N., ver- treten durch Dr. Ewald Gleisberg. Gablonz a. d. N., Berggasse 4. LEHRKÖRPER DER HANDELSAKADEMIE in Königgrätz. LERKÖRPER DER HANDELSAKADEMIE in Olmütz, vertreten durch Dr. Karl Preissler. Olmütz, Josef-v.-Engel-Strasse 12. LEHRKÖRPER DER HANDELSSCHULE DES NEUEN HANDELS- GREMIUMS in Prag, vertreten durch Direktor Franz Trmal. Prag, Mariengasse 32. LEHRKÖRPER DER KOMMUNAL-HANDELSSCHULE, Küstenau (Vorarlberg). LEHRKÖRPER DER PRIVATHANDELSSCHULE KAPAMADZIJA in Wien, vertreten durch Direktor Ludwig Legat. Wien VI, Millergasse 43. VERBAND ZUR FÖRDERUNG DES FACHLICH-GEWERBLICHEÈN FORTBILDUNGSSCHULWESENS in Österreich, vertreten durch Direktor Adolf Hess. Wien I, Judenplatz 3. VEREIN ZUR FÖRDERUNG DER HANDELS- UND FORTBILDUNGS- SCHULEN in Wien VII, vertreten durch Emanuel Margold. Wien VII, Neustiftgasse 100. VEREIN ABSOLVIERTER PRAGER HANDELS-AKADEMIKER Prag. VEREIN DER ÖSTERREICHISCHEN HANDELSSCHULLEHRER, Linz, Handelsakademie. Einzelmitglieder Membres individuels: ADAM, Heinrich, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV, Schönburgstrasse 27. ADLER, Alfred, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffentlich- keitsrecht. Wien III, Marokkanergasse 10. AIGNER, Moritz, Bankoberbeamter, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Burggasse 79. ALLINA, Max, kaiserlicher Rat, Direktor der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffentlichkeitsrecht. Wien I, Weihburggasse 21. ANTONIEWICZ, Boleslaus, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Krakau. Krakau, Sobieskigasse 5. Mödling, Grillparzerstrasse 2. an der Prager Handelsakademie, Prag, Naprstekgasse 215. BAAR, Rudolf, wirklicher Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie, Wien VIII, Josefstädterstrasse 93. BACHMAYER, Ignatz, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Uhlplatz 5. BAMBERGER, Sophie, Präsidentin des Deutschen Prager Frauenerwerb- vereines. Prag, Ferdinandstrasse 10. BARTA, Rudolf, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien III, Ungargasse 21. ARENZ, Eduard, Handelsschulleiter. AUSSERWINKLER, Ludwig, Professor BASUR, Guiseppe, kaiserl. Rat, Handelskammerrat, Triest. BERGER, Johann, k. k. Regierungsrat, Handelsakademiedirektor i. P. Graz, Glacisstrasse 13. BERGER, J. L., Sekretär der Bezirkskrankenkasse und Besitzer und Leiter einer Privathandelslehranstalt, Sobieskiplatz 10. Tarnopol (Galizien). BERGER, Thomas, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Richard-Wagner-Strasse 8. 17 I BERGMEISTER, Dr. Rud., Prof. an der k. k. Handels- und nautischen Aka- demie, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz, Triest, Piazza Lipsia. BERKA, Viktor, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Merangasse 50. BESTAUX, Eugen, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Bahnhofplatz 20. BILECKI, Alois, wirklicher Lehrer an der schlesischen Handelsschule in Troppau. Troppau. BINSTORFER, Michael, Bürgerschuldirektor, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Walriesstrasse 75. BITTNER, Eduard, k. k. Kommerzialrat, Handelsakademieprofessor i. P. Wien III, Arenberggasse 1. BLAHA, Max, wirklicher Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Parkstrasse 3. BOCK, Jakob, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffentlich- keitsrecht. Wien V. Pilgramgasse 8. BÖCKL, August, Professor an der städtischen Handelsschule in Teplitz. Teplitz, Hohenlohestrasse 26. BÖCKLE, Rudolf, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Fallmerayerstrasse 2. BÖHM, Karl, Direktor der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Elisabethstrasse 10. BÖRNER, Emil, k. k. Professor, Lehrer an der Höheren Handelsschule für Mädchen. Wien IX, Lustkandlgasse 32. BRABBÉE, Ewald, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VII, Schottenfeldgasse 80. BRASSLOFF, Dr. Stephan, Dozent an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien XVIII, Währingerstrasse 127. BRAUN, Dr. Alfred, Supplent an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handels- akademie in Brünn. Brünn, Anastasius-Grün-Gasse 6. BRAUN, Friedrich, Professor an der Handelsschule in Salzburg, Salzburg- Maxglan, Straubingerstrasse 21. BROD, Ignatz, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffentlichkeits- recht. Wien II, Czerninplatz 1. BROSSARD, Eugen, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VI, Mariahilferstrasse 5. BRÜCKNER, Kamillo, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Lederergasse 22. BRUHNS, Alois, Bürgerschullehrer, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Halbgasse 7. BRUMAT, Josef, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck-Mühlau (Dollinger). BULSKY, Eugen, Direktor der Handelsschule in Ungarisch-Hradisch. Ungarisch-Hradisch. BÜNZEL-FEDERN, Julius, Vorstand des deutschen Prager kaufmännischen Vereins. Prag. BURGGASSER, Karl, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Linz. Linz, Volksgartenstrasse 7. CHLUP, Rudolf, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. CHRISTOF, Mieczyslao, k. k. Professor an der Handelsakademie. Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. 2 18 CHUDAREK, Josef, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Weinberggasse 24. CORDIER, Dr. Viktor v., Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Naglergasse 10. CTIBOR, Johann, Direktor an der Handelsakademie in Chrudim. Chrudim. CUBERKA, Ferdinand, Bankrevident, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter, Professor an der Gremialhandelsfach- schule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VIII, Albertgasse 54. CZECH, Johann, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Talgasse 22: DECKER, Achilles, k. k. a. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien V, Schönbrunnerstrasse 70. DEIMEL, Eduard, k. k. Schulrat, Professor an der Prager Handels- akademie. Prag, Niklasstrasse 32. DENHOF, Heinrich, Zuckerfabrikant. Prag, Stupartsgasse 7. DEUTSCHMANN, Johann, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsschule in Görz. Görz, Piazza St. Antonio 12. DEVERDUN-RAJECKI, Heinrich, Dozent an der Wiener Handelsakademie, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter. Wien VIII, Hamerlingplatz 4. DLABAC, Dr. Friedrich, k. k. Sektionsrat im Ministerium für Kultus und Unterricht. Wien III, Strohgasse 24. DOBIECKI, August Ritter v., k. k. Ministerialrat im Handelsministerium, Wien III, Hintzerstrasse 1. DONNER, Josef Alexander, kaiserlicher Rat, a. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien VIII, Blindengasse 35. DÖRFEL, Franz, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien XVIII, Herbeckstrasse 25 a. DUBEY, Alfred, Lehrer an der Handelsschule der christlichen Schulbrüder in Strebersdorf bei Wien. Strebersdorf bei Wien. DUCHACEK, Dr. Franz, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. DÜCK, Johannes, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Goethestrasse 5. DUFAUX, Eugen, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffent- lichkeitsrecht. Wien I, Weihburggasse 8. DVORAK, Josef, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. EFFENBERGER, Eduard, k. k. Rechnungsrat und Lehrer an der Handels- schule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter. Wien VIII, Piaristengasse 58. EHRENHAFT-STEINDLER, Dr. Olga, Direktion der Höheren Handels- schule für Mädchen. Wien I, Wiesingerstrasse I. EHRLICH, Jakob, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffent- lichkeitsrecht. Wien III, Linke Bahngasse 5. EHRMANN, Dr. Heinrich, Advokat und Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Schwedengasse 3. Handelsschule der christlichen Strebersdorf bei Wien. Direktor der städtischen Teplitz, Waagestrasse 9. Handelsschule in Teplitz. ELBOGEN, Richard, k. k. Kommerzialrat, Grossindustrieller. Prag. ERBEN, Josef, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Karolinenthal, Havlicekgasse 103. EICHFELDER, Servantius, Direktor der Schulbrüder in Strebersdorf bei Wien. EISENKOLB, Heinrich, kaiserlicher Rat, 19 EXNER, Dr. Wilhelm Franz, k. k. Sektionschef, Präsident des k. k. Gewerbeförderungsamtes. Wien IX, Währingerstrasse 59. FEIFALIK, Otto, Landeshandelsschulprofessor und Supplent an der Gre- mialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes, Krems a. d. Donau. FEITLER, Dr. Siegmund, k. k. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien IX, Liechtensteinstrasse 62. FELDMANN, Erich, wirklicher Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handels- akademie. Wien VIII, Pfeilgasse 44. FISARA, Karl, Direktor der k. k. Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Giskrastrasse 38. FISCHER, Dr. August, Direktor der Privathandelsschule Weiss' Nach- folger und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien I, Getreidemarkt 16. FITZ, Karl, Sekretär der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Pfeilgasse 7. FLEISCHNER, Ludwig, Professor an der städtischen Handelsschule in Budweis. Budweis, Ottokargasse 10. FLORA, Karl, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Schwaz. Schwaz. FLUSSER, Dr. Max, k. k. Hauptlehrer, Lehrer an der Höheren Handels- schule für Mädchen. Wien V, Margaretenstrasse 125. FORCHHEIMER, Otto, Präses des Prager Handelsgremiums. GÄRTNER, Franz, k. k. Regierungsrat, Prag, Langegasse 41. FREUND, Oskar, Supplent an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien II, Thugutstrasse 4. FREY, Felix, Sparkassebuchhalter und Professor an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Mödling, Institutsgasse 16. FRUCHT, Adolf, k. k. Schulrat, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Attemsgasse 21. FUCHS, Max, Supplent an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Scheffelgasse 2. FÜHRER, Franz, wirklicher Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Brockmanngasse 26. GANSEL, Dr. Bernhard, Supplent an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien II, Rembrandtstrasse 16. Direktor der k. k. Lehranstalt für Textilindustrie in Asch. Asch. GATTERER, Karl J., Bankoberbeamter, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XIII, Auhofstrasse 34. GAUGLITZ, Maximilian, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Radetzkystrasse 15. GEIERSBACH, Wilhelm, Direktor der Handelsschule in Salzburg. Parsch bei Salzburg. GELCICH, Eugen, k. k. wirkl. Hofrat, k. k. Zentralinspektor f. d. kommer- ziellen Unterricht, Vizepräsident der Internationalen Gesellschaft zur Förderung des kaufmännischen Unterrichtswesens, Vorsitzender der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Wien III, Strohgasse 24. GEORGIADÈS, Georg, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Lenaugasse 1. GIRTLER, Franz, k. k. Ministerialassistent und Supplent an der Gre- mialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XIX, Billrothstrasse 11. • 20 GIRZIK, Eduard. Bankbeamter und Supplent an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IX, Lackierergasse 1. GLÄSER, Dr. Konrad, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsakademie in Linz. Linz, Lessinggasse 11. GLASSER, Franz, kaiserlicher Rat, k. k. Professor, Direktor der Privat- handelsschule Glasser vormals Pazelt und der privaten höheren Handels- lehranstalt Glasser. Wien I, Judenplatz. GLAUSER, Dr. Karl, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie, II. Schriftführer der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Wien IV, Schelleingasse 23. GLEISBERG, Dr. Ewald, Direktor der Handelsakademie in Gablonz a.d. N. Gablonz a. d. N., Berggasse 4. GOLDBERGER, Leopold, wirklicher Lehrer an der Höheren Handels- schule für Mädchen. Wien VIII, Albertgasse 14. GONISETH, Theodor, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter, Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Schulgasse 26. GORA, Witold, k. k. Prof. an der Handelsakademie Lemberg. GÖTZL, Dr., Heinrich, Professor an der Handelsakademie. Aussig. GRAF, Viktor, wirklicher Lehrer an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Deutschen Handelsakademie in Pilsen. Pilsen. GRAZIADEI, Dr. Heinrich, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Innstrasse 40. GROHMANN, Eduard, Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Dreilaufergasse 16. GRÜNSPANN, Max, städt. Oberlehrer und Supplent an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien II, Leopoldsgasse 15a. GRUNZEL, Dr. Josef, k. k. Regierungsrat, k. k. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien XIII, Baumgartenstrasse 23. GUIC, Johann, Supplent an der k. k. Handelsschule in Spalato. Spalato. HAAN, Ludwig, Freiherr v., k. k. Ministerialvizesekretär im Handels- ministerium. Wien I, Rotenturmstrasse 14. HAAS, Ernst, Assistent an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Karmelitergasse 15. HANAUSEK, Eduard, k. k. Schulrat, Professor an der Wiener Handels- akademie. Wien IV, Kolschitzkygasse 5. HANTSCH, Viktor, Bankprokurist i. P., Abteilungsvorstand und Pro- fessor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Schottenfeldgasse 40. HAUDEK, Raimund, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener kaufmännischen Vereins. Wien VIII, Laudongasse 69. HAUSER, Joh., Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. HASSACK, Dr. Karl, Professor und Direktor der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Graz, Grazbachgasse 69. HAUSMANN, Josef, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Teplitz. Teplitz, Schönauer Kirchenplatz 8. HEIDERICH, Dr. Franz, k. k. a. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien VIII, Josefstädterstrasse 105. HEILSBERG, Alois, k. k. Gymnasialprofessor, Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IX, Dreihackengasse 4. HEISEK, Leo, Direktor der schlesischen Handelsschule in Troppau, Troppau 21 HELLAUER, Dr. Josef, k. k. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien IX, Pichlergasse 2. HENKE, Rudolf, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademic. Innsbruck-Mühlau 103. HENNER, Dr. Kamillo, k. k. o. ö. Universitätsprofessor, k. k. Inspektor für den kommerziellen Unterricht, Mitglied der österreichischen Reprä- sentanz. Prag II. Nr. 1677. HERLITSCHKA, Hans, Bürgerschullehrer und Lehrer an der Handels- schule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter, Wien XIV, Reindorfgasse 26. HERTL, Josef, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV, Weyringergasse 1. HERTZKA, Oskar, Direktorstellvertreter der Filiale der k. k. priv. österr. Kreditanstalt. Prag, Didrichsgasse 1773. HESS, Adolf, Direktor des Seminars zur Ausbildung von Lehrerinnen für Koch- und Haushaltungsschulen und der Fachschule der Genossenschaft der Gastwirte u. Kaffeesieder, Professor an der Privathandelsschule Allina. Wien I, Kurrentgasse 5. HIRMKE, Paul, Supplent an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Deutschen Handels- akademie in Pilsen. Pilsen. HOCHDORF, Dr. Leonhard, k. k. Ministerialvizesekretär im Handels- ministerium. Wien VIII, Schmidgasse 4. HOFER, Karl, Bürgerschullehrer, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Schul- vereins für Beamtentöchter, Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Mentergasse 5. HOFMANN, Alfred Ritter v., k. k. Regierungsrat, Inhaber der Privat- handelsschule Strells Nachfolger. Wien III, Wassergasse 16. HOFFMANN, Theodor, Direktor der böhmischen Eskontebank, Prag. HOLMAN, Bohuslav, Professor an der k. k. Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Giskrastrasse 38. HORAK, Josef, kaiserlicher Rat, Eisenbahninspektor, Lehrer an der Handels- schule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter, Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Theresiengasse 44. HORNER, Dr. Emil, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IX, Seegasse 6. HRUSKA, Ig. Egon, Bankinspektor und Professor an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XIII, Linzerstrasse 70. HUBER, Franz, Bürgerschullehrer und Supplent an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IX, Spittelauerlände 23. HURT, Ludwig Karl, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien II, Valeriestrasse 50. HÜTTNER, Ludwig, wirklicher Lehrer an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Smichow, Königsstrasse 1118. IFFINGER, Walter, Beamter und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Sternwartestrasse 35. IPPOLDT, Julius, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Krakau. Krakau, Wietopolegasse 18. IRRALL, Oskar, Sparkassebeamter, Professor an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes, Leiter der Privathandelsschule für Mädchen in Hietzing. Wien XVIII, Pötzleinsdorferstrasse 130. JANIG, Karl, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Brüx. Brüx, Ringstrasse 60. JELCIC, Anton, Direktor der k. k. Handelsschule in Spalato. Spalato. 22 s JELINEK, Julius, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener kaufmännischen Vereines. Wien VIII, Blindengasse 18. JERUSALEM, Dr. Edmund, wirklicher Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handels- akademie. Wien XIII, Hüttelbergstrasse 25. JIRACEK, Georg, Professor an der k. k. Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Giskrastrasse 38. JORDAN, Alfred Ritter v., k. k. Sektionsrat, Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien III, Pettenkofengasse 5. JORDAN, Emil, Lehrer an der Handelsschule in Görz. Görz, Via Cipréssi 2. KADERSCHAFKA, Vinzenz, Fachlehrer an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVI, Grundsteingasse 32. KAISER, Thomas, Bürgerschullehrer, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VI, Stiegengasse 9. KALLA, Anton, Supplent an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Franzenskai 6. KANNENBERG, Josef, Direktor der k. k. Handelsakademie in Krakau. Krakau, Wraszewskigasse 29. KARPINSKI, Kasimir, Hilfslehrer an der Handelsakademie. Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. KARSCHULIN, Dr. Georg, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IX, Kinderspitalgasse 4. KATZ, Dr. Marie, Lehrerin an der Höheren Handelsschule für Mädchen. Wien IX, Sechsschimmelgasse 6. KIRCHHOF, Karl, Vize-Präsident der Handels- und Gewerbekammer. Reichenberg. KITT, Dr. Moritz, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VII, Lerchenfelderstrasse 31. KLINGER, Franz, Hilfslehrer an der Prager Handelsakademic. Prag-Smichow, Moldaugasse 30. KLEIBEL, Anton, k. k. Regierungsrat, Direktor der Wiener Handels- akademie, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Wien I, Akademiestrasse 12. KLIMA, Josef, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Waisenhausgasse 4. KNAPP, Ernst, Direktor der städtischen Handelsschule in Schwaz. Schwaz. KOHN, Dr. Emmerich, Lehrer an der Höheren Handelsschule für Mädchen. Wien II, Obere Donaustrasse 43. KOJETINSKI, Johann, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV, Phorusgasse 11. KOLISCH, Ludwig, Dozent an der Exportakademie. Wien IX, Alserstrasse 28. KOMORCZYNSKI, Dr. Egon v., Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien XVIII, Karl-Ludwig-Strasse 16. KONVICKA, Josef, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. KOPPLER, Moritz, k. k. Schulrat, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Nibelungengasse 24. KORNER, Gustav, Direktor der Länderbank-Filiale, Prag. KÖRSCHNER, Ludwig, wirklicher Lehrer an der schlesischen Handels- schule in Troppau. Troppau. 23 I KOSTINEC, Anton, Direktor der Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Pilsen. Pilsen, Nerudagasse 12. KOTERA, Anton, k. k. Schulrat, Handelsakademiedirektor i. P. Prag Weinberge, Hradsinecgasse 16. KRAEGER, Josef, Direktor der Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Deutschen Handels- akademie in Pilsen. Pilsen. KRAMMER, Dr. Heinrich, k. k. Landesgerichtsrat i. P., Lehrer an der k. k. Handels- und nautischen Akademie. Triest, Via St. Antonio 1. KRATOCHWILL, Karl, k. k. Offizial und Lehrer an der Privathandels- schule Glasser. Wien XVIII, Währingerstrasse 128. KRATZERT, Rudolf, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Franz-Josef-Strasse 31. KRAUS, Dr. Wlastimil, wirklicher Lehrer an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Deutschen Handelsakademie in Pilsen. Pilsen. KREIBIG, Dr. Josef Klemens, k. k. Regierungsrat, k. k. Inspektor für den kommerziellen Unterricht. Wien VI, Magdalenenstrasse 40. KREJCI, Franz, Hilfslehrer an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Krakauergasse 5. KREMSER, Josef, Assistent an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Walriesstrasse 72. KRENCICH, Rudolf, Assistent an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien XIX, Döblinger Hauptstrasse 17. KRICKL, Rudolf, k. k. Regierungsrat. k. k. Kommerzialrat, Direktor der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes, Kassier der öster- reichischen Repräsentanz. Wien I, Getreidemarkt 16. KVETON, Franz, Professor an der k. k. Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Giskrastrasse 38. KUNCZITZKY, Karl, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien V, Franzensgasse 11. LAASCH, Otto, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Karolinenthal, Riegerplatz 7. LAMBERTZ, Gottfried, kaiserlicher Rat, Lyzealdirektor, Abteilungsvor- stand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Neustiftgasse 5. LANGE, August, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VI, Getreidemarkt 15. LANGER, Karl, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VIII, Buchfeldgasse 4. LEDERER, Siegfried, Professor an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Deutschen Handelsakademie in Pilsen. LENZ, Dr. Oskar, k. k. Hofrat, k. k. o. ö. Universitätsprofessor. Prag-Weinberge, Untere Blanikgasse 6. LEYERER, Konstantin, Professor an der k. k. Handels- und nautischen Akademie. Triest, Piazza Cornelia Romana 2. LIEBERGESELL, Klemens, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffentlichkeitsrecht. Wien III, Reisnerstrasse 36. LITSCHAUER, Viktor, Professor an der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Mandelsbergerstrasse 9. LAFAR, Theodor, Bürgerschullehrer und Supplent an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IV, Wiedner Gürtel 52. LENECEK, Dr. Ottokar, Dr. Ottokar, Professor an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Lichtenauergasse 6. Pilsen. V 24 LOEBL, Friederike, Lehrerin an der Höheren Handelsschule für Mädchen. Wien IV, Wohllebengasse 19. LONGIN, Josef, Direktor der städtischen Handelsschule in Brüx. Brüx, Vogelstange 30. LUDWIG, Karl, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Warnsdorf. Warnsdorf. LUDWIG, Dr. Karl, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Linz, Obmann des Vereins der österreichischen Handelsschullehrer. Linz, Altstadt 30. LULEK, Dr. Thomas, wirklicher Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Krakau. Krakau, Niecata 10. LÜNEMANN, Erich, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV. Weyringergasse 40. MAILINGER, Eduard, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Eichhorngasse 53. MAREK, Dr. Richard, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Pestalozzistrasse 31. MARTIN, Dr. Franz, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademic. Prag, Wenzelsgasse 326. MATHIEU, Heinrich, Hilfslehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener kauf- männischen Vereines. Wien IV, Margaretenstrasse 34. MAYER, Max, Lehrer an der Handelsschule der christlichen Schulbrüder in Strebersdorf bei Wien. Strebersdorf bei Wien. MAYR, Dr. Richard, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV, Schönbrunnerstrasse 4. MELNITZKY, Julius, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Josefstädterstrasse 20. MERGENTHALER, Franz, Bürgerschullehrer und Professor Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. an der Wien XVII, Jörgerstrasse 50. METZL, Alois, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Josefstädterstrasse 87. MORD, Alois, k. k. Professor i. P., Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wien XVI, Ottakringerstrasse 240. Wiener Frauen-Erwerbsvereins. MOSER, Karl, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener kauf- Wien VIII, Stolzenthalergasse 2. männischen Vereines. MRHA, Dr. Josef, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Smichow, Königsstrasse 33. MULLY, Robert v. Oppenried, Sparkassebeamter, Dozent an der Export- akademie, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfach- schule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien I, Stubenring 18. MÜLLER, Edmund, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule Brüx, Ringstrasse 12. MÜLLER, Josef, I'rofessor an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Deutschen Handels- akademie in Pilsen. Pilsen. in Brüx. MURR, Paul, Sekretär der Innsbrucker Handelsakademie. Innsbruck, Kiebachgasse 15. NACHTIGALL, Dr. Rajko, Dozent an der Exportakademie. Wien XVIII, Herbeckstrasse 115. NAEF, Heinrich, Professor an der k. k. Handels- und nautischen Akademie. Triest, Vicolo delle ville 6. NAHODIL, Marie, Lehrerin an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Rudolfsgasse 32. ↓ 25 z 1. NASH, Thomas, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV, Starhemberggasse 44. NEMECEK, Dr. Ottokar, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VII, Schottenfeldgasse 82. NEMLUWIL, Franz, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsakademie in Linz. Linz, Waldeggstrasse 12. NESENI, Robert, Professor an der neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Florianigasse 47. NEUMANN, Alois, Präsident der Handels- und Gewerbekammer. Reichenberg. NEURATH, Otto, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IX, Löblichgasse 6. NITSCHE, Johann, Bürgerschuldirektor, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IX, Glasergasse 8. OBERDORFER, Friedrich, Professor an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Haberlergasse 51. ERTL, Rudolf, Supplent an der städtischen Handelsschule in Warnsdorf. Warnsdorf. OPPELT, Dr. Rudolf, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Karolinenthal, Riegergasse 5. OSBAHR, Wilhelm, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien XVIII, Vinzenzgasse 24. OTAHAL, Wilhelm, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. OTTEL, Klemens, k. k. Landesschulinspektor, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Wien IV, Wiedner Hauptstrasse 39. OUDIN, Armand, Lehrer an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Lazarusgasse 10. PANY, Leopold, k. k. Schulrat, k. k. Professor a. D., Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Alserstrasse 53. PAPE, Dr. Rudolf, Magistratssekretär und Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VIII, Bennogasse 9. PAUKSCH, Dr. Julius, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Lustenau. Lustenau. PAWLOWSKI, Anton, k. k. Regierungsrat, Direktor der k. k. Handels- akademie in Lemberg, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Lemberg, Skarbekgasse 39. PAZOUREK, Dr. Josef, Direktor der Handelsakademie, Königgrätz. PETYMAK-SANECKI, Dr. Kasima, k. k. wirklicher Lehrer an der Handels- Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. PFALZNER, Leopold, Bürgerschullehrer, Hilfslehrer an der Handelsschule Wien XVI, Ippengasse 1. PFOHL, Ernst, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Reichenberg. Reichenberg, Kammerbergstrasse 4. PICHLER, Franz, Professor an der k. k. Lehranstalt für Textilindustrie in Asch. Asch. akademie. des Wiener kaufmännischen Vereins. • DE PIETTE, Ludwig, Papierfabrikant, Pilsen. PILZ, Edwin, Supplent an der städtischen Handelsschule in Teplitz. Teplitz, Elisabethstrasse 14. PISKO, Gabriele, Inhaberin der Privathandelsschule für Mädchen in Hietzing. Wien XIII, Altgasse 21. I 26 PIVEC, Dr. Alois, Bürgerschuldirektor und Supplent an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. POLLAK, Heinrich, Wien VII, Neubaugasse 42. PLASCHKE, Konrad, wirklicher Lehrer an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Deutschen Handelsakademie in Pilsen. PLISZEWSKY, Johann, k. k. Professor an der Handelsakademie Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. Professor an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Deutschen Handelsakademie in Pilsen. Pilsen. POLLAK, Dr. Rudolf, k. k. Landesgerichtsrat, k. k. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien VII, Kirchengasse 48. PÖLZL, Ignatz, k. k. Professor i. P., Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener Frauen-Erwerbvereins. Wien IV, Alleegasse 30. POPPER, Isidor, kaiserlicher Rat, Industrieller. Wien VIII, Hamerlingplatz 6. PÖSCHL, Dr. Viktor, Supplent an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Klosterwiesgasse 19. POSSELT, Adolf, Bürgermeister und Landtagsabgeordneter. Gablonz a. d. N. POSTEL, Paul, k. k. Professor an der Handelsakademie, Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. PREISSLER, Dr. Karl, k. k. Professor und Direktor der Handelsakademie in Olmütz. Olmütz, Josef-v.-Engel-Strasse 12. PRIEBSCH, Dr. Josef, k. k. a. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien XVIII, Gentzgasse 115. RADDA, Joh. Emanuel, Eisenbahnsekretär, Abteilungsvorstand und Pro- fessor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Mariahilferstrasse 70. RASCHNER, Adolf, Hilfslehrer an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Weinberge, Brandlgasse 13. RAULICH, Hugo, Direktor der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. REICHMANN, Hans, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Getreidemarkt 8. REINTHALER, Franz, Ingenieur, Assistent an der Exportakademie. Wien IV, Kleine Neugasse 21. REY, Armand, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Pilsen. Wien VI, Mariahilferstrasse 49. REZABEK, Dr. Johann, k. k. Regierungsrat, Direktor der Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Prag, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz, Prag, Resselgasse. RIED, Theodor, k. k. Regierungsrat, Direktor der Prager Handelsakademie. Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Prag, Fleischmarkt 8. RIEDL, Josef, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Weinberge, Parkstrasse 555. RIESENFELD, Rudolf, Supplent an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien XIX, Gymnasiumstrasse 62. RIGLER, Rudolf, Bürgerschullehrer, Hilfslehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener kaufmännischen Vereins, Professor an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVI, Brunnengasse 69. RONGIER, Paul, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Krakau. Krakau, Ringplatz 8. ROSCHER, Fridolin, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Warnsdorf. Warnsdorf. } 27 ROTHAUG, Johann Georg, Bürgerschullehrer und Lehrer an der Handels- schule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter. Wien VIII, Langegasse 47. ROUGEMONT, Ernst, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien I, Wollzeile 14. RUCKER, Dr. Friedrich, Bürgerschuldirektor, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Köhlergasse 14. RUPRICH, Alfred, Inhaber der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Rudolfsgasse 6. SARIC, Johann, Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsschule in Spalato. Spalato. SATZINGER, Dr. Karl, k. k. Finanzkommissär, Dozent an der Export- akademie. Wien I, Hoher Markt 3. SAUER, Johann Julius, Professor an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handels- akademie. in Brünn. Brünn, Beischlägerstrasse 17. SCHATZ, Albert, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffent- lichkeitsrecht. Wien VI, Sonnenuhrgasse 2. SCHIGUT, Eugen, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Bennoplatz 8. SCHILLER, Friedrich, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Reichenberg. Reichenberg, Schlossgasse 3. SCHMERBER, Dr. Hugo, Privatdozent an der k. k. Technischen Hoch- schule. Prag, Aujedzgasse 595. o. Professor an der Export- der österreichischen Reprä- Wien IX, Berggasse 16. SCHMID, Anton, k. k. Regierungsrat, k. k. akademie, Stellvertreter des Vorsitzenden sentanz. SCHMIEDHOFER, Ferdinand, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Augustinergasse 14. SCHNEIDER, Fritz, Supplent an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IV, Gusshausstrasse 26. SCHNELLER, Theodor, Direktor der Handelsakademie in Linz. Linz, Landstrasse 85. SCHOLZ, Dominik, städt. Lehrer und Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener Frauen-Erwerbsvereins. Wien XV, Sechshauserstrasse 26. SCHÖNNETT, Maximilian, Dr., k. k. Professor an der Handelsakademie. Leutberg, Skarbekgasse. SCHÜCKE, Oskar, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter. Wien IX, Schwarzspanierstrasse 20. SCHULTSCHIK, Dr. Johann, Hof- und Gerichtsadvokat, Supplent an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien III, Hauptstrasse 19. SCHULTEIS, Johann, Bürgerschullehrer und Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XXI, Schöpfleuthnergasse 10. SCHULZ, Dr. Felix, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Deutschen Frauen- Erwerbsvereines in Brünn. Brünn, Zinhartgasse 6. SCHUSTER, Adrian, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie, Direktor der Handelsschule des Wiener Frauen-Erwerbsvereins. Wien IV, Hechtengasse 5. SCHWAB, Amalie, Lehrerin an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Kottgasse 4. SCHWAB, Franz, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Ruprich in Brünn. Brünn, Tivoligasse 10. 28 SCHWARZ, Emil, Hilfslehrer an der k. k. Handels- und nautischen Akademie. Triest, Via Chiozza 70. SCHWARZ, Sigismund, Direktor, Stellvertreter der Filiale der k. k. priv. österr. Kreditanstalt für Handel und Gewerbe. Prag. SCHWETTER, Dr. Alfred, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien V1, Windmühlgasse 42. SEITER, Franz, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffentlich- keitsrecht. Wien XVIII, Lacknergasse 106. SELCH, Dr. Emmerich, Professor an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handels- akademie in Brünn. Brünn, Elisabethstrasse 10. SENONER, Paul, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffent- lichkeitsrecht. Wien VIII, Hernalser Gürtel 2. SIMÉONS, Dr. Karl, k. k. Ministerialsekretär im Handelsministerium. Wien I, Grillparzerstrasse 11. SIMON, Otto, Professor an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien VIII, Josefstädterstrasse 87. SINGER, Richard, Bankprokurist i. P., Dozent an der Exportakademie. Wien I, Renngasse 9. SINWEL, Rudolf, Professor an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handels- akademie in Brünn. Brünn, Schmerlingstrasse 13. SKOKAN, Karl, wirklicher Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Maigasse 25. SMITAL, Johann, Bürgerschuldirektor, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XXI, Am Spitz 14. SOMMER, Franz, Lehrer an der Handelsschule der christlichen Schulbrüder in Strebersdorf bei Wien. Strebersdorf bei Wien. SONNDORFER, Dr. Rudolf, Dozent an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien I, Kärntnerstrasse 23. SONNDORFER, Dr. Rudolf, k. k. Regierungsrat, Handelsakademiedirektor i. P. Wien XIII, Hietzinger Hauptstrasse 25. STEINITZ, Wenzel, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag-Smichow, Königsstrasse 42. STOISER, Dr. Josef, Professor an der Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien IV, Schönburgstrasse 38. STOLZ, Dr. Ernst, k. k. Finanzsekretär, Professor an der Wiener Handels- akademie. Wien III, Kollergasse 1. STRAUSS, Dr. Ludwig, Hof- und Gerichtsadvokat, k. k. o. Professor an der Exportakademie. Wien I, Schottenbastei 16. STREHLE, Josef, kaiserl. Rat, Direktor der Handelsschule des Schul- vereins für Beamtentöchter. Wien VII, Mariahilferstrasse 70. STÜTZ, Engelbert, Sparkassebeamter, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter, Professor an der Gremialḥandelsfach- schule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien II, Darwingasse 36. SUCHY, Ferdinand, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule iu Brüx. Brüx, Goethestrasse 7. SUIDA, Dr. Wilhelm, k. k. o. ö. Professor an der Technischen Hochschule. Wien XIII, Trauttmansdorffgasse 19. SYROVY, Vinzenz, Professor an der k. k. Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Giskrastrasse 38. TASCHEK, W. H., Assekuranzbeamter, Hauptstrasse 41, T. 9, Wien XVII. TEGEL, Adolf, Volksschullehrer und Supplent an der Gremialhandelsfach- schule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien III, Rasumofskygasse 2. pag 29 Į TEIBER, Heinrich, Banksekretär, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Währingerstrasse 99. TESCHAUER, Franz, Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Allina mit Öffent- lichkeitsrecht. Wien IV, Schleifmühlgasse 23. TEUCHERT, Dr. Karl, Hof- und Gerichtsadvokat, Lehrer an der Handels- schule des Schulvereins für Beamtentöchter, Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien I, Walfischgasse 13. TIPPEL, Josef, kaiserlicher Rat, Direktor der städtischen Handelsschule in Warnsdorf. Warnsdorf, Bürgerstrasse 122. TISCHLER, Rudolf, Direktor der Böhmischen Unionsbank, Prag. TITZER, Josef, k. k. Ministerialassistent, Professor an der Gremialhandels- fachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVIII, Weitlofgasse 10. TUTSCHNER, Ferdinand, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handels- schule in Brüx. Brüx, Jahnstrasse 28. ULLRICH, Gustav, Supplent an der städtischen Handelsschule in Warnsdorf. Warnsdorf. ULRICH, Emil, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule in Brüx. Brüx, Teplitzer Strasse 404. UNCYOWSKI, Heinrich, k. k. Professor an der Handelsakademie. Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. URBAN, Hans, Gremialschulsekretär und Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien V, Wienstrasse 16. URBAN, Josef, Bürgerschuldirektor, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XVI, Fröbelgasse 31. UTSCHIG - DITTRICH, Josef, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handels- akademie. Wien VIII, Lerchenfelder Gürtel 66. UTSCHIG-DITTRICH, Richard, Direktor der städtischen Handelsschule in Saaz. Saaz. VACLAVICEK, Johann, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Chrudim. Chrudim. VARMUZA, Johann, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz. Prossnitz. VEPS, Wenzel, Professor an der k. k. Böhmischen Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Giskrastrasse 38. VERZAN, Armand, Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Jakominigasse 108. VIERTHALER, August, Direktor der Handelsschule in Görz. Görz, Corso Francesco-Giuseppe 25. WÄCHTER, Wilhelm, Supplent an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Kremenetzgasse 17. WATZKE, Alfred, Professor an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handels- akademie in Brünn. Brünn, Gomperzgasse 12. WAWRUCH, Rudolf, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Prossnitz Prossnitz. WEHNER, Alfred, Direktor der städtischen Handelsschule in Lustenau. Lustenau. WEIDINGER, Paul, Eisenbahninspektor und Lehrer an der Privat- handelsschule Glasser. Wien II, Rueppgasse 7. WEIL, Hugo Dr., Advokat. Prag, Lazarusgasse 17. 30 WEIGT, Herkules, wirklicher Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Krakau. Krakau, Staszica 6. WEINGARTNER, Dr. Josef, wirklicher Lehrer an der Kaiser-Franz-Josef- Pilsen. Deutschen. Handelsakademie in Pilsen. WEISS, Arthur, kaiserlicher Rat, Dozent an der Exportakademie. Wien IX, Berggasse 32. WEISS, Ritter v. Wellenstein, Gustav Dr., kaiserlicher Rat, Handels- kammerrat, Wien. Wien. WEISS, Maximilian, wirklicher Lehrer an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Langegasse 2. WENGER, Dr. Karl, wirklicher Lehrer an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz, Felix-Dahn-Platz 2. WERNER, Wilhelm, Bürgerschuldirektor und Professor an der Gremial- handelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien XIX, Döblinger Hauptstrasse 44. WERTHEIMER, Wilhelm, Handelsschuldirektor in Prag. Prag. WESSELY, Karl, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Linz. Linz, Feldstrasse 20. WEYDE, Julius, Direktor der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie, Mitglied der österreichischen Repräsentanz. Wien VIII, Hamerlingplatz 6. WOHANKA, Josef, Ritter v., Herrenhausmitglied, em. Handelskammer- präsident, Prag. Prag. WIEDENHOFER, Georg, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handels- schule in Schwaz. Schwaz. WOLF-ZDEKAUER, Dr. Karl Freiherr v., Bankier. Prag, Rittergasse 28. ZALOZIECKI, Roman, k. k. Professor an der Handelsakademie Lemberg. Lemberg, Skarbekgasse. ZECHBAUER, Franz, Sparkassebeamter, Lehrer an der Handelsschule des Wiener Frauen-Erwerbvereins, Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VII, Zieglergasse 39. ZEEMANN, Anton, Lehrer an der Neuen Wiener Handelsakademie. Wien V, Wienstrasse 28. ZEIDLER, Leopold, wirklicher Lehrer an der Handelsakademie Aussig. Aussig. ZENKER, Franz, Professor an der Prager Handelsakademie. Prag, Klemensgasse 26. ZENS, Mathias, Bürgerschuldirektor, Abteilungsvorstand und Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien VIII, Josefstädterstrasse 99. ZICKERO, Franz, Professor an der Gremialhandelsfachschule des Wiener Handelsstandes. Wien IX, Sensengasse 8. ZIEGLER, Dr. Artur, Professor an der Handelsakademie in Reichenberg. Reichenberg, Paulsdorfergasse 3. ZIEGLER, Julius, k. k. a. o. Professor an der Exportakademie, I. Schrift- führer der österreichischen Repräsentanz, Redaktor der „Österr. Handels- Schulzeitung". Wien XII, Schönbrunnerstrasse 188. ZIMMER, Wilhelm, wirklicher Lehrer an der schlesischen Handelsschule in Troppau. Troppau. ZINGG, Eugen, Lehrer an der k. k. Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Handelsakademie in Brünn. Brünn, Scheffelgasse 20. ZITTE, Ferdinand, wirklicher Lehrer an der städtischen Handelsschule Schwaz. in Schwaz. ZÜGNER, Friedrich, Bankbeamter und Lehrer an der Privathandelsschule Glasser. Wien VII, Neustiftgasse 18. 31 - Belgien. Kollektivmitglieder: Belgique Membres collectifs ASSOCIATION DES LICENCIÉS SORTIS DE L'UNIVERSITÉ DE LIÈGE, Rue Pont d'Avroy, 21, Liège. Président: M. Béthune, CERCLE POLYGLOTTE, Place de l'Hôpital, 4, Huy. CERCLE POLYGLOTTE ET D'ÉTUDES COMMERCIALES, Rue Trappé, 6, Liège. CERCLE DES ANCIENS ÉTUDIANTS DE L'INSTITUT SUPÉRIEUR DE COMMERCE D'ANVERS. M. Plouvier, Trésorier, Rue Osy, 26, Anvers. CHAMBRE DE COMMERCE. M. Liebaert, Trésorier, Ostende. CHAMBRE DE COMMERCE D'ANVERS. M. Ch. Corty, président. Local de la Bourse, Anvers. CHAMBRE DE COMMERCE DE BRUXELLES, Union syndicale. M. Monnoyer, président, Bruxelles. COURS DE LANGUES DU SYNDICAT GÉNÉRAL DES VOYAGEURS, EMPLOYÉS ET PATRONS, Rue Jennart, 24, Bruxelles. COURS COMMERCIAUX ET DE LANGUES DE LA SOCIÉTÉ MUTUELLE DES EMPLOYÉS, Rue de la Fourche, 40, Bruxelles. COURS GRATUITS DE STÉNOGRAPHIE, Association Sténographique unitaire de Belgique, Rue du Marché, 59, Bruxelles. COURS COMMERCIAUX ET DE LANGUES, „ENGLISH CLUB“, Rue Savaen, 27-29, Gand. COURS DE COMMERCE ET DE LANGUES DU SYNDICAT GÉNÉRAL DES VOYAGEURS, EMPLOYÉS, NÉGOCIANTS ET PATRONS, M. J. de Tiège, Trésorier du Syndicat, Rue Félix Wodon, 36, Namur. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Braine-le Comte. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Bruges. Secrétaire-trésorier: M. De Caluwé, Hôtel-de-Ville. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Palais du Midi, Bruxelles. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Charleroi. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Châtelet. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Chênée. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Dour. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Fontaine-l'Evêque. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Frameries. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Gand. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Huy. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Jumet. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, La Louvière. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Leuze. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Louvain. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Morlanwelz. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Seraing. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Soignies. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Tournai. ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE, Wasmes. Directeur M. Schmit, à la Villa Mathilde à Cuesmes. ÉCOLE NATIONALE d'Horlogerie, d'Electricité et de petite Mécanique, Palais du Midi, Bruxelles. ÉCOLE PROFESSIONNELLE ET ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE DE COURTRAI, M. L. de Geyne, directeur, Courtrai. I 32 ÉCOLE PROFESSIONNELLE D'ARMURERIE DE LIÈGE. M. Ch. Francotte, président de la Commission administrative, Liège. ÉCOLE SUPÉRIEURE COMMERCIALE ET CONSULAIRE DE MONS. Directeur: M. Van Caenegen, Grand'Place, Mons. ÉCOLE SUPÉRIEURE de Commerce annexée à l'Institut St-Ignace. Directeur M. Serigiers, Anvers. ÉCOLE DES HAUTES ÉTUDES COMMERCIALES ET CONSULAIRES. Directeur: M. Lecoq, Liège. ÉCOLE DES SCIENCES COMMERCIALES ET CONSULAIRES, ANNEXÉE A L'UNIVERSITÉ CATHOLIQUE. Directeur: M. Brants, Louvain. ECOLE SUPÉRIEURE DES TEXTILES, Verviers. FÉDÉRATION DES ASSOCIATIONS COMMERCIALES ET INDU- STRIELLES LIÉGEOISES. Secrétariat: Place Ste-Véronique, 4, Liège. INSTITUT SUPÉRIEURE DE COMMERCE, Anvers. INSTITUT COMMERCIAL DES INDUSTRIELS DU HAINAUT. Directeur: M. E. Jottrand, Mons. MUSÉE PROVINCIAL ET ÉCOLE INDUSTRIELLE SUPÉRIEURE. Directeur: M. Omer Buyse, Charleroi. SOCIÉTÉ INDUSTRIELLE FT COMMERCIALE, Verviers. SYNDICAT BELGE DES COMPTABLES. Trésorier: M. L. Crauwels, Longue rue Neuve, 107, Anvers. SYNDICAT GÉNÉRAL DES VOYAGEURS, EMPLOYÉS, NÉGOCIANTS ET PATRONS, Rue St.-Jacques, Dinant. UNIVERSITÉ LIBRE DE BRUXELLES. ECOLE DE COMMERCE SOLVAY (Membre permanent), Bruxelles. Membres individuels ALBERTI, G., Négociant, Ans-lez-Liège. VON BARY, Albert, Consul général d'Italie, Anvers. DE RYCKE, Théophile, Supérieur du collège de la Ste.-Vierge, Termonde. DESCHAMPS, Fernand, Docteur en droit, Professeur à l'Institut supérieur de Commerce d'Anvers, à Reeth-lez-Boom. DUBOIS, Directeur de l'Institut supérieur de Commerce d'Anvers, Aivers. DUTRIEUX, Henri, Ingénieur en chef, Directeur de service aux chemins de fer de l'État, Président de la Commission administrative de l'Institut Commercial des Industriels du Hainaut, Mons. ECKELS, Pierre-Joseph, Professeur à l'Institut supérieur de Commerce Rue Albert von Bary, 4, Anvers. .. . . . Einzelmitglieder: FAGNART, E., Professeur à l'Université de Gand, Place des Gueux, 9, Bruxelles. FRANCOTTE, ancien Ministre de l'Industrie et du Travail (Président d'honneur), Place du Luxembourg, Bruxelles. GADEYNE, Rodolphe, Directeur des cours de la Société Mutuelle des Employés. Bruxelles. GILIS, J.-Hubert, Expert Comptable et Directeur de l'Institut de Compta- bilité et de Finances, Rue Traversière, 49, Bruxelles. GOSSUIN, Georges, Rue de la Halle, 21, Mons. LAMBILLIOTTE, Alphonse, Professeur à l'Institut Commercial des Indu- striels du Hainaut, Correspondant du Travail, Rue des Belneux, 14, Mons. LEFÈBVRE, L., Président de la Chambre syndicale des Comptables, Rue du Parc, 67, Liège. Rue du Bailly, 68, Bruxelles. MAISTRIAUX, Valdor, Professeur, 33 1 MAWET, E., Secrétaire de la Commission administrative de l'École des hautes Études Commerciales et Consulaires de Liège, Rue Fabry, 12, Liège. MICHOTTE, P., Professeur au Collège Saint-Pierre, Louvain. MOREAU, Léon, Professeur à l'Athénée Royal, Arlon. ORBAN, Professeur à l'Université, Rue Basse-Wez, 26, Liège. PLOUVIER, Prosper, Professeur à l'Institut supérieur de Commerce, Rue Osy, 28, Anvers. ROMBAUT, Eugène, Inspecteur général de l'Enseignement industriel et professionnel (Président d'honneur), Rue des Drapiers, 15, Bruxelles. SCHUCHARD, Alfred, Négociant, Anvers. SOLVAY, Ernest, Industriel, Rue des Champs-Elysées, 43, Bruxelles. STEVENS, Jean, Directeur général de l'Enseignement industriel et pro- fessionnel au Ministère de l'Industrie et du Travail, Rue de la Loi, 19, Bruxelles. STRAUSS, Louis, Négociant, Président du Conseil supérieur de l'Industrie et du Commerce de Belgique, Boulevard Léopold, 114, Anvers. WAROCQUÉ, Raoul, Député, Industriel, Bourgmestre de Morlanwelz, Château de Mariemont. WAUTERS, Paul, Ingénieur, Inspecteur principal au Ministère de l'In- dustrie et du Travail (Membre d'honneur), Bruxelles. J Bulgarie Membre individuel YABLANSKY, D. M., Canada Membre collectif ÉCOLE DES HAUTES ÉTUDES Bulgarien. Einzelmitglied: Sofia. Kanada. Kollektivmitglied: COMMERCIALES DE MONTRÉAL, Montréal. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: BÉIQUE, H. A., avocat, 216, Place d'Armes, New York Life Building, Montréal. CONTANT, J., ancien président de la Chambre de Commerce et membre du Conseil d'administration de l'Ecole des Hautes Etudes commerciales de Montréal, 439, rue Berri, Montréal. DE BRAY, A. J., Directeur de l'École des hautes Études commerciales de Montréal, Square Viger, Montréal. FYEN, A., directeur de l'Ecole polytechnique (Université Laval), 467, rue Berri, Montréal. LARIVIÈRE, F. C., négociant, vice-président de la Chambre de Commerce, 448, rue Berri, Montréal. LEBLOND DE BRUMATH, principal de l'Académie commerciale catholique, 85, rue Ste-Catherine Est, Montréal. MERCIER, Honoré, Membre du Parlement, secrétaire trésorier du Conseil d'administration de l'École des hautes Études commerciales, Montréal. 3 1 34 PRÉFONTAINE, Isaie, Président de la Chambre de Commerce et Président du Conseil d'Administration de l'École des hautes Études commerciales, Montréal. SMITH, Chs. F., ancien échevin et membre du Conseil d'administration de l'Ecole des Hautes Etudes commerciales de Montréal, 78, rue Durocher, Montréal. Danemark Membres collectifs GEMEINSCHAFTLICHER AUSSCHUSS DER HANDELSVEREINE IN DEN PROVINZEN. Sekretariat: Fredericksborggade 31, Kopenhagen. HANDELS- UND KONTORISTEN-VEREIN, Kongens Nejton 6, Kopenhagen. KOMITEE DER SOCIETAT DER GROSSKAUFLEUTE, Börsen, Kopenhagen. VEREIN FÜR AUSBILDUNG JUNGER KAUFLEUTE, Fiolstrade 50, Kopenhagen. Espagne Dänemark. Kollektivmitglieder: Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: KAALUND, R., Kaufmann, Kgl. schwed. und norweg. Konsul, Kolding. MÖLLER, Herm., Justizrat, Direktor der Aalborg Handelskole og Handels institut, Aalborg. MÖLLER, H. L., Dr., Unterrichtsinspektor für die dem Staate unterstellten Handelsschulen, Fiolstrade 44, Kopenhagen. PETERSEN, Holger, Grosskaufmann, Mitglied der innern Kammer des Reichstages, Kobmagergade 44, Kopenhagen. Etats-Unis Spanien. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: LINARES, Paul, Hto S. Basilio, Cordoba. PLIAZ DE LA VEGA, Ant., Secrétaire et Professeur de l'École supérieure de Commerce de Séville, Rue Lepanto 5, Sevilla. RODRIGUEZ y APARICIO, Cristeto, Camara de Comercio, Cordoba. VILLEGAS, Eduardo, Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, Valladolid. Vereinigte Staaten. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: ADAMS, Henry C., Professeur à l'Université de Michigan, Aun-Arbor, Michigan. COFFIN, C. W. D., Editeur de livres commerciaux, Washingten Square, 100, New-York City. CRAWFORD, William C., Master, Washington Allston Schooldistrict, Boston (Mass.). DAVIS, Allan, Directeur de l'Institut supérieur de Commerce, D. C. Washington. ELLIS, B. Carlos, Département Commercial de l'Ecole supérieure, Springfield (Mass.) L I 35 FUY, W. W., Collège libre commercial et financier, Philadelphie. GAINES, Clement E., Président de la „Eastman School,“ Poughkeepsie, New-York. HEALEY, G. Horace, Editeur du „Penmans Artistic Journal“, Broadway, 202, New-York City. HERRICH, Cheesmann A., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure centrale, Philadelphie. JAMES, John N., Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure, KEASBY, Lindley M., Professeur, Collège (B.) Bryn-Maur. LEHMANN WENDELL, Busines man, Box 83, Tacoma, Wash. LORD, Geo P., Directeur de l'Ecole commerciale de Salem Salem (Mass.). MILLER, Chas. M., Directeur de l'Ecole commerciale Miller, Broadway 1133, New-York City. OSBORN, A. S., Directeur de l'Institut de Commerce de Rochester, Rochester (New-York). PERSON, H. S., Amos Tuck, Director and Professor of Commerce and Industry, School of Administration and Finances, Hanover, N. Hampshire. SCHOCH, Parke, Directeur du Département du Commerce et des Finances, Institut Drexel, Philadelphie. SCOTT, Dr. William A., Directeur de l'Ecole de Commerce, Université de Wisconsin, Madison. SHEPPERD, James J., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, New-York City. SPRINGER, D. W., Directeur du Département Commercial de l'Ecole supérieure, Michigan, Aun-Arbor. THOMSON, Frank V., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, Boston (Mass.). Finlande Wisconsin, West Superior. THURBER, Dr. Chas. H., Editeur Expert. Beaconstreet, 29, Boston (Mass.). WEAVER, Herbert S., A. M. Head master. Girl High School of practical Boston (Mass.). Arts. YOUNG, James T., Directeur de l'Ecole Wharton, Université de Pennsilvania, Philadelphia, Pa. Membres collectifs Finnland. Membres individuels JÄRVINEN, Kyösti, Direktor des Handelsinstituts der finnischen Kauf- mannschaft, Helsinki. LINDEQUIST, Directeur de l'Institut de Commerce, Abö. France Einzelmitglieder: Frankreich. Kollektivmitglieder: ASSOCIATION FRANÇAISE POUR LE DÉVELOPPEMENT DE L'EN- SEIGNEMENT TECHNIQUE, INDUSTRIEL ET COMMERCIAL, 28, Rue Serpento, Paris. CHAMBRE DE COMMERCE, Bordeaux. CHAMBRE DE COMMERCE, 2, Place de la Bourse, Paris. 36 ÉCOLE SUPÉRIEURE DE COMMERCE ET D'INDUSTRIE, 66, Rue St-Sernin, Bordeaux. ÉCOLE SUPÉRIEURE DE COMMERCE, Boulevard François Ier, Le Havre. SOCIÉTÉ ACADÉMIQUE DE COMPTABILITÉ, 92, Rue Richelieu, Paris. UNION DES ASSOCIATIONS DES ANCIENS ÉLÈVES DES ÉCOLES SUPÉRIEURES DE COMMERCE RECONNUES PAR L'ÉTAT, 15 et 17, Rue Auber, Paris. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder AUDEMAR, Henri, Ingénieur, Inspecteur de l'Enseignement technique, Dôle (Jura). 1 AUTIN, A., pharmacien, 3, rue de la Mariette, Le Mans. BAZIN, Charles-François, Professeur à l'Ecole pratique de Commerce, Charleville (Ardennes). BERNHEIM, Paul, Négociant, 65, rue de Miromesnil, Paris. BISCH, Ernest, Secrétaire général de l'Union des Associations des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, reconnues par l'Etat, Rue de Lafayette, 157, Paris. BLONDEL, Dr. G., Professeur au Musée social, et à l'Ecole des Hautes Etudes commerciales, 31, Rue de Bellechasse, Paris. BOSSU, Henri, Négociant, ancien Président de l'Association des anciens Élèves de l'École de Commerce, Vice-président de l'Union des Asso- ciations des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, 5, Rue Coq-Héron, Paris. BOUETTI & Co., J.-B., Chaussée d'Autin, 12, Paris. BOUCHET, Rédacteur au Ministère du Commerce, ancien Secrétaire de l'Association amicale des anciens Élèves de l'École supérieure de Com- merce, Rue du Lycée, 76, Sceaux. BRAILLON René, Négociant, Vice-Président de l'Association des anciens Élèves de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce de Paris. Membre du Comité de l'Union des Associations, Rue de Château-Landon, 28. Paris. BURNIER, Sébastien-Louis, Directeur de l'École des hautes Études Com- Ruc de Tocqueville, 43, Paris. merciales, CAZAUX-MOUTOU, Jean-Marie, Industriel, Lourdes. CHALOT, Négociant, Rue de Stockholm, 4, Paris. CHAMBARD, Arthur, Ingénieur, Inspecteur de l'Enseignement Technique à Auxerre (Yonne) et à Paris, Rue de Constantinople, 8. CHATEL, Maurice, Négociant, Membre du Comité de l'Union des Asso- ciations des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, Rue du Quatre-Septembre, 2, Paris. COLAS, Pierre-Alphonse, Graveur-Imprimeur, Rue Sedaine, 32, Paris. COMBES, Adrien, Directeur de l'École supérieure de Commerce, Rue de Paradis, 148, Marseille. CONZA, Antoine, Négociant Exportateur, Rue Meslay, 59, Paris. COQUENTIN, Alfred, Professeur honoraire de l'Institut Commercial à Paris, Boulevard Riondet, 8, Hyères (Var.). CORMOULS-HOULÈS, Edouard, Industriel, Docteur en droit, Conseiller du Commerce extérieur de la France, Inspecteur départemental de l'En- seignement technique, Mazamet (Tarn.). DARTEVELLE, Louis, Mandataire aux Halles, Membre du Comité des Associations des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, Rue Française, 4, Paris. 37 DELAPORTE, René Edgard, Directeur de la Section commerciale annexée au Gymnase Panchypion, Nicosie (Chypre). DELOMBRE, Paul, Ancien Ministre du Commerce et de l'Industrie, Prési- dent de l'Union des Associations des anciens Élèves des Ecoles supé- rieures de Commerce de France, Rue de Monceau, 89, Paris. DOAT, Henry L. J., Ingénieur civil, 428, Rue des Vennes, Liège (Belgique). DUFOURCQ-LAGELOUSE, Léon, Banquier, Vice-Président de la Société. Académique de Comptabilité, 69, Rue d'A'msterdam, Paris. DUJARDIN & Co, Ingénieurs Constructeurs, Rue Brûle Maison, 82, Lille. FALCK, Félix, Membre du Comité de l'Union des Associations des anciens élèves des Écoles supérieures de commerce, Avenue de la Grande Armée, 49, Paris. FAURE, Gabriel, Arbitre au Tribunal de Commerce de la Seine, Rue de Berne, 35, Paris. FOUCQUIER, Amedée, Agent général de la Compagnie des Mines d'Aniche, Membre du Comité de l'Union des Associations des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, Boulevard Magenta, 124, Paris. GADRAS, Léon, Professeur à l'École pratique de Commerce, Rue Montjoli, 17, Charleville (Ardennes). GIRON, Achille, Rentier, Rue de Metz, 38, Nancy. GUZEL, Michel, Membre du Comité de l'Union de l'Association des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, Rue Treilhard, 4, Paris. HUMBLOT, Firmin, Professeur de Comptabilité, Rue Guersant, 12, Paris. JEANNE-JULIEN, Georges, Administrateur de sociétés, Trésorier honoraire de l'Union des Associations des anciens élèves des Écoles supérieures de commerce, Rue Demours, 5, Paris. KIRSCHBAUM, Catherine, Directrice de l'École pratique de Commerce et d'Industrie de Jeunes Filles, Rue du Lycée, 130, Le Havre. LANGLOIS, Godfroy, Journaliste, 58, Avenue Laval, Montréal (Canada). LEBLANC, Joseph, Expert-Comtable, ancien Secrétaire général de la Société Académique de Comptabilité, Professeur d'Economie Politique, de droit Commercial et de Comptabilité, Rue des St.-Pères, 40, Paris. LEBOIS, Claude, Inspecteur général de l'Enseignement Technique, Place Fourneyron, St.-Etienne. LEMOINE, Georges, Professeur de Comptabilité, Administrateur de la Société Académique de Comptabilité, Rue Trousseau, 15, Paris. MARANDE, Ch.-Auguste, Rue Saint-Roch, 13, Le Havre. MARCHAL, J., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, 56, Boulevard François Ier, Le Havre. MARTIN, Paul, Expert-comptable, Directeur de la Revue des Sciences commerciales. 110, Boulevard de la Corderie, Marseille. MAXWELL, Sam., Avocat à la Cour d'Appel de Bordeaux, Secrétaire général de la Société Philomatique. Rue Vital Carlos, 44, Bordeaux. MERCKLING, François-Joseph, Directeur de l'École supérieure de Commerce et d'industrie de Bordeaux. 66, Rue Saint Sernin, Bordeaux. MORTIER, Raoul, Professeur à l'École national professionnelle, Vierzon. MÜLLER, Alfred, Conseiller du Commerce extérieur de la France. Membre du comité de l'Union des Associations des anciens Élèves des Écoles supérieures de Commerce, Secrétaire général de l'Association nationale pour l'étude des langues étrangères, 15, Rue de Téhéran, Paris. PARENT, Louis, Ingénieur, Rue de la Pompe, 1, Paris. 1 38 PATHIER, Achille, Manufacturier, ancien Président de l'Association ami- cale des anciens Élèves de l'École supérieure de Commerce de Paris, Membre du comité de l'Union des Associations. Rue de la Huchette, 13, Paris. PENOT, St-Cyr, Directeur de l'École supérieure de Commerce. Rue de la Charité, 34, Lyon. PFEIFFER, Bernard, Expert, ancien fourreur-pelletier, Boulevard St-Germain, 280, Paris. PLOUSSU, G., commerçant, 6, rue Lafayette, Grenoble. RENOUARD, Alfred, Ingénieur, Président honoraire de l'Association des anciens Élèves de l'École supérieure de Commerce, Membre du Comité de l'Union des Associations des anciens élèves des Ecoles supérieures de Commerce, Rue Mozart, 49, Paris. ROUX, F., Directeur de l'Ecole nationale professionnelle, Vierzon, Cher. SAIGNAT, Léo, Professeur à la Faculté de Droit, Président du comité permanent des Congrès de l'Enseignement technique. Rue Mably, 18, Bordeaux. TARAVANT, M., commerçant, 38, rue des Jeuneurs, Paris. TELLIÈRE, Négociant, Vice-Président honoraire de l'Association amicale des anciens Élèves de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, 12, Avenue de l'Isle, Villiers sur Marne (Seine et Oise). URWILLER, Auguste, 16, Rue Littré, Paris. Grèce Griechenland. Membre collectif Kollektivmitglied: CHAMBRE HELLÉNIQUE DE COMMERCE, Alexandrie (Égypte). Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: COCHET, Anatole, Professeur à l'École publique de Commerce. Rue Solon, 7, Athènes. CONSTANTINIDES, Polybius J., Professeur à Limassol (Cypern). KAOS, Jacques, Professeur à l'Ecole de commerce, KYTARIDOS, Nicolas, professeur à l'Ecole de commerce, PANAYOTOPOULOS, Constantin, Directeur de l'École commerciale du Pirée. Rue de Notara, 41, Le Pirée. PAPACOSTAS, Hercules, directeur de l'Ecole de commerce, PAPAZECHARIAS, directeur de l'Ecole de commerce, RAZIS, Dr. G., directeur de l'Ecole de commerce, RHOUSOPOULOS, Dr. O. H., Directeur de l'Académic de l'Industrie et du Syra. Volo. Corfou. Commerce. Corfou. Corfou. Athènes. Patras. SPORIDES, Michel, professeur à l'Ecole de commerce, STÉPHANOS, Cyparissos, Professeur à l'Université nationale, Directeur de l'École publique de Commerce, Secrétaire générale de la Société bio- technique hellénique. Athènes. ZYGOURAS, Th.-H., directeur de l'Ecole de commerce du Gouvernement, Patras. 39 : Hollande Holland. Membre collectif Kollektivmitglied: NATIONALE VEREENIGING VOOR HANDELSONDERWYS, Amsterdam. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder. BOISSEVAIN, Ch. E. H., Industriel, Trésorier de la National Vereeniging van Eeghenstr. 92, Amsterdam. BOS, Dr. P., Négociant, Directeur de la Banque hypothécaire. voor Handelsonderwys. Winschoten. HULSMANN, J. H. H., Jun. Dr. Willemsparkweg, Amsterdam. KRÜLL, A. C. F., Rotterdam. ODINK VAN T’HUL, Jean H., Membre du Comité directeur de l'Association nationale pour l'Enseignement commercial. Amsterdam. TJEENK-WILLINK, Dr. P., Advokat. Ged. Oude. Gracht, 90-92, Haarlem. VAN DEN BERG, Dr. N. P., Président de la Banque des Pay-Bas. Amsterdam. WITVLIET, M. M., Professeur et Rédacteur de la Revue „Het Handels- onderwys", Nassaukade, 127, Amsterdam. YSSEL DE SCHEPPER, Dr., Directeur de la Fabrique royale de bougies, Gouda. Hongrie Ungarn. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: BERGER, Léon, Direktor der Produktiv - Tischler - Genossenschaft, K Tarnopol. BRICHT, Léopold, Professeur et Secrétaire de l'Académie Commerciale, Alkotmany utcza, 11, Budapest. GOCKLER, Dr., Ludwig, Professor an der Handelsakademie, Kismezö-ùtca, 7, Kolozvàr. KANITZ, Dr., Ludwig, Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce de M. Aranyosi, Budapest. KARPATI, Bela, Professor der höhern Handelsschule, Mesterutcza, 27, Budapest. KOVATS, Dr. Jean Alexander, Directeur de l'École de Commerce, Nagyvarad. KRBECK, Arnold, Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce, Brasso. KRISCH, Eugen, Professor der staatlichen höheren Handelsschule, Veszprem. KUNOS, Dr. Ignaz, Directeur de l'École orientale de Commerce, Kalmanngasse, 6, Budapest. MITTELMANN, Ferdinand, Professor an der höhern Handelsschule, Lipot Kornt, 16, Budapest. RÖSER, Dr. Joh, Direktor der höhern Handelsschule, Aradi utcza, 10, Budapest. ROTH, Dr., Philippe, professeur à l'Ecole sup. de commerce, Szombathely. SCHACK, Dr. Bela, Professor, Generalinspektor der höheren Handels- Lipot Kornt, 16-IV-26, Budapest. schulen, 3 40 SZUPPAN, W., Direktor der Handelsakademie, kgl. Rat, Budapest. TRAUTMANN, Heinrich, Professor an der Handelsakademie, Akot Mani utcza II, Budapest V. VLAICU, Arseniu, Direktor der höhern Handelsschule, Kirchenzesle, 6 Brasso. Italien. Italie Membres collectifs Kollektivmitglieder: ASSOCIAZIONE FRA INDUSTRIALI, COMMERCIANTI ED ESERCENTI. Président: M. le Chevalier Camillo Franco, Livorno. CAMERA DI COMMERCIO ED ARTI, Piazza della Borsa, Napoli. SCUOLA SUPERIORE DI STUDI APPLICATI AL COMMERCIO, Torino. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: BESTA, Fabio, Professore alla Scuola superiore di Commercio, Venezia. CASTELLI, Giuseppe, Professore, Direttore dell' Insegnamento industriale e commerciale nel Ministero di agricoltura, industria e commercio, Roma. CASTELNUOVO, Cav., Direttore della Scuola superiore di Commercio, Venezia. FROLA, S., Membre du Parlement, Président du Musée royal italien, Turin. GAGLIARDI, Enrico, Professore alla Scuola superiore di Commercio, Genova. LANZONI, Professeur, Président de l'Association des anciens Étudiants de l'École royale supérieure de Commerce, Venise. MANZATA, Renato, Professore alla Scuola superiore di Commercio, Venezia. MASSA, Carlo, Direttore della R. Scuola superiore di Commercio, Bari. MORELLI, Enrico, Comm., Professore nel R Istituto tecnico, Via del Tritone, 46, Roma. Palazzolo sull'Oglio (Brescia). Palazzolo sull'Oglio (Brescia). NIGGELER, Giovanni, fabricant, NIGGELER, Ernesto, fabricant, RIGOBON, Pietro, Professore alla Scuola superiore di Commercio, Venezia. SABBATINI, Dr., Recteur de l'Université Commerciale, Luigi Bocconi, Milano. SCHMIDT, G., Négociant, Via Gallo, 2, Milano. VANDEY, Antoine-D., professeur de français à l'Université commerciale Viale Trotter, 2, Milano. VIMERCATI, Guido, Professore, Direttore della Scuola media di studi applicati al Commercio, Via San Lorenzo, 26, Firenze. L. Bocconi, Japan. Japon Membres individuels NASA TADAYNKI, Professeur, Tokio. TAKIMOTO, Josio, École supérieure de Commerce, Tokio. FUKUDA, Dr. Tokuso, Professeur à l'Université libre Keio-Gijuku, Tokio. Einzelmitglieder. 1 41 Norvège Membres collectifs BÖRSE IN CHRISTIANIA (Ständiges Mitglied HANDELSGYMNASIUM, Christiania. Norwegen. Kollektivmitglieder: Membre permanent). Membres individuels AARS, Jens, Konsul, Handelsgymnasium, ANDERSEN-AARS, Konsul, Bankdirektor, BACKER, Georg, Oberlehrer, Handelsgymnasium, BJERCKE, Alf., Grosskaufmann, BJÖRNSTAD, Kr., Bevollmächtigter, Handelsgymnasium, ADA — Einzelmitglieder: BOMMEN, Alf., Grosskaufmann, BORNHOFF, K., Bankdirektor, DAHL, Erling, Handelslehrer, Handelsgymnasium, DUBORGH, W., Konsul, DUE, Reidar, Börsenkommissär, Börse, FLEISCHER, Eiler, Grosskaufmann, HENRIKSEN, Gustav, Kontorchef, LARSEN, J. Haldor, Konsul, PLATOU, E., Professor, Inspektor am Handelsgymnasium, POLACZEK, E., Professor, Direktor des Handelsgymnasiums, SIMONSEN, E., Chemiker, Handelsgymnasium, SCHNITLER, C. J., Direktor des Handelsgymnasiums Bergen, TUFTE, S. A., Professor am Handelsgymnasium Bergen, Roumanie Men d Rumänien. Einzelmitglieder: Christiania. Russie Russland. Membres collectifs Kollektivmitglieder: HANDELSINSTITUT NABILKOW, Paul Awrorin, Moskau. KOMITEE DER BÖRSE ZU PERNAU, Pernau. KOMITEE DER BÖRSE ZU REVAL, Reval. PETERSSCHULE DER PETERSBURGERKAUFMANNSCHAFT, ་ RAF F F F F F £2 t. }} "" " " "1 >> "" Bergen. Membres individuels COLTOFEANU, J., Commerçant, Galatz. HRUBES, Stefan, Docteur en droit, licencié en sciences commerciales et consulaires. Strada Carol I, 38, Bucharest. MUNTEANU, J. G., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, Galatz. NEAGU BOERESCU, Licencié en sciences commerciales et consulaires, Calea Victorici, 21, Bucarest. NEAMTZU, C., Directeur de l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, Chef comp- table de la Banque Nationale. Craiova. NICOLAU, Emanoil J., Komercoficisto, Str. Decebal, 5, Bucarest. RADULESCO - STROITZA, Dr., chef du service des informations et des publications au Ministère du Commerce et de l'Industrie, rue Polona, 138, Bucarest. SIMIONESCU, Nae, Commerçant et industriel, Calea Victorici 53, Bucarest. TEODORESCU, A. V., Commerçant, Vice-président de la Chambre de Com- merce. Braïla. "9 " Fontanka, 62, St. Petersburg. 42 Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: AJSPURIT, A., Tchvinskaja 10, log. 1, Moscou. DEHIO, Erhard, Negoziant, Vizepräsident des Komitees der Börse zu Reval, Reval. FAIG, Heinrich, Gründer des Handelsinstituts, Odessa. S. E. DE FISCHER, Max, wirkl. Staatsrat, (Stiftendes Mitglied), Inspektor des Unterrichtswesens am Handels- und Industrie-Ministerium, Kazanskaïa, 5, St. Petersburg. GOUSSOW, Victor, Inspektor der Handelsschule, Crementchoug. KLACZKO, Max, Kandidat der Handelswissenschaften, Schemenstrasse 19, Riga, į KONATZKY, Ivan Grigoriewitsch, Kaufmann. Persp. Newsky, 173, St. Petersburg. KORZLINSKII, Nikolao, Sredniaia Kislovka, dom Volkov, Moscou. S. E. KÖNIG, Jos., wirkl. Staatsrat, Direktor der Handelsschule St. Anna Kirotschnaja Uliza, St. Petersburg. KRUTSCHKOFF, Ivan Semenowitsch, Staatsrat. Tschernichoff Pereoulok, 18-20, St. Petersburg. KYLIUS, Théodore, Präparator an der Handelsschule Faig. Torgowaja, 7, Odessa. MICHELSOHN, L., Stud. der Handelsswissenschaften. Ellenbogenstr. 6, Libau. MIRTSCHINK, Théodore, Staatsrat, Professor an der Moskowitischen Schule der Handelswissenschaften. Moskau. MITTELSTEINER, E., Staatsrat, Direktor der Realschule bei der evang.- Odessa. luther. St. Pauls-Kirche. S. E. MOREW, Demetrius, wirkl. Staatsrat, a. D., Gorodichsche-Orlowez, Gouvern. Kiew. PARUN-SARKISSOW, Alex., Sekretär des Kollegiums, Professor am Handels- Tiflis. institut von Tiflis. STEPANOV, Sergius, Regierungsrat, Ministerium der Volksaufklärung. St. Petersburg. STRECKER, Arnold, in Firma Tillmanns & Co., Baku. STRÖHM, Arthur, Chef der Firma Kluge & Ströhm, Reval. STÜRMER, Victor, Staatsrat a. D., Insel Wassiliewsky. Grande Perspective, St. Petersburg. SWATOSCH, Jaroslaw, Staatsrat, Inspektor des Handelsinstituts von Tiflis. Tiflis. SZABUNIEWICZ, Stanislaw, Mjasnickaja, domo de Keppen 3, Moscou. TILLMANNS, E., Kommerzienrat, Quai de l'Amirauté, 6, St. Petersburg. WOLFF, Adolf, Markowitsch, Redaktor, Newsky 64, St. Petersburg. ZAGERSKY, Professor am Polytechnikum von Sosnowka, St. Petersburg. Serbie Serbien. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: BAJLONI, Ignjat J., Brasserie, firme Bajloni & Sinovi, Belgrade. VULETITCH, Marco, Négociant, Chef de la firme: Vuletitch & Garrilovitch. Belgrade. 43 Suède Schweden. Membres collectifs · HANDELSHÖGSKOLAN (Université commerciale), HANDELSINSTITUT, Göteborg. INSTITUT COMMERCIAL FRANZ SCHARTAU, Stockholm. MALMÖ HÖGRE HANDELSINSTITUT, Malmö. Kollektivmitglieder: " Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder: AHLSTRÖM, Dr. A., Directeur de l'Institut de Commerce. Victoriagatham 22, Gothembourg. AXELSON, Henrik, Membre de la Direction de l'Union Suèdoise des Em- ployés, Président de Direction du Musée Commercial, Président du Comité de l'Union générale Suédoise pour les Intérêts du Commerce. p Brunkebergstorg, 2, Stockholm. 24, Swartmangatan, Stockholm. BERGSTRÖM, Chr., Directeur de la Banque Commerciale, Président de la Direction de l'Institut de commerce. Gothenbourg. BOHMAN, Knut, Négociant, Consul du Brésil, Membre de la Direction de l'Institut Franz Schartau, Sturegatan, 22, Stockholm. CRONLUND, John, professeur à l'Institut de commerce, Gothenbourg. HARTVIG, Herman, Négociant, Membre de la Direction de l'Institut com- mercial de Gothenbourg. Gothenbourg. HERDIN, Dr. E., Directeur de l'Institut supérieur de commerce, Helsingborg. HOLM, Imri, Professeur à l'Institut de commerce, Gothenbourg. KEY, Dr. Helmer, Rédacteur du „Svenska Dagbladet", Stockholm. KÖNEMANN, C., Professeur à l'Institut supérieur de commerce, Helsingborg. LAMM, Herm., Négociant, Brunkebergstorg, 24, Stockholm. LOFSTRAND, Victor, Professeur à l'Institut de commerce, Gothenbourg. MELIN, Olof, Négociant, Djursholm (par Stockholm). MUNTHE, Ake W., Directeur de l'Institut Commercial Franz Schartau, Stockholm. NORDENSKJÖLD, Otto, professeur à l'Université, Gothenbourg. NORDENSKJÖLD, Thure, Directeur de l'Institut supérieur de commerce, Malmö. NORDFELT, Dr., A., membre du Conseil supérieur de l'enseignement, ins- pecteur des écoles de commerce, Stockholm. RAMM, Axel, Chef du Bureau Municipal de Revision, Secrétaire de l'Union de la Bourse. Gothenbourg. SMITH, Dr., Stilleryd b. Karlsham. SOMMELIUS, Matte, Directeur, Président du Conseil municipal, Président de l'Institut supérieur de commerce, Helsingborg. SVENSON, J., Directeur de la Caisse d'épargne, Helsingborg. WALLENBERG, Marcus, (Ständiges Mitglied), Directeur de la „Stockholms Enskilda Bank" Stockholm. WALLER, J. A., négociant, Membre de la Direction de l'Institut com- Gothenbourg. mercial, WARN, P. C., négociant, membre de la Direction de l'Institut commercial, Gothenbourg. < 44 Suisse Schweiz. Membres collectifs Kollektivmitglieder: AARGAUISCHE HANDELSKAMMER (Aargauischer Handels- und Industrie- Verein). Aarau. SCHWEIZERISCHER HANDELSLEHRERVEREIN, (Präsident: Rektor Balsiger) Bern. ASSOCIATION DES PROFESSEURS DE L'ECOLE SUPÉRIEURE DE COMMERCE, Lausanne. BASLER HANDELSKAMMER, Basel. BERNISCHER VEREIN FÜR HANDEL- UND INDUSTRIE, Sektion Biel, Biel. K CHAMBRE DE COMMERCE DE L'UNION VAUDOISE DU COMMERCE ET DE L'INDUSTRIE, Lausanne. DIPARTIMENTO Di PUBBLICA EDUCAZIONE DEL CANTONE TICINO, Bellinzona. DIREKTION DES INNERN DES KANTONS BERN, Bern. ÉCOLE DE COMMERCE, Chaux-de-Fonds. ÉCOLE DE COMMERCE DE LA VILLE DE NEUCHATEL, Neuchâtel. ECOLES SUPÉRIEURES DE COMMERCE, D'ADMINISTRATION ET DE CHEMINS DE FER DU CANTON DE VAUD, Lausanne. ÉCOLE SUPÉRIEURE DE COMMERCE DE JEUNES FILLES, Fribour g EIDGENÖSSISCHES HANDELSDEPARTEMENT, Bern. HANDELSABTEILUNG DER HÖHERN TÖCHTERSCHULE, Zürich. INDUSTRIE-VEREIN ST. GALLEN, St. Gallen. INSTITUT DR. SCHMIDT, St. Gallen. KANTONALE HANDELSSCHULE BASEL, Basel. KAUFMÄNNISCHER VEREIN ST. GALLEN, St. Gallen. SCHWEIZERISCHE GESELLSCHAFT FÜR KAUFM. BILDUNGSWESEN (Association suisse pour l'enseignement commercial), Zürich. SCUOLA CANTONALE DI COMMERCIO, Bellinzona. TÖCHTER-HANDELSSCHULE BERN, Bern. UNTERRICHTSKOMMISSION DES KAUFMÄNNISCHEN VEREINS BASEL, Basel. UNTERRICHTSKOMMISSION DES KAUFMÄNNISCHEN VEREINS LUZERN, Luzern. VEREIN SCHWEIZ. GESCHÄFTSREISENDER, Zentralvorstand, Bern. VORORT DES SCHWEIZ, HANDELS- UND INDUSTRIEVEREINS, Zürich. Membres individuels Einzelmitglieder. ADDOR, Marius, Av. Juste Olivier, Lausanne. AMAUDRUZ, Ch., Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, Avenue Ruchonnet, Lausanne. AMMANN, G., Danzas & Co., Mitglied der Zürcher Handelskammer, Zürich II. BACHMANN, Dr. G, Professor der Handelswissenschaften an der Univer- Winterthur. sität Zürich. BÆHNI, Eugène, Fabrikant, Biel. BELLENOT, Gustave, Dr., Professeur à l'Ecole de Commerce. Evole, 15, Neuchâtel. BERGER, Edouard, Directeur de l'Ecole de Commerce, Neuchâtel. BERNET-HANHART, Theophil, Rektor der Kantonalen Handelsschule. Klosbachstrasse 73, Zürich V. 45 S BERTA, G. Dr., Professor an der Handelsakademie, St. Gallen. BLANC, Ch., professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Lausanne. BLASER, Adolphe, Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce. Avenue Druey, 13, Lausanne. BLASER, Ed., professeur à l'Ecole de commerce, Chaux-de-Fonds. BOLLE, J. H., Professor an der Kantonalen Handelsschule, Zürich. BRATSCHI, R, Oberstlicutenant, Präsident der kantonalen bern. Handels- und Gewerbekammer. Alpenstrasse 19, Bern. BRIOD, Henri, Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce. Avenue de la Harpe, Lausanne. CADISCH, J., Handelslehrer am städtischen Gymnasium. Effingerstrasse 57, Bern. CENTURIER, F., Professor am Seminar Wettingen und an der Schule des Kaufmännischen Vereins Baden. Baden. COSTA, Cesare, Sprachlehrer, Wil (St. Gallen). COULON, Louis, Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce. Pontaise, Villa Mont Blanc A, Lausanne. DECKER, Paul, Professeur à l'Ecole de Commerce. Route d'Echallens, 87, Lausanne. DELESSERT, Camille, Directeur des Postes, Lausanne. DELLEY, M., professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de commerce pour jeunes filles, Avenue de Villars 11, Fribourg. DIEM-SAXER, E., Kaufmann, St. Gallen. DUCLOUX, E., Stadtrat, Schuldirektor, Luzern. DUDDLE, Ad., Sekundarlehrer, Wyl. DUTTWEILER, Max, Dr., städt. Finanzsekretär, Neptunstr. 45, Zürich V. EBERLI, Henri, Professor an der Kant. Handelsschule. Schanzenberg 3, Zürich I. ERNST, Ulrich, Dr., Professor an der Kantonsschule, Blatterstrasse 21, Zürich V. FAVRE, J., professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Lausanne. FLURY, W., Professor an der kantonalen Handelsschule. Vereins Zürich. Seefeldstr. 108, Zürich V. FUCHS, Friedrich, Hauptlehrer an der Handelsschule des kaufmännischen Treichlerstrasse 5, Zürich. GAILLE, Charles, Studiendirektor des Instituts Dr. Schmidt, St. Gallen. GEERING, T. Dr., Sekretär der Basler Handelskammer, Basel. GENOUD, Léon, Directeur de l'École des Arts et Métiers, Fribourg. GEORG, Alfred Dr., Conseiller National, Secrétaire de la Chambre de Genève. Commerce. GERN, Julien, Directeur de l'École de Commerce, Ithaque (Grèce). GLAUSER, Ch. Dr., Officier de l'Instruction publique, Professor an der Schelleingasse 23, Wien. GLÜCKSMANN, Dr., Direktor der Akademie der Handelswissenschaften. Postgasse 68, Bern. Wiener Handelsakademie. GOBAT, Ch. A., Conseiller National, Berne. GELDI, G., directeur de l'Académie de commerce, Lausanne. GRAESER, Louis, Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce. Les Clochetons, Route de Morges, Lausanne. GROGG-KÜENZI, M., Handelslehrer an der höhern Töchterschule, Reichensteinerstrasse 78, Basel. HALDI, Adolf, Bücherrevisor der Schweiz. Nationalbank, Zürich. 46 } HEDINGER, O. Dr., Lektor der Handelswissenschaften an der Hochschule Aarau. Bern und Handelskammersekretär. HIRT, A, Professor an der Handelsabteilung der Kantonsschule, Aarau. HIRTER, J., Nationalrat, Kaufmann, Gurtengasse 3, Bern. HONOLD, Otto, Kaufmann, Winterthur. JACCARD, H. A., professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de commerce, Chailly, Lausanne. JACOT-COLIN, Louis, Professeur à l'École de Commerce, Le Locle. JUNGI, H., Sekundarlehrer, Rektor der Handelsschule des kaufmännischen Vereins. Langenthal. JUNOD, A., Abteilungssekretär für das kaufmännische Bildungswesen am eidgenössischen Handelsdepartement. Bern. KELLER, A., Dr., Lehrer an der Mädchensekundarschule, Basel. KISTLER, C., Handelslehrer, Villa Ab-Yberg, Schwyz. KUMMER, Dr., Handelslehrer am kaufmännischen Verein, Luzern. KÜNZLE, E. Dr., Handelslehrer an der Handelsschule des kaufmännischen Gemeindestr. 26, Zürich. Vereins Zürich. LEUZINGER, Heinrich, Zollikon. MANUEL, P., Directeur de l'École d'Ingénieurs. Rue Beau Séjour, 22, Lausanne. MAREL, Ed., Professeur, Avenue d'Echallens, 83, Lausanne. MARIANINI, Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce, Les Ruches, Avenue du Servan, Lausanne. METRAUX, Aug., Kassier der Handelsschule des kaufmännischen Vereins, Schöller, Chessex & Co., Schaffhausen. MEYER, Eduard Erwin, Verlagsbuchhändler, Aarau. MORF, Léon, Directeur de l'École supérieure de Commerce. Place Chauderon, 3, Lausanne. MOTTAZ, E., Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce, Les Tonnelles, Route d'Echallens, Lausanne. NEF-KERN, Kaufmann, St. Gallen. NERFIN, Négociant, Aubonne. NESSI, Em., Direttore della Banca popolare, Lugano. NIEDERER, A., Handelslehrer des kaufmännischen Vereins. Promenadengasse 14, Zürich V. OLIVETTI, T. G., Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce. Villa Espérance, 25, Place Chauderon, Lausanne. PAILLARD, Dr. G., professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de commerce et à l'Université de Neuchâtel, rue Neuve, 9, Lausanne. PERRELET, B. Dr., Professeur à l'École de Commerce. M Passage St-Jean, Neuchâtel. PERRET, C., instituteur, Avenue de Morges, 24, Lausanne. PETITPIERRE, Ed., Professeur à l'École supérieure de commerce. Avenue des Alpes, Lausanne. PYTHON, M.-J., Conseiller d'État, Directeur de l'Instruction Publique du canton de Fribourg. Fribourg. RAPIN, W., Professeur à l'École supérieure de Commerce. Les Rossinières, Avenue Ruchonnet, Lausanne. RENZ, Dr., Hugo, Professor an der Kantonalen Handelsschule, Dornacherstrasse 9, Basel. REYMOND, Fritz, Nég., Vice-Président de la Chambre de Commerce, Bienne. RICHARD, E., Oberst, Sekretär der Zürcher Handelskammer. Börsenstrasse 21, Zürich. 47 Magdal ROSEN, Ch., commerçant, rue Numa Droz, 171, La Chaux-de-Fonds. ROSSI, R. Dr., Direttore della Scuola cantonale di Commercio, Bellinzona. ROTZETTER, J., Professeur au Collège St-Michel. Place du Collège, 15, Fribourg. ROULIN, A., Professeur à l'Ecole superieure de commerce, Lausanne. RUSS-SUCHARD, Charles, Fabricant, Neuchâtel. RUSS-SUCHARD & Co., Fabrique de Chocolat, Serrières près Neuchâtel. SCHÄRTLIN, G. Dr., Direktor der Schweiz. Lebensversicherungs- und Rentenanstalt. Alpenquai 40, Zürich II. · SCHERRER, Roman, Fabrikant, Luzern. SCHEURER, Frédéric, Directeur de l'École de Commerce, Chaux-de-Fonds. SCHINDLER-HUBER, Dietrich, Direktor der Maschinenfabrik Örlikon A.-G., Hohenbühlstrasse, Zürich V. Mitglied der Handelskammer. SCHMUTZ-PERNAUX, F. G., Direktor des Instituts „Erika“. Wangen an der Aare. SCHNEIDER, H., Dr., Prorektor der Kantonalen Handelsschule, Zürich. SCHRAG, A. Dr., Sekundarschulinspektor, Rabbental, Bern. SCHREIBER, O., Handelslehrer an der höhern Töchterschule. Universitätsstrasse 21, Zürich V. SCHUDEL, Hans, Professor an der Handelsabteilung der Kantonsschule, Chur. SCHULZE, Ed. O., Dr., Rektor der städt. Handelsakademie. Dufourstrasse 32, St. Gallen. SCHURTER, Joh., Rektor der Handelsabteilung der höhern Töchterschule. Gerechtigkeitsgasse 19, Zürich I. SIGG, D., Directeur des Cours de la Société suisse de commerçants. Porrentruy (Berne). SOHRMANN, Julius, Francesco Camponovo & Cie., La Nationale". ** Chiasso. SPRENG, A., Lehrer an der Töchterhandelsschule, Bern. STADLER, J., Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce. Belles Roches, 11, Lausanne. STÄHLI, R., Rektor der Handelsschule des Kaufmännischen Vereins. Kurvenstrasse 23, Zürich IV. STEIGER, J., Dr. jur., Redaktor, Dufourstrasse 11, Bern. STUDER, J., Lehrer an der Töchterhandelschule, Bern. SYZ, John, Präsident des Schweiz. Spinner-, Weber- und Zwirner-Vereins. Thorgasse 4, Zürich. TSCHUMI, Albert, Professeur à l'Ecole de Commerce. Plan Perret, 6, Neuchâtel. TURMANN, Max, Dr., Professeur à l'Université, Directeur de l'Ecole Fribourg. supérieure de Commerce de jeunes filles. VOLLENWEIDER, Dr., Otto, Riedtlistrasse 34, Zürich-Unterstrass. VULLIEMIN, Ch., ancien Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce. Belles Roches, 1, Lausanne. WÄCKERLIN, Rud., Lehrer an der Mädchen-Sekundarschule, Vogesenstrasse 29, Basel. WALDBURGER, E., Vize-Direktor der Schweizerischen Kreditanstalt, St. Gallen. WALDNER, Paul-G., Professeur à l'Ecole de Commerce, Chaux-de-Fonds. WALTER, A., Professeur à l'Ecole supérieure de Commerce, Lausanne. WEISS, Heinr., jun., zur Gerbe, Affoltern a. A. 48. WENGER, K., Dr., Professor an der k. k. Handelsakademie in Graz. Graz. WICK, W., Vorsteher der Kantonalen Handelsschule, Redaktor der Schweiz. Zeitschrift für Kaufmännisches Bildungswesen. Burgfelderstr. 23, Basel. WIDEMANN, René, Dr. jur., Vorsteher von Widemanns Handelsschule. Kohlenberg 13, Basel. WOLF, J., commerçant, rue du Parc, 130, La Chaux-de-Fonds. Turquie Membre individuel Einzelmitglied. NOUCAS, Thomas, professeur et sous-directeur à l'Ecole pratique de commerce Etienne Noucas, Salonique. Récapitulation Membres Juillet 1910 Allemagne Deutschland Angleterre England Argentine Argentinien Autriche Österreich Belgique Belgien Bulgarie Bulgarien Kanada Canada Danemark Espagne- Etats Unis M P M ▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬ ▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬ Make ▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬▬ • Dänemark Finlande Finland. France Frankreich Grèce Griechenland Hollande Holland . Hongrie Ungarn Italie Italien. Japon Japan. Norvège Norwegen Roumanie Rumänien Spanien. Russie Russland Serbie Serbien Suède Schweden Suisse Schweiz Turquie Türkei Vereinigte Staaten • • • • • · · Türkei. Rekapitulation. Collectifs • 18 21 18 1 1 4 7 1 HH 1 col col 3 1 4 1 4 15253 Total 139 Individuels 68 15 1 370 27 1 9 4 4 24 2 59 12 9 16 16 3 18 9 25 2 24 116 1 835 Total 86 15 1 391 75 1 10 8 ++*&B!! 4 24 2 66 13 10 16 19 3 20 9 29 2 28. 141 1 974 1009 HE P18 The Philadelphia Commercial Museum ; Foreign Trade Bureau The Philadelphia Commercial Museum A brief account of the organization and methods of the institution, and an outline of the services its Foreign Trade Bureau renders to American exporters The Commercial Museum 34th Street below Spruce Philadelphia The Philadelphia Museums The corporate name of the municipal mu- seum system of Philadelphia is the "Philadelphia Museums". It is designed to develop this system into a group of allied museums similar in character to those maintained by the city of London. The first to be established in this group is the Commercial Museum. The work of this institution is conducted by two administrative divisions: (1) the Scientific Department having charge of install- ing and maintaining the exhibits and conducting the educational work carried on for the schools of Philadelphia and Pennsylvania; and (2) the Foreign Trade Bureau, which conducts that portion of the Museum's work designed to make the Museum's facilities available to manufacturers throughout the country in the extension of their export trade. The Commercial Museum is located in three public buildings constructed for the Museums in West Philadelphia. These have a floor area of over 200,000 square feet which may be doubled when required. The second floor of the North Building is occupied by the executive offices, library and Foreign Trade Bureau; while the first floor of this building and all of the other two buildings are reserved for the exhibits now in place or to be installed. 2 671-41 Phila, Comm. Reclass, 12-18-27. E.R, THE Methods of the Commercial Museum HE Commercial Museum is controlled by a Board of Trustees composed of prominent citizens of Philadelphia, who hold office by appointment, and eight ex-officio members, including the Governor of Pennsylvania, the Mayor of Philadelphia, the Presidents of the two branches of the Philadelphia City Councils, the President of the Philadelphia Board of Public Educa- tion, the Superintendent of Schools, the State Superin- tendent of Public Instruction, and the State Forestry Commissioner. The executive head of the institution is the Director, W. P. Wilson, Sc. D. Under his personal supervision the exhibits in the Museum are installed, and the work of the Foreign Trade Bureau is conducted. The chief sources of revenue for the institution are appropriations from the city of Philadelphia and the state of Pennsylvania. The Foreign Trade Bureau makes a small annual charge to members using its facili- ties, but all the money received from this source is 3 applied directly to conducting the Bureau's work and enlarging and building up its equipment. This makes it possible for the Bureau to render service which fre- quently represents an actual outlay greater than the return received from the subscriber. The public character of the institution of which it is a part, has made it undesirable for the Foreign Trade Bureau to advertise itself in this country as it would be necessary and entirely proper for a private institution to do. But this very feature, which makes the Bureau less well-known at home, has made it possible for it to become better known abroad than a private enterprise could be under any circumstances. Its public character, as an institution devoted exclusively to the building up of American export trade, has made friends for it in com- mercial and official circles and has opened to it channels of information which are closed to any private enterprise. Operating in this way it is impossible for it to serve any private ends or to work with any attempt at gain or profit. 4 Aid to American Exporters I N the following pages will be found a statement of the methods employed by the Foreign Trade Bureau in its efforts to help American ex- porters establish and conduct a profitable foreign business. The Bureau is doing a work which, according to those who are familiar with it, is not to be matched anywhere for practical value and efficiency. The system by which this work is done is the result of more than a decade of practical experi- ence with the single work of promoting the interests of American exporters, and making the contact between the reliable exporter in this counry and the trustworthy buyer of American goods in other countries more intimate and direct. Being unlike anything else in existence, this system is difficult to describe in a few words. All that can be attempted is a summary of a few of the main features. 5 How the Foreign Trade Bureau Works THE HE service rendered by the Foreign Trade Bureau falls under a few general heads, although every ef- fort is made to adapt the service to the require- ments of the individual subscriber. Thus, while the service rendered to no two members is identical, the privi- leges offered by the Bureau to its subscribers come under the three main classifications: (1) Publication service, (2) Information service, and (3) Translation service. I. The Publication Service comprises a system of pub- licity and printed commercial information. There are two regular publications, COMMERCIAL AMERICA, a monthly paper for circulation in foreign countries, and the WEEKLY BULLETIN, a confidential pamphlet circulated among the subscribers to the Bureau. These two publications together are designed to stimulate an interest on the part of foreign buyers in American goods on the one hand, and to convey to American exporters live and timely information concern- ing foreign markets on the other. It is believed that this combination of two papers covers the export information. 6 field, so far as it can be covered by periodical printed f matter, in a much more thorough and systematic manner than can be done by any single publication. 2. The Information Service depends for its value, to each subscriber, very largely upon the ability of the member to ask specific questions. Among the subjects most commonly covered by the members' questions are: Reports on foreign market conditions, details of shipment, packing, invoicing, routing, etc.; amount and method of collection of customs duties, commercial travelers' license taxes, and other dues; foreign collection and payment methods; lists of reputable foreign houses handling spe- cial lines; foreign agents, their proper location and intelligent selection; the general character and business methods of foreign houses; practical advice and help in securing the payment of bad or slow foreign debts. This list, however, suggests only a few of the lines covered by this service. · 3. The Translation Service is designed to put at the command of members the Bureau's corps of thor- oughly equipped translators, for translating foreign letters into English or English letters into foreign languages. Arrangements have been made also for translating circu- lar and catalogue matter at rates lower than can ordina- rily be secured for such work. Some American exporters can afford to maintain their own translation departments, but the number that can do this economically is relatively small. The facilities offered by the Bureau for this work have proved to be very satisfactory to the members. 7 Publication Service Tw WO publications issued regularly by the Foreign Trade Bureau of the Commercial Museum for the benefit of its subscribers are COMMERCIAL AMERICA and the WEEKLY BULLETIN. COMMERCIAL AMERICA is a monthly publication de- signed for circulation among foreign buyers of American goods and prepared with a view to conveying information of interest and value to any one desiring to build up trade with this country. THE WEEKLY BULLETIN is a confidential publication issued every Saturday to the subscribers to the Bureau. It is a compact pamphlet, containing inquiries for Ameri- can goods received from abroad; general news items such as statistical matter, changes in tariff, trademark or pat tent laws, travelers' regulations, etc., and grouped busi- ness suggestions, notes on trade openings and lists of new undertakings abroad offering a chance for the sale of American goods. 8 A Spanish edition of COMMERCIAL AMERICA will be published for circulation in Latin-American coun- tries beginning with the July, 1910 number; the English edition will continue to be circulated in all other parts of the world. Information and Translation Services THE HE material gathered by the Foreign Trade Bureau during the fourteen years that it has been in opera- tion includes reports on the general character of over 300,000 foreign houses. These are being revised and added to constantly by information received from resident and traveling correspondents of the Bureau. A large number of American manufacturers have found that their foreign business can best be handled through local agencies established in well-selected dis- tributing centers. The Bureau's reports are daily being used for supplying information making possible the intel- ligent selection of such agencies, aiding not only in the choice of the agent, but the point of distribution as well. These reports are also continually doing good service in saving needless loss from the contracting of bad accounts. Special inquiries from members, on whatever sub- ject, are given prompt answer from the information in hand whenever possible, or when this cannot be done, from reports on the subject secured from the Bureau's correspondents abroad. Foreign inquiries for American goods are promptly forwarded to manufacturers who are considered likely to be interested, and in this work members, of course, are given preference. Many requests are received from foreign buyers for lists of names of American manufacturers of special lines of goods. Connections established as a direct outcome of these inquiries have frequently resulted in large re- turns in the way of profitable business. 9 The Translation Department, operated as one feature of the work of the Foreign Trade Bureau, has established a reputation for efficiency and promptness. Members are not charged for the translation of their regular busi- ness correspondence, including the rendering into Eng- lish the letters received in foreign languages, and the putting into foreign languages of outgoing letters. One member, testifying to the efficiency of this department, writes: "Your translations are promptly rendered and we really could not do without this feature." The Bureau is frequently asked to undertake the translation of catalogues and circular matter. While the demands of the regular service make it impossible to do this work in the institution, the Bureau will undertake the general supervision of such translations, putting the material into competent hands, overseeing it, and giving it revision by expert commercial translators. 302 IO Question of Efficiency TH HE foregoing pages have been a rough and incomplete outline of how the Foreign Trade Bureau is organized and what it aims to do. Space does not allow a full description of the details of the systems of collecting, revising and sending out information which have been developed during the life of the institution. Such details, while they might have more or less interest, are, after all, not vital to the present or prospective users of the service. The main question with the exporter is not "How does it work? but "How well does it succeed in doing the work it attempts"? The best answer to this is found in the opinions of those who have applied to it the business-like measure of EFFICIENCY. II Does the Bureau Stand the Test? Information Service Manufacturing Chemists Our firm, as you know, is actively developing its export busi- ness, and we find the information furnished by the Philadelphia Museums of the greatest value. 1st. In furnishing the names of reliable firms to act as agents and distributors of our products. 2d. In furnishing accurate information on trade conditions. 3d. In furnishing information as to the products needed as well as the countries at the present time supplying the market. Your services are practical and satisfactory. H. K. MULFORD COMPANY. Makers of Shaving and Toilet Soaps The Commercial Museum gives us data which we would not know how to get elsewhere. THE J. B. WILLIAMS COMPANY. Makers of Oil Well Supplies The services rendered us by you in this connection have always been so concise and, so far as we have been able to determine by comparison with information from other sources, so correct, that it affords us much pleasure to make a statement to that effect. We might also add that the service has been exceedingly prompt. OIL WELL, SUPPLY COMPANY. Makers of Typewriters We have made use of your services in many different ways, many times to such an extent that we have almost wondered if we were not imposing upon you, but the results have always been in every way entirelv satisfactory to us. FOX TYPEWRITER COMPANY. 12 Makers of Ink, Typewriter Supplies and Stationers' Specialties We cannot refrain from complimenting you on the accurate and thorough way you have handled all of our inquiries, and when the wide range these included is considered, the service in its complete- ness is most remarkable During the past year we have taken occasion to write several of our correspondents in this country of your organization, and we will gladly allow you to use our name as a reference for the effi- ciency and worth of the services of your various departments. THE CARTER'S INK COMPANY. Dealer in Gums and Resins For efficient service, prompt response to inquiries and thorough- ness of attention to detail, we have never had in nineteen years of business dealings with commercial institutions, a connection which has been more pleasing, reliable and satisfactory than the connection we have maintained for some years with your good selves. WILLIAM H. SCHEEL. Translation Service Machinists and Brass Founders We rely upon the Translation Department for our correspond- ence in foreign languages and have, in several instances, been com- plimented by our foreign customers upon writing their language so perfectly, which is, of course, due to the efficiency of your translators. REMINGTON MACHINE COMPANY. Makers of Street Lamps We ship our "Sun" lamps to all parts of the world and the care- ful and correct translation of our foreign correspondence to and from our foreign patrons in various required languages by your Transla- tion Department is in itself worth much more than the annual membership fee. SUN VAPOR LIGHT COMPANY. Makers of Blotting Paper We have been subscribers to your Museum for a number of years and have found your work practical and efficient. For translating, which has been the greater part of your service to us, you are prompt and accurate and always obliging. We have a great deal of this work and have found your services to be entirely satisfactory. ALBEMARLE PAPER COMPANY. 13 CONVINCIAL AMONGS Heller Brothery Nay Ba 10/ 31 The rowhe CLASSIFIED ADVER MENTS LUBRICATING DI Fo LOWAY SHOOK Bel Gebo Tango Ny GENERAL MADRY MARITICAL AVER Nene TANK FAR MORE INGESTED GRAND COMP Tu B WWWONA ANDINA TWARA Filter COMMERCIAL AMERICA PONGAA AMMONIA Anhydr in and Agda ON SANE K 1988 PORARIO MNITY BY THE MACK SOUM INDEX TO BUSNESS CARIS Cloebrow AMOR COMMERCIAL AMERICA The circulation of "Commercial America" is among a selected list of foreign concerns in a position to buy American goods and pay for what they buy. The reading matter is prepared with the foreign reader constantly in mind. Each issue is designed to leave him with an active interest in American goods as they apply to his own line of trade. The business cards and the display advertising pages are designed to show him the shortest way to satisfactory purchases. 14 A Spanish edition of COMMERCIAL AMERICA will be published for circulation in Latin-American coun- tries beginning with the July, 1910 number; the English edition will continue to be circulated in all other parts of the world. Manufacturers of Shoe Blacking It is with great pleasure that we assure you our advertisement in Commercial America" has been of advantage to us, as it has been the cause of many inquiries and has put us in direct communication with firms selling our commodities; which is essential to any adver- tising medium. 46 We appreciate the willingness and promptness with which you have furnished us and answered information as to prospective cus- tomers and conditions in the countries that are reached by your pub- lication. Makers of Malleable Iron Goods If there is any satisfaction in your knowing that some of your undertakings are meeting with signal success we wish to put in our word especially concerning your monthly journal Commercial America," in which we have had a quarter-page advertisement for five years and a half. JAMES S. MASON COMPANY. The large number of inquiries coming to us from all parts of the globe is evidence that you have extended your field of usefulness and that your journal actually reaches firms all over the world. THOMAS DEVLIN MANUFACTURING COMPANY. " An American Firm of Manufacturing Chemists Through the medium of "Commercial America, Commercial America," under the de- partment" Agents Wanted," we have recently succeeded in placing an agency for our in Norway and Sweden, and are in correspondence with several other people for agencies in Colombia, S. A.; Spain, and the Island of Cuba and we are very well satisfied with our investment if we get nothing more than mercial America." " Com- A General Importer in Berlin " We take esteemed pleasure in renewing our subscription to your valuable paper Commercial America," which we find of much interest and value owing to the complete information which it con- tains about your great country. " An Importing House in Vienna I have been handed a copy of a paper which it is stated you pub- lish under the title of Commercial America." As it is exceedingly valuable to me will you please state how I can receive regular copies. 15 Tas saphat MICRON J TAK MANCERAPIGA submisijai pem MA 100% t $ the same word put beway the ph be The 15 at ✰✰ 304 <GALAR- *3+PRIN 2047430) - เศษ Amer Mat POPE IPELAINE Fund were brein IIS BETTIE IN I look BROS MORSE ARM LABORION QUADRE поверить Red Lines All aut · < M "Hamburg-American Lie (finu, FREDNE PORODIDEAS no malaking har arbetare a way Tote bags by hypoge kot Son York Presen. Mutang Prabang pag ar pana in the theater on the market tears ~ MA 1107016 (52 +44 +44 best mugh } y 1 sd, at wo is t bes* *** *** Street art tot 95D IN SAFE MAGING, barak why air Prav 8 109 1 " OPLATNA C I have is ing on an try band CAM, 24 " A mappi, 100 flasped a Pepsiren, i all as year by Is Martin B6, the FORENT ASETE YVONO ERFURTER, - Ân cho kh A PLANE Ao *** 10% br $ha que he betrayan bh about hogy váng anh 1. ah pregrad, met 206-4 was 3, mp4 beset water tre Jul _*), 1980. Jubang 4. Help Bathshen Bryanera, mehed, the shop son with tours, the wine" Apolo ONT WHEELING THAT more than for Yo Now b 7 Y A M BRIPS wome 蟹 Avibn Balduin & Co. CHÍNH THẦN THÁNH ) - n th c JANI Kuu Vanče DANG BAS POSING OROBANKS Əngapi dinar on babi seenage Brak, PurẢnh 1 đề Manu së baras Kangra men puthet DE SUN A 00, wd 3 the best and by thether "BEGINS. baker tape SAP 440 VJETRA KRAGONAIR { # 400, Amat ! AVA BAR 1, + [/m² By ARIT VL, BRE pas vrata falgar jatt, SODAN Z N vimal, digh Sad » Van, stel. – 2021 apa danh từ năm thứ này gây vous and, dat va viden angle, sheer va 100 myrna verga Vegan durende Boeker JevtSA ved dog, Marth dem at bite than Nguncha song peni qurdu. D gaben. Det magnesi aikana na mene RA ĐI LÀ la ca Van Road Test, Your Sant Berhard by Jo permite da for bus har ft phare Sp metal. Ja, igo báť pondebin sveida ja Vente d'unmann in Sand, prin anggeng The Game Antony The Charbus, la dev ▸ No Nuts Anato MAX CO FERMIT SALIVES-APGA. Dunkel men sputada vee to Day" WARRAN Nate poma all p de bote k to manage made durum, Yarat, if fetalen i na Jandarmekatwater bir SACOLA DONANIMA I MAWg matha, Amiga ja ta Evans Are ( mundiain menu modelpu JONA MORE PUB kabel gruppement & Pet PA > Autor, we \\@gmatika ta At PRODDA PEKAL SEK2000) me. Notakosť dohcbds. The Emera Vauban dung, there is mutat 1 an Ka Han vil bunch, button, vi Fokokter blade, sevsner be babes be a man, OK ME A A verwerth of the tela, Me Anabbt heat Agre ___", " Gadg DE THE WEEKLY BULLETIN OF THE PHILADELPHIA COMMERCIAL M - Page Led by and the same (n) Pub by any budem in the date ngers, tad de su se med den Part X www boy wewn NOVIN • Yan KOPEL BANKA MODRO A WIDE NDAJ Appa A BULLETIN OF FOREIGN TRADE, INFORMATION PUBLISHED EVERY SATURDAY urbo 90% deale ·kg meme be the PROČ PERAJALAREK zawektu ezern OF ONELA, NIVEST ww · bg Don't move any streden y say kong I LAL No a NAPRA TÊN N ka irm A A Vannes * 1300 VAKE A bat va ana bang néant hi nghe đang tinh bột nghệ ng Na anne vannet ble JAPA • Set un mot meh ww pr 19 yo meta woman MA, MG, MOČINA, Đi một mai gia nghiên vg KČ VŠ vaND wow energ HỤ N Chaan pene - kaw na pang padat • Jum For me DWYE am, por alg SARA Set za v ACA That MA, MO Mart bank Suna shen, Pink, wpł A MADE Dď v pe PR AE POČE V www A *^* Ajvar Shop Moder (aka pale waren, bagnataka, vt per PARA {1 ANÝJAR V JANGAN MEGANGEN, MD) V Sym has all hadde sth. Pu → 11 } THE WEEKLY BULLETIN This confidential weekly circulated among subscrib- ers to the Bureau service contains more live information for exporters than any other publication issued in this country. Among its regular features are: 1. A list of inquiries received for American goods. 2. A list of trade suggestions and opportunities gath- ered from sources not available to other publi- cations. 3. A group of export news of vital interest. 4. A list of mail and freight sailings for the month. 16 As will be seen from this list of features, it is the purpose of the "Weekly Bulletin" to give to the export- ing manufacturer each week, in condensed form, just such information as will enable him to make the best possible use of such foreign connections as he already has, and at the same time form reliable new ones. Below will be found some plain statements of how this work appeals to those for whom it is done: Makers of Firearms and Bicycles We find your "Weekly Bulletin" of a special interest and the use of many items in same has given us very satisfactory results. IVER JOHNSON'S ARMS AND CYCLE WORKS. Manufacturers of Ice and Refrigerating Machinery "The Weekly Bulletin" gives us valuable information and we have made it a practice to carefully follow all inquiries for ice-inaking and refrigerating machinery, which is our special line. In several cases we are able to trace orders directly from this source, and, no doubt, other business has come to us for which you are entitled to the credit. REMINGTON MACHINE COMPANY. Manufacturers of Shoes The publications of the Museum are a source of benefit to us and we have often found suggestions therein very useful. THE GEORGE E. KEITH COMPANY. Makers of Gas Lamps The Weekly Bulletin" of trade opportunities, with a list of in- quiries for goods or catalogues, together with the sailing dates of vessels from Philadelphia and New York is continually valuable. THE WELSBACH COMPANY. W 17 Commercial Library TH HE Commercial Library of the Museum is probably the most complete, strictly commercial library in the world. Full commercial statistics are received regularly from practically every country which issues them at all. Some of these sets of commercial statistics were never available in this country until the Museum was es- tablished. They furnish a valuable source of information on foreign trade movements, making possible a good first-hand knowledge of the character and sources of for- eign purchases. In addition to these there are being re- ceived at all times official reports and private works on commercial subjects. Consular reports in full sets from American, British, Austrian, French, Belgian and other consuls throughout the world are received as issued, and the library contains an unusual collection of the best and most recent works of travel and description. The Museum is a depository for all United States Government publications on commercial and industrial subjects. In the library there is a collection of tariff schedules 18 of every country in the world and these are corrected and kept up-to-date by means of information received through a number of official and other sources. The library of commercial directories mentioned elsewhere, covers practically every commercial center in the world and represents a very remarkable collection of books of this character. These directories include not only the standard city directories of the principal com- mercial centers but also a number of directories of trades and industries. In connection with this department of the work there has been established a catalogue library, and all members are urged to see that this library is supplied with their latest catalogues both in English and in foreign languages. The leading trade, industrial and commercial peri- odicals published in the United States and in foreign countries are regularly received and filed in the library, where they may be referred to at any time. The current matter, whether statistical or periodical, is kept on the shelves of the main reading room, and the more important of the superseded material is filed for reference in the stack room, which has a floor area of over 7,000 square feet. The facilities which this library affords for collating reliable and up-to-date information concerning foreign markets, are unequalled by the equipment of any other institution in this country. Difficult questions of both fact and opinion concerning commercial matters are con- stantly being answered by reference to this library for inquirers in all parts of the country. 19 The Philadelphia Museums 34th Street below Spruce Philadelphia BOARD OF TRUSTEES EX-OFFICIO THE GOVERNOR OF PENNSYLVANIA. THE MAYOR OF PHILADELPHIA. THE PRESIDENT OF SELECT COUNCIL. THE PRESIDENT OF COMMON COUNCIL. THE PRESIDENT OF THE BOARD OF PUBLIC EDUCATION. THE SUPERINTENDENT OF SCHOOLS. THE STATE SUPERINTENDENT OF PUBLIC INSTRUCTION. THE STATE FORESTRY COMMISSIONER. BY APPOINTMENT DANIEL BAUGH, WILSON H. BROWN, THEODORE N. ELY, W. W. FOULKROD, ELLIS A. GIMBEL, SIMON GRATZ, OFFICERS OF THE BOARD W. S. HARVEY, President. CHARLES F. WARWICK, Vice-President and Counsel. W. S. HARVEY, WILLIAM W. SUPPLEE, WM. T. TILDEN, CHARLES F. WARWICK, W. P. WILSON, SYDNEY L. WRIGHT. DANIEL BAUGH, Treasurer. WILFRED H. SCHOFF, Secretary and Assistant Treasurer. EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE WILLIAM W. SUPPLEE, Chairman. THEODORE N. ELY, W. S. HARVEY. DANIEL BAUGH, WILSON H. BROWN, DIRECTOR OF THE MUSEUMS-W. P. WILSON, SC.D. CURATOR-CHARLES R. TOOTHAKER. LIBRARIAN-JOHN J. MACFARLANE. CHIEF OF THE FOREIGN TRADE BUREAU--DUDLEV BARTLETT. 20 HF NOV 9 1918 ބ 1009 P18 i REGULATIONS GOVERNING Steel Distribution CHICAGO FROM WAREHOUSES Excerpts from Supplement No. 2 to Circular No. 4 JOSEPH T. RYERSON & SON NEW YORK ST. LOUIS DETROIT REGULATIONS GOVERNING STEEL DISTRIBUTION FROM WAREHOUSES The following are excerpts from Supplement No. 2 to Circular No. 4 of the War Industries Board, Priori- ties Division, issued October 15th. The portions here given are such as pertain to warehouse distribution, rearranged in proper sequence for that purpose, but with the same section and subdivision indices as occur in the original publication. Parts given in script are explanations or abbreviations inserted by us where the original text is complicated by cross references or includes matter irrelevant to warehouse distribution. Pledge "Sec. 9D. (b) the retailer or customer form: I do hereby pledge myself not to use, or, so far as lies within my power, permit the use of, any stocks now in or which may hereafter come into my possession or control, save for essential uses, as that terin may be defined from time to time by the Priorities Division of the War Industries Board; that I will not hoard or countenance the hoarding of stocks, and will use my utmost endeavor to insure that they be distributed and applied solely to essential uses." The jobber must require of a pledge in the following Certification for "Sec. 9D. (c)" Orders for materials Class A Orders for purposes taking automatic classifi- cations or covered by Priority Certificates of A rating as listed in Section 8 must be accompanied by a certification in in the following form: are "I hereby certify that the materials covered by this order are intended for use and will be used solely for the following purpose. .(state purpose), and that orders for such purpose are entitled to automatic classification of A. rating under the provisions of Circular No. 4 of the Priorities Division, dated July 1, 1918, as amended by Supplement No. 2, issued October 15, 1918, and all amendments thereto for the purpose of completing an order covered by Priority Certificate No... bearing A.... rating." •1 Automatic Ratings or Use whichever is applicable. Certification for Orders for materials for purposes Class B and Other taking automatic classifications of Purposes B rating as listed in Section No. 8, or for other purposes not enumerated herein, should carry a statement definitely giving the purpose for which material will be used. "Sec. 8. Each order for materials, equipment (see Sec. 9A), or supplies for the purposes or uses hereinafter in this Section mentioned shall, by virtue of this rule, automatically take a classification as herein prescribed, namely: (a) For the manufacture of turbines (all classes). A-4 1 i J Reclass 15-4K (b) For the repair or construction of locomotives for use on rail- roads under the jurisdiction of the United States railroad administration, for use of the United States military railroads, or for use by the allies in military operations. (c) For the production of electrodes.... (d) For the manufacture of rope wire and of wire rope. (i) (j) (e) For the building of ships, or other water craft for and under direct contracts with the United States Army, the United States Navy, or the United States Shipping Board Emergency Fleet Corporation.... (k) (1) .A-5 (f) For the building of all cargo water craft, including tugs, barges, and dredges (but not pleasure craft), save such as are under construction by or for the United States Army, the United States Navy, or the United States Shipping Board Emergency Fleet Corporation.... • (g) For the manufacture of machine tools for working both metal and wood; of machinists' tools, of small tools, of hand tools, and of mining tools, mining machinery, and mining equip- ment.... • (s) • .A-6 (h) For the manufacture of railroad materials, equipment, and supplies (other than locomotives) for use on the railroads under the jurisdiction of the United States Railroad Ad- ministration.. .. • • • · • • • · • • For the manufacture of electrical equipment (excepting turbines) for the generation, distribution and utilization of electrical energy for power, traction, and light, of radio apparatus, of electromedical apparatus, of electric welding apparatus, of electric furnaces, of electric signal and com- municating systems and of such electrical supplies only as are essentially required in the installation or use of such electrical equipment or systems, on strict compliance with the provisions of this section and with the provisions of Circular No. 53 issued by the Priorities Division of date October 15th, 1918 For the manufacture of farm implements. • • • · For the manufacture of electric and hand-traveling cranes, shipyard cranes, track pile drivers, portable electric hoists, electric monorail hoists, grab buckets, I-beam trolleys and chain blocks, save such as are under construction for the United States Army, the United States Navy, or the United States Shipping Board Emergency Fleet Corporation (see also subdivisions (ab) and (ac) hereof).. .B-1 ► For the manufacture of textile machinery and textile machine supplies.. (m) For the manufacture of tools, implements, machinery and equipment required for the production, harvesting, distribu- tion, milling, preserving, canning and refining of foods and feeds.. • • A-4 A-5 A-5 .B-2 B-2 (n) For the manufacture of binder twine and rope. (0) For the manufacture of oil-well supplies or equipment-by which is meant supplies for the production of petroleum and natural gas-but not including pipe lines, storage tanks of 1,000 barrels capacity or over, tank cars, or refineries (see also subdivision (u) hereof). .B-2 • (p) For the operation, repair, and maintenance (not including new construction, expansion, or materials entering into the finished product) of coke-oven plants, mines, ore-reduction plants, furnaces, rolling mills, wire-drawing mills, and pipe and tube mills, employed in the production of fuels, metals and metal products, and for the operation, repair, and main- tenance of benzol plants and toluol plants and for the opera- tion, repair and maintenance of plant railroads employed in plants named herein. B-1 .B-2 B-1 (q) For the manufacture of iron and steel chain and sprocket wheels... (r) .B-2 B-2 A-6 B-2 For the manufacture of repair parts to shoe machinery and for the operation and maintenance (not new construction, expansion, or replacement, or materials entering into the finished product) of shoe manufacturing plants.. B-2 For the maintenance of jobbers' stocks of heavy hardware, farm implements, mining tools, mining machinery and mining equipment, and similar iron and steel products, to the extent of quantities delivered during the preceding month for uses entitled to preference treatment as from time to time determ- ined by the Priorities Division upon compliance with the conditions of this section, and of section 9D, subdivisions (a) and (b) of this circular.. B-4 (t) The automatic rating heretofore provided for in this sub- division for the maintenance of stocks of fabricators of steel is hereby discontinued. Fabricators may, however, make application for priority assistance, on the regular form, Form P. C. 15. (u) For the production of, and for the obtaining of stocks to be distributed for the production of, petroleum and natural gas, including essential repairs and supplies for maintenance of existing pipe lines, storage tanks, tank cars, and refineries, but not including materials, equipment, or supplies for new construction, extension, or replacement of pipe lines, storage tanks of 1,000 barrels capacity or over, tank cars, refineries (see also subdivision (o) hereof). • (v) For the manufacture of telephonic and telegraphic instru- ments and equipment for use in connection with the military program. A-4 (w) For the manufacture of marine equipment to be installed in ships or other water craft (save pleasure craft). • • * J (x) For the manufacture of steam condensers. (y) For the manufacture of high-pressure boilers, super-heaters and circulating pumps. • B-2 A-6 A-6 (z) For the manufacture of automatic stokers. (aa) For repairs to gas, light, water and power plants operated as public utilities. A-5 (ae) For the operation, repair and maintenance (not including new construction, expansion, or raw materials entering into the finished product) of plants manufacturing textiles, including processes of manufacturing. (ab) For the manufacture of locomotive cranes, including raised pier, portal pier, and gantry types and wrecking cranes, save such as are under construction for the United States Army, the United States Navy, or the United States Shipping Board and Emergency Fleet Corporation (see also subdivisions (i) and (ac) hereof) A-6 all (af) For the maintenance of jobbers' stocks of the following iron and steel products, other than as provided for in subdivision (ag) hereof; sheared, universal mill rolled and floor plates; blue annealed, galvanized, one pass cold rolled, and full cold-rolled sheets, formed roofing and siding and special finish sheets of all kinds; hot-rolled steel bars and small shapes, cold- rolled shafting, iron bars, concrete reinforcing bars, toe calk steel, spring steel, tire steel, hot-rolled strip steel, hoops, bands and rails; angles, channels, beams, tee bars and other structural shapes; wrought-iron pipe, steel pipe, boiler tubes, mechanical tubing; rolled and drawn wire; wire rope; cold- rolled strip steel; and tool steel; and other similar iron or steel rolled products not of a manufactured nature; upon strict compliance with the condition prescribed in this section and in section 9D hereof.. B-1 B-2 (ac) For the manufacture of all types of cranes listed in sub- divisions (i) and (ab) above, when, for, and under direct con- tract with the United States Army, the United States Navy, or the United States Shipping Board Emergency Fleet Corp.. A-5 (ad) For the operation, repair and maintenance (not including new construction, expansion, or raw materials entering into the finished product) of plants manufacturing chlorine, calcium carbide, acetylene, oxygen, hydrogen, and hydrocarbon gases, apparatus employed in their utilization, and shipping containers therefor. A-6 B-2 B-4 (ag) For the maintenance of jobbers' stocks of iron or steel products enumerated in subdivision (af) above, when intended for use exclusively for purposes for which automatic classifications of A-6 or higher rating are provided in Circular No. 4 of the Priorities Division, and amendments thereto, or for use to complete orders covered by priority certificates of A-6 or higher rating, upon strict compliance with the conditions of this section and of section 9D hêreof.. A-6" Automatic Rating for "Sec. 8A. As it is in the Certain Repairs public interest that existing facilities should be operated without interruption and also that existing equipment should be repaired rather than new equipment constructed, each order for the repair of, and each order for materials, equipment (see Section 9A), or supplies for necessary repairs to, a product for the manufacture or production of which. an automatic rating is provided in Section 8, and all amendments thereto, shall be entitled to an automatic priority rating one point higher than is provided for the manufacture or production of the product itself. The affidavit given below should in such case refer both to this section and to the subdivision of Section 8 providing the automatic rating for the manufacture of the product. Unless rerated by express order in writing by the Priorities Com- mittee of the War Industries Board, this order is by authority of said Priorities Committee rated as class. under and by virtue of subdivision. of Section 8 of Circular No. 4 issued by the Priorities Division of the War Industries Board of date July 1, 1918, as amended by Supplement No. 2 issued October 15, 1918, and all amendments thereto. • For the purpose of securing said rating I do solemnly swear- (1) That I have taken and filed whatever pledge is required by the War Industries Board from the industry of which I am a member; and · (2) That the materials, equipment, or supplies covered by this order are intended for use and will be used, for the purpose or purposes mentioned in said subdivision or subdivisions of said Section 8, and for no other purpose." I, Industry Priority "Sec. 9E. The Priorities Di- Certificates vision has issued and is from time to time issuing Circulars dealing with certain industries as a whole, and providing allotments of materials for the entire industry. Where such action has been taken the Priorities Committee, on proper showing, issues what is designated as an Industry Priority Certificate, which entitles the concern to whom the certificate is issued to order and purchase the quantity of material specified in the certificate, and allows on such orders a designated Priority rating. To secure the rating under an Industry Priority Certificate, the concern entitled to the rating must accompany its order by an affidavit in the following form: ... solemnly swear that I am. (official position) of (a) That said company holds unrevoked Industry Priority Cer- tificate No... dated. issued to it by the Priorities Division of the War Industries Board, granting it per mission to procure materials for the construction of products as specified in said certificate, and giving its orders placed thereunder Class priority rating; (name of company). • ..? •• - (b) That orders placed and purchases made pursuant to said certificate, including this order and materials already on hand, are in the aggregate for quantities of materials not in excess of the quantities said company is expressly permitted to purchase under the terms of said certificate; (c) That said company has taken and filed whatever pledge is required by the War Industries Board from the industry of which it constitutes a part; (d) That materials and products covered by this order are intended to be used and will be used for the purpose mentioned in said pledge and said certificate and for no other purpose." Manufacturers and producers in receiving orders accompanied by affidavits as above set out should rate. such orders in accordance with the automatic rating designated in the affidavit." The term, 'materials Interpretation "Sec. 9A. "Materials and and equipment' as used in the Equipment" first line of Sections 7A, 8 and 9 and the fifth line of Section 8A shall be taken to mean only such materials and equipment as enter in- to the product itself as a component part thereof." 009 PI NOV 16 20 Commerce PUBLICATIONS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE No. 438 S B Organization of Commerce The American System of Improving and Administering Commercial Facilities J. BRUCE BYALL, Philadelphia The British System of Improving and Administering Ports and Terminal Facilities Russell Smith, Instructor in University of Pennsylvania Price: 50 cents Relation of the Government in Germany to the Promotion of Commerce SOLOMON HUEBNER, Assistant in Commerce, University of Pennsylvania Reprinted from THE ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science for November, -1904 PHILADELPHIA AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE ENGLAND. P. S. King & Son, 2 Great Smith St., Westminster, London, FRANCE: L. Larose, rue Soufflot 22, Paris ITALY: Direzione del Giornale degli Economisti, Rome, via Monte Savello, Palazzo Orsini SPAIN. Capdeville, 9 Plaza de Santa Ana, Madrid ......... COLOR 2. ORGANIZATION OF COMMERCE Commerce THE AMERICAN SYSTEM OF IMPROVING AND ADMIN- ISTERING COMMERCIAL FACILITIES In this paper the endeavor will be to collate the legislation of the Federal and of the State Governments on the subject of commercial facilities, and to discover, if possible, the general trend of legislative activity. The study of harbors, the connecting link between railway and ocean transportation, becomes of increasing interest and importance as foreign trade develops. Unless harbors are properly constructed and efficiently regulated foreign trade is of necessity heavily handi- capped. Previous to the adoption of the Constitution the various States regulated their commerce as so many separate nations, the Federal Government having a merely nominal suggestive power. Not only was there no uniformity in their legislation, there was bitter antagonism, States endeavoring to enact laws to cripple the commerce of other States. In the actual construction and equipment of harbor and wharf facilities, individuals were left largely to follow their own whims and desires. From such a condition of affairs there has been a steady change, first toward more activity on the part of the State Governments, and later on the part of the Federal Govern- ment. The Constitution gives Congress the power to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts and excises which shall be uniform throughout the United States; to regulate commerce with foreign nations, among the several States and with the Indian tribes; and likewise places the following restrictions on the States: no State shall without the con- sent of Congress lay any imposts or duties on imports and exports, except what may be absolutely necessary for the execution of its inspcetion laws; and no State shall without the consent of Congress. lay any duty of tonnage. But these clauses of the Constitution, like many others, meant little until interpreted by the Supreme Court, and judicial decisions, in a series of cases from 1824 to 1884, were necessary to establish an apparent understanding between the Federal and State Governments in the regulation of rivers and harbors. [489] 60 The Annals of the American Academy Legal Decisions Distinguishing Between Federal and State Authority. By the Act of March 19, 1787, the Legislature of New York granted to John Fitch the sole and exclusive right of making and using every kind of boat or vessel impelled by steam on all creeks, rivers, bays and waters within the territory and jurisdiction of the State for a period of fourteen years. John Fitch, it appears, failed to exercise the extensive powers bestowed upon him, and, by a number of Acts this right was transferred to Robert R. Livingstone and Robert Fulton, changed only as to the time limit of the monopoly. By these Acts the exclusive right was given them to use steam navi- gation on all the waters of New York for a term of thirty years from 1808. According to the laws of New York, any steam vessel without a Livingstone and Fulton license was liable to seizure and forfeiture if found within the waters of the State. Opposed to this was a Connecticut law forbidding any vessel with such a license from entering the State, and, according to a New Jersey law, if the representatives of Livingstone and Fulton carried into effect by judicial process the provisions of the New York laws, they exposed themselves to a State action in New Jersey for all damages and treble costs. This law of the State of New York finally came before the Supreme Court in the year 1824 in the famous Gibbons vs. Ogden case,¹ and the decision was the entering wedge in the separation of State and Federal authority over navigable waterways of the United States. Because of its repugnance to that clause of the Constitution giving Congress power to regulate commerce with foreign nations among the several States and with the Indian tribes, this law was declared unconstitutional, insofar as it prohibited vessels licensed according to the laws of the United States from carrying on the coasting trade, and from navigating the waters of the State of New York. In other words, no State may exclude vessels of the United States from her waters. The next phase of the question was brought to light in the State of Maryland. In 1821 the Legislature passed a law that all importers of foreign articles or commodities of dry goods, wares or merchandise by bale or package, or wine, rum, brandy, whisky and other distilled spirituous liquors, etc., and those persons selling the same by whole- sale bale or package, hogshead, barrel or tierce should, before they 19 Wheaton 1. [490] American System of Commercial Facilities 61 were authorized to sell, take out a license for which they were to pay $50. In 1827 the Supreme Court' declared this law unconstitutional, being contrary to the clause, "No State shall, without the con- sent of Congress, lay any imposts or duties on imports and exports;" and also to the clause, "Congress shall have power to regulate commerce ***' That is, a tax on importers is a tax on and a regulation of commerce and, therefore, unconstitutional. 3 The matter of registration was the next point to come before the Supreme Court. In 1854 the State of Alabama passed a law requiring the owners of steamboats navigating the waters of the State, before a boat should leave the port of Mobile, to file a statement in writing in the office of the Probate Judge of Mobile County, setting forth: first, the name of the vessel; second, the name of the owner or owners; third, his or their place of residence, and, fourth, the inter- est each has in the vessel. This law also was declared unconstitu- tional insofar as it applied to a vessel which had taken out a license and was duly enrolled under the Act of Congress for carrying on the coasting trade and plied between New Orleans and the cities of Wetumpka and Montgomery in Alabama. Special State registration is an unlawful requirement of vessels engaged in coastwise trade. The case of Foster vs. Davenport differed from the above case in this respect only, that the vessel seized for non-compliance was engaged in lightering to and from vessels anchored in the lower bay of Mobile and the wharves of the city, and in towing vessels anchored there to and from the city, and in some instances towing the same beyond the outer bar of the bay and into the Gulf to a distance of several miles, but was duly enrolled and licensed to carry on the coast- ing trade while engaged in this business. The argument of the Court being that lightering or towing was but a prolongation of the voyage of the vessels assisted to their port of destination. 4 The next case³ dealt with the subject of taxation. In 1866 the State of Alabama passed a revenue law fixing the rate of taxation for property generally at one-half of one per cent., but on all the steam- boats, vessels or other watercraft plying in the navigable waters of the State, the rate was placed at one dollar per ton of the regulated tonnage, to be collected if practicable at the port where such vessels 2 Brown vs. Maryland 12, Wheaton 419. 8 Sinnot vs. Davenport 22, Howard 227. 22 Howard 244. Cox vs. Collector 12, Wallace 204. - [491] 62 The Annals of the American Academy were registered, otherwise at any other port of landing within the state where such vessel might be. The vessels in question were enrolled and licensed for carrying on the coastwise trade, but, as a matter of fact, plied only on waters within the State. The Supreme Court decided that although taxes levied, as on property, by a State upon vessels owned by its citizens and based on the valuation of the same, are not prohibited by the Constitution, yet taxes cannot be imposed on them by a State at so much per ton of the registered tonnage. Vessels have long been obliged to pay pilotage whether assisted to and from the harbors by pilots or not, and in 1855 the State Legis- lature of Louisiana authorized the Master and Wardens of the Port of New Orleans to collect five dollars from every vessel arriving at the port, whether called upon to perform any service for the vessel or not. But in 1867 the Supreme Court pronounced the law a regu- lation of commerce and unconstitutional, since it was a tax levied on all ships. It was further stated that the fees of the Master and Wardens differed from that of the pilots, in that the pilot laws of the States received Federal confirmation in 1789, and also that the pilot laws rest on contract, i.e., payment for actual service. 7 The last important case of this series was that of Moran vs. New Orleans. In 1870 the State authorized the city of New Orleans "to levy, impose and collect a tax upon all persons pursuing any trade, profession or calling, and to provide for its collection;" and further added that this law should not be construed to be a tax on property. Under the authority of this Act the city established the following license: "Every member of a firm or company, every agent, person or corporation owning and running towboats to and from the Gulf of Mexico, $500." Cooper was the owner of two steam pro- pellers, each measuring over 100 tons, duly enrolled and licensed at the port of New Orleans under the laws of the United States, to be employed in the coasting trade. Upon his refusal to pay the license. judgment was obtained by the city and sustained by the Supreme Court of the State. The Supreme Court of the United States, how- ever, decided that the license was in reality a charge made under the authority of the State for the privilege of employing vessels in the manner authorized by the license of the United States and was, there- fore, a restriction of commerce and unconstitutional. Steamship Co. vs. Portwardens 6, Wall 31. 7112 U. S. 69. [492] American System of Commercial Facilities 63 This chronological review of laws and court findings is necessary, in order to get some idea of the relation of the Federal and State Governments in the control of vessels plying to and from our ports. Vessels may be taxed by the State Governments, but such taxation must be based on property value and be collected at port of registra- tion. And no vessel licensed and enrolled under the laws of the United States for carrying on the coastwise trade may be burdened by any special registration, license, fee, or tonnage tax by any State. The Constitution has been interpreted strictly, and the States are limited in their taxation of commerce to what may be absolutely necessary for the execution of their inspection laws. Governmental Control of Pilots and Pilotage. 8 "" Pilots are largely under State control. Prior to 1789 most of the States had adopted pilot laws, and these laws were early confirmed by Congress in these words: "Until further provision is made by Congress all pilots in bays, inlets, rivers, harbors and ports shall continue to be regulated by the laws of the States wherein such pilots may be or with such laws as the States may respectfully enact for the purpose. Friction soon arose between such States as Penn- sylvania and Delaware, both of which have pilots competing for ser- vice to and from ports on the Delaware River, giving opportunity to vessels to discriminate between the pilots of the two States. This led to a law of the United States requiring the master of any vessel coming into or going out of any port situated upon waters which are the boundary of two States to accept the first qualified pilot who offers his services, whether he be licensed in one State or the other. The Revised Statutes of the United States (No. 4237) prohibit any State from making any discrimination in the rate of pilotage or half pilotage between vessels sailing between ports of one State and ves- sels sailing between ports of different States. Revised Statutes (No. 4444) make it unlawful for a State or Municipal Government to require pilots of steam vessels to procure State or other license, in addition to that issued by the United States, or any other regulation which will impede pilots in the exercise of their duties. Except for these general regulations the control of pilots and pilotage is left to the State and Municipal Governments. Taking Philadelphia Revised Statutes 4235. [493] 64 The Annals of the American Academy for an illustration, one of the duties of the Board of Wardens is to license pilots and make rules for their government. There There are eighty-four pilots, half of whom are licensed by the state of Penn- sylvania and half by the state of Delaware. They serve in turn, first-class pilots taking vessels with draft of eighteen feet and over, and the second-class pilots taking vessels of less than eighteen feet draft. The rate of pilotage is fixed by law, twelve feet draft and less being $1.87 per half foot; over twelve feet, $2.25 per half foot. Pilotage is compulsory; a vessel entering the Delaware River must lie beyond breakwater for twenty-four hours, if need be, waiting for a pilot, who, when accepted, must be paid according to the rate decided upon by the State from which the pilot shall have come. In New York harbor the number of pilots is limited to one hundred and thirty. They are incorporated, take steamers by turn, pool their earnings, and draw a salary of $200 per month when working full time. Pilotage is not compulsory unless a pilot offers his services. The rate of pilotage on inward bound vessels drawing twenty-one feet draft and upwards is $4.88 per foot. At Baltimore pilotage is compulsory. There are fifty-four pilots licensed yearly by the State. The rate of pilotage on vessels of fifteen feet draft and over is $5 per foot. Improvement and Control of Waterways. In the first part of the paper we endeavored to discover the rela- tion between the Federal and State Governments in the general oversight of vessels and cargoes as they come and go in the harbors of the United States. Attention will now be directed to the re- lation between the Federal and the State Governments in the main- tenance, improvement and control of waterways.º C In a general way it may be said that the Federal Government has authority over the channels of rivers between the wharf lines, and that the States have authority over the docks, wharves and other conveniences for loading and unloading cargoes. This authority is sometimes exercised directly, as in the State of Washington, where the State has made Constitutional provision for the protection of the For a study of the activity of the Federal Government in improving harbors, see article by Professor Emory R. Johnson, Annals of the Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. ii, page 782-811. Professor Albert Bushnell Hart's "Essays on American Government, Chapter ix. " [494] American System of Commercial Facilities 65 water front; in other States it is delegated to municipalities, and in others individual initiative is largely left unguided and uncontrolled. On the other hand, individuals, corporations and State authorities are not prohibited from improving river channels, but are sub- jected to the regulation of Congress, the Secretary of War and the Chief of Engineers of the Army. Prior to the adoption of the Constitution the States exercised their sovereignty, improved waterways and levied tolls to meet their expenditures; after 1789 the lighthouses, beacons, buoys and public piers were ceded to the United States, and the care of them no longer devolved on the State Governments, thus removing the principal occasion for the collection of duties. However, the collection of tonnage duties did not cease immediately, and Congress passed frequent enabling acts empowering States to collect duties for needed improvements. If a State wished to make some river or harbor improvements she would lay her plans before Congress and if ap- proved receive authority to collect by means of taxation of commerce sufficient funds for the completion of the enterprise. For example, in 1806 Congress passed an enabling Act to empower the Board of Wardens for the Port of Philadelphia to collect a duty of four cents per ton on all vessels clearing from the port of Philadelphia for any port or place whatsoever, to be expended in building piers and other- wise improving the navigation of the river Delaware. Removal of Obstructions from Channels. During the entire first half of the century there appears to have been no clear understanding as to whose duty it was to supervise the waterways of the United States and keep them in suitable con- dition to insure safety and rapidity to commerce. Even as late as 1859 the Legislature of the State of Pennsylvania passed an Act introduced by the following preamble which plainly indicates the un- certainty as to where the duty should rest: "Whereas frequent obstructions to the safe navigation of the river Delaware and the river Schuylkill within the tidewaters thereof do frequently occur by the sinking of canal boats, barges and other vessels and there being no adequate remedy to compel the owner, måster or other agent having charge thereof to raise and remove the same." The Act authorized the Master Warden of the Port of Philadelphia immediately upon information of the sinking of any vessel in the channel of the tide- [495] 66 The Annals of the American Academy waters of the Delaware or Schuylkill, within the limits of the port to notify the owner to raise the same within ten days under penalty, and upon failure of owner to remove the wreck the Master Warden should do so, selling the cargo to meet the expenses. In 1864 the Act was amended by authorizing the Master Warden to recover damages from the owner. Not until 1880 did Congress take action upon this subject.10 In that year the Secretary of War was authorized in case. of the obstruction of any navigable waterway of the United States, river, lake, harbor or bay, to give proper notice to all persons inter- ested in the craft or cargo to remove the same, and upon their failure to do so the Secretary of War should treat the sunken vessel as abandoned and derelict, removing and selling both vessel and cargo and depositing the proceeds in the treasury of the United States to the credit of a fund for the removal of such obstructions. This act remained unchanged for two years, but in 1882 the powers of the Secretary of War were enlarged by authorizing him to sell the vessel and cargo before raising the same. In 1890 he was further author- ized¹¹ to break up and remove, without any liability for damage to the owner, any wreck or obstruction that had been allowed to remain more than two months. In section six of the same Act Congress forbids the casting from any boat pier or manufacturing establish- ment any ballast, gravel, cinders, sawdust or other waste into any of the navigable waters of the United States, and where the casting of such material into navigable waterways is necessary for the improve- ment of the same a permit from the Secretary of War must be obtained. Construction of Bridges, Dams and Dykes. The Federal Government, having assumed the duty of keeping the channels free from obstructions, would naturally take the next step of defining more accurately the boundaries of waterways. On March 3, 1899, Congress, in order to further protect the channels of waterways, passed an Act regulating the construction of bridges, dams and dykes, making it unlawful to construct or commence the construction of any bridge, dam, dyke or causeway over or in any port, roadstead, haven, harbor, canal, navigable river or other navigable water of the United States until the consent of Congress 10 River and Harbor Act, Section 4. 11 River and Harbor Act, Sec. 8. [496] American System of Commercial Facilities 67 to the building of such structure shall have been obtained and until the plans for the same shall have been submitted to and approved by the Chief of Engineers of the Army and the Secretary of War. However, such structures may be built under the authority of the legislature of a State over rivers and other waterways, the navigable portions of which lie wholly within the limits of a single State, pro- vided the location and plans thereof are submitted to and approved by the Chief of Engineers of the Army and the Secretary of War before construction is commenced. The only difference in the build- ing of a structure over a river wholly within a single State and one which forms the boundary between two States is that in the latter case the consent of Congress must be obtained, which is not necessary in the former, but in both instances the plans must be approved by the Chief of Engineers of the Army and Secretary of War. Plans once approved must not be deviated from in the least, either before or after completion of structure without being submitted to and receiving the approval of both the Chief of Engineers and the Secre- tary of War. Section ten of the same law extended the Federal authority, making it unlawful to create any obstruction to the navigable capacity of any waters of the United States, unless affirmatively authorized by Congress; and also making it unlawful to build or com- mence building any wharf, pier, dolphin, boom, river breakwater bulkhead, jetty or other structure in any port, roadstead, haven, harbor, canal, navigable river, or other water of the United States outside established harbor lines, or where no harbor lines have been established, without having first received the approval before men- tioned. Harbor Lines Established by the Secretary of War. Section eleven of the same Act authorizes the Secretary of War to establish harbor lines wherever it is made manifest to him that such lines are essential to the preservation and protection of any harbor, and beyond these lines no piers, wharves or bulkheads or other works may be extended, or deposits made except under such regula- tions as from time to time may be prescribed by him. He is also authorized to require any party who is given the right to build a pier or other structure to excavate, if necessary, in another part of the harbor sufficient space to compensate for the water displaced by the Monda [497] 68 The Annals of the American Academy structure. Prior to this date, wharf lines were located by State or local boards, and even yet are usually so located, but wherever the Secretary of War has fixed wharf lines, the local boards have made their lines correspond. Section eighteen of the same Act authorizes the Secretary of War to compel the reconstruction of any bridge, railway or other- wise, wherever in his judgment it is deemed an obstruction of free navigation. In giving an order for reconstruction the notice must be accompanied by a plan of the change recommended by the Chief of Engineers of the Army. Failure to obey a reconstruction order is a criminal offense, and each aditional month's delay is a new offense. The Secretary of War, likewise, has the power when the public wel- fare requires it to make all needful rules and regulations for the open- ing of drawbridges and such rules when so made have the force of law. The speed of vessels, the navigation of canals, the floating of logs and sack rafts, all come under his supervision. Relation of State Governments to Wharves and Docks. The State Governments have exercised their authority over docks, wharves and harbor lines in numerous ways and with no attempt at uniformity. In some cases the authority is exercised by State Boards with large discretionary power; in others by State Boards closely guided by statutory laws; and in others still by elec- tive municipal boards with appointed heads or by departments under the charge of a commissioner. The following table 12 gives the forms of wharf and dock owner- ship and control in the principal ports of the United States: Portland. Boston 13 New York. Philadelphia.. Baltimore. • Norfolk. Newport News.. Savannah... • Railroad and Private (C Public, Public, C "" "C "C "( "" " Massachusetts State Board on Docks and Terminal Facilities, p. 14. 18The South Boston public pier has been constructed since above date. (C (C 66 " "C << "C [498] American System of Commercial Facilities 69 Charleston. New Orleans. Galveston • • San Francisco. • Public, Railroad and Private (( (( (C " Public At San Francisco the docks are public, under the control of the Board of State Harbor Commissioners first appointed in 1863. This Board is composed of three persons appointed by the Governor, by and with the consent of the Senate, for a term of four years. They are given possession and control of the waterfront of the city and county of San Francisco, with powers to erect structures within a given line. The Board with the Governor and Mayor may estab- lish rates for dockage and wharfage, collecting from each equal sums of which the total shall not exceed a small designated amount. The Board is empowered to locate and construct wharves wherever it deems best and to erect all such improvements as may be neces- sary for the safe landing, loading, unloading and protecting of all classes of merchandise passing in and out of the city and county of San Francisco. In the construction of wharves, no dock nor slip may be less than 136 feet at the narrowest point between the wharves. The Board has control of the mooring and anchoring of vessels in the harbor and keeping the waterways unobstructed and also the authority to extend any of the streets lying along the water- front of the city and county to a width of 150 feet, the water side of which may be used as a landing place on which tolls are collected. The State of Washington incorporated in her Constitution a clause prohibiting the State from selling or relinquishing any water areas beyond high-water-mark "but such areas shall be forever reserved for landings, wharves and streets and other conveniences of navigation and commerce." A Harbor Line Commission estab- lished harbor lines in the navigable tide water of the State adjacent to cities, with a view to providing for docks having a length of 600 feet and avenues fronting thereon of from 100 to 250 feet in width. By this means the water frontage of all the cities in the State is to be preserved in a uniform condition, under the control of the State, for the purpose of improving the State's commerce. New Orleans has about thirty miles of water frontage on both sides of the river. The wharves and all riparian rights are owned and controlled by the city. Leases and licenses have, however, [499] · 70 The Annals of the American Academy been given frequently to individuals and corporations. For many years all wharfage charges were collected by the officers of the city and turned into the city treasury for the maintenance of wharves and other landings; but in 1891 a lease for a term of ten years was made of five miles of the water frontage, the lessees being allowed to collect and retain all charges paid for the use of the property. This method of control did not prove satisfactory and the commercial bodies decided that "with the keen competition of other ports and the general tendency of business to seek ports which offer the best opportunity for the cheap handling of freight, nothing short of free wharfage will relieve the situation." In 1896 a law¹¹ was passed establishing a Board of Commissioners of the Port of New Orleans with power "to regulate the commerce and traffic of the harbor in such a manner as may in their judgment be best for its maintenance and development; to administer the public wharves; to construct new wharves where necessary; to erect sheds thereon to protect merchandise in transit; to place and keep the wharves, sheds and levees in good condition; to maintain sufficient depth of water and to provide for lighting and policing the wharves and sheds; to levy charges for defraying expenses in accordance with the sched- ule in the Act and to repossess themselves of the frontage farmed out under the ten year lease." The Board of Commissioners con- sisted of five men, resident in the city of New Orleans and ap- pointed by the Governor of the State. By the laws of Maryland the control of the harbor of Baltimore is vested in the Mayor and the City Councils who have established a Harbor Board consisting of the Mayor and six citizens, having control of all matters connected with the harbor and the expenditure of any funds appropriated therefor. The State owns two wharves, on which are warehouses wherein any citizen of Mary- land who raises tobacco may store it indefinitely with no other charges than a payment of two dollars per hogshead on removal of the same. At the ends of some of the streets there are a few wharves and an enclosed dock called the city dock, all owned and controlled by the city, at which boats with garden truck and small steamboats are furnished landings. The rest of the ownership is private. There are six harbor masters who are appointed in the same manner as other city officers and among their duties is that of the 14Act of the General Assembly of Louisiana, No. 70. [500] American System of Commercial Facilities 71 collection of wharfage and dockage rates, paying the proceeds to the city register. New York. The docks and wharves of the City of New York are largely owned by the municipality under a grant in colonial times, and are under the control of the Commissioner of Docks. Notwithstanding this grant about half the waterfront is claimed as private property. From 1870 until 1902 the duty of maintaining and improving the harbor devolved upon the Board of Docks. Previous to the organization of the dock department in 1870 there had been no systematic plan of construction of wharves around the city, each pier owner building to suit his own fancy or convenience. During the period of thirty-two years in which the control of the har- bor was vested in the Board of Docks the total gross revenue from leased wharves increased from $315,524.54 in 1871 to $2,673,333.30 in 1902; the revenue from ferry leases and franchises increased from $144,640 in 1871 to $303,406.47 in 1902; and the total annual expenditure audited increased from $486,449.12 in 1871 to $2,409- 376.49 in 1902. Wharf property valued at $11,692,579.71 was acquired by the city, and in addition to this a number of piers claimed by private individuals was restored to the city. In 1890 a board of United States Engineers established a bulk- head around the island upon which the department has built several miles of masonry which is to be continued until the island is com- pletely surrounded. Wharf construction is now systematically planned and carried out under the Commissioner of Docks, appointed by the Mayor. The wharves are leased for terms of years varying from ten years to those terminable at the pleasure of the Com- missioner and at rentals of from $50 to $100,000 per year under one lease. Leases may be renewed for periods of ten years, but the aggregate number of years cannot exceed fifty. The Com- missioner of Docks 15 has exclusive charge and control, subject in certain particulars to the Commissioners of the Sinking Fund, of the wharf property belonging to the corporation of the City of New York, including wharves, piers, bulkheads and structures thereon and water adjacent thereto and all slips, basins, docks, waterfronts, land under water and structures thereon and has exclusive charge and control of repairing and building, rebuilding, maintaining, 15Laws of New York, 1902, vol. ii, chap. 609. Ma [501] 72 The Annals of the American Academy altering, strengthening, leasing and protecting the property. No wharf, pier, bulkhead or other structure may be erected without the plans first being approved by the Commissioners of the Sinking Fund and filed with the Commissioner of Docks. He also is author- ized to regulate the charges for wharfage, cranage and lockage of all vessels admitted to the wharves, piers, bulkheads, slips, docks and basins constructed under the provisions of the law. Boston. In 1894 a joint commission on improvement of the docks and wharves of the City of Boston found "That there is not any public department, State or municipal, having supervision of the business of the docks and wharves, of their capacity, size or of the uses made of them." The number of wharves in the city at that time was over two hundred, all private property, used for private purposes and information concerning them rested entirely upon the good-will of the proprietor. Since that time the powers of the Harbor and Land Commission have been enlarged and as stated in the laws of Massachusetts, chap. 96, sec. 7, are the general care and supervision of the harbors and tide waters within the Commonwealth, of the flats and lands flowed thereby; of the waters and banks of the Connecticut within the Commonwealth and of all structures therein in order to prevent and remove unauthorized encroachments and causes of every kind which may injure the river or interfere with the navigation of such harbors; injure their channels or cause a reduction of their tide waters. The Board is also authorized to take by purchase or otherwise, lands or materials needed for improvements or repairs; to recommend harbor lines to the general court which, if established by the court, become the lines beyond which no pier or other structure may be extended. In 1897 the Legislature 10 authorized the Harbor and Land Commis- sioners to construct a pier and dock on the Commonwealth Flats at South Boston at an expenditure not exceeding $400,000. This pier 1200 feet long and 400 feet wide, creating a surface of wharf area of eleven acres, has been built and is the one pier owned by the Commonwealth. 16 • Philadelphia. Contrary to the general rule, the port of Phila- delphia was more or less carefully organized from its origin. By the charter of 1701 William Penn constituted the city of Phila- 16Chap. 513, Acts of Massachusetts. [502] American System of Commercial Facilities 73 delphia to be a port or harbor for the discharging and unloading of merchandise from ships upon so many wharves and quays as the Mayor, Aldermen and Common Council of the city should from time to time establish. The wharves of Philadelphia were of two kinds, public, such as the ends of the streets, which were for the use of the city, and pri- vate, such as were erected by the owners of the soil. In both cases the right of the riparian owner extended only to low-water mark, the privilege of erecting wharves to extend into the stream being one which the Proprietary or his successor, the State, might grant or withhold. In 1763 the Provincial Assembly, to encourage commerce and to render approach to these ports more secure, passed an Act providing for a lighthouse at the entrance of the bay and the placing of buoys in the bay and river. In 1773 provision was made for the appointment of wardens for the port of Philadelphia and for the regulation of pilots plying in the river and bay and the price of pilotage. The wardens were to choose one of their number president, examine pilots and grant certificates; make rules of pilotage; appoint the lighthouse keeper and provide for the building of more piers in which vessels might take shelter. Their accounts were laid yearly before the Accounts Committee of the Assembly. Finally in 1803 the groundwork of the present system was adopted. The law provided for one warden and six assistant wardens, four of whom should be inhabitants of the city of Philadelphia, one of the Northern Liberties and one of the District of Southwark. The Governor was authorized to appoint a harbor master, removable at pleasure. The duties of the wardens were to grant licenses to persons to act as pilots in the bay and river Delaware and to make rules for their government while employed in that service, to decide. all differences which arose between masters, owners and consignees of ships or vessels and pilots, except in certain cases; to direct the moving of ships and vessels in the harbor and the order in which they should lay, load or unload at the wharves and to make, ordain and publish such rules and regulations and with such penalties. for the breach thereof in respect of the matters before mentioned as they should deem fitting and proper. In 1851 the Legislature passed a law¹7 declaring that no previous law should be construed to authorize the building or extension of 17 Pennsylvania Laws, 1851, p. 862. [503] 74 The Annals of the American Academy wharves on the river Delaware in front of the city and county of Philadelphia or the establishment of wharf lines unless the wharf lines should first be approved by the Board of Wardens for the Port of Philadelphia. At this time the Board consisted of the Master Warden appointed by the Governor and thirteen port wardens appointed by the Select and Common Councils and the Commissioners of the Boroughs of Bridesburg, Richmond, Kensington, the Northern Liberties, South- wark and Moyamensing. In 1853 the jurisdiction of the Board was extended over the entire county and only wharves licensed by them were lawful struc- tures. The Board was now made to consist of one master appointed by the Governor and sixteen assistant wardens elected by the Select and Common Councils. This Act made it the duty of Councils to fix wharf lines beyond which no wharf or pier may be built; to keep the navigable water within the city open and free from obstruc- tions; to regulate pilots and the better disposition of vessels within the port. An Act of March 31, 1864, made it the duty of the Board of Wardens, guided by the plan prepared by the City Surveyor, to fix the wharf lines of Delaware County beyond which they could not authorize the construction of any wharf or pier. In the same year they were given the authority to fix an arbitrary low water mark beyond which no encroachment nor improvement should be made without a license from the Board. In 1870, owing to a decision of the Supreme Court, 18 above mentioned, the Board of Port Wardens was constituted a depart- ment of the city known as "the Department of Port Wardens," all its receipts being paid into the city treasury and its accounts audited by the City Controller. Previous to this the Master Warden and Harbor Master had received a fee of seventy-five cents collected from each vessel coming into the harbor. The fee having been declared unconstitutional, the payment of the salaries was assumed by the State government. The Board of Wardens has supervision of the port of Phila- delphia under the guidance of the State and the municipal govern- ments and operates principally through the Master Warden, and the 18Steamship Company vs. Portwardens, 6 Wallace 31, [504] American System of Commercial Facilities 75 Harbor Master who has charge of the placing of vessels, the cleaning of docks and wharves and other similar duties. Summary. In the past we have thought of harbors and transportation terminals as places where commerce was halted, now we are learning to think of them as integral parts of the great carrying systems, parts where speed and freedom of movement must be unrestricted, where discriminations and petty bickerings which result from unre- strained competition must be eliminated. While our foreign trade was comparatively small and sea-going vessels, of shallow draft, the equipment of harbors was of less importance; but with our immense and rapidly growing foreign trade, and with modern ocean vessels that draw from twenty-seven to thirty-three feet, special harbor facilities are indispensable. In 1902, 561 vessels with a loaded draft of from twenty-seven to thirty-three feet left New York harbor. In order to provide for such vessels as these, the Federal Government is deepening and improving our channel ways and giving increased power and supervision to the Secretary of War. The State and the municipal governments are centralizing the responsibilities of their Harbor Commissioners and granting specific powers, as well as general supervision. The Board of Docks in New York City has been superseded by the Commissioner of Docks. The powers of the Boston Harbor and Land Commissioners have been increased by authority to construct the South Boston pier. The New Orleans Board of Commissioners was given authority to repossess themselves of the river front, farmed out under the ten year lease and to regulate the commerce and traffic of the harbor "in such manner as may in their judgment be best;" while the harbor of San Francisco and the shore line of the State of Washington are under the direct guardianship of the State Government. As stated earlier in the paper the Federal Government has con- trol over the channels of rivers between wharf lines and the State Governments have control over the docks and wharves. In some States this authority is exercised through the municipalities as is the case in Maryland, Pennsylvania and New York, where the ports are controlled largely by the municipality or by a department of the municipality, but in Massachusetts, Louisiana, California and Wash- [505] 76 The Annals of the American Academy ington the authority is exercised by State Boards appointed by the Governors. But in either case the tendency has been the same, to centralize the authority of the Board and to grant more complete discretionary powers. J. BRUCE Byall. Philadelphia, Pa. [506] } THE BRITISH SYSTEM OF IMPROVING AND ADMINIS- TERING PORTS AND TERMINAL FACILITIES European countries present a wide range of experience in the management and ownership of ports and harbors. England alone has many varieties, differing in nearly all cases from those most in vogue on the Continent. Germany is a country with a highly organized and successful governmental activity for fostering trade. The present striking success of these efforts is calling the atten- tion of other nations to what Germany is doing, but it is true that England has been for more than a century the prominent figure in the commercial world, and that, too, without the thorough and formal organization of Germany. British freedom of trade has had a deeper meaning than the mere question of tariffs. The German governments act. The British government has only guided and controlled the action of individuals. These different policies are in part explained by the differing history of the two nations. For nearly ten centuries England has been united, unconquered and practically unthreatened by a foreign foe. During the whole of this period she has had more internal freedom in her political and economic life than any country of Europe except Holland. For two centuries England and Scotland have been united with freedom of trade and almost continuous internal peace. British wars have been fought abroad. During this same period the continent of Europe has, decade after decade, been devastated by war from end to end, and the British manu- facturers and traders have profited by the disturbance and have been allowed to develop their industries naturally. The continental manufacturer has been harassed more by tariffs than by wars. Germany in 1818 with sixty or more tariff-levying divisions with independent and varying fiscal policies was an impos- sible place for import, export or the assembling of raw material. Dynastic, military and political disturbances strengthened the hand of centralization and fettered individual liberty and initiative. The raw materials of the Continent, especially of Germany, were scattered and must needs await the coming of the railway and the steamer. Principalities, wars and tyrants dammed up the stream [507] 78 The Annals of the American Academy of German progress until that country with its increasing popula- tion was a disconnected mass of prostrate possibilities needing only the touch of opportunity to move forward with exceptional rapidity. That opportunity has come with the latter part of the 19th century at the hands of a government that had tasted the bitterness of defeat and had realized and acted upon the idea that national power was desirable and only to be attained by the raising of the efficiency of every individual and of every industry. After the German humiliation at Jena, Prussia began consciously and deliberately to educate that she might have efficiency and through efficiency, power. This policy was vindicated in 1870 when it was said that the German schoolmaster won at Sedan. It might also be said that he is now winning in the foreign market. The policy that began by educating the German peasant in 1820 has broken down Germany's internal tariffs, has made the leading technical and commercial schools of the world, and through state activity, has produced the Prussian state railway system with its preferential and export rates; has put the export bounty on sugar, the bounties on shipbuilding; has sent subsidized steam- ships to the far Indies and has made Hamburg the most efficient port in the world. England has had a more even, a more natural and latterly a less systematic development of commerce and its necessary facili- ties. Her raw materials, especially of coal and iron, and her water power have been abundant and favorably located. Internal freedom of trade and internal peace have left her people free to develop industry and trade. Her insular position has removed her from danger of foreign aggression so that the force of tyranny has declined and the individuals or the associations of individuals have been free to act as occasion demanded, and they have met commercial wants as they arose. Not being hampered like Germany, Britain's wants have not accumulated until a comprehensive system was demanded. These wants having been satisfied as they manifested themselves, we find that instead of a comprehensive system Britain has a com- plex accretion, the result of slow and gradual growth and chiefly by individual initiative. Such is the system of operating commercial facilities, such is the British school system, the British Constitution and the genius of British civilization. The British system has its advantages and its drawbacks. [508] British System of Commercial Administration 79 It was early in the field, but it is necessarily incomplete, and when the time arrives for more systematic improvements the private interests that first met the demand are often conservative resisters of progress with vested interests demanding protection. This be- comes more noticeable as the scale of modern commerce increases and demands facilities of a magnitude that the individual finds it impossible to supply. The British system is now at many points beginning to show itself inadequate to meet the demands of 20th century commerce and the more systematic competition of Germany. Many symptoms show that the United Kingdom feels the compe- tition of Germany and the United States and is attempting to meet it by a more thorough organization. The Chamberlain tariff agitation is an effort to protect England from her rivals. She has felt the need of a comprehensive educational system, but the passage of a satisfactory education act is hampered by conflict with the very numerous private schools-an outgrown result of private initiative. In this respect England is far behind Germany. Humili- ated Germany has spent a century in education and technical training and equipment. The United Kingdom, the unquestioned and unthreatened victor of the Napoleonic wars, mistress of the seas, secure in her isles, has spent that century in strife between the aristocratic and democratic classes who have fought within the political arena concerning the right to vote and govern. The British nation has now reached the point where it must repeat and is repeating the history of Germany. Great Britain feels her weakness and strives to improve her weak points. Individual efficiency must and will be raised by an improved educational sys- tem. The tariff may or may not be changed, but it will be im- proved if possible; shipping has been protected and aided by in- creased subsidies, and the tendency to betterment in the control and organization of commercial facilities is suggested by the recent agitation for bettering the port of London where it is proposed to make vast improvements and transfer control from several private bodies to a central authority. The original repository of power of general control over ports in Great Britain was the municipality but the fact that the munici- pality rarely cared to make extensive improvements in its corporate capacity left the field open to private activity. The size of the operations necessary for harbor improvements and the uncertainty [509] 80 The Annals of the American Academy of profitable return were such that individuals and partnerships were usually deterred from venturing into this field which was left for the joint stock company, the corporation. But corporations in great Britain are creatures of Parliament. So from the earliest harbor improvements to the present day there has been a constant succession of acts of Parliament creating bodies, private, semi-public and public for the improvement, operation and control of docks. and other port facilities. The first stage in this progress was the dock company, pure and simple. The rise and fall of the tide on British coasts is so great that vessels must anchor far from shore or lie on the bottom at low tide. This made slight difference in the days of light trade and of that carried by shallops and small sailing vessels. With the early years of the 19th century came heavier commerce and larger vessels which needed the shelter of enclosed docks with water con- stantly at high tide level. The first half of the 19th century was the era of the dock com- panies. They were organized in all the leading ports and usually prospered upon the charges made upon vessels and goods entering their premises. But this prosperity was not to last. The middle. of the 19th century witnessed three changes in commerce, each in itself revolutionary. (1) The railway gave the whole of Great Britain access to the sea. (2) The steamship made equal improve- ments in the accessibility of foreign lands and products. Further- more the steamship was shortly made of iron and greatly enlarged. (3) The coming of the free trade era caused a great increase in the imports of bulky commodities. The increased commerce and the larger ships made obsolete the docks of the old sailing ship days. The improvements necessary to accommodate the larger type of vessel were so expensive that the dock companies were with few exceptions unable to comply with the demands of trade and their decline set in. Except in favored ports the time had passed when a dock company could from its dues derive sufficient revenue to pay expensive salaries, interest charges and dividends on its stock. Henceforth the dock company had to be reorganized on a non-profit basis or become a part of some larger system in which it was an integral part. Numerous reorganizations followed, resulting in many varieties [510] 1. British System of Commercial Administration 81 of port arrangements, but all fall under one of three distinct types. which will be taken up in the order named: I. Public trust, in which the idea of corporate profit is aban- doned in the interests of public welfare. II. Municipal ownership and operation as a public utility, not as a source of revenue. III. Private ownership and control, usually by a railway company as a part of an extensive system. I. The Public Trust. The public trust is the most typical of all forms and by the compromise methods of its organization offers an excellent example of the British way of doing things. The public trust is a business corporation, organized like any other corporation, by Act of Parliament. Membership upon the board of directors is an honor but without financial reward in any way. In these respects and in the attitude towards the public the British harbor trust closely resembles the board of trustees of an American university. In the distribution of the powers of appointing directors we see the element of compromise that led to their origin. When the increased commerce of the free trade era had brought conditions to a standstill various official and non-official organizations had usually been exerting more or less power and the common method was for the Act of Parliament to give these and possibly others repre- sentation in the board of a new and more comprehensive governing body, the non-profit, the non-salary-paying corporation, or public trust. For the City of Glasgow the Clyde Navigation Trust was con- stituted by an Act of Parliament in 1858. It consists of twenty-five members as follows: The Lord Pro- vost of Glasgow, ex officio, chairman; nine town counselors of Glasgow; two nominees of the Chamber of Commerce; two nominees of the Merchants House; two nominees of the Trade House, nine persons elected by the shipowners and harbor rate payers. An Act was introduced in 1901 to reduce the municipal representation in this board. Liverpool is unique in having no municipal representatives whatever upon the board of its harbor trust. The Thames Conservancy Board has control of the Port of Lon- [511] 82 The Annals of the American Academy don, the navigation improvements of the Thames from the deep sea to and above London and also controls the waters of the Thames and its entire drainage basin with certain small exceptions. By the revision of 1894, this board has thirty-eight members appointed or elected as follows: Appointed by the Admiralty, two; by the Board of Trade, two; by the Trinity House, two; by the Glouces- tershire and Wiltshire County Councils, one; by the Oxfordshire County Council, one; by the Berkshire County Council, one; by the Buckingham County Council, one; by the Hertfordshire County Council, one; by the Surrey County Council, one; by the Middlesex County Council, one; by the London County Council, six; by the Common Council, six; by the Essex County Council, one; by the Kent County Council, one; by the Metropolitan Water Companies, one; by the Oxford City and County Borough, one; by the County Borough of Reading, one; by the County Borough of West Ham, one. Elected: By shipowners, three; by owners of sailing barges, lighters and steam tugs, two; by dock owners, one; by wharfingers, one. The board divides itself into an Upper River Committee consisting mainly of representatives of the counties bordering on the Upper River and a Lower River Committee consisting almost entirely of Lower River representatives. The Liverpool harbor authority is the Mersey Docks and Harbor Board, created by Act of 1857. Of the twenty-eight members four are nominated by the Conservancy Commission of the River Mersey, i. e., The First Lord of the Admiralty, the President of the Board of Trade, and the Chancellor of the Duchy of Lancaster. The remaining twenty-four members of the board are elected by the persons who have paid not less than £10 in dock rates during any year. In practice this results in combinations so that the members. really represent the commercial and mercantile organizations of the port, as the Steamship Owners' Association, the General Brokers' Association, the Cotton Association, the Corn Association, etc., thus practically duplicating in part the Glasgow method. The public trust, being the most highly organized of British harbor types and handling effectively the commerce of her larger ports merits a presentation of its (a) advantages, (b) its operations and (c) its historical development. (a) Its great advantage in management is the directness of control, the direct connection between the causes at interest and [512] British System of Commercial Administration 83 the power to remedy. If the harbor of a particular port were under the national legislature, Parliament, harbor questions would be dealt with by a bureaucracy or by new legislation which would have to struggle for attention against all kinds of national, colonial and international questions. Even under the care of the municipality the harbor question would have to be passed upon by people whose only interest might be in municipal sanitation, transportation, education or other problems of city life. The harbor trust and especially that of Liverpool avoids all of these entanglements by placing the harbor in the hands of a select board representing only the people who are interested in the port. The interests and the power of remedy are united and as all rules are and must be general, favoritism is impossible and the whole population of the city is benefited by anything which aids and improves the commerce of the port. (b) The effectiveness of the harbor trusts is proved by the success of their work. Since 1858 the Clyde, a narrow and rocky stream has been made by the expenditure of $35,000,000 into a safe waterway and ocean steamers now lie in the stream where it was then fordable. Glasgow has been raised from comparative insignificance to the rank of a great port. Liverpool has had an equally satisfactory experience. By Acts of Parliament of 1857-58 the Mersey Docks and Harbor Board took over the consolidated authority over the river and port and all the docks on both sides of the river. These improvements had been begun in 1709, and later, by private companies which had got into financial difficulties and sold out to the city of Liverpool in 1855, three years before the transfer to the board. The financial security based upon these properties and powers was excellent and the borrowing powers of the new management were good. Interest payments at low rates replaced the necessity of paying good dividends and operating expenses were lightened by a board whose members served without pay. Heavy borrowings and extensive harbor improvements and enlargements were immediately made and there have from first to last been over two hundred million dollars expended upon the port. Between 1857 and 1901, the present board made capital expendi- tures of nineteen and one-third million pounds sterling under its borrowing powers and two and one-fifth million pounds sterling from [513] 84 The Annals of the American Academy avenue. For the decade 1891-1901 the annual expenditure for dredg- ing was £125,000. Along with all of these expenditures and heavy debts the financial condition of the port is satisfactory and reductions have been made in dues on both ships and goods. At the same time new docks are being dug and the facilities of the port are being steadily improved, enlarged and kept abreast of latest requirements. In addition to docks the board owns warehouses for the storage of all kinds of merchandise and especially constructed warehouses for the storing and ventilating of grain. There are also privately owned warehouses in the city which compete with these, but there are no private docks; docks are a monopoly in control of the board. The revenues are raised by tonnage dues on ships entering the harbor, by dues on ships entering the docks and dues at prescribed rates on the goods carried by the ships, provided it is not trans- shipment cargo. The finances are managed with the double object of making the port facilities of Liverpool thoroughly efficient and as cheap as possible. In the former it is succeeding. The port is magnificently equipped and complaints are rare. Surplus revenues lead to reduction in dues. (c) The historical development, the natural history, of a pub- lic harbor trust can be best studied in London where for the past five years the dissatisfaction with the old private companies has been ripening into activity looking to the establishment of a public trust. At the present time, London, the commerical metropolis of the world's greatest commercial nation, still depends upon a port domin- ated by the old private interests of the type that perished in most of the other ports of Britain nearly half a century since. True the control is moribund and must be superseded by a more compre- hensive authority. The private companies of London have sur- vived longer than those of Liverpool or Glasgow or Southampton because they had a great commerce to spur them to great develop- ments before the free trade era and to give them an impetus that has carried them on with declining energy to the present time, when they lie powerless to cope with present demands. The high value per ton of London commerce has probably enabled it to bear burdens that would have been unbearable elsewhere. The commerce of the port has been suffering for some years because of inadequate facilities, high charges, and delays in handling of freight. These [514] British System of Commercial Administration 85 troubles arise partly from conflicts of authority between the various private bodies active within the port. Of these there are no less than four: (a) The Trinity House, controlling pilots and the marking of channels by buoys. (b) Thames Conservancy, having charge of the river and channel and improvements therein. (c) The Dock Companies, owning the docks and charging for the use of the same. (d) The Watermen's Company, having practically a monopoly of and control over the lighters and river boats. (a) The Trinity House is derived from an ancient guild or fraternity of pilots and seamen located at Deptford Strand in Kent. It began by having certain duties in the Government Navy Yard at Deptford, but it is now confined to lighting, buoying and pilotage. This Trinity House is the general lighthouse authority for England and Wales, and Gibraltar, but its jurisdiction does not extend to many ports, having been removed by the various port Acts of the 19th century. It does the buoying, lighting and pilotage in the Thames and examines London dock masters as well as pilots. This body is a closed corporation, being composed of "Elder Brethren" and "Younger Brethren." The Elder Brethren have sole control, filling their own vacancies by election from the Younger Brethren and recruiting the Younger Brethren by election from the outside. In the hands of this closed corporation of private individuals the British Government leaves a considerable share of its commercial authority and the expenditure of some special revenues raised by light dues on shipping. Such are the methods of individualistic and unsystematic Britain. Complaints are not numerous, although there is danger from lack of co-operation between the Trinity House, the channel marking body, and the Thames Conservancy. (b) The Thames Conservancy is the channel deepening body. This board is a creation of the same Parliament (1857) that enacted the Liverpool and Glasgow Harbor Acts and its activity has been one of the conditions necessary to the long survival of the private dock companies of the port. The Conservancy Board has entire charge of the tidal waters of the Thames, including the deepening of the channels, the regulation of vessels within the port, the licensing [515] 86 The Annals of the American Academy of docks, piers and embankments, etc., and making necessary by-laws and regulations for the control of the river. The revenues are raised by slight tonnage dues upon all vessels entering and leaving the port. In addition to the danger from lack of co-operation with the Trinity House, the Conservancy Board, while affording relief in 1857 when it was created, is now financially unable to provide further necessary channel improvements and the traffic cannot stand an increase of tonnage dues. (c) The dock companies have come to a similar standstill after an experience of a century. In 1800 the harbor was insufferably congested. For two centuries the customs regulations had per- mitted goods to be landed only on certain "legal quays" and "suf- ferance wharves." Cargoes were often stored on lighters for weeks awaiting turn at these favored wharves. In 1800 the West India Dock Company was authorized and was soon followed by two more. Each was given a monopoly of ships in certain trades for twenty-one years and the privilege of building and operating bonded warehouses. The companies derived their revenues from dues on ships entering the docks, from goods discharged on their quays. and from the rental of warehouses. This injured the owners of "legal quays," "sufferance wharves," the lighters and others who had to be compensated by the new companies to the extent of about a million pounds sterling. The dock companies were also compelled to admit lighters to the docks to take goods from the vessels free of charge. This last privilege is called the "free water clause" and has been a part of all subsequent dock legislation and the subject of much dispute. The great profits of the early dock companies were from their warehouses, the want of which had been the compelling motive to the building of docks. Consequently the rates on shipping were put low. The expiration of the monopolies and the refusal of Parliament to renew them was followed by a rush to build docks. Bonded warehouses were also built outside of the dock premises and the competition of the new docks and new warehouses was greatly increased by the coming of free trade and the consequent decline in the bonded warehouse business. Parliament, however, refused in 1855 to pass the bill to repeal the free water clause as the com- panies were still doing a profitable business, but from this time [516] British System of Commercial Administration 87 forward their prosperity declined. Severe rate wars ensued, their finances were impaired and as the result of several consolidations, there were but two strong competing companies in 1880. In the struggle for trade each increased its debt, built fine new docks and cut rates until they came to an agreement in 1888 and were consolidated in 1900, but with hopeless finances, dividends having been nominal or entirely absent for several successive years. The capital involved was about eight million pounds in bonds and eleven million in capital stock. While unsatisfactory to the stockholders, the dock company is also unsatisfactory to the patrons and to the community at large. The free water clause gives the lighters entrance to the dock and mechanical improvements have made the lighter a large and efficient craft depending upon steam power, and used so much "that the docks in London themselves are in great measure only stations at which goods arrive from the sea to be immediately placed upon barges to be conveyed to wharves or piers at other parts of the river or to shipping lying therein." It is estimated that over 75 per cent. of the freight is so handled, and to the great detri- ment of the dock company's revenues. 2 The impossibility of sorting import goods on the deck of the ship preparatory to putting them over to the lighters has led to the larger steamship lines making arrangements to do this sorting on the quays and then transfer goods to lighters without paying dock dues. These constructive "overside conditions" have led to great con- fusion and delay. While a large ship lies alongside a quay the lighters cannot reach the quay and sometimes the ship is immediately replaced by another when it goes away so that two or even three cargoes may be piled in confusion upon one quay while the owners of the goods are losing time and paying demurrage on lighters that cannot get at the goods they have been engaged to carry. It is sometimes cheaper to pay warehouse dues and railroad freight than to wait and take cargo off the quay into the importer's own lighter. This condition is unsatisfactory to the dock companies because they lose revenue and to the importer, the lighter owner and private warehousemen because they are delayed and thereby lose money. None of the suffering parties can apply a remedy. The efforts of the dock companies to secure legal permission. 1 Report on the Port of London, 1902, p. 30. 2 Ibid., p. 78. [517] 88 The Annals of the American Academy to tax the lighters has been successfully opposed by the wharf, lighter and outside warehouse interests and the London Chamber of Commerce. (d) The situation in the port of London is further complicated by the Watermen's Company, the modern form of a 16th century guild, whose members obtained their membership through apprentice- ship and had the monopoly of running boats upon the Thames in London limits. In its inception it was a regulation of rowboats in the interests of personal safety. By Act of 1894 the time of service before receiving license to run a boat on the Thames was reduced to two years, but it includes the river steamers as well as the freight boat, nearly 12,000 craft in all. The strike of 1900 showed that the Watermen's monopoly may be oppressive in a port where the lighter is such a vital factor in the daily work of handling freight. Under the combined guidance of the four governing bodies and the conflicting private interests, the port of London has, by the year 1904, reached a condition of standstill where further progress is impossible. The Thames Conservancy cannot deepen the channel, the dock companies cannot build new docks or deepen old ones and the Trinity House and the Watermen's Company conflict with both. The deadlock will, in all probability, be broken by the action of Parliament, based upon the advice of a Royal Commission, which, after two years of investigation, has recommended a public trust, which shall take over the property of the dock companies and the privileges and authorities of the Trinity House, the Water- men's Company and the Thames Conservancy insofar as they pertain to the Thames and the port of London. This new and unified authority if established as recommended would immedi- ately expend for channel and dock improvements seven million pounds, of which four and one-half million will be borrowed and two and one-half million pounds donated by the London County Council. The National Exchequer has no shere in this stupendous transaction, which will represent nearly as much money as the pro- jected Panama Canal. The revenues will be derived from tonnage dues on ships entering the port, dock dues on ships using docks, freight dues on all goods landed in the port and from license fees. on lighters. The composition of the board of directors of this new port author- ity as proposed by the Royal Commissioners is as follows: • - [518] British System of Commercial Administration 89 "On the assumption that the London County Council and the City Corporation accept the financial responsibilities . . . men- tioned above . the nominated members should be appointed by the following bodies: (a) By the London County Council (b) By the City Corporation (c) By the Admiralty. (d) By the Board of Trade • • • • • • (e) By the Trinity House (f) By the Kent County Council (9) By the Essex County Council (h) By the London Chamber of Commerce (i) By the Governors of the Bank of Eng- land from among persons belonging to the mercantile community of London.. The elected members should be elected by different groups of voters, viz: 5 (j) By the oversea (or ocean) trading ship- owners (k) By the short sea-trading shipowners. (7) By the wharfingers and owners of private warehouses on the river. (m) By owners of lighters, barges and river craft, including river passenger • steamers (n) By railway companies connecting with the docks. II members 3 I I I I I 2 "C 3 (C 2 (C (6 (( (( 5 members (( 2 66 (( "( " 2 The electing persons, firms or companies, should be given a number of votes varying according to the amounts paid in dues upon goods, or upon shipping as the case may be." If this measure can survive the unexpected opposition of the London County Council, the port of London will have completed its evolution and reached the condition of the greater British ports. This detailed account of the conditions leading up to this end may be taken as an example, rather complex because of its size, but none the less a typical example, of the difficulties through which British ports have been passing in the effort to accommodate them- selves to the growing demands of modern commerce. [519] 90 The Annals of the American Academy II. Municipal Ports. In the early days of the breakdown of the private dock com- panies, the municipalities frequently undertook the management of their harbors. Usually this effort proved unsatisfactory and Bristol is now the only one of the large ports that is conducted directly and entirely by the Municipal Council, several others, including Liverpool, having sought Parliamentary approval for public trusts after an unsatisfactory municipal venture. Two minor ports, Preston and Boston, have municipal ports and the Manchester city government has taken an active part in the affairs of the port of Manchester The Bristol docks were begun by a private company in 1803. Continuous financial difficulties led to sale to the city in 1848. In 1877 and 1881 two private companies opened rival docks further down the River Severn at Avonmouth and Portishead. Desperate competition ensued between the new docks and the municipal docks of Bristol with the result that the city, in self-defense bought out the two private companies in 1884 at less than cost and has since operated their plant as a part of the municipal system. The direct management is in charge of a committee of Councils, who employ a general manager who is responsible for the conduct of the property. The result is satisfactory. The arrangement of docks, quays, railway tracks, freight sheds, freight handling machin- ery serves to make Bristol an efficient port for the handling of freight and one of the leading importing ports for the kingdom. The people are satisfied with their port. In the words of the Bristol Docks Committee: "The policy of taking over the whole of the docks by the citizens has proved an exceedingly wise one, the foreign trade, population and wealth of the city having enormously increased and the works having been maintained in a high state of efficiency, generally out of surplus revenue earned by the docks! "The principle aimed at is not so much to make a profit as to increase the volume of traffic by keeping the tariff of charges low and providing from time to time (largely out of revenue), such further sheds, cranes, quays, railways, telephones, etc., and other facilities as the ever-changing type of traffic and vessels in which it is con- ducted seem to call for." They further proceed to contrast their management with that of private companies as follows: "Private [520] British System of Commercial Administration 91 owners, seeking only to work the docks for dividends, naturally maintain a high scale of charges which is against the traders' interest. They also hesitate to expend further capital until they are actually forced to do so either by a threatened loss of traffic, or an inability to accommodate the ordinary vessel plying at the time in the different trades." In comparing their port with those controlled by private com- panies the Bristol authorities lay much stress upon the fact that the rates are absolutely the same to all parties and that there are no rebates whatever. The municipality has the great financial advantage of being able to borrow its cash capital at about 2 per cent., and, with no dividends to pay, the rates of service can be low. At Preston and Boston, the only other fully municipal ports the experience has not been so satisfactory. In both cases the towns had no harbors and the payment of high railway freights drove the people to dock building to control the freight rates. In this they were highly successful. The dues from the ports have not, however, as yet been sufficient to meet interest charges and the deficit is made up from the city taxes, but the burden is cheerfully borne. The business interests of both communities are agreed that the reduc- tion of transportation costs, the cheapening of necessities and raw material, has stimulated trade and industry to such a degree that, upon the whole, the costly docks have paid. Manchester, while not possessing a strictly municipal port has shared in an experience somewhat akin to that of Preston and Boston. In 1882 the people of Manchester resolved to free them- selves from the necessity of conducting all import and export business through Liverpool where the port charges had to be added to a railway rate that was considered too high. The relief was to come through the Manchester ship canal undertaken by a private com- pany who set out to make Manchester accessible to ocean vessels and receive their reward in tolls. Unforeseen difficulties doubled the cost of the undertaking, the city had to come to the assistance of the company with a first and second loan, contributing about five of the fourteen million pounds sterling. Upon the granting of the first loan the city received representation in the company and with the second loan the representation became control. The revenues of the canal have been disappointing. The city has had to meet the interest on its stock by taxes and the private [521] 92 The Annals of the American Academy stockholders have had little return on their investment. It is generally considered that the commerce of the place has greatly improved. The coming of ocean ships to the heart of the city has been a great aid and the opening of the canal in 1894 was immedi- ately followed by sweeping reductions in railway freight rates. It was estimated in the first two and a half years after opening the direct saving in tolls and freight rates for the district amounted to ten million dollars. It should be remembered. however, that this saving was to the community at large and did not take the form of returns on the capital invested. III. Private Ports. The most important class of private ports is that dominated by the railroad companies. The coming of railways coincided with and helped to produce a great boom in all branches of commerce necessitating the reorganization of port administration and equip- ment. All ports that were of first importance at the time of the coming of the railroad, except London, were thus reorganized under public or semi-public control. No private enterprise could cope with the situation in a port with a large and well-established trade. At the same time there were many small, often local, ports with commerce too insignificant to warrant the building of first-class docks and harbors under the then existing conditions, and had such been desirable, they could not have been built by the weak communities that would have used the improvements. Such ports, however, offered the rapidly extending railways an opportunity to secure their coveted terminal facilities and port connections by building the same in places where land was cheap and possibilities of port development seemed propitious. So it was that the railway com- panies became the creators of ports or the improvers of ports, in places where the population and commerce did not warrant any other method. Southampton is probably the most conspicuous port in the class and the list includes Cardiff, Hull, Harwich, Grimsby and many minor ports throughout the kingdom. The history of Grimsby is a good example of the progress and development of a railway port. It is particularly good because it shows how a railway may create both a port and a city. In 1801 this port was first improved by the opening of a dock by a private [522] British System of Commercial Administration 93 company. Later it was sold to the Manchester, Sheffield & Lincoln- shire Railway. This line, running east and west through the indus- trial districts of Central England, desired an outlet to the North Sea and between 1846 and 1852 they built a new dock, the Royal Dock, capable of admitting the largest war vessels. From that time to the present this railway company and its successor, the Great Central Railway Company, have improved and extended the docks which are the port of Grimsby and now have a water area of 1031 acres with great extensions in view. The convenience and efficiency of these docks are of the very best. It may fairly be said that the railway with its harbor has made the town. Five years before the railroad dock was begun, the town had less than 4000 population, sixty years later, fifteen times as many. Similar increase occurred in shipments of coal and fish and in imports of timber and the entrances and clearances in the foreign trade have grown nearly tenfold and now exceed those of Galveston, Texas. This railway company has not been content to act purely as a harbor maker, waiting for others to create trade. The harbor, like so much new trackage, was built to secure traffic. In 1864 Parlia- mentary permission was obtained to run steamers to numerous continental ports between Antwerp, Stockholm and St. Petersburg, a large steamship company was bought out and direct service by the company began in 1865. This service has been frequently improved and extended. In 1891 daily sailings to Hamburg were inaugurated. In 1889 a further Parliamentary grant authorized connections to be established with practically all ports in Scandinavia and the Continent east of Ghent. While the railway company uses its docks as the terminus for its own steamship lines there is no monopoly and it is a harbor in the true sense and open upon payment of dues to ships of all com- panies and nations alike. The company built it as a terminus, but it is managed toward the public like any other public or private dock company, as for example, the London docks or the Liverpool docks. As at all British ports the dues charged are under parlia- mentary limitations. The experience of this railway company with the fishing industry is a typical and successful example of the relation of the docks to the prosperity of the railway. By catering in all possible ways to the [523] 94 The Annals of the American Academy 3 North Sea Fisheries and the requirements of the fishing boats, the company has been able to increase its tonnage dues at the docks through the entrance of fishing boats and then to secure in the fish shipments a lucrative freight business for the railway. Inci- dentally, population has thronged to Grimsby to carry on this work and the railway profits by the freight traffic of the city. The history of Southampton and other railway ports might be rehearsed at length, but few new principles would appear. It would be but a repetition of the Grimsby experience with variation in details. The tendency in British port ownership seems to be toward private ownership and in the form of railway termini. The docks of London will probably be transferred to a public trust and there may be occasional repetitions of this movement and occasional examples of municipalization; but the great ports are firmly fixed and the greater number of changes within the past thirty years have been toward the building of railway ports in the smaller cities. The British railways are consolidated into a few strong companies and the building of a dock as a part and feeder of a great system is a natural step in its development. There is a tendency in commerce at the present time toward the building up of numerous smaller ports both for the foreign and the domestic trade. Few of these places will reach importance without the railways provide the facilities. They are of the size that the railways have taken hold of in the past and the railway will usually feel the need of docks and build them before the municipality or a public trust would think of undertaking it. Such, at least has been the case in the recent past and there appears to be no reason to anticipate a change in the near future. J. RUSSELL SMITH. University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia. a Special fish docks were built, enterable at all times of the tide, with graving docks, floating dry docks, hydraulic coal hoists to put coal directly into fishing steamers and an artificial ice plant alongside the quay. [524] RELATION OF THE GOVERNMENT IN GERMANY TO THE PROMOTION OF COMMERCE¹ Prior to the unification of the Empire in 1871, Germany repre- sented an agricultural nation with few manufactures, with scarcely any merchant marine and with comparatively little foreign trade. Nearly two-thirds of the population was rural. Her industrial capital was small and business in general was conducted with extreme care and caution. Within the short space of a few decades, however, the situation has been strikingly reversed, and her interests, instead of being mainly agricultural, have become overwhelmingly those of a manufacturing and commercial nation. Her population, already equal to over 650 for every thousand acres of food-producing land, still shows the surprising increase of eight per cent. during the half decade from 1895 to 1900. No less than fifty-seven per cent. of her fifty-six million people in 1900 were engaged in industry and commerce as distinguished from agricultural pursuits; while during the generation from 1871 to 1900 her urban population in- creased fifteen and three-fourths millions as opposed to an increase of only fifteen and one-third millions for the entire country. In other words, Germany has reached an economic position which is essentially that of the United Kingdom, of a country no longer self-contained, but whose industries depend to an increasing degree upon raw materials from abroad and one-third of whose popu- lation is fed with foreign food. To protect herself against the vicis- situdes of the future, Germany must necessarily become more and more an exporting and maritime nation. Such being the problem which demands solution, it is easy to understand why the several governments, State and Imperial, have utilized every means at their disposal to stimulate trade and navi- gation. Indeed, government aid in Germany has been extended so as to embrace every phase of commercial activity. In the first ". ¹Among the chief authorities relied upon in this sketch_are the British Diplomatic and Consular Reports; The American Consular Reports; the Reports of the Commissioner of Navigation from 1899 to 1903; "Hamburg's Handel und Schiffahrt;' Lotz's "Verkehrsent- wickelung in Deutschland 1800-1900;' H. R. Meyer's series of articles on German canals and railways in the Railway Age for 1903; and Alfred von Weber-Ebenhoft's articles "Waterways in Europe" in the International Quarterly for 1904. Special mention must be made of Dr Wiedenfeld's "Die nordwesteuropäischen Welthäfen.' Information has been freely drawn from this work. It proved to be extre.nely valuable on account of its general and exhaustive treatment of the subject. " [525] 96 The Annals of the American Academy place, German manufacturers enjoy a foreign market which has been vastly enlarged since 1891 through favorable treaty arrangements. Large sums are expended annually in fostering industrial and com- mercial education to an extent seldom met with in other countries and with results which have called forth warning notes from British and American Consuls in all parts of the world. The shipbuilding industry is favored not only with preferential railway rates and an exemption from the payment of customs duties on shipbuilding material, but also with a monopoly in the construction of national war vessels and subsidized mail steamers. Furthermore, the Im- perial Government has embarked upon a policy of subsidizing the merchant marine. Over 7,000,000 marks are paid annually in the form of mail subsidies to those lines which are engaged in the Asiatic, Pacific and African service. While this sum is paid, nominally, for carrying the mails, there can be no doubt that an equally impor- tant reason is the desire to strengthen the navy, to free German commerce from the agency of foreign nations and to extend German trade and influence to those parts of the earth where her position is weakest and where private initiative, if left to itself, might prove inadequate. All these methods of assisting commerce, however, constitute only a part, and perhaps the smallest part, of the general system of government aid. In her search for a short cut to commercial power, Germany, like all the great nations, has emphasized the importance of cheap and easy transportation in the winning of distant markets. Neither money nor labor has been spared in an endeavor to facilitate transportation to the innermost parts of the empire and to unite the highly ramified system of artificial and natural waterways of the interior with the larger commercial life of the ocean. It is to a discussion of this last phase of German commerce that the present paper is principally directed. In this connection it will be attempted to state briefly the essential facts. with reference, first, to the control and improvement of the harbors; and, secondly, to the relation which exists between these harbors and the interior through the network of rivers, canals and rail- ways. I. The Management of Harbors. Although the Imperial Government of Germany exercises a large measure of control over the merchant marine and over naviga- [526] Promotion of Commerce in Germany 97 tion on interstate waterways, it possesses, broadly speaking, no authority to construct or manage harbors, this function being intrusted solely to the care of the several States. In Hamburg and Bremen the harbors are operated as State property, the work of construction being placed in the hands of a special department for this purpose and the general supervision and care of the harbor being exercised in Hamburg by a Depart- ment of Trade and Commerce and in Bremen by a Department for Harbors and Railways. Over both these departments stands the Senate of the State, which exercises the ultimate executive power. All expenditures for purposes of construction and operation are borne by the two city-republics themselves, and are defrayed from general taxation. The receipts, on the other hand, are merged with the general income of the State, there being no necessary connection between the expenditures for harbors and the receipts derived therefrom. In the case of both these world-ports, the State either owns or controls the larger portion of the warehouse system. Bremen, for example, in return for a stipulated percentage of the net earnings, furnishes the ground and constructs the buildings, but does not interfere with the management or business activity of the system, except as regards the regulation of the warehouse dues. Ham- burg, on the other hand, does not in the main assume the duty of constructing the buildings, but merely leases the ground for a certain percentage of the net earnings to a Free Harbor Warehouse Asso- ciation. This association, while obliged to construct all neces- sary buildings and bear all financial losses, is, nevertheless, subject to a large measure of State control. To the Senate belongs the right of regulating the warehouse dues and of determining the nature of the buildings to be constructed. Likewise all acts which involve an increase in the capital stock or indebtedness of the asso- ciation, or a change in its rules must be sanctioned by the Senate. Finally, the State is represented in the directorate of the association and possesses the power to suspend any act of that body until the Senate may have passed on its expediency. What has been said concerning Hamburg and Bremen holds in a general way for the other German harbors. As a rule, their construction and management is intrusted to the care of local boards or commissions subject to the general supervision of the State: [527] 98 The Annals of the American Academy in Luebeck to a Board of Public Works and the police authority, in Rostock to a Board of Public Works, and in Wismar to a Harbor Department. In Prussia the management and improvement of harbors is conducted either under the supervision of the Board of Public Works for each respective city or by permanent commissions, which are local in character, but which must receive the sanction of the State as regards harbor improvements and other important changes. To be specific, all harbor matters in Stettin are man- aged by a Board of Public Works; in Kiel, by a Harbor Commis- sion; in Flensburg by a Harbor and Bridge Commission; in Swine- muende, by a Royal Commission of Navigation officiating as a local authority; and in Koenigsberg by a Royal Harbor Police Com- mission. The operating expenses, as a rule, are borne by the local communities and are defrayed from the harbor receipts. II. Improvement of Harbor Channels. During the last twenty-five years nearly all the leading sea- ports of Northwest Europe have exerted themselves to the utmost in an endeavor to adapt their facilities to the growing conditions. of international trade. Indeed, practically all the leading ports, with the exception of London, have remained close rivals in this respect during the whole of this period. This strenuous compe- tition may be attributed, first, to the rapidly increasing size and draught of ocean steamers, and, secondly, to the struggle between these ports for the Eastern trade and the consequent desire to accommodate ships of the Suez standard. The less anyone of these harbors is dependent upon the influence of tide, the greater is the advantage of that port. Hence any effort on the part of one harbor to deepen its channel or to improve its facilities for landing, loading and unloading, has resulted in a corresponding effort on the part of the other ports. As regards the channel leading from the sea to the landing place, the German-Dutch-Belgian ports cannot be said to have been favored by nature. Whatever position these harbors now hold has been the result of vast labor and expenditure and the improve- ments have by no means been completed. Hamburg, until about 1850, possessed a channel measuring only from 4.0 to 4.3 meters. in depth at high tide. At an enormous expenditure this depth has been increased to 8.3 meters, while arrangements have been [528] Promotion of Commerce in Germany 99 made for a further increase of 1.7 meters. Bremen has also labored under unusual difficulties since its original channel measured only 2.5 meters in depth. After an outlay of some 50,000,000 marks, however, this city has secured a channel which can accommodate ocean-going vessels with a draught of 6 meters. The three Dutch-Belgian ports have each abandoned their original channel during the nineteenth century, and with the help of the State have constructed for themselves an entirely new open- ing to the sea. Amsterdam has received fully 37,000,000 marks from the State during the last thirty years for the improvement of the North Sea Canal and has increased its depth to 9 meters, so that all ships, except the very largest, can obtain an easy access to the port. Rotterdam, assisted liberally by the National Govern- ment, has secured the construction of a new channel at a cost of approximately 61,700,000 marks. For Antwerp the State has also expended large sums toward deepening and straightening the channel, and, according to plans now being arranged, it is intended to increase the present depth of 6 meters at low tide and 10.4 meters at high tide to 8 and 12.4 meters, respectively. In the case of every one of these ports large sums have thus been expended to secure a suit- able waterway. With the exception of Bremen, each port has also plans arranged for or under prosecution, which, when com- pleted, will enable it to receive vessels with a draught at least equal to the Suez standard. III. Improvement of Harbor Facilities. The rivalry between the leading ports of Europe concerning the improvement of their channels also exists in the provision of basins, wharves, warehouses and other necessary equipment. Enor- mous sums have been paid by most of the ports in rendering easier and swifter the process of loading and unloading. Particularly is this true of Hamburg, nearly all of whose harbor facilities have been constructed during the last twenty years. Even as late as 1866 all sea-going vessels were obliged to anchor in the open stream, and the whole process of loading and unloading had to be conducted by means of lighters. About that time, however, Hamburg began the construction of a series of improvements with the result that to-day her system of docks and piers is reputed to be the best in existence and her ship lines, according to Dr. Wiedenfeld, enjoy an [529] | 100 The Annals of the American Academy ease of communication with the shore far superior to that furnished by the English ports. Besides possessing probably the best system of warehouses. in the world, Hamburg has made admirable connection with the railways and interior waterways. Separate harbor basins have been constructed for the numerous canal and river boats where they may remain to await the arrival of steamers. The steamer basins have been constructed with a view to making a swift transfer of freight to and from vessels the prime consideration, any gain in this respect meaning of course a corresponding gain in the length of available piers. The wharves, besides being exceedingly spacious and built of durable material, are amply supplied with hydraulic machinery. At the present time the basins cover an area of 336.4 acres, while the total length of quays approximates 8.5 miles. Ex- tensions are now being made, however, which will increase the area of the basins to 612.56 acres and the length of the quays to 12 miles. When this project is completed Hamburg will have spent some 180,000,000 marks since 1880 for its harbor facilities-of which sum the Imperial Government contributed 40,000,000 marks at the time of Hamburg's accession to the Customs Union—and this enormous outlay does not include the large sums expended in deepening and otherwise improving the channel, or in constructing the excellent system of warehouses. It only requires the further deepening of the channel, for which arrangements have already been made, and the completion of the extensions referred to above, to make Hamburg's harbor satisfy the highest requirements of modern efficiency. What has been said of Hamburg is true of Bremen and the Dutch-Belgian ports, though on a smaller scale. In the provision of appliances for loading and unloading freight these harbors are practically on a par, and meet the latest requirements. In all, too, the construction of the harbor was so arranged that the new warehouses would be situated at once near the water and in the immediate vicinity of the large mercantile offices. Limiting our discussion to the sums expended, it appears that subsequent to 1885 Bremen has paid in round numbers 93,- 800,000 marks for its harbor facilities, exclusive of the 50,000,000 marks devoted to the deepening of the channel. Of this sum the Imperial Government contributed 12,000,000 marks when Bremen [530] Promotion of Commerce in Germany 101 joined the Customs Union in 1888 and 1,800,000 marks towards the construction of the Kaiserdock at Bremerhafen. Exclusive of the expenditures for the improvement of the channel, Amster- dam has spent 42,500,000 marks for its harbor facilities; Rotterdam about 30,000,000 marks; 'while Antwerp since 1879 has paid approxi- mately 130,000,000 francs, of which sum the State contributed considerable more than one-half. Large sums have also been expended in Stettin, Danzig, Kiel, Emden and other smaller ports on the North Sea. Stettin after an outlay of some 40,000,000 marks has secured a harbor which is not only beginning to share in the American trade, but which at the expense of Copenhagen and Gothenburg, is rapidly acquiring more and more of the Russian and Scandinavian trade. Altogether, it has been estimated that the several governments of Germany have devoted about $125,000,000 since 1888 towards the improvement of harbors, and that of this sum about six-tenths has been used for the channel and other facili- ties of Hamburg alone. This single port, it has been said, "has spent more money than any other two harbors in the world together during the last score of years to perfect its technical facilities."2 IV. Commercial Growth of Harbors. Along with the large expenditures for harbor improvements there has followed an increased power to handle traffic and a tre- mendous growth in the importance of these harbors from the stand- point of international trade. This becomes especially clear if one compares the net registered tonnage of vessels entering and leaving the various ports. Thus the total net registered tonnage of vessels engaged in foreign trade has been compiled as follows for the eight leading harbors of Northern Europe: London Liverpool. Hamburg.. Bremen .. Antwerp. Rotterdam. Amsterdam Havre.. • • TOTAL FOREIGN TRADE IN THE YEAR. 3 1000 Net Registered Tons. 1870 • .7,116 .6,773 .3,200 1,325 .2,282 .2,096 714 .2,321 • 1880 10,577 9,659 5,529 2,345 5,982 3,368 1,463 3,912 1890 13,481 10,941 10,417 3,482 9,022 5,754 2,068 4,419 1900 16,701 11,668 16,088 5,032 13,366 11,733 2,972 4,406 A glance at the above table will show that the tonnage of Ham- 2Wolf von Schierbrand: "Germany: The Welding of a World Power," Wiedenfeld's "Die nordwesteuropaeischen Welthaefen," p. 361. p. 201. [531] 102 The Annals of the American Academy burg in 1900 (16,088,000) is but slightly less than the tonnage of London (16,701,000); while Antwerp and Rotterdam each has a tonnage which about equals that of Liverpool. It appears, furthermore, that the tonnage of the three ports of Hamburg, Rotterdam and Antwerp has increased during the last thirty years by 443 per cent. as opposed to an increase of only 135 per cent. for London, only 72 per cent. for Liverpool, and 90 per cent. for Havre. Indeed, during the single decade from 1890 to 1900 the total net registered tonnage for the first three cities increased over 63 per cent., whereas for London, Liverpool and Havre the increase but slightly exceeded 13 per cent. For the year 1902 the total imports and exports of Hamburg were approximately $1,707,664,000 and for Antwerp $660,060,000, as opposed to $528,741,000 for Bremen, $1,260,290,000 for London and $1,138,700,000 for Liverpool. It is interesting also to note that the combined trade in tons of the four ports of Koenigsberg, Danzig, Luebeck and Stettin has increased by approximately 50 per cent. during the decade from 1890 to 1900, or at a rate not very much below that of Hamburg and Bremen. V. Construction of Canals and Canalization of Rivers. The extraordinary growth which we have just noted in the sea navigation of Hamburg, Bremen and the Dutch-Belgian ports can only be explained by their good connection with the German interior. It is the relation to a large and productive interior, more than any other factor, which determines the international importance of harbors, and Hamburg, be it said in this connection, is more favorably situated than any other city of the Old World. Its influence extends not only over most of Germany and Austro- Hungary, but, as regards certain commodities, even into Russia and Switzerland. Besides being the terminal of seven systems of railways, this port receives the traffic drained by an extensive network of inland waterways which carries its influence into central Europe. The Elbe and Moldau rivers, navigable for a distance of 582 miles, secure for Hamburg the trade of the region around the important centers of Magdeburg, Dresden and Prague. The Saale, Havel and Spree rivers drain the commerce of Thuringia and Berlin; while the Oder-Spree and the Finow canals make tributary to this port a large portion of the trade from Silesia, the whole Upper, Middle and Lower Oder, as well as the Warthe. In [532] Promotion of Commerce in Germany 103 large measure this extensive system of waterways is navigable for ships of 400 tons, and, in the main, does not require the payment of tolls. Bremen, as contrasted with Hamburg, is at a disadvantage when we consider inland navigation, its influence being confined chiefly to the relatively unimportant Weser. The Dutch-Belgian ports, however, derive traffic from the rivers and canals of nearly the whole of Northwest Europe. Besides controlling the trade of the numerous waterways of Holland and Belgium, they share in common the commerce of the Rhine. This river is navigable as far as Mannheim (a distance of 560 km.) for ships of 1500 tons, and to Strassburg (700 km.) for ships of 800 tons. Through its princi- pal tributaries-the Meuse, the Mosel and the Main-it also draws to these ports much of the trade drained by the numerous canals of France and Western Germany. The Meuse, for example, has been rendered navigable through canalization for ships of 300 tons for a distance of 600 kilometers. Through canals this river has also been connected with the Rhine, the Seine and the Sâone-Rhone, thus making tributary, especially to Rotterdam, much of the trade from all of Northern and Eastern France. The Mosel, navigable to Nancy for 200 ton ships, is likewise united with the system of French canals. The Main has been canalized so as to be navigable for ships of 1500 tons as far as Frankfort, for 120 ton ships as far as Bamberg, and from there has been connected with the Danube through the Ludwig canal. Proceeding still further up the Rhine, we find that Strassburg has been united with the whole of Alsace and with the Sâone and Rhone by means of canals which can accom- modate ships of at least 200 tons. This extended account of existing waterways is given with a view of showing the extent to which the State has assisted com- merce by constructing canals and canalizing rivers. The importance of such aid cannot well be overemphasized. Transportation by water has decided advantages over transportation by rail inso- far that cheap and bulky commodities can be carried much more cheaply over long distances, and, secondly, because tolls on those artificial waterways of Germany which belong to the State are levied strictly in accordance with the cost of maintenance and replacement. These two advantages of water transportation-cheap con- [533] 104 The Annals of the American Academy veyance for bulky commodities and a tariff policy varying with the cost of maintenance—are of fundamental importance in Ger- many where the railways constitute a State monopoly used largely as a revenue producing agency of the government, and where the leading manufacturing centers and the principal sources of fuel and raw material are situated remotely from the coast. This be- comes especially apparent when it is remembered that the receipts per ton-mile concerning the traffic on the rivers in Germany varies between 0.176 ct. and 0.519 ct., and upon the canals from 0.346 ct. to 0.692 ct., whereas for the railways the average earning per ton-mile in 1899 was about 1.42 cents. Roughly speaking, there- fore, the rates on the rivers and canals may be said to be about one-third as high as those charged on the railways. Moreover, there is the important consideration that subsequent to 1875 the average receipts per ton-mile on the waterways decreased about 50 per cent. as opposed to a decrease of only 15 per cent. on the railways." 4 Along with these low and declining freight rates has gone a marvelous increase in traffic. During the twenty years from 1877 to 1897 the number of canal and river boats increased 28 per cent.; the carrying capacity of these boats, however, increased during the same period to 3,400,000 tons or 143 per cent.; while the actual traffic increased 159 per cent. Practically all the recent canal projects of the country have in view the accommodation of 600 ton ships west of the Oder and 400 tons ships east of that river. In 1900 the canals and rivers carried approximately 24 per cent. of the total traffic of the country, the average haul being 320 kilometers or twice that on the railways. It is from the standpoint of the import and export trade of the leading ports, however, that the importance of interior water- ways has shown itself most prominently. By weight about one- half of the export trade to the Dutch ports from the region along the Rhine and about three-fourths of the import trade moves by river. Indeed, during the decade ending in 1900 the trade of Rotter- dam by way of the Rhine has nearly trebled and at present exceeds the railway traffic of the city by almost two times. Likewise, of the extensive trade between Hamburg and the region tributary H. R. Meyer: Railway Age, July 17, 1903. pp. 62. •Ibid. [534] Promotion of Commerce in Germany 105 to the Elbe and Oder rivers and the Oder-Spree canal, over four- fifths by weight and nearly three-fifths by value is carried by water. These figures illustrate the tremendous importance of inland navigation in developing industry and in enlarging the export trade. Yet in the effort to extend water-routes to every part of the Empire Germany has been only one of a number of European countries, which are all striving to accomplish the same end. Some notion of this activity may be gained from the statement that since 1830 Belgium has spent in the neighborhood of five hundred million francs on its inland waterways. France, according to its programme of 1879, has already devoted thirteen hundred million francs toward the improvement of its rivers, canals and harbors; while Austria and Russia are likewise executing extensive improvements along this line. In Germany, moreover, projects are under consideration, which, if carried out, will add greatly to the 5495 kilometers of artificial water- ways existing in that country. The Prussian Canal Bill communi- cated to the Landtag in January, 1901, proposed an expenditure of nearly four hundred million marks. Besides providing for the opening of the whole region of Silesia by means of canals, and the canalization of a number of important rivers, this bill empowered the government to construct a Rhine-Weser-Elbe-canal, an Oder- Vistula canal and a large waterway between Berlin and Stettin. The Elbe and Oder being already connected, this bill contemplates a union of the five great rivers of Germany which flow into the North and Baltic seas. Among numerous other projects may be mentioned the proposed enlargement of the Danube-Main canal, and the plan of Austria to unite the Danube with the Elbe-Moldau and the Oder. If these plans are realized, it will mean not only a union of the five great rivers of Northern Germany with their numerous tributaries and branch canals, and a continuous waterway from end to end of the German Empire, but through the Rhine will also mean a union of these waterways with the Seine, the Sâone and the Rhone. Moreover, the Danube will be connected through separate canals with the Rhine, the Elbe and the Oder, thus consti- tuting an uninterrupted water-route from the North Sea to the Black Sea. The principal obstacle to the realization of these larger plans is the opposition of the Agrarian Party. But Germany is rapidly outgrowing its agricultural conditions, and there is every [535] 106 The Annals of the American Academy reason to believe that an important form of State aid to commerce in the future, as in the past, will be the construction of canals and the canalization of rivers. VI. Influence of Preferential Railway Rates. In the foregoing pages the discussion has been concerning the improvement of harbors and interior waterways. It now remains. to discuss briefly the manner in which the State has endeavored to facilitate transportation by rail. Owing to the central position of Germany in Europe, her ports and railways must necessarily compete with those of the surrounding nations. To meet this competition and to assist in developing home industry and the export trade, the railway management of Prussia has from time to time introduced numerous so-called prefer- ential railway tariffs. In the main, these tariffs have also been adopted by the other German States, the various railway manage- ments presenting in this respect a united policy in the interests of the whole nation. Compared with the rates of other leading European nations, these preferential tariffs are conspicuously low, and are applicable at present to no less than 63 per cent. of the total railway ton-mileage of the country. 6 - A detailed examination of these preferential rates shows that they operate to the advantage of the German North Sea harbors. as opposed to the Dutch-Belgian ports, the Russian Black Sea harbors and the Austro-Hungarian ports on the Adriatic. Even at the expense of its own seaports, Prussia has granted preferential rates to Hamburg and Bremen in order to assist them in their compe- tition with the harbors of Northwest and Southwest Europe. Thus, for example, to divert traffic away from the Dutch-Belgian ports preferential rates are granted in the trade between the German coast and the Rhine-Westphalian region on tobacco, cotton, fish, coffee, rice and a variety of other commodities, the rate being as low for the distance from Essen to Bremen as for the distance from Essen to Amsterdam. Likewise, to counteract the influence of the harbors on the Adriatic and Black Seas, preferential rates are 7 "For a complete statement of all the preferential railway rates in force on the Prussian State lines in 1897, see the list prepared by Mr. W. S. H. Gastrell (British Accounts and Papers for 1898, vol. xcii, p. 54). For the most important additions to Mr. Gastrell's list of 1897 see the list prepared by Mr. Robert Collier (British Diplomatic and Consular Reports, No 574, Miscellaneous Series, Feb., 1902. A Report on Prussian Railways). "Wiedenfeld: "Die nordwesteuropaeischen Welthaefen," p. 322. [536] Promotion of Commerce in Germany 107 ww accorded to cotton, tobacco, coffee, rice, hides, iron ore, petroleum and a large variety of articles which are forwarded via Germany to Austro-Hungary, Russia or Roumania.8 Other instances may be mentioned to show that where the interests of German industry or international trade make it desirable, the German railway managements have not refrained from granting preferential tariffs without regard to the nationality of the port. To illustrate, the Dutch-Belgian ports, though deriving a large share of their trade from the interior waterways of Germany, are also dependent for another large portion upon the railways of Germany. It is true that much of their trade is diverted to the North German coast; but on the other hand, they enjoy the benefits of special rates in the exportation of such commodities as coal, grain, iron and other minerals and the importation to Southern Germany and Switzerland of products like coffee, tea, cocoa, pepper and rice. 9 One other important feature of the German system of rail- way rates remains to be noticed, namely, the so-called Levant and East African Traffic Tariffs. According to these tariffs, intro- duced respectively in 1890 and 1895, largely reduced rates are granted by the State railways to goods exported from the interior of the country to a large number of places in the Levant and East Africa, as well as to stations on the Oriental and East African railways. Aside from a reduction in the usual rates, these traffic tariffs also offer the advantage of sending goods on through bills of lading from the place of departure to the foreign point of destination. Summar- ized according to different classes of goods the reduction in freight afforded by this arrangement is as follows: "For the goods of Special Tariffs II and III only 1.5 to 1.7 pf. is charged instead of 3.5 and 2.2 to 2.6 pf., for the goods of Special Tariff I only 2.0 to 3.0 pf. instead of 4.5 pf., for all other goods in car-load lots only 3.0 to 3.4 pf., for piece goods only 3.5 to 4.5 pf. instead of 6 to 11 pf. per km". "10 In general the rates are about one-half as high as the ordinary rates and appear to be unusually low as compared with the tariffs of other European nations. The British Select Committee in its report on foreign ship subsidies for 1902 shows that the cost of transportation on the German railways, as concerns the Levant and East African tariffs, is only one-third to one-fifth as high for 8Wiedenfeld: "Die nordwesteuropaeischen Welthaefen," p. 322. Ibid. 10 Ibid., p. 323. [537] 108 The Annals of the American Academy a large number of commodities as the British rate and concludes that "these reduced rates have been and are fixed in accordance with the experience gained in Germany as regards the working cost per train-mile over long distances and that the primary object is the building up, promoting or increasing of German export trade to the countries in question and the enabling it to complete successfully with the trade of other foreign States to those countries." Summary of Results of Germany's Policy. From the foregoing review it must appear that State aid to commerce in Germany has been both liberal and general. It has manifested itself prominently in industrial and commercial educa- tion, in the development of the shipbuilding industry and the mer- chant marine, in the improvement of harbor channels and harbor facilities and in the construction of canals and the promotion of trans- portation by rail. Much of this assistance has been given by the States as distinguished from the Imperial Government. In the main, however, the several States have acted in harmony, and, as was seen in the case of Prussia, have not unduly emphasized local interests to the detriment of other parts of the Empire. Their funds have been expended judiciously and in a manner not at all prejudicial to national progress. Viewed from the standpoint of material results, the paternal attitude of the Government towards commerce has been productive of wonderful results. Since 1872 the import and export trade of the country has increased by 72 per cent. and 100 per cent., respec- tively, and the exports of £233,890,000 in 1902 compare very favor- ably with the British exports of £277,552,000 for that year. More- over, Germany has become a daring investor and promoter. Official estimates place her foreign investments at about five billion dollars, or a sum equal to half the foreign investments of Great Britain. The growth of her shipping has also been phenomenal. During the twenty years ending in 1900 Germany has increased the steam ton- nage of her merchant marine elevenfold; while the total tonnage has increased nearly fivefold. From fourth place which she held in this respect in 1880, she has risen to second and has increased her portion of the world's entire merchant fleet since that date from 6.6 to nearly 10 per cent. Her shipbuilding industry has sprung into existence almost wholly since 1871 and has developed [538] 1 Promotion of Commerce in Germany 109 so as not only to provide for the greater share of her own rapidly increasing demand for ships, but also to fill orders for other countries. In a word, the progress of Germany has taken place along all lines, in manufacturing, trade, shipping and shipbuilding. However important other factors may have been in bringing about this general advance, there can be no doubt that Germany furnishes an excellent example of the salutary influence which the State may exert in foster- ing those phases of commercial activity upon which the domestic prosperity and international prestige of a nation is principally dependent. SOLOMON HUEBNER. • [539] THE AMERICAN ACADEMY K MA POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE Former Presidents, EDMUND J. JAMES, Ph. D., President of University of Illinois (1890-1900) SAMUEL MCCUNE LINDSAY, Ph. D., University of Pennsylvania (1900-1902), SAMUEL MCCUNE LINDSAY, Ph. D., University of Pennsylvania. ".. Secretary JAMES T. YOUNG, Ph. D., University of Pennsylvania. PHILADELPHIA President, L. S. ROWE, Ph. D., University of Pennsylvania ܘ ܘܠܐ ܥ OF Treasurer STUART WOOD, Esq., 400 Chestnut Street, Philadelphia. University of Minnesota. HON. LYMAN J. GAGE, Vice-Presidents, RT. HON. ARTHUR J. BALFOUR, M. P London, England. PROF. C. F BASTABLE, Dublin Univeršity PROFF W. BLACKMAR, University of Kansas. PROF. R. T. ELY, Wisconsin University. PROF. HENRY W. FARNAM. Yale University. PROF. W, W. FOLWELL, WOODROW WILSON Ph. D. Princeton University VM New York, NY. DR KARL T. von INAMA-STERNEGG, Vienna, Austrla. FRANKLIN H. GIDDINGS, IL. D. Columbia University. GENERAL ADVISORY COMMITTEE .. Counsel HON, CLINTON ROGERS WOODRUFF North American Building, Philadelphia. Librarian, JAMES W. GARNER, Ph.D. University of Illinois PROF JOHN K. INGRAM, LL. D. Trinity College, Dublin, PROF. J. W. JENKS Cornell University PROF. FLEVASSEUR, Paris, France. PROF, AUGUST MEITZEN. University of Berlin. PROF. BERNARD MOSES. University of California PROF HENRY WADE BOGERS Yale University PROF LESTER F WARD, Washington, D. C. PROF. WILLIAM SMART, LL. D., University of Glasgow HON. HANNIS TAYLOR LL. D. Mobile, Alabama. 人地 ..... EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR BY JAMES DAVIE BUTLER, LL. D. From [FROM PROCEEDINGS OF STATE HISTORICAL SOCIETY OF WISCONSIN, 1894] June MADISON, WIS. STATE HISTORICAL SOCIETY OF WISCONSİN 10190- 1895 EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. 85 EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. ♥ BY JAMES DAVIE BUTLER, LL. D. [Address delivered at the Forty-second Annual Meeting of the State Historical Society of Wisconsin, December 13, 1894.] Walking down to the oldest pier in the city of Superior, I saw on the right the shattered wreck of a vessel. This ruin- ous heap,- keel, keelson, with ribs, as well as something of stem, stern, and sheathing, I was told to be all that remained of the "Algonquin," an old-timer which some people believed the first decked vessel that had reached the head of the lake. land and half on water, This amphibious mass, lying half on I perceived to be highly prized as a quarry of curios. The rusting spikes had tinged the water-logged oak with charming tints, and hence canes, chairs, and tables had been fashioned out of the hulk. Seeing these things, full both of associations and of intrinsic beauty, I quoted Shakespeare: "Nothing of it that doth fade, But hath suffered a sea change, Into something rich and strange." What manner of vessel the "Algonquin" had been, where she hailed from, when she was built, and when she perished, were questions I found no one to answer. Fortunately one of my friends in Detroit had been early in government employ on the great lake. By writing him I found what I sought, — that he had seen the "Algonquin" on the first day of June, 1840, at the Soo,' where she had just been dragged over the portage on ways and rollers. She was a schooner of about sixty tons, built in Lorain, a town about twenty miles west of Cleveland, by the Ohio Fishing and Mining Company in 1839. ¹ Modern popular name for the Sault Ste. Marie, connecting Lakes Supe- rior and Huron.- ED. ! 86. WISCONSIN HISTORICAL SOCIETY. C The first Methodist missionary, Pitezel, relates that in the fall of 1844 he had hoped to sail up the lake on the "Algonquin, but learned at the Soo that she had been chartered for carry- ing supplies to Fort Wilkins - a post which had been estab- lished at Copper Harbor the summer before. I find an account of the "Algonquin," which from 1845 was commanded by Capt. John McKay, who finally bought her as an active agent in de- veloping the settlement and commerce of Lake Superior. Ac- cording to a statement by the captain's son, her dimensions were fifty-four feet in length, twenty-six feet beam, five feet in depth of hold, ribs five by six inches spaced thirteen inches apart with one and a half inch planking. These figures may enable experts to estimate her real tonnage, which is variously stated: Steere says 50 tons, Hubbard 60, and Houghton 70. In 1853 she became the fishing smack of Captain Davis, and nearly a decade after died of old age. Growing leaky, she was abandoned, and sank not far from where her remains now lie. According to Voltaire, when men die old their death is not much noticed, in fact they scarcely notice it themselves. So fared it with the "Algonquin." Age is thrown into unregarded cor- ners. My inquiries about her had scarcely begun when I ascer- tained that she was by no means the first decked vessel on Lake Superior. Others came to my knowledge which were there be- fore her not only in 1835, and then in 1823, but in 1815 and even in the first decade of our century. The next surprise was, ascertaining that a bark of 95 tons had crossed the great lake many a time before the year 1800, and sometimes ten times in a single year. Nor was this all. In 1785 a schooner had ar- rived at the Soo for passing up the rapid, while another had been built above that descent in 1771, and yet another forty years earlier, or about 1731. In the lowest deep, a lower deep." In view of such disclosures one is ready to exclaim: We may next expect that the first land on which the ark of Noah rested will turn out to be the shore of Lake Superior, which geologists agree is the oldest spot on the face of the earth. HAD All sailing vessels on our grandest lake, during the last cen- ¹John H. Pitezel's Lights and Shades of Missionary Life (Cincinnati, 1883), p. 61.-Ed. Co 纂 ✩ "" } EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. 87 tury and the first four decades of the present, owed their exist- ence to fur. Throughout that period fur was king, and pre- eminently on that innermost lake. Hence, as early as 1679 DuLhut was already a fur-dealer on the site of the city which now bears his name.¹ There he feared no English or other rival. There he could laugh at restrictions which fettered traders in Canada. There furs were best and prices lowest. We cease to wonder that the furor for fur was born so early and lived so long, when we glance at the career of the Hudson's Bay Company, which was incorporated in 1670. Their price cur- rent for a beaver, when brought to their posts, was a quart of brandy, much watered; or, if preferred, a dozen needles, or twenty flints, or four fire-steels. What they thus bought they sold at such rates that for a hundred years their dividends never fell below sixty per cent. They realized the best specu- lation imagined by poets, which is: }} "To buy a fool up at the price he is worth, And sell him for that which he puts on himself." No modern speculator has better understood the three ground rules of success, namely, multiplication, division, and silence. Their watchword was "Mum." Hence, nothing in my research has been so hard as to ascertain what the Hudson's Bay Com- pany accomplished in ship-building on our grandest lake. The earliest builder of a vessel on Lake Superior, with sails larger than an Indian blanket, whose name has been discovered in the New Dominion archives at Ottawa, was La Ronde, a Frenchman, who about 1731 had already constructed at his own expense a bark of forty tons, though he was obliged to trans- port the rigging and other materials as far as the Soo in canoes.² His reward was the monopoly of the fur trade at La Pointe the only post on the south shore of the lake for a century after- ward. He thus became an autocrat there. Madelaine island, on Bellin's map, issued at Paris in 1745, is printed "Isle de La Ronde. M No doubt the Catholic church helped La Ronde in his ship- building, for he would give missionaries a free passage to an ¹ Parkman's La Salle, p. 257. 2 Minnesota Historical Society Collections, v., p. 425. " 88 WISCONSIN HISTORICAL SOCIETY. • $ inviting field—the asylum where their converts, when driven from Lake Simcoe by Iroquois, had found the safest refuge. He must also have been helped by some of those French who were then sanguine of success in opening a short-cut to China through the most western of mediterranean lakes. From that point, in 1722, Charlevoix tried hard to adventure to the Pa- cific. Others may have aided him as a prospector for copper, surface indications of which, and indeed Eshcol clusters, were abundant in his domain. In 1740 La Ronde was sick, and went to Montreal. In 1747 his son is mentioned as on his way to his father's western post. "! 1 2 It is a pity we know no more concerning the fates and for- tunes of the pioneer sloop. But if its career was as long as the "Algonquin's," it did not come to its end before companions of its own class had been launched on the same water. About 1766, Capt. Jonathan Carver spent a year in coasting Lake Superior. He states that the French, while they were in possession of Canada, had kept a small schooner on this lake. In the Calendar of Canadian Archives we have a notice of the loss of this vessel, soon after the conquest of Canada in 1763.² Agents now at work in Paris, as the New Dominion archivist writes me, may probably find what we so long for, regarding the earliest of white man's vessels on the innermost of lakes. La Salle's sloop, the "Griffin," launched just above Niagara in 1679, was never heard of after that year. The French never built another vessel on Lake Erie.. Upon the uppermost lake fur was of a better quality and far more plentiful, and trade safer from both English rivals and Indian hostiles. They therefore chose to build on Superior, and not on Erie. The date of the earliest launch in Detroit was 1769, and that by English. Within less than a decade after the British had mastered Lake Superior, another decked vessel was launched on its north shore at Point aux Pins. This point, where La Ronde and other French seem to have had their ship-yards, is seven miles above the Soo. One Henry Baxter had gone over to London, re- enforcing the reports of Carver with such stories about virgin (( ¹ Carver's Travels, p. 134. 2 Calendar of Canadian Archives, 1888, p. 64. t 1 EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. 89 copper, and such specimens of that mineral, that a company was there formed which furnished money for mining. Early in 1770, Baxter and his money-bags were at the Soo. He joined with Alexander Henry, a trader from New Jersey, as well as Boston agents and partners, who composed a company for working Su- perior mines. In August, 1770, they laid the keel of a sloop of 70 tons, and during the following winter finished a barge. Henry says: "Early in May, 1771, we departed [in our barge] from our ship-yard three leagues from the Soo. We crossed to the south side of the lake, and coasted westward till we reached the Ontonagon, where we landed miners and arranged every- thing for their accommodation during the winter, and returned to the Soo. In the spring of 1772 the southern mine had caved in and was abandoned. Henry continues: "In August, 1772, we launched our sloop and carried miners to the copper ore on the north side of the lake. In 1773 we carried them as far as the river Pic [which is half way to Port Arthur] and sent copper to England, but the partners declined entering into. further expenses. So in 1774 Mr. Baxter disposed of the sloop."2 >>1 The failure of this enterprise is ascribed by the best authori- ties not to any mismanagement, but to the extreme difficulties of forwarding supplies, especially provisions, to the miners. But that the project was born out of due time, would at all events have been soon demonstrated by what Carver calls the dis- tracted situation of affairs "- meaning the outbreak of the Revo- lutionary War. No doubt the sloop fell into the hands of fur traders who well knew the value of such a craft for their busi- ness, and some of whose firms may already have made more than one vessel as large, regarding which no chronicle remains. How- ever this may be, nine years after Baxter's sale, when the North- west Fur Company was organized in 1783, one of their first endeavors was to secure a decked vessel on the chief lake. With this view, in 1784, they petitioned the military governor of Canada for permission to build a vessel at Detroit, to be sent early in the spring to the Soo, for the purpose of getting her ¹ Travels and Adventures of Alexander Henry, pp. 226-234. 2 Ibid. "" w 90 WISCONSIN HISTORICAL SOCIETY. up the falls and to be employed on Lake Superior. They showed that canoes could not supply their demands, but that a large vessel was needed to carry merchandise and provisions to the Grand Portage,¹ and was indispensable for the prosecution of their trade in furs.2 Their petition was promptly granted, and a schooner named the "Beaver was at once constructed. Her dimensions were, keel thirty-four feet, beam thirteen, and hold four feet; cost £1,843 13s 2d. She arrived at the foot of the Soo in May, 1785. For some unexplained reason, however, it proved impos- sible to bring her then over the portage.³ But no doubt the "Beaver" was either brought over another season, or some similar craft was very soon prepared. For such a vessel became a necessity immediate and constant. The head- quarters of the Northwest Company were established about thirty miles west of Port Arthur. The spot was called Grand Portage because by a land-carriage of nine miles from that point. goods reached navigable water on Pigeon river. Through this stream, and others interlocking, they could be transported in canoes to multitudinous posts, many of which thanks to felici- tous positions — could intercept Indian trade which had before gone to Hudson's Bay. But in order to equip these posts the same year, merchandise must arrive at Grand Portage by mid- summer. For this purpose, the utmost dispatch was demanded in the transit from the Soo. Otherwise goods forwarded from Montreal at the opening of navigation could not be brought to their market till the close of the second season. Manifestly they needed something which could bestride the waves like a colossus, when shallow bauble boats of weak, untimbered sides, that did not fly to harbor, became a toast for Neptune. • We have a description of such a vessel which in the last year of last century was, it may be, already a dozen years old. Har- mon, a Vermont boy who had enlisted in the fur company's serv- ice, had made his way to the Soo in thirty-three days from Mont- "} C 2 Cal. Canad. Arch., 1888, pp. 64–72. 3 ³ Id., 1890, p. 50. → ¹ See Wis. Hist. Colls., xi., pp. 123-125, for historical sketch of Grand Portage.-ED. EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. 91 "" real, on the last of May, 1800. He there at Pine Point in- spected the company's vessel and was informed by the captain that she would carry as many as ninety-five tons, and that she made four or five trips to Grand Portage every season. A saw- mill at the Soo was preparing lumber for her to transport, and a canal had been cut on the Canadian side so that loaded canoes might need no portage for conveying their freight to the vessel.¹ In 1798 the Northwest Company had had a British garrison for a decade at Grand Portage; they had in their pay 1,205 employes; and as no crops were raised at their posts they were forced to carry food as well as other supplies over the lake—an additional proof that they must have early provided on that water a vessel with larger sails than Indian blankets. The crowning proof, however, lies in the fact that such a vessel-named the "Speed- well —was afloat there in 1789, and flying the flag of their most formidable competitor, the Hudson's Bay Company.2 The rivalry of competing corporations is now fierce, but it is tame compared with that of the clashing fur companies. For their thrusts and counter-thrusts I find no parallel, save in the odium theologicum between the Greek and Latin churches. In their ecclesiastical antagonism it is reported that when one party was proud of a skull of Peter, a twelve-year-old fisher boy, the other produced the skull of the selfsame Peter, full grown and chief of the apostles. It could not have been long after the Hudson's Bay men hoisted their banner on the "Speedwell" be- fore she encountered a foeman worthy of her steel, and battling for the Northwesters. A proverb declares: "Where'er for God we holy churches rear, Beside them Satan's chapels soon appear." Which company gave proof of the more devil-wit it would be hard to decide. During the first years of the nineteenth century, several other decked vessels appeared on Lake Superior. At the beginning of the year 1812 the Northwesters reported to the Canadian government that in case of war they would put at its disposal ¹ D. W. Harmon's Journal, p. 37. 2 U. S. Service Mag., ii., p. 458. Article by a medical officer on the lake fleet in the War of 1812-15. 92 WISCONSIN HISTORICAL SOCIETY. } 井 one vessel of 120 tons that could carry six or eight guns, and another of 60 tons.' Nor were these two the whole of the Superior fleet, for in July, 1814, three others were captured by the Americans, namely: the "Perseverance," of 85 tons, the schooner "Mink," of 45 tons, and the sloop "Nancy," of 38 tons. As an indemnity for two of them, £3,500 were paid the company by the British government.2 There was yet another schooner on the uppermost lake before 1812, This was the "Recovery," which through fear of Ameri- can privateers was secreted in one of the deep-water canyons at the northeast end of Isle Royale. Her spars were taken out, and being covered with brushwood she lay undetected until the termination of hostilities. Then, put again in commission, she was after a while run down the rapids, and under Captain Fel- lows she was engaged in the Lake Erie lumber trade. Wrecked at last near Fort Erie, opposite Buffalo, her skeleton there was long pointed out to strangers. 3 It is possible that the Northwest Company had no sailing vessel on Superior after the war which closed in 1815. An act of Congress in 1816, which forbade their doing business within the limits of the United States, led them to sell out to John Jacob Astor, who styled himself the American Fur Company. But their sale may have included more than one vessel. More- over, it is certain that in 1822 a schooner bearing the British ensign was sailing on Lake Superior. This vessel was, com- manded by Lieutenant Bayfield of the British navy, who in that year and the next made a far better survey and chart of that lake than had been hitherto attempted. This service for the admiralty was rewarded by the immediate promotion of Bay- field, who at length became an admiral; and it is fitly com- memorated in the name of a Wisconsin city and county. 4 If Astor had bought no decked vessel he probably built one His need of such a craft was similar to that of the com- soon. * Sid ¹ Mich. Pion. Colls., x., p. 68, and Cal. Canad. Arch. 2 These three vessels seem to have been at first reserved by the fur company for carrying on their business during the war. T. Houghton, Mineral Region of Lake Superior (Buffalo, 1846). 4 Major Long's Expedition, ii., p. 181. ? } EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. 93 pan y he had supplanted. Having hired the same men who had done the work of the old company, he would naturally adopt their methods. The Wisconsin Historical Society has published a list of his employes in 1818 and 1819. More than one-fifth of them appear on that roster as stationed at Fond du Lac that is, operating at posts radiating from the head of Lake Superior. Of these fifty-eight Fond du Lac agents, eleven drew salaries of $1,000 or upward. One was paid $2,400. In 1834 the timbers and planks for the brig "John Jacob Astor" were fashioned at Charlestown, Ohio, and the next spring they were carried to the Soo on the schooner “Bridget. The keel of the "Astor was laid above the falls May 17, 1835, and she sailed for La Pointe on the 15th of August. She was rated at 112 tons, and after nine years was wrecked at Copper Harbor in the equinoctial storm of Sept. 21, 1844. It is hard to believe that Astor, succeeding to the business of the North- west Company, waited well-nigh a score of years before follow- ing their example of ship-building, or that his first experiment was on so large a scale as his namesake brig. In regard to the Hudson's Bay Company's vessels on Superior, mention has been made of the "Speedwell" as there in 1789. The 'Whitefish" was chronicled by Bela Hubbard as at the Soo in 1840, and she was but two or three years younger than the "Astor." The "Elizabeth" and the "Isabel" are described as two others of their navy. They are well remembered by the older inhabitants of the Soo. In 1837 the American Fur Company built the "Madelaine," of about 20 tons, sailed by Captain Angus, and employed chiefly in fishing. Within two years she was stranded at the upper end of Minnesota Point. This wreck was much talked of in the " "} 1 1 Wis. Hist. Colls., xii., p. 170. Sky "" spring of 1839, when Vincent Roy first came down St. Louis river. The "William Brewster," a schooner of the American Fur Company, was of 73 tons and launched in 1838. Her frame was prepared in Euclid, Ohio. Having run down the rapids in 1842, she then saw service on Lake Erie. In regard to steam vessels, the "Sam Ward" is erroneously 94 WISCONSIN HISTORICAL SOCIETY. 1 believed by some to have been the first on our largest lake. The truth is, that that craft was not seen there before 1848. It seems certain that the first steamer was the "Independence,” a propeller of 280 tons. It was 1845 when she first arrived in Copper Harbor. This propeller's maximum speed in good weather was four miles an hour. In the same year in which she had been drawn over the portage, Vincent Roy came in her to La Pointe, which she reached November 1, 1845. In 1846, another steamer, also of 280 tons, the "Julia Palmer, " appears. According to Judge Steere, her bones are still visible some eight miles west of Point Iroquois. In that year, 1846, the census of the Lake Superior navy, as made by Jacob Houghton, was as follows: Nine sail vessels, namely three of seventy tons, "Algonquin," "Swallow," "Merchant; " four of forty tons, "Uncle Tom," Chippewa," "Fur Trader, "Siskowit; one. of fifty tons, the “Whitefish.” + (( }" "" It Two years earlier, in 1844, mining had begun in earnest, an industry which multiplied both steamers and sail vessels. was, however, the completion of the ship canal at the Soo, opened May 21, 1855,- and pre-eminently the deeper canal of 1881,- which broke down the barrier between sea-going ships and our central sea. In 1883, the completion of the railway from the Pacific to Duluth first made Lake Superior the mediter- ranean highway of commerce from farthest West to farthest East. Now the last and greatest need, the one thing needful, is deep waterways the Toronto international convention's end and aim. We mark the advance of navigation on Lake Superior as we contrast the "Beaver," I have described as built in 1784, and the "Northwest," built a century and a decade later. The former's keel was thirty-four feet, the latter's length was 400, wanting one rod; thirty-four feet was the depth of one, the other's was four; the ancient vessel cost $9,000, the modern a hundred times more; the one could give no real accommodation to a single passenger, the other could carry 400 amid more tasteful surroundings than I have discovered in most Old World palaces. Last summer I was in such a company from end to end of the great lake. As to electrics, the "Northwest" surpassed every EARLY SHIPPING ON LAKE SUPERIOR. 95 one of the three and twenty sea-going steamers which had borne me around the terraqueous globe. In no point was it far be- hind ocean grey-hounds. On the Inland Sea of Japan, the "Kobi Maru" pleased me so well that I longed to imitate Peter Schlemihl, who clapped whatever took his fancy into a magic So I threatened purse, and when he had need took it out again. the captain that I would purse up his ship and crew for launch- ing on all oceans I should encounter in rounding the world. Happy the traveler who shall carry in his pocket the new- crowned empress of our most imperial lake, or who shall traverse that lake of lakes encompassed in her arms. Furs, alike for their beauty and utility, have been coveted the world over and through all ages. They are equally service- able for a glory and for a covering, so that nature affords noth- ing better to warm a monarch than the fur that has warmed a bear. The finer varieties beaver, otter, mink, marten, and wild cat were early discovered by the French and their successors to be at their fullest and best, as well as easiest to procure, either in a ring around Superior, or in regions to which that water was the royal road. It is therefore no wonder that large vessels began to be constructed at an early day, and that they continued to be fabricated so long as that country continued to be the hunter's paradise, whether he sought ermine for judges, or sables for settled age or the light and careless livery of youth. J Again, ship-building must needs grow with the growth of mining industries, which sprang up in luxuriant life as soon as the the lacustrine copper and iron treasuries were revealed richest deposits known. Added to this the discovery of wheat oceans westward, balanced by the miraculous movement of coal from the east, giving ship-masters assurance of freight both ways, have given birth to the witty inventions of the world- famous whale-backs," and raised the tonnage on our chiefest lake to more millions than pass through the Suez canal, that conflux of commerce from all the continents. The exports alone, the current season, are valued at more than a hundred and fifty millions. " After all, iron and copper mining on Lake Superior — tributary — — 96 1 WISCONSIN HISTORICAL SOCIETY. agriculture westward, and coal-digging eastward are still in their infancy. The greatest is behind. When they have done their perfect work, what shall Superior navigation become? It must be something worthy of that lake's peerless magnitude and felicitous position at once the key to both oceans, and the bond of perfectness to unify them both. We see much, but we see only Modą "The baby figure of a giant mass Of things to come at large,” which in the r seeds and weak beginnings lie intreasured. HF 1009 P18 Foreign Trade Figures A Collection of Statistics Covering some Features C of the World's Commerce and Indicating the Share in it of the United States ISSUED BY THE BUREAU OF INFORMATION OF THE PHILADELPHIA COMMERCIAL MUSEUM The Philadelphia Commercial Museum L AND ITS BUREAU OF INFORMATION : L The Philadelphia Commercial Museum is a public institution and is a part of the museum system of the City of Philadelphia. Its object is to maintain collections which will be of both academic and practical value to anyone interested in commerce whether from a scientific or a business point of view. The Bureau of Information is that branch of the Museum organization which aims. to make the resources of the institution available to American exporters in securing and handling foreign trade. During the more than ten years that it has been in operation the Bureau has built up systems for collecting and giving out commercial information which have brought splendid returns to a large clientele. Full particulars of the service will be supplied upon request... J The Philadelphia Commercial Museum, 34th street below Spruce, Philadelphia, Pa. U. S. A. 1790 1795 1800 1805 1810 1815 1820 1825 1830 1835 1840 1845 1850 1855 1860 1865 1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1906 • YEAR • · • · Population 3,924,214 5,308,483 7,239,881 9,638,453 12,866,020 17,069,453 23,191,876 31,443,321 38,558,371 50,155,783 62,622,250 76,303,387 83,143,000 84, 154,000 A Century of American Trade Total Trade $ 43,205,156 117,746,140 162,224,548 216,166,021 152,157,970 165,599,027 144,141,669 180,927,643 134,391,681 251,980,097 221,927,638 219,224,433 317,885,252 476,717,211 687,192,176 404,774,883 828,730,176 1,046,448, 147 1,503,593,304 1,319,716,084 1,647,139,093 1,539,508,130 2,244,424,266 2,636,074,737 2,970,426,946 *A Total Exports 20,205, 156 47,989,872 70,971,780 95,566,021 66,757,970 52,557,753 69,691,669 90,738,333 71,670,735 115,215,802 123,668,932 106,040, III 144,375,726 218,909,503 333,576,057 166,029,303 392,771,768 513,442,711 835,638,658 742,189,755 857,828,684 807,338, 165 1,394,483,082 1,518,561,666 1,743,864,500 Per Capita $13.37 9.22 7.22 5.57 7.25 6.23 10.61 9.77 16.43 13.50 17.96 18.26 20.72 Total Imports 23,000,000 69,756,268 91,252,768 120,600,000 $5,400,000 113,041,274 74,450,000 90,189,310 62,720,956 136,764,295 98,258,706 113,184,322 173,509,526 257,SOS, 708 353,616,119 238,745,580 435,958,408 533,005,436 667,954,746 577,527,329 789,310,409 731,969,965 849,941, 184 1,117,513,071 1,226,562,446 Per Capita $17.19 II.80 7.71 4.86 5.76 7.48 11.25 11.06 12.51 12.35 10.88 13.40 14.58 N YEAR · 1905. 1906. Exports of Merchandise from the United States Grouped by Articles According to Source of Production. 1880--1906 Manufactured Product Value Per cent of total ធំៗ 1880 1885. 1890 1895 183,595,743 23.14 1900 433,851,756 31.65 Agricultural Product Value Per cent of total 38 $102,856,015 12.48 $685,961,091 530,172,966 72.91 147,187,527 20.25 151,102,376 | 17.87 629,820,808 74.51 553,210,026 69 73 835,858, 123 60.98 543,607,975 36:44 820,863,403| 55.03 603,227,836 35.11 969,457,306 | 56.43 | Mineral Product Value Per cent of total 83.25 $ 5,863,232 Forestry Product Value Per cent of total & 5 Fishery Product Value Per cent of total Miscellaneous Value Per cent of total .71 15,797,885 2.18 22,014,839 | 3.03 5,955, 122.82 | 22,297,755 2.64 29,473,084 3.49 7,458,385.88 16,509,814 2.33 28,576,235 3.61 5,328,807.67 4,171,974.52 37,843,742 2.76 52,218,112 3.81 6,326,620.46 4,665,218 | .34 50,968,052 3.42 | 62,122,378 4.17 7,241,025.48| 6,941,806.46 53,055,261 3.09 75,512,311 4.40 8,212,820.48 8,487,848 |.49 Total Exports $17,321,268 2.11 $5,255,402 .64 $6,689,345.81 $ 823,946,353 5,554,607.76 726,682,946 5,141,420.61 845,293,828 793,392,599 1,370,763,571 1,491,744,641 1,717,953,382 3 Growth of Exports of Manufactures The exports of manufactures for the year 1905 show an increase of 25 per cent. over those for the year 1900. While this gain is just cause for satisfaction, some analysis of the figures is necessary in order to obtain an adequate idea of their real significance. If the increase in manufactured exports is to be taken as in any sense an accurate measure of the intelligent energy being exercised in the extension of the foreign sale of American manufactured products, it is necessary to give some attention to the conditions under which such increases as have taken place have been brought about. In order to understand what real progress is being made in the matter of exports by the rank and file of Ameri- can manufacturers it is necessary to eliminate from the total such lines of manufactured goods as are sold abroad under conditions other than those of normal, open competition. To do this it is necessary to eliminate four general classes of goods: (1) The exports of manufactures which are chiefly sold through the selling departments of large industrial combinations, such as refined mineral oil and some of the more important articles manu- factured of iron and steel. (2) Exports of manufactures whose foreign sale is largely in the hands of a very few concerns. These articles include such lines as gunpowder, electrical machinery and locomotives, which, while not handled by the selling departments of trusts, owe the extension of their foreign sale not so much to the energy and intelligence of American manufacturers in general as to the organizing ability of a very few concerns. (3) Exports of manufactures in which there is no competition in the usual sense. These articles include books, patent medicines, and other lines, which might be classed as specialties, and the foreign sale of which is, perhaps, due to a very high grade of selling ability, but can in no sense be said to reflect any credit on the energy of the American manufacturer in general. (4) The exports of manufactures, the sale of which is due to peculiar conditions rather than to sales energy. These include such goods as wood, copper and cotton cloth, the sale of which is due rather to natural monopoly than to any display of well directed energy. The elimination of these four classes leaves something more than sixty items from the list of manufactured products in the official export statistics issued by the Bureau of Statistics of the Depart- ment of Commerce and Labor in which competition may be said to be relatively free and sales conditions normal. These classes together represent a value equivalent to about one-third of the total exports of manufactures and the gain which they have made represents with a reasonable degree of accuracy the progress made in the development of American export trade in lines where competition exists. Of course, any such treatment as this of the export figures must necessarily be more or less arbitrary and some of the lines cannot be placed with any degree of accuracy, but, when due allowance. has been made for any such misunderstandings as may arise from the arbitrary character of this classi- fication, we believe that the 16.5 per cent. of gain which appears as the increase for the competitive. lines during the five year period ending with 1905 is a considerably more accurate measure of the real progress made than in the 25 per cent. apparent gain shown by the total figures for exported manu- actures as prepared by the Bureau of Statistics. 4 1J Exports of Manufactures. 1900--1905 Showing the Percentage of Growth in Lines Exported Under Normal Conditions Exports of manufactures Exports of manufactures chiefly sold through selling departments of large industrial combinations • Exports of manufactures in which there is no competition in the usual sense • Exports of manufactures whose sale is due to peculiar conditions rather than sales energy Exports of manufactures whose foreign sale is largely in the hands of only a few concerns Exports of the remaining more than sixty classes in which competi- tion is relatively free and sales conditions normal • 1900 $433,851,756 157,608,401 7,019, 127 93,088,885 30,379,524 145,755,819 1905 $543,607,975 174,285,605 12,201,865 148,455,001 38,953,280 169,712,224 Gain $109,756,219 16,677,204 5,182,738 55,366,116 Per cent Gain 23,956,405 25.0 10.4 74.0 59.5 8,573,756 28.0 16.5 5 > Articles exported chiefly through selling departments of large industrial combinations Agricultural implements. Cars, passenger and freight. Iron and steel-Pig, scrap, bar, rods, billets, hoop, rails, sheets, plates, struc- tural, nails and pipes Oil, mineral, refined Paraffin and paraffin wax Tobacco and manufactures of Paper and manufactures Spirits, distilled. Sugar, refined, and confec Matches Starch. Cycles and parts Lead and manufactures of Zinc and manufactures of • • Gunpowder & other expl'vs . Sewing machines Typewriters Electrical machinery Shoe machinery Pumps and pumping mach'y Laundry machinery Fire engines Locomotives Safes Sole leather · • • • Patent and prop'y medicines, Books, maps and engravings, Cash registers Art works 1900 • $16,099,149 $20,721.741 3,542,677 3,154,008 36,791,352 68,247,588 8,602,723 Export articles handled by a very few concerns 95,422 2,604,362 3,553, 149 6,010,141 5,690,203 6,213,833 8,238,088 2,278,111 1,569,622 331,057 1,669,215 1905 1,430,572 3,859,671 667,194 1,319,619 $157,630,301 $173,285,608 1900 43,893,919 73,433,787 7,789,160 $1,891,604 4,541,774 2,697,544 4,340,992 1,163,265 3,112,525 441,562 2,572,152 1,462,659 52,834 $2,559,837 6, 104, 279 4,745,285 7,290,932 1,273,015 3,116,088 518,800 16,856 3,617,010 266,305 9,444,873 14,915 5,592,403 149,637 6,433,303 $30,379,614 $38,953,280 Articles in which there is no competition in the usual sense of the word 1900 1905 1905 $2,999,153 2,943,435 813,096 263,443 $ 4,911,005 4,844, 160 2,036, 107 410,593 $7,019,127 $ 12,201,865 Articles whose sale abroad is due to peculiar condi- tions rather than to sales energy Cotton, manufactures of Wood, manufactures of Copper, manufactures of Blacking Brass and manufactures of . Bricks Brooms and brushes Candles Carriages Chemicals. drugs, etc. (not patent medicines. Clocks and watches Coffee and cocoa, prepared Earthenware, stoneware and china Fertilizers • Competitive exports not controlled by monopolies or combinations Fibers, vegetable and mfrs. Glass and glassware India rubber, g. p. and mfrs., Ink Instruments, scientific, etc. Iron & Steel (builders' hard- ware, car wheels, castings, cuttlery, firearms, steam stationary engines, boilers, wood working and miscel- laneous machinery, scales, stoves and unenumerated iron and steel • • Jewelry Lamps Leather (glazed kid, patent and enamel, splits, buff, etc.. Boots and shoes Saddles and harness All other mfrs of leather, Lime and cement . Malt liquors, Marble and stone mfrs Musical instruments 1900 Oils, vegetable (not cotton, corn or linseed . Paints and colors. Perfumery and cosmetics Platedware $24,903,087 $49,666,080 11,232,838 12,563,630 57,852,960 86,225,291 $93,088,885 $148,455,001 1900 $880,598 1,866,727 516,481 232,968 191,687 2,809,784 9, 133, 220 1,977,694 231,509 576,702 841,857 4,441,839 1,936,119 3,123,925 259,776 6,435,766 62,254,403 I, 143,638 978,874 15,363,854 4,276,656 505,467 1905 713,730 249,016 2,139,216 1,556,772 1,958,779 811,503 1,902,367 359,827 509,776 1905 $ 599,366 3,025,764 642,501 327,083 701,357 3,596,758 9,549,485 2,316,414 362,270 880,827 734,612 6,766,809 2,252,799 5,508,664 438,886 8,172,980 61,849,794 1,419,225 1,579,125 18,613,469 8,057,697 502,660 1,318,046 I,549,765 1,012,808 1,055,220 3,144,787 490, 139 3,126,317 490,297 703,783 6 Competitive exports not controlled by monopolies or combinations.-(Continued). Silk manufactures Soap Stationery, except paper Stereotype and electroplates, Straw and palm leaf mfrs. Tin and manufactures of Toys Continents Africa. Asia. Europe North America* . Oceania . South America *Exclusive of United States. Continents • Africa. Asia. Europe North America*. Oceania. South America 1900 * Exclusive of United States. 252,608 1,774,024 592,427 48,877 402,861 387,381 216,512 Total $265,909,677 919,131,980 6,124,983,479 353,580,979 317,449,733 520,402,059 1905 Trade of the World by Continents and the United States' Share A Five Year Comparison Total 620,572 2,670,231 41,838 502, 132 751,602 506,638 Trunks and bags . Varnish 1900 EXPORTS Vinegar Wool, manufactures of Miscellaneous manufactures To United States $ 6,476,420 88,557,040 454,058,485 15), 391,271 29,744,965 120, 198,063 1900 IMPORTS • From United States Per cent to U. S 2.4 9.6 7.4 45.9 9.3 23. I Per cent from U. S. $ 388,057,594 $ 15,700,725 885,872,793 50,659.974 5.7 7,989,380,386 1,396,043,328 17.4 387,638,866 204,001,966 52.6 285,025,616 28,079,603 329,085,680 9.8 44,707,799 13.6 4. I Total $349,635,021 1,354,241,022 7,292,165,378 508,250,984 395,565,837 764,792,363 Total 1900 $371,071,502 1,441,802,712 8,795,290,759 533,586,189 291,979,881 521,775,013 119,777 620, 104 231,728 791,578 12,583 1,300,362 9,844,575 17,158 2,035.954 10,753.984 $145,753,955 $169,852,249 1905 To United States $ 7,862,255 124,641,636 590,030,449 271,751,916 1905 24,933,545 129,982,326 1905 From United States! Per cent to U. S. 2.2 9.2 8.9 53.4 6.5 16.9 Per cent from U. S. 5.3 8.2 1,278,688,965 14.5 $ 19,866,077 118,205,536 286,192,167 53.6 35,417,982 61, 102, 107 12. I 11.7 7 • Trade of the World by Countries and the United States' Share A Five Year Comparison (Where it has been impossible to obtain 1905 figures, those for the latest available year have been taken. Figures marked (*) are for 1904; (†) 1903; (1) 1902; (§) 1901, EXPORTS Abyssinia Afghanistan Algeria Angola Antigua Argentine Republic Australia Austria Hungary • · • Bahamas Baluchistan Barbados Belgium. Bermudas ► • • Bhutan Bismarck Archipelago Bolivia Brazil British Central Africa British East Africa British Guiana . British Honduras British India British New Guinea British North Borneo British Somaliland British West Indies Bulgaria. • Countries Canada Cape Verde Islands Ceylon Chile China (proper) Colombia (1898) Congo Free State Costa Rica Crete Cuba Dahomey Denmark Dominica • Curacao and Dependencies. Cyprus Dutch East Indies Dutch Guiana • · • $4 Total 561,162 49,463,400 5,278,475 509,950 154,600,412 224,607,995 388,400,600 861,585 236,154 4,595,055 384,576,836 468,845 100,635 223,508 14,263,075 203,401,535 391,245 608,425 9,639,800 1,301,000 363,611,072 332,890 1,668,310 1,961,875 29,754,000 10,796,000 148,008,000 387,143 35,335,488 61,201,242 105,997,834 18,487,000 10.097,650 6,821, 195 1,118,087 51,452,614 168,070 1,867,210 2,555,175 106,272,000 334, 105 92,234,5II 2,308,690 1900 To United States ✡A 321,000 335,080 6,882,763 23,426,570 7,587,000 593, 150 2,505,825 15,372,200 427,995 360,000 87,333,960 4,189,950 352,000 25,398, 166 8,895, 164 12,800 Per cent to U. S. 1,865,430 65,805 II, 140,756 1,260,365 .6 65 7 4.4 10.4 1.9 60.9 54.5 3.9 87 4 2.5 42.9 43.4 27. 6.9 29.8 .I 37,049,000 2,200,978 2,331,381 9,834,420 6,837,000 37. 3,683,445 53.9 33,615,627 65.3 10,825 25. 6.2 3.7 9.2 5 1.7 19.7 12. I 52.9 Total †$1,310,000 2,207,333 45,752,600 *5,609.578 *580,920 322,823,841 276,626,370 435,685,000 948,688 *3,165,475 4, 190, 112 466,735,295 770,310 *302,518 11,821,218 219,255,222 242,265 1,173,320 9,557,030 * 971,319 525,694,343 *337,530 *2,136,336 *883,230 29,254,448 29,592, 137 203,316,872 †201,680 34,063,236 96,801,355 166,358,583 10,376, 104 8,138,152 2,244,880 110,167,484 *306,270 *2,330,650 *2,228,301 134,190,000 $333,065 *107,447,648 *1,538,505 *. 1905 To United States $ 324,200 200 24,304 88,130,157 208,480 35.9 15.717.458 5,108,894 23,721,200 4.8 1.8 5.4 674.544 1,396,225 18,458,965 711,321 10 394,000 2,626,017 512,549 32.438,477 10,489,212 282,300 77,404,071 2,718,549 15,623,812 14,918,024 3,836,427 95,330,095 17.455 Per cent to C S. 4,408,020 53,565 10,839.320 452,305 .7 70. 32. I 3.9 92.3 .2 40.2 32.7 27.4 52.8 6. I 34. .9 38. I 7.9 16. I 8.9 47. I 86.5 .7 3.2 16. IO. 29. 8 Export Trade of the World-(Continued) Ecuador. Egypt Falkland Islands Federated Malay States Fiji Islands Formosa. France French Congo French Guiana French Guinea French India French Indo China French Somali Coast Gold Coast Greece Gambia German East Africa German South West Africa Germany Greenland Grenada. Guadeloupe Guam Guatemala Iceland Italy Ivory Coast Jamaica Japan • Hawaiian Islands Hayti. Honduras Countries • Kameroon Korea. · • • Mayotte . Mexico Labuan Lagos Leeward Islands Liberia • • Madagascar Malta Marshall Islands Martinique Mauritius • Montserrat Montenegro Morocco Mozambique • • • • • • · • • • Total $7,677,138 $5,620,570 557,695 19,307,464 3,099, 180 5,265,000 821,740,000 1,510,000 I,271,000 I,744,080 1,856,669 27,587,445 138,602 1,200,525 1,046,575 I, 188, 150,000 2,672,115 20,747,774 85,000 1,558,405 7,393,000 I,275,000 5,000 1,740,020 2,642,475 267,649,250 1,614,918 9,340,400 99,031,773 I, 210, 200 4,719,935 517,635 3,638,395 1,505,055 2,124,975 32,357,833 121, 189 1,696,970 10,341,833 261,986 80,278,538 33,990 491,650 8,323,718 38,510 1900 To United States $ 1,589,720 5,214,785 483,000 51,040,009 28,855 109,900,000 113,390 1,505,019 159,375 I, 200,009 ,009 1,157,610 24, 282,500 5,910,320 26, 283, 198 17,245 560 871,906 61,912,514 Per cent to U. S. 20.7 6. I 9. I 6.2 2.2 9.3 4.2 7.2 10.2 94. I 66.5 • 9. 63.2 26.5 1. I 8.4 77.1 9,605 28.3 Total $ 10,642,096 101,801,425 *837,250 *26,848,492 3,437.827 *11,411,215 919,013,000 2,427,092 †2,380,000 †2,781,505 *6.109, 510 30,913, 123 * 3,299,603 1,401,360 2,237,641 +860,877 1,364,131,000 7,241,975 *16, 185,000 89,750 1,565,928 *2,586,654 70,261 8,237,755 36, 128,650 2,472,890 *2,823,400 329,522,000 *2,056,945 6,992,061 160,766,805 *1,900,667 *3,538,975 *820,765 *5,095,265 1,631,742 * *576,786 4,510,000 42, 220, 120 *145,838 *2.635,255 II, 231, 137 *3,871,492 104,260,225 *100,070 *583,600 +8,612,850 1,178,811 1905 To United States $2.564,549 6,284,240 219,000 715,000 57,389,020 42,000 135,750,000 96,860 839, 142 297,479 573 36,069, 109 2,054.540 39,189,600 3.738,193 47,004,535 5 28,805 368,675 69,984, 709 6,130 244,889 Per cent to U. S. 24. I 6. I 6.3 6.2 6.2 1.8 9.3 1.3 5. I 18.9 8 99. $3. 11.9 53.4 28.9 1.7 .8 67. I 6. I 2.8 Export Trade of the World—(Continued) 9 Nepal Netherlands Nevis St. Christopher. New Caledonia Newfoundland and Labrador . New Hebrides. New Zealand • Nicaragua. Northern Nigeria Norway Oman. Panama Paraguay Persia. Peru • Countries Reunion. Rumania • Philippine Islands Portugal. Porto Rico Portuguese East Africa Portuguese Guinea Portuguese India • Russia in Europe Russia in Asia. St. Lucia St. Pierre and Miquelon St. Vincent ■ • Salvador Samoa Santo Domingo Sarawak. Sardinia. Senegal. Servia. Seychelles. Siam Sierra Leone Sikkim South Africa • • Southern Nigeria Spain Straits Settlements Sweden Switzerland Tahiti. Timor (Portuguese) Togoland Tonga Islands Tripoli Trinidad and Tobago ▸ Total $3,124,411 678,600,576 434,460 1,713,050 8,863,950 251,600 66,239,805 3,961,015 443,915 47,695,528 1,359,893 2,652,067 13,785,853 22,489,995 19,750,068 35,171,064 332,979 125,000 3,490,000 56,000,086 365,793,250 I, 147, 180 2,693,490 488,845 250,000 5,224,000 2,608,518 6,586,425 13,304,392 241,399 16,196,315 1,813,705 116,097 52,626,835 5,968,020 167,224,433 127,803,000 105,960, 179 167,215,940 607,805 134,220 764,750 533,965 2,092,500 12,922,745 1900 To United States $31,696,987 342,780 1,033,075 2,293,980 I, 147,215 532,764 55,982 4,774,485 3,522, 160 625,752 310 1,831,000 198, 150 27,470 3,554,000 • I,540 132, 100 3,490,423 13, 159,000 17,586,000 292,255 282,500 3,962, 195 Per cent to U. S. 4.7 78.9 11,6 3.4 28.9 moo I. I .4 21. I 17.8 1.7 .5 17.2 IO.2 68. 2 .2 10.3 10.5 48. I 13.5 30.6 Total *4,995,003 799,694,017 *642,490 2,003,315 10,669,000 78,279,735 *3,926,000 *764, 105 58,631,000 1,746, 155 *1,086,000 *3,178,819 *20,381,960 *20,333.195 32,352,615 †31,596 45! 18,248,948 †1,734,083 $342,540 *526,289 *2,716,536 *52,374,467 548,537,390 40,858,420 837,212 *1,532,077 252,595 5,647,698 506,960 6,880,890 *2,718,644 *5,984,178 *12,431,213 269,344 32,014,475 †1,657,990 +78,370 186,821,591 *8,593,585 169,393,000 132,592,301 *111,146,000 193,864, 200 570,665 *82,006 *887.759 553,640 *1,932,800 12,045,800 1905 To United States $38,689,627 13,270 1.419,000 3,556,550 2,089,000 981,990 1,049,000 49,672 1,900,005 15,668,026 781,164 15,527,265 1,897,525 7.484 1,419,000. 9,387 I,242,403 8,350 4,484,271 200 62,711 5,926,000 15,958, 150 25,009,816 369,805 3,380,498 Per cent to U. S. 4.9 2. I 13.3 4.5 53.2 1.6 96.6 .2 9.3 48.4 2. I 80. ·3 • .8 92.6 3.6 22. 1.6 65. I 3.5 12. 12.9 64.8 28. 10 Export Trade of the World-(Continued) Tunis Turks Island Turkey, Asiatic Turkey, Europea i Uganda United Kingdom United States Uruguay Venezuela. Virgin Islands Zanzibar Countries Algeria Angola Antigua Arabia Abyssinia Afghanistan • COUNTRIES • Argentine Republic Australia Austria-Hungary • Bahamas Baluchistan Barbados Belgium. Bermudas • Bolivia Brazil British Central Africa British East Africa . British Guiana British Honduras British India. British New Guinea British North Borneo British Somaliland British West Indies Bulgaria. · Total $8,512,040 166,945 1,261,453,225 1,394,483,082 29,442,205 $ 14,900,000 14,060 5,838,970 Total 817.041 64 763.600 6,366,887 626,520 113.485,069 206,630,095 337,261,600 1,676,345 436.593 5,226,260 443.150,593 1,985.680 5.337,645 98,813,790 950, 120 2,213,990 6,593,505 1,198,792 251,014,935 253,546 1,589,464 2,262,515 1900 32,709,000 9,268,000 To United States Trade of the World by Countries and the United States' Share A Five Year Comparison Where it has been impossible to obtain 1905 figures, those for the latest available year have been taken. Figures marked (*) are for 1904; (†) 1903; (‡) 1902; and (3) 1901. ' IMPORTS $ 6,260 128,570 186,719,775 1,671 955 7,722,564 ** 1900 From United States 406,385 6.8 789,000 228.535 13,428,539 20,413,265 30,564,600 1,129,480 1,787,660 53,334,800 1,253,645 326,162 12,259,690 Per cent to U. S. 3,040 126,500 1,881,610 708,403 5,005,412 . I 76.9 11,894.520 48,000 14.8 5.6 51.8 Per cent from U. S. 1.2 36.4 11.8 98 8.9 67 5 34.2 12. 63.7 6. I 123 .3 5.7 28.7 مين 59 9 1.9 Total 36.3 .5 $ *15.336.355 119,490 $38,460,000 $16,020,000 336,875 1,605.053,000 1,743,864.500 39,763,573 17,930,316 *22,780 5,603.250 Total $ †1,061,500 3.522,036 76,777,400 *8,335,000 *714,825 205,154,420 186,620,758 455,487,000 1,446,573 *4.976,474 5.203,728 613,667.352 3,077,728 8,195.508 145,835,803 1,103,585 2,590, 175 7,380,437 1,876.550 348,042,485 *378,160 *1,448,131 *1,457,300 37,012,390 24.449.987 } 1905 To United States GA $20,210 99,035 96,000 236,410,040 1,969 095 2,832,629 1905 5 319,310 From United States 500,000 672,005 257,580 28,920,443 21,834 796 68,234.800 1,070,360 1,717,903 44.453,217 1,435,929 685,362 14,796,336 1,100 163,000 2,128,704 957,481 5,128,449 Per cent to U. S. 12,790,325 283.428 1 83.1 28.5 14.7 4.3 35.7 5.7 Per cent from U. S. $47.1 .8 36. 14. I II.7 14.9 73.9 33. 7.2 46 6 8.3 IO. I .I 63 289 51. 1.4 34.6 I. I 11 Import Trade of the World-(Continued) Canada Cape Verde Islands Ceylon Chile China (proper) Colombia Congo Free State Costa Rica Crete Cuba Dahomey Denmark Dominica Curacao and Dependencies Cyprus Dutch East Indies Dutch Guiana Ecuador. Egypt. Countries • • • Falkland Islands. Federated Malay States Fiji Islands Formosa France French Congo French Guiana French Guinea French India French Indo China. French Somali Coast. Jamaica Japan Gambia German East Africa German South West Africa Germany Gold Coast Greece Greenland. Grenada. Guadeloupe Guam Guatemala • Hawaiian Islands Hayti Honduras • • Iceland Italy. Ivory Coast • • + Total $ 180,804,316 3,127.615 38,181,415 46,916,421 140,713,614 11,085,000 4,620,410 4,934.550 2,215,211 70,079,214 1, 100, 130 1,862,960 2,954.245 I12,374,000 400, 720 70,428,832 3,069,410 6,574,270 70,561,850 334,740 15,645,878 1,749.450 6,758,000 939,560,000 2,110,000 1,884,000 2.428,320 962, 200 23,084,898 1,185,822 972,040 2,786, 200 1,260,750,000 9.005, 135 26,277,278 207.750 1,163,950 3,127,100 4,712,116 2,047,940 2,576,740 340,047, 132 1,816,175 9,221,660 143,630,992 1900 From United States $ 109,844.378 207,000 4.416,064 11,149,662 4,936,000 6,310 2,269,893 32.197,019 1,555 21,016,530 I 10, 140 1,117,053 591,350 1,680,910 1,446,650 36,519 756,000 101,900,000 190,466 57,460 254,200,000 00,00 515,635 723.570 332,860 1,134,485 45,263,000 Per cent from U. S. 4,002,640 31.380.598 609 .5 9.5 7.9 44.3 . I 46.2 45.9 . I 187 27.4 1.5 19 2 256 2. 2.7 JI 2 10.8 IO. I 2.3 16.9 5.7 2.7 27 7 3.401,257 72.4 1,524,985 74.4 36. I 133 43.4 21. I Total $261.435,000 †1,765.370 36, 108, 109 68,837,692 326,385,570 4.668,846 5.239,477 3.087,000 94,806,600 *1,175.545 *1,944,525 *2,136,247 124.942,000 * *455 440 *73.732,427 *3,083,125 *7,699,085 107,820,380 *290,775 *18,433,564 2,155,212 *11.497,377 902,056,000 1,811,630 †2,020,000 †3.588,575 *1,169,710 45,275,093 *2,533.276 1,525,905 3,584.722 †1,982,688 1,696,660,000 7,430,340 *27,171,000 183,250 1,247,176 *2,653,574 74,649 6,841,445 14,658,483 +3,538,975 2,362,760 3,127,400 401, 127,000 *3,512,280 8,187,466 244.269,008 1905 From United States $162,738.571 267.052 6,886,801 56,149 291 2,706,063 42,891,888 2,735 20, 105, 280 143, 160 1,291,155 636,200 2,399,945 2,438.425 32.383 361.500 110,884,800 202,000 53,090 126,425 251. 251,075,000 150,125 303,410 370,260 14,116 2,453,515 11,643,519 2,054,540 1,689,880 47,778,400 66,975 3,500,407 52.143.264 Per cent from U. S 62.2 7 IO. 17.1 51.4 453 . I 16 I 314 1.7 20.6 31.I 2.2 I. I 3. I 12.3 IO. 1.5 .2 13.5 .2 I. I 29.6 189 36.6 79.5 58.1 71.5 11.9 1.9 42.7 21.3 12 Import Trade of the World-(Continued) Kameroon. Korea. Countries Labuan Lagos. Leeward Islands Liberia Mayotte Mexico Madagascar Malta . Marshall Islands Martinique. Mauritius • · • Montserrat Montenegro Morocco. Mozambique. Nepal. Netherlands • • Nevis St. Christopher New Caledonia Newfoundland and Labrador. New Hebrides. New Zealand Nicaragua Northern Nigeria Norway. Oman. Panama Paraguay Persia . Peru. Reunion. Rumania n Philippine Islands Portugal. Porto Rico Portuguese East Africa Portuguese Guinea Portuguese India . • Russia in Europe Russia in Asia . • Salvador Samoa Santo Domingo Sarawak * · St. Lucia St. Pierre and Miquelon St. Vincent • • • Total $2,783,300 5.506,795 826,600 4.152.345 1,860,905 7,970, 175 37,171.445 109 850 3.823.795 10,661,666 112,324 65,412,727 134,555 590,345 6,292,257 5,617,270 8,249, 180 787,136,026 682,175 2,232,250 7,702,550 273,900 53,230,480 3.517,450 456.710 83.876,310 3,365.883 2,555 924 17,056,398 11,585,660 20,597,167 65,123,236 950,828 288,625 4.405,000 43.397,177 304,138,500 J 2,017,985 1,865,207 480,955 400,000 2,986,000 1,924,339 1900 From United States $ 26,135 700,255 6,560 1,237,635 253,146 33,880,000 20, 260 121,236,381 336,900 2,048, 120 5,309.365 1,407,500 4,609,710 61,690 109, 155 18,249 1,480.595 1,656,469 9,679,392 • 181,912 23,170,465 621,315 72,745 1,800,000 Per cent from U. S. .6 37.5 .I 32.3 2.3 51.8 15. 15.5 49.4 26.6 9.9 40. 5.5 1.8 4.2 . I 12.8 8. 14 8 .4 7.6 30.7 18.1 60.3 'Total $*2,291,918 *13,681,915 *1,150,510 *4,599,120 1,889.346 *642,676 6,239,680 48,679,295 *111,049 *3,093,940 8,981,466 *154,385 85,861,081 *104,425 *576,400 *13.353,935 6,721,094 *8,802, 163 1,030,918 335 *708, 145 2,145,000 10,279,000 64, 144,285 *3,202,000 *722,720 84,302,000 3,403,867 *759,000 *3.565.531 *30,802,892 *21,490,015 30,876,350 65 545,323 15,949,646 †7,202,972 546,596 1,806,218 *3,861,174 62,274,322 321,663,680 34, 184.735 1,804, 102 *1,246,137 361,291 4,341,304 720,465 2,738,828 *2,293.770 1905 From United States $903,000 10,875 720, 130 7,165 1,064,085 84.925 48.303,167 12,300 92,897,459 302,570 2,750,000 21,036,315 Per cent from U. S. 624,047 130,000 73.711 1,352,627 100,945 1,961,075 6.6 2 38. 1 .I 34.4 .9 56 2 11.8 9. 42.7 26.8 7,192,505 1,668,000 2,557,980 3. 133,000 39 522,000 68.8 125,297 512,085 3,964,535 5,761,498 6,663,060 13,387,457 II.2 52.1 3.5 1.6 18. 18.6 IO. I 80.8 6.5 34.5 10.4 20.4 31. 14. 71.3 Import Trade of the World-(Continued) 13 Countries Senegal Servia. Seychelles Siam Sierra Leone Sikkim South Africa Southern Nigeria Spain Straits Settlements Sweden Switzerland Tunis Turks Island • Turkey, Asiatic Turkey, European Tahiti Timor (Portuguese) Togoland Tonga Islands Tripoli Trinidad and Tobago Uganda United Kingdom United States Uruguay. • • • Venezuela. Virgin Islands. Zanzibar • • · " · Total $ 8,275,850 10,805,445 326,970 13.468,700 2,759,355 170,986 146,996,265 5,577,915 196,888, 189 152,852,000 144,432,477 222,221,940 695,255 195,461 879,200 444,590 2,497,500 12,501,290 12,302,850 147,820 2,615,375,865 849,941,184 23,978,006 8,560,000 16,935 5,580, 205 1900 From United States $ 218, 140 223,800 112,600 221,870 I1,555,395 30.265 21,172,495 913,000 2,479,833 12,262,000 327,085 3,027,025 391,810 III, 195 693,946,305 2,182,945 2,704,908 2,026 303,905 Per cent from U. S. 2.6 2. I .8 8. 7.8 .5 10.7 .5 1.7 55 47. 24.2 3. I 75. 26.5 8. I 31.6 11.9 5.4 Total $*9,969,348 12,185,281 263,262 20,759,335 †3.564,135 †120,380 158,406,642 *8.962,340 188,899,000 159,888,774 *153,732,000 271,845,000 * 599,635 *81,467 *1,724.500 354,340 *1,806,500 12,794,714 *16,676,885 141,150 $49,670,000 241,600,000 748,685 2,275,970,000 1,226,562,446 31,824,043 $5,425,000 *27,530 5,549,780 1905 From United States $ 402,120 149,955 284,690 175,205 14,508,871 40,520 20,453,751 1,059,622 2,560,176 11,385,874 298,230 3,296,782 190,225 93,825 107,280 577,865,255 2,375,019 1,948,000 4,520 378,990 Per cent from U. S. 4. I.2 1.3 5.2 9. I .4 10.8 6 1.6 4. I 49.8 24.9 I. I 66.5 14.2 25.3 7.1 35.9 16.8 6.6 14 Area, Population, and Exports and Imports By Countries Populations given are the most recent returns. Figures for exports and imports are for the year 1905, excepting those marked (*) which are for 1904; (†) 1903; and (†) 1902. Abyssinia. Afghanistan Algeria Angola Antigua Argentine Republic Australia Austria-Hungary Countries • Bahamas Baluchistan Barbados Belgíum Bermudas Bismarck Archipelago Bolivia Brazil British Central Africa. British East Africa British Guiana British Honduras British India British New Guinea British North Borneo British Somaliland British West Indies • • • • • Dahomey Denmark Dominica • Bulgaria. Canada Cape Verde Islands Caroline Islands Ceylon Chile. China (Proper) Colombia Congo Free State Cook Islands. • Costa Rica. Crete Cuba • ► · • • • · · • • · • • Dutch East Indies Dutch Guiana Ecuador Egypt ✔a • Curacao & Dependencies.. Cyprus • • • .. • • D Area: Sq. Miles 150,000| 3,500,000 215,400 184,474 4,000,000 4,739,556 4,119,000 34,953 4,794,149 3,782,347 484,800 170 1,129,400 2,972,906 241,133 4,404 132,315 166 11,373 19 20,000 617,478 3,342,594 45,404,267 57,146 1,049,808 199,514 7,160,547 20,206 400,000 1,576,248 14,344,118 924,106 40,980 300,000 90,277 2,500,000 295,122 7,562 1,766,642 39,668 294,361,056 350,000 90,540 31,116 175,000 68,000 300,029 12,010 37,200 3,619,819 1,480 370 Population 25,333 305,497 1,353,350 473,202 900,000 142 18,400 3,365 44,000 403 3,584 60,000 15,388 291 736,399 46,060 118,869 400,000 8,400 331,340 303,543 1,572,845 ✓ 53,244 237,002 1,000,000 2,464,770] 30,790 35,533,552 76,798 1,275,600 9,734,005 Total Exports $1,310,000 2,207,333 45,752,600 *5,609,578 *580,920 322,544,000 276,626,370 422,487,000 948,688 *3,165,475 4,190,112 466,735,295 770,310 *302,518 11,821,218 219,255,222 525,694,343 *377,530 *2,136,336 883,230 1,678,375 29,254,448 3,744,300 29,592,137 5,371,315 147,424 203,316,872 281,680 33,000 3,578,333 2,712,145 81,553 34,063,236 96,801,355 383,253,029 166,358,583 3,593,000 (98) 18,487,000 30,000,000 10,376,104 242,265 1,173,320 9,557,030 971,319 *143,220 8,138,152 2,244,880 110,167,484 *306,270 2,330,650 *2,228,301 95.467,000 333,065 *107,447,648 *1,538,505 10,642,096 101,810,425 Per Capita $ .37 .55 9.65 1.36 16.59 67.281 73.14 9.30 16.63 3.01 21.05 65.18 38.50 .75 7.51 15.28 .25 .46 32.38 24.89 1.78 1.07 12.20 2.94 17.43 7.92 37.85 1.91 2.47 9.52 35.67 .43 5.14 .34 17.04 27.60 7.40 · 70.03 5.77 9.83 2.23 38.74 10.84 3.02 20.06 8.34 10.45 Total Imports ‡$1,061,500 3,522,036 76,777,400 *8,355,770 *714,825 205,151,000 186,620,758 438,685,000 1,446,573 *4,976,474 5,203,728 613,667,352 3,077,728 *439,779 8,119,508 145,835,803 1,103,485 2,590,715 7,380,437 1,876,550 384,042,485 *378,160 *1,448,131 1,457,300| 37,012,390 24,449,987 261,435,000| †1,765,370 167,592 36,108,109 68,837,692 326,385,577 (98)11,083,000 4.668,846 *227,585 5,239,477) 3,087,000 94,806,600 *1,175,545 1,944,525, *2,136,247 124,942,000 455,440 *73,732,427 *3,083,125 7,669,085 107,820,380| Per Capita les .30 .81: 16.20 2.02 20.42 42.79 49.34 9.66. 25.39 4.73 26.63 85.77 153.65 1.97 5.15 10.16 1.19 1.03 25.01 48.02 1.18 1.08 8.27 4.86 22.05 6.53 48.67 12.00 5.06 10.09 25.38 .85 3.08 .15 27.32 15.82 10.18 66.27 22.18 8.20 2.14 50.70 14.83 2.07 40.19 6.01 11.07 15 Area, Population, etc,-(Continued) Ellice Islands Eritrea. Falkland Islands Federated Malay States.. Fiji Islands. Formosa France. Countries • French Congo French Guiana French Guinea French India French Indo-China French Somali Coast Gambia. German East Africa. Hayti.. Honduras • • • Iceland Italy. Ivory Coast Mayotte Mexico • German New Guinea German Southwest Africa Germany Gilbert Island Gold Coast Greece.. Greenland Grenada. Guadeloupe Guam Guatemala Hawaiian Islands • • · • • Martinique Mauritius • • • · • Monsterrat Montenegro Morocco Nepal . Jamaica Japan. Kameroon Korea . Labuan Lagos Leeward Islands Liberia .. Madagascar Maldine Islands Malta . • • • • · Marianne Islands Marshall Islands • • • • • • • · • • • • • • Area: Sq. Miles 14! 88,500 6,500 36,559 8,034 13,458 207,054 450,000 30,500 95,000 196 363,130 12,000 3,126 384,180 69,027 322,450 208,830 153 339,900| 25,014 46,740 133 688 150 48,290 6,449 10,204 46,250 39,756 110,550 116,000| 4,207 161,198 191,130 82,000 30 3,420 700 45,000 227,950 117 250| 158 380 729 140 767,261| 321 3,630 219,000 54,000 Population 2,400 450,000 2,009 763,184 124,230 3,059,235 38,961,945 10,000,000 44,010 2,200,000 275,094 18,230,000 50,000 85,784 6,703,000 110,000 200,000 56,367,931 50,000 23,455,600 2,645,177 11,893 68,253 182,110| 9,000 1,364,678 154,001 1,425,000 543,741 78,470 33,476,117 2,000,000| 803.838 47,812,138 3,500,000| 10,519,000 8,411 85,607 128,235 2,129,000| 2,505,240 30,000 202,134 2,000 13,000 203,700 383,864 11,640 13,605,919 13,127 228,000 5,000,000 4,000,000 Total Exports 104,888 *562,933 837,250 *26,848,492 3,437,827 *11,411,215 919,013,000 2,427,092 †2,380,000 2,781,505 *6,109,510 30,913,123 *3,299,603 1,401,360 2,237,641 *13,568 +860,878 1,364,131,000 104,888 7,241,975 16,185,000 89,750 1,565,928 *2,586,654 70,261 8,237,755 159,541 1,275,000| 2,472,890 *2,823,400 329,522,000 *2,056,945 6,992,061 160,766,805 *1,900,667 *3,538,975 *820,745 *5,095,265 1,631,742 *576,786 4,510,800 *630,889 42,220,120 *38,444 *145,838 *2,635,255 11,231,137 *3,871,492 104,260,225 *110,780 *583,603 *8,612,850 *4,995,503 Per Capita 43.66 1.25 418.501 35.18 27.73 3.73 23.64 .24 54.09 1.47 22.07 1.69 65.00 16.35 .33 .12 4.30 24.20 2.09 .31 6.12 7.60 23.02 14.21 7.80 6.03 .38 .89 4.54 36.01 9.85 1.02 8.69 3.21 .55 .33 97.70 59.901 12.73 .27 1.80 21.03 209.01 19.22 11.21 12.93 29.25 333.73 7.66 8.51 2.56 1.72 1.25 Total Imports 11,407 1,555,453 290,775 *18,433,564 2,155,212 *11,497,377 902,056,000 1,811,630 †2,020,000 3,588,575 *1,169,710 45,275,093 *2,533,267 1,525,905 3,584,722 *141,626) 1,982,688 1,696,660,000, 87,537 7,430,340 27,171,000 183,250 1,247,176 *2,653,574 74,649 6,841,445 !3,014,964 4,900,000 2,362,760 *3,127,400 401,127,000] *3,512,280] 8,187,466 244,269,008 *2,291,918 *13,681,915 *1,150,510 *4,599,120 1,889,346 *642,676 6,239,680 *55,122 48,679,295 *29,942 *111,049 *3,093,940 8,981,466 *154,385 85,861,081 *104,425 *576,000 *13,353,935 *8,802,163 Per Capita 4.77 3.45 145.35 24.16 17.13 3.75 23.15 .18 48.18 1.63 4.25 2.45 50.66 17.80 .52 1.28 9.91 30.09 1.75 .31 10.27 15.52 18.18 14.59 8.29 5.01 19.57 3.43 4.34 39.89 11.97 1.75 10.18 5.10 .65 1.30 136.97 53.72 14.76 .30 2.49 1.84 240.96 14.97 8.54 15.16 23.12 13.30 6.31 8.03 2.52 2.67 2.20 ! Including trade with the United States, the exports of the Hawaiian Islands were $36,123,867 or $231.51 per capita; imports were $14,658,483 or $95.18 per capita. 16 Area, Population, etc.-(Continued) Netherlands Nevis New Caledonia. Newfoundl'd & Labrador New Hebrides New Zealand Countries · Nicaragua Northern Nigeria. Norway Oman Panama Paraquay Persia Peru • • Philippine Islands Porto Rico Reunion Rumania Portugal. Portuguese East Africa.. Portuguese Guinea Portuguese India . Russia in Asia Russia in Europe • Sarawak Senegal . Servia • Salvador Samoa Santo Domingo • • • St. Helena St. Lucia. St. Pierre & Miquelon St. Vincent • • · • Seychelles Siam. Sierre Leone Sikkim South Africa Southern Nigeria Spain Straits Settlements Sweden Switzerland Tahiti. Timor · • Tunis Turks Islands • • • • · Togoland Tonga . Tripoli. Trinidad and Tobaga • • • Turkey in Asia Turkey in Europe . • Area: Sq. Miles 12,648 85 7,600 162,734 5,852 104,751 49,000 258,000 124,129 82,000 31,571 122,095 628,000 695,916 127,853 3,606 35,490 293,400 13,940 1,558 966 50,720 6,220,440 1,996,743 47 233 92 133 7,225 1,100 18,045 50,000 806,000 18,630 149 200,000 4,000 2,818 909,613 51,500 194,783 1,523 Population 172,876 15,976 5,509,659 13,699 52,756 222,643 72,430 857,539 420,000 9,161,700 2,240,032 1,500,000 340,000 635,571 7,653,000 4,609,999 7,635,426 953,243 5,423,132 3,120,000 820,000 572,290 173,200 5,956,690 19,140,326 107,446,109 3,458 52,682 6,250 49,236 1,006,848 38,400 416,000 500,000 4,523,000 2,492,882 20,767 6,070,000 77,181 59,014 6,336,756 3,000,500 18,618,086 Total Exports 799,694,017 *642,490 2,003,315 10,669,000 251,600 78,279,735 *3,926,000 *764,105 58,631,000 1,746,155 *1,086,000 *3,178,819 *20,381,960 *20,333,195 32,352,615 !3,076,420 31,596,451 +1,734,083 †342,540 *526,284. *2,716,536 52,374,467 40,858,420 548,537,390 3,175 837,212 *1,532,077 252,595 5,647,698 506,960 6,880,890 *2,718,644 *5,984,178 *12,431,213 269,344 32,014,475 1,057,990 +78,370 186,821,591 *8,593,585 189,393,000 132,592,301 *111,146,000 193,864,200 Per Capita 570,665 *82,006 *887,7501 553,640 145.13 42.731 38.01 47.93 3.471 91.29 9.341 .08 26.17 1.16 3.19 4.99 2.66 4.41 4.23 3.22 5.82 .55 .41 .92 15.69 8.71 2.19 5.15 .91 15.91 247.69 5.16 5.60 13.20 16.54 5.43 1.32 4.99 13.01 5.27 21.53 1.33 29.48 2.86 10.16 230.91 21.64 56.47 35.00 Total .27 .59 Imports 1,030,918,335 *708,145 2,145,000 10,279,000 573,598 5,136,441 3,427,626 16,300 700 300,000 .27 1,500,000 1.15 20,223 27.68 17.71 1.93 1.80 7,458 33,700 374 389,900 1,754 51,000 166 693,610 65,350 1,000,000 290,800 *1,932,800 12,065,800 41.43 43.96 1,900,000 *15,336,355 5,300 119,490 16,898,800 (01)38,460,000] 6,130,000 (01)16,v20,000| 8.07 22.53 2.29 141,150 (01) 49,670,000 (01) 41,600,000| 8.77 26.62 2.94 2.61 6.78 ! Including trade with the United States, the exports of Porto Rico were $18,248,948 or $19.14 per capita; imports were $15,949,646 or $16.73 per capita. 273,900 64,144,285 *3,202,000 *722,720 84,302,000 3,403,867 *759,000 *3,565,531 *30,802,892 *21,490,015 30,876,350 ! 2,562,189 65,545,320 †7,202,972. *546,596| *1,806,218. *3,861,174] 62,274,322 34,184,735 321,663,680 263,935 1,804,102 *1,246,237 361,291 4,341,304 720,465 2,736,828 *2,293,770 *9,969,348 *12,185,281 263,262 20,759,335 3,504,135 †120,380 158,406,642 *8,962,340 188,899,000 159,888,774 *153,732,000 271,845,000 Per Capita 599,635 *81,467 *1,724,500 354,340 *1,806,500 12,794,714 *16,676,885 187.09 52.06 40.70 46.09 3.79 74.80 7.62 .08 33.16 2.26 2.23 5.60 4.02 4.66 4.04 2.68 12.08 2.30 .66 3.12 22.31 10.45 1.79 2.99 77.61 34.29 200.98 7.35 4.31 18.76 6.57 4.58 2.20 4.89 12.71 3.42 45.50 2.04 24.96 2.99 10.14 278.55 29.93 79.34 36.78 Area, Population, etc.-(Continued). 17 Uganda United Kingdom United States Uruguay Venezuela Countries • Virgin Islands Zanzibar • • Italy Japan Africa Asia Europe North America Oceania South America • • • • • Continents Countries Aus-.Hungary Belgium France. Germany · • Netherlands Switzerland · · • • • .. • • Area: Sq. Miles ! 150,000 121,391 3,026,789 72,431 533,937 57 1,020 Area: Sq. Miles 619,610,561 131,861,766 United Kingdom 605,485,585 United States 1,028,793,341| Population 4,000,000 41,976,827 84,154,000 964,577 2,444,816 5,143 200,000 1900 $359,434,665 326,598,780 605,980,000 1,072,075,000 202,912,800 21,426,280 Population Total Area, Population, Exports and Imports By Continents (Areas open to commerce only included.) 336,875 1,605,053,000 1,743 864,500 39,763,673 7,653,000 *22,780 5,603,250 $349,010,461 10,242,899 144,635,021| 13,124,950 861,394,768 1,354,241,022 3,786,008 400,688,773 7,292,165,378 2,252,115,484, 7,875,134 114,015,989 3,276,321 13,444,222 7,585,355 37,358,167| 395,565,837 764.792,363| Exports Total 1905 $397,422,561 362,286,920 631,540,000 1,089,716,305 219,274,400 35,150,823 717,599,598 146,367,428 563,716,305 1,088,467,292 Exports Gain or Loss $37,987,896 35,688,140 25,560,000 17,841,305 Experts Exports from and Imports into Ten Leading Commercial Countries by Continents 16,361,600 13,724,543 Per Capita 97,989,037 14,505,602 -31,769,280 59,673,951 .08 38.23 20.70 41.22| 3.13 4.46 28.01 (In these tables the figures given in the 1905 column for Austria-Hungary, France and Japan are for the year 1903, and those for Italy and the Netherlands, for 1904.) EUROPE Per Capita $ 2.41 1.57 18.19 19.75 29.42 20.47| Total 748,685 2,275,970,000, 1,226,562,446) 1900 $258,764,323 313,703,880 583,060,000 943,800,000 250,986,800 63,196,700 505,407,927 191,941,889 1,113,665,100] 440,567,314 Imports 31,824,042 †5,425,000 *27,530 5,549,780 Total Imports $371,071,502 1,441,802,712 8,795,290,750 1,760,148,635 291,979,880 521,775,013 Imports Per Capita 1905 $288,573,551 433,013,420 491,340,000 1,149,500,000 269,405,000 48,057,106 638,886,280 243,391,086 1,175,145,580 540,773,092 .18 54.22 14.60 32.92 2.21 5.39 27.79 Per Capita $ 2.53 1.67 21.95 15.43 21.71 13.97 Gain or Loss $29,809,228 120,309,540 -91,720,000 205,700,000 19,318,200 -15,139,594 133,478,353 51,449,197 81,480,480 100,205,778 18 Exports and Imports, Ten Leading Countries-(Continued) Countries Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy Japan • Netherlands Switzerland United Kingdom United States Italy Japan Aus.-Hungary Belgíum. France Germany • • Netherlands Switzerland Italy Japan • · • Netherlands Switzerland • Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy. Japan • United Kingdom United States .. • Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany · • United Kingdom United States .. • Netherlands Switzerland * • • • · • • ❤ ❤ ✔ NORTH AMERICA (exclusive of the United States). ↓ United Kingdom United States J 1900 $815,522 4,522,000 14,660,000 17,500,000 26,158,800 1,491,619 593,528 2,079,105 91,626,665 176,611,003 $1,631,939 6,443,920 27,520,000 47,225,000 20,105,200 9,044 2,016,980 3,416,230 148,973,805 38,337,647 $12,128,500 10,220,780 23,820,000 58,925,000 8,840,200 46,880,204 26,893,556 7,389,813 358,737,365 64,768,475 $6,590,453 7,865,880 83,000,000 18,325,000 8,760,000 138,976 1,952,696 1,607,371 158,724,280 19,449,393 Exports 1905 $1,109,818 14,387,960 15,700,000 44,975,000 39,935,200 1,497,880 735,644 3,782,015 99,160,940 247,445,486 $1,966,271 18,653,980 30,460,000 78,975,000 32,217,000 6,006 4,132,992 5,296,001 100,916,510 56,569,376 $9,156,520 22,732,800 20,300,000 83,200,000| 11,584,250 62,549,787 29,129,104 8,832,534 461,224,585 127,822,005 $6,897,308) 13,994,260 SOUTH AMERICA 91,181,600 30,800,000 12,719,600 161,332 3,611,456 2,204,055 Gain or Loss 168,853,945 18,469,899 $294,296 9,875,960 1,040,000 27,475,000 13,776,400 6,261 142,116 1,702,810 7,534,275 70,834,483 $334,332 12,210,060 2,940,000 31,750,000 12,118,000 -3,038| 2,116,012 1,879,771 -48,057,295 18,231,729 ASIA $-2,971,500| 12,512,020 -3,520,000 24,275,000 2,744,050 15,669,583 2,235,548 1,442,721 102,487,220 63,053,530 AFRICA $306,855 6,128,380 8,181,600 12,475,000 3,959,600 22,356 1,658,760 596,684 10,129,665 -979,494| 1900 $3,364,051 3,326,575 29,340,000 31,950,000 45,988,000 } 159,397 1,214,670 2,168,644 126,049,445 130,035,221 $11,780,521 40,384,600 42,360,000 128,125,000 11,428,400 5,340 45,541,580 5,002,227 135,132,465 93,666,774 $23,946,199 11,112,040 89,860,000 97,475,000 26,791,600 44,644,581 125,104,988 6,127,472 250,129,130 139,842,330 $7,760,332 7,523,340 65,820,000 36,775,000 5,259,800 734,049 3,793,368 3,998,303 108,074,390 11,218,437| Imports 1905 $2,510,025 4,279,540 33,050,000 36,015,000 49,030,600 250,339 3,561,688 1,297,889 153,700,050 227,229,145 $13,029,131| 69,802,260 97,680,000 200,600,000 11,798,200 1,713 45,992,872 6,495,376 168,357,565 150,795,800 $49,158,576 29,013,920 118,760,000 135,075,000 44,025,200 84,371,826 179,879,708 7,539,028 274,863,270 161,982,901 $7,516,746 17,011,960 86,540,000 61,272,000 7,587,000 1,200,799 4,727,364 3,829,602 131,275,650 11,343,622 Gain or Loss $-854,000 952,965 3,710,000 3,055,000 3,042,600 90,942 2,347,018 -870,755 27,650,605 97,193,924 $1,248,610 29,317,660 55,320,000 72,475,000 369,800 -3,627 451,292 1,493,149 33,225,100 57,129,026 $26,212,377 17,901,880 28,900,000 37,600,000 17,233,400 39,727,245 54,774,720 1,411,556 24,734,140 22,140,571 $-243,686 9,488,620 10,720,000 24,497,000 2,327,200 466,750 933,996 -168,701 23,201,260 125,185 Exports and Imports, Ten Leading Countries-(Continued) 19 Countries Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy Japan • • Netherlands Switzerland. • Italy Japan • · United Kingdom United States .. Countries • Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany. Italy Japan • · • Netherlands Switzerland. · • • • · Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany • • United Kingdom United States • • Netherlands Switzerland OCEANIA • • ·· United Kingdom United States • 1900 Exports from and Imports into Ten Leading Commercial Countries by Trade Route Groupings $212,618 2,957,040 3,380,000 13,825,000 • 870,240 2,541,219 139,588 836,198 (In these tables the figures given in the 1905 column for Austria-Hungary, France and Japan are for the year 1903, and those for Italy and the Netherlands, for 1904.) WESTERN EUROPE 124,951,950 42,803,712 1900 $283,618,765 306,958,880 525,880,000 750,050,000 123,458,600 17,526,616 611,466,004 112,142,133 558,698,025 985,910,284 Exports $81,245,590 23,431,980 147,100,000 184,325,000 89,182,400 4,038,637 8,286,696 21,417,588 1905 99,216,670| 44,204,558 $269,378 2,817,440 2,780,000 14,574,000 1,290,400 3,640,883 297,040 1,028,722 117,331,805| 32,970,583| Exports 1905 $306,550,098 337,030,840 539,380,000 773,650,000 128,484,000 28,973,022 Gain or LOSS 705,242,392 120,145,073 $56,700 -139,600 -600,000 $95,173,572 33,649,920 166,680,000 327,325,000 112,837,200 749,000 420,160 1,999,664 6,354,129 13,511,592 27,709,664 170,149,250 56,082,349 157,452 195,524 -7,620,145 -9,833,129 Gain or Loss 1900 $22,931,333 30,071,960 13,500,000 23,600,000 5,025,400 $2,208,286 7,523,340 22,520,000 31,900,000 $13,927,982 10,217,940 19,580,000 143,000,000 23,654,800 2,315,492 4,224,896 / 6,292,076 70,932,580 11,877,791 494,720 2,372,749 662,460 1,369,501 186,716,880 34,611,108 13,446,406 93,776,288 8,002,940 115,573,655 463,124,370 953,569,169 -32,341,115 THE MEDITERRANEAN 1900 $196,933,995 204,950,860 426,540,000| 699,950,000 186,952,800 59,211,642 473,577,664 142,920,450 1,037,325,115] 395,028,174 Imports 1905 $67,755,748 20,237,100 150,060,000 263,100,000 70,311,000 4,716,604 24,857,220 53,045,618 171,297,315 57,012,830 $1,067,030 15,389,720 20,800,000 41,750,000 695,600 2,313,853 1,848,204 2,030,487 203,520,980 25,388,421 Imports 1905 $219,976,010 378,517,620 390,560,000 867,575,000 206,690,000 44,968,097 607,771,348 184,440,686 1,108,601,695 482,555,152 $73,856,863| 57,675,860 174,920,000 361,025,000 Gain or LoSS $-1,141,250 7,866,380 -1,720,000 9,850,000 200,880 -68,896 71,428,600 4,289,805 32,644,600 63,304,067 219,652,150 72,885,691 1,185,744 660,986 16,804,100 9,222,687 Gain or Loss $23,042,015 173,566,760 -35,980,000 167,625,000 19,737,200 -14,243,545 134,193,682 41,520,236 71,276,580 87,526,978 $6,101,115 37,438,760 18,860,000 97,925,000 1,117,600 -426,799 7,786,380 10,258,449 48,354,835 15,872,861 20 Exports and Imports, Ten Leading Countries-(Continued) Countries Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy • Netherlands Switzerland · United Kingdom United States Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy · Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy · Netherlands United Kingdom United States • Netherlands Switzerland Italy Japan · • Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany. Italy Netherlands Switzerland • United Kingdom United States Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany ✔ • United Kingdom United States Netherlands Switzerland • • • · · EAST AFRICA · • United Kingdom United States 1900 $88,020 188,820 11,280,000 2,950,000 417,200 549,852 316,062 7,405,405 822,954 $590 2,797,860 6,440,000 7,550,000 144,200 1,247,940 21,779,660 871,659 $793,942 1,081,000 920,000 3,500,000 8,800 76,896 280,629 63,789,375 16,256,194 $1,382,344 6,371,520 9,880,000 30,472,500 17,995,000 38,440 2,735,815 73,514,155 24,495,005 Exports $241,273 1,896,320 14,340,000 14,925,000 2,055,600 1,713 13,828 549,966 1905 22,699,775 6,160,769 $54,464 372,300 8,300,000 2,980,000 470,800 788,944 261,607 18,054,785 2,214,341 239,092 ----54,455 10,549,340 1,381,387 AFRICA $720| 764,300 640,000 2,275,000 -5,000 615,180 437,175 2,670,685 SOUTH AFRICA $437,195 517,400 180,000 4,975 132,800 46,644 $1,310 3,562,160 5,800,000 9,825,000 139,200 1,863,120 22,216,835 3,542,344 WEST $356,747 1,598,400 1,100,000 8,475,000 141,600 123,540 248,261 Gain or Loss $----33,556 183,480 -2,980,000 1,984,104 4,320,583 108,698,365 36,435,097 6,006 2,784 750,577 30,496,440 10,870,197 30,000 53,600 ----32,368 81,801,595 18,012,240 11,946,100 -4,310,094 EAST COAST OF SOUTH AMERICA $1,644,185 15,980,700 21,420,000 11,540,000 56,600,000 26,127,500 29,745,400 11,750,400 1,945,664 1,584,768 35,184,210 11,940,092 $261,841 9,619,180 K 1900 $54,466 416,200 -8,340,000 22,425,000 214,400 4,293 ----11,044 200,611 7,796,665 4,709,428 $1,129,815 6,040 5,300,000 3,725,000 74,800 994,356 56,381 2,493,310 22,133 $99,096 540,000 8,160,000 12,775,000 5,000 1,772,056| 14,719,305 681,769 $32,043 6,520 WEST COAST OF SOUTH AMERICA $295,839 2,312,520 4,000,000 37,350,000 2,270,000 3,060,000 6,500,000| 1,000 42 208,698 19,965,345 1,039,182 $9,586,142 26,268,240 76,960,000 91,525,000 10,253,600 32,372,064 4,316,229 98,494,110 68,035,838 $2,171,956 320,040 17,560,000 28,675,000 1,174,800 5,340 11,949,580 113,889 31,440,260 10,759,769 Imports 1905 $30,500 147,560 7,300,000 5,025,000 770,800 129,308 34,184 2,903,445 968.507 $296,868 12,842,000 10,600,000 22,500,000 48,200 3,068,324 16,637,395 778,603 $68,408 1,163,200 3,520,000 9,025,000 4,000 43 118,558 27,707,310 628,249 $10,560,687 57,652,500 78,660,000 140,225,000 10,754,600 29,375,172 5,560,774 129,809,505 118,359,056 $2,409,116| 11,621,660 16,660,000 51,700,000 1,234,000 9,044 15,103,628 150,350 43,027,330 16,763,893 Gain or Loss $1,099,315 141,520 2,000,000 1,300,000 696,000 -865,048 22,197 410,134 946,374 $197,772 12,302,000 2,440,000 9,725,000 43,200 1,296,268 1,918,090 96,834 $36,365 1,156,780 460,000 2,525,000 3,000 1 -90,140 7,741,965 -610,933 $974,545 31,384,260 1,700,000 48,700,000 501,000 -2,996,892 1,244,545 30,315,395 50,323,218 $237,160 11,301,620 -900,000 23,025,000 59,200 3,704 3,154,048 36,461 11,587,070 6,004,124 (Exports and Imports, Ten Leading Countries-Continued) 21 Countries Aus.-Hungary Belgium France. Germany Italy Japan • Netherlands Switzerland Italy Japan United Kingdom United States .. Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany · Italy Japan • · • • Switzerland • • • United Kingdom United States Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Italy. . Japan • • Netherlands Switzerland Aus.-Hungary Belgium France Germany Netherlands Switzerland • • • United Kingdom United States United Kingdom United States • THE CARIBBEAN AND MEXICAN GULF 1900 $222,427 1,502,260 17,640,000 14,325,000 1,603,000 16,288 2,526,124 1,268,762 41,986,680 94,193,281 $9,278,243] 4,535,340 14,280,000 25,300,000 5,990,000 4,608,185 26,727,808 3,307,074 194,764,475 8,113,673 Exports $2,491,002 5,804,980 6,900,000 32,425,000 1,313,200 43,400,640 1,190,984 3,395,260 96,429,185 58,413,883 1905 $332,579 5,482,330 17,900,000 22,050,000 1,877,400 36,111 3,081,744 1,836,399 46,991,400 122,927,571 $169,701 2,752,140 580,000 5,450,000 85,800 1,461,769 4,340,936 61,707,165| Gain or Loss CANADA, NEWFOUNDLAND AND LABRADOR $74,916 3,156,380 520,000 5,000,000 324,300 1,475,331 1,681,620 40,633,550 90,045,256 16,880,000 22,700,000 $110,152 3,980,070 260,000 60,000 450,000 -238,500 13,562 2,659,316 21,173,615 133,779,997| 43,734,741 7,195,400 8,189,659 27,757,656 4,101,720 7,725,000 2,744,0001 19,823 555,620 567,637 5,004,720 38,734,290| SOUTHERN ASIA 267,639,400 21,583,594 $6,979,256| $-2,298,977 8,230,080 $94,785 -404,2401 143,007,045 112,060,099 3,694,740 2,600,000 -2,600,000 1,205,400 3,581,474 1,029,843) 794,646 72,874,925 3,469,921 EASTERN ASIA $2,115,341 $-375,661 14,702,480 8,897,500 2,960,000 45,475,000 863,400 55,197,936 1,380,692 3,937,675 -3,940,000 13,050,000 -450,000] 11,697,296 189,708 542,415 1900 46,577,860 53,646,286 $1,722,706 924,380 32,020,000 22,575,000 492,8061 1,063 2,443,204 1,593,126 21,090,915 104,974,555j $31,2821 13,720 1,780,000 1,600,000| 232,000 158,334 2,295,212 117,551,625| 39,931,833| $21,110,703] 101,500 43,560,000 78,825,000 10,536,000 17,573,121 124,994,900 2,254,256 203,419,540] 74,785,658 $2,056,532 62,300 47,760,000 13,650,000 12,296,600 28,713,605 Imports 132,136 3,782,309 33,235,655 66,894,311 1905 $1,393,329 2,118,600 27,920,000 28,800,000 623,800 819 5,075,760 1,724,086 25,387,455 179,279,276 $59,316 2,608,180| 2,000,000 2,450,000 638,200 249,519 719,708 131,021,025 63,653,861| $26,056,155 23,506,560 61,320,000 110,450,000 44,995,800 50,683,161 178,613,074 2,922,897 250,932,425 76,101,181 $2,604,870 3,086,800 58,100,000 16,475,000 17,299,000 33,899,569 1,281,880 3,937,143 22,294,605 92,502,553 Gain or Loss $329,377 1,194,220 --4,100,000 6,225,000 130,994 -244 2,632,556 130,960 4,296,540 74,304,721 $28,034 2,594,460 220,000 850,000 406,200 91,185 -1,575,504 13,469,400 23.722,028 $4,945,452 23,405,060 17,760,000 31,625,000 34,459,800 33,110,040 53,618,174 668,641 47,512,885 1,315,523 $548,338 3,024,500 10,340,000 2,825,000 5,002,400 5,185,964 149,744 154,834 -10,941,050 25,608,242 22 Exports and Imports, Ten Countries-(Continued). Countries Aus.-Hungary Belgium France. Germany Italy Japan Netherlands Switzerland Aus.-Hungary Belgium France. Germany. 1850 United Kingdom United States 1860 • 1870 1880 1890 • 1900 Italy. Japan United Kingdom United States • • • · • • ... • • ·· AUSTRALIA AND NEW ZEALAND 1900 $128,509 2,817,500 1,640,000 11,975,000 868,000 1,265,262 115,208 836,198 135,308,365 26,583,784 1 $84,109 1,700,000 525,000 800 647,393 953,720 484,517 Exports 1905 $197,881 2,635,160 1,060,000 12,675,000 1,284,000 1,676,232 290,792 1,028,720 117,089,010 26,263,186 Gain or Loss $69,372 -182,340 -580,000 -18,219,355 -320,598 700,000 416,000 410,970 175,584 192,522 20,000 50,000 4,000 479,498 -397,640 24,496 p " 1900, $750,639 5,706,760 18,360,000 30,550,000 487,600 1,227,969 662,408 1,369,500 177,081,005 5,468,196 OCEANIA (exclusive of Australia and New Zealand) 3,040 $71,497 $- 12,612 3,040 1,680,000 575,000 4,800 1,126,891 556,080 $1,457,646 150 1,600,000 800,000 509,013 Imports 2,632 1,231,920 516,481 1905 $717,507 15,343,720 13,560,000 39,475,000 683,860 599,967 1,833,004 2,030,487 201,905,995 11,892,914 $359,523 2,140,000 1,600,000 3,104 2,273,605 837,603 Comparison of the Course of Foreign Tonnage with that of Coast- wise Tonnage and the Progress of the Foreign Trade of the United States since 1850 Gain or Loss $-33,132 9,636,960 -3,800,000 8,925,000 196,260 -628,002 1,170,596 660,987 24,824,990 6,424,718 $1,098,123 -150 540,000 800,000 382 1,041,685 321,122 U.S. foreign trade - Imports and exports U.S.tonnage employed in the foreign trade U.S.tonnage employed in the coastwise trade m 1905 Foreign and Coastwise Tonnage, etc.-(Continued). 23 Year 1850 1860 1870 1880 [1890 1900 1905 Tonnage Employed in the Foreign and Coastwise Trade of the United States In Foreign Trade • 1790 1800 1810 1820 1830 1840 Year 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1850. 1860 1870 1880. 1890. 1900 1905 • Imports 1,439,694 2,379.396 1,448,846 Foreign Trade of the United States--By Sea $ 178,138,318 362,166,254 462 377,587 652,812,281 748,629,048 805.5 8.675 1,038,787,801 1,314.402 928,062 816.795 943.750 Exports $151,998,720 400, 122,296 529,519,302 829.799.730 824.878,782 1.283.999.941 1,355,063,232 In Coastwise Trade 1,797,825 2,644,867 2,639,247 2,637 686 3.409.435 4,286.516 5.441,688 Total $ 330.137.038 762,288,550 991,896,889 1,482,612,01 1,573 567,830 2.089.528,616 2,393,851,033 The tonnage employed in the foreign trade increased 65 per cent from 1850 to 1860 and was accompanied by an increase of 130 per cent in the value of the foreign trade, which was almost as great a percentage of increase in the foreign trade as there was in the next thirty-eight years. The foreign tonnage decreased 60 per cent since 1860, while the coastwise tonnage has increased over 100 per cent since that date and the value of the foreign trade by sea has increased 215 per cent. Proportion of United States Foreign Trade Carried in United States Vessels 1905 24 1790. 1800. 1810. 1820. 1830. 1840. 1850. Percentage of United States Foreign Trade Carried in United States Vessels 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1905 • · • • Year • Imports 4I. 91. 93. 90. 93.6 86.6 77.8 Exports Year 40. 87. 90. 89. 86.3 79.9 65.5 Total Trade 40.5 89.0 91 6 89.4 89.7 82.8 72.1 1860 1870 1880. 1890. 1900. 1905. Year • $507,247,757 352,969.401 258,346,577 202,451,086 195,084, 192 290,607,946 • Value of the Total United States Trade by Sea Showing Portion Carried in United States and in Foreign Vessels • United States Vessels Imports 63.0 33. I 22.9 16.7 12 9 15.5 Foreign Vessels Exports $255,040,793 638,927,488 1,224,265,434 1,371,116,744 1,894,444,424 2,103,201,462 70.0 37.7 13.1 9.4 7.I 9.6 Total Trade 66.5 356 17.4 129 93 12. I Total by Sea $ 762,288,550 991,896,889 1,482,612,011 1,573,567,830 2,089,528,616 2,393,809,408 The percentage of trade carried in United States vessels has steadily decreased since 1830, but the great break occurred after 1860, largely caused by the war and the change from wooden to iron ships, and not only the percentage has decreased since 1860, but also the value, which was not much more than half as much in 1905 as in 1860. If we allow only 10 per cent for freight and insurance, the amount paid to foreign ship owners is over 200 million dollars annually. } K Commercial America In July 1904 the Bureau of Information of the Philadelphia Commercial Museum began the publication of COMMERCIAL AMERICA, a monthly journal designed for circulation among foreign buyers of American goods, and prepared with the sole object of conveying information of interest and value to anyone desiring to build up trade with this country. The two and a half years of operation of this undertaking have demon- strated the importance of the field it aims to occupy and have paid a very gratifying. compliment to the methods adopted for conducting the paper's work. The Classified List of American Manufacturers which appears in each issue as a feature of this publication has yielded thoroughly satisfactory results, and taken in con- nection with the Buyer's List made up from it, forms a valuable list of American ex- porting manufacturers which is coming to be recognized by foreign buyers as a standard. On at least the two points of convenience and frequency of revision it is without an equal. } SOUTH AMERICA The Philadelphia Commercial Museum still has on hand a few copies of the Com- mercial Encyclopedia of the South American Continent. This is a collection of com- mercial monographs treating separately each of the South American republics. Each section has a complete gazetteer of the country covered. There are eleven maps and a 'full index. The volume contains just the information required by exporters interested in the South American countries. Sent postpaid to any part of the United States for $3.50. 1 ; R → stapletený katalog BOARD OF TRUSTEES OF THE Philadelphia Museums Daniel Baugh, WILSON H. Brown, THEODORE N. ELY, W. W. FOULKROD, ELLIS A. Gimbel, SIMON GRATZ, 1 EX-OFFICIO THE GOVERNOR OF PENNSYLVANIA. THE MAYOR OF PHILADELPHIA. THE PRESIDENT OF SELECT COUNCIL. THE PRESIDent of ComMON COUNCIL. THE PRESIDENT OF THE BOARD OF PUBLIC EDUCATION. THE SUPERINTENDENT OF PUBLIC SCHOOLS. THE STATE SUPERINTENDENT OF PUBLIC INSTRUCTION. THE STATE FORESTRY COMMISSIONER. BY APPOINTMENT W. S. HARVEY, CHARLES F. Warwick, "; DANIEL BAUGH, WILFRED H. SCHOFF, į DANIEL BAUGH, WILSON H. BROWN, OFFICERS OF THE BOARD President. W. S. HARVEY, W. W. SUPflee, W. T. TILDEN, CHARLES F. WARWICK, W. P. WILSON, SYDNEY L. WRIGHT. Vice-President and Counsel. Treasurer. Secretary and Asst. Treas. EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE W. W. SUPPLEE, Chairman. THEODORE N. ELY, W. S. HARVEY. DIRECTOR OF THE MUSEUMS. W. P. WILSON, SC.D.`- 1009 1 - : .P18 ~Y~ Form Projener McLaughlin REPRINTED FROM THE JOURNAL OF THE PROCEEDINGS OF THE Oct., 03 ROYAL SOCIETY OF ANTIQUARIES OF IRELAND, FORMERLY THE ROYAL HISTORICAL AND ARCHEOLOGICAL ASSOCIATION OF IRELAND. Part 4.-Vol. XXXI., 4th Quarter, Dec., 1901. - ·· : From Propener MaLaughlin Profess bat.,03 } • + REPRINTED FROM THE JOURNAL OF THE PROCEEDINGS OF THE ROYAL SOCIETY OF ANTIQUARIES OF IRELAND, FORMERLY THE ROYAL HISTORICAL AND ARCHEOLOGICAL ASSOCIATION OF IRELAND. Part 4.-Vol. XXXI,, 4th Quarter, Dec., 1901. T ་ 1 ( 371 ) THE KING'S AND QUEEN'S CORPORATION FOR THE LINEN MANUFACTURE IN IRELAND. BY W. R. SCOTT, M.A., D. PHIL., FELlow. ご [Submitted OCTOBER 1, 1901.] THO HOUGH the linen industry was very early established in Ireland, little progress had been made in developing it till the last decade of the seventeenth century. Prior to this period, notwithstanding the efforts of the Marquis of Ormonde from 1666–1668, Irish weaving was much inferior to the French, and the latter practically held the English market, so that most of the finer fabrics were imported from the Continent. That there was great room for improvement in Irish linens is shown by the description of the older system in a treatise published, in 1706, by Louis Crommelin (to whom reference will be made below), entitled, "An Essay towards Improving the Hempen and Flaxen Manufactures in the North of Ireland." 1 With the arrival of the French Huguenots many improved methods of manufactures of different kinds were introduced into England. Some of the refugees came to Ireland with equally happy results. Francis Hutcheson, who has left a considerable reputation as a philosopher, when writing his "Inquiry concerning the Original of our Ideas of Beauty and Virtue" at Dublin in 1723-1724 (published in 1725), alludes to the progress of the country, through industrial improvements made by French Protestants. It is generally believed that the first important technical changes in the production of linen in Ireland were introduced by the Frenchman, Louis Crommelin, already mentioned, who set up looms at Lisburn about 1696-1697. However, Crommelin was preceded by an important company, which did much to lay the foundations of the industry, and this company was an offshoot of a another linen corporation founded earlier in England. The investigation of the beginning of the improvement in the linen. trade brings to light a somewhat interesting fact, namely, that either through timidity, or poverty, Ireland was not able to provide the comparatively modest capital for the necessary improvements. Thus the funds required for the first attempt were largely provided from England, and those for the second by Frenchmen. In both cases the method of raising the capital was the same, i.e. by the formation of a 1 Carte's "Life of Ormonde," vol. ii., p. 343. 2 E.g. Ulster Journal of Archæology, i., pp. 212–214. 2 372 ROYAL SOCIETY OF ANTIQUARIES OF IRELAND. joint-stock company, working under a charter from the Crown, and directly encouraged by the State. Of the first attempt to improve the industry very little has hitherto been known. As already stated, it was an offshoot of a larger English company, and as there was a certain relation between the two, it is necessary for a clear understanding of the circumstances to discover the events leading up to the formation, flotation, and collapse of the first English Linen Company. 1 During the second half of the seventeenth century many efforts were made to establish new industries in England. At this period Political Economy was in its infancy, and the vague ideas on foreign trade that were crystallized by the "Mercantilist System," urged the making the country, as far as possible, self-supporting, so as to prevent the exportation of the bullion required to pay for imports from other countries. With regard to the linen trade, there was another reason that led the Government to wish to see it established. At this period the employment of the poor was a problem that engaged the attention of thoughtful persons. It was considered that the linen industry would support large numbers of work-people, and therefore it was held to be worthy of the encouragement of the State. Prior to 1690, a patent had been granted for the establishing of linen-looms. Whether the patentees produced linens does not appear, but their interest in the patent was acquired by a French refugee, Nicholas Dupin, who may be named as the first person to introduce French methods in England. On May 27, 1690, Dupin, Henry Million, with several others, were incorporated by charter, as the "Governor and Assistants of the King's and Queen's Corporation for the Linen Manufacture in England." This grant states that the persons named had, at their own charges, both in foreign parts and at home, found out several profitable arts and mysteries not hitherto used in England, i.e. the art of preparing flax and hemp for making all sorts of sewing and working threads, the art of making and weaving all sorts of cambrics, lawns, diapers, damasks, bag- hollands, and other sorts of cloth, and the making of looms, heckles, and other engines, not hitherto used in this kingdom, which are necessary for preparing the threads, and weaving, working, and bleaching the said manufactures. To encourage the corporation, the sole privilege of exercising these inventions was granted it for ever.³ 2 4 There are no sufficient data for determining the amount of the capital of the Company. In 1690 there were 340 shares, possibly of a nominal value of £20 or £25 per share; this being common at the time. 1 MSS. Public Record Office, London. State Papers, Domestic, Will. & Mary, Pet. Entry Book, i., p. 146. 2 State Papers, ut supra, Domestic, Will. & Mary, Signet Office, 12, p. 355. 866 Proposals of the Gov". and Assts. of the King's and Queen's Corporation for the Linen Manufacture in England."-Brit. Mus., 816. m. 13, No. 48. 4 Ibid. THE 7 LINEN MANUFACTURE IN IRELAND. 373 Where, after the Revolution, the capital of a company was not divided into stock, shares, as a rule, were of £20 or £25 nominal-as, for in- stance, in the cases of the Royal Lustring Company, many mining com- panies, and the various undertakings for the recovery of wrecks. In fact, the chief of the few exceptions were the Irish and Scotch Linen Com- panies when the shares were only £5 each. If the shares in the "King's and Queen's Corporation for the Linen Manufacture in England" were of £25 or £20, the capital at the inception of the company would have been either £8500 or £6800. 4 1 The Corporation started under very favourable auspices; Dupin had the reputation of being acquainted with the technical side of the manu- facture, and the company was under the patronage of the Royal Family. By the Patent the monopoly of the Linen produced in England was secured, and there was a probability that difficulties would be placed in the way of importers of linens from abroad. These favourable circum- stances drew attention to the company; and Narcissus Luttrell, writing on December 18th, 1690, says that the " new Linen Corporation is much in- creased."1 It was stated by a contemporary writer that the shares had been quoted at 350 per cent." If the shares were of £20 each, this would mean a quotation of £70 per share, a conjecture confirmed by the fact that, in 1691, a new issue of shares was made at £50 per share,³ and, in 1692, the highest price was £42.4 The subscribed capital was expended in purchasing the previous Patent already mentioned, and in establishing factories and workshops." Besides acting as a legitimate manufacturing undertaking, the Corpora- tion was a "parent company" promoting subsidiary linen companies in Ireland (1690), and in Scotland (1694). The capital of the Irish Com- pany was £5000 in £5 shares; but by 1691 only 400 shares had been taken up, making the actual capital £2000; a considerable part of this was subscribed by the English Company. In consideration of the pro- vision of capital by the English Company, the Irish one undertook to sell its linens only in England, by which agreement the English Company controlled the whole market." 6 As early as June, 1691, the English Company was in want of working 1A Brief Narrative of State Affairs," ii., p. 147. 2 "The Anatomy of Exchange Alley," reprinted in the Chronicles of the Stock Exchange, by John Francis (London, 1849), p. 365. 3 "Proposals of the Gov. of the K's. and Q's. Corp. for Lin. Mf. in England,” ut supra. 4 From a newspaper published by John Houghton, giving quotations of Stocks and Shares, entitled A Collection for the Improvement of Husbandry and Trade. (London: 1692-1703.) 5 Public Record Office-State Papers, Domestic, Will. & Mary, Pet. Entry Book, i., p. 146. 6 Letter of James Bonnell to Tobie Bonnell, in Ulster Journal of Archæology, iii., p. 197. 7 The Linnen and Woolen Manufactory discovered with the Nature of Companies in General” (London, 1691), pp. 11-12. (Advocate's Lib., Edinburgh.) XI., Fifth Series. Jour. R.S.A.I. { Vol. XXXI., Consec. Ser. 2 D 374 ROYAL SOCIETY OF ANTIQUARIES OF IRELAND. capital, and the Governor petitioned the Crown for the privilege of raising wrecks on the south coast of England, "so that the linen industry should not sink for want of support during its minority,"-a homeo- pathic remedy of upholding a sinking industry by the raising of foundered ships. The want of capital was accentuated by the flotation of the "Com- pany for the Scots' Linen Manufacture" in 1694. The English Corpo- ration undertook to find one-half of a total capital of £6000, and the agreement between Dupin and the Scottish subscribers provided that half the governing body should represent the English shareholders.2 The object of this arrangement, copied from the "Darien Company," was to avoid friction such as had then arisen between the English and Irish Corporations. The want of adequate capital, the common disorder of most early com- panies, brought the English Corporation into difficulties. During the first year of its existence, the prospects had been favourable, and as already shown the price of the shares was three and a-half times the original value. Within a short time the outlook became less promising, and gradually the credit of the Corporation declined, as will be seen by the following table of the quotations of the shares :- PRICES OF SHARES. YEAR. 1692, 1693, 1694, 1695, 1696, 1697, • HIGHEST. 42 45 22 LOWEST. 29 18 8 7 7 After 1697 the Company ceased to have an active existence, though in 1720 an attempt was made by the last shareholders to bar a proposed new linen company on the ground of the monopoly granted by the Patent, but at an inquiry held before the English Attorney-General, it could not be shown that the Corporation had continued to exist.³ Contemporary opinion attributed the failure of the Corporation to the evils of "stock-jobbing," which at this period was in very bad repute. The idea of the association of capitalists in a joint-stock company for 1 State Papers, Domestic, Will. & Mary, Pet. Entry Book, i., p. 146. 2 Articles of Agreement made and agreed on this twenty-eighth day of May, in the year of our Lord, 1694, between the Royal free Burrows. of Scotland, who shall be pleased to subscribe and be concerned in the Scots' Linen subscription-book for the Linen Manufacture in that kingdom on the one part, and Nicholas • Dupin, in trust for the members, who shall hereafter be pleased to subscribe and be concerned in the aforesaid manufacture in England of the other part. (Edinburgh, 1694, pp. 1–2.) 3 Caledonian Mercury, July 25, 1720. • 9.5. THE LINEN MANUFACTURE IN IRELAND. 375 (C manufactures was comparatively new, and the frequent failures of early companies were attributed to disadvantages arising out of the facilities for the transfer of shares. Thus the Commissioners of Trade instanced this Corporation as a case of the evils of stock-jobbing, "whereby the linen trade was not in so flourishing a condition as it might have been had it not fallen under this kind of misfortune." In similar terms, the author of Angliæ Tutamen" describes the fall of the Corporation "which," he writes, “expected to have produced great profit, for the actions? mounted apace, and were in great probability of being higher, when all of a sudden some mean spirits fell to stock-jobbing, and scared the easy and timorous, and brought the actions down, and abundance sold off their shares contented with their first profits which were considerable rather than attend the hazard of making greater in a little time or losing some of the present; and so, by degrees, the reputation of this mighty manu- facture sunk here, and, I understand, will hardly hold up its head, much less advance any further."3 No doubt in many new industries the sale of shares by the few persons who alone were possessed of the necessary technical knowledge accounts for the failure of several early companies, but this explanation does not apply in the present case, as Dupin held his shares during the depreciation. The true cause of the failure is to be found partly in the insufficiency of capital, partly in the disagreement with the Irish Corporation; and this brings us to the consideration of the subsidiary company formed by Dupin in Ireland, concerning which the details are in many respects fuller than those obtainable about the English Company. On December 13, 1690, a warrant was issued to incorporate H. Million, N. Dupin, and a number of noblemen and gentlemen residing in Ireland, as the "King's and Queen's Corporation for the Linen Manufacture in Ireland," with the usual privileges of a corporation and the right of electing a governor, deputy-governor, and thirty assistants—the latter being the seventeenth-century equivalent of the more modern director. The noblemen and gentry were "admitted more for their countenance and favour than for any great help that could be expected either from their purses or heads."5 Evidently their resources were very low, for the nominal capital was only £5000 divided into 1000 shares of £5 each. At the flotation of the corporation no more than 400 shares were issued, so that the total capital, at that time, credited as fully paid, was £2000. James Bonnell characterizes this issue (C as sensical," and asks, "who would put their money into such a stock?" Small as the capital was, only a part was subscribed in Ireland, the remainder being guaranteed by the English Corporation, which non- 1 Journals of the House of Commons, xi., p. 595. 2 1.e. shares. 3 Page 24. 4 State Papers, Domestic, Will. & Mary, Signet Office, 12, p. 355. 5Wm. Molyneux to John Locke," September 26, 1696-" Locke's Works' (ed. 1727), iii., p. 552. It was nonsense from the beginning to give away 400 shares out of 1000 at £5 a piece." Ulster Journal of Archeology, iii., p. 197. 2 D 2 376 ROYAL SOCIETY OF ANTIQUARIES OF IRELAND. stipulated in return that it should control the output of the Irish looms. Within a short time linens were produced, and the " shareholders promised themselves prodigious gains," so that the shares advanced in price to £40 and £50 for the £5 share.¹ The Irish Corporation had difficulties of its own to contend against. Another linen company had been formed at Drogheda without any charter of incorporation. The capital had been issued "on equaller terms "2 and this company 173 "thrived very well at first." Once its competition began to be felt by the Corporation, the latter set to work to secure the monopoly given it by its charter. The result was that the Drogheda Company, owing to the want of legal authorisation, was unable to maintain its independent position, and it was finally absorbed by the chartered Company.* No sooner was this amalgamation carried through than a more serious difficulty had to be faced. The working agreement with the English Company led to friction. No doubt circumstances arose in which the Irish Corporation found that the control of its output by the parent Company was inconvenient, and the agreement appears to have been broken. In 1691, the governor of the Irish Company declared this principle of community of interests "unreasonable," and the English Corporation replied that, if it were not observed, "such a breach is likely to happen as will turn to the ruin of the linen manufacture in Ireland.”5 The warning was not taken, and the "breach" duly followed with the result that the "work of the Company began to flag, and the price of the shares to lower mightily." The prediction of the "ruin of the linen manufacture" followed as far as that of the Irish Corporation, but not of the industry generally, as Dupin's secrets were diffused through the country; and, though the Corporation ceased to manufacture, fine linens were still produced. Thus Molyneux, writing on September 26, 1696, says, at that date, looms and bleaching yards were established by private individuals. "We have many of these in many parts of Ireland, and, I believe, no country in the world is better adapted for it, especially at the north. I have as good diaper, made by some of my tenants nigh Armagh, as can come to a table, and all other cloth for household use. 997 Though Molyneux commends the linen produced in 1696, there was still room for great improvement, and, though nothing was done in England, a fresh effort was made to encourage the Irish industry. In 1696, a bill but was promoted in the Irish Parliament, for a new linen company, apparently without success. In the following year, another Frenchman, 8 1 “Locke's Works," ut supra. 2 Ulster Journal of Archæology, iii., p. 197. 4 Ibid. 3" Locke's Works," ut supra. 5 British Museum-Add. MSS., No. 28,877, f. 109 (dated September 18, 1691). 6 "Locke's Works," ut supra. " Ibid., iii., p. 552. 8 British Museum--Add. MSS., No. 27,382, f. 8. ¿ THE LINEN MANUFACTURE IN IRELAND. 377 Louis Crommelin,' brought seventy persons to Lisburn, with their looms. and other requisites.2 He formed what might be described as a company on a co-operative basis. The looms and other tools were valued, and capital given in his company accordingly. The total capital raised in this way was valued at £10,000; and subsequently a grant was made by the State, of interest thereon at 8 per cent. per annum as a bounty. In addition, Crommelin was allowed £200 a year as overseer of the royal linen manufactory, £120 to be divided between his three assistants, and £60 as stipend of a minister. On the creation of the trustees of the linen manufacture, the interest-charge of £800 was transferred to them with powers to dispose of it in any way that would encourage the industry. The clerical party was opposed to the trustees, because it was feared that further bounties given to the linen trade would be charged against the tithes. Archbishop King, writing, in 1705, of one of the many bills in the Irish Parliament for the encouragement of the industry, says "The clergy's party is most shamefully invaded, and half their tythes given away without sense or reason . . sacrilege is an ill way of improving manufactures." The grant at the disposal of the trustees was divided between Crom- melin's company, and other manufacturers in equal parts. On November 28, 1711, Crommelin states in a petition that the allowance made him had been reduced to £400 a-year, which produced "not 3 per cent. interest instead of 8 per cent."5 As a payment of 4 per cent. on the original capital of £10,000 would give £400 a-year, the capital of his company must have increased in the fourteen years to over £13,000. The colony at Lisburn had grown with it, for the members now numbered 120. The trustees recommended that Crommelin should be "encouraged"; and, in 1717, it was proposed to grant him a pension of £400 a year in recognition of his services." He died ten years later, in 1727. The history of the early improvement of the linen industry may be said to have ended with the establishment of Crommelin's Company. The same method was adopted with other French immigrants who brought their looms with them. In each case such persons were credited with the estimated value of their appliances, as if such a sum had been lent the ¹ The name is sometimes spelt Cromellin, or Cromelin, or Crommellin. 2 "Precedents and Abstracts from the Journals of the Trustees of the Linen and Hempen Manufacturers of Ireland to the 25th of March, 1737," by James Corry (Dublin, 1784), p. 3. 3 "Precedents and Abstracts," ut supra, p. 4; Journals of the House of Commons, xiii., p. 299. 4 MS. Letters of Archbishop King, Library, Trinity College, Dublin (under date April 28, 1705). 5Precedents and Abstracts," ut supra, p. 4. 6 Ibid., p. 23. £200 a year was his salary as overseer; £400 was his proposed pension. 4 378 ROYAL SOCIETY OF ANTIQUARIES OF IRELAND. State, and interest was paid thereon accordingly, as long as their work was approved of by the trustees. In this way small groups of skilled workers were settled in suitable localities, and in time, as acquaintance with improved methods of weaving became diffused, workmen grew sufficiently skilled to avail themselves of the natural advantages of certain districts for the production of flax suitable for the finest linens. Capital, having once found its way to the linen trade through the joint-stock system, continued to support it, so that the three requisites for a success- ful industry-localised advantages, technical skill, and capital acting in co-operation, the trade took firm root. ( HF ↓ 100.9 P18 This thins Complirato no AUG 15 1912 UNIV THE MANN-ELKINS ACT, AMENDING THE ACT TO REGULATE COMMERCE 1 BY FRANK HAIGH DIXON THERE ARE REPRINTED FROM THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS VOL. XXIV, AUGUST, 1910 THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Published by Harvard University Is established for the advancement of knowledge by the full and free discussion of economic questions. The editors assume no responsibility for the views of contributors, beyond a guarantee that they have a good claim to the attention of well-informed readers. Communications for the editors should be addressed to the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Cambridge, Mass.; business communications and subscriptions ($3.00 a year), to the Publication Agent of Harvard University, 2 University Hall, Cambridge, Mass. CONTENTS FOR MAY, 1910 II. I. THE SEPARATION OF STATE AND LOCAL REVENUES THE SUBJECTIVE ELEMENT IN THE FIRST PRINCI- PLES OF TAXATION. III. CONTROL OF RAILROAD ACCOUNTS IN LEADING EUROPEAN COUNTRIES. IV. SMALL HOLDINGS AND AGRICULTURAL CO-OPERA- TION IN ENGLAND V. PRESENT WORK AND PRESENT WAGES REVIEWS: APPENDIX: • Some Recent Books on Protective Tariffs NOTES AND MEMORANDA: The Cleveland Street Railway Settlement Recent Changes in Australasian Laws Against Strikes The Decline in Trade Union Membership An American Experiment in Workmen's Insurance The British Minimum Wages Act of 1909 tance Text of British Minimum Wages Act of 1909 • I. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT, AMENDING THE ACT TO REGULATE COMMERCE II. PROPOSALS FOR STRENGTHENING THE NATIONAL BANKING SYSTEM. H CONTENTS FOR AUGUST, 1910 III. COMPULSORY ARBITRATION IN NEW ZEALAND IV. OLD AGE PENSION SCHEMES: A CRITICISM AND A PROGRAM NOTES AND MEMORANDA: Commercial Banking and the Rate of Interest A Revised Index Number for Measuring the Rise in Prices Method of Taxing the Unearned Increment The French Old Age Insurance Law of 1910 Charles J. Bullock F. Y. Edgeworth C. R. Fay J. G. Thompson Edward Van Dyke Robinson A. M. Sakolski Edward W. Bemis Victor S. Clark C. H. Parker Henry Davis Bushnell A. N. Holcombe 1 Frank Haigh Dixon O. M. W. Sprague. James Edward Le Rossignol William Downie Stewart F. Spencer Baldwin • Harry G. Brown J. Pease Norton Edgar H. Johnson Robert F. Foerster THE *. { $ 梯 + ft C 01/ Par J.S. R QUARTERLY JOURNAL k OF ECONOMICS AUGUST, 1910 THE MANN-ELKINS ACT, AMENDING THE ACT TO REGULATE COMMERCE SUMMARY Legislative history of the act, 593. Carriers subject to the act, 596. Long and short haul clause, 597. - Rates and routes; Sus- pension of rates, 601. Misquotation of rates, 605. — Through routes, 606. Classification, Right to route traffic, 608. Passes, 611. 612. Additional Powers: Power to initiate inquiries, 612. Regu- lations and practices, 613. Facilities for through routes, 614. Procedure: the Commerce Court, 615. Miscellaneous Provisions: Penalties, 624. - Disclosure of information, 624. Statistics, 625. Enjoining state statutes, 625. Projects which failed of enactment: Agreements as to rates, 626. Control of capitalization, 627. - Physical valuation, 628. Miscellaneous provisions, 628. Subjects which failed of action in either house: Control of water carriers, 629. — Minimum rates, 630. No amendment of the commodities clause, 630. "Insurgents" responsible for the Act, 631. — Grave responsibility of the Commission, 633. M k M In its platform of 1908, upon which Mr. Taft was elected to the Presidency, the Republican party ex- pressed its approval of the railroad rate law and of the vigorous manner in which it was being enforced, and recommended that it be further amended so as to permit railroads to make traffic agreements, which should preserve the principle of competition, and avoid the common control of competing railroad lines. It 593 594 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS also expressed itself as favorable to such national legislation and supervision as would prevent the future over-issue of stocks and bonds by interstate carriers. Taking his stand upon this platform, President Taft planned his policy for the regulation of interstate carriers. He advised at length with members of Con- gress, members of the Interstate Commerce Com- mission, and other departmental officials, and especially with his Attorney-General. As it became clear that he intended to make recommendations of a serious nature to Congress, conferences with railroad officers became frequent, doubtless at the suggestion of the railroad men themselves. In the annual message in December, the question was not touched upon, but was reserved for a special message on January 7, 1910. This message proved to be merely an outline of a bill already drawn by the Attorney-General, and about to be offered to both houses for their consideration. The bill was introduced in both House and Senate and referred to the appropriate committees. In conformity with the pledges of the platform, it con- tained provisions for traffic agreements and for federal control of capitalization. The President's natural inter- est in judicial affairs had turned his attention to ques- tions of procedure, and much of the bill was taken up with the creation of a new court. Other provisions, such as the right to suspend rate increases, doubtless came into the bill at the suggestion of the Interstate Commerce Commission and the various members of Congress with whom the President consulted. With the committees of both houses the Attorney- General put himself into touch, and as a result of conferences, he re-wrote many sections of the measure. When it was finally in satisfactory form, it was re- ported by the Senate Committee on March 28 without THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 595 amendment, and without serious committee considera- tion. The House Committee amended it radically before reporting it on March 24. It was completely reconstructed in both houses and passed the House on May 10, the Senate on June 3. The Conference Committee gave it ten days' consideration, their report was promptly adopted by both houses, and it received the approval of the President on June 18. Considering the radical character of the Mann- Elkins Act, it is somewhat surprising that it was de- bated and passed with so little demonstration on the part of either public or carriers. No such extraordinary campaign of publicity was undertaken by the railroads as was the case four years before, nor did the discussion of the question occupy the same space in the press or the same attention in public address. Several ex- planations suggest themselves. In the first place, the campaign of 1906 was fought over fundamental principles -the right of a Commission to make rates, the right of the courts to suspend orders of the Com- mission without a hearing, and the like. These ques- tions were then settled once for all, and it was the task of the present Congress to strengthen the earlier act at its weak spots. The Act of 1910 takes some steps in advance, yet its main purpose is to make secure the positions occupied in 1906. Hence debate centered largely upon technical questions with which the public had little familiarity, and did not take that broad view of the problem of regulation which was so characteristic of the earlier struggle. That the railroads did not renew their policy of publicity was doubtless due to the effect which their campaign of 1905-06 produced. Through their propagandist literature, they had familiarized the public as never before with the railroad problem, but they found at 596 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS the end that their instruction had proved a boomerang, and that instead of convincing the public of the sound- ness of their reasoning, they had built up a resistless opposition, now for the first time fully aware of its needs and its opportunities. This time the railroad officials confined themselves to personal conferences with the President and party leaders. Such testimony as they offered before committees of Congress was of a most perfunctory sort, and few of their spokesmen appeared at all at the public hearings. It is my purpose to consider somewhat in detail the signifi- cance of this last amendment of the Interstate Com- merce Act. CARRIERS SUBJECT TO THE ACT Upon the Interstate Commerce Commission, whose jurisdiction had been extended by the amendments of 1906, the new Act lays still further responsibilities. Interstate telegraph, telephone, and cable companies, whether wire or wireless, are declared to be common carriers within the purpose of the Act, and are placed under the regulating authority of the Commission. These companies are allowed to classify their messages into day, night, press, government, and other forms of service, and to prescribe different rates for the different classes, and are authorized to enter into contracts with other common carriers for the exchange of services. The original suggestion for the inclusion of these carriers came from a Democratic member of the House, and his amendment was promptly adopted over the objections of those in charge of the railroad bill in that body, who protested against hasty action that would bring these carriers under a law ill-adapted to their regulation, and framed for transportation corporations whose operations were of a distinctly THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 597 different character. Yet with the right to classify messages, the principle of just discrimination is rec- ognized, and there seems to be no good reason why the Commission cannot apply to agencies of this character the same rules of action that are applied to transportation companies. Beyond this the juris- diction of the Commission over interstate carriers remains as before. LONG AND SHORT HAUL CLAUSE The amendment to the Act which will probably be most far-reaching in its effects is that which restores the long and short haul clause to a place of active participation in the task of railroad regulation. In order to make clear the changes, it will be well to re- produce this section as it has stood untouched since 1887. SECTION 4. That it shall be unlawful for any common carrier subject to the provisions of this Act to charge or receive any greater compensation in the aggregate for the transportation of passengers or of like kind of property, under substantially similar circum- stances and conditions, for a shorter than for a longer distance over the same line, in the same direction, the shorter being included within the longer distance; but this shall not be construed as authorizing any common carrier within the terms of this Act to charge and receive as great compensation for a shorter as for a longer distance: Provided, however, That upon application to the Commission appointed under the provisions of this Act, such common carrier may, in special cases, after investigation by the Commission, be authorized to charge less for longer than for shorter distances for the transportation of passengers or property; and the Commission may from time to time prescribe the extent to which such designated common carrier may be relieved from the operation of this section of this Act. This clause was shorn of all significance by a Supreme Court decision in 1897¹ which virtually de- 1 Interstate Commerce Commission v. Alabama Midland Ry. Co., et al. 168 U. S. 144. 598 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS clared that competition of railroads at terminal points created those dissimilar circumstances that warranted a suspension of the clause, and furthermore, that if circumstances were substantially dissimilar, the rail- roads were not in violation of the statute if they charged a less rate for the longer distance without permission of the Commission. Justice Harlan in his dissenting opinion said, "Taken in connection. with other decisions defining the powers of the Inter- state Commerce Commission, the present decision, it seems to me, goes far to make that Commission a useless body." That the decision was a severe blow to the power and prestige of the Commission was clear, and it became clearer as time went on, for this evil, which Chairman Knapp called "the most irritat- ing and obnoxious form of discrimination that has been encountered," did not cease, but became if any- thing more widespread and burdensome. It has been present in full force in the South in the basing- point system. As the cities of the Rocky Mountain region have grown in strength, they have wished to build up a distributing business in mountain territory, and the practice of giving rates to Pacific Coast points lower than those granted to the interior has become to them well nigh intolerable. Every stream of water, whether navigable or not, has been eagerly seized upon by the railroads and raised to the dignity of a competitor, in order to justify the low rate to a distant point. Every attempt on the part of public or Commission to equalize rates on a plan which approximated the distance basis, has been met by the roads with the plea that such a revolution would utterly destroy established industries. "God help New England if the long and short haul clause is restored," is the remark of a railroad president which 1 2 THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 599 typifies fairly the position of the carriers. In view of the burdens imposed on so many industries under the existing practice of the railroads, it is surprising that no action was taken and that the subject was not even seriously considered, when the Act of 1906 was passed. Failure to act at that time was due in large part to the vigorous protests of the railroads. No amendment of the clause was suggested this time in the Administration bill, but in both Senate and House the western representatives were insistent. that the subject should not be passed over. The "insurgents" gained new strength from the alliance with these mountain Congressmen, and succeeded in giving Section 4 a new lease of life. It was the House amendment which finally became law. This eliminated from the old section the words "under substantially similar circumstances and conditions,” thus making it unlawful under any circumstances to charge more for the longer than for the shorter distance, unless permission should be secured in ad- vance from the Commission. No other changes. were made in the section except that (1) the prohibi- tion was extended to include route as well as line, thus making it clear that jurisdiction extends over routes made up of more than one railroad line, and (2) carriers were prohibited from charging more for a through route than the aggregate of the intermediate rates, which legalizes a rule that the Commission has consistently followed in its decisions. No rates are required to be changed under this clause until six months after the passage of the Act. If held con- stitutional in its amended form, the section will put into the hands of the Commission a power by which they may readjust the entire rate structure of the country, subject only to the limitation that rates 600 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS must be reasonable. How far they will take advantage of this sudden and extraordinary increase in their authority remains to be seen. Judging from recent decisions, they are likely to continue their readjust- ment of rates in trans-Mississippi territory with much more confidence that their findings will be sustained by the Courts. I refer to the question of constitutionality, be- cause able lawyers in both House and Senate expressed doubts whether the clause as worded would stand the judicial test. It prescribes no rule by which the Commission is to be guided in the discharge of its duty and hence, it is argued, confers the legislative power upon an administrative body. The form of the amendment in the Senate bill was in this respect more acceptable, for it stated in detail the circum- stances under which the Commission could suspend the clause. But the House conferees insisted upon their form of amendment, probably because there seemed less likelihood that decisions under it could be reviewed by the courts, and they prevailed. An amendment which had been recommended by the National Waterways Commission in its recent report to Congress was submitted by its Chairman, Senator Burton, and became a part of Section 4. It provided that whenever a railroad in competition with a water route should reduce its rates to competitive points, it should not be permitted to increase them unless, after hearing before the Commission, it should be found that such increase rested upon changed con- ditions other than the elimination of water competi- tion. The only provision of this kind previously in existence in this country is to be found in the constitu- tion of California, under which document the Railroad Commission of that state is created, and it was from THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 601 this source that the suggestion of the Waterways Commission came. The clause therein contained is practically identical with the one adopted by Con- gress. A provision in the Senate bill, giving the Commission the right to prescribe minimum railroad rates on lines competing with waterways, whenever in its opinion the object of the railroad in reducing rates is to destroy waterway competition, unfortu- nately failed in conference. The purpose of the clause as enacted is obvious. It is to restrain railroads from continuing the practice, now so common, of driving boat lines from the rivers and canals by ex- traordinarily low rates, and then recouping themselves later by raising their rates to a point even higher than what would be reasonable in the absence of any competition. This clause should give an impulse to the movement already begun for a restoration of boat lines on the Ohio and lower Mississippi. RATES AND ROUTES Suspension of Rates. To realize the full signifi- cance of the amendment to Section 15, which gives the Commission power to suspend proposed changes in rates, it is necessary to discuss the practical working of the Hepburn Act, now in operation nearly four years. That Act gave the Commission power to prescribe rates, but only after hearing and upon com- plaint, and no complaint could be entertained until a rate was actually in effect. It is clear, therefore, that a shipper had no satisfactory method of avoiding the burden of an increased rate, until he could actually prove by experience that it was unreasonable. If the rate as put into effect proved unreasonable, he might obtain from the Commission an order on the P 602 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS carrier for reparation, but if he were a small shipper he would probably have been driven out of business before his case was decided. Moreover, there are other reasons why this reparation method is not an adequate solution of the difficulty. It is slow, cumber- some, and costly and it does not restore to the shipper the property of which he has been deprived. Loss of his business to a competitor because of an unreason- able rate cannot be compensated for by a return of the excess over the reasonable rate. In probably a majority of cases, the burden of the freight rate is shifted to the consignee, is absorbed into the retail price of the goods, and paid by the ultimate consumer, who is not a party to the shipment and has no standing before court or Commission. His interest, so vital and so intangible, can only be protected by an authority which stands for universal justice and equality, and has power to determine, before a new rate becomes effective, whether such rate is desirable and just. In addition to demands on the Commission for reparation, the shipper has to some extent invoked the aid of the courts to restrain an advance in rates. This method has not proved satisfactory. In the first place, the power of the courts to suspend rates before they become effective has been bitterly con- tested. We are certainly led to think that one must scurry far and wide to find good legal grounds for suspension of rate advances by the courts, after ob- serving the manner in which the Administration invoked the Sherman Anti-trust Act as a means of enjoining the western roads from raising their rates, by declaring them to be a combination in restraint of interstate commerce, and then, when the railroads agreed to submit their proposed increases to the Commission under the pending law, it dismissed the THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 603 grave charge against them, and had the injunction suspended. But even if the power exists in the courts to restrain rate increases, an injunction can issue only in favor of the petitioners, and only upon the filing of a bond. The large body of shippers who cannot file a bond, and who do not petition the courts, are obliged to pay the new rate. Again, such a court injunction applies only to the circuit over which the court has jurisdiction, and hence may cause confusion in cases of shipments which pass through more than one circuit. It is obvious that no carrier should be compelled to lower a rate without a hearing. It should be equally obvious that no shipper should be compelled to suffer an increased burden without having an opportunity to present his case. A rate long in existence is presumptively reasonable, and no serious hardship can arise if a postponement of the effective date of a change in such rate is made pending an examination of its reasonableness. This was the situation which influenced the Admin- istration and Congress to make a radical change in our method of rate control. It is now provided that whenever there shall be filed with the Commission any new rate or fare or classification, or any regulation affecting a rate, the Commission is authorized, either upon complaint or upon its own motion, after reasonable notice to the carrier, to enter upon a hearing, and pending such hearing and decision, it may suspend the operation of the rate or other regula- tion for not more than 120 days beyond the time when it would have gone into effect. If the hearing is not then completed, it may extend the time of suspension for a further period of six months. After full hearing, the Commission may make such order 604 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS as would be proper in a proceeding initiated after the rate became effective. In any hearing involving a rate increased after January 1, 1910, the burden of proof is on the carrier to show that the increased rate is just and reasonable. In other words, the Commission may suspend rates for ten months beyond their effective date but no longer, and if the investigation is not then com- plete, the rates automatically go into effect. The "insurgents" of the Senate led by Senator Cummins failed in an effort to secure a provision which should require the approval of the Commission to make rates effective, yet the length of time granted for investigation should make that desirable result possi- ble in most of the important cases.¹ Strength is added to the position of the Commission by the pro- vision making all increases in rates presumptively unreasonable. Those who consider this legislation as revolutionary and drastic should bear in mind. that this is merely giving those same safeguards to the shippers and the public, that we have long given through statute and constitutional privilege to the common carriers. If a rate has been lowered by order of the Commission, the carrier has had the right to enjoin its enforcement and the ultimate determination of the question has been postponed often for years, the old rates in many instances con- tinuing in force. Except in complicated cases in- volving extensive changes over wide areas of country, it is unlikely that the Commission will take advantage of the full ten months permitted by law, and prelimi- G 1 When it is observed that in the month of July (1910) 15,000 tariffs were filed announcing advances in rates in trunk line territory alone, it becomes clear that the Commission, in the ten months allowed by law, would not have time even to issue the necessary suspending orders covering all the advances. Yet when conditions again become normal, it is probable that all important increases which occasion any serious complaint can be adequately considered within the time limit. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 605 nary notice of from four to six months of changes in rates, which is likely to be the practice, should not injure the carriers and should prove of immense value to shippers. Obviously, however, the greatest benefit to the public in general will come from those suspen- sions of rates which become permanent and never reach an effective date. Misquotation of Rates. Section 6 of the Act requires carriers to post their tariffs for public in- spection at all stations where freight is received for transportation. The shipper is then presumed to consult these schedules and ascertain the rate for himself. But the schedules are so voluminous, and even in their constantly improving condition so complicated, that theory does not accord with fact. The shipper cannot discover the rate. He must therefore rely upon the statement of the agent, and if the latter misquotes the rate so that he enters upon engagements in which he suffers loss when the correct rate is collected, he has no recovery, for under the decisions of the Supreme Court carriers must collect their published rates or be subject to severe penalties, even tho they have quoted a different rate to the shipper, in good faith, upon which he has acted.¹ To bring relief to this situation, Section 6 has been amended by providing that if, after written request has been made upon the agent of a common carrier for a written statement of a rate applicable to a desired shipment between stated places, under tariffs to which the carrier is a party, such common carrier shall refuse or omit to give such statement within a reasonable time, or shall misstate in writing the applicable rate, and if the applicant suffers 1 202 U. S. 242. 606 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS damage, either through making the shipment over an unnecessarily costly route, or through entering into a contract to pay the freight charges, then the carrier is liable to a penalty of $250 which is to accrue to the United States. The misquotation or non- quotation of a rate after a proper request is now made a misdemeanor, with a penalty payable to the United States. A majority of Congress felt that any scheme which would have permitted a civil suit for damages, with recovery by the shipper, would have opened an easy road to rebates, and it was for this reason that a Senate amendment giving a shipper this right of recovery was dropped out in conference. But with the heavy penalties in existence against rebating, and with the ease with which the carrier and shipper could be detected through the written statements required under this section, it is not at all clear that a provision which would permit shippers to recover damages would promote rebating. Yet to the law-makers a penalty that would serve to make agents more responsible seemed to be the only feasible plan. Through Routes. The Hepburn Act authorized the Commission to establish through routes and joint rates when carriers had refused or neglected to establish such routes and rates voluntarily, and no reasonable or satisfactory through route existed. The difficulty in the enforcement of this provision has been in the interpretation of the words "reason- able or satisfactory," for what might be reasonable or satisfactory for one purpose and under one set of conditions, was not so for another purpose or under other conditions. This was shown in the Portland Gateway Case,¹ in which the Commission held that 1 Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. Interstate Commerce Commission, 23d Annual Report of Commission, p. 36. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 607 because a large group of passengers could not secure joint rates from St. Louis to Seattle by way of Port- land, but could do so only by the "Hill" lines, no satisfactory through route existed for them, and they ordered one established by way of Portland. Against this order, the Circuit Court granted an injunction bas- ing its action upon the literal wording of the statute. The Commission, therefore, urged that this limitation upon its power to prescribe through routes be re- moved, at least so far as passenger business was concerned. Again, there are frequently conditions in freight traffic due to car shortage, lack of facilities, and the like, when public necessity and convenience demand that some pressure should be brought to bear upon the initial carrier to provide additional through routes. In the Act under consideration, the proviso that "no reasonable or satisfactory through route exists" is eliminated, and the Commission may, after hearing, order such through routes and prescribe such joint rates as seem desirable, even when one of the connect- ing carriers is a water line. The only limitations upon its power in this regard are, (1) that because of its obvious impracticability, no through route shall be formed with a street electric passenger railway not engaged in freight business, (2) that no route may be established when the transportation is wholly by water, as this would be beyond the jurisdiction of the Commission, and (3) that no railroad company shall be required without its consent to embrace in the through route substantially less than the entire length of its road, or any intermediate road under its control, which lies between the termini of the proposed route, unless this would make such route unreasonably long as compared with a more practicable route. 608 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS This last limitation, embraced in the Administration bill, was eliminated from the House bill, but was restored on the floor, in response to the urgent de- mands of the railroads who feared that the Commission might, in seeking for the speediest routes, take small portions out of their lines, and deprive them of much of their long haul business. Yet in its present form it is doubtful whether the clause is workable at all, and whether the Commission's power over through routing is not less than before. When each railroad can include substantially all of its line in a through route to which it is a party, it will establish it volun- tarily, and the Commission's authority will not be invoked. It is in cases where the through route requires the inclusion of a part only of a carrier's line that conflict will arise and the Commission will be requested to exercise its authority, and it is in just such cases that the hands of the Commission are tied. It is not unlikely that this limiting proviso has nullified the entire clause. Right to Route Traffic. Doubtless in the majority of cases a shipper is indifferent as to the route which his property takes, provided he secures satisfactory service and the lowest rates. Again, it is probably true that the expressed wishes of the shipper as to route, particularly if he is a large shipper at a com- petitive point, have been in most cases readily con- ceded by the carrier. Nevertheless, the shipper has had no legal right to determine the route of his ship- ment; in fact, the courts have expressly denied him this right whenever the carriers have in their tariffs reserved control over routing. In the California Orange Routing Cases, it appeared that the carriers had reserved the control over the routing of the fruit to prevent alleged rebating upon certain connecting THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 609 1 lines, over which the fruit shippers wished their pro- duct to move. This practice of the initial carriers was held by the Commission to be an undue prejudice and disadvantage to the orange shippers, and a viola- tion of Section 3 of the Act; but the practice was sustained by the Supreme Court of the United States.¹ In their appearance before the House Committee on Interstate Commerce, the shippers contended that the carrier had no property right in the goods, and should leave the routing to the owners, that it was frequently necessary to know the route in advance in order to safeguard the shipments and arrange for their receipt, that if they arranged the routing, delays in transit due to blockades or to the reloading practices of connecting roads might be avoided, and that in general the shipper would be in a better position to secure the most efficient service. It was contended further that the present policy of leaving the routing to the initial carrier tended to the development of pooling and exchange of traffic between certain car- riers to the exclusion of competitors, and hence re- sulted in increase of rates and in deterioration of the service. The right to route traffic would be of special value to the local shipper who could not make as effective demands upon the carrier as the large shipper at the competitive point. The main argument of the railroads for a continuation of the existing prac- tice was that without a policy of reciprocation between connecting lines, it would be impossible to secure the facilities necessary to serve the public, and a with- drawal of the practice would tend to less efficient and more expensive transportation. It is now provided that when two or more through routes and through rates exist, to which the initial 1 200 U. S. 536. 610 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS railroad is a party, the shipper, subject to such ex- ceptions as the Commission may prescribe, may designate in writing the route which he prefers, and a bill of lading must then be issued in conformity with his instructions. It is further provided that where competing lines form part of a through route, the shipper may designate over which of the competing lines his freight shall be transported, even tho no joint rates have been agreed upon or filed. This additional proviso would seem to give the shipper all the freedom he could possibly wish for shipments of any distance. For it would be difficult to find any route of any considerable length in which for at least a portion of the way there do not exist competing lines of railroad. Yet it is doubtful whether in the long run this radical change of policy will work out to the best interest of the shipper. His main concern is to name the delivering road, and he will, to be sure, have more freedom in this respect hereafter. But his requests, when reasonable, have heretofore usually been granted by the initial carrier. Now by naming his own route, he assumes all responsibility and the carrier must follow his instructions, strikes, blockades, and acts of God to the contrary notwith- standing. To be sure, the so-called Carmack amend- ment adopted in 1906, which makes the initial carrier liable to the shipper for damage, even if the damage occurs off its own line, is still in force. In fact, a Senate amendment relieving the carrier from liability beyond its own line, when the shipper selects a line over which no through route has been established, was thrown out in conference. Yet it is inconceivable that the courts will ever insist upon the liability of an initial carrier for a shipment over a series of con- necting roads, where neither a through route nor a joint rate has been agreed upon. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 611 (( Passes. -The Anti-pass clause has been modified by adding to the excepted classes to whom the rail- roads may grant free transportation, necessary care- takers of milk, and by enlarging the meaning of the term employees" so as to include the disabled, infirm, pensioned, and superannuated and their families, the bodies of employees killed in the service, the families of such employees, and the widows and minor children of those who die while in employment. The following proviso was also added: ― That this provision shall not be construed to prohibit the privi- lege of passes or franks, or the exchange thereof with each other, for the officers, agents, employees, and their families of such tele- graph, telephone, and cable lines, and the officers, agents, employees, and their families of other common carriers subject to the pro- visions of this act. I have quoted the exact words in order that each reader may determine its true significance for himself. It appears to be directed only to the telegraph and telephone companies newly incorporated in the Act, and yet the urgency with which the express companies pleaded their cause in the hearings before the House Committee makes one look for a deeper meaning. The Supreme Court, last February,¹ held that the Act did not permit express companies to issue franks to their officers and employees, or their families, or to exchange them for railroad passes, because the permissive clause of the Act applied solely to the carriage of passengers. The express companies have felt aggrieved by this decision and have urged that they be brought "within the spirit of the law." The exchange of telegraph and telephone franks, if properly safeguarded, should not be injurious to the public welfare. Express franks might also be permitted 1 212 U. S. 522. 612 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS + under careful restrictions and certainly should be allowed if the privilege is granted to other classes of carriers. But the illegitimate issue of express franks has become such a scandal that there can be no justi- fication for permitting their unrestricted use. It is significant that this cyptic clause had its birth in the Conference Committee. Classification. For the first time, the Act specifi- cally provides that carriers shall establish and enforce reasonable classifications of property for transporta- tion. This gives the Commission no authority which it has not exercised since 1906, but merely puts its power beyond dispute. A provision in the Senate bill directing the Commission to investigate and report as to the feasibility of a uniform classification of articles of commerce throughout the country was eliminated in conference. ADDITIONAL POWERS Power to initiate Inquiries. -The original Act (Section 13) authorized the Commission to institute any inquiry on its own motion in the same manner and to the same effect as tho complaint had been made." The Commission frequently in its history has made use of this power, and has itself begun proceedings for the removal of unreasonable condi- tions in rates and practices. But the Hepburn Act, in conferring upon the Commission the rate-making power, authorized it (Section 15) to make orders “after full hearing upon complaint made as provided in Section 13." It then became uncertain whether the Commission could make an order under Section 15 in a proceeding which it had instituted on its own motion as authorized by Section 13. It was of the ،، THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 613 greatest importance from the public standpoint that the Commission should continue to act on its own initiative whenever a situation seemed to warrant it. Frequently it was desirable that complaints should be broadened, and that the Commission should in- vestigate on a more comprehensive plan than the complaint as filed would permit. The Commission has in a few instances followed this policy, but it seemed undesirable that it should continue to exercise the right under a clouded title. Section 13 has now been amended so as to leave no doubt as to the powers of the Commission. It is given full authority at any time to institute any inquiry on its own motion, as to any matter concern- ing which any complaint is authorized, or any ques- tion may arise under the provisions of the Act, and its powers are to be the same, including the power to make and enforce orders, as tho the matter had arisen through formal complaint. Section 15, which gives the Commission power to prescribe rates upon complaint and after hearing, is amended by authoriz- ing the Commission to issue orders " after full hearing under an order for investigation and hearing made by the Commission on its own initiative (either in extension of any pending complaint or without any complaint whatever).” Regulations and Practices. It is required by the new Act that carriers shall prescribe just and reason- able regulations concerning the issuance, form, and substance of tickets, bills of lading, manner of mark- ing, packing, and delivering property, carrying of personal, sample, and excess baggage, and all other matters relating to the handling or storing of property, and all unreasonable regulations are prohibited and declared to be unlawful. This clause covers a mul- . .... M - 614 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS titude of details in connection with both passenger and freight traffic, concerning which there has been from time to time complaint on the part of shippers and passengers. One instance is that of sample baggage. Representatives of the traveling salesmen, in hearings before the House Committee, complained of the anomalous position which they occupy with respect to their baggage. Sample bag- gage in some states cannot be carried as personal bag- gage; in some sections railroads refuse to carry it at all; in other sections, railroads accept it, but assume no responsibility and the salesman is without standing before the Commission if he complains of unreasonable treatment. Another illustration of the kind of supervision which the Commission is expected to exercise under this section is found in the Act regulating the trans- portation of explosives, passed originally in 1908 and re-enacted in 1909, which directed the Commission to prepare regulations for the safe carriage of such traffic. Such power of supervision is now conferred in a general way by this amendment over all methods of handling and transporting property. It is made unlawful for a railroad to enforce other than reasonable regulations, and by an amendment to Section 15, the Commission is given jurisdiction over all regulations and practices of carriers and the power to prescribe reasonable regulations to be here- after followed. This broadens the scope of the Com- mission's authority, for under the Act of 1906 the Commission had no jurisdiction over the regulations and practices of a railroad except as they entered into the value of transportation to the shipper. Facilities for Through Routes. In connection with the requirement that every carrier shall establish THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 615 through routes and just and reasonable rates applicable thereto, it is now made the duty of each to provide reasonable facilities for the operation of these routes, proper rules for the interchange of cars, and reasonable compensation to those entitled to it. This clause was aimed at those railroads which limit the range of movement of their equipment, and was designed to promote the efficiency of through business. PROCEDURE The entire question of procedure may best be con- sidered in connection with the sections creating the Commerce Court. This court is to consist of five judges appointed for terms of five years. At the beginning, the President is to appoint five additional circuit judges for terms of from one to five years. At the expiration or termination of the assignment, the Chief Justice of the Supreme Court is to designate a circuit judge to fill the vacancy. After 1914, no circuit judge is to be reassigned to service in the Commerce Court without an interval of one year. Four judges constitute a quorum of the Court, and a majority must concur in all decisions. Regular sessions of the court are to be held in the city of Wash- ington. If at any time the business of the Court is not sufficient to demand the services of all the judges, the Chief Justice of the United States may terminate the assignment of any judge, or temporarily assign him for service in any circuit court or circuit court of appeals. Exclusive jurisdiction is conferred upon this Court over the following kinds of cases: 1. All cases for the enforcement of any order of the Commission other than for the payment of money, 616 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS where enforcement does not involve the collection of a forfeiture or penalty, or the infliction of criminal punishment. 2. All cases brought to enjoin or set aside in whole or in part any order of the Commission. 3. Suits brought under the Elkins Act to enjoin illegal discriminations or departures from published rates. 4. Suits brought under Section 20, praying for the issuance of writs of mandamus, to compel the filing of proper reports or the keeping of prescribed accounts, and under Section 23 to compel the movement of interstate traffic or the furnishing of facilities. The first class of cases comprises those in which an order of the Commission has been disobeyed by the carrier, and suit is brought for its enforcement. Suits for the collection of damages are left as in the Hepburn Act. The complainant files his petition in the Circuit Court of the United States, and the case proceeds. as do other civil suits of similar nature. The only change made in the new Act in this respect is the inclusion of a permission to file such suits also in state courts of general jurisdiction. If orders other than those excepted are disobeyed, the Commission or any party injured, or the United States, may apply by petition to the Commerce Court, and this Court, if it determines that the order was regularly made and duly served, . . . shall enforce obedience by a writ of injunction or other proper process." In the second class of cases are included orders of the Commission which the carrier seeks to enjoin or annul. Such appeal by a carrier does not operate of itself to stay the order of the Commission, but the Court may suspend in whole or in part the operation of the order pending final hearing of the suit. No (6 THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 617 injunction may issue except upon notice and after hearing. In cases where irreparable damage is liable to ensue, the Court, or a single judge thereof, may grant a stay of not more than sixty days, but such stay can only be granted upon hearing, and after three days' notice to the Commission and the Attorney- General, and the order granting the stay must contain a specific finding based upon evidence that such irreparable damage will ensue, and specifying its nature. Upon hearing the application, the full Court may continue the temporary stay beyond the sixty- day period until its final decision. The procedure retains in modified form the principle so bitterly contended for in the passage of the Hepburn Act, that notice and hearing must precede the issue of even a temporary injunction. The five days' pre- liminary notice of the Act of 1906 has been now reduced to three days.¹ As in the Hepburn Act, appeals may be taken from an interlocutory order granting an injunction, if made within thirty days, and from a final judgment of the Commerce Court if made within sixty days. Such appeals do not operate to supersede or stay the judgment unless so directed by the Supreme Court, and such cases have priority in hearing and determination over all except criminal causes. It should be noted that in exercising jurisdiction over the first two classes of cases, those for enforce- ment of the Commission's order following disobedience by the carrier, and those brought by a carrier in protest of the Commission's order, the new law holds the ground gained by the judicial interpretation 1 The measure as it passed the House provided for no preliminary notice, but limited the operation of the injunction to seven days. The Senate bill provided a five days' preliminary notice, and a stay of sixty days. 618 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 66 of the Hepburn Act. That Act put all orders of the Commission into effect unless suspended or set aside. by a court of competent jurisdiction, and it also provided that "if upon such hearing as the court may determine to be necessary it appears that the order was regularly made and duly served . . . the court shall enforce obedience." In discussing the Hepburn Act soon after its passage, I commented upon this provision in the following words: 1 It is perfectly clear that the judicial power is expected to interfere only when the order of the Commission is ultra vires or unconstitutional. Whether the Supreme Court will decide that the intent of the statute is unequivocally expressed in its terms remains to be seen. If upheld, a permanent step has been taken in the solution of the problem of railroad con- trol. Not only will the orders themselves be more effective, but their value will be enormously increased by the expedition with which they will go into effect." In the recent case of the Interstate Commerce Com- mission v. Illinois Central Railroad Company 2 this specific question was at issue and the Court seems to hold that it can only inquire as to the power of the Commission to make the order, and not into the expediency or wisdom of it; and in determining whether it should be set aside, it must consider solely whether the order was constitutional and whether it was within the scope of the Commission's delegated au- thority. So significant did this decision appear to be in limiting the powers of the Circuit Courts, and in strengthening the administrative powers of the Commission, that the advocates of administrative supervision insisted upon restricting the powers of 1 Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. xxi, p. 46. 2 215 U. S. Rep. 452. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 619 the new Court explicitly to those which, by this de- cision of the Supreme Court, the regular circuit courts were held to possess. Hence the Attorney-General, altho he contended that the bill as framed guarded this matter adequately, framed an amendment, provid- ing that "nothing contained in this Act shall be construed as enlarging the jurisdiction now possessed by the circuit courts of the United States or the judges thereof, that is hereby transferred to and vested in the commerce court," and this provision became a part of the measure as adopted. Care has been taken in the framing of these sections to furnish as simple a mode of procedure as possible in invoking the jurisdiction of the Court, and partic- ularly to eliminate all technical details of procedure that might furnish pretexts for delay to contesting counsel. Thus, for example, when a case is appealed to the Supreme Court, the Commerce Court is au- thorized to transmit the original record instead of a transcript, thus saving expense and eliminating the opportunity to question the accuracy of the record. Again, in order to avoid delay incident to the service of papers, every carrier is required to designate an agent in Washington upon whom process may be served. The question of procedure which the Administra- tion had most at heart was that which provided for the bringing of suits against the United States, in- stead of against the Interstate Commerce Commission; gave to the Attorney-General of the United States entire charge of all cases in the Commerce Court and in the Supreme Court on appeal; and stipulated that the Interstate Commerce Commission and its attorneys should take no part in the litigation. Heretofore, suits to review or set aside orders of 620 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 1 the Commission have been brought against it eo nomine, and have been defended by its own attorneys under the nominal supervision of the Attorney-Gen- eral. This practice has given rise to the criticism that the Commission assumes the functions of inves- tigator, judge, and then prosecutor, and that it is undignified for the Commission, having once rendered a judicial decision ¹ to go into the courts as a litigant in defense of its own orders. But the influence that was probably responsible for this provision emanated from a sensitive Department of Justice, which felt that the prosecuting force of the Interstate Com- merce Commission was invading its territory. This clause was framed by the Attorney-General of the United States with the purpose of defining clearly the functions of two conflicting departments, and re-establishing the Department of Justice in the position where he thought it properly belonged. But his ambitious program received a serious check at the hands of the "insurgents " in both houses, particularly in the Senate where generous provision for intervention of interested parties was made. Suits are to be brought against the United States rather than the Interstate Commerce Com- mission, and the Attorney-General is to have control of the interests of the Government in the Commerce Court and on appeal; but the Interstate Commerce Commission, and any party in interest to the proceed- ing before the Commission, may appear as parties of their own motion and as of right, and be represented by counsel, and the Court, not the Attorney-General, is to make all rules concerning appearances, procedure and number of counsel. A majority of the Senate 1 The Illinois Central Case, just referred to, would seem to imply that the Com- mission is a legislative and not a judicial body. - ( THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 621 Committee, in introducing the Administration meas- ure, discussed this subject of intervention, and de- clared that such a practice "would introduce intol- erable confusion in legal proceedings, and subordinate the general interests of all the people to the selfish concerns of one or more parties, whose special interests might be wholly at variance with the general public welfare," and that "it would be impossible for the Attorney-General to discharge the duty of defending the interests of the Government, if the conduct of the lawsuit were suffered to be complicated by one or a dozen or perhaps fifty intervening citizens, each advocating his own particular views, which might or might not harmonize with those of the counsel for the Government." Yet in the face of such arguments, the Act provides that not only interested parties, as already noted, but also communities, associations, corporations, firms, and individuals "who are in- terested in the controversy or question" before the Commission, may intervene at any time after the institution of a suit, and the Attorney-General shall not dispose of a suit over the objection of such inter- venor. This procedure, which seems to carry infor- mality to an extreme, came in response to the wellnigh unanimous protest of shippers against the administra- tion program. They contended that if cases were taken out of their hands, and if the Commission itself were denied participation, there would be no one connected with the case in the courts who had had any familiarity with it in its earlier stages, and that in complicated traffic questions this lack of association with the contest from the beginning would render the United States attorneys so helpless in contest with the railroads, that a disastrous outcome to the litigation in the courts would be a 622 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS foregone conclusion. They were unwilling to rely upon the self-interest of the Attorney-General to employ shippers' counsel as his assistants. The motives which led to the recommendation of a Commerce Court were stated in the special mes- sage of the President on January 7, when he called attention to the delay now attending the adjudication of cases in the United States Courts, the contrariety of opinion which issues from them, and the apparent inability of circuit judges to cope with the mass of conflicting and highly technical evidence. But the proposition met with surprisingly little cordial support. Its defense was perfunctory, the attack upon it was vigorous and pointed, and its adoption after signifi- cant amendment was apparently the result of a com- promise with the radicals, who granted this pet project of the President's in return for provisions which they considered vital to the measure. The Court was attacked, in the first place, as an unnecessary expense. It was shown that the number of cases that arose during the period from the passage of the Hep- burn Act to the close of 1909 and would have come under the jurisdiction of the Commerce Court, was only 26, and that the decision of the Supreme Court in the Illinois Central Car-distribution Case so narrowed the power of the courts over orders of the Commission, that the number of cases was likely to diminish in the future. In answer to the claim that delays would be avoided by a court which devoted its attention exclusively to railroad cases, it was contended that the delays arose in the preparation of cases, the taking of evidence, and in the presenta- tion and adjudication of cases on appeal in the Supreme Court, and that none of these delays would be avoided under the new arrangement. Such uniformity as THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 623 was desired from this Court was now being secured on appeal to the Supreme Court, whose business it was to look at these national questions in a broad way, and harmonize conflicting judgments. More- over, such a court, set apart to handle a specific kind of cases, in which corporations with enormous capital and great influence were interested, would become a special target for attack, and this would tend to lessen respect for our judiciary even if the attacks had no justification. Even among those who favored the creation of the Court, there were many, like the members of the Interstate Commerce Commission and prominent railroad attorneys, who objected to its shifting character. If expert knowledge of railroad questions was a desirable possession on the part of the judges in this Court, then why should they not be made a permanent body instead of being transferred every five years, or even more frequently, if the supply of cases did not meet the demand? Is it probable that expert knowledge would be found in a court, which, after five years, would be drafted from the general body of circuit judges? A final conclusion as to the wisdom of this policy must wait upon experience. Certainly the criticism of it was weighty enough to throw the burden of proof upon its advocates. That uniformity in de- cision is desirable by courts below our highest tribunal is not self-evident, that speed will be secured is a question of fact to be settled by actual test. A perusal of Supreme Court decisions on interstate commerce questions would lead one to desire a greater interest in technical traffic questions on the part of our judi- ciary, but this plan does not relieve the situation in the Supreme Court, and helps little in the Commerce 624 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Court, because judges are assigned to this work for a temporary period. That the Court may have more occupation than it would have had during the last three years is very likely, for the amendments to the Act will add to the litigation on interstate matters, and further amendments to the law are not improbable. Specialization in judicial affairs. should be beneficial as it has been in other fields of activity, and carefully chosen judges of unquestioned integrity should be able to withstand demagogic attacks. However, all that can be said for the Com- merce Court at the present time is that it can do no harm, and that it has in it some possibilities for good. MISCELLANEOUS PROVISIONS Penalties. The provisions of Section 10 which have stood unchanged since 1889, and which provide penalties of a $5000 fine and a two years' imprisonment against both shippers and carriers for infractions. of the Act such as false billing, and against shippers for inducing common carriers to discriminate, are now made applicable to all cases for which no penalty is otherwise provided. Offenses against which the section is directed are made more specific, especially those which cover misrepresentation on the part of the shipper of the actual character of his shipment. For this offense, not only the agents of corporations, but shipper corporations themselves, are now made liable. Disclosure of Information. It has been made a misdemeanor, with a penalty of $1000, for any common carrier, or any agent or employee, to disclose any information concerning the nature, route, or destina- tion of any shipment, when such information may qda da da da da 4 THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 625 be used to the injury of the shipper in favor of a com- petitor. It is likewise made unlawful for any person. to solicit such information. Thus a tardy step has been taken to protect shippers against a most con- temptible form of espionage practiced by competitors, usually by those who are powerful and well organized, and who, through the pressure which they can bring to bear as large shippers, can secure from the rail- roads information concerning the business of their rivals. In many instances, they have resorted to outright bribery of railroad employees. Had this law been on the statute books for the last twenty-five years and been vigorously enforced, small shippers would have had one less reason to denounce the abuses of aggregated capital. Statistics. Section 20 relating to statistics and accounts is amended by permitting the Commission to adopt for its statistical reports, the calendar year instead of the government fiscal year as at present, and by making more specific its power to call for periodical and special reports under oath. Enjoining State Statutes. A section was added at the end of the Act, which has no direct relation to the problem of common carrier regulation, yet has been called forth mainly by the conflicts of juris- diction in railroad cases. It provides that any petition for an interlocutory injunction, suspending a state statute, shall be made before three judges, of whom one shall be a justice of the Supreme Court of the United States, or a circuit judge. The appli- cation shall be heard only after five days' notice, except when irreparable loss or damage would result, in which case any one of the judges may grant a restraining order, which shall be effective only until the application for injunction can be heard. Appeal is direct to the Supreme Court. 626 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS The Act is to take effect at the expiration of sixty days after its passage, that is, after August 17, except the rate section and that creating a Commission on capitalization. These two sections took effect immediately. PROJECTS WHICH FAILED OF ENACTMENT The projects which failed of incorporation in the Act were quite as interesting and important as those which were adopted, and deserve a moment's con- sideration. It is significant that the two specific recommendations made in the Republican platform for amendment of the Interstate Commerce Act both failed of passage. The amendment authoriz- ing agreements between carriers as to rates failed to pass either house. Conflict arose over the questions as to whether such agreements should be approved in advance by the Commission and whether in fact it would be practicable to require such approval. It was contended that if such agreements contained all the rates involved, a submission of the agreements to the Commission would mean a costly duplication of the present labor incurred in connection with the filing of tariffs. But the real cause for the defeat of this proposal was the conviction that this meant a repeal of the Anti-trust law so far as railroads were concerned. It is apparent that the people are not yet ready to accept the principle of combination as applied to these great aggregations of capital invested in the transportation industry. How long we shall continue fondly to hug this fallacy of com- petition no one knows. There is certainly no im- mediate prospect that it will be abandoned in favor of any other economic principle. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 627 The elaborate provisions which, with certain im- portant exceptions, forbade the purchase by one railroad of the stock of another, and those which were intended to place the control of future capital issues in the hands of the Commission, all went down in defeat. They were extensively amended in the House. They were thrown out in the Senate by an almost unanimous vote. Their opponents represented three points of view. There were those who opposed stock and bond regulation of any kind. There was the element which regarded this project of federal regulation as an invasion of the rights of the States. Finally there was the group which strongly favored the principle, but which felt that the specific plan of the Administration was so cumbered with excep- tions, and so guarded with provisions of one kind and another, that the net result was a legalization of the present situation and a validation of a mass of worth- less securities. The House section went to conference and would have been thrown out altogether, but for the President's insistent reminder of the platform pledges. However, the most he could secure was the right to appoint a commission with authority to investigate questions pertaining to the issuance of stocks and bonds by railroad corporations, and the power of Congress to regulate such issues. While the desirability of control of capitalization is un- questioned, yet the plan as proposed was so compli- cated and the step after all so radical, in view of our previous policy, that it would seem wise to make haste slowly. If the commission does nothing else, it will at least give the public and its representatives in Congress an opportunity to gain a better acquaint- ance with the problem, and it may help to educate them along lines of wise regulation. It is to be hoped 628 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS that the proposal of the Administration bill will appear at the next session, shorn of a mass of the verbiage which now surrounds it. The House sent to the Conference Committee an amendment directing the Interstate Commerce Com- mission immediately to ascertain the value in money of all railroad property in the United States, and after the completion of this valuation, to ascertain periodically the value of extensions and improvements, such valuation to be received as prima facie evidence of the actual value of railroad property in all proceed- ings before the Commission and the courts. Those who passed this amendment in the House had no expectation that it could run the gauntlet of the Senate conferees. However, it is significant as a first attempt to respond to the urgent recommenda- tion of the Interstate Commerce Commission. Other proposals which passed one house but failed in conference, included the House proposals to extend jurisdiction of the Commission over water transporta- tion in Hawaii and over transportation to Alaska, and to grant to the Commission power to pass sep- arately on terminal and switching charges that are a part of the through rate. From the Senate, there were instructions that the Commission should every six months make an analysis of classifications and tariffs, showing changes in through rates on all staple commodities and report annually to Congress; and from the House, that the Commission should investi- gate the facts and practices as to discrimination, should report concerning investigations heretofore made, and should recommend changes in existing law. The failure of these provisions in conference must have occasioned prayers of thanksgiving in the offices of the Commission. THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 629 Finally, one or two matters should be mentioned which failed of action in either house, but which must sooner or later become subjects of serious con- sideration. It is difficult to understand why water carriers are still exempt from control. To be sure, they still proffer the old argument that they are a competitive industry, which by its very nature is so subject to competition that regulation is unnecessary. Divine Providence, they insist, may be trusted to care for the interests of shippers by water without any aid from the Interstate Commerce Commission. But any one who has given the situation a cursory examination knows how fallacious these contentions are, to what an extent the water lines are controlled by the railroads, and how largely rates between points ostensibly competing are made by combinations between the two agencies. More power seems to be given the Commission over water carriage than ever before by its authority to make through routes to which one of the parties may be a water line. Yet, in view of the fact that water carriers are by Section 1 placed under the jurisdiction of the Act only when they are used under a common control, manage- ment or arrangement for a continuous carriage or shipment," it is at least doubtful whether the Com- mission can force a water carrier against its will to become party to a through route or a joint rate. If a through route is made, and the water line becomes voluntarily a party to it and files its joint rates, the water carrier is under the jurisdiction of the Commission only with respect to business carried on these joint rates. One further extension of the jurisdiction of the Commission should be made, and water carriers should be placed under the Act along with other interstate carriers. 66 630 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Lack of power on the part of the Commission to prescribe minimum rates has proved, as was pre- dicted in 1906, to be an obstacle to the promotion of exact justice between shipping communities and between markets. This power the Commission should have. The commodities clause stands unamended, not- withstanding the interpretation of the Supreme Court, which, while nominally sustaining its constitutionality, robbed it of all practical efficacy. The Court held that the ownership of the stock of a coal company by a railroad company did not give the latter an interest direct or indirect in the coal which was mined, neither was the carrier in violation of the clause, if, being the legal owner of the coal, it sold it before transportation began. Attempts were made, notably that of Senator Bailey, to modify the wording so that the original intent of the clause might be re- stored, but neither house seemed disposed to make the simple verbal change necessary to give the clause the meaning which it was supposed to have when adopted four years ago. President Taft has received many congratulations for the success with which he has carried through his railroad policy, and doubtless he deserves great credit for the initial impulse to legislation given by his special message, and the bill which he and his advisers drafted. Likewise his influence should not be underestimated in rousing more than once the flagging interest of the Republican leaders, particularly in the Senate, and in giving final shape to many of the clauses through those frequent informal con- ferences of which the public knows little. Yet when we compare the Administration bill upon which THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 631 the President stood at the beginning, with the Act as passed, and when we follow carefully the course of the original bill in both houses and the debates upon it, we find that the valuable features contained in the measure as finally enacted were not written into it by the Administration, but were wrung from the Republican leaders by the persistent and able appeals of the "insurgent element, backed by a vigorously asserted public opinion, and supported in the chamber in many cases by the votes of the Democrats. More than this: the most desirable features of the Administration bill failed of enactment altogether. It will be generally conceded that the two most important clauses in the new law are those which vitalize the long and short haul clause and which empower the Commission to suspend pro- spective rate changes. The first was not included in the President's bill at all, the second was so worded as to permit suspension for only sixty days, which would have been of little or no value in the case of important rate changes. The extension of the Act to cover transmission of intelligence as well as passengers and freight, the discouragement of destructive competition against water lines, the strengthening of the penalty provisions, the establishment of the principle that a rate increased by a carrier is presumptively unreasonable, the de- claration in unmistakable terms that the Commission may initiate inquiries, the legislation against divulg- ing information concerning shipments, all were introduced into the bill after it left the hands of the Administration, and most of them on the floor of Congress and at the instance of "insurgent insurgent" Sena- "" tors and Representatives. On the other hand, three of the most important 1 632 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS features of the President's bill, that authorizing agree- ments as to rates, that forbidding the merger of com- peting lines, and that authorizing federal regulation of stock and bond issues, failed. The proposal for traffic agreements passed neither house. The capi- talization provisions failed in the Senate, were ma- terially modified in the House, and came out of conference in the form of a harmless investigating Commission. The only feature of the President's bill which retained a semblance of its original form was the Commerce Court, probably the least im- portant, certainly the least necessary portion of the Act, and even here the right of the public in pro- ceedings against the railroads would have been seriously jeopardized if the bill had been passed as introduced. It is to the credit of men like Senators Cummins and Clapp that the procedure was so modi- fied as to insure the shipping public adequate rep- resentation in court. This complete transformation of the proposals of the Administration into a measure far more radical than was intended by its authors finds its explanation in the demand of the people of the country, constantly becoming more insistent, for genuine regulation of the industry upon which their very life depends. In spite of the protests of the railroads, that further tampering with their operations would react to injure the service and put a check on extension and im- provement, the people have gone steadily on, not to be withstood in their determination to secure justice and equality in railway service, and the end is not yet. By the Acts of 1906 and 1910 they have created an administrative agency clothed with powers more extraordinary than have ever before been entrusted C THE MANN-ELKINS ACT 633 to any similar body in the history of this country. The Interstate Commerce Commission has jurisdiction over all important carriers of interstate commerce in the United States, except those operating solely by water. Their rates, classifications, regulations and practices are subject to the Commission's au- thority either with or or without complaint. Pro- spective rate changes may be suspended by it for ten months beyond their effective date, and if the Commission wills it, may never become effective. Its permission must be secured before a less rate can be charged for a longer than a shorter distance. At its discretion it may establish through routes and joint rates. Its orders are in force when made unless the courts set them aside, and this the courts cannot do without a hearing after notice. Finally, if present rulings are not overthrown, the courts will enforce all the Commission's orders, unless they are uncon- stitutional or beyond its authority. Surely the people of the United States have placed upon this Commission a grave responsibility. Upon its wisdom and justice the people rely for a successful regulation of the interstate commerce of this country.¹ DARTMOUTH COLLEGE. FRANK HAIGH DIXON. 1 Other interstate commerce legislation enacted, under separate measures, at the last session of Congress, include an act granting authority to the Commission to in- vestigate railroad accidents; a supplement to the safety-appliance acts requiring that cars after July 1, 1911, be equipped with sill-steps, hand-brakes, ladders and running boards; and an amendment to the employers' liability act defining the procedure and right of action. HF 1009 P18 DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE BUREAU OF THE CENSUS SAM. L. ROGERS, DIRECTOR Ir # 11 sli CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES 4.5. Солонка вел A IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS Prepared under the supervision of EUGENE F. HARTLEY, Chief Statistician for Manufactures • ·· Explanation of statistics... Diagrams showing stocks, consumption, and requirements.. TABLE I.-Stocks on hand or in transit, September 1, 1918 TABLE II.-Consumption, January 1 to June 30, 1918…… TABLE III.—Estimated requirements, July 1 to December 31, 1918. TABLE IV.-Summary-Stocks, consumption and requirements: A.-Manufacturers of the specified products-Steel works, roll- ing mills, etc…. B.-Wholesalers, jobbers, and dealers. C.-Railroad companies. D.-Shipyards.. E.-War Department MAN 101 CONTENTS F.-Manufacturers of agricultural implements and vehicles other than motor vehicles.. ☆ Page 3 4 5 6 8 UNITED 9999= 10 10 10 10 11 EPARTMENT OF TABLE IV-Continued. G.—Manufacturers of motor vehicles-Automobiles, trucks, and accessories... P.-Miscellaneous Per cent distribution.. 11 Schedule used in making the canvass. STATES H.-Manufacturers of bolts, nuts, rivets, nails, screws, etc. I.-Manufacturers of electric and electric-power machinery, apparatus, and supplies J.-Manufacturers of engines, pumps, compressors, etc., boil- ers, and tanks.. K.-Manufacturers of machine tools L.-Manufacturers of tools and hardware. M.-Manufacturers of machinery other than the foregoing. N.-Manufacturers of munitions and ordnance O.-Fabrications-Structural and architectural ironwork. COMMERCE WASHINGTON ☆ FAMERIC GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE → Page 11 11 -- - ………. 2 222 12 12 12 12 13 13 13 13 14 15 1919 NOTE. Reports received after completion of tabulation and not included in the tables, comprising: Railroad companies, 13; steel works and rolling mills, 1; shipyards, 2; manufacturers of agricultural implements, etc., 3; manufacturers of motor vehicles, etc., 1; manufacturers of engines, pumps, etc., 1; manufacturers of machinery not elsewhere specified, 4; manufacturers of munitions and ordnance, 2; and fabrications, 1-Total, 28. (Tons of 2,000 pounds.) CLASS OF STEEL. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs. Skelp, flue, etc. Wire rods. Plates (inch and over) Sheets (under } inch)……….. • Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches... Long angle splice bars... Structural shapes. Seamless tubes... Tubular products other than seamless tubes. Rails: 50 pounds and over.... Under 50 pounds.. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. Wire products.. Tool steel.. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel. Total.. --- STOCKS, SEPT. 1, 1918. Total. 2,034 281 452 3,331 293 3, 479 330 1,881 587 686 10, 787 1,001 3,058 1,926 144 2,792 33,062 Railroad com- panies. 80 281 1 557 208 2,106 300 88 329 377 10, 697 1,000 3,056 203 28 314 19,625 Other. 1,954 451 2,774 85 1,373 30 1,793 258 309 90 1 2 1,723 116 2,478 13,437 Total. CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS, 1918. 148,830 116 31,603 7,156 533 11, 634 443 9,779 931 582 14,096 805 12,052 15,043 216 6, 497 260,316 Railroad com- panies. 155 116 3 1,098 385 7,262 40 57 404 261 14,088 800 12,052 479 33 542 37,775 Other. 148, 675 31,600 6,058 148 4,372 403 9,722 527 321 8 ∞ LO 5 14,564 183 5,955 222, 541 For Government contracts. Amount. Per cent. 111,055 23, 700 2,933 22 2,086 970 515 25 10,814 160 2,113 154,393 75.3 75.0 41.0 4.2 17.9 9.9 55.3 4.3 71.9 74.1 32.5 59.3 2 EXPLANATION OF STATISTICS. 1972 ER Reclas The_accompanying tables present the statistics for Iron and Steel Products as reported by 10,494 establishments. The canvass included the manufacturers of the specified classes of iron and steel products; the wholesalers, dealers, jobbers, and supply houses carrying stocks; and manufacturers using the products as material in further processes of manufacture, including railroads and public service corporations that operate construction and repair shops and carry stocks for the upkeep of their properties, systems, and lines. The statistics include the consumption by the producers-that is, by the rolling mills, the wire-drawing mills, forging shops, etc.-of the specified classes of products in further processes of manufacture. ESTABLISHMENTS. The number of establishments is the number of reports received and not the number of individual plants, shops, or works. Thus, the United States Steel Corporation made one report covering 148 plants, mills, works, shops, and warehouses; the United States Railroad Administration, one report for the various corporations commonly known as Pennsylvania Lines West of Pittsburgh and one report for the Eastern Lines; the War Department, one report for all shops and works under the control of the Corps of Engineers. The report for the Corps of Engineers covers stocks only, data for consumption and requirements not being furnished. Separate reports were furnished for the arsenals with full data. The only report received from the Navy Department was for the Mare Island Navy Yard, Cal. This has been included with the data for the War Department. Establishments reporting less than half a ton of steel on hand or consumed have not been included in the tabulation. Approximately 850 reports of this character were received. TABLES. The statistics are presented in four tables as follows: TABLE I shows stocks on hand or in transit to the reporting establishment on September 1, 1918. TABLE II presents the statistics of consumption for the first half of the year, January 1 to June 30, 1918. TABLE III presents the statistics for requirements for the last half of the year, July 1 to December 31, 1918. TABLE IV is a summary showing stocks and consumption- requirement data for the year for all establishments and for the several groups of establishments, with per cent of distribution. A graphic presentation of the statistics by bar diagrams precedes the tables and a copy of the schedule used is shown at the end of this bulletin. CLASSIFICATION. The information given in answer to Inquiry III of the schedule has been used as a basis of classification according to chief products. The reports have been classified under 16 groups as follows: CC A. The producing establishments designated as Manufacturers of the specified products Steel works, rolling mills, etc." This group includes also tube and wire-drawing mills, forging shops, and tin- plate mills. These establishments reported stocks on hand, Sep- tember 1, of the various classes of steel, including ingots, billets, bars, etc., in process, stocks of the finished rolled products, and stocks of products of a higher degree of manufacture called for by the schedule, such as tubular products and wire. The producing establishments reported under Inquiry II of the schedule only the quantities of the specified classes of steel consumed in or required for their own establishment in further processes of manufacture; structural steel in fabrications, plates fabricated for ship and other constructions, horseshoe bars in the manufacture of horseshoes, etc. B.-Wholesalers, jobbers, and dealers.-This class reported stocks only-Railroad companies, both steam and electric. These companies reported stocks on hand for use in their repair shops and rails and track material, and consumption and requirements for repairs of rolling stock, track repairs, and replacements and new construction. D.-Shipyards. The shipbuilding companies reported the stocks on hand of the specified products in unfabricated forms, and con- sumption and requirement data for same. Supplies of plates and structural steel received in fabricated forms ready for assembling were not included, these being the products of the mills that fashioned them ready for erection and are included in the reports for such establishments. E-War Department.-These reports include the statistics for the arsenals and the shops and works under the control of the Corps of Engineers, the latter, however, being confined to stocks, as before stated. There are also included the statistics for the Mare Island Navy Yard. The remaining groups comprise the manufacturing establish- ments that use iron and steel materials of the specified classes. The establishments are classified according to their chief products, although in many cases they reported products which belong under another classification, shown, for example, by a large consumption of projectile steel by establishments engaged primarily in the man- ufacture of bolts, nuts, etc., and machinery, and projectile steel requirements for establishments included in the "Motor vehicle" and "Miscellaneous" groups. F.-Manufacturers of agricultural implements and vehicles other than motor vehicles. G.-Manufacturers of motor vehicles-Automobiles, trucks, and accessories. H.-Manufacturers of bolts, nuts, rivets, nails, screws, etc. I.— Manufacturers of electric and electric-pov:er machinery, appara- tus, and supplies. Manufacturers of engines, pumps, compressors, etc., boilers, J and tanks. • K.-Manufacturers of machine tools. L.-Manufacturers of tools and hardware. M.-Manufacturers of machinery other than the foregoing. N.-Manufacturers of munitions and ordnance. O.-Fabrications-Structural and architectural ironwork. P.-Miscellaneous, or manufacturers of commodities not else- where provided for. DURATION OF SUPPLY. On September 1, 1918, there was, in the aggregate, 8,589,000 tons of iron and steel material of the various classes on hand, not includ- ing scrap. The figures for consumption and requirements, taken as representing the year's consumption, aggregate 31,690,000 tons. These figures indicate that the stocks in the country, as of said date, were equal to approximately three and one-fourth months' supply for all classes of establishments. The following tabular statement gives, in terms of months' sup- ply, the ratio between stocks and consumption and requirements for the year (1) for the various classes of steel, and (2) for the industrial groups: All stocks..... CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars.. Months. 31 4. Skelp, flue, etc.. 5. Wire rods.. 6. Plates.. 7. Sheets. 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches →→→ 9. Reinforced-concrete bars 1 10. Long angle splice bars 11. Structural shapes.. 12. Seamless tubes.. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes 1 14. Rails.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie- plates. 16. Tin plate.. 17. Barbed wire ¹ 18. Wire rope 1 19. Other wire products ¹ 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties¹ 21. Tool steel... 22. Other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel……. 2212- 23 23 FOUR=4*** 41 4 14 24 G 12 6} 11 4 14 kapa sijui 25p de found 10 4 INDUSTRIAL GROUPS. Months. A.-Manufacturers of the specified products-Steel works, rolling mills, etc... C.-Railroad companies.. D.-Shipyards.. E.-War Department .. F.-Manufacturers of agricultural implements and vehicles other than motor vehicles.. G.-Manufacturers of motor ve- hicles Automobiles, trucks, and accessories.. H.-Manufacturers of bolts, nuts, rivets, nails, screws, etc. I.-Manufacturers of electric and electric-power machinery, appa- ratus, and supplies.. J.-Manufacturers of engines, pumps, compressors, etc., boilers, and tanks. 21 K.-Manufacturers of machine tools. L.-Manufacturers of tools and hard- ware... M.-Manufacturers of machinery other than the foregoing……. N.-Manufacturers of munitions and ordnance. O.-Fabrications-Structural architectural ironwork…. P.-Miscellaneous. and 1 Not comparable-largely used by consumers not canvassed. 2 Not comparable-consumption and requirements not fully reported. ********** 21 61 3} 41 23 3 51 LO 5 4 3 ~ 31 −444 21 31 3 4 CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. TOTAL.. CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, billets, etc. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet and tinplate-bars.... 4. Skelp, flue, etc.. 5. Wire rods.. 6. Plates.. 7. Sheets... 8. Merchant bars and shapes.. 9. Reinforced-concrete bars.. 10. Long angle splice bars.. 11. Structural shapes. 12–13. Tubular products…… 14. Rails.... 15. Rail joints, etc.. 16. Tin-plate.………. 17-19. Wire products. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties... 21-22. Tool steel, and all other- INDUSTRIAL GROUPS. A.-Steel works, rolling mills, etc.. B.-Dealers. C.-Railroad companies..... D.-Shipyards. E.-War Department. STOCKS, SEPT. 1, 1918; CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS, 1918. F.-Agricultural implements.. G.-Motor vehicles, etc.... H.-Bolts, nuts, etc I. Electrical machinery, etc. J.- Engines, pumps, etc...... K.-Machine tools... L.-Tools and hardware.... M.-Other machinery N.-Munitions and ordnance…. O.- Fabrications.. P.- Miscellaneous.. 1 2 Z ZZ Garan 17 2 TOTAL. Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918 Consumption and requirements, 1918: For Government contracts. Other... ? 6 3 m 2 ··· S OTHER 6 10 10 8 • MILLIONS OF TONS 20 MILLIONS OF TONS 16 7 6 CLASS OF STEEL. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs. Projectile steel.. Plates (inch and over), Sheets (under (inch). work.. All other. MILLIONS OF TONS 8 10 STOOKS, SEPT. 1, 1918 CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS, Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (includ- spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). Structural shapes Rails... Wire products. All other. 1918: FOR GOVERNMENT CONTRACTS S, 589, 047 16,922, 899 14, 767, 168 · 9 • INDUSTRIAL GROUP, 7 Steel works, rolling mills, etc. Wholesalers, jobbers, and dealers Railroad companies.. Shipyards.... War Department. Agricultural implements and vehicles other than motor vehicles. Motor vehicles—Automobiles, trucks, and acces- sories. Fabrications-Structural and architectural iron- I 7. 7 1 26 12 13 8 1 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 1,692,879 381,000 788, 227 724, 839 9 1,213, 714 581, 328 715, 905 331,735 2, 159, 420 14 15 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 3,747,216 542, 355 940, 312 451, 816 101, 533 305,409 288,819 315, 224 1.896, 363 90 Total. CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS, 1918. 10 10,338, 169 1,686, 144 2,857,461 1,804, 274 18 36 Total. Govern- ment contracts. 3,760,087 1,895, 431 2,190, 198 1,591, 428 1,288, 102 137, 413 1, 121, 925 314,504 6,643,707 2,195, 342 6,349, 834 1,683, 927 2, 136, 253 618,767 17 18 CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS, 1918. Govern- ment contracts. 17,599,500 10,423,869 1,688, 306 1,510,668 46,358 847, 163 1,300, 844 1,760,056 6,937, 172 1,448, 043 46,358 72,597 498, 516 1,166,957 3, 266, 559 * IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS. in 5 ܢ ܝ ܐ Number of establishments.. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 4. Skelp, flue, etc……… 5. Wire rods.. 6. Plates (inch and over) 7. Sheets (under inch).. 11. Structural shapes... 12. Seamless tubes.. 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). 9. Reinforced-concrete bars.. 10. Long angle splice bars. CLASS OF STEEL. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 14. Rails: TOTAL.... 23. Scrap iron and steel... 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate. 17. Barbed wire. Table 1.-STOCKS ON HAND OR IN TRANSIT, SEPTEMBER 1, 1918. (Tons of 2,000 pounds.) CLASS OF STEEL. 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel.. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel………. ·· 5. Wire rods. 6. Plates (inch and over). 7. Sheets (under inch). Number of establishments... 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars... 4. Skelp, flue, etc……. 11. Structural shapes.. 12. Seamless tubes.. 14. Rails: 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.)...... 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars. · plates.. 16. Tin plate. 17. Barbed wire. 13. Tubular products other than seam- less tubes.. • 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie- 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel.. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel. TOTAL.. 23. Scrap iron and steel.. 1 Agricul- tural im- plements and vehicles other than motor vehicles. -} • 4 55 610 1, 813 172 39 779 1,598 14, 97815, 955 27, 489 | 85, 535 484 tegn pag may mga ma .175, 203 50, 651 30 50 3, 219 368 218 Motor vehicles- Auto- mobiles, trucks, and acces- sories. 132 3,797 14, 350 1, 292 C 9,999 1,743 8, 793 7,258 9,309 13,509 798 30 590 1,969 2,866 8 48 318: 1 5, 922 5,735 6, 647 2,300 Bolts, nuts, rivets, nails, screws, etc. I 214 220 759 17, 191 181 37,644 95,746 30 10 105 298 78 12 468 14,962 1, 634 1, 156 I 19, 156 Total. 1 10, 494 1,692, 879 381, 000 190, 317 179, 317 118, 398 788, 227! 724, 839 1, 213, 714 85,952 17,956 581, 328 78, 228 440, 333 650, 256 65, 649 181, 334 .301, 950 10, 201 24, 695 296, 839 91, 912 61, 586 412, 137 8, 589, 047 1,873, 988 59 26 1, 127 13,960 47, 344 21, 147 239 142 6, 748 658 5,683 1,096 406 347 1,298 1, 102 653 13, 206 189, 950 116, 873 7,883 65 111 Manufacturers of the specified | Wholesalers, products- I jobbers, Steel works, and rolling mills, dealers, etc. + 629 7,263 51 17 441 1,639, 943 267, 118 186, 646 176, 202 79,056 186, 815 147, 558 272, 843 21, 362 12, 279 7,854 163, 118 22, 193 19, 437 75, 460 3, 747, 216 1, 429, 554 MANUFACTURERS CLASSIFIED ACCORDING TO CHIEF product. Electric and electric- Machinery other power ma- pressors, Machine Tools and chinery, etc., tools. hardware. than the ! apparatus, boilers, foregoing. Engines, pumps, com- and supplies. and tanks. 418 1, 151 305 151, 539 11, 315 112,412 19, 826 14, 780 98, 204 20, 644 24, 566 45, 590 5,062 662 73 437 257 515 50, 688; 2, 443 55, 808 4,681 190 for 33, 740 19, 538 68 44 1 4 2,075 352 7 145 ¿ 807 2,942 2,004 1, 413 1, 916 1,498 2, 946: 22, 995 19 30 T 3 1,966 41 82 1,075 1, 686 490 10, 487 27, 555 217, 926 69, 044 46, 671 16, 433 675 631 106 5,915 799 29, 227 39, 301 156, 003 22, 657 20 942 259 36 50 25, 937 5, 688 171, 103 43, 945 75, 291 305, 409 288, 819 13, 406 10, 023 35, 692 1 1 ¹ Including United States Navy Yard, Mare Island, Cal. 5,371 5,877 1, 133 10, 672 1,453 1,810 33, 399 10, 910 5,599 15, 051 542, 355 16, 874 51,747 50, 561 461 189 2 127 576 17,783 73 1,823 18, 819 1,216 3,947 21, 212 869 62 189 6, 153 9, 155 8, 253 I t Railroad companies. 40 69, 272 19, 170 93,822 7,426 1, 024 38, 372 22, 814 14, 868 494, 935 4, 941 143, 947 402 1, 839 727 4, 126 98 1, 178 11, 421 940, 312 145, 598 499 6, 233 20 637 1,023 4, 935 12, 354 273 341. 17,761 17, 511 738 1, 043 410 784 13 667 2,956 911 4,744 1,366 83, 103 5 165 9, 216 6, 470 Munitions and ordnance. Shipyards. 5, 807 46 60: 69 249, 746 7,112 20 3,418 102 6,577 135, 289 668 5,067 ! 40, 013 371 2 5 1 1, 312 96 29 519 1,495 451, 816 4,823 3, 040 333 141 43, 013 27, 014 374 3,588 124, 943- 335 442 564 502 60 $5 569 2,099 199 1,050 756 137 18, 625 34,573 5, 470 3, 237 132, 880 193, 739 120, 606 315, 224 13, 242, 29, 405 5, 355 17,058 636 2,774 392 79 1 935 77, 679 19, 350 7,852 1,736 911 War Depart- ment.! 10 Fabri- cations- Structural Miscel- and archi-' laneous. tectural ironwork. 5, 611 327 12, 647 6,576 5, 880 2,428 29 10, 109 232 1, 243 21, 333 18, 558 7,771 132 1, 330 165 2, 106 22 234 1,800 101, 533 5, 354 3,076 5, 142 14, 621 998 190 13, 052 36, 166 180, 030 98,000 411 491 25,741 9, 942 53, 726 22,332 12, 633 2,643 236,855 319 4, 256 5-1, 719 21, 790 8,923 52,365 855, 345 76, 617 6 CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. O CT A CNT 2 3 5 6 7000 1224 8 9 10 11 13 15 16 070 2222 **** NO 17 18 19 20 21 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 22** *0* 34 *** **♡ ♡ go 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 50 2. Projectile steel..... 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. Used for Government contracts. Used for Government contracts. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars.. Used for Government contracts... 4. Skelp, flue, etc………. Used for Government contracts. 5. Wire rods... Used for Government contracts.. CLASS OF STEEL. 6. Plates ( inch and over).... Used for Government contracts. 7. Sheets (under inch). Used for Government contracts. Table I.-CONSUMPTION, JANUARY 1 TO JUNE 30, 1918. (Tons of 2,000 pounds.) 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). Used for Government contracts. 9. Reinforced-concrete bars.. 12. Seamless tubes.. Used for Government contracts. -- 10. Long angle splice bars.... Used for Government contracts. 11. Structural shapes... Used for Government contracts.. 14. Rails: Used for Government contracts. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. Used for Government contracts... 17. Barbed wire. 50 pounds and over. Used for Government contracts. Under 50 pounds.. Used for Government contracts.. 18. Wire rope.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. Úsed for Government contracts. 16. Tin plate.. Used for Government contracts... Used for Government contracts. 19. Other wire products... Used for Government contracts.. 21. Tool steel. Used for Government contracts. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties.. TOTAL... Used for Government contracts. Used for Government contracts. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel. Used for Government contracts.. 49 23. Scrap iron and steel... Used for Government contracts.. Total. Used for Government contracts. 4, 942, 888 2, 883, 680 662, 752 660, 863 629, 102 201, 016 321, 586 116, 783 427, 733 112, 919 1, 145, 467 748, 065 882, 843 224, 693 1,757, 735 803, 947 30, 433 6, 976 40, 423 33, 227 932, 752 615, 207 91, 769 50, 269 200, 534 63, 954 583, 553 45, 872 36, 142 22, 126 91, 258 2, 233 418, 193 26, 964 31, 409 11, 612 14, 881 3, 114 473, 666 97, 200 146, 995 43, 774 44, 089 25, 487 640, 659 192, 143 14,546, 862 6, 992, 124 Manufacturers of the specified products-Steel works, rolling mills, etc. 4,792, 211 2,759, 950 438, 346 436, 646 626, 813 200, 466 318, 302 116, 548 346, 334 79, 471 213, 970 129, 437 71, 355 26, 528 600, 277 358,515 1, 064 103 34, 232 32, 165 284, 686 236, 815 19, 212 14, 701 4,366 193 56, 984 22, 739 10, 059 10, 006 585 367 7,856 202 22, 425 11, 239 98 53 256, 955 55, 920 60, 525 18, 063 4, 708 2, 971 54, 650 30, 925 8, 226, 013 4, 544, 023 4, 453, 030 2,243, 474 1 Including United States Navy Yard, Mare Island, Cal. 3,876, 679 2,084, 682 Railroad companies. 6, 093 87 304 40 50,054 16, 375 97,628 5, 218 3,851 32, 537 12, 556 13, 464 486, 270 3, 408 87,298 460 1, 128 742 2,317 46 717 17,869 838, 462 53, 813 • Shipyards. 9,039. 8, 951 4 4 315, 377 301, 373 9, 524 8, 591 41, 460 36, 932 574 478 73 72 134, 877 124, 348 384 309 5,757 5, 017 4, 587 3, 156 480 470 333 185 38 38 24 2, 027 1,880 182 134 5 сл сл 5 486 453 3,875 3,847 529, 106 496, 243 4, 986 1,896 War Do- partment.1 1,552 1,552 201 201 4, 054 4, 054 1,256 1,256 1, 319 1, 319 52 52 12 12 875 875 457 457 457 457 1, 116 1, 116 13 13 15 15 2,976 2,976 12 12 28 28 36 36 A 1 1 293 293 2,988 2,988 17, 713 17, 713 4, 197 4, 197 H+OF 4 1 " 1 + IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS. 7 Agricultural Implements and vehicles other than motor vehicles. 1,901 120 8 368 627 890 74 21, 259 1, 467 35, 096 816 252, 116 21, 868 227 13 32 9, 480 461 1,228 32 14, 006 521 41 293 191 227 10 7, 452 48 15,369 798 1,071 21 55, 511 4, 046 417, 393 30, 295 69, 991 1, 821 Motor vehicles- Automobiles, trucks, and accessories, 3, 356 1, 480 6 6 4 1 2, 545 1, 927 28, 516 17,984 247, 469 39, 276 70, 626 26, 280 3, 370 180 • 473 188 9, 800 3, 845 9, 484 4, 719 1,851 542 1, 632 1,242 61 50 232 181 2,290 99 101 1 4, 614 53 4, 722 1, 138 7,794 2,032 2,479 594 272, 282 40, 276 673, 707 142, 094 11, 371 6, 265 Table II.-CONSUMPTION, JANUARY 1 TO JUNE 30, 1918-Continued. (Tons of 2,000 pounds.) Bolts, nuts, rivets, nails, screws, etc. 1, 251 4, 250 4, 250 503 100 48, 718 18, 127 359 15 16, 665 3,380 200, 659 118,562 40 10 14. .64 137 125 434 100 112 37 105 249 61 25, 493 6,838 2,842 575 812 385 22, 602 12, 480 325, 295 165, 049 8, 152 78 MANUFACTURERS CLASSIFIED ACCORDING TO CHIEF PRODUCT. Electric and electric- power machinery, apparatus, and supplies. 3,248 2, 410 128 128 58 1 543 382 10, 636 6, 914 47, 987 26, 683 15, 210 6, 854 569 59 128 17 10, 036 4,794 441 231 8,995 2,882 1, 140 175 554 356 44 13 148 125 336 183 2,269 1,263 1, 600 1, 147 613 386 15, 767 7,855 120, 450 62, 858 12, 308 9, 271 Engines, pumps, com- pressors, etc., boilers, and tanks. 18, 809 16, 541 50 288 47 179, 403 113, 747 75, 861 27, 088 61, 119 31, 592 445 146 169 74 24, 279 15, 201 32, 910 23,696 32, 637 15, 871 369 220 40 3 1,975 21 125 248 87 831 248 1, 124 207 576 359 13, 059 5, 467 444, 320 250, 612 73,552 31, 653 Machine tools. 6, 005 5,967 45 45 16 15 422 201 2, 584 1, 135 4, 285 998 17,064 9, 879 75 38 27 25 2,283 1,097 376 131 2, 972 2, 171 55 30 30 сл 49 18 17 2, 945 45 727 475 132 27 10, 691 8, 991 28, 637 18, 093 79, 443 49, 380 37,076 26, 032 Tools and hardware. 3, 936 1,373 3 12 1 711 94 5, 789 3, 481 2,732 1,262 32, 619 11, 582 65, 533 33, 317 283 30 1, 458 448 708 611 5,578 1,480 1, 477 389 109 100 552 5 11, 496 2, 394 18, 358 3, 232 10, 526 5, 122 19,058 7,891 180, 938 72, 812 13, 773 4, 052 } Machinery other than the foregoing. 8, 477 3, 834: 113, 811 113, 750 51 16 3 451 98 ! 24, 146 6, 133 28, 753 4,585 68, 483 24, 637 268 39 206 141 20, 726 6, 621 1,675 666 16, 830 4, 670 681 98 2,010 267 194 7 953 187 49 1 1, 011 236 3, 185 977 1,689 524 6, 097 3,252 44, 716 13, 491 344, 465 184, 230 65, 231 19, 264 1 Munitions and ord- nance. 9,553 8,985 93, 713 93, 713 37 5 228 188 13, 410 7, 200 4, 291 3, 616 10,927 7, 115 20 20 1 1 5,207 2, 159 131 35 132 104 20 7,487 76. 38: 35 1, 450 822 157 125 712 468 7,022 3,934 154, 536 128, 601 I 8, 133 6,372 Fabrications— Structural and architectural ironwork. 73, 180 69, 929 2 142 11 3,630 1, 147 190, 653 128, 088 40, 753 15, 660 88, 682 47, 331 18, 153 5,781 217 114 343,918 199, 334 713 515 10, 399 5, 903 4, 150 1, 655 1,001 502 257 70 2,254 1, 195 321 21 173 104 6, 446 2,097 446 117 226 70 3, 812 1,487 789, 528 481, 131 66, 832 8, 503 Miscellaneous. ¦ 1, 136 41 4,277 2, 588 12, 390 12, 325 5 1, 514 500 6 : 1 9 17,650 7,571 10 1 88,314 11 29, 256 12 250, 554 13 54, 634 14 166, 632 15 79,746 16 358 17 57 18 Spad 1 1 234 719 19 388 20 52, 526 21 19, 205 22 7 8 11, 357 23 24 4, 041 { 82, 656 25 24,043 26 I 27 28 26, 549 15, 471 18,445 29 10,432 : 30 1 2,292 31 1,395 32 389,825 33 21, 619 34 6, 801 : 35 22136 1,593 37 334 38 150, 105 39 24, 810 40 36,907 41 16, 921 42 1 4, 082 43 2, 122, 44 78, 811 : 45 39, 363 46 1, 405, 493 47 367,083 48 116, 936 | 49 39,388, 50 xc CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. 123TLO CO 5 6 -J 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 ON 2222 **** 17 18 19 20 21 23 24 25 26 ww 27 28 29 30 31 12 32 33 34 3288888 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 CTA AN 47 48 49 50 ! 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. For Government contracts.. 2. Projectile steel... For Government contracts. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars.. For Government contracts. 4. Skelp, flue, etc..... 5. Wire rods………….. For Government contracts.. For Government contracts. Table III.-ESTIMATED REQUIREMENTS, JULY 1 TO. DECEMBER 31, 1918. (Tons of 2,000 pounds.) 6. Plates (inch and over)………. For Government contracts. 7. Sheets (under inch). CLASS OF STEEL. For Government contracts.. 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). For Government contracts.. 35 17. Barbed wire. 36 9. Reinforced-concrete bars... For Government contracts. 10. Long angle splice bars.... For Government contracts. 11. Structural shapes……….. For Government contracts.. 12. Seamless tubes.... 37 18. Wire rope.. 14. Rails: For Government contracts. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. For Government contracts.. 50 pounds and over.. For Government contracts. Under 50 pounds……… 16. Tin plate..... For Government contracts.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates.. For Government contracts.. For Government contracts.. For Government contracts... For Government contracts. -- 19. Other wire products..... 21. Tool steel.. For Government contracts.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties... contracts.. For Government contracts. TOTAL. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel. For Government contracts.... For Government contracts. 23. Scrap iron and steel.. For Government contracts.. Total. 5,395, 281 3,466, 154 1,023, 392 1,023, 064 747, 474 318,586 453, 116 146, 806 516, 708 182, 919 1,711, 994 1,388, 188 921, 431 394, 074 2,002, 352 1,091, 484 42,869 16, 561 - 45, 174 36, 768 1,257, 446 976, 221 113, 123 53, 017 235, 184 99, 239 625, 251 49, 866 43, 156 19, 549 97, 787 1, 660 471, 752 61, 743 71, 073 49, 550 13,095 4, 593 515, 801 148, 435 165, 214 65, 943 48, 694 30, 844 623, 838 305, 511 17, 143, 205 9,930, 775 A po dogo sanaan dado q Manufacturers of the specified products-Steel works, rolling mills, etc. 5, 203, 234 3, 313, 674 561, 973 561, 973 745, 471 317, 554 447, 385 146, 164 417, 577 137, 210 298, 056 260, 170 87,671. 50, 584 644, 274 452, 306 929 103 36, 017 35,000 372, 749 350, 810 25, 640 5, 444 5, 244 313 59, 661 25, 127 10, 066 10, 026 2,972 359 10, 302 3,335 58,398 49, 228 112 64 244,525 84, 169 73, 451 27,779 5, 385 3,666 62, 395 44, 788 9, 373, 487 5,879, 846 5, 248, 687 2, 911, 760 4, 570, 747 2,623, 239 Including United States Navy Yard, Mare Island, Cal, Railroad companies. 8, 594 76 150 、 36 49, 302 3, 297 95, 729 8, 043 6, 203 38, 938 14, 709 11, 417 500, 784 1,580 91, 216 . 518 1,362 777 2,372 59 875 15, 807 849, 844 47,816 J 1 • Shipyards. 9,789 9, 742 44 592, 614 582, 420 13, 916 13, 666 68, 839 63,372 10, 259 10, 137 336 306 258, 376 247, 174 948 918 8,750 8, 310 6, 445 5, 724 807 797 193 117 164 164 7 3,099 3,000 203 193 121 63 732 710 5, 960 4, 983 981, 562 951, 800 8, 176 6, 656 War De- partment,¹ 8, 548 8, 548 226 226 5, 224 5, 224 1,372 1,372 1, 702 1, 702 195 195 12 12 2,032 2,032 50 50 602 602 325 325 10 10 1 1 3,823 3,823 1 49 49 54 54 1 1 367 367 4,051 4, 051 28, 645 28, 645 26, 886 26, 886 +3 A Men man and Agricultural implements and vehicles other than motor vehicles. 3,009 266 10 308 741 1,057 70 21, 067 2, 331 36, 433 1, 459 261, 677 29, 814 210 32 8, 201 820 1,350 215 14, 979 776 60 12 298 288 230 15 7, 447 40 16, 036 915 1,032 36 55, 305 5, 533 429, 770 42, 302 85,973 18, 904 IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS. Table III.-ESTIMATED REQUIREMENTS, JULY 1 TO DECEMBER 31, 1918-Continued. (Tons of 2,000 pounds.) Motor vehicles- Automobiles, trucks, and accessories. 5,340 2,271 19, 400 19, 400 8 1 3, 002 2, 362 69, 915 63,072 192, 136 105, 746 80, 486 40, 985 2, 123 89 474 242 14, 012 7,116 11, 069 6, 833 2, 168 889 1, 280 50 335 215 149 19 2,483 156 101 1 847 112 4, 625 1, 194 5, 969 2,506 2,587 1, 330 208, 628 101, 833 627, 137 356, 422 38, 764 25, 783 Bolts, nuts, rivets, nails, screws, etc. 1, 356 2,200 150 58,007 26, 429 660 20 20, 765 6, 953 249, 640 168, 158 50 5 ·20 23. 52 3 128 117 691 118 125 51 110 257 62 26, 580 12, 545 2,363 583 966 547 27, 423 17, 022 391, 373 232, 763 S, 139 132 MANUFACTURERS CLASSIFIED ACCORDING TO CHIEF PRODUCT. Electric and electric- power machinery, apparatus, and supplies. 4,331 3, 691 8 1 873 612 16, 330 12, 208 -51, 091 33, 242 19,823 12, 460 704 3 165 23 12, 819 6, 718 456 280 11, 142 3,776 969 265 733 577 17 14 109 83 396 159 2,685 1,685 2,353: 2, 118 681 463 20, 743 12, 862 146, 428 91, 240 I 13, 428 10, 714 t 1 Engines, pumps, com- pressors, etc., boilers, and tanks. 22, 878 19, 570 50 290 81 216, 297 149, 948 90,478 34, 682 74, 920 39, 083 305 200 149 76 29, 133 20, 069 42, 107 31, 469 37,948 18, 087 367 291 15 2 1,871 47 155 284 97 956 267 979 151 655 425 15,496 7, 029 535, 393 .321, 574 85, 016 43, 763 Machine tools. 7,243 4, 517 56 56 19 17 460 183 2,597 1,988 4,371 1,250 18,066 10, 562 25 12 52 50 2,303 1,801 317 124 2,637 2,251 30 30 43 19 17 2,928 70 827 438 161 25 12, 353 10, 170 31, 789 19, 302 88, 296 52, 863 41, 086 31, 965 } Tools and hardware. 6, 529 2, 165 3 62 51 1, 400 492 7,778 5, 599 2, 844 1,372 38, 974 15, 527 81, 262 45, 110 311 80 1,801 699 719 578 5,755 2, 466 1 1 2, 502 1,008 1 833 32 11,547 4, 753 18, 058 4, 951 11, 686 7,361 22, 757 10, 566 214, 823 102, 811 13, 658 3, 299 Machinery other than the foregoing. 7,509 2,856 183, 471 183, 270 62 28 10 5 429 208 26, 149 8, 411 29, 263 7,386 72, 376 18,259 177 36 412 364 21, 567 8, 382 1,891 513 19, 407 7,172 707 94 1,985 192 260 15 1,073 192 49 1, 103 277 3, 520 1, 424 1, 649 575 6, 149 3,307 49, 104 15, 048 428, 317 258, 009 70, 056 27,032 F i ! • Munitions and ordnance 10, 191 4, 165 210, 571 210, 571 8 8 182 162 20, 564 19, 394 4, 665 4, 268 14, 805 12, 034 20 20 1 1 4,898 : 3, 074 124 41 130 114 : 7,085 73 50 6 1,542 528 116 91 956 741 6, 543 3, 423 282, 451 258, 717 8, 196 6, 456 1 Fabrications- Structural and architectural ironwork. 93, 606 91, 069 141: 3,769 732 259, 758 203, 653 11, 835 19, 142 104, 016 69, 672 19, 546 5,661 295 193 413, 883 279, 484 S11 558 11, 533 6, 800 5, 059 2,036 822 245 336 182 2, 649 1,664 406 51 204 158 7,429 2,496 335 130 127 68 3,968 1,832 970, 528 685, 826 + 94, 442 13, 538 1 1 Miscellaneous. 3, 620 47,858 5, 124 1 47, 794 1,311, 5 926 1, 235 9 23, 018 193 TO SO + 7 8 9 9, 041 10 4 Į 6 130, 617. 11 77,977. 12 13 305, 164 98, 797 14 214, 737 · 15 127,967, 16 283 17 100 18 715 : 19 1 421 20 76, 682: 21 48, 039 22 17 12, 804 23 5,874 24 102, 781 25 47,565 26 49, 654 : 27 15,954 28 26, 713 7,443 29 30 2,642 31 952 32 ! 438,707 33 51, 147 34 10, 176: 35 252 36 1,926 37 492: 38 203,489 39 38, 649 40 43, 563 41 26,055 42 4, 143 | 43 1, 653 44 93, 869 45 57, 239 46 1,797, 211 | 47 667,957 48 136, 304 49 73, 393 50 10 CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. 1 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 4. Skelp, flue, etc. 5. Wire rods. CLASS OF STEEL. 6. Plates (inch and over) 7. Sheets (under inch). 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (in- cluding spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.).. 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars. 11. Structural shapes. 12. Seamless tubes. • → Table ÏV.—SUMMARY—STOCKS, CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS. TOTAL.-10,494 ESTABLISHMENTS. - 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds... 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate.. 17. Barbed wire. 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel... TOTAL.. 23. Scrap iron and steel. • 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.... 4. Skelp, flue, etc.. 5. Wire rods. 14. Rails: • 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes.. 440, 333 14. Rails: CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs……. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 6. Plates (inch and over) 7. Sheets (under 1 inch).. · 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.) - 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars.. 11. Structural shapes. 12. Seamless tubes. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes... - ❤ TOTAL... 23. Scrap iron and steel.. 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds……. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates.. 16. Tin plate. 17. Barbed wire. 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel….. Stocks. Sept.1,1918. 118, 398 788, 227 724, 839 1, 692, 879 10, 338, 169 381, 000 1, 686, 144 190, 317 1, 376, 576 179, 317 774, 702 944, 441 2,857, 461 1, 804, 274 1, 213, 714 85, 952 17, 956 581, 328 78, 228 10, 201 24, 695 296, 839 91, 912 61, 586 650, 256 1, 208, 804 65, 649 79, 298 181, 334 189, 045 301, 950 889, 945 102, 482 B.-WHOLESALERS, JOBBERS, AND DEALERS (942 ESTABLISHMENTS). Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. Per cent Amount. of Consumption and requirements, 1918. class total. 259 (¹) 36 (1) 50 (1) 799 0.7 3.7 5.4 29, 227 39, 301 Total. 156, 003 12.9 22, 657 26.4 20 0.1 25, 937 4. 5 5,688 7.3 171, 103 38.9 5,371 5,877 1, 133 10, 672 1, 453 14. 3 1,810 7.3 33, 399 11.3 10, 910 11.9 5,599 9.1 3, 760, 087 73, 302 85, 616 2, 190, 198 204, 892 435, 718 27,976 991, 467 312, 209 92, 783 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. For Government contracts. 1, 1, 116, 645 20, 125 3, 557 895, 431 50. 4 23, 537 32.1 69,995 81.8 591, 428 72.2 103, 286 50.4 163, 193 37.5 95, 738 7.9 41, 675 52.6 3, 893 2.1 10.0 18, 158 61, 162 58.7 80, 823 7,707 27.9 210 245, 635 24.8 501, 480 109, 717 35.1 133, 976 56, 331 60.7 10, 093 412, 137 1, 264, 497 497, 654 39.3 75, 460 117, 045 75, 713 64.7 18.3 9.1 8, 589, 047 31, 690, 067|16, 922, 899 53. 43, 747, 21617, 599, 500 10, 423, 869 59.2 43.6 55.5 88, 707 1, 873, 988 9, 701, 717 1, 429, 554 8, 447, 426 76.3 87.0 6.233 Amount. C.—RAILROAD COMPANIES (499 20 637 40 69, 272 19, 170 ESTABLISHMENTS). · Per cent. Consump- tion and require- ments, 1918. 6, 349, 834 61. 41, 639, 943 9, 995, 445 1, 683, 927 99.9 267, 118 1, 000, 319 519, 602 37.7 186, 646 1, 372, 284 263, 589 34.0 176, 202 765, 687 295, 838 31.3 79, 056 763, 911 2, 136, 253 74.8 186, 815 512, 026 618, 767 34.3 147, 558 159, 026 A.-MANUFACTURERS OF THE SPECIFIED PRODUCTS-STEEL WORKS, ROLLING MILLS, ETC. (441 ESTABLISHMENTS). Stocks. Stooks, Sept.1,1918. Per cent of class total. 12, 687 0.4 163 (¹) 454 0.4 76 (¹) 99, 356 8.8 19, 672 2.6 272, 843 1, 244, 551 21, 362 1,993 12, 279 70, 249 151, 539 657, 435 44, 852 9, 610 11, 315 112, 412 98, 204 20, 644 24, 566 45, 590 5, 062 7,854 163, 118 22, 193 19, 437 Consumption and requirements. Consumption and requirements, 1918. $ Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. Total. 6, 577 0.1 (¹) 0.1 (¹) 3.5 249, 746 1.1 7, 112 193, 357 7.7 5. 2 40, 013 13, 261 8.6 18.1 371 10, 054| 22.6 11.8 2 71, 475 6.6 3.2|| 135, 289 27, 265 29. 2 13.3 668 24, 881 3.4 5.7 5, 067 3, 040 333 141 5 987, 054 76. 0 81. 7 4, 988 7.5 6. 3 178, 514 79:4 94.5 978 0.1 0.1 2, 490 18.0 2.4 1,519 2.9 5. 4 4,689 1.3 0.5 105 0.1 (¹) 1,592 1.9 1.7 Total. 18, 828 For Governinent contracts. D.-SHIPYARDS (102 ESTABLISIIMENTS). 8 907, 991 23, 440 Amount. 110, 299 10,833 409 393, 253 393, 253 1, 332 14, 507 11, 032 1, 287 526 202 Por cont. Consumption and require- ments, 1918. 31 5, 126 385 6, 073, 624 60.8 96.9 96.7 998, 619 99.8 70.1 59.3 518, 020 37.7 98.1 99.7 262, 712 34.3 98.3 98.8 216, 681 28.4 66.8 80.9 389, 607 76.1 23.7 18.0 77, 112 48.5 20.4 8.8 Per cent of class total. 810, 821 65.1 22.5 33.1 206 10.3 24.9 2.7 67, 165 95.6 68.3 82.1 587, 625 89.4 26.1 30.0 20, 145 44.9 14.5 21.9 506 5.3 25.5 2.2 Stocks. 47, 866 41.0 15.1 9.6 20, 032 99.5 31.4 25.4 726 20.4 13.6 1.9 3, 537 19.5 15.1 2.0 60, 467 74.8 49.6 79.0 117 55.7 31.8 0.8 140, 089 27.9 55.0 50.5 45, 842 34.2 24.2 42.9 6, 637 65.8 31.3 10.9 For Government contracts. A mount. and require- Consumption ments. 93, 822 7,426 4, 024 38, 372 22, 814 14, 868 0.8 494, 935 9.0 4, 941 0.6 143, 947 3.5 402 1, 839 727 4, 126 98 1, 178 1, 312 96 126 1, 218 29 519 15, 051 3.7 11, 421 33, 676 2.7 2.7 1, 495 9, 835 542, 355 6. 3 940, 3121, 688, 306 10.9 5.3 451, 8161, 510, 6681, 448, 043 95. 9 16,874 0.9 145,598 101, 629 7.8 1.0 1 ¹ Less than one-tenth of 1 per cent. 4,823 13, 162 Per cent of class total. Stocks. Consumption requirements. Per cent. 18, 693 99.2 0.4 0.2 pub 8100.0 (¹) 883, 793 97.3 31. 7 31. 3 22, 257 95.0 1.0 1.3 100, 304 90.9 3.3 2.9 10, 615 98.0 0.4 14.8 378 92.4 (1) 0.5 371, 522 94.5 23.2 18.0 1, 227 92.2 0.9 0.7 13, 327 91.9 8,880 80.5 0.5 0.9 1,267 98.4 0.5 1.6 302 57.4 0.1 0.3 1.2 3.3 202 100. 0 (1) 88 $3 4,880 95. 2 5.3 18.3 327 84.9 (1) 68.53.9 (¹) 1, 163 95.5 0.9 1.3 8,830 89.8 0.3 0.8 5.3 4.8 0.3 0.1 IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS. 11 Table IV.-SUMMARY-STOCKS, CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS-Continued. E.—ward EPARTMENT* (10 ESTAB- LISHMENTS). CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs... 2. Projectile steel... 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 4. Skelp, flue, etc…….. 5. Wire rods. 6. Plates (inch and over) 7. Sheets (under inch).. 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars.. 11. Structural shapes... 12. Seamless tubes... · 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 14. Rails: 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products. 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds…… 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates 16. Tin plate.. 17. Barbed wire. TOTAL.. 23. Scrap iron and steel... 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel.. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel. CLASS OF STEEL. · 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. 2. Projectile steel.. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 4. Skelp, flue, etc... 5. Wire rods. 6. Plates (+ inch and over). 7. Sheets (under 1 inch).. 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.).. 9. Reinforced-concrete bars……. 10. Long angle splice bars.. 11. Structural shapes... 12. Seamless tubes.. 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate. ... 17. Barbed wire. 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.. TOTAL... 23. Scrap iron and steel.. • Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 50, 651 3,219 368 8,793 7,258 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 13, 509 14. Rails: 1,969 2, 866 8 1,598 15,955 85, 535 798 30 48 318 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 1 5,922 5,735 6, 617 2, 300 Total. 5, 880 2, 428 29 10, 109 232 1, 243 327 12, 647 6, 576 8, 696 19, 406 12 5, 547 98, 431 439, 605 151, 112 5, 493 947 23, 812 20, 553 4, 019 Consump- tion and require- ments, 1918. 5, 611 10, 100 0.3 0.1 2,912 396 381 4, 773 202 5, 461 9, 347 13, 763 5,066 Consumption and require- ments, 1918. 1.2 5, 354 31,083 0.3 G.—MANUFACTURERS OF MOTOR VEHICLES-AUTO- || MOBILES, TRUCKS, AND ACCESSORIES (590 ESTAB- LISHMENTS). 3, 021 247 24 2, 907 507 Amount. Per cent of class total. 427 0.3 0.1 9,278 0.3 1.6 0.9 2, 628 0.1 21, 333 18, 558 7,771 132 1,330 165 2, 106 22 234 4,800 7,039 1.1 101, 533 46, 358 46,358 Stocks. For Government contracts. * Including United States Navy Yard, Mare Island, Cal. 1, 059 0.3 0.5 0.1 2.8 0.3 0.2 (¹) 1.7 0.1 HÖÖ Per cent. 0.3 Consumption and require- ments. 1, 441 3.2 0. 1 23 28.3 (1) 16 4.3 (¹) 6, 799 (¹) 0.8 13 13.1 (¹) 77 0.7 0.3 90 0.7 (¹) 2 (1) (¹) 660 0.4 0.4 0.7 0.6 0.3 0.2 Stocks. Per cent of class total. Consumption and require- monts. 3,751 43. 1 0.1 0.1 19,406 100. 0 0.7 1.2 2 16.7 (¹) (¹) 4, 289 77.3 1.4 0.6 81, 056 82.3 2.0 3.4 145, 022 32.8 11.8 24. 4 67, 265 44. 5 4. 2 4.0 269 4.9 3.7 7.5 430 45.4 2.0 1. 1 10, 961 46.0 1.5 1.1 11, 552 56.2 9.3 10.0 1,431 35.6 3.1 0.9 IMPLE- F.-MANUFACTURERS OF AGRICULTURAL MENTS AND VEHICLES OTHER THAN MOTOR VEHI- CLES (610 ESTABLISHMENTS). Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 1, 813 172 39 779 14,978 27, 489 175, 203 30 50 9,999 1, 743 9, 3091 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 220 759 17, 491 181 37,644 Consumption and require- ments, 1918. Total. 10 105 298 4, 910 18 676 1, 368 1,947 42, 326 71, 529 78 12 468 14, 962 1, 634 1, 156 For Govern- ment contracts. Total. Amount. 2, 607 4, 250 2,703 106, 725 1, 019 37, 430 144 3, 798 2, 275 513, 793 51, 682 10. 1 437 13 3.0 64 17,681 2,578 28, 985 101 0.1 4 55 4 218 8 (¹) 591 479 457 14, 899 31, 405 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.5 132 25 5.5 0.5 1.6 3,797 88 0.6 1.4 1.5 14, 350 1,703 5.4 15.6 10. 1 1, 292 2, 103 57 2.7 2. 1 43, 945 110, 816 9,579 8.6 10.7 0.1|| 305, 409 847, 163 72,597 8.6 3.6 35, 692 155, 964, 2.3 8.8 3.6 2.7 1.9 1.6 0.3 116 265 1, 125 1,281 247 1,297 Per cent. 386 7.9 0.1 (¹) (1) 0.9 3.2 7.2 9.6 4. 5 12 11.9 Amount. 95, 746 450, 299 286, 720 30 90 (¹) 7.2 0.7 H.-MANUFACTURERS OF BOLTS, NUTS, RIVETS, NAILS, SCREWS, ETC. (214 ESTABLISHMENTS). For Government contracts. Per cent of class total. Stocks. 0.1 Per cent. Consumption and require- Per cent of ments, 1918. class total. 0.1 0.2 0.2 1.9 1.5 3.8 4.0 1 14. 4' 13.7 (1) 0.6 0.3 0.1 1. 7 0.8 2.2 1. 3 2.1 6.7 (1) 0.1 Consumption and require- ments. - 1 Stocks. (¹) Consumption and require- ments. 4, 250 100.0 250 9.3 0.4 0.4 44, 556 41. 8 14. 8 11.3 35 3.4 (1) (1) 10, 333 2.8 5.2 2.1 1,292 44.4 0.1 0.2 265 66.9 0.1 0.5 200 52.5 (¹) 0.2 255 5.3 0.1 0.5 2 0.9 (¹) 0.2 165 3.0 24.0 19.5 2, 332 24.9 1.9 0.9 4, 538 33.0 7.2 4. 4 1, 924 38.0 3.8 5.2 75, 291 480, 910 142, 109 29.6 18.5 38.0 19, 156 50, 025 29, 502 59.0 4. 6 4.0 288, 819 1, 300, 844 498, 516 38.3 3.4 4.1 189,950 716,668 397, 812 55.5 2.2 2.3 13, 406 80, 135 0.5 0.2 3.4 0.7 0.8 10, 023 16, 291 ¹ Less than one-tenth of 1 per cent. (1) 63.7 7.9 12.0 15 16.7 (¹) 0. 1 0.3 7 6.0 (¹) (1) 242 91.3 0. 1 0.1 218 19.3 (¹) 0.3 237 88 37.1 (¹) (¹) 215 0.1 0.2 506 123 24.3 1.9 1.8 52, 07319, 383 37.2 5, 205 1, 158 22.3 1,778 5.0 5.3 1.8 1.7 1.9 1.9 932 52.4 12 CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 4. Skelp, flue, etc. 5. Wire rods.. Table IV.—SUMMARY—STOCKS, CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS—Continued. I.--MANUFACTURERS OF ELECTRIC AND ELECTRIC- POWER MACHINERY, APPARATUS, AND SUPPLIES (418 ESTABLISHMENTS). 6. Plates (inch and over). 7. Sheets (under inch). 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain. bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars. 11. Structural shapes. 12. Seamless tubes.. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 14. Rails: 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds.. 15. Rail joints. fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate.. 17. Barbed wire. 18. Wire rope.. 19. Other wire products... 20. Iloops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel.. TOTAL.. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.... 23. Scrap iron and steel. · 4. Skelp, flue, etc. 5. Wire rods.. CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. 2. Projectile steel.. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars. 6. Plates (inch and over) 7. Sheets (under inch). - 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.).. · 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars. 11. Structural shapes. 12. Seamless tubes... · 17. Barbed wire. 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products. - • 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes.. 14. Rails: 50 pounds and over.. Under 50 pounds... 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel.. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.. TOTAL 23. Scrap iron and steel………. Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. ¦ 1, 151 305 59 26 1, 127 13, 960 47, 344 21, 147 239 142 6,748 658 5,683 1,096 106 65 111 347 1,298 1, 102 653 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 4, 681 190 515 2, 443 2,946 Consumption and require- ments, 1918. 19, 538 1 4 2,075 352 1, 216 Total. 732 4,954 3, 953 1,294 13, 206 36, 510 115, 873 266, 878 7, 883 25, 736 7 145 19 30 7,579 128 66 1,416 26,966 99, 078 35, 033 1,273 293 22,855 897 20, 137 2, 109 1,287 61 257 Total. 13, 2-18 101 35 8821 5, 181 8, 656 35, 130 100 79 4, 586 693 5, 609 For Government contracts. 55 60 5 Amount. 92 37 5, 873 1, 554 293 23,044 Per cent. Consumption and require- ments, 1918. K.-MANUFACTURERS OF MACHINE TOOLS (437 ESTABLISHMENTS). 6, 101 80.5 0.1 0.1 12S 100.0 0.1 (¹) 2 3.0 3.0 (¹) (¹) 994 70.2 0.9 0.2 19,122 70.9 0.9 59, 925 60. 5 5.5 1.8 6.51 19, 314 55.1 1.7 62 4.9 0.3 40 13.7 0.8 11,512 50.4 1.2 511 57.0 0.8 6,658 33.1 1.3 Per cent of class total. 440 20.9 733 72.5 27 44.3 (1) Stocks. For Government contracts. A mount. 208 80.9 (1) Per cent. 10, 484 79. 1 101 100.0 32 91.4 0.2 0.2 1.6 0.6 (¹) 00円 1 342 46.7 1.4 2.6 2,948 59.5' 0. 0.4 0.5 3,265 82.6. 1.2 1.3 $49 65, 6 1.1 1.4 20,717 56.7 154,098 57.7 Consumption and require- ments. 0.9 1.8 0.3 1.1 0.4 4.6 Stocks. Per cent of class total. 20, 441 38. 2 1.6 50 50.0 (¹) 75 94.9 (1) 2,898 63. 2 255 36.8 4, 422 78.8 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 (¹) (¹) 384 43.5 0.5 0.1 3, 123 50.3 0.3 0.2 2,248 26.0 0.4 0.5 (¹) 60 100.0 0.2 662 73 736 55 3' 1,966 3 3,846 11' 280 82 532 1,075 1, 787 1,686 2, 103 190 1,231 3.2 2.9 10,487 28, 555 1.4 0.8|| 217,926 979, 653 0.4 0.3 46, 671 158, 568 Consumption and require- ments. 0.9 0.1 (1) 0.4 0.2 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 1.3 675 631 106 5, 915 27, 555 50, 424 37, 395 61. 9 69, 044 165, 739 102, 243 61.7 16, 433 79, 041 ¹ Less than one-tenth of 1 per cent. (¹) 0.1 COM. J.-MANUFACTURERS OF ENGINES, PUMPS, PRESSORS, ETC., BOILERS, AND TANKS (629 ESTABLISHMENTS), 34 91.9 (¹) 115 2.0 2.7 21. 913 58.8 0.2 0.2 52 17.7 0.1 (¹) 19, 161 83. 1 9.6 24.8 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 7, 263 51 17 33, 740 68 44 19, 826 14,780 18, S19 257 578 50, 688 395, 700 55, 808 166, 339 1 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. Consumption and require- ments, 1918. Total. 2,004 1, 413 1, 916 1, 498 22,995 136, 039 750 318 53, 412 53, 412 75, 017 75, 017 70, 70,585 41, 687 36, 111 86. 6 100 869 62 189 6, 153 9, 155 8, 253 2, 942 10, 465) 6 Total. For Government contracts. 74 2, 111 13, 567 5, 576 71, 593 Amount. 594 3, 259 1, 427 11, 333 Per cent. 128 22.1 263, 695 66. 6 61, 770 37. I Per cent of class total. Stocks. For Government contracts. Amount. 70, 67552.0 346 46.1 150 47.1 2.8 3.6 0.1 1.0 0.3 0.4 35, 270| 66.6| 3.4 2.4 55, 165 73.5 18.9 36.6 33, 758 78.1 4.3 16.2 0.4 0.4 (¹) L.-MANUFACTURERS OF TOOLS AND HARDWARE (807 ESTABLISHMENTS). Consumption and require- ments, 1918. Per cent 511 69.4 0.1 0.1 1 3,979 110 1, 385 23, 043 36, 416 22, 212 6.7 4.8 18, 625 41, 815 18, 457 44. 1 0.8 0.5 132, 880 395, 761 175, 623 44. 4 0.8 0.8 13, 242 27, 27, 431 mɔt i on and requirc- ments. 0.2 0.1 6.4 13.8 7.7 9.2 80 2 3.6 0.1 0.1 68 1.8 184) 34. C 515 28. S 358 17.0 784 63.7 • 12,496 43.7 2.5 2.5 2.2 572, 186 58.1 2.5 2.5 (¹) (¹) 0.7 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 1.9 0.4 0.2 1.8 0.7 0.8 1.3 4. 3 0.5 51, 747 146, 795 78, 427 53. 4 461 2 110 18.5 (¹) 576 1, 147 35.2 0.1 73 1, 189 83. 3 0.1 3,947 3, 946 34.8 0.9 Stocks. 3. 1 1.6 Per cent of class total. 3, 538 33.8 0.2 (1) 52 70.3 1.1 () 586 27.8 08 9,080 66.9 1.6 2, 634 47.2 0.2 27, 109 37.9 3. 2 Consumption and require- inents. 0.1 0.3 1. 4 0.2 4.0 3.9 0.7 0.2 0.7 2.6 1100.0 (¹) 1, 397 35.1 0.3 0.4 100 90.9 0.6 0.1 37 2.7 0.8 5.0 7, 147 31.0 2. 1 2.3 8, 183 22.5 10.0 11.7 12, 483 56. 2 13. 4 23.9 4.5 3.3 1.5 1.3 0.7 0.3 IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS. 13 Table IV.-SUMMARY-STOCKS, CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS-Continued. M.-MANUfacturers OF MACHINERY OTHER THAN THE FOREGOING (1,023 ESTABLISHMENTS). CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs………. 2. Projectile steel.. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars.. 4. Skelp, flue, etc. 5. Wire rods. 6. Plates (inch and over). 7. Sheets (under 1 inch)……… 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.). 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars.. 11. Structural shapes.. 12. Seamless tubes... · · 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds... 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate. 17. Barbed wire. 18. Wire rope.. 19. Other wire products.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Total steel.. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.. TOTAL.. · · 23. Scrap iron and steel... 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes.. 21, 212 14. Rails: CLASS OF STEEL, 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs……… 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars... 4. Skelp, flue, etc.. 5. Wire rods... 14. Rails: 6. Plates (1 inch and over). 7. Sheets (under † inch)……. 8. Merchant bars and shape sunder 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.)………. 9. Reinforced-concrete bars……. 10. Long angle splice bars.. 11. Structural shapes.. 12. Seamless tubes... 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes.. · 18. Wire rope.. 19. Other wire products. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Toof steel. 04 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates.. 16. Tin plate.. 17. Barbed wire. TOTAL... 23. Scrap iron and steel……. 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.. · Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. ↑ 341 17, 761 19,511 4,935 15,986 12, 354 297, 282 273 113 8 880 50, 295 58,016 50, 561 189 127 17, 783 1, 823 Consumption and require- ments, 1918. Stocks, Sept 1, 1918. Total. 2,774 392 79 1 935 77,674 19, 350 43, 013 27, 014 374 124, 943 442 7,852 1, 736 911 564 502 60 85 2,099 1,050 137 140,859 445 618 42, 293 3,566 36, 237. 1,388 3,995. 454 2, 026i 98. 2, 114 For Government contracts. 738 1,043 410 784 13 667 2,956 6,705. 941 3,338 4,744 12, 246 34, 573 93,870, 28, 539 30.4 193, 739 772, 782 442, 239 57.2 29, 405 135, 287 Total. A mount. 7,399 450, 411 450, 411 82, 588 Per cent. 192, 698 37,699 512 757, 801 1, 524 6, 690 41.8 297,020 99.6 44 38.9 0.3 0.2 3.3 17.6 0.1 (¹) (¹) 306 34.8 0.3 0.1 2.2 1.8 14,544 28.9 11, 971 20.6 2.7 3.2 ().—FABRICATIONS—STRUCTURAL AND ARCHITECTURAL IRONWORK (636 ESTABLISHMENTS). 1 4.2 3.7 42, 896 30.5 75 16.9 0.2 0.6 505 81.7 0.7 0.7 15,003 35.5 3.1 1.9 1, 179 33. 1. 2.3 1.7 11,842 32.7 4.8 8.3. For Government contracts. Amount. 192 13.8 0.1 0.1 459 11.5 1.6 5.0 22 4.8 0.2 0.2 379 14.4 0.3 0.2 1 1.0 0.1 0.1 513 24.3 2.7 2,401 35.8 1.0 0.7 1,099 32.9 1.0 1.0 6,559 53.6 7.7 13.2 7.6 166,786 160,998 96. 5 2 283 Per cent of class total. 1 Consumption and require- Per cent of ments, 1918. class total. ! Per cent. Stocks. and require- Consumption ments. 1,879 25.4 331, 741 73.7 34, 802 42.1 0.1 1.6 0.1 (¹) 11 3.9 (¹) (¹) (¹) 0.7 0.7 9.9 15.8 2.7 4.6 Consumption and requiro- ments. 12: N. MANUFACTURERS OF MUNITIONS AND ORDNANCE (60 ESTABLISHMENTS). Consumption and require- ments, 1918. Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. 0.8 3.7 0.9 1.7 1,366 19,744 83, 103 304, 284 5 45 165 9, 216 6, 470 5,807 46 3, 588 335 69 Stocks, Sept. 1, 1918. I 20 3,418 14,572 4; 569: 199 756 117, 013 60.7 3.5 5.1 11, 442 30.3 31.4 51.4 307 74.5 2.1 0.6 478, 818 63.2 21.5 34. 6 1,073 70.4 0.6 0.8 12, 703 57.9 1.8 5.0. 3,691 40.1 0.3 0.8 22,332 747 41.0 1.4 2.3 12, 633 252 42.5 0.3 0.3 2,643 2,859 58.3 0.2 0.6 236, 855 72 1:0 0.6 0.7 319 262 69.5 0.3 1.3 4, 256 13, 875 4,593 33.1 0.7 1.4 54, 719 781 247 31.6 1.2 0.2 21, 790 353 138 39.1 0.2 0.4 8, 923 3,237 7,780 3,319 42.7 315, 224 1,760, 0561, 166, 957 66.3 17,058 161, 274 21, 932 9, 209 1,823 593 4, 903 727 377 ¹ Less than one-tenth of 1 per cent. 5, 142 14, 621 998 190 13, 052 36, 166 180, 030 Total. 98,000 411 491 25,741 9, 942 i 410 33,974 8,956 { 25,732 40 2 10, 105 255 262 20 88 2,992 273 1,658 7.4 5, 470 13, 565 7,357 54. 2 2.2 2.4 120, 606 436, 987 387, 318 88. 6 1.6 1.4 5,355 16,329 8.4 Total. For Government contracts. 9, 401 60, 248 2,825 2,371 40, 668 218, 931 555,718 Amount. 381, 369 641 1, 434 129,208 24, 161 53,726 185, 437| Per cent. 3 13, 150 66.6 0.1 0.2 304, 284 100.0 21.8 18. 0 13. 28.9 (¹) (1) 350 85.4 0.1 (¹) 1.2 1.2 26,594 78.3 7,884 88.0 0.9 0.5 19, 149 74.4 40 100.0 2,100.0 5, 233 51.8 79 31.0 218 83.2 (¹) P.-MISCELLANEOUS (3,076 ESTABLISHMENTS). Consumption and require- ments, 1918. Per cent of class total. Stocks. Amount. For Government contracts. (¹) 149 1.0 1. 1 Per cent. 1 0.5 0.7 0.1 0.1 öö | Consumption and require ments. 6 1.6 I 41. 46.6 (¹) 0.3 1,350, 45. 1 0.2 0.3 215 79.1 0.2 0.1 1,209 72.5 1.3 1. 1 1.3 1.4 1.4 0.3 0.2 Stocks. (¹) 0.5 0. 1 0. 1 (¹) 1. 1 Per cent of class total. and require- Consumption ments. 0.3 0.1 6, 208 66.0 60, 119 99.8 3.8 3.6 1,426 50.0 0.5 0.2 41 1.7 0.1 0.3 16, 612 40.8 11.0 4.3 107, 233 49.0 4.6 7.7 153, 431 27. 6 24.8 30.8 207, 713 54.5 207, 713 54.5 8.1 10.2 157 24.5 0.5 0.9 807 56.4 2.6 1.7 67,244 52.0 4.4 5.9 9,915 41.0 12.7 11.8 71, 608 38.6 12.0 42.6 31, 425 41.2 3.4 6.3 17,875 39.6 19.2 57.0 2,347 47.6 1.5 2.6 72,766 8.8 78.5 93.1 473 2.8 3.1 16. 826 23.5 17.4 12.6 76, 203 45, 158 4, 934 828, 532 16,977 3,519 353, 594 80, 470 8, 225 52,365 172, 680 96, 602 55.9 12.7 13.7 5. 6|| 855, 3453, 202, 704|1, 035, 040 32.3 10.0 10.1 2.6 0.7 76, 617 253, 240 4. 1 63,459 17.9 18.4 35.7 42, 976 53.4 23.7 25.8 3,775 45.9 14.5 8.9 14 CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. Table IV.—S UMMARY—STOCKS, CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS—Continued. (Per cent distribution based on figures shown on the preceding pages.) CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs.. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars.. 4. Skelp, flue, etc.. 5. Wire rods. 6. Plates (inch and over). 7. Sheets (under inch).. 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.) 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars. 11. Structural shapes. 12. Seamless tubes.. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 14. Rails: - 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate... 17. Barbed wire.. TOTAL.. 18. Wire rope.. 19. Other wire products.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties.. 21. Tool steel. 23. Scrap iron and steel... 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel.. CLASS OF STEEL. -- 4. Skelp, flue, etc.. 5. Wire rods.. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs. 2. Projectile steel. 3. Sheet bars and tin-plate bars... -- 9. Reinforced-concrete bars. 10. Long angle splice bars. 11. Structural shapes.. 12. Seamless tubes.. • 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds.. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tin plate... 17. Barbed wire. TOTAL... 23. Scrap iron and steel. 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products.. 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel. • A 6. Plates (1 inch and over). 7. Sheets (under inch).... 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (in- cluding spike, chain, bolt, and nut rods, horseshoe bars, etc.) A Steel works, roll- ing mills, etc. 96.9 70.1 98. 1 98.3 66. 8 23.7 20.4 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes.. 14. Rails: 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel..... B Wholesalers, job- bers, and dealers. Railroad compa- € (¹) с nies. 0.4 0.4 Steel works, roll- ing mills, etc. (¹) 0.4 (1) (1) 0.7 (1) 3.7 8.8 31.7 5.4 2.6 1.0 A C Shipyards. Railroad compa- D • • • D • 96.7 0.1 0. 59.3 99.7 (2) 98.8 0.1 80.9 (¹) (¹) 18.0 3.5 31. 3 8.8 1. 1 1. 3 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.1 (¹) 0.7 · • • • E War Department. 3. 3 0.4 22.5 12.9 7.7 24.9 26.4 | 8.6 68.3 0.1 22. 6 26. 1 4.5 6.6 7.3 29.2 (1) 23.2 0.9 14.5 25.5 38.9 3.4 1.2 (¹) ·| (¹) 0.1 0.1 15. 1 0.8 76.0 0. 0.5 3.2 31. 4 9.0 7.5 0.5 28.3 13. 6 0.6 79.4 0.1 4.3 15. 1 3.5 0.1 (¹) (¹) 49.6 14.3 18. 0 (1) 13.1 0.1 (¹) 31.8 7.3 2.9 5.3 0.7 0.5 24.0 55.0 11.3 1.3 (¹) 0.7 1. 4 1.9 24.2 11.9 0.1 (¹) (¹) 15.6 7.2 31. 3 9. 1 1.9 0.9 0.4 2.1 3.8 18.3 3.7 2.7 0.3 1.1 10.7 18. 5 43.6 6.3 10.9 5.3 1.2 | 3. 6 | 3. 4 76.3 0.9 7.8 0.3 0.3 0 1.9 0.7 siss 0.5 14. 4 2.8 0.2 (1) 0.3 1.7 2.2 0.3 2.1 7 0.3 0.2 0.1 1 0.1 (¹) (¹) 0.3 0.7 1.4 1.6 1.9 2.0 0 9 3.8 11.8 • F E · vehicles, Agricultural im- plements, etc. G • · Motor etc. F 4.2 3.7 2.0 1.5 9.3 3. 1 (¹) 0.1 0.1 0.1 STOCKS. G H Bolts, nuts, etc. e pe ed 1. 1 10.0 0.9 0.9 (¹) 0.1 1.9 5.0 1.8 1.9 H I Electric machin- ery, etc. 0.1 0.1 (¹) 0.4 14. 8 (¹) 5.2 6.5 (¹) (1) 0.9 1.8 J 33.1 5.2 2.9 0.1 13.7 4.0 12.0 2.7 18.1 14.8 0.3 0.6 7.5 0.1 82.1 11.8 0.5 (¹) 0.1 1.1 30.0 3.2 18.0 0.1 21.9 13.3 0.7 0.3 2.2 5.7 3.3 0.2 0.8 1.3 6.7 Engines, pumps, etc. (¹) 0. 1 0.3 K J 0.4 0. 1 0.2 0.6 11.30.2 0.1 0.3 1.5 3.4 (¹) 0.9 13.8 0.1 4.0 24.4 2.1 5.5 9.2 Machine tools. 4. 3 0.5 1.7 2.8 1.6 0.3 0.1 (¹) 0.8 0.3 (¹) 3.4 18. 9 (¹) 4.2 0.5 3.5 8.1 0.2 0.1 31. 4 0.5 0.7 2.1 2.6 3. 1 0.6 21.5 4.4 0.4 0.6 12.7 1.2 0. 1 0.4 0.4 0.8 0.1 2.3 1.3 4.3 0.3 0.9 4.8 (1) 1.8 12.0 0.1 0.2 0.1 (¹) 0.6 0.1 0.2 (¹) (1) (1) 3. 4 19.2 1.6 0.3 1.4 0.3 1.5 0.2 78.5 '0. 2 0.3 (1) 0.7 (¹) 0.3 (1) 0.4 3. 1 17. 4 18.4 23. 7 14. 5 0.6 0.1 0.6 1.4 0.3 2.7 0.8 2.7 (1) 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.2 2. 1 1.0 0.2 0.7 1.2 1.8 0.1 10.0 1.0 0.2 1.2 1. 1 0.8 9.6 13.4 7.7 1.3 0.2 4.6.3.2 2.5 6.7 4.5 8.4 1.3 0.8 2.2 1.4 2.5 0.8 1.5 | 2. 2 1.4 3.7 10.0° 50 0.4 2.5 0.8 0.7 | 1.6 | 0.3 0.9 4. 1 | 2.2 | 0.5 CONSUMPTION AND REQUIREMENTS (TOTAL): 1918. I K L 0.1 (¹) 0.1 0.4 0.1 1.2 0.3 (1) (2) 0.1 (¹) 0.2 8 L Tools and hard- ware. LETEURINGE! Other machinery. Z 0.1 0.2 0.5 M 88 N 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.3 3.3 21. 8 0.1 3.8 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.1 1.1 0.1 (¹) (¹) 0.8 0.2 0.5 1.6 0.3 0.1 0.7 6.4 0.3 0.2 2.2 1.2 9.9 7.7 0.4 3.2 2.7 0.9 2.7 0.5 0.1 11.0 4. 6 24.8 M and 0.1 0.2 17.6 8 0.3 1. 4 0. 1 0.2 0.2 1.8 4.0 3.2 Munitions ordnance. 0 (¹) 1.1 Fabrications. NO 0. 0.2 18.0 (1) P Miscellaneous. 1.6 O P (¹) 0.7 1.2 15.8 0.5 | 4. 6 12.7 ´0.1 3.6 0.2 0.3 4. 3 7.7 30.8 10. 2 0.9 1.7 0.9 3.6 0.9 3.9 3.7 0.7 5.1 1.8 1.0 0.1 0.6 0.1 51.4 0.3 0.4 (¹) 0.7 0.7 (¹) 0.6 1.1 2.4 2.4 0.2 0.2 0.2 1.9 0.5 34.6 5.9 0.4 36.6 0.3 0.7 1.7 0.1 0.8 11.8 1.3 4.6 16.2 2.6 8.3 0.1 5.0 | 42. 6 (¹) 0.8 2.3 0.3 93. 1 16.6 0.6 0.7 1.3 12. 6 0.3 1.4 35.7 0.1 0.2 25.8 1. 1 0.4 8.9 6.3 57.0 2.6 0.2 0.1 9.6 81.7 81.7 0.9 0.1 25.4 6.3 1.6 (¹) 1.9 94.5 0.3 (1) 2.0 0.1 2. 4 0.8 5.4 18.3 50.5 0.5 0.2 0.1 (¹) 1.6 0.1 0.1 (¹). | (¹) (¹) 0.4 0.3 79.0 0.1 0.5 5.0 0.2 (¹) 0.2 0.8 0.1 0.5 (1) 0.4 0.2 1.6 (¹) 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.3 1.6 19.5 1.8 2.6 1.9 21.0 5.0 7.6 0.3 1.5 0.9 5.3 0.5 0.2 0.2 2.3 0.7 10. 1 4.4 1.7 1.3 0.7 0.1 11.7 1.0 1.7 1. 3 0.7 2.3 5.2 1.9 1. 4 1.3 24. 8 23.9 13. 2 9.1 2.7 0.8 0.6 8.8 38.0 4.0 2.9 2.2 4.8 3.3 7.4 42.9 (1) 88 10.9 1.1 0.7 13.7 55.5 5.3 4.8 0.1 2.7 4.1 2.3 0.8 3.1 0.5 | 1.3 2.4 1.4 5.6 10.1 87.0 1.0 0.1 0.3 1.6 0.8 1.7 0.2 Q.3 1.6 0.8 | 0.3 1.4 0.2 2.6 ¹ Less than one-tenth of 1 per cent. IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS. 15 CONFIDENTIAL-(WAR MEASURE) To be forwarded within 10 days WAR INDUSTRIES BOARD BERNARD BARUCH, CHAIRMAN IN COOPERATION WITH THE DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE BUREAU OF THE CENSUS SAM. L. ROGERS, DIRECTOR STATISTICS OF IRON AND STEEL PRODUCTS EUGENE F. HARTLEY Chief STATISTICIAN FOR MANUFACTURES Name of establishmENT. LOCATION OF ESTABLISHMENT: State ADDRESS OF GENERAL OFFICE Nature of BUSINESS IF A COMBINED REPORT, ENUMERATE PLANts and estabLISHMENTS COVERED BY THIS REPORT. Class A, B, or C. (Such as “tube mill,” “jobber," "tool anufacturer,” elo.) NAMES And addrESSES: The following classes of establishments are asked to report: A. Steel works, rolling mills, tube mills, forging shops, wire-drawing mills, tinplate mills, and all other manufacturers of the products mentioned in Inquiry I of this questionnaire. B. Wholesalers, jobbers, dealers, warehouses, and supply houses carrying stocks of tho products listed under Inquiry I of this questionnaire. C. Consumers of these products or establishments using them in the manufacturo of more highly finished products. Date, WASHINGTON, D. C., August 21, 1918. A census of capacity and stocks of iron and steel products, acourato data concerning which are absolutely necessary to the proper conduct and furtherance of the war, is authorized by the Secretary of Commerco under tho provisions of section 8 of the organic act creating the Department of Commerce and Labor, as follows: "That the Secretary of Commerce shall *** from time to time make such special investigations and reports as he may be required to do by the President, or by either House of Congress, or which he himself may deem necessary and urgent.' And the special authority of the President of the United States, under dato of April 8, 1918, as follows: "Tho Secretary of Commerce in hereby authorized to cause the compilation by the Bureau of the Census of such statistical data within its lawful scope and relating to the supply, production, and consumption of commodities as may be needed and be called for by any branch of the Federal Government in connection with the conduct of the war." Information regarding individual concerns will bo kept strictly confidential, but aggregato atatistics may be placed at the disposal of the trade. City or town Important.-Tho presont war emergency demands the patriotic cooperation of all interests that centralized information may be available to permit immediate and complete ure of all facilities, the conservation of raw materials and efficient distribution thereof. Accurate and prompt replies aro imperative. CERTIFICATE THIS IS TO CERTIFY that the information contained in this schedule is complete and correct to the best of my knowledge and belief. } 1918. SAM. L. ROGERS, Director of the Census. (Signature of person furnishing the information.) (Title and address.) ← -021A I. Stocks on Hand or in Transit to Establishment. Report stocks as of September 1, 1918. (a) This inquiry is designed primarily to show the stocks of iron and steel available for the manufacture and fabrication of finished iron and steel commodities, tools, machines, and constructions as a basis of war program. The following classes of establishments are asked to report: A. Steel works, rolling mills, tubo mills, forging shops, wire-drawing mille, tinplate mills, and all other manufacturers of the products mentioned in Inquiry I of this questionnaire. B. Wholesalors, jobbers, dealers, warehouses, and supply houses carrying stocks of the products listed under Inquiry I of this questionnaire. C. Consumers of these products or establishments using them in the manufacture of more highly finished products. (b) All classes of establishments: Report stocks in possession in your own mills, works, warehouses, atorerooms, and other space owued or ronted by you in the United States and Canada whether you have title to the stocks or not. Establishments will not report stocks already in process of manufacture into more highly finished forms. Include stocks in transit to you. (c) Establishments of the first (A) and second (B) classes, that is manufacturers of the products listed under this inquiry and dealers in the same, should not report stocka sold and in transit from their mills or warehouses as these will be reported by the consignee or purchaser. State all tonnage in net tons of 2,000 pounds. 1. Ingote, blooms, billets, and slabs. 2. Shoot bar and tinplate bar. 3. Skolp, fluo, etc. 4. Wiro roda 5. Projectile stoel 6. Platos (} inch and over in thickness) 7. Shoots (under inch in thickness). 8. Morchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (including spike and chain rods, bolt and nut rods, horseshov bars, otc.). 9. Reinforced-concreto bera 10. Long anglò splice bars. 11 Structural shapes. 12. Seamless tubes 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 14. Rails: 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds. 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates 16. Tinplate 17. Barbed wire 18. Wiro rope 19. Other wire products 20. Hoops, bands, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel 22. All other finished, rolled, and drawn iron and steel (specify the principal commodities and tonnago; do not include pig iron, castings, forgings, or parts finished or in process) · 23. Scrap iron and stool. (2) TONS. -4210 16 CENSUS OF WAR COMMODITIES. о } II. Consumption, 1918. (a) In column I, state the total amount of iron and steel of each class used during the six montha ending June 30, 1918. (b) In column II, state the total amount of iron and steel of each class used for Government contracts or sub- contracts. Include only iron and steel used during the first six months in filling Government orders, con- tracts, or subcontracts. This should include contracts for any branch of the United States Government or any foreign Government. Do not include iron and steel used in the manufacture of products that eventually were bought by the Government, but not directly covered by Government contracts or sub- contracts. (c) In column III, state the estimated requirements of iron and steel of each class for the period, July 1 to De- cember 31, 1918, to keep plants running at full capacity. Include that already used since July 1. (d) In column IV, state the estimated requirements of iron and steel of each class to fill Government orders, contracts, or subcontracts during the six months, July 1 to December 31, 1918. Include only require- ments for contracts which are actually booked prior to Setpember 1, not those under negotiation or anticipated. Include iron and steel used, except those excluded below in Item 23, on contracts since July 1, as well as estimated amount necessary on contracts to December 31, 1918. State all tonnage in net tons of 2,000 pounds. CLASS OF STEEL. 1. Ingots, blooms, billets, and slabs 2. Sheet bar and tinplate bar 3. Skelp, fluc, ete 4. Wire rods. 5. Projectile stoel. G. Plates (inch and over in thickness) 7. Sheets (under 1 inch in thickness). 8. Merchant bars and shapes under 3 inches (includ- ing spike and chain rods, bolt and nut rods, horseshoe bars, çic.) 9. Reinforced concrete bars. Loug angle splice bars. 11. Structural shapes. 12. Scamless tubes.. 13. Tubular products other than seamless tubes. 14. Rails: 50 pounds and over. Under 50 pounds... 15. Rail joints, fastenings, and tie-plates. 16. Tinplate..... 17. Barbed wire.... 18. Wire rope. 19. Other wire products... 20. Hoops, bauda, and cotton ties. 21. Tool steel.. 22. All other finished, rolled and drawn iron and steel (specify the principal commodities and tonnage; do not include pig iron, castings, forgings, or parts finished or in process).. 23. Scrap iron and steel. do a la IRON AND STEEL USED FOR SIX MontaS ENDING JUNE 80, 1918. (I) Total quantity. (3) (I) Quantity used for Government con- tracts. IRON AND STEEL REQUIREMENTS ESTIMATED for Six MoNTIIS END- INO DECEMBER 31, 1918. (III) Total quantity. Kan du (IV) Quantity to fill Government con- tracts. 03-214 • ! III. Production of Consuming Establishments. Establishments of Class C (consumers) will report below the production of principal articles, in which material listed in inquiries I and II in some form is an important item of raw material, from January 1 to June 30, 1918. (a) Include only articles in which material listed in inquiries I and II in some form is an important item of raw material. (b) List a sufficient number of articles to represent 90% or more of your consumption of the material listed in inquiries I and II. (c) Include as nearly as possible quantities of articles actually completed for the market whether on contract or not, and whether delivered or not, during the six months period, January 1 to June 30, 1918. State unit of measure commonly used in each case, such as 200-pound kegs of nails, etc. NAME OF ARTICLE. (4) PRODUCTION, JAN. 1-June 30, 1918. Specify unit of measure used in reporting quantity. i Quantity. 43-4210