Commercial Federation and Colonial Trade Policy. JOHN DAVIDSON, M.A., Phil. D. (Edin.) Professor of Political Economy in the University of A'ew Brunswick. SWAN SONNENSCHEIN & CO., Ltd. New York: CHARLES SCRIBNER'S SONS. 1900. In conipliaiuc wiili ( iii rciii c()|)\riolu lau\ l.BS Arc lii\cil IVodiicts produced lliis replacement volume on paper that meets the ANSI Standard Z:M).4S-19(S4torei)lacethe irreparably deteriorated oi ii>inal 1<)i/ta, pp. 29-30. 18 COMMERCIAL POLICY. in the policy pursued by the government, and necessity was the only law. ^ But when peace was restored, there came an opportunity to take wider views of things and to apply the lessons of experience. Then reforms came thick and fast; and they were inspired by as definite a purpose as had been the enactments of the old colonial system which they were intended to destroy. By 1850 — by 1826 according to Hali- burton — the work of reform was practically complete. There remained but few restrictions on the trade of the colonies ; and these were of a political character, and were afterwards removed for political reasons. There were four stages in the passing of the old colonial system. At first particular concessions were made to the necessities of the colonies during the war period ; and at intervals the sphere of their application was widened and sanctioned by imperial legislation. Then, after the peace, systematic reforms were carried out, culminating either in Huskisson's modification of the Navigation Laws in 1826 or in the final repeal of those laws in 1850. These reforms aroused little interest in the colonies, because the restrictions that were removed had caused no serious inconvenience. Then came, in the forties, the period during which, to the great indignation of the colonists, the colonial preferences in the English market were attacked and finally removed from the statute book. The last period is from 1850 onwards, when the remaining restrictions, which affected the political free- dom rather than the commercial prosperity of the colonies, were removed as occasion demanded, after representations from the colonies and generally in opposition to the ideas and policy of the mother country. The restrictive system cannot, on the whole, be said to have '^C/. Merivale, Lectures on Colonization, preface, pp. v-vi. "During: the conti- nental war and for many subsequent years our colonial empire had been administered after no very regular pattern but in accordance with certain received usages." COMMERCIAL POLICY. 19 borne hardly on the colonies after the War of Independence. They were restricted to the English market, it is true, but they would naturally have bought and sold there. So far as the interests of England were concerned, the criticism which Brougham passed on the regulations of the colonial system before the war may with more truth be applied to the regula- tions of the period under discussion. The prohibitions or discouragements [he said] given to certain kinds of colonial industry have been rather superfluous than burdensome. They have generally been framed with a view to prevent that which was never likely to happen. Or, as he said later, of the more purely trade regulations : Here again the restrictive policy has only secured by a superfluous and harmless anxiety that arrangement which would of itself have taken place if things had been left to their natural course. ' On the West Indies the system did bear hardly, but the ad- vantage accrued to Canada and the continental colonies, and not to England; and as early as 1794 Canada had reciprocity in inland trade with the United States. The complaints re- garding the restrictions were few in number and were not the expression of wide discontent ; they were protests on the score that liberty, not prosperity, was denied. The great and obvious advantages of the compensating preferences recon- ciled the colonies to these restraints. - The restrictive system, as it had been in operation before the war, consisted of three parts : the monopoly of colonial buying and selling ; the prohibirion and discouragement of 1 Brougham, An Inquiry into the Colonial Policy, etc., vol. i, pp. 140-246. iA British American League was founded in Montreal m 1850, in protest against the abandonment of colonial interests ; and at one ot the meetings a speaker declarsd that he did not regret the change, because the trade policy of the mother country could not altogether harmonize wiih the interests of the colonies, though so long as redprocaJ benefits were given it was tolerable. t.«a^'!^p^f:«^^pw^?^^;w!5'^*^>^. ' -'^ 20 COMMERCIAL POLICY. colonial manufactures ; and the Navigation Laws. There never was the slightest tendency in the colonies to develop manufactures which were likely to come into competition with English manufactures. The " line of employment," as Brougham pointed out, " most profitable to the inhabitants of all new settlements is . . . the raising of raw produce " ;^ and the effect of the whole system in Canada was to stimu- late the raising of produce and the development of rudimen- tary manufacturing industries. In the West Indies, where the English settlements were older, the restriction upon manu- facturing did damage the colonies. Upon the West Indian sugar plantations it was possible to refine or clay sugar econo- mically, with but small addition to the machinery used for boiling cane juice; but this, in 1803, the planters were prac- tically forbidden to do. In the interest of the English sugar refiners — who, according to Brougham, consisted of about fifty families, mainly foreigners — a duty on the exportation of re- fined sugar was imposed, which was practically prohibitive,^ But the West Indies were not in favour during this period, and consequently little heed was paid to their protests. The Navigation Laws, on the other hand, proved a great advantage to the colonies. The monopoly of the colonial market was no real hardship, because England was the natural market for colonial buying. The wars of the period made the colonists more than ever dependent on the home market ; and though here and there some suffered, the suffering was in- dividual. On the other hand, the monopoly of the produce of the colonies, combined as it was with preferential duties in the English market, was a great apparent benefit ; and the destruction of the monopoly was a cause of discontent so ' op. et he. cit. 'i/bid., vol. i, page 241. "The French Islands have always been free from this oppression, and owed a considerable share of their former prosperity to so eminent an advantage." COMMERCIAL POLICY. 'J I great that it gave rise to disloyal mutterings, and sometimes to loudly expressed threats of seeking annexation to the United States or, at least, independence. It is important, too, to remember that the purely restrictive part of the system was the first to be abolished ; while the differential duties were maintained for fully twenty years longer. The memory of these restrictions had almost entirely faded before the dif- ferential duties were seriously reduced ; and what the colo- nists meant by " the abandonment of the old trade principles of England under which she had flourished for centuries''^ was the abolition of the part which benefited them. They naturally forgot that the greater part of the old colonial system had disappeared without protest from them, and that the appeal to an established policy was futile when the re- formers were demanding that the same privileges of unpre- judiced importation as had been conferred on the colonists should be extended! to the British consumer. In 1794, by Jay's Treaty, Canada had been granted the right to import from the United States ; even the West Indies, in one round- about way or another, had acquired the right ; and naturally the English consumer felt that he ought to have the same freedom. Sir Robert Peel declared on one occasion that the colonies should be treated as if they were counties in Eng- land ; the reformers practically claimed that the counties in England should be granted the privilege, already held by the colonies, of buying in the cheapest markets. The North American; colonies that remained British had been subject, before the War of Independence, to the same restrictions as the colonies that revolted ; but the restrictions had not occasioned the same annoyance. The industrial de- velopment of the Canadian colonies was not great ; and the 1 British American League Declaration f 1850). Cf. Resolution moved by Mr. now Senator) Wark in New Brunswick House of Assembly, March 18, 1850: "That British colonies, having- been reared up under a commercial system by which the productions of the various parts of the Empire enjoyed national protection in their respective markets." etc. '••^ 22 COMMERCIAL POLICY. pressure of the system could be felt only where there was some measure of industrial development. There was little need for restriction ; and the comparative scarcity of regu- lations regarding Canadian commerce and industry indicates that even the government recognized the fact. In 1766 Lieu- tenant-Governor Francklin of Nova Scotia was directed to make report regarding the development of industries in that colony ; and in a letter to the Earl of Shelbume he wrote : I cannot omit representing- to your Lordship on this occasion that this government has at no time given encouragement to manufactures which could interfere with those of Great Britain ; nor has there been the least appearance of any association of private persons for that purpose ; nor are there any persons who profess themselves weavers so as to make it their employment or business, but only work at it in their own families during winter and other leisure time. It may be also proper to observe to your Lordship that the inhabitants of this colony are employed either in husbandry, fishing or providing lumber, and that all the manufactures for their clothing and the utensils for farming and fishing are made in Great Britain. ' In the same year Governor Francklin, writing for instructions, made a report and proposals to the government in London regarding the Cape Breton coal mines ; but his proposals did not meet with approval, for he was informed, under date of December 2, 1776, that his Majesty would not at present authorize or permit any coal mines to be opened or worked in the island of Cape Breton, and that all petitions and proposals for that purpose should be dismissed.' For some reason or other the coal deposits in Cape Breton had, before this, caused anxiety to the home government ; for in 1768 the governor was instructed to forbid the work- ing of the coal deposits in Cape Breton ; and later, while the 'Quoted by Campbell, History of Nova Scotia, page i6i ■2 Brown, History of Cape Breton, pag^e 364. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 23 colonial administration was enjoined to assist, to the extent of its ability, the Loyalists desirous of settling in the colony, it was aJso specially instructed to see that no land grants were made to them in Cape Breton. On the whole, how- ever, the government seems to have encouraged the growth of such manufactures as the colonies developed spontaneously. In 1785 we find Governor Parr reporting to Lord Sydney that there were ninety sawmills in the colony of Xova Scotia, of which twenty-five had been erected since 1783. Though the English government had tried at the outset to discourage any tendency to develop linen and woollen manufactures, bounties for the production of hemp were repeatedly given. This was part of the policy, afterwards more fully developed, of look- ing to the continental colonies as sources of naval supplies. In 1787 the Xova Scotia Assembly requested Lord Sydney, through Governor Parr, to renew the bounties on hemp and timber; and in 1801 the Duke of Pordand forwarded in- structions to the governor of the colony to encourage the growth of hemp. For hemp and for timber for masts there was a constant demand in England. The industry of ship- building, for which, as subsequent history showed, the mari- time colonies had great natural facilities, was encouraged by the Navigation Laws ; for these e.xcluded all ships built in New England, where even greater facilities then existed. The New England colonies, according to Mr. Fiske, could build much more cheaply than the English yards, in the ratio of $38 to $50 or $60 per ton; and at the time of the Revolution fully one-third of the British ships afloat had been built in New England. The exclusion of ships built in the United States greatly diminished the supply, and this was the oppor- tunity of the Canadian colonists. Adam Smith had declared that the separation of the Ameri- can colonies, while politically undesirable, might be an evil which could be tolerated, provided the separation were '^ 24 COMMERCIAL POLICY. effected without war and an advantageous treaty of commerce were concluded between them and the mother country. Un- fortunately his pacific prognostications were not realized ; but for! a time there was some probabilit}-, even after the war, that his views about commerce might prevail. Oswald, who negotiated the treaty of peace from the English side, was a friend and disciple of Adam Smith; and one clause in the draft treaty proposed that the British merchants and merchant ships, on the one hand, shall enjoy in the United States, and in all places belonging to them, the same protection and commercial privileges, and be liable only to the same charges and duties, as their own merchants and merchant ships ; and, on the other hand, the merchants and merchant ships of the United States shall enjoy in all places belonging to his Britannic Majesty the same protection and commercial privileges, and be liable only to the same charges and duties, [as] British merchants and mer- chant ships, saving always to the chartered trading companies of Great Britain such exclusive use and trade [in] their respective posts and establishments as neither the subjects of Great Britain nor any of the more favored nations participate in.^ This clause was rejected by the English ministry on the ground that the English representatives had no authority to interfere with the Navigation Laws. In the same year Pitt introduced a bill to secure unconditional free trade between England and the United States ; but Lord Sheffield's views prevailed. Had Adam Smith, through Oswald or through Pitt, been able to carry out his views, colonial policy for the next half century would have been a much simpler matter. But Lord Sheffield, who, through one much-quoted sentence, has come to be regarded as the representative of the old colonial policy, had on his side the inertia of a cen- tury of mercantile legislation; and in July, 1783, the Navi- gation Acts were applied to trade between the United States 1 Wharton, Diplomatic Correspondence of the American Revolut'on, vol. v, page 807. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 25 and the British West Indies. Goods from the United States could be imported from the state of origin — a piece of gratuitous insolence which the United States were not in a position to resent, though it called attention to the imperfect character of their union. England's position was strong : she would grant nothing except for a quid pro quo, and the United States had nothing to offer. They could not buy elsewhere so profitably as in England, and the West Indian trade had been their mainstay before the Revolution. Congress more- over was too weak to levy duties on English goods ; and separate action by the individual states only made matters worse. ^ But the disadvantage was not all on one side. The advan- tages of commerce are mutual ; and if the United States lost trade, the West Indian islands, cut off from their natural market, suffered extremely. Relaxations had to be made in the Navigation Laws as early as 1787, when free ports were created in Jamaica and other islands,-^ and the islands were permitted to carrv' on trade with all foreign colonies in vessels of one deck — a provision which really permitted a roundabout trade with the United States. These relaxations, however, were by no means sufficient. The British North American colonies were quite unable to perform their share of the traffic ; and, after many protests from the West Indies, both nations came to reason and recognized the mutual advantage derived from trade. The strictness of the Navigation Laws was therefore further relaxed by Jay's Treaty. American ves- sels not exceeding seventy tons burden were allowed to trade with the islands on the same footing as that on which British iln the circumstances the truth of the following opinion is obvious: "The commercial advantages [of the Jay Treaty] were not very considerable ; but they at least served as an entering- wedge, to quote Jay's expression, and they were pro tanto a clear gain to America." — Pellew, John Jay, c. 2. 227 Geo, III, c. 27; made perpetual, 32 Geo. Ill, c. 37; and amended, 33 Geo. Ill, c. so. m.>?^^*^W^- ^'^^^W^f^!?'' 26 COMMERCIAL POLICY. vessels were placed by 23 George III., chapter 39, or by annual orders in council. Jay's Treaty marks a substantial advance of the British colonies towards commercial freedom. The West Indies were the greatest gainers. Canada's vexatious monopoly of the West Indian trade w-as somewhat restricted ; but in return she gained freedom to import and export, by road, river, lake or canal, whatever she pleased from and to the United States. The territory of the Hudson's Bay Company was naturally ex- cluded from the scope of the treaty, because the Americans would thus have been granted privileges denied to British sub- jects. In the case of Canada the treaty wasi perpetual ; in the case of West Indies the clauses w^ere to cease to operate two years after the conclusion of a treaty of peace in Europe. The maritime continental colonies were apparently excluded because their trade with the United States was not conducted overland ; but in their case the strictness was relaxed by annual orders in council, which were periodically renewed and extended in each case before the current period had expired.^ The probable reason for the relaxations was the war with France, which not only stopped the roundabout trade between the West Indian islands and the United States and rendered trade between Canada and the islands more than ever irregu- lar, but also withdrew from the island trade many of the British vessels which had been engaged in it. The navy was unable to provide the necessary convoys, and colonial trading ships were liable to capture by French ships of war and priva- teers, vt-hich swarmed in the Caribbean Sea. This risk of capture, and the superior profits to be obtained by hiring v'essels to the government for the transport of troops, induced English merchants to with^lraw from this branch of the carry- ing trade. - iSee New BrunswicU Royal Gazette, paxsitn. ■^\t the end of the war. according- to an estimate made by Mr. Huskisson (Speeches, vol. iii, page 17), there were discharged from the navy 1236 vessels ok COMMERCIAL POLICY. 27 The concessions under Jay's Treaty gave no adequate re- lief ; for these concessions were hedged round by so many conditions that trade was not even so free as it was intended to be. Under these circumstances the governors of the West Indian islands, relying on subsequent indemnification from Imperial Parliament, felt themselves forced, in direct and flagrant violation of the Navigation Laws, to sanction the direct trade with the United States ; and while the war lasted the trade continued without protest. But when the war closed with the Peace of Amiens, the British shipping interests sought to take up the old trade which they had abandoned. The concessions under the Jay Treaty had still two years to run ; but against the open violation of the Navigation Laws by the West Indian governors the British traders could and did protest. These protests were readily entertained ; for it happened, as a crowning misfortune, that at the beginning of Pitt's second administration the assembly of Jamaica was at variance with the imperial government. In 1804 Lord Cam- den wrote to the governor of Jamaica and the governors of the other islands, instructing them not to open the ports of the islands over which they presided for the admission of articles from the United States which were not allowed to be imported by law — except in cases of real and very gfreat necessity. The illegal permission was accordingly revoked ; but there was such a violent protest that permission had to be further ex- tended for six months, though on this occasion for lumber and grain only. The remonstrance of the Jamaica Assembly showed how completely the Navigation Laws had been super- seded ; for it stated that not one-twelfth of the imports came 270,382 tons which had been hired as transports ; and in addition 333 vessels of war of 93.350 tons were sold by the naval authorities, because adapted to other purposes than those of war. Thus nearly i6oo vessels, or one-fourth of the Eng-lish marine before the outbreak of the war, were withdrawn from the merchant service ; and considering- the reduced efficiency of what remained, it was no wonder that ships were lacking for the dangerous West Indian trade. 28 COMMERCIAL POLICY. from British North America, that six-sevenths of the imports from the United States were carried in American shipping, and that, if the ports were closed, 456 British ships employ- ing 2862 seamen must at once be available to avert ruin and disaster. As the ships were not available, nor likely to be available — for war had again broken out — the permission was extended. The governor of the Windward Islands saved him- self ail this trouble by declaring that the keeping of the ports open was a " real and very great necessity." In spite of the extended permission, there was great scar- city in Jamaica ; and in the early months of 1806 a petition was presented to Lord Nugent, the governor, showing that the suspension of our late intercourse with the United States of America must render a further supply of the above-mentioned necessary articles [chiefly lumber and provisions] very scanty and precarious, it having been abundantly proved by upwards of twenty years' experience that the British colonies are altng-e'her inadequate to furnish our wants, and in times of war supplies in Briti'.h bottoms from the United States cannot be in any measure relied upon ; . . . in many parishes there is not a sing-le barrel of flour or meal or bushel of gfrain for sale. ^ The prayer of the petitioners was granted, and the whole question of colonial trade was in consequence brought up in the Imperial Parliament. The necessity of an open trade, which by one means and another had continued for thirteen years, was recognised. It had been continued in open viola- tion of the statutory law of the empire ; and it was obviously IDispatch dated from King-ston. Jamaica. May 21. 1806. to the New Brunswick Royal Gazette. The R'>val Gnzette, down to the year 18 jy. was not merely an official advertising' org'an but a g'eneral newspaper, which vindicated its official title by dealing; only with In haute politique. It is invaluable as a source of information regarding the early history of Canada and all matters concerning colonial policy; and its natural official bias renders the information it supplies regarding the evil effects of the colonial policy absolutely trustworthy. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 29 inexpedient to allow the colonial governors to use their dis- cretion in setting aside that law by proclamation or by order in council. The English Government sought to regularize the practice of past years, and to relieve the colonial governors from the responsibility' to which they had been exposed of periodically suspending the Navigation Laws. In introducing the bill, the chancellor of the exchequer admitted the absolute necessity of open trade to prevent suffering and disaster in the West Indian islands. The shipowners [he said] in consequence of the discretion thus re- posed in the j^overnors had been exposed to a degree of uncertainty destructive to their real interests. With respect to the islands it was essential not only to their prosperity but to their security that they should be supplied where local circum-^tances rendered the assistance they received most abundant and regular. During the ten or twelve years, when a different system was pursued, instances of distress had occurred, the bare mention of which would excite the most painful sensations; and common humanity had led the administration for the last thirteen years to abandon the former rigid system both in peace and war. So far were the continental establishments of this coun- try across the Atlantic from being capable of supplying the British islands [i.e., the West Indies] that at one period they were found inadequate to their own subsistence.^ The bill was in appearance a great breach in the old policy, but in reality it injured no interest. However, it encountered violent opposition in and out of Parliament ; and long after the bill had been passed the British shipowners attributed to it all their distresses. It certainly impaired their monopoly of the West Indian trade ; but since they had deserted the island service for the more lucrative employment of transporting troops, it was hardly rational to expect that the colonists should starve till it suited the shipowners to resume the trade. iDebate in House of Commons, April ai, i8o6 ; quoted ia New Brunswick Royal Gazette, June 9, 1806. 30 COMMERCIAL POLICY. At the best they could not supply the colonies ; and, as Sir Francis Baring declared in the same debate, it would have been " dangerous and cruel as well as impolitic to trust to them at the risk of starving thousands should they fail in the attempt." But the opposition was not based on any regard for the interests of the West Indies. The Navigation Laws were attacked and the conservative instinct was roused in their defence. The master of the rolls, in the course of the debate, said that this bill, with a force and conciseness beyond all example, strikes out of your statute books or reduces to a dead letter all the body of the laws of this realm made for the support of our navigation, the rule of our colonial system and everything that depends on both ; and he further insinuated that the bill " contained a meaning and had an object which they did not think fit to disclose to Parliament." The general argument was that " this was the first relaxation of the Navigation Laws enacted by Parha- ment." As a matter of history, this was not the case; for the Navigation Laws had been frequently in part suspended in time of war, and more than once in time of peace; and in the preamble to an act of 1802 (42 George IIL, chapter 80), it was declared that the commerce of the country had greatly benefited by such relaxation.^ This act and the discussion had reference primarily to the West Indian colonies; but it was not long before similar re- laxations were granted to the maritime continental colonies also. The Canadas had, under the Jay Treaty, practical free- dom of trade, so that there was no question of their position. The maritime colonies continued to receive the same right periodically by proclamation, till in 1809 a law was enacted . permitting freedom of trade in certain specified commodities "Cobbett's Parliamentary Debates, vol. vii. Cf. Annual Register, 1806, page 89. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 31 between New Brunswick and Nova Scotia and the United States, in any vessel or ship whatsoever, till March 25, 181 2 ; and by an order in council, transmitted by Castlereagh in the previous year, certain ports in these colonies were practically made free ports. ^ In October, 1811, before the act of 1809 had expired, another order in council extended permission, till further no'tice, to export in any vessels except those of France, to ports of the United States of America to which British vessels were not admitted, all articles the produce or manufacture of the British Isles or the colonies, under cer- tificate that such articles had been imported in British ships ; and to import from such ports of the United States wheat and grain, bread, biscuit, flour, pitch, tar and turpentine.-' In this order in council we have traces of the notorious con- tinental system, with its orders in council, its Berlin and Milan decrees, and the consequent embargo and non-intercourse acts. The effect of these measures was, on the whole, a benefit to Newfoundland and Canada. Of course trade with the United States did not cease because of the embargo ; and the mari- time ports became to a certain extent, as the order in council evidently intended they should become, entrepots for the trade between England and the United States. The West Indies suffered a great deal, and in some cases offered bounties on the imports of food-stuffs.^ But in the West Indies, as a speaker in the House of Commons said in 1824, " distress was the habitual condition and prosperity the exception";* and at a time when war was imminent between England and the United States the distress was likely to be regarded as an iHaliburton, History of Nova Scotia, vol. i, page 249. 2New Brunswick Rovil Gazette, January 13, 1812. 3New Brunswick Royal Gazette, March 2. 1812. contains a copy ot such a proclamation by the Governor of Gaudeloupe. July i, .811, by which bounties, in some cases specific, in others ad valorem, are offered for six months and until three months notice shall have been given. *Huskisson, Speeches, vol. ii, page 367. 82 COMMERCIAL POLICY. incident of the war. The northern colonies prospered greatly during the embargo period and during the war. They were, as we saw, used as entrepots, and they secured a large share of the fish trade to the Mediterranean and to South America. " The war made the fortunes of Newfoundland merchants. Fish were smuggled into Spain through Portugal, and New- foundland merchants had the whole Peninsular market and Italy without a rival." ^ Intercolonial trade received an im- petus. Newfoundland obtained a large part of its food sup- plies from British North America.- The mother country also was forced to import from Canada many goods previously supplied by the United States. Wheat was exported in con- siderable quantities, and Canadian lumber in large quantities. Six hundred lumber ships loaded at Quebec in 1810, and saw- mills, many of them operated by steam, sprang up everywhere. With the War of 18 12 all treaties lapsed, and there was a free field for constructive legislation. But the treaty of commerce in 181 5 practically restored the condition of affairs before the war, except that an attempt was made to demand reciprocal concessions from the United States. There was to be equality of all charges upon the ships belonging to either country in the ports of the other, and a hke equality of duty upon all articles the production of the one country, imported into the O'ther, whether such importation was made in the ships of the one or of the other. ^ This convention was re- newed in 18 18 for a period of ten years ; but it did not work easily. It was a case of pouring new wine into old bottles ; iProwse, History of Newfoundland, pag-e 395, note. ^The British Provinces "supplied all the lumber, cattle, butter, oats, corn, hay, and other produce that had always been procured from America. Of course they could not supply all the flour that was required, but it shows vhat progress they were making' that, out of 85,000 cwt. of bread and flour, British America supplied Newfoundland in 1813 with nearly 12,000 cwt. ; and also with 1400 oxen, 1400 sheep and 2i million feet of board." — Prowse, op. cit., page 393. ^Convention of 1815, art. ii. Treaties and ConventioQS ot the United States, page 345. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 33 and the modifications of the Navigation Laws did not har- monize with the old principles which had remained unmodi- fied. The new reciprocal system operated to the prejudice of British shipping. American ships could use English ports as entrepots — and the more profitably on account of the extension of the warehousing system ; but English ships were liable to seizure if they imported into the United States any article not the produce of the United Kingdom. The United States was hampered by the convention in the control of its own tariff. The protectionist spirit had increased during the war, and attempts were made to raise the duties on certain articles which as that period were manufactured only by England. The result was a further suspension of intercourse (1820) be- tween the United States and the West Indies ; and this con- tinued till in 1822 an act was passed by which American ships were allowed to trade directly between the United States and the West Indies and North American colonies. The systematic reform of the Navigation Laws ; the repeal of the preferences granted to the colonies ; and the gradual removal, in the latter half of the present century, of the re- strictions which prevented the colonies from framing an in- dependent commercial policy — these changes have still to be examined. ( 34 ) CHAPTER 11. ENGLAND'S COMMERCIAL POLICY TOWARDS HER COLONIES SINCE THE TREATY OF PARIS. THE reform of the Navigation Laws, which began with Wallace's measure in 1822, was the inception of a systematic reform, culminating in Huskisson's measures in 1826, which practically swept away all the burdensome restric- tions that affected the trade of the colonies and gave them freedom to develop. The partial modifications had worked so ill that it became necessary to reconsider the whole policy and to adapt it to the changed circumstances of the political, com- mercial and colonial world. When the Navigation System was established, the competitors of England were all European nations : Asia, Africa and America were merely spheres of colonization, for a share of whose commerce the different European nations competed. On these continents there were no maritime nations whose power was feared. As the number and the area of the independent nations extended in these continents, the colonial sphere contracted. The situation in the first decades of this century, when the Portuguese colony of Brazil and then the Spanish] colonies of South America asserted their independence, was analogous to the situation which existed when the United States achieved their indepen- dence. " Great Britain had no choice but to apply the Euro- pean principles to the commerce and navigation of Brazil^ though out of Europe,"^ and consequently later to the com- merce and navigation of Colombia and Buenos Ayres and the rest. One of the new states which had arisen since the inception ^Huskisson, Speeches, III, page 27. COMMERCIAL POLICY. of this navigation policy was a much more dangerous naval competitor than any of the European states. Yet it was pre- cisely to this power that the greatest concessions had been made in the way of departure from the strict principles of the Navigation Laws. It is true that the concessions were due to the exigencies of war, thus violating the rule which England herself had tried to enforce in the Seven Years' War. But when once the concessions had been made, colonial interests forbade their withdrawal ; and a foreign nation was thus ad- mitted to a share of England's colonial trade. The United States had applied to English trade the same policy which England had in 1785 applied to American shipping, by refus- ing to consider the British colonies as integral parts of the British Empire — a piece of insolence which could be paral- leled only by England's insult in 1785.^ The aim of the Navigation Laws had been relative, not absolute, power. A nation endeavoured to engross as much of the world's traffic as it could, and then sought to prevent any other single country from engrossing too great a share of what remained. From the nations of Europe England had no longer anything to fear; but, in defiance of the Navigation Laws, she was favoring above all other nations the United States, and thus allowing a large share of the trade she her- self could not engross to be carried on by her most dangerous maritime rival. The remedy obviously could not be sought in a return to the older and unmodified policy. In particular, the interests of the West Indies forbade such a solution. British shipping simply could not supply the needs of the colo- nies ; and the relaxation of the old system was essential to the prosperity and to the very existence of these colonies. The remedy therefore lay in admitting European nations to the English colonial trade, in order to prevent the United States from engrossing the West Indian trade. Thus iHuskisson, Speeches, passim. 36 COMMERCIAL POLICY. the islands would be at once relieved from their depen- dence on one sole market, which had been twice closed to them by war and at least twice by political measures ; and at the same time the supremacy of the United States in these waters would be qualified. This policy was in the true line of the Navigation Acts, preserving their spirit while modifying their letter to suit the altered circumstances of the case. The conditions were altered, not merely because new nations had risen up beyond the Atlantic or because England, having practically no industrial rival, no longer attributed so much importance to the idea of relative power, but also be- cause from one reason or another men could no longer naively assume that colonies existed to be exploited. The causes of the change in the EngUsh sentiment have been suggested; but the most important of them was the fact that the colo- nists were becoming strong enough to make their influence felt. The continental colonies had benefited greatly by all the incidents cf the commercial policy of the war. They had a preference in the English market, because England had a quarrel with the Baltic powers ; and the War of 1812 had for a time given them a monopoly of the Mediterranean market and had restored to them their m_onopoly of the West Indian market. The country was better settled, communications had been opened up and industry was developing. They naturally turned, therefore, to politics and to agitation against what they conceived to be grievances. The greater part of their energy was devoted to the struggle for responsible govern- ment, which turned mainly on the question of the control of the crown duties. These were nominally collected to regulate commerce, and against this purpose they had little to say ; but the revenue could hardly be said to be within their control, for the amount derived from the duties imposed under the act of 1825 was ^75,000 a year, and of this ^^68,000 was ex- pended in paying crown officers appointed by the home COMMERCIAL POLICY. 37 government^ to secure the regulation of colonial commerce. In the long run, the grant of responsible government was the ground of the colonial claim to complete control of their own tariffs ; but in the early decades of the century the politicaJ restrictions naturally drew their attention from those which were more ostensibly commercial. They had some energy left, however, to protest against even thei slight injustice which these limitations caused. In 1809 Sir Erasmus Gower, Governor of Newfoundland, reported to the home govern- ment that there were evidences of discontent with the colo- nial restrictions : It is eig^hteen years since I was first on this station, and the great improvements and changes that have taken place in that time render it now absolutely necessary that the capital of this colony should no longer be cramped, cabined and confined by laws and restrictions, which at present are entirely unsuited to its conditions and progress.^ From 1810 onwards they protested against the restrictions to which they were subjected. It is true that their protests were incidental and were directed against grievances which were in the main sentimental ;^ but they served to show how the wind was blowing. The main protests continued to come from the West Indies, where the grievance was not merely sentimental and where the restrictive system, with all the relaxations granted, not only handicapped them in their competition with newer sugar islands, but also subjected them periodically to the dangers of dearth and famine. These were the changes in circumstances which, accord- ing to Huskisson, demanded a modification of the Navigation ' McCulIoch, Dictionary of Commerce, article " Colonies, " pajjc ;?37. sProwse, History of NewfoundLinJ, pp 383-384. 3 In April. 181 1, the Assembly of Nova Scotia protested agrainst the practice of prosecuting- breaches of the Imperial revenue laws in the court of the Vice-.\dmiralty at Halifax, and adopted a string- of resolutions condemning the practice as a great grievance and as betraying a want of confidence in the people of the province.— Haliburton, Nova Scotia, I, 288. 42a347 38 COMMERCIAL FOLICY. Laws ; and the changes were so generally recognized that he could treat a return to the old system as an impossible alter- native. What remained to be done, in his view, was to throw open the colonial ports to the ships of all nations, reserving only the intercourse between the mother country and the colonies, which was to be treated as a coasting trade. The freedom of trade was, however, to be granted on reciprocal terms only; and the imports were still to be subject to the crown duties intended to give a preference to the produc- tions of the mother country in the colonial market and to those of the respective colonies in the markets of each other. McCulloch claimed that the conditions and regulations in- troduced were, for the most part, in direct contradiction of the principles laid down by Huskisson himself.^ But McCulloch was a polemical free trader, while Huskisson was a statesman making the first steps towards free trade; and the acts of 1825 and 1826 mark an enormous advance in both commercial and colonial policy. The concessions made to the colonists were that the casual relaxations of the system made in favor of trade with the United States were regularized and made permanent, and that these relaxations were granted to all other nations on the same terms as to the United States. Free ports were created in the various colonies and the privilege of warehousing was extended. The preferential duties in favor of the mother country were not abolished ; but, in place of absolute prohibition of many articles, an ad valorem duty was established, and the act of 1826 (which simply consohdated two acts of 1825) significantly includes, not a list of enumerated articles which might be imported, but a brief table of restrictions. " It is not to be dissembled that this is a great change in our colonial system," said Huskisson ;- but he claimed that 1 McCulloch, op. et. art. cit., pag^e t^^t,. ^Huskisson, Speeches, II, -jiS. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 39 great benefits to both the mother country and the colonies would ensue from it. Since the consequences of the Treaty of Paris had borne out all that Adam Smith had said about the advantages of open trade and the disadvantages of mono- poly, there had been other instances of prosperity resulting from the opening up of trade, to which he could appeal as precedents justifying the change he proposed. In 1813 the East Indian trade had been thrown open, with a result which proved, he said, " as the history of all modern commerce proves, that wherever you give a free scope to capital, to industry, to the stirring intelligence and active spirit of ad- venture . . . you are in fact opening new roads to entei- prise."^ He had another precedent in the restrictions on the Irish trade. An open trade, especially to a rich and thriving country [he con- cludes], is infinitely more valuable than any monopoly, however exclusive, which the public power of the state may be able either to enforce agfainst its own colonial dominions or to establish in its intercourse with other parts of the world.' In addition to these commercial advantages, which the re- lease of the colonial trade would bring to the mother country, he believed that political advantages in her relations to the continental colonies would also accrue. They would connect their increased prosperity with the liberal treatment, and would " neither look with envy at the growth of other states on the same continent, nor wish for the dissolution of old and the formation of new political connexions." These were the advantages to the mother country which he foresaw, and he relied on this general argument to prove that the concessions should be extended to the West Indian islands. He con- sidered a supposed objection, that the privileges need not have been extended to the West Indies, because " they can- not help themselves, however rigid the rules of monopoly or l/»:rf., II, 320. "^Ibid. II, 321. -^ 40 COMMERCIAL POLICY. dependence " under which they may be placed ;^ and an- swered it by asserting that at no time since the independence of the United States had it been found possible to enforce the statutory- restrictions, and that to attempt to do so would expose the islands to the greatest distress and would injure the shipping interests which opposed his reforms. From all the experience which we can collect from the conduct of this country in respect to Ireland and to its colonies — from all that we witness of what is passing in the colonies of other states, I come clearly to the conclusion that so far as the colonies themselves are concerned, their prosperity is cramped and impeded by the old sys- tem of exclusion and monopoly; and I feel myself equally warranted in my next inference, that whatever tends to increase the prosperity of the colonies cannot fail, in the long run, to advance in an equal degree the general interests of the parent state. '^ This is his general argument ; but in the case of the con- tinental colonies he found other reasons, based upon the industrial conditions in the colonies. Without these conces- sions, he feared, they would not continue tO' be able to meet the competition of the United States. The war had brought great prosperity to the maritime colonies, because it had given them a practical monopoly of the great markets for fish ; but after the war there had been considerable distress, because, being handicapped by the Navigation Laws, which forbade them to take return cargoes, the Nova Scotia fisher- men could not meet the competition of the United States in neutral markets. These were the arguments which, in the teeth of the oppo- sition of the shipping interests, carried through the first great modification of the colonial system. It was carried almost amid the indifference of the colonies. Canada was content with a colonial system which gave her the English market for timber, and she resen-ed her reforming zeal for constitutional iHuskisson, Speeches, III, no. I -fbid., II, 313, 314. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 41 questions. The colonists were gratified that the restrictions were removed, though they had not been seriously incon- venienced by them. Practically, all that any one had ever contended for was thus granted them, and with scarcely a pause they resumed their agitation for responsible govern- ment. Those, only who were in opposition to the popular demand saw great significance in Huskisson's reforms. Hali- burton wrote : Thus ended colonial monopoly, and with it, it is to be hoped, those ungenerous feeling's which led many persons in Great Britain to suppose that although members of the same Empire their interests were distinct from ours ; that any benefit derived to us from an inter- colonial trade was an indirect disadvantage to them ; and that the poverty of the colonies which that very monopoly created, while it rendered us sometimes burthensome and often importunate, was a reason for viewing us rather in the light of needy dependents than good customers. The benefit of this extension of trade, and the soundness of the principle on which it is founded, will soon appear in the increase of the national shipping — in the impulse given to colonial enterprise — in the growing demand for British manufactures and in more punc- tual remittances. ' HaJiburton's amiable hope that this was the end of the " ungenerous feelings " was not to be realized ; for this reform of Huskisson's, with the prosperity which came to the colo- nies in consequence, was only the starting point and the occasion for greater virulence on the part of those whom we now revile as Little Englanders. The colonial monopoly had not coma to an end, but only that part of it which could with any reason be said to benefit the mother country. The colonial preferences in the English market still remained ; but it was argued that what was beneficial to the colonies would surely be beneficial to the mother country in the end, iHaliburton, History of Nova Scotia, II, 388. 42 COMMERCIAL POLICY. Whatever principles may have been involved, Huskisson's re- form was justified by the result. Trade expanded and pros- perity increased. There was at first some difficulty with the United States, with whose objections to reciprocity McCulloch expressed his sympathy ; and the result was another suspen- sion of intercourse. Reports were made to the Senate of the United States early in 1826, condemning Huskisson's acts as "giving too little and asking too much.'' . . . The commitlee are not aware that any great advantage is to be derived to the commerce of the United States in making British colonial ports places of entrepot for the warehousing and trans- shipment of merchandize to be received from, or imported into, the United States, when it could probably be both brought and carried, without resort to them, directly to its ultimate destination with less cost and greater benefit ; more especially when such ports are sub- ject to exclusion without their previous knowledge or concurrence, as is recently demonstrated to be the case with regard to Halifax in Nova Scotia.^ This difficulty about the reservation of the intercolonial trade was not completely removed till the Navigation Laws were finally repealed ; but a compromise was patched up, and trade was renewed on reciprocal terms in 1830, when Eng- land modified some of the colonial duties which were intended to promote intercolonial trade ; and in that year the benefits of the acts of 1825 and 1826 were realized by the West Indies. But when this quarrel had beeni adjusted, the trade of the colonies grew.- They imported more than ever from the mother country, but their imports from foreign countries increased even faster. They exported to foreign countries that surplus which the United Kingdom could not take (and in this concession the West Indies found a certain means of 1 Report to U. S. Senate, January 25, 1826, quoted in the New Brunswick Royal Gazette, March 21, 1826. Halifax, an open port, had been closed, "in mid- winter and without notice, on an extremely hazardous and inclement coast.' -McCulloch, op. et art. cit., page 333. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 43 tiding over the crisis caused by the emancipation of the slaves) ; and colonial ships traded to all parts of the world. So great was the development that a wnriter in the Quebec Gazette, apparently in 1837, tried to account for the slower progress of Canada, as compared with the United States, by referring to the old restrictive system. From 1784 to the present time, our neigfhbours have had the free range of the world, going- and coming; while the colonies, until a comparatively recent period, were confined to the trade with the mother country and with the other colonies.* Ten years later the governor of Nova Scotia wrote to Earl Grey, the colonial secretary ; and his report is the final justi- fication of Huskisson's reforms. Prior to 1824, the foreign trade of Nova Scotia was very limited, but the changes in the commercial policy of the empire, suggested and carried through by Mr. Huskisson, opened a wider field for colonial enterprise, of which the North Americans were not slow to avail themselves. With every relaxation yielded by the Imperial Parliament, the foreign commerce of the colonies has attained a further development, and Nova Scotia vessels, besides their traffic with the neighbouring states, Canada and the West Indies, now trade to the Baltic, the Mediterranean, China, the {sic\ Maritius, the East Indies, the Brazils and the \sic\ Havanah ; and our merchants and mariners are fast acquiring an accurate acquaintance with distant seas and with foreign markets in every part of the world. With this report he sent a tabular statement (in part repro- duced on p. 44, note), which showed, by a comparison of the trade of 1827 with that of 1847, the extent of this de- velopment. With Huskisson's reforms the restrictions on the external trade of the colonies ended. There remained the preferen- tial duties in their tariffs in favor of English manufactures : 'Quoted in Martin's Colonies. 44 COMMERCIAL POLICY. the important fact that the opening of trade depended on reciprocal concessions, the value of which was adjudged by the Imperial Parliament ; and the classification of the trade between the colonies and the mother country as a coasting trade. The preferences in favor of the mother country im- posed no great burden on the colonies. England exported no food stuffs, and could manufacture more cheaply than any other nation ; and the colonies could have regarded the abolition of these preferences with profound indifference, had they not known that this act of apparent self-denial was but a prelude to the abolition of what they valued — the colonial preference in the English market. The complete repeal of the Navigation Laws — thus opening the colonial trade to all nations, irrespective of reciprocal concessions — was not re- garded as a boon, but in fact nearly drove the North Ameri- can colonies to the verge of revolt, if words meant anything. In 1 84 1 the Imperial duties at colonial ports were reduced and the prohibitions entirely removed; and in 1846 the colo- nial legislatures were authorized to repeal all the differential duties which had been imposed in the colonies to favor British produce and to encourage British and colonial shij>- ping. The speech from the throne at the opening of the Imperial Parliament in 1847 suggested that this freedom should be exercised for the benefit of the consumer. NoTB {c/. p. 43). — Imports into Nova Scotia (including Cape Breton)y>-om United Kingdom British Possessions U.S. and Foreign Ports Total 1827 £307,907 £190,309 £312,603 £810,819 1847 33o.9'S 220,550 480,489 Exfiorts from Nova Scotia to i.o3i>9So United Kingdom British Possessions U.S. and Foreign Porta Total 1827 £121,617 £107,738 £36,922 £267,277 1847 71.804 446,006 5i3'2S9 Shipping (tons) cleared for 831,071 United Kingdom British Poseesaiona U.S. md Foreign Ports Tot»J i8a7 22,615 100,324 «o,874 123.813 1847 67,049 149,524 199,880 416,463 See also Porter, Progress of the Nation, pp. 796 et seq. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 45 The colonial, legislatures took different courses of action in the matter of repeal. In Canada, in 1847, Mr. Cayley intro- duced a budget which did away with protection to British products, as compared with foreign, and in place of the old crown duties substituted duties for revenue, without any dis- tinction as to the source of the goods. Nova Scotia followed the same course; but New Brunswick — pathetically loyal to the last — maintained in her tariff of 1848 a discrimination in favor of the mother country and the other colonies, amount- ing in some cases to three or four hundred per cent. ^ The final repeal of the Navigation Laws, instead of being welcomed, was the occasion of great distress and serious dis- content in the seaboard colonies of the North American conti- nent. The act of 1849 repealed Huskisson's definition of the direct trade between the mother country and the colonies and of the intercolonial trade as a coasting trade, and threw open the whole carrying trade of the British Empire to the com- petition of the world. This destroyed the advantage which the North American colonies had enjoyed in the West Indian trade; and in 1851 a further blow seemed to be struck at colonial prosperity, when the colonial preference on timber, already greatly reduced, was cut in half. This double blow at their prosperity was the signal for a great outburst of dis- loyalty and discontent. In Montreal and St. John the e.xcite- ment rose to the pitch of frenzy. The mother country had cast them over, and they saw nothing but ruin staring them in the face. The repeal was, however, probably what the colonies needed most. It threw them on their own resources 'Journal of New Brunswick House of Assembly, March 28, 1848. The following are some of the items : Eng. and Coloi lial. Foreign, Eng. I &nd Colonial. Foreiji £ s. d. £ s. d. Butter, per cwt. 4 6 9 Boots aX 30% Cattle 100 a Carriages 4% 30% Clocks, each 5 IS Sugar, per cwt. S 10 N. E. S. 4% .5% 46 COMMERCIAL POLICY. and made them realize the duties as well as the privileges of responsible government. The ruin that was imminent did not come, because they set to work to avert it; and the threat of ruin was ultimately the industrial salvation of the colonies. The human mind [says Leroy Beaulieu] is so constituted that it will not have recourse to heroic measures until the situation is clear and definite. It will not depart from routine nor make full use of all its resources until it has seen all other hope of safety disappear. * This truth was abundantly illustrated in the case of the colo- nies after their desertion by the mother country. There was a good deal of immediate distress and suffering ; but it worked out right in the end. A contemporary New Brunswick ob- server, writing a quarter of a century later, said that the danger turned out to be more illusory than real ;- but it was averted because the energy of the colonists was called out. When they found that their appeals and protests were dis- regarded and that the English market was no longer to be their preserve, they began to set their house in order and to accommodate their business methods to the new conditions. The possession of the preference had encouraged unbusiness- like ways and a spirit of dependence on governments. Hence- forth they talked less politics and devoted them^-^lves to trade; and even the lumber industry was probably not less profitable in the face of competition than it had been in the days of the preference, although undoubtedly it was no longer so easy.^ iDe la Colonization, (zme idit.). page 203. 'Fenety, Political Notes (First Series), pag-e 329. 'Owing to wasteful methods of securing the lumber, " it is doubtful whether the trade was more profitable than it is at present, notwithstanding the enormous pro- ductiveness of the forests and the advantage which New Brunswick and the other colonies then had in the markets of Great Britain."— James Hannay, Life of Sir L. Tilley, page 40. There was another side to this prosperity, as the first minister at Pictou, Nora Scotia, pointed out. " But the grand cause of our depravation is the COMMERCIAL POLICY. 47 The immediate effect, however, was to daunt the bravest and the most loyal- It had been argued in England that the removal of the restrictions, by encouraging the enterprise and rousing the industry of the colonies, would increase their re- sources, and would thus enable them in a shorter time to throw off the yoke and effect their separation from the mother country. But it was the immediate distress, rather than the ultimate prosperity, which threatened tO' make for separation. Public opinion, whether in the legislative a.'^semblies, in public meetings or in the press, was disloyal. The expression of discontent was participated in by the staid, solid and sober members of the community, always famous for their conser- vatism and strong attachment to everything English.^ An shutting' up of the Baltic. If the Devil contrived it tor the ruin of our morals, he is a master in politics ; for it were hard to contrive a more effectual scheme for that purpose. . . . Ever since that event, ships, sailors, money and spirituous liquors with their attendant evils, have been pouring in among us continually. The great demand for timber has in a manner caused us to lay aside farming, our most innocent, and in the long run our most proiitable earthly employment, and g'vo ourselves up to the felling, squaring, hauling, rafting, and selling of timber to the ships, and the squandering of inoney . . . The prosperity of fools destroys them . . ." And the biographer of this minister explains with more restraint the effect of the demand for colonial timber. " It might have been expected that such prosperity would at least have had an important influence upon the improvement of the coimtry. But it would be difficult to find in any land an example of such prosperity leaving so few permanent results for good even upon its material progress. Farming retrograded. The f.\rmers went to the woods for timber, and left their farms to neglect. The land was thus depreciated by having the valuable timber removed from it without its being cleared or rendered tit for the plough ; while a ruinous system of farming impoverished the land already under cultivation. The farmer thought only of hastily committing his seed to the ground in spring, and of removing the crop in harvest, and paid no atten- tion to manuring, rotation, or other improved systems oi agriculture. ... In this way the farms became thoroughly exhausted, and the evils of this state of things have continued to the present day (1859), both by the improper system of farming, which is not even yet entirely abolished, and by the bad reputation which the country gained as to its capabilities for agriculture. The merchants, partly owing to the system of credit, and partly owing to the changes which took place in the lumber market, nearly all failed .... and the country came out of a season of commercial prosperity, such as it has never since seen, with exhausted resources." (Patterson : .Memoir of the Rev. James MacGregor, D.D., of Pictou. Nova Scotia, pp. 369-371). This is an unexpected picture of the results of a really effective English preferential tariff in tavour of colonial produce, but it can hardly be regarded as greatly exaggerated. ' Fenety, op. cit., page 329. 48 COMMERCIAL POLICY. address in favor of annexation to the United States, prepared in Montreal and signed by 325 mercliants of tliat city, rested its complaint on " the most disastrous effect " which the " reversal of the ancient policy of Great Britain " had upon Canada ; and although outside of Montreal there was not much favor shown to the annexation idea, language equally strong was employed to denounce the selfish policy of the mother country. At a joint meeting of the British-American League and the Colonial Association of New Brunswick it was resolved : That tha commercial evils now oppressing the British-American provinces are to be traced principally to the abandonment by Great Britain of her former colonial policy, thus depriving them of the preference previoasly enjoyed in the British market, without securing advantages in any other market. That these colonies cannot remain in their present position without the prospect of immediate ruin and that it is the duty of the Imperial Government either first to restore to the colonies a preference in the British markets over foreign goods, or second to have opened to them the markets of foreign countries, and more especially the United States upon terms of reciprocity. The resolutions proposed by Mr. (now Senator) Wark, to which reference has already been made, deserve quotation, not simply because they express clearly the discontent in New Brunswick, which suffered especially from the changes, but because they indicate clearly the restrictions to which the colonies were still subject, and to* the removal of which the energy of the colonists was directed, as soon as they had given up the vain hope that their protests might avail to change the English policy. The colonists had as yet, he claimed, neither the full power of regulating their tariff nor the right to enter into commercial treaties with foreign countries ; and he demanded a further extension of the powers of the colonial legislature to accomplish these ends. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 49 His resolutions were not adopted ; but those which were substituted for them recognized the necessity that new markets should be opened up, and formulated clearly the demand for a reciprocity treaty with the United States. There can be no doubt that the changes effected in 1849 and 185 1 did practically threaten the industries which had grown up in Canada during the first half of the century. The colonists claimed that the change was an outcome of the tendency to promote the manufacturing at the expense of the colonial interests of England ; and the difficulty of effecting the reform, with the distress and discontent it caused, is but another instance of the political danger of creating " in- terests '' by the manipulation of tariffs. The colonists had a strong case for consideration. They could have shown that the system of preferential duties had originated in the poli- tical and naval necessities of the mother country and that the benefit to the colonies was an afterthought, emphasized by those in authority to reconcile freemen to a system of political slavery which was a benefit to office-holders only. While ad- mitting that it had given prosperity and industrial develop- ment to the colonies, they could have argued that it had tended to restrict their industrial development to one line and had hindered the natural diversification of industrv*. Adam Smith may have been right, when he said that bounties on colonial timber assisted in the clearing of the land ; but a system of such excessive preferences as had been established had manifestly no such tendency, because lumbering remained so profitable that agricultural development was checked. The net results were: (i) the prosperity of the country was made to depend on one industry, which was naturally subject to fluctuations, according to the seasons, and did not therefore encourage a true industrial spirit; (2) the prosperity of this ;' industry in Canada was subject to the caprices and interests i of a legislative power over which the colonies could exercise ; 50 COMMERCIAL POLICY. no legislative control ; (3) although the colonies had a pre- ference in the English market, their lumber had, so long as that preference was substantial, been subject to heavy duties at home — with the result, according to the showing of Eng- lish Parliamentary committees, that a fluctuation of price in the English market to the extent of five per cent, meant a fluctuation of thirty per cent, in the colonies; (4) although they had protested against these fluctuations, they were being ruined by the removal of so ambiguous a benefit, because that industry, the creation to a large extent of Parliamentary preference, was their sole support. Most of these allegations could have been supported by reference to the Journals of the House of Commons. The benefit of the preferences was real enough, but at the same time an artificial direction and concentration was given to the industry of the country. Had the maintenance of the pre- ferences been within their own control, this artificiality would have been a trivial matter in comparison with the real bene- fits of the preference ; but it was dependent on the breath of English opinion, which had changed. Still, a great deal of consideration was actually shown for colonial interests by English statesmen. The colonial pre- ferences were the last portions of the old colonial system to be removed. Down to i860 the colonies enjoyed a preference of 45. a load on timber, which ought to have been suflScient to counterbalance the longer journey. The preferences were not all at once abolished, and the colonists had ample warn- ing to set their house in order ; so that, had it not been .for the acquired Micawber instinct of waiting for the government to do something, they would not have been left in the lurch at the last. The case of the West Indies was harder. They had suf- fered more from the other parts of the colonial system ; and yet, even when the preference was highest, they had derived COMMERCIAL POLICY. 51 little real benefit from it. The monopoly granted to the West , Indian planter, said Huskisson,i was of little or no advan- \ tage to him. ' By conquests made during: the last war, by cessions obtained at the last peace, you have extended your sugar colonies in such a degree that the quantity they now send to this country exceeds by 60,000 hogsheads (about one-fifth of the whole supply) the con- sumption of this country. This excess must be sold in the general market of Europe. The price which it will command in that market, It IS obvious, must be regulated by the rate at which other sugars of hke quality (those of Cuba, Brazil and the East Indies) can be afforded in the same market. It is equally obvious that the price of this excess must determine the price of the other four-fifths consumed m the United Kingdom. The monolopy, therefore, affords little if any substantial advantage to those upon whom it is conferred. They must be able to produce sugar in competition with the foreign grower. The abolition of the preference was, nevertheless, a hard blow to the West Indies. The preference hadi encouraged them to confine themselves to the cultivation of a single staple, for the production, of which they were by no means so well suited as were the competitors they now had to meet. From this blow they never recovered, because they were not able, as were their fellow-sufiferers in the continental colonies, to turn their energies to other fields; and at the present moment there is a strong demand— and little likelihood— that m some form or other the preference in the English market may be restored to them. The whole history of the preferential duties is one long warning against an attempt to give an artificial direction to industry. ^ THuskisson. Speeches. Ill, ..4. Cf. also III, 603: - Much as the West India planters have been, trom time to time, promised, nothing has as yet beea done for mem. f ul'^'^'\ history of the preferential duties is represented in tabular torm below. The timber and sugar duties are taken as typical ; but these, though the most imporUnt. were not the only preferences enjoyed. In 1840, according to Porters evidence before 52 COMMERCIAL POLICY. The act of 1846 has generally been regarded as the close of the period of commercial regulations ; and doubtless it was, for practical purposes. But there still remained certain restrictions on the commercial freedom of the colonies. The removal of the restrictions was, as has been said, a triumph rather of free trade than of freedom. The English govern- ment did not propose to allow the colonies to mar the example which England was offering to the world, and accordingly it the famous Import Committee of that year, there were 82 differential duties in favor of colonial products ; by 1853 all of these but the preferences on timber, food, wine and spirits had disappeared ; and in i860 the last, the timber duty, was abolished. 1798 Colonial timber was admitted free till 1798, when it was charged 3°/, 1803 ad valorem ; but there was practically no importation till 1803, when the 1806 duty stood at 2s. a load. This duty was abolished in i8o6. Owing- to diffi- culties with the Baltic powers, a large addition was made to duties on Baltic 's ^ r '''"ber in 1809, and in the following year these duties were doubled. After the failure of Napoleon's Russian campaign, when the Baltic ports were 1813 again opened, an addition of 25'/, was made, not from military necessity, but to favour the colonic;s ; although the result was still further to decrease 1821 Baltic shipping. This continued to 1821, when a duty of los. a load was imposed on colonial timber, and the duty on foreign reduced from 65s. to 555. In 183 1 an attempt was made still further to reduce the colonial pref- erence, but ineffectually ; and the Whig government in 1841 was equally 1842 unsuccessful. Peel successfully dealt with the subject in his first budget, and ag:ain in 1843 ; and in 1846 changes were proposed, to take effect in 1848 two stages, 1847 and 1848, at which date the preference had been reduced 1851 to 15s on foreign and is. per load on colonial. The preference was in 1851 i86o again reduced by half, and finally in i860 the duties were equalized at is. a load on foreign and colonial timber alike. — Down to 1S41 the duty on foreign sugar was prohibitory and the imports practically nothing. In that year the Whig ministry proposed to reduce foreign sugar from 65s. per cwt. to 36s., the duty on colonial remaining at 24s. per cwt. ; but their proposal was rejected on the ground that it granted favours to slave products. Peel, 1844 in 1844, admitted foreign sugar, the product of free labour in China, Java and Manila, at an intermediate rate of 355. 8d., the duties on foreign slave- 1845 grown being 66s. 2d. In the next year the duties on all classes were reduced and stood at 63s., 23s. i,d. and 14s. ; and provision was made that by 1851 colonial sugar should be reduced to 105., and that in 1854 all 1846 rates were to be equalized. But in 1846 the Whig ministry abolished the distinction between slave-grown and free-grown, and reduced the duty on all foreign sugar to 21s. per quintal, which was gradually to be reduced to 14s. in 1851, when all preferences were to disappear. In 1848, however, in consequence of protest, the time of protection to colonial sugar was 1854 extended three years, to 1854, in which year all preferences disappeared, though the sugar duties continued till 1874. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 53 desired to keep the colonies in subjection to the ideas of the mother country. The benefits [wrote Lord Grey in 1849 to Sir Edmund Head] ^¥hich are expected to arise from this policy [that is, free trade] will be greatly increased through its general adoption by the principal nations of the world, which Her Majesty's government hope to see eventually brought about. But it would materially interfere with the attainment of this happy result if it should be observed by foreign countries that the former and narrow policy of endeavouring, by bounties or restrictions, to divert capital and industry to other than their natural channels, was again adopted with Her Majesty's assent in any part of Her Dominion. ' To many in the colonies it seemed, and perhaps still seems, that the mother country was pursuing her own in- terests at the expense of the colonies. Mr- Wark, in his resolutions, claimed that the manufacturing interests of the mother country were being advanced at the expense of the colonial interests ; that England had no longer any need for restrictions to secure her own market, and was interested in having the world's markets thrown open to her; and that, for the sake of the example to foreign countries, she was still prepared to sacrifice the interests of the colonies, or what seemed tO' the colonists tO' be their interests. The colonies were not yet free, but were still mere conveniences to serve the ends of the mother; country. England had abandoned specific restrictions, but she still maintained the restrictive system. If there were any in England who believed that, be- cause specific restrictions might have weighed on the colo- nies, they would welcome the principles of free trade, they were speedily undeceived ; for the colonists at once began to claim the right to manipulate their tariffs in ways quite con- trary to the principles of free trade. This brought them into IDispatch 170, December 4, 1849, Journals of New Brunswick House, 1850. 54 COMMERCIAL POLICY. conflict with the home government, which still thought to regulate colonial ideas. The restrictions on the freedom of the colonists, stated briefly, in the order in which they came up fori discussion, were three : (i) They were denied the right to favor their own industries, by means of import duties or by bounties; (2.) they were not free to enter into reciprocity treaties with other colonies or with foreign countries ; and (3) they were bound by Imperial treaties, in the framing of which they were not consulted. These three restrictions have been removed : the first in 1859; the second in 1868 for Canada, in 1873 and 1895 for the Cape and the AustraHan colonies ; the third, partially in 1881 and finally in 1897. In 1842 the last tariff was framed for the colonies ; and in the following year it was conceded by speakers in the Eng- lish House of Commons that Canada possessed the exclusive right to regulate her own tariff. ^ But when the colonies began to exercise this right according to their own ideas, the home government protested and instructed colonial governors not to give their assent to bills which were- contrary to free- trade principles. The Assembly of New Brunswick sought to establish a bounty on hemp, and the colonial secretary re- buked the Assembly for their ignorance of economic prin- ciples as well as for their presumption. So well known were the sentiments of the home government, and so thoroughly was it recognized in the colonies that they were prepared to enforce these sentiments, that in 1849 Mr- Hincks, the in- spector-general of Canada, in introducing a free-trade budget, declared that tO' establish a protective system in Canada would be tantamount to a declaration of independence. He referred to Lord Grey's dispatches ; and he asked what in- ducement England would have in keeping up any connection with Canada, if the colony deprived her of the power of iTodd, Parliamentary Government in the British Colonies, page 177. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 55 trading with them. In this Mr. Hincks showed that he understood the temper of the mother country, for nothing has retarded the growth of the Imperial Federation idea in England so much as the existence of protective tariffs in the colonies. But apparently neither Lord Grey nor Mr. Hincks was aware of the strength of the protectionist sentiment in the colonies, or of the logical importance of the grant of responsible government. The colonies simply ignored the protests of the home government; and against their invin- cible determination— or, as the free traders at home might have said, against their invincible ignorance— the home government could not prevail, except at the risk of disorga- nizing the colonies altogether The grant of responsible government carried with it the control of fiscal affairs accord- ing to their own ideas ; and in the end the power of logic prevailed. In 1856 the principle was distinctly enunciated, in the revised edition of the " Rules and Regulations for Her Majesty's Colonial Service," that the customs establishments in all the colonies are under the control and management of the several colonial governments, and the colonial legislatures are empowered to establish their own customs regulations and rates of duty ;' and by an act of 1857 the powers of the self-governing coIo nies were further extended. The last episode in the struggle took place in 1859, when, on the motion of the manufacturers of Sheffield, the Duke of xXewcastle protested against a new Canadian tariff. The rights of the colonies were finally vin- dicated by the memorandum of Sir Alexander (then Mr.) Gait, the Canadian minister of finance ; and the broad prin- ciple he then enunciated has never since been questioned : Self-government would be utterly annihilated if the views of the Imperial Government were to be preferred to those of the people of >Todd, op. cii., pa|2;e 178. 56 COMMERCIAL POLICY. Canada. It is, therefore, the duty of the present government [of Canada] distinctly to affirm the right of the Canadian legislature to adjust the taxation of the people in the way they deem best, even if it should unfortunately happen to meet the disapproval of the Imperial ministry. Her Majesty cannot be advised to disallow such acts, unless her advisers are prepared to assume the administration of the affairs of the colony, irrespective of the views of its inhabitants. The Imperial Government are not responsible for the debts and en- gagements of Canada, they do not maintain its judicial, educational or civil service, they contribute nothing to the internal government of the country, and the Provincial Legislature, acting through a ministry directly responsible to it, has to make provision for all these wants. They must necessarily claim and exercise the widest latitude as to the nature and extent of the burdens to be placed on the industry of the people. ^ This principle was finally sanctioned by the Imperial Padia- ment, in the British North America Act, 1867, §91, which recognizes the exclusive legislative authority of the Parlia- ment of Canada over all matters relating to " the regulation of trade and commerce," " the raising of money by any mode or system of taxation," and " navigation and shipping." Ac- cordingly, when, in 1879, on the adoption of a highly pro- tectionist national policy, the secretary for the colonies was invited in the House of Commons- to disallow the act, he declined to interfere, because the matter was entirely within the competence of the Dominion Parliament. Down to the year of the appointment of the Marquis of Lome (1878), instructions were issued to the successive gover- nors-general to reserv-e for the consideration of the Imperial government any bills imposing differential duties ; and the omission of the specific instruction in his case may be re- garded as the close of this contention. One part of the con- tention had many years before been definitely settled in favor of the colonies — namely, the right to discriminate in 'Canada Sessional Papers, i860, No. 38. ■i March ao, 1879, Todd, op. cit., page 183. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 57 favor of other colonies, subject always to the treaty obliga- tions of the Imperial government ; but the right, for which the colonies contended, to discriminate in favor of foreign nations has not yet been admitted — in form, at least. The contention arose from the position of distress in which the colonies found themselves, after the repeal of the colonial preferences in the English market. Lord Grey's dispatches (March 22 and November 8, 1848), instructing colonial gover- nors, evidently have reference to differentials granted to the mother country and are inspired by all the fanaticism of absolute free-trade doctrine. The reply to the address which the Assembly of New Brunswick made to the Queen, on the subject of the repeal of the Navigation Laws, contains the suggestion that the North American colonies were at liberty to place intercolonial commerce on the footing of the coast- ing trade (to which foreigners were not admitted) ; and the Assembly responded by a request to be allowed to do so, preparatory to a demand on the United States for reciprocity. But, in spite of this admission of the principle and in spite of their own suggestion, the Imperial government continued to interpose objections and difficulries regarding intercolonial reciprocity. The objections were based on an incorrect read- ing of the terms of certain treaties ; and the home govern- ment claimed that the mother country alone, of all the nations of the earth, would be excluded from the operation of the reciprocity treaties. Despite these objections, however, par- tial facilities were from time to time granted : and before the formation of the Confederation in 1867 the British North America colonies were more or less granting reciprocal con- cessions to each other. The quesrion was settled, so far as Canada was concerned, when the American colonies entered the Confederation ; but in 1868, before Prince Edward Island had entered the Dominion, the problem again came up for discussion. The newly formed Dominion admitted certain 68 COMMERCIAL POLICY. articles duty free from Prince Edward Island, and in return Canadian breadstuff s were admitted free into the island. The secretary for the colonies protested that this was con- trary to the treaty obligations of the mother country; but Sir John Rose pointed to the precedent of an act of the old province of Canada, passed in 1850, permitting free entry of the products of other North American colonies — an act which was not disallowed. Again in i860, as he reminded the colonial secretary, when it was proposed to extend exist- ing arrangements so as to admit all articles of colonial growth and manufacture free of duty on reciprocal terms, although the Lords of the*Committee of the Privy Council on Trade recommended that assent to this law be conditional on the granting of a like concession to all other countries, the Duke of Newcastle (February 5, 1861) was forced to admit that " they had no wish to offer any obstacle to any endeavours which might be made to bring about a free commercial intercourse between the North American colonies." To the legislation of 1868, the Board of Trade (to which colonial commercial legislation is referred by the colonial secretary) objected that the differential duties must be ex- tended to all countries having " a most favored nation clause " in a treaty which extended to British possessions as well as to the United Kingdom. The ultimate result, they said, might be that British produce, i.e., the produce of the United Kingdom and of British possessions not situated in North America, will be the only produce which is shut out by differential duties from consump- tion in Canada. The colonial secretary was, however, fain to content himself with the hope that, if ever the products referred to in the sixth section of this act are COMMERCIAL POLICY. 59 admitted free of duty from the United States, a similar immunity will be extended to the same products of the United Kingdom and of all foreign countries.,', Thus the Board of Trade was discomfited, and the question of intercolonial reciprocity was settled — at the time for Canada, but constructively for all self-governing colonies. The other colonies were not long in claiming a similar privilege, though they have not yet agreed to act upon the permission) which was a few years later (1873) granted to them. In 1870 the Intercolonial Free Trade Act passed by the legislature of Tasmania was disallowed ;" and in the following year the Australasian colonies — New South Wales, Tasmania, South Australia, Victoria and New Zealand — made formal application to be allowed to establish a com- mercial union. They joined to this application a request that no treaty should be concluded by the Imperial government with any foreign power which should conflict with the exer- cise of intercolonial reciprocity, and that Imperial interference with intercolonial fiscal legislation should cease. The colo- nial secretary apparently dodged the main issue, and insisted that " the constitutional right of the Queen to conclude treaties binding all parts of the Empire cannot be ques- tioned " ; although he seemed to admit the power of the colonial parliaments toi make the treaties a dead letter, so far as they were concerned, by refusing to pass the laws " which may be required to bring such treaties into operation." The Australasians were not satisfied with this answer ; and a colo- nial conference, at which Queensland and Western Australia were also represented, was held at Sydney in February, 1873, to urge the necessity of the removal of all Imperial restric- tions on intercolonial free trade. The colonies had their 1 Canada Sessional Papers, No. 47, i86g. 2Todd, of), cii., p. 127. The Australian colonies were precluded, by the Con- stitution Acts granted to them, from entering into differential tariff agreements with each other or with any other country. 60 COMMERCIAL POLICY. way, as the colonies generally have ; and the Australian Colo- nies Duties x^ct (1873) ^^'^^ passed, which granted full power to each of the colonies concerned to make laws, imposing or remitting duties whether differential or preferential or otherwise, for or against one another. It also extends the powers of the colo- nial legislatures in Australia to regulate the duties on the importation of articles not the growth, produce or manufacture of Australia or New Zealand. But it retains the prohibition against differential duties on goods imported into the colonies from foreign countries or from Great Britain.^ The latter prohibition, against discriminating in favor of the mother country, continued in force till the denunciation of the German and Belgian treaties in 1897. The colonies are not yet free to impose differential duties so as to confer exceptional advantages upon foreign over British trade, and they may not use their liberty to the direct injury of British commerce. That much, at least, is involved in the idea of empire ; and the mother country- claims — and is likely to have her claim always allowed — to be en- titled to the most favored nation clause. This right has never been seriously questioned, though in 1854 it was by mutual consent ignored. The repeal of the colonial pre- ferences in the English market and of the Navigation Laws"^ had wrought so much distress in the colonies that it was im- perative, to use the words of the address adopted bv the iTodd. op. cit.. pp. 195-197. Down to the year (1880) of the publication of this work, at least, the governors of the Cape of Good Hope and of South Australia were instructed to withhold assent from all bills imposing- differential duties (other than as allowed by the Australian Colonies Duties Act of 1873) ; and in form, at least, they were unable to grant differentials to non-.\ustrallan colonies, till 1895 (s^ Vict. c. 3), when the restriction was removed. — Todd. op. cit., page 132. -The repeal of the Navigation Laws was a grievance in the seaboard colonies only. The old province of Canada gained little from the restriction and was debarred by it from taking advantage of her "opportunity for securing for her vast system of inland navigation the great and growing carrying trade of North-western America" ; and in 1848 numerous petitions for the repeal of the Navigation Laws, so far as they applied to Canada, were sent to London. — Todd, op. cit,, page 179. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 61 New Brunswick Assembly in 1850, that they should "obtain the open ports and the unrestricted coasting trade of the American Union ";^ and accordingly in 1854 Elgin's Treaty was negotiated. The difficulty about discriminating against the mother country was not raised, partly owing to the neces- sities of the colonies and partly also to the fact that it was a discrimination in name only, for the reciprocity was confined to certain natural products which the mother countr}- did not export.^ This concession would have formed an admirable precedent for a more extended treaty, had such a precedent ever been sought ; but Canadian official negotiations with Washington have always been based on the terms of the treaty of 1854 — reciprocity of natural products. When the Liberal party in Canada adopted the program of unrestricted reci- procity, there were not wanting those who denounced this last right of the mother country to rank as a most favored nation. That unrestricted reciprocity would practically, as well as nominally, have discriminated against the mother countr}', cannot well be denied ; and those who advocated it had to fall back on the argument that it was a matter of indifference to England whether her goods were excluded by a tariff framed at Washington or at Ottawa, and that England would gain an increase of trade from the greater prosperity of the Dominion of Canada, resulting from reciprocal trade rela- tions with the United States.^ The movement for unre- 1 Journals of New Brunswick House of Assembly, April 25. 1850. 2" In 1854 the treaty known as the Reciprocity Treaty was finally concluded, admitting- certain natural products of each country free into the other, without any qualification as to the differential or discriminating character of its provisions." — Confidential report to Governor-General for transmission, made by Sir John Rose, September 3, 1868, Canada Sessional Papers, No. 47, 1869. 3 See the speeches of Sir Richard Cartwright and others in Canadian Hansard, 1890, I, 144-646. Informal negotiations between Canada and the United States were broken oflF in 1892, because the Canadian delegates were not willing to discriminate against the mother country ; and on the protest of Canada, when the Newfoundland government proposed to pass legislation to carry out the convention ot 1890 with the 62 COMMERCIAL POLICY. stricted reciprocity now has few adherents in Canada; and the right of the mother countiy to at least the treatment of the most favored nation is supported by the practically un- animous conviction of the Canadian people and, while the present Imperial temper lasts, is not likely to be called in question. The several commercial concessions made to the colonies during the last half century were invariably qualified by a clause respecting the treaty obligations of the Empire. A colony, however free and independent, is bound by all Im- perial treaties, unless specially exempt from their scope ; and before the days of colonial freedom the Imperial Parliament had entered into treaties which bound the colonies not to discriminate in favor of the products of the mother country. The last phase of the colonial struggle for commercial free- dom has been the effort to secure the following concessions : (i) That the colonies should not be included in commercial treaties without their own consent; (2) that in the framing of treaties directly affecting their interests they should be directly represented ; and (3) that all past treaties which re- stricted the action of the colonies in working towards an Imperial customs union should be denounced. The first two rights were readily yielded. They were so obviously the logical outcome of the control of their own fiscal affairs that they had but to be demanded to be con- ceded. When the Canadian government informed the colo- nial office that thereafter (March 26, 1881) it desired to be informed of the inception of any new treaty, and that in future no stipulation binding upon the commerce of Canada should be introduced into United States, tlie colonial secretary (March 26, 1892) assured the Dominion govern- ment that legislation discriminating against Canada would be disallowed. — Lord Ripon's Despatch to Governor-General of Canada, June 28, 1895 ; Canadian Statistical Year Book, 1894, page 309. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 63 any treaty without reserving to the Canadian government the option of acceptance or refusal/ it was perfectly natural that Lord Carnarvon should agree that a new clause should be inserted in all treaties there- after concluded, to the effect that no colony was included except at its own option. As regards the second demand, while, of course, no colony could enter into direct negotia- tions with an outside power, the difficulty was got over by naming colonial statesmen as Imperial representatives for the negotiation of treaties peculiarly affecting colonial interests. Thus far there was no difficulty ; but when it came to the denunciation of treaties then in force, the interests of the mother country were directly involved. To denounce the treaties, it was feared, might derange English trade with important customers — and that without immediate prospect of any compensating advantage. The colonies did not show any great desire to favor English goods and had all, with one exception, discriminated against her manufacturers in favor of their o\Tn. Therefore, until a quid pro quo was offered in the shape of an actual discrimination in her favor, public sentiment in England did not call for the denunciation of the treaties. The colonists proceeded in the wrong way to achieve their end. An Imperial customs union meant for them a discrimination in the English market for colonial goods, for which they were willing to pay the price of granting English goods a differential. They protested against the treaties, be- cause these stood in the way of their ultimately obtaining privileges for which they could concede none; and English sentiment naturally remained unaffected. The treaties which stood in the \v-ay were the treaty with Belgium of 1862 and that with the German Zollver'ein of 1865. These stood upon a special footing. ^Canadian Senate Hansard, 1891, pp. 613 et seq. 64 COMMERCIAL POLICY. The ordinary most favored nation clause in various treaties between Great Britain and foreign powers would not preclude the conclusion of special preferential arrangements between the colonies, or between a colony and Great Britain. As against foreign powers, in the absence of specific provision, the Empire is a whole or a unit, within which any fiscal arrangements may be made without infringing the concession involved in that clause. ^ While these treaties did not prevent differential treatment by the United Kingdom in favor of the British colonies, or differential treatment by British colonies in favor of each other, they did prevent differential treatment by British colo- nies in favor of the United Kingdom, without extending the same concessions to foreign contracting powers. Thus, by the operation of the most favored nation clause in other treaties, they admitted all the nations with which the United Kingdom had commercial treaties. Their existence was, then, an obstacle to an Imperial customs union. These treaties were passed during the period when colonial interests were being treated with unsalutary neglect j^ and Lord Salisbury admitted some years ago that no reason had been given — or could be found — for the permission given to a foreign power to interfere in what should have been the purely private affairs of the empire. But, however the clauses had come to be inserted, there they were; and they effectually barred the way to preferential treatment of the mother country by the colonies. They not only did this, but they also compelled the colonies to molify their fiscal legislation.-^ But the de- iLord Jersey's Report to the Colonial Secretary on the Colonial Conference at Ottawa, 1894. This report and Lord Ripon's despatches are printed in the Canadian Statistical Year Book, 1894, pp. 270-310. _ 2 Burke claimed that the colonies had prospered because :hey had been treated with "salutarj- negrlect." 3 ■• We have already had to modify our legislation, in a way which we ourselves did not desire, in consequence of these treaties." (Sir John Abbot, in Canadian Senate, September 25. .891. Senate Hansard, 1895, page 6.3). The German govern- ment had protested against the inclusion in the invoice price at Canadian ports of freight charges on German goods to the United Kingdom which were reexported from England to Canada. COMMERCIAL POLICY. 65 nunciation could come from the Imperial government only ; and, while the commerce of the United Kingdom with Bel- gium and Germany would be exposed to risks, and " would have to be carried on under fiscal conditions subject to con- stant changes and fluctuations, or, at all events, without that permanence and security which is of primary importance to successful and profitable interchange," on the other hand, no scheme had been proposed which foreshadowed " any precise advantages to be secured to the export trade . . . from the United Kingdom to the colonies in the event of the ter- mination of these treaties. "^ The Canadian preferential tariff of 1897 changed all the conditions. A " precise advantage '" was offered, and the loyal sentiment of the year necessitated England's acceptance of the offer. Whether the Canadian government was correct in its contention that the concessions granted were not gratuitous but were a return for concessions already made by the mother countr}', and therefore did not come under the interpretation of the most favored nation clause, need not now he dis- cussed. It is obvious, as Sir John Abbot foresaw in 1891. that such an interpretation would have led to litigation ; and the British governmient wisely cut the knot by denouncing the treaties. The last restriction on the colonies was thus ren-:0\-e(l. Their right to be considered in the making of treaties had already been granted. The right to say whether they would be bound by treaties contracted before they had obtained the former right, was conceded by the denunciation. Lord Jersey, in his report of the colonial conference, had sug- gested that an additional article should' be included in all British commercial treaties, enabling " any colony to with- draw from the treaty at the date when it is terminable '" ; "Lord Ripons Despatch, June 2S, iS.»s.— Canadian Statistical Year Book, 1894, pag^e 305. 66 COMMERCIAL POLICY. but the action of the Imperial government, by practically ad- mitting the right of colonial initiative in Imperial affairs, had advanced matters further than Lord Jersey had ventured to suggest. The restrictive commercial system has narrowed down to the following minor points : The mother country claims to be included as a most favored nation in all treaties contracted on behalf of the colonies ; the colonies cannot disregard the Im- perial obligations, by discriminating in favor of one nation and against another, when the mother country has with the excluded foreign state commercial treaties containing the most favored nation clause; no colony can endeavour, in direct or indirect negotiation, to obtain an advantage at the expense of any other part of the Empire ; and finally, in the case of preference being' sought by or offered to the colony in respect of any article in which it competed seriously with other colo- nies, or with the mother country, Her Majesty's Government would feel it to be their duty to use every effort to obtain the extension of the concession to the rest of the Empire."' These seem to constitute the minimum of empire. They might be conceded, if demanded ; but the concession would be equivalent to breaking up the Empire into a number of independent states — a result which none of the colonies in any measure desires. 1 Lord Ripou's Despatch, Canadian Year Book, page 310. ( '37 ) CHAPTER III. COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. WHEN Prince Bismarck declared in 1884 that it was not the intention of the German Government to found provinces but commercial undertakings'^ he set forth not only the intention of the German Government but the motive of all colonisation and the ideal of colonial policy of all nations. This is the one permanent colonial problem — how to raise up a nation of customers. Other problems have attracted attention and have been solved or disappeared naturally in the development of history. Indeed, nothing is so remark- able in the history of colonial policy as this fact of the com- plete disappearance of so many of those problems on which the fate of our colonial empire seemed to depend, and about which whole generations of men ha\e vexed and agitated themselves. Men used to grow heated over the pro and cons of responsible government, of penal settlements, and systematic colonisation and state aided emigration, of land grants and the treatment of natives. Yet these questions are all dead issues. Some of them have solved themselves and other have been solved by contriving to shift the respon- sibility from the Imperial Government to the colonial adminis- trations. These questions, if they remain questions at all, are no longer problems of colonial policy but problems in the domestic politics of the colonies. The land question, which so interested Wakefield and his fellows, was transferred tc^ the colonial legislatures, and has there, the theorists to the contrary, been settled satisfactorily, to the colonists at least, iDawson: Bismarck and State Socialism, page iji. 1 68 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. in the way best fitted to promote the growth of the colonies ; and the treatment of the natives by colonial governments has been, at the worst, as satisfactory as it was while the Imperial Government was worried by the Nonconformist conscience. Canada, for instance, has no cause ta be ashamed of her treatment of the Indians if comparison must be made with the policy of the Imperial Government on this question. Whether, settled or not, these are no longer questions of colonial policy. But there is one question of colonial policy whose interest is perennial. It has never been satisfactorily solved ; and it cannot be devolved upon the colonial legislatures, because it cannot be treated as a problem of domestic interest of any one colony or group of colonies. This is the question of the commercial relations of the colonies to the mother country and of the mother country to the colonies. Each generation has had its own solution, but the problem isi still unsolved and still pressing for solution, and still apparently as far from solution as ever. Various policies have been adopted, varying from absolute monopoly to the absolute freedom of in- difference on the one side, and from high protection against the products of the mother country and even quasi discrimina- tion against her to preferential treatment on the other. These policies can hardly be said to have been suited to the genera- tions which adopted them ; and they have never satisfied the generations which followed. This problem has been for four hundred years before the minds of those statesmen who have concerned themselves with over-seas expansion. In the charter which Henry VII. granted to the Cabots traces of it appear. It was the object of the old colonial policy which ended in the disruption of the empire. Commercial con- siderations determined the attitude of the Little Englanders and commercial considerations animate the Federationists of to-day. Mr. Chamberlain, like Henry VII., dreams of un- COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 69 developed resources and hopes to exploit them on behalf of the mother country-. The commercial relations of the various parts of the Empire has been the dominant idea in times of expansion, of disruption, and of consolidation ; and the problem still demands solution. It cannot be set aside ; and to-day, notwithstanding the growth of imperial sentiment and the realisation by the colonies of their imperial heritage, it may still be said that the future of the Empire depends on the solution of this question. The present practical importance of the problem is due to the renewed interest which the predominant partner is taking in it. The cosmopolitan indifference which the mother country has for nearly half a century shown towards the com- merce of her colonies has given way ; and in a few short years there has not only been a revival of interest in the commercial aspects of colonial policy, but also a remarkable ripening of opinion regarding the possibility of finding a solution of the difficulties. The change has not been in the attitude of the colonists. There are still living those who remember the palmy days when Canadian lumber had a pre- ference in the English market ; and there has been a con- tinuity of opinion in favour of a return to that side of the colonial policy which benefited the colonies. For a time the effects of the Reciprocity Treaty of 1854 were such as to remove the most powerful causes of discontent at the change ; but the repeated failures to get that Treaty renewed in some shape or form, and the economic effects of the National Policy, which, by restricting purchases also restricted the sales of Canadian produce, again turned colonial attention to the market which a fiscal preference had once made their own. Without realising how profound a change had been effected in English policy by the simplification of the tariff, the colo- nists naively demanded that the new policy should be set aside or so modified as to suit colonial interests. They had 70 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. no conception how irritating such a demand was to those who thought that England's prosperity dated from 1845, and there certainly was no intention of adopting a " stand and deliver " attitude towards the English consumer. It has been said that England lost half of her colonial empire because she persisted in taxing her colonists, and was like to lose the other half because she would not allow her colonists to tax her. This could be said from the English point of view only. The colonists not only had no conception of demanding con- cessions in return for their loyalty to the Imperial connection ; but it never crossed their minds that such an interpretation could be placed upon their demands. The irritation was perhaps natural enough upon the part of the mother country which had made visible sacrifices for her colonies and could see no visible advantages which protectionist colonies con- ferred upon her; but it cannot be too often repeated that the colonists intended neither to irritate nor to threaten. To the colonist the demand seemed to involve nothing more than a modification of the tariff such as he was annually accustomed to. In the colonies there was practically no free trade principle. A party in opposition might adopt free trade as a party cry ; but the individual members of the rank and file of the party had no understanding of what the policy in- volved and no hesitation in modifying their platform when they came into oflfice so as to preserve a continuity of protectionist policy. Those who expected that the Liberal party in Canada after 1896 would redeem their pre-election promises were quickly shown how baseless their expectations were. The hope did more credit to their belief in the consistency of politicians than to their own insight into the political and financial con- ditions of the country. For while it rem.alned necessary to raise the greater portion of the revenue by customs taxation no colony could possibly be other than protective in its fiscal policy. COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. So to the colonists, to free trader as well as to protec- tionist, the question was one simply of tariff manipulation and the persistent refusal of the mother countr\- to make such a trifling modification of her tariff as the imposition of a five per cent, duty on non-imperial products would have in- volved, was but another evidence of the survival of the little England spirit. As a matter of fact the refusal was simplv the assertion of the predominant partner that she was entitled to the same freedom to manage her own tariff policy as the colonies had quarter of a century before asserted for themselves. Britain was as much entitled to adopt free trade as the colonies had been to adopt a protection tariff. To the mother country a five per cent, preference to colonial products was a difference of kind, not of degree, as it would have been in the colonies ; and she was of the sentiment of Mrs. Easy when the nurse excused her illegitimate child on the ground that it was only a little one. No English statesman could regard the question as the simple matter it appeared to every colonist. It in- volved an abandonment of principle or rather the modifica- tion of a policy which success had crystallised into a prin- ciple. The colonial demand seemed to those responsible for British policy to be of the same character as the demand which a heavy drinker might make of a total abstainer, in the interest of harmony of life and principle, to split the difference and come to a compromise at two glasses a day. It was in the circumstances not unnatural for English Free Traders to imagine that the colonists were attempting to drive a bargain for their loyalty, and somewhat curtly to remind the colonist that the English quid pro quo had long since been paid over. For a generation the question remained in this region of misunderstanding. But of late years there has come more understanding on the side of the mother country at least. 72 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. The colonies have partially shown that they understand the position of the mother country and the course of events in the industrial world have led many at home to remember that Free Trade is after all a policy only. How far this better un- derstanding has been helped in the mother country by the re-appearance of those economic conditions which produced the mercantile system we need not consider at length. There can be little doubt that the United Kingdom became a Free Trade country because the old ideas of relative advantage had lost all their importance. The absolute advantage for which she willingly sacrificed the niggling devices of the mer- cantile system remained hers for nearly three-quarters of a century. But naturally she could not always retain her posi- tion of absolute and unquestioned industrial supremacy. She had a long start but the United States and Germany during the last quarter of a century have been making rapid strides and capturing certain branches of English trade. "},Iade in Germany" has even become the subject of a searching of heart and alarmists have spoken of the decline and fall of England's industrial supremacy. In the nature of things this renewal of competition was to be expected ; and it need not be the cause of alarm. It is only once in a lifetime that one can be twice the age of one's younger brothers, and though the relative advantage may grow less, may indeed at certain points disappear altogether, the absolute advantage may re- main. But the re-appearance of competition has bent, not policy but, some opinion back from considerations of plenty to considerations of power; and mercantile ideas are beginn-, ing again to find expression. War and commerce are again spoken of in the same breath. We hear more of the re- sources of the Empire, of trade and the flag and the commer- cial advantage of expansion ; and in Mr. Chamberlain we have just such another statesman as Adam Smith so vehem- ently denounced more than a century ago. COMMERCIAL FEDERATION This change of conditions may not have made the fallacies of Fair Trade less fallacious but it certainly makes them more popular; and there may be a growing minority ready to coquet with protection. The strength of this minority is certainly overestimated in the colonies, perhaps also at home. A momentary irritation at the capture of the English market by certain goods made in Germany or at the invasion by the United States of markets which the English manufacturer has come to regard as his preserve, may lead some men to blas- pheme against Free Trade ; but is not likely to lead them de- liberately to vote against it. They complain of its drawbacks as they complain of the weather. And it certainly remains true that the party which proposes to lay a tax on the peo- ples bread whether to aid the colonies or to benefit the land- owner has an uphill fight to make with little prospect of vic- tory at the end. The situation would invite the "picture poli- tics" of the great and the little loaf and a cartoon has ere now decided the direction of English financial policy. The change of sentiment, however far it might lead the English electorate, is fortunate in one way at least. It has rendered possible an unprejudiced discussion of the whole question of commercial federation ; and has convinced the colonies that England's adherence to Free Trade is not a matter of abstract or book principle, but a matter of financial and industrial expediency, which, when you come to think of it, is the only intelligible principle in tariff legislation. The colonies could understand why England's conception of her commercial and industrial interests might stand in the way of federation ; but the appeal to a book principle which they neither understand nor appreciate served only to irritate. There have been many misconceptions of what free trade is, but the strangest of all is, that a pis allcr policy like Free Trade should be regarded as a sacred principle for which men and nations should be prepared to testify. What Eng- 74 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. lish statesmen object to is dicussing annually a question which had better be settled wrongly than annually unsettled. They think that the burden of the proof lies on those who would disturb the status quo and they are not ready to take every random expression of discontent as a proof that a policy, justified by half a centur>-'s expression, should be re- versed. In commercial federation we may or may not have a reason for disturbing the status quo and many Free Traders have expressed their opinion that an intensive is preferable to an extensive cultivation of Free Trade. The important point, however, is that commercial federation seems, to a large and a growing section of the English electorate, to be a end great enough and worthy enough to lead to a partial reconsidera- tion of a pis allcr policy. A more important influence producing this change of Eng- lish sentiment was the Canadian preferential tariff of 1897. The revi\'al of mercantile ideas is after all not of much posi- tive importance for the development of a sound colonial policy. For it is only by confusion of thought that the vic- tims of mercantilism imagine they are in favour of colonial development. Mercantilism wrought its perfect work on the colonies in the i8th century and would go as far again in the same direction as it dared. But the Canadian preferential tariff appealed to a more influential section of the nation. It influenced those who were adherents of a policy which had led to the development of the colonies in the past but now was in danger of becoming an obstacle to their further de- velopment. The majority of the people of the United King- dom were in favour of granting the colonies the most abso- lute freedom to manage their own affairs, but the same ma- jority suspected that the colonies had designs on the freedom of the mother country. The value of the Canadian preferen- tial tariff consisted not in the amount of the preference given, for, as the event has shown, the volume of British exports to COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. Canada has not materially increased ; but in the conviction which the manner of giving inspired in the minds of the peo- ple in the mother country. The English public had acquies- ced in colonial protective tariffs which treated English goods as badly as the goods produced by foreign nations while at the worst England's Free Trade tariff only treated foreigners as well as it treated the colonists ; but it took all Sir Charles Tupper's eloquence, during many years of his resi- dence in England, to remove the false impression that Canada in fact, if not in name, discriminated against English goods in favour of the products of the United States ; and to all his charming in the direction of a differential duty on foreign grain they turned an absolutely deaf ear. This to their minds was simply another colonial raid on the imperial pocket. They were not prepared to make a profound change in their trade policy to secure the possibility of some trifling change being made in colonial tariffs. In spite of suggestions and appeals, they were not by any means so ready as many colonists thought they should have been, considering their imperial responsibilities, to enter into negotiations for a settlement of this problem of commercial relations. As a matter of fact they were tolerably well content with things as they were, and saw no reason why they should court change to suit those who were discontented. The Canadian preferential tariff had the effect of changing all this. It abandoned the colonial attitude of waiting for England to make the first move. It was not a proposal for negotiations but a definite concession with which there was coupled no sinister demand for a quid pro quo. To many Canadians it seemed then, and seems still, to have been a grand mistake not to make the concession the basis of nego- tiations, and there have not been wanting those who declare that Sir Wilfred Laurier was false to the interests of Canada when he failed to demand a reciprocal concession and still 76 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. more when he later repudiated the idea of making such a i.Ie- mand. This feeling is not confined to his poUtical and out- witted opponents. Many of his supporters who are in party bound to defend his poUcy in pubUc, do not hesitate to ex- press in private their regret that their leader failed to take ad- vantage of his undoubted opportunicies. It seemed so na- tural to strike while the iron of British prejudice was at the white heat of the Jubilee year, and reap the full advantage of the sentiment which the Canadian offer evoked. He had placed himself on record as being in favour of preferential treatment in the English market and it seemed the very refine- ment of punctiliousness not to ask and receive at such a time what he, and every Canadian, wanted, and not an English- man of them all would at that time have refused to grant. Lewd politicians of the baser sort have suggested that it was the prospect of the Cobden Club medal that made him thus betray the interests of Canada ! Yet it should not be difificult to see, except for the most pre- judiced of his opponents, that he did not betray the interests of Canada unless it can be shown that the interests of the Empire and the interests of Canada are opposed to each other. He may in that case have been false to the interests of Canada but he was true to the interests of the Empire. A reciprocal concession might have been made in the haste of sentiment to be repented of in the leisure of experience. Sir Wilfred Laurier showed good taste as well as good states- manship in refusing to take advantage of a Jubilee enthu- siasm. He very wisely consented to wait England's own time. To have rushed matters then would have been detrimental to the interests of the Empire. It would have created within a few months a party in English politics hostile to the colonies, which is the very last thing an imperially minded statesman would desire to create. Practically by his attitude he said : Here is our concession. We leave it to your good sense and COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 77 discretion what return you sliall make for it. We give freely and we ask nothing. We have received freel\- from you in the past. This is the beginning of the return which the eldest daughter of the En^pire makes. You know our desires and our aspirations but take your own time and manner. Nothing from an imperial point of view could have been more fortunate than such a course. It disarmed suspicion. It converted the English by platoons and battalions to the idea of Commercial Federation. It gave Canada a position in the councils of the Empire which nothing else could have done. It may have delayed the satisfaction of Canadian de- sires but it made the achievement of the purpose more secure in the end. There was also one direct and tangible result of the con- cession. The German and Belgian treaties, against which the colonies for nearly half a century had raged in vain, were denounced and the way towards commercial federation of the empire was opened up. The arguments which had seemed so conclusive and so valid reasons for inaction, as recently as 1894, when the Colonial Conference at Ottawa desired the denunciation of these treaties were swept; aside. But the principal result must be sought in the change of English senti- ment of which the denunciation of the treaties was a sign. As yet England has done nothing to match the Canadian conces- sion; and there has even been a disposition to act as if noth- ing more need be done. Some writers seem to see the re- quired quid pro quo in the increased English purchases of Canadian produce. But that is not a sufficient, or any kind of return. From such a point of view the preferential tariff has the reward of a skilfully planned advertisement. But it was not intended as an advertisement and indeed the in- creased purchases of Canadian produce are due to the long continued and well calculated advertising which the Canadian agricultural department and the High Commissioners' staff 78 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. have carried on for years. The preferential tariff was a con- tribution to Imperial unity, and those who see in increased sentimental purchases an adequate return for the Canadian concession have little knowledge of what the colonies hope. So far indeed no other concession than this has been made ; but it stands with English honour that some adequate return should be made. There shouj.d be no doubt of what the colonies desire. Three years have passed without a sign and many are grow- ing impatient. But there has been no abatement of the de- sire. No Canadian would dare to say he did not desire a preference in the English market and no one is likely to say it. The only difference is that many are tired waiting for England's own time, while others still have confidence, or say they have confidence, that the mother country will sooner or later see her way clear to make the necessary concession. Should England make no effort to carry out her side of the implied obligation there would be great disappointment in Canada and the event would be fatal to the prestige of the party which did not exact terms when it might have exacted them without difficulty. The Conservative party in Canada oscillates in this matter between a sneer at a fraudulent con- cession which does not mean increased British imports and a denunciation of the Liberal party as traitors to the interests of Canada — positions which are hardly consistent with each other, unless it be taken for granted that a fraudulent conces- sion should have been made the basis of a demand for a real preference in the British market. But it is firm on this point that a concession is due from the English people ; and the Liberal party which still professes confidence in Enghsh sense of honour is equally positive and convinced that in time the proper return will be made. The action of the mother country in this matter is not merely a Canadian question. It is one in which all the colo COMMERCIAL FEDERATION nies are interested. While no one of them would care to adopt the abandoned position and try to extort a concession in return for a concession, the fact that England had made no return and was prepared to make none would have a large influence on their course of action. Increased purchases will not be regarded by any colony as England's equivalent. Nor will it do to point to England's expenditure on commerce and defence of which the colonies have the benefit. Gratitude, in politics at least, is a sense of favours to come ; and in any case the question of defence stands by itself and is a problem for which, as the events of last, year showed, a solution is being found. The inaction of the mother countr}- is fortunately not due to any lack of appreciation of the preference offered. Criti- cism on that score has been confined to quarters from which criticism can come without a breach of good taste. It is per- fectly open for Canadians to point out that the concession has not been followed by any tangible results for British trade. There has been no proportional increase of imports into Canada from Great Britain; and Canada has largely in- creased her purchases from the United States and even from Germany. This is fair enough criticism, but those who make should remember that the quid pro quo is still to be obtained, and is not likely to be so substantial as it would be, had the impression not been created that the preference, if not frau- dulent, is more in name than in fact. The effects on trade are what might have been expected and an anonymous letter writer to the New York Sun in June 1897 pointed out that the so called preference would not materially affect American trade with Canada. Great Britain and the United States are as Sir Charles Tupper used to show, in no real sense com- petitors for the Canadian market. The bulk of what Canada buys from the United States she could not buy from Great Britain; and the increased imports from the United States 80 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. under a tariff which gives a preference to Great Britain are due to the revival of industrial activity in Canada. The real competitor of Great Britain in the Canadian market is Canada herself. Textiles form more than half of the Cana- dian imports from Great Britain ; and except in cottons the quantity of textiles imported from the United States are neg- ligeable quantities. But the output of Canadian mills far exceeds the imports of textiles from Great Britain. In 1891 the output was nearly 17 millions of dollars and the imports from Great Britain in the same year (and since then there has been a marked decrease) amounted ton millions only. The preference to English goods was really little more than a slight diminution of the protection given the Canadian manu- facturer against his English competitor. And this twenty-five per cent, reduction was not a clear reduction. The tariff rate was lirst of all raised ; and though the net result was a reduc- tion it was not a reduction of twenty-five per cent. The rate on printed cottons was raised from thirty tO' thirty-five per cent, before the 'preference' came into play. The tariff gave the full twenty five per cent, reduction as against Germany and the United States whence there was no serious competi- tion ; but the net result was a reduction of 3.75 per cent, in the preference which the Canadian manufacturer had' en- joyed.^ In fact the position of the English manufacturer in the Canadian market was not materially improved ; and in- creased imports were not to be expected, if the inevitable de- velopment of manufacturing in Canada had been taken into account. This aspect of the preferential tariff may be confidently commended to the consideration of those English dreamers who look for an Imperial Customs Union on a free trade basis. Protectionist sentiment in Canada was so strong that even a Government, elected from a free trade platform, and 1 Hansard (Canada) Ap. 22nd, 1897, pp. 1197 et seq. COMMERCIAL FEDERATIOX. SI in the enthusiasm of the Jubilee year, found itself compelled, in the act of conceding a 25 per cent, preference, or more properly a 7^-^ per cent, reduction of the protection duty, to take back with one hand half of the gift proffered with the other. But the significance of the preferential tariff does not fie- pend on the exact amount of the increase of Canadian im- ports from the mother country, and there has been noi disposi- tion to look at the question from this narrow point of view. The act was of cardinal importance in the history of colonial policy because of its influence of English opinion ; and makes the development of preferential relations within the Empire inevitable because it has opened the way for free and unpre- judiced discussion of the problem. And the problem is of such complexity and involves interests so diverse and so im- mense that the fuller and freer the discussion the better. Discussion of the problem has hitherto been too much at random and without an adequate recognition of the difficul- ties and of the limitations which these difficulties impose. The publication of Sir Rawson Rawson's Synopsis of the Tariffs and Trade of the British Empire might have been ex- pected to dispose of some of the glittering generalities which have bewildered the mind. It ought to have led to a recog- nition of the fact that an Imperial Customs Union is, in the strict sense of the word, an impossibility for the British Em- pire. The German Zollverein had a great influence in creat- ing the German Empire; but the units of the British Empire are not in the same position as the constituent states of the German Zollverein. The German principalities were bound together by common economic interests and many of them were shut out from the sea. The interests of the various units of the British Empire are as diverse as their situations ; and the radical differences in their tariffs are the outcome of the striking economic differences between the units. There 82 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. mav be more harmony of interest than the tariffs would lead us to conclude, and as some writers have endeavoured to show ; but it must be remembered that for all practical pur- poses the interests of the colonies must be allowed to be what the colonists think they are ; and their tariffs are the best in- dications of where they think their interest Ues. The British Empire may come in the course of time to have a common tariff but it will come to this happy consummation as the re suit of its immemorial policy of groping from precedent to precedent and not by the adoption of a logical and elaborate plan of consolidation. '^ We may lay it down as a cardinal version of colonial policy that no portion of the Empire should be ex- pected to sacrifice what it conceives to be its economic in- terests to promote the good of the rest. We have in the his- tory of colonial policy too many disastrous instances of the effects of the opposite policy. Each unit of the Empire will jealously maintain its right to direct its own economic policy; and it would only lead to misunderstanding and the straining of relations to invade the undoubted right of each to guard its own interests in its own way. We may further lay it down as a rule in the discussion of the question of commercial federa- tion that, in view of this maxim of colonial policy, all pro- posals should follow the lines of least resistance, which in the present instance means that none should be put forward which calls for the abandonment of the traditional policy of any unit of the Empire except on its own initiation. Practically all the proposals which have been made can be i"A few enthusiasts may have dreamed of or longed for a common British tariff. But they could have had but little knowledge of the difficulties which render such an agreement impossible while the present system of taxation exists throughout the Empire; and the majority of those who desire a closer commercial union and believe it to be within the range of practical politics have a very indistinct knowledge of the interests with which they have to deal and of the obstacles they would have to encounter in comings to any adjustment which would be acceptable to the many members of Empire."— /Jawion.- Synopsis etc., page S- COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 83 reduced to one or other of two types — those which call for Free Trade within the Empire, leaving the further question of protection against outsiders in the obscurity of the back- ground — and those which insist on discrimination within the empire in favour of its own members and against all outsiders, while to the suggestion of free trade within the Empire a negative, or at any rate no positive, answer is given. Both of these proposals offend against the cardinal maxim of colonial policy; and both of them, with singular futility, have sought the lines of greatest resistance. The first of the proposed solutions is a purely artificial scheme which has been developed not to meet a demand but to overcome the objection which the British public seemed to have to the alternative proposal. There is no need to con- sider the further question whether it would be possible to ob- tain the consent of the Empire, and in particular of the pre- dominant partner, to a scheme which involved protection, however slight against the outside world. For Free Trade within the Empire, the attractive aspect of the proposal is politically and financially impossible. The colonies, judging from the history of their relations to the mother country, and from their temper, would not for a moment consider a pro- posal which removed the control of their tariff to some com- mon imperial Board of Trade. The outstanding feature of our colonial system is the jealousy with which the various members of the Empire guard their own independence of ac- tion. The interests of the different sections are not harmon- ious and each considers its interests best served when it looks after them itself. These interests seem to the colon- ies to demand a protective policy and even if it were possible to overcome the colonial prejudices in favour of protection, and against Free Trade, the obstinate fact remains that, while the financial conditions of the colonies remain the same, pro- tection itself could not be sot rid of. While for constitutional 84 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. or fiscal reasons the colonies are limited to indirect taxation as the source of revenue, their tariffs must be protective. It is a simple question in arithmetic what the average rate of taxation must be; and whether it be 1 6 or 20 per cent, it is alike protective. It is true that the colonies are not expressly hmited to indirect methods of raising revenue. By the 91st section of the British North American Act the Dominion of Canada is given power to raise revenue by either direct or indirect taxation ; and it has raised revenue by direct taxation But practically the Dominion is barred from levying direct taxes. By section 92 of the Act the Provinces are restricted to direct taxation and it would be more or less an invasion of their sphere for the Dominion to levy direct taxes — a fact which is practically recognised. Indirect taxation must be levied largely on imports, and cannot when the volume of im- ports is small help being protective and protective to a very considerable extent. Even the late Lord Farrer recognised that the Free Trade in Canada was a financial impossibility ; and what is true of Canada is more or less true of the other colonies. For many years to come it may safely be said con- siderations of revenue will stand in the way of a purely re- venue tariff. This academic proposal may therefore be ruled out of consideration. It offends against the cardinal maxim of colo- nial policy. The colonies are deliberately protective : it asks them to adopt Free Trade. It requires them to abandon the most fruitful sources of revenue and to surrender that inde- pendence which they so jealously guard. It is not in the line of least resistance for it embodies a policy which, how- ever it might commend itself to the predominant partner, runs counter to the established trade policy of the colonies. The utmost length to which the colonies will go is to place, as Canada has done, imperial trade on a more favourable footing than foreign trade. Even from goods manufactured within COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 85 the Empire the colonies must seek to raise a revenue ;^ and in aJl cases the colonies are likely to insist on retaining con- trol of their own policy. There is nothing academic about the alternative proposal It meets a strong colonial demand. One has to live in the colonies, or be a colonist, to realise how strongly their minds are set on obtaining this object of their desire. Canada, in particular, has been so insistent on this particular scheme as to give rise to the suspicion in some minds that her object is to secure through the agency of Great Britain that protection to agricultural produce which her own tariff can only pretend to yield. However that may be, there can be no question that the demand for preferential treatment in the English market is the strongest factor in colonial politics to-day. The colo- nists are passionately in earnest about this matter, in which they see their greatest possibility of development ; and they unhesitatingly read into Mr. Chamberlain's phrases about the undeveloped resources of the Empire an acknowledgment of the justice of their claims. This proposal requires as its initial step protection in the different markets of the Empire against outsiders. The fur- ther stage is not considered at all ; and if we must consider it, the reasons why Free Trade within the Empire is impossible as the initial step towards federation are equally strong and vaJid against Free Trade as the second or the ultimate step in the same direction. To this proposal also we must apply the tests whether it leaves each unit in the Empire in full con- trol of its own domestic policy and secondly whether it fol- lows the lines of least resistance. iThe Canadian Finance Minister, through the Controller of Customs, claimed that the increase of the duties on printed cottons, etc., with which he prcf.iccd the preferential tariff, was due to the necessity oi raising- a revenue somehow. — Cutiadian Hansard Dfbatrs, iS<)y, page 1 1 ig The Hofmeycr proposal is simply the Can.idian scheme shorn of its concession to Free Trade principle, and complicated by e.ir- marking- the proceeds of the 5 per cent, surtax on goods coming from foreign countries to provide a fund for Imperial defence. 86 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. Technically the proposal meets the first test. It leaves each member of the Empire masters of its own house. Canada has no less a control over her fiscal arrangements since the adoption of a preferential tariff than she had before, and Great Britain would be as well able to manipulate her tariff after granting a five per cent, preference to the colonies as she is at present. The change would come from her own initiation and would involve no interference of the colonies in the domestic affairs of the mother country. The policy involves neither a common treasury nor a common Board of Trade. The example of Canada is conclusive in this respect. Like an Imperial Postal Union an Imperial Customs' Union on these lines implies only concurrent action. But it meets the test O'nly technically. There are other ways of exercising control than by direct interference or physical and legal coercion. The mother country would not be free to abandon the policy after its adoption without evoking protests such as she would be unable to meet ; and compul- sion of a very forcible character might be brought to bear on her to adopt the change. And it is necessary to postulate that the proposal should be accepted freely and unreservedly and at her own initiative. Otherwise it does involve, not directly it is true, but still it does involve, interference. with the inter- nal freedom and independence of one of the partners of the Empire. When we come to apply the second test whether the pro- posal follows the lines of least resistance, the poUcy most completely fails. It would be dogmatic to say that the mother country could not be brought to consider the sug- gestion ; but it is at least true that nothing could be more problematic than the mother country's acceptance of it. It is idle, and worse than idle, for it raises false hopes, to point to the weakening of Free Trade sentiment in the United Kingdom. It is within the limits of human possibility that COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 87 in some constituencies a majority ctnihi he found for pro ion against goods made in Germany and elsewhere ; and in other places a candidate who declared in favour of a re-enactment of the Corn Laws might be victorious. But these two wings of a possible protectionist party cherish contradictory ideals, and would fall out as soon as they came to practical legisla- tion. Moreover the English protectionist is not necessarily an imperialist, and indeed can only through confusion of minved altogether to the advantage not only of colonial credit — and it should be remembered always that the apparently heavy debts of the colonies are, directly or indirectly, to a large extent first-class investments — but also to the advantage of the money market at home. Further the Imperial Government might within limits guar- antee colonial government debts, and thus permit their con- version into 2], 2 per cents. It might even go further and make loans for the construction of great public works like the Canadian Pacilic railway; which the late Mr. W. E. Foster considered a wise policy.^ it might do more than it does to promote emigration, and divert to the self-govern- ing colonies that stream of emigrants which the colonies grudge to see flowing towards the United States. What the colonies need above all is the surplus living capital of the United Kingdom. Without a great influx of population they cannot hope to develop the enormous national resources which they are only beginning to touch. It is true, as I have shown elsewhere, that immigration is a consequence rather than a cause of prosperity.- But in the case of the colonies every element of prosperity and development is present but the population to carry them forward. There might with great advantage to both parties be an imperial and colonial partnership in promoting emigration to the self governing colonies. iProc. Royal Col. Inst.. Vol. XI, pag:e 51. 2 Davidson: Bargaia Theory ot Wages, c. vi. 98 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. These are not heroic measures, but they would secure the end in view. They have the further advantage that they cannot provoke retahation. The preference they give to the colonies will be as real as the preference by discriminating duties. Foreign nations, however, will have no pretext for complaint. They may attempt to meet the competition of our colonial goods in the common market by subsidizing steamers to carry their products ; but they will have to do so at their own expense, and most of them would have to subsidize British vessels for the benevolent purpose of making goods cheaper to the British consumer. This policy would have the effect of cheapening both food and raw materials, and would not reduce the power of the manufacturers in the old country to meet foreign competition. It would, there- fore, be a permanent policy, because not likely to provoke a reaction. The cost would be plain and visible, and the incidence of the burden of the necessary taxation would be determined. The present system of taxation and trade policy would remain untouched. From the colonial point of view the preference in this shape would be more advan- tageous. It would produce no sudden boom. Develop- ment would be rapid but secure, and the goodwill of the English electorate, on which any industrial progress of the colonies that resulted from a preference would depend, would be practically assured ; for the policy being in^ accordance with the principles, the prejudices, and the interest of the predominant partner would meet with her most emphatic approval. The main question, however, is would it be effective? A policy may be good in the abstract, may be practicable for the giver but if it does not secure the desired end it is worthless. The concession is required to meet the colonial demand. Will a reduction in the cost of freights and an improvement of the means of communication be in any sense COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 99 an equivalent to a preferential duty? The colonies want the English market for themselves. Would this proposed concession give it to them. Mr. Colmer proposed a three per cent, preference, and even the most extreme colonial demand is for a five per cent, duty on foreign goods. Can freights be so reduced by means of subsidies so as to give an equivalent preference? To ask the question is sufficient. It is hardly possible to over estimate the inlluence of the cost of transport and the existence of transport facilities in determining the course of trade. German trade is to a large extent due to the subsidies given to German shipping. The cost may be greater than the increment of trade is worth to Germany ; but Germany does not think so. Transport and other trade facilities have given the United Kingdom, as compared with the United States, the trade of South America. In this case, there is no suggestion of a national preference for English goods. The question is one simply of the facilities afforded for transportation. There has been no subsidy to this branch of trade, ostensibly at least for trade purposes. But the trade goes to English harbours in spite of the greater distance which the goods must be carried. The greatest obstacles which the colonies have to face in the competition for the English market is the greater facilities of transportation which some of their rivals enjoy. The disa- bilities under which the colonies suffer on this account are greater than generally imagined. According to a well informed writer, Australia is at a disadvantage as compared with the United States in competing foT the English wheatj market of no less than seven shillings a quarter ; and Canada, which is nearer by a thousand miles, is owing to the better organisation of freight service to United States ports, at a disadvantage of at least two shillings per quarter.^ ' W. J. Harris: The CommerciuL Advantages of Federation : Proc. Royal Colonial Institute, Vol. XIH, pp. 2og-i$i). Mr. Harris, from whose paper the writer 100 COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. This lack of oversea transportation facilities not only han- dicaps the colonies in their competition, but by diverting a portion of their trade to United States ports for shipment, reduces the earning powers of their railways, and renders the splendid system of internal communications which they have built up less efficient. It is a difficult matter to estimate the cost of such a system of subsidies. But it is safe to say that it would pay the mother country to pay the whole of the present cost of freight on her colonial imports rather than to adopt even Mr. Colmer's three per cent. duty. The freight on all colonial goods shipped to the mother country does not exceed fifty million dollars. The average cost of freight on the world's trade is ten per cent, of the imports. The average on British colonial goods is probably higher, perhaps 15 per cent. The difference between the values exported and the values imported is roughly speaking due to the cost of trans- portation. The self governing colonies of New South Wales, New Zealand and Canada, exported goods (1896) to the value of 144 million dollars, while England imports from them goods to the value of 164 million dollars, a difference of about 14 per cent. The imports from aU the self governing colonies into the United Kingdom (annual average 1892-96) amounted to ;^5o,47 7,000, of which, at the above rate, 14 per cent., or about ^7 millions was due to the cost of transportation. If we include the exports from the United Kingdom to these self governing colonists, the value of the derived the first suggestion of the proposal outlined above of commercial federation by means of cheaper freights, does not draw the obvious conclusion that shipping subsidies provide the proper solution. He seems to favour, as one of his critics put it, "a protectionist duty on wheat and meat, with a differentiated scale according to the geographical distances from which they come " ; although at one place he approaches the proper solution when he says (p. 220) that " the general feeling of most Englishmen would be rather to give our colonists equal advantages with foreigners, than to punish foreigners for their sakes": here he approaches very nearly to the policy which follows the line of least resistance. COMMERCIAL FEDERATION. 101 total trade for the above period was ^84,709,000; on which some £^i i millions was paid in freight. This is practically the amount of the extra taxation which the English consumer at the least would pay under Mr. Cohner's three per cent, tax on four articles alone. The effect on colonial trade would be the same, whether a preferential duty of five p>er cent, were imposed or a reduction; of one third could be made in the cost of transportation. The freight charges we found amounted to 14 per cent. A reduction of one third would give a five per cent, preference. But the cost to England would be between 3 and 4 millions sterling, only fifteen or twenty million dollars. This would not benefit colonial export trade alone. It would benefit equally her own export trade, and a part at least of the cost would come back in the shape of increased trade. No outlay which the British Government could make would be productive of better results ; and these results could be secured without any departure from established policy. This suggestion is in accordance with the principles laid down. It involves no interference with the internal freedom of any member of the Empire, and a concession in this form would create no heartburnings at home, because it would run counter to no principle or interest. It would, moreover, secure the desired result, even more fully than the direct preference which the colonies demand. But the policy would need to be explicitly, almost ostentatiously, adopted. Other- wise the colonies might not recognize that a preference in this shape was being given, and might still clamour for a preferential duty. The admission of colonial storks as trust investments was a concession of some importance ; but with the exception of some Canadian Liberals, who are looking for a jusrification of the method of their preferential tariff, there were few who recognized its importance. ( 102 ) CHAPTER IV. CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. FEW people, at home or in the colonies, recognise the profound change which has come over colonial senti- ment regarding the Empire. To-day, in Canada, we are all more demonstratively loyal than the inhabitants of the mother country, and are inclined to regard them with a certain pity and scorn on that account. Ten years since our ideas were very different. But the change has been so profound that, recent though it is, it is difficult to find anyone to admit that there has been any change. We are inclined toi think that we always were as enthusiastic imperialists as we are to day. Yet as a matter of fact there has been a profound change. One short decade ago we were so far from being imperialists that there was an active annexation party in our midst. One of our great political parties ran an election on the issue of un- restricted reciprocity, and many of its most influential me:"^- bers were in favour of commercial union with the United States. And many who were then as strongly prejudiced against the republic to the South, as we all are to-day, were in favour of national independence. " Canada First " and " Canada for the Canadians " were popular maxims. If there were little Englanders at home in those days, Canada was full of little Canadians who, however loyal they may have been, were certainly not imperialist in their sentiments. Ten years ago one would not have been very much in error who, judging not of the deep underlying instincts of the race, but of the common expressions of opinion, declared that Canada at least, among the colonies, was not conspicuously fervent in her appreciation of the glories of the British Empire. An CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 103 intelligent and imperial observer like Mr. Greenwood actually declared in those days that French Canada would be the last refuge of Canadian loyalty — a remark which in view of recent events shows either how completely we have changed or how far astray with the rest of us Mr. Greenwood could go. It is Canadian sentiment that has changed ; and the evidence that there has been an overwhelming change would be found by comparing the files of almost, any journal in Canada, for 1890. say with its files to-day. Quotations are certainly no criterion. They might be the casual expressions of indi\adual opinion, and by judicious selection it might be possible to quote as much on the one side as on the other. There were imperialist expressions then as there are little Canadian expressions to-dav. But La Fatrie does not make Canada anti-imperialist to-day ; and the waving of the old flag does not prove Canada imperialist then. We must judge of the temper of a people by many signs and indications : and ten years ago Canada seemed to be entering on a course which made for disruption rather than for consolidation. The Imperial Federation movement was, as Mr. Goldwin Smith pointed, out, a reactionary movement in Canada : and the idea was even shorter lived in the colonies than it was at home. The London Speaker (Ap. 4th, 1891') seems ver\- fairly to have grasped the situation then. "The Canadian Liberals," it said, "have definitely declared for Commercial Union with the States, and are no longer in a position tO' entertain commercial union with the mother country. And as for the Conservatives, the backbone of the party consists of manufacturers who would be ruined by the competition of English goods." Let us speak of something else, it con- temptuously concluded ; and in these ten years we have been talking of nothing else. Both parties have adopted com.mer- cial union as their programme — but not commercial union with the United States ; and as then the Speaker could 1 104 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. see little difference between them in their practical opposi- tion, so now we can see little difference between them in their practical acceptance of the idea thus summarily dismissed. The change towards the subject of commercial union is typical of the change towards the imperial idea. It may seem to contradict this idea that the Conservative party under the astute leadership of Sir John Macdonald carried the general elections in 1891 by waving the old flag and draping the nakedness of their economic platform in its sacred folds ; and it is true that there was a deep under- lying attachment to the Empire which he was quick to see and to make use of. But even then the expressions of opinion seemed to point in another direction. Had the election come three weeks earlier the Liberals would have been elected and unrestricted reciprocity established. Had the elections come three weeks later the defeat of the Liberals would have been even more crushing. The appeals to the sentiment of loyalty were met with jeers at first ; and it is possible that many who were disinclined to seek disruption openly were themselves but lukewarm in their sympathies. Certainly many who by nature and by training were disposed to be imperialists were not inclined to commit themselves. The contemptuous in- difference of the little Englanders on the one hand, and the arrogance of the great Englanders of the Imperial Federation League on the other hand, were alike disheartening. The break up of that body was one of the most fortunate things possible for the Empire. The loyalty that was demanded from the colonies was loyalty to England, not loyalty to the Empire; and the colonials rather resented the idea that, man for man, the electors of England were their political superiors. One must judge of a matter like this by one's own im- pressions ; and an adult immigrant, interested in politics and in the trend of public opinion, has an opportunity of judging which is given neither to the native born nor to the outsider. CANADA AXD THE EMPIRE. 105 In 1892, when I came to Canada, one could still hear echoes, not very faint either, of the reciprocity controversy ; and Canada seemed to be considering her future destiny. I remember writing home to an English student of politics that there were two parties in Canada, roughly distinguishable as the American party and a professedly English but really in- dependent party. The distinction was not of much value ; but in the condition of public opinion in Canada then it was an excusable mistake. A newcomer could hardly appreciate the strength of a sentiment which found no expression ; and the opinions which were expressed seemed to point away from imperialism. There was in the early nineties a large section of the Canadian public which agreed more or less with Mr. Goldwin Smith in regarding Canada as an American power. No one to-day is ever accused of being an annexa- tionist. But in those days Goldwin Smith was still a power in the land and his views and opinions were regarded as of sufficient importance to require refutation and denunciation. We denounce those ideas only which we have not risen far enough above to try to understand ; and Canada as a whole, tried by this test, seemed to recognise that she was face to face with the problem of her destiny. To-day the question has been so far settled that no man refers either in praise or blame to Goldwin Smith's ideals. But in 1892 it was neces- sary to refer to them in some way because they were then attractive ideals.^ , It would be hard in these times to get any Canadian to consider these ideals. To-day they are exploded, discredited and rejected ideals ; but they had in them at that time the il have before me, as I write, a copy of a book called the " Haniibook of Reciprocity." It was part ot my business to make myself as quickly as might be familiar with Canadian problems, and this was the first book I bous^ht in Canada. The careful way in which I find the book is annotated, with remarks queried here and statements underlined there, shows me how important I thought the question to be in 1892. The book has a purely antiquarian v,->lue to-day. H 106 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. attraction which the phrase manifest destiny always has. Yet with it all and the "Canada First" movement, there was a spirit in man which, though it might not reveal itself on all occasions or to all observers, yet did open up new possi- bilities. It was this underlying loyalty which in the end con- founded all theories and converted the " Canada First " into a " Canada first in the Empire " movement. From the van- tage ground of experience we can see now that this loyalty was the dominant factor in the situation. But it was not so easy to see it then. For it was not perhaps the creed of the politically intelligent ; it certainly was not the creed of the politically outspoken. But it was the creed of the dumb mass of the people and possibly underlay the transient ideals of the others. At any rate it was the sentiment which was to pre- vail, though few observers were able to read the signs of the times. Even in the early nineties the old cries were losing their meaning ; and gradually, one knows not how, gradually but completely and irrevocably, the nation swung round from its " manifest destiny " to its manifest duty. The Jubilee year marked the perfect triumph of the Imperial idea ; and in that year the most practical politicians in the world perhaps, re- cognised that the change was complete. The Canadian Liberal party set the seal to the accomplished fact. To-day our old attitude is unintelligible and men even deny that it ever was taken. We no longer complain that we are patronised and that recognition is denied our undoubted merits. We ask no recognition for there are none to recog- nise us. We are part of the Empire, and when Mr. Tarte talks, as he does to-day, about the South African trouble being a purely English question, Canadians, or some of them, in spite of their indignation, have some of the pitying toleration for him that one has for an anachronism. He stands where we, many of us, stood ten years ago, and may, if we have CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 107 patience and he has intelligence, come to share in the ardent imperialism of his fellow citizens. The causes of this triumph of imperial sentiment over poli- tical theories may be symbolised in the two names of Grover Cleveland and Rudyard Kipling. President Cleveland was not alone responsible for that growth of anti-American senti- ment which is one of the most distinctive political factors in Canadian life to-day ; nor did Rudyard Kipling alone create the imperial sentiment of the colonies. But each served to give form to chaotic impressions. The Venezuelan message was in fact the burial service of the American idea in Canada. It has been dead for some time. It was now forgotten. Kipling brought the colonists to self consciousness and made them realise clearly for the first time what in a dim way they had long felt, viz., that there was no question of loyalty before them but one of simple self respect. As Edward I. was the hammer of the Scots, so Grover Cleveland proved to be the hammer of the Canadians. It is easy to say now that there was no possibility of war over the Venezuelan affair and that the whole excitement was ridicu- lous. But we did not think so then ; and it is doubtful whether any Canadian thinks so yet. At all events we be- lieved that war was inevitable then and we knew that on us in Canada the first and last and awful brunt of war would fall. But there was not one moment's hesitation. A quiver ran down the line and Canadians, one and all, stood ready. It did one good and made one proud of the breed that there should be no question in the face of such an emergency. For- gotten were the old ideas that our interests were on the American continent. It was a quarrel, as one might have said, with which Canada had nothing to do; but we had un- consciously made our choice before the crisis, and when it came we stood proudly forth as British subjects ready to do or to suffer, and we knew that the sufifering at least would be 108 CA^^ADA AND THE EMPIRE. ours. The possession of a few square miles of malarial swamp, the allegiance of a few tribes of wandering Indians were perhaps not questions on which to hazard our lives and homes ; but we made it so and announced then so that the world, and we ourselves, could hear it that the Empire's; quarrels were, for ever and always, Canada's quarrels. It has generally been assumed that the hammer of the Scots made a nation out of the discordant elements which inhabited the northern half of the island. But historically, as well as on a priori grounds, one can pronounce such a view unfounded. Had Scotland been so disorganised as this view assumes, its manifest destiny, as it appeared to the masterful Edward I., would have been accomplished ; and Scotland merged to its manifest economic advantage in the larger life of the English people. On the contrary, as Mr. Hume Brown has pointed out, Scotland was not at the War of Indep>en- dence a country barely emerged from barbarism with the elements of its population at strife and variance. " With the exception of England, indeed, no country in Christendom had in the same degree (as Scotland) filled out its limits and welded its people .... the War of Independence was to prove that a Scottish nation had really been formed in the long process in which the first step had been taken by Kenneth MacAlpin."^ "It has constantly been said that through their long struggle with England, the Scots were fashioned into national unity : it would be more correct to say that had Scotland not been a nation before, it must in- e\dtably have gone to pieces, in the long ordeal through which it had passed."" History is past politics and it would be just as absurd for us to say to-day that Grover Cleveland found Canada tremb- ling on the verge of dissolving her imperial connection ; and 1 History of Scotland, Vol. I, pp. 129-130. i- ^Ibid, pp. 179-180. CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. V 9 by one rash threat changed the current of American history as Edward I. is popularly supposed to have altered the course of British history. For if Scotland had, as Mr. Hume Brown puts it, her dynasty of centuries standing, her national council, her national church, and her national law, Canada, in like manner, had her British tradition which was never so dear as when threatened by the rude bluster of a shirt sleeves' dip- lomat. Scotland had been gradually schooled by many un- successful attempts on the part of England to assert a supre- macy, to be ready to resent the effort to achieve by force what guile had failed to accompUsh. And Canada had been, or what comes to the same thing, conceived herself to have been, the victim of a long series of similar attempts to coerce her. The methods were, of course, the methods of the nine- teenth century. The expedients of the feudal system could not be used but the weapons of trade warfare were used with the same effect of irritating the northern people. Canada was, and is still, economically dependent on the United States ; and the tariff mongers of the Republic had en- deavoured in many ways to assert an economic suzerainty. And as there were those who, in the perplexed state of Scottish affairs following the death of Alexander III., thought, and from a cosmopolitan standpoint perhaps thought cor- rectly, that it was a consummation devoutly to be wished for that the old feuds of the two kingdoms should be ended by the union of the two nations, so in Canada there had been many who thought that economically, perhaps also politically, it was desirable that Canada should be absorbed in the larger political power to the south. One can almost hear the Scot- tish Goldwin Smiths declaring that there was not room in the island for the development of two English speaking nations, that the northern kingdom had a great race question to solve and the Anglo-Saxon element in the northern king- dom needed all the help it could obtain from association with 110 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. their English brethren to the south, that trade naturally fol- lowed the lines of longitude and that economic and commer- cial considerations were too important to be set aside in favour of mere sentiment.^ But just as the early sympathisers with our supposititious Scottish Goldwin Smith were forced by stress of events finally to declare themselves and to break with England, so the Canadian sympathisers with the American idea have been converted by the persistent commercial persecution on the part of United States politicians, and forced to abandon their annexation or reciprocity platform. And just as Robert Bruce through constant hardship and relentless pursuit, and later through the inspiration of success, gradually rose from the position of a not over scrupulous adventurer seeking a throne , to become the patriot king and almost the patron saint of an adoring people, so Laurier and the Canadian Liberal party, after many rebuffs at Washington, came finally in the exalted sentiment of a Jubilee year to make the greatest contribution of this generation to the realisation of the Imperial idea.^ 'These Scottish Goldwin Smiths practised more than they preached; but the comment has come later. From Anderson's Origin of Commerce we may take the following (Vol. III. page 26): "And great pity it truly may be said to be, that two nations sprung from the same original stock, speaking the same language, essentially possessing the same religion, and whom Nature seems to have designed for one by being separated by the great ocean from the rest of mankind, should not have sooner pursued their true and evident mutual interests, and thereby have much sooner increased in we:ilth. security and power. If upon the death of Alexander the Third and of his grancicliild. stiied The Maid ol Norway, Scotland had voluntarily united itself to England near five hundred years ago, how much more populous, powerful and rich would both parts ot the island have probably been at this time." ■lit has been pointed out to me that the historical view of the character of Robert the Bruce which looks at him as having with success become a good man as well as a great man, which he alwaj s was, is not understood ; and that the suggested ana'.ogy between Laurier and the Scottish king can only appear ridiculous. Between the popular conception of Bruce and the actual Laurier one could make no com- parison ; but between the actual Bruce, as his character is drawn by Mr. Hume Brown, for instance, and the actual Laurier, there is a kind of antithetic parallelism. Bruce was great and became a good king. Laurier has always deserved his reputa- tion for "amiability," and he has certainly made his name historical with the I'rcferential Tariff of 1899. CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. Ill It has been said that one can prove anything by analogy ; but when nothing is to be proved it may be allowable to follow out the analogy which suggests itself between Canada in the latter half of the nineteenth century and Scotland in the latter part of the seventeenth. The economic relations between Canada and the United States are of much the same character as those between Scotland and England in the seventeenth century. Scotland made the same demand for commercial intercourse with England as Canada has sought so often and in vain from the United States. The short ex- perience of free trade which Scotland had during the Com- monwealth period may be compared with Canada's golden age of Reciprocity. The reciprocity was in both cases mutually beneficial, but particularly so to> the northern party ; and in both cases, after a short continuance, it was brought to a sudden conclusion. In Scotland underlying the ecclesias- tical troubles there was a strong desire for a renewal of this free trade with England ; and in the event this desire proved the strongest argument for the Union of Parliaments. In England, however, there was the same commercial jealousy of the gains which Scotland made, or was likely to make, as the United States, with less excuse in the temper of the times, has shown towards Canada. English jealousy wrecked the Scottish Darien scheme as United States jealousy has repeatedly endeavoured as in Alaska and the Behring Sea to check the development of Canadian enterprise. The analogy is singularly complete. Canada, like Scotland, was the poorer northern neighbour, and was economically tributary to the Southron. Canada, like Scotland, found a career for her more energetic sons in the wealthier and more developed country to the south. There was, moreover, the same jealousy of Scottish immigration on the part of England as the United States has, officially at least, shown towards Canadian inunigration. Yet, in the one case as in the other, 112 CANADA AXD THE EMPIRE. the immigration was an economic necessity to the receiving country. Scotland gave cheap labour and brains to England and Canada has paid the same tribute to her wealthier neigh- bour. At one point the analogy breaks down and breaks down, decisively. Scotland and England became parts of one poli- tical unit; while Canada and the United States remain and will remain separate. England desired political union more than the maintenance of commercial monopoly and Scotlaad valued access to the English market at home and in tie colonies more than the retention of a barren political inde- pendence. Both played their strongest card. Scotland by the Act of Security in 1703 refused to ratify the Act of Setde- ment ; and declared that the admitted successor to the Crown of England was ipso facto excluded from the choice of the people of Scotland ; while England in retaliation made the commercial exclusion of Scotland more rigorous than ever. The Union of Parliaments then became inevitable. But had Scotland's ancient ally of France been to her what Canada's ancient ally was to her, the issue might have been different. The ancient alliance was dictated by a common hate and common necessities ; but gradually, even in the time of Queen Mary, the spread of Reformation principles in Scodand brought the old alliance into disrepute. There was neither common race nor common traditions between Scot- land and France. There was indeed for Scots the right of citizenship in France, but religious differences had made that a dead letter. France, moreover, did not offer to Scotland such a commercial alternative, as England did to Canada when her suits were rejected by the United States. In short, if France could have been to Scotland what the mother countr}' has been to Canada the issue might have been different, and England have remained a second rate power. Canada's ancient ally was all that France failed to be to Scotland in the crisis of her fortimes ; and the ancient CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 113 alliance in this case, backed up as it was by Southron in- solence, proved too much for manifest destiny.^ The Venezuelan message did much to give form and shape to the vague irritation which a generation of rebuffs had created. As time had gone on, the fruitless joumeyings to Washington provoked not regret at the failure but irritation at the snubs received ; and Canada was entering on her maturity and beginning to feel that she couid stand alone. The Venezuelan message was the last straw. It revealed that as a nation we had made up our minds and were ready to meet contempt with contempt and arms with arms. Those amiable enthusiasts who preach at home in the islands that Canada's duty to the Empire is to bring the Anglo-Saxon peoples more closely together must be singularly ignorant of the real Canadian sentiment towards the United States. There are exceptions of course — and in the interests of in- ternational amity it is v.-ell that there are exceptions — but the tone of the average Canadian towards the United States is in the old fashion of Scottish sentiment towards the "auld enemy."' But the open threat in the Venezuelan message could not alone have produced the effect it did had there not for years been growing up in Canada a new consciousness of the place which a colony holds in the Empire. Many forces have con- tributed to this development, but the influence of the writings of Rudyard Kipling has been perhaps the strongest of these forces. I do not know the full measure of Kipling's popu- larity in the Empire, but if Canada may be taken as a stan- dard it must be tremendous. Among us he speaks as a iThe analogy suggests one curious reflection. Scotland, like Canada, »as formed out of two peoples In the long strutrgle the Celt went under; but in these latter days has enslaved his conquerors. It Is the fashion for even pure Saxon families in Scotland to trace relationship to mythical Highland clans. Will the s.ime phenomenon appear in Canada ? Will the pride of descent from the Loyalist give place to a desire to prove some seigneur or even some habitant to be one's ancestor ? Further, will Sir Wilfred Laurier become the rallying point of Canadian Roman- ticism ? There were during the last few years indications of a growing Laurier mythus, but recent events have probably dispelled these romantic notions. ]W4''^'Wi^f^W' ■ ' '^^^^^^'^"'^^ '^?!!^7'WW^- 114 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. prophet ; and the most random utterance of his pen is rap- turously and reverently received, and at once becomes an in- evitable rule of conduct. His merits as a writer do not enter into the question, though, as a matter of fact, we believe that he has no equal. There are few Kipling Clubs in Canada because there is no one to exclude. We have heard perhaps enough of Kipling as the Empire builder; and while he has made us all imperialists it was not as an Empire builder that he won our love. To the Eng- lishman he may be the poet of the forward movement ; to the colonist he is above all the poet of the Native Bom, the man who first revealed to us the full glory of our imperial heritage. We had always known the British tradition. England's his- tory was our history and her troubles our troubles. But we stood in the outer court of the Temple, not aliens indeed, but still outsiders ; and there was no one to tell us that we had the right of entry. We were not faithless ; but we were despondent and did not bear ourselves with confidence. We protested our loyalty toO' much and yet regarded the Empire as England's, not as ours. Canada was a dependency, a great self-governing colony if you will, but still a dependency ; and much as we disliked to admit the individual superiority of the men of the islands we did bear ourselves as inferiors and allowed ourselves to be patronised. Kipling brought us to self-consciousness and to self-respect. He made us see that all talk about loyalty to the Empire was a mistaken use of terms because it did not express the truth of the situation. He showed us that the Empire was ours and that colonists had in it not the place of a hired servant but that of a younger son who had not wasted his substance in riotous living in a far country. It is as the poet of the native-born that he has done most for the Empire. He has not only brought the colonies to a perfect passion of devotedness : he has also expressed the thoughts they themselves did not know CANADA AXD THE EMPIRE. 115 they cherished. He has, in short, been to the Empire what Burns was to Scotland, the revealer of men to themseh-es. Outsiders have often been puzzled to understand why the Scottish people should make so much more of Burns than of Scott, who was a worthier man, and perhaps also the greater genius. The reason is that in Bums the Scottish people found part expression and that he said for them what thev dared not say for themselves. Scott never revealed to Scots their inmost feelings, and to the end of his days was almost as tongue-tied as themselves. Therefore he has not that love which the name of Bums evokes. And what Burns did for Scotland Rudyard Kipling has done in part for the Native Born, He has revealed to them the worthiness of their position as well as the grandeur of their heritage. He has taught us that the deeds which won the Empdre were not the haxd hand strokes of war only, but those patient and unheroic efforts by which the colonies are slowly building up out of their virgin resources new strong- holds for the race. He has called a new kind of patriotism into existence, which is pride in work done and results accom- plished, because he has shown us that the tiller of the soil, the miner, and the trapper, and the railroad builder with no visions, is each in his way a true empire builder and a work- man who needeth not to be ashamed of what he is doing on its behalf. Some English critics would have us believe that Kipling's vogue will be like the vogue of many another Jingo poet ; and one superior person declares that a single stanza by a certain minor poet called Yeats is worth the whole of Kipling's brutal and bloodthirsty ravings. It may be so. It may be that future generations of Englishmen will appreciate more highly the minor tones of the Celtic fringe than the majors of the Empire ; but till our race has lost its imperial instinct Rudyard Kipling will hold his place. These critics 116 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. have compared him with Campbell, who, except for some imperishable lyrics, is unread and forgotten ; but who that knows the outhers of the Empire would make such, a com- parison. Rule Britannia is still the war song of the Empire; but it did not call a new world of patriotism into existence. It gave expression to a passing sentiment which any cockney snob may feel and feel again. But Kipling has done more than this. He has called into active life the dormant forces and motives of the Empire. He has given form to that which before was without form and void. He has made the colonies aware of their inmost feelings and ideals. He knew the colonies better than the colonists themselves did. The rebuke in the following letter, which appears in Mr. Beckles VVillson's, " The Tenth Island," shows from what Kipling has rescued and raised colonial expression. It appears that certain Newfoundlanders were grieved at the poet's omission of St. John from his " Song of the English," and their remonstrance elicited the following letter : " Indeed I am not unmindful of Newfoundland. Per- haps I may know more about it than you think, and, certainly, no man in his senses ever doubted the loyalty of the senior colony. We may leave that, I think, to the Yankees who seem to take comfort from inventing curious fictions of that nature But we will make a bargain. I will put in a four line verse among the ' Song of the Cities ' if you, on your part, will drop, and influence other people to drop, allusions to the " loyalty " of the " colonies." In the first place, I dislike the word " colonies," and if you look through my verses, you will find I very seldom use it. It is out of date and misleading, besides being provincial. In the second place, there is no need to talk of " loyalty " among white men. That is one of the things we all take for granted — because the Empire is us, we ourselves — and for the white man to explain that he is loyal is about as unnecessary as for CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 117 a respectable woman Lo volunteer the fact that she is chaste." That is the situation in a single sentence. He has ex- pressed what the colonies have long felt and still are feeling. The word " colony " is misleading and provincial ; and there is undying fame for the orator who finds the right word to express the facts as they exist to-day. " The Empire is us, we ourselves," and, therefore, it is needless to protest our loyalty. A dependency may be loyal : colonies, such as Canada and Australia, have long felt that this was not a proper word for them. They use it only in default of a better. The colonist has not yet achieved that serene dignity of imperial ownership which the English of the island exhibit. He still protests too much and exclaims too much. It is doubtful whether many Canadians understood the spirit of Kipling's school story, " The Flag of their Country." Certain passages in it must have struck many as rank blasphemy. From no one but Kipling would it have been received with- out violent protest. For we are still at the stage when we perorate like " Mr. Raymond Martin, M.P.," about the old flag, though, thank God, we no longer use it as a party emblem. The flag is always and everywhere in evidence. It is the ambition of every country school-house to own one, and the schoolmistress organises concerts and " socials " to raise the necessary funds to purchase it. No meeting, public or private, may close without a demonstration of loyalty. Staid sober gatherings rise to their feet and sing with immense enthusiasm the "National Anthem"; and I have heard the venerable Chancellor of a Colonial University solemnly pro- pose at the end of a public lecture on " Railroad Nationalisa- tion," that the audience join in singing " God Save the Queen." Even the Women's Christian Temperance Union is infected with the same enthusiasm. Our local branch opened its annual meeting with prayer, reading of the Scriptures, and the singing of the music-hall " Soldiers of the Queen !" This 118 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. new-found expression is sometimes extravagant and intolerant, and we have still to learn that there may be a legitimate diflference of opinion regarding the action or inaction of the Imperial Government. But this kind of exuberance will pass away and the colonists will gradually come to see that they are no more loyal than the English of the island because they talk more about it. The important thing is that they are coming to take their loyalty for granted. They are coming to take the loyalty of their political opponents even for granted. During the excite- ment raised by the curious inaction of the Canadian Liberal administration regarding the Canadian contingent for the Transvaal no one ventured to draw an indictment against half a nation. The Opposition naturally regarded the attitude of the administration with what v/e may call chastened sorrow, because they hoped to detach many Liberals from their party allegiance on that account. But no one said, and certainly no one thought, that the party was responsible for the in- action. There was a great deal of indignation expressed at the attitude of various prominent individuals, but it marked the stage Canada now occupies that the most outspoken were members of the government party. The question of loyalty can never again be made a party question because it is clearly seen that loyalty is a matter o£ self respect. The Minister of Public Works was criticised because he had obstructed the realisation of our ideal, " Canada first in the Empire," Few criticised, or cared to inquire about the attitude, of the individual minister. That was regarded pretty much in the same light as the utterances of an individual Nationalist member. His private opinion was hia own business, but it was generally conceived that he had misrepresented Canada's position in an Imperial matter. Naturally Kipling's influence has not been wholly good. His teaching is strong meat for men and the diet was perftaps CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 119 too generous. One result is that he will soon have to write a Recessional purely for the colonies. We are getting a little out of hand. We are jingoes to a man. We do not say ' my country right or wrong' as a perfervid patriot once said, we shout 'my country always right' and we do not stop enough to consider. Colonial sentiment may be rec- koned on for many years to come as an accession to the jingo element in the Empire. We are in favour of every forward movement and great was our disappointment when Lord Salisbury refused to declare Egypt a part of the Empire. I know of one map which was coloured red in anticipatiorL If Mr. Chamberlain or another colonial secretary were to de- clare to-morrow for the annexation of some of the German colonies in Africa his action would be applauded by a large number of colonials. We are all in favour of almost any for- ward policy ; and drunk with the contemplation of our vast undeveloped resources and confident in our power to develop them, we would regard any extension of the Empire simply as a pegging out of claims for posterity. Without enquiring into the extent of the burden — which to do us justice wet are ready to share — we are ready to clamour for the annexation of the Yang Tse Valley or the remotest god- knows-where pass or hill fort in the Pamirs. That it is a forward movement is enough for us and those who dare to think otherwise must take the consequences. That the Eng- lish of the island should for a moment tolerate John Morley after he had dared to call us "a pirate empire" is unintelli- gible, that they should listen to him with respect is intoler- able. For good and evil, colonial sentiment is jingo. That is part of the exuberance of our newly-found utterance and may correct itself in time. Meantime it is a factor in Imperial politics which must be taken into account When Canada has so far settled down that she can criticise her own ideals, there will doubtless be the same wholesome 120 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. division of opindon here as there is at home, where the forces of expansion and of consoHdation are more or less in balance. Perhaps since the outbreak of the war in South Africa it would be hard to- find any one who thought the colonies disposed to drive a bargain for their loyalty. Preferential trade may come or it may not come but the loyalty of the colonies is beyond all question. The sending of the various colonial contingents not only demonstrated the solidarity of the Empire : it also intensified the colonial interest in Im- perial affairs. Had there been no colonial " soldiers of the Queen '' at the front, much less enthusiasm would have been displayed. The result of all the expression of imperial senr timent in the colonies, during the war, has been to prepare the way for the proper consideration of some of the problems which await solution. This is true particularly of the problem of Imperial De- fence, and colonial public opinion is ready for the considera- tion of a comprehensive scheme. But those who have to elaborate such a scheme must keep in mind the underlying forces which ultimately govern policies. The colonies are prepared to do as much as is needed, and more even; but, except in the event of a life and death struggle for the exis- tence of the Empire, it is doubtful, whether directly or in- directly, they would hand over the control of their finances, in whole or in part, to the military dictatorship of any Im- perial Council, even should they find representation on that Council. The colonies are, and intend to remain, self-govern- ing communities. In the height of our patriotic paroxysms, in the Spring of 1900, Sir Charles Tupper went almost out of his way, apparently to the embarrassment of many of his own party and tO' the delight of his opponents, to reiterate at Quebec the views he has long held regarding Imperial De- fence. He holds that it is no part of Canada's duty to pay contributions into the Imperial Exchequer; and at Quebec .«f uuw; 'JTM^- •'(»' mm"' CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 121 he gloried in the part he had taken in destroying the Imperial Federation League, whose programme was that the colonies should contribute to the support and maintenance of the Empire to which they owed everything and contributed nothing. Sir Charles Tupper's contention was that Canada, by developing her own resources, and more particularly by building the trans-continental railroad, had done her duty and her whole duty by the Empire. The old extravaganza, " millions for defence but not a cent for tribute," may be taken as an exaggeration of the attitude which Sir Charles Tupper takes at the present moment. When necessity arises there will be no standing on rights and privileges, but until necessity does arise, there should be no attempt to invade those rights. A daughter goes to the help of a mother in time of need, not because it is a duty, but because she is a daughter; but at the same time she is, and desires to remain, mistress of her own house, managing her own affairs in her own way. It is possible that the growing pretensions of the colonies will compel them to do more directly for the defence of the Empire than they have done ; but there can be no doubt) that the instinct of the colonies, and their right instinct, is that the first line of defence must be maintained by the mother country. To this instinct Sir Charles Tupper has given negative expression. The need of the situation is that the instinct should receive positive expression. The military function of the colonies is to form the reserve of the Empire ; and this they can do best by strictly attending tO' their own proper business of developing their own resources. The main factor in the production of wealth is what Prof. Nicholson has called the personal capital of a country ; and in a new country this factor is relatively the more important. The productive capacity of human labour working on the virgin resources of countries like the colonies is very great ; and it 122 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. would be a wanton perversion of function, and a wanton waste of effort, to divert any portion of that labour unnecessarily to purely unproductive employment, such as military service. The blood tax of conscription or of heavy armaments is burdensome, not so much because of what it takes out, as because of what it keeps out of the pockets of the people. The military function of the colonies is not tO' maintain a large standing arm, or even to make contributions to the maintenance of such an army elsewhere, but to see to it that they maintain the reserve in good and available order, and, on occasion, to demonstrate to the Intelligence Departments of other powers, as was done by the sending of the contingents to South Africa, that the reserves of the Empire can be in- stantly called out. If, over and above the duty which has been committed to them of maintaining order within their own borders, and the further duty of increasing in wealth and population, the colonies should find themselves ready to undertake some specific and recognizable part of the task of defence, it should take the form of assuming responsibility for the maintenance of some portion of the Imperial Reserve. Thus Canada, for instance, might, without any departure from her policy, and without attracting wealth producers from their more important task, undertake to organize among her fishing population, by means of bounties paid out of the Dominion Treasury, a naval reserve sufficient to re-man the North Atlantic and the North Pacific Squadrons. This would be doing something which needs to be done, while it would involve the very minimum of interference with the real func- tion of the newer portions of the Empire. A scheme of defence which does not take account of the difference of function of the different units of the empire is not likely to succeed. Defence may be of more importance than opulence ; but a system of defence which strikes at the root of opulence is likely to break down in the hour of need. CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 123 The recognition of the importance of this fact does not, however, place any obstacle in the way of the colonies doing as they have done, either at the call of necessity or in obedience to their own enthusiasms, by sending regirnents from the colonies to fight in the regular armies of the Empire. Sir Charles Tupper, who has so persistently maintained that the duty of the colonies is best performed by the develop- ment of their own resources, was one of the first to call for the sending of a Canadian contingent to South Africa ; and he very properly refuses to make a free will offering in a time of national danger the basis for extorting concessions from the mother country. The contrast between the attitude of the two Canadian parties on the two great questions of pre- ferential trade and of imperial defence is very curious. Each seems to have got hold of the correct view of one of the questions, and to have adopted, on the other question, the attitude which one would have expected its opponents to hold. The Conservatives insist on a quid pro quo in the case of trade, and will have nothing to do with the demand for Imperial Representation as the price of sending Canadian troops to South Africa. The Liberals insist that there should be no demand for a quid pro quo in matters of trade — such a demand being injudicious, if not selfish — while, if Mr. Tarte is to be taken as the spokesman of the Liberal party (which is more than doubtful in this instance), thev are desirous of making a free will offering of troops in a time of national stress the basis of a demand for a quid pro quo. Mr. Tarte's advocacy is not likelv to commend a polirv of demanding Imperial representation to the people of Canada ; but there is without doubt a strong sentiment in Canada in favour of some sort of Imperial representation. But it is important to understand the true inwardness of the sentiment. Possibly nine men out of ten would gladly see Canadian representatives at Westminster ; but it is to be always remem- bered that it is the honour, and not the responsibility, they '1 124 CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. covet. What the colonies want out of Imperial representation is recognition, not power. They are tolerably well content with the constitution of the British Empire as it is, and they understand the enormous difficulties which stand in the way of devising and working a new constitution. They would be just as well satisfied if the Agents General were ipso facto members of the House of Lords. In such a way they would obtain the desired recognition and yet avoid the dangers for their own politics. Canadians are not likely to forget the de- terioration which has set in in provincial politics since Con- federation. The better men seek the larger field ; and in the case of Imperial representation it would be the Dominion that would suffer. The truth is that Canada cannot afford to send her good men, and, for her reputation's sake, can- not afford to send her poor men to represent her : and with Imperial representation we should be compelled to impale ourselves on one or other horn of the dilemma. But the essential part of the demand is not the representation at Westminster, but a clearer recognition of the importance of the colonies in the Empire. Whv, for instance, should not colonials receive a larger share of the birthday honours? Why should not the mayors of Toronto and Montreal be able to look forward to a knighthood with the same reasonable assurance as the provosts of Edinburgh or the mayors of Liverpool, for instance, can do. The colonial civic masris- trates mav not be all that we desire in a knisrht ; but who pretends that the knightly qualities are conspicuous in the recipients of these honours at home. A freer recognition of the merits of individual colonists for positions of tnist in the government service at home and elsewhere, would prevent us from contemplating the necessity of climbing " o'er the house to unlock the little gate." As it is, every such honour con- ferred on a Canadian is regarded as an honour conferred on Canada ; and the desire for Imperial representation is little CANADA AND THE EMPIRE. 125 more than a desire that Canada should have the honour of having some of her sons seated in the mother of Parhaments. If this be the meaning of the colonial desire for imperial representation, there is no necessity of casting the constitution into the melting pot, as some think we must be prepared to do. In spite of all that is said to the contrary, there is no need for any elaborate scheme of reconstruction. We can very well go on as we are so far as constitutional arrange- ments are concerned. The British Empire is not that loose congeries of states which must be more tightly bound to- gether. Publicists talk much of the state as an organism, if ever there was a state which could be described as an organism (which is doubtful) the British Empire may be so called; and those who clamour for reconstruction seek to replace the organism by a dead mechanism between the various parts of which there can be only friction, which must be minimised, instead of a growing life. The Empire is no mechanism to-day. It has its separate organs, each with its own function, and its own life, which yet is the common life of all ; and nothing but harm can come of attempts to bring the various organs of the national Ufe intO' close and un- natural contact. There are many problems still to solve, but they are problems of particulars ; and provided that no cause of friction is introduced they can be solved. But they must ail be solved on the basis of freedom to each unit of the empire to govern its own policy in its own way. Canada has shown the way in the matter of trade, and both parties re- cognize the importance of the accomplished fact. The Con- servatives, while they continue to upbraid the Liberals for having omitted to take advantage of Canada's opportunity, are not likely to undo their work. What they may do is, like the Liberal government itself, to increase the tariff rate on those articles in which the English and Canadian manufac- turers compete, before they bring the thirty-three and a third "•WTfV^ 12^5 CANADA AXD THE EMPIRE. preference, to which figure Mr. Fielding, without any special reason, has increased the preference. So far as practical poUcy is concerned both parties will act in the same way, for the reason that both parties are at one in their attach- ment and devotion to our common Empire.^ iMr. Georg-e E. Foster, House of Commons, Ottawa, Tuesday, March 27, 1900 speaking- officially on behalf of the Conservative party, after criticising the Budget of Mr. Fielding, went on to say :— '• But we are told : This preference to Great Britain is now an accomplished fact. When you get into power, what will you do with it? Will you repeal the preference to Great Britain ? That is a question that will be asked ; that is a question that must be answered. My answer to it is this -that certain facts, when once they are accomplished facts, and though they were accom- plished against the wisn of one party, and against what was considered by that party to be a fair and judicious policy, yet, when once they have been accomplished, it becomes a question whether profitably to the interest of ihe country, and to what extent, these accomplished fiicts can be repudiated or antagonized. One thing^ however, is sure— that when the Liberal Conservative party comes into power, what- ever preference is given to the Uriush manufacturer, that party will take care to see that home industries are fairly and adequately protected, no matter what advantage is given to others." ( ii-'' ) CHAPTER V. TRADE AND THE FLAG. ''T^HE maxim, trade follows the flag, seems to inspire men to 1 practical contradictio'ns. Those who believe that it does spend their energy in devising systems of commerce by which trade may be made to do what it already does ; and those who deny its truth find themselves compelled to object to all proposals which seek so desirable a consummation. If the maxim were true, it might form the motto of those who seek to expand the limits of empire ; but it is as frequently in the mouths of those who seek not expansion but consolidation. The idea itself is essentially modern. The old colonial policy was inspired by its contrary. The " mean and malig- nant" expedients of the mercantile system were intended to force trade to follow the flag which had it been left to itself, is precisely what it perversely would not have done. The nearest approach to the modern idea was made by Lord Brougham who declared that the restrictions of the old sys- tem were superfluous rather than burdensome ; and even he seems to have considered it the natural course that trade should follow the price list rather than the flag. The colo- nies had only, according to his defence, which, from a poli- tical point of view, therefore, becomes a strong indictment of the O'ld system, been restricted to the market in which they would otherwise have bought and sold. The unexpected commercial consequences of the emanci- pation of England's American colonies induced many to be- lieve that the flag was a hindrance rather than a help to trade. " Trade," said Sir G. C. Lewis, " between England and the United States is probably far more profitable to the mother ^^ 128 TRADE AND THE FLAG. countiy than it would have been if they had remained in a state of dependence on her,"^ and it was as true as it was re- markable that the United States bought twice as much from England as the colonies had done. We should err, however, if we went on to draw the extreme conclusion the little Eng- landers sought to draw, viz., that it would pay to^ cut the painter and turn the colonies adrift. For it does not follow that the trade with the United States would not have grown to the same extent had complete self-government, as we now under- stand the term, been granted instead of independence. What restricted trade under the old colonial system was not the flag but the numberless superfluous regulations. And it is more than possible that, with as much commercial freedom as Ca- nada and Australia now enjoy, the trade of the emancipated colonies with the United Kingdom, had they remained under the flag, would have been greater than it is to day. What the experience of history teaches is not that trade does not follow the flag but that the attempt to compel it to follow national lines is to a large extent destructive of the trade that would otherwise exist. The teachings of history are borne out by present experience. Those nations which continue to place restrictions on the colonial trade do' not engross to themselves so large a share of the import trade of their colonies as the United Kingdom does of hers after having abandoned to the last detail the policy of restriction. Fifty-live per cent, of the im- ports into British colonies come from the mother country ; and the proportion is 63 per cent, if we omit the Straits Set- tlement which does mainly a transit trade. The Dutch East Indies take but one third of their imports, Dutch Guiana about one half from Holland. Portuguese colonies take but one third and the Spanish colonies in 1896 took well under one third of their imports from their stepmother countries. France engrosses her purely colonial market to the extent of I The Government of Dependencies (Mr Lucas's Edition) page 218. TRADE AND THE FLAG. 129 34.9 per cent. ; and even if we include, Tunis and Algiers, the French share of their colonial import trade is 61 per cent, only. ^ This result is the more remarkable in view of the fact that nations which still retain the old restrictive colonial system in whole or part find themselves compelled to make heavy expenditures to meet the costs of colonial administra- tion. German trade with German colonies amounted to ;^738,ooo. The subsidies which the Empire paid amounted to ;£739,ooo exceeding not only the whole profit of the colo- nial trade but the whole volume of that trade.- The expen- diture of France on her colonies is not quite so barren of commercial results. In 1897 France exported goods to her colonies to the value of ;2{^i 4,330,000 while the net charge im- posed on the French home treasury for the public service in French possessions was ;^4, 500,000, one third of the total ex- port trade and certainly in excess of any possible profit in the colonial trade. '^ The imports into the colonies trom France must be largely to cover administrative expenses. Reunion, for instance, imported, on the annual average 1873-1883, from France goods to the value of 8,737,244 frs. as against goods valued at 15,858,000 frs. from other countries; and on the annual average 1887-91 9,047,000 frs. from France as against 13,724,000 frs. from other countries. But the imperial expenditure of France in the island, according to Budget of 1898, was 4,458,000 frs. practically half of the exports sent to Reunion.* Even when the restrictive system is not adopted subsidies and expenses of colonial administration may account for much of the trade which the mother country does with lit is not surprising that Professor Flux, from whose paper in the Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Sept., 1899, these figures are taken, draws as his final conclusion : " The efficiency of the policj' ot exclusive trade privileges to the sovereign state, whether in promoting its own trade or the trade of its colonies, is not conspicuous in the records." "i Spectator, Nov. 2Sth, 1899. ^J^urn. Stat. Soc, Sept., 1899. 'iLeroy Beaulieu : De la Colonisation, page 343. Journ. Stat. Soc. utsupra. Statesman's Year Book, 1898. 130 TRADE AND THE FLAG. her colonies. The imports into the Congo Free State for in- stance are derived mainly from Belgium although there is no discrimination in favour of Belgian goods. Out of 16,070,370 frs. imported in 1896, Belgium sent 10,204,477 or about two thirds. But at least three million francs of the revenue of the Congo Free Sate was, directly or indirectly, a subsidy from the Belgian treasury.^ In cases like these trade will follow the flag as it would follow anything else. Communities do not refuse the goods when gifts are presented or rather forced upon them; and we must make allowance in the discussion for the exports to a colony which represent merely imperial expenditure there. The trade which follows the flag must follow it both volun- tarily and without the compulsion or inducement of imperial subsidies and expenditure ; othenvise no conclusion of any im- portance can be drawn fro'm the facts. In short, we must confine our consideration to the trade between self-governing colonies and a mother country which leaves them free to buy where they please and makes no im- perial contribution to the expenses of their administration. We must further restrict the area under consideration. The maxim can be proved or disproved only regarding self-govern- ing communities which would be independent if they were not part of the Empire. In the case of dependencies like India, trade will follow the flag. British trade would be cut off were the British flag to be hauled down. For India, if not a de- pendency of Great Britain, would be under the dominion of some other European power ; and because this \ ower would apply to Indian trade the principles which rule its trade else- where, British trade would be reduced to the narrow limits it has at present in the trade of foreign nations and their de- pendencies. Does trade follow the flag when it flies over self-governing 1 Statesman's Year Book, 1898, page 440. TRADE AND THE FLAG. 131 colonies ? The arguments advanced pro and con do not meet each other. One party declares that the colonial is a better customer, man for man, than the foreigner ; and that the colo- nies do the greater part of their buying within the Empire. The other party replies with an ignoraiio elenchi that the proportion of colonial trade to the total trade of the mother country is small and not growing ; which may be argument against handicapping the foreign trade to benefit the colonial but can hardly be regarded as disproving the maxim. For if the colonies buy and sell all, or nearly all, they have to buy and sell, within the Empire, they can hardly be expected to do more. The trade of the United Kingdom with her colonies when contrasted with the trade with foreign countries is so much greater as to justify many maxims like Sir Julius Vogel's. The total trade with the United States is 47s., with Germany 24s., with France 35s., per head of the population of these coun- tries ; but when we turn to colonial trade the figure suddenly mounts to 68s. per head of the population of the colonies.^ If we confine our attention to the export trade of the United Kingdom the contrast is still more remarkable. The United States bought British goods to the amount of 13s. lod., Ger- many to 3s. 4d., France 9s. 3d., per head ; while Canada was a customer to the extent of ^2 3s., the Cape and Australia, respectively, to the amounts of £^2 i6s., and ;^8 6s. per head of their population.- An Australian as it has been more picturesquely put is as good a customer to the United King- dom as 16 Americans, and every Canadian is worth more to British trade than 35 Russians. The colonial is almost as good a customer of the British manufacturer as the native of the islands while the average Australian actually buys a greater value of British manufactures than that purchased by the aver- iCaldecott: English Colonization, pag-e i86. -Schonbcrg's HanJbuch, Vol. II, page 1075. 132 TRADE AND THE FLAG. age Englishman. Indeed it might be said, as it has been said, " England is the only portion of the British Empire that con- sumes foreign goods to any extent, the colonies almost ex- clusively purchasing goods produced within the limits of the Empire itself."^ Whatever justification may be found or not found foT the maxim that trade follows the flag, we have here the very solid fact that a colonial consumer, from whatever cause, is worth more to the United Kingdom than six Euro- pean consumers of whatever nation. The conclusion which is immediately drawn from these figures is reached by what Mill called the method of agree- ment. A (Canada) buys more than B (France), C (Cape Colony) buys more than D (Holland). The only difference between A and C on the one hand, and B and D on the other, is the flag and all that the flag implies. The flag is the only circumstance which varies, therefore it is concluded that the flag is the cause of the greater trade. But the argument is not conclusive. The flag is evidently not the only circum- stance which varies. Otherwise how account for the differ- ences between different colonies under the same flag. For Canada takes British exports to the value per head of 43s. only while Australia takes nearly four times as much, i66s. per head. We cannot find the explanation by Mill's other method of concomitant variations, for the flag is the flag in Canada as it is in Australia, and the Canadian is as loyal as the Africander. These facts cannot be denied and no attempt is made to impugn them. It is on the practical conclusion only that the disputants come within range of each other. The obvious difficulty is that there are so few of these desirable colonial customers. Whatever may be the case when the colonies have attained their growth, the number of the colonial cus- ' Webster : England's Colonial Granaries. Proc. Royal Colonial Institute, Vol. XIII. page »i. TRADE AND THE FZAG. 133 tomers, however much they buy, is ver)- small in proportion to the number of foreign customers. Twenty-five per cent, of the total British trade is with the colonies. Twenty-five per cent, of her imports come from the colonies. Twenty-eight per cent, of her exports are taken by the colonies. And when we consider the practical conclusion, this vs a sm.all percent- age for which the United Kingdom is asked to penalise the remaining seventy-five per cent, of her trad,^ The colonies cannot do much more than they are doing. Some of them import eighty per cent, of all they import from the United Kingdom. But the bulk of the trade is small, and it is bulk and not percentage which counts towards a nation's wealth. Moreover, the colonial trade is not growing in importance. It is difficult to see how it could when, at present, they take nearly sixty per cent, of all they buy from the United King- dom. Colonial trade has done no more than keep pace with the other trade of the British isles. If the colonies have in- creased in wealth and in population, and buy two and a half times as much as they did half a century ago, at the same rime new foreign markets have been opened up. and old cm'^- tomers among foreigji nations have increased the amount of their purchases, till the foreign trade bears the same propor- tion to the colonial trade as it did fifty vears ago. The facts were put succinctly in u despatch by Lord Ripon to Lord Jer- sey who was chairman of the Colonial Conference at Ottawa in 1894. Tn the period 18^4-58 British imports were in total ;^83o millions of which £ig^ millions were colonial or 2.-^.8 per cent, of the whole. During the five years 1889-9^ the total imports were /^2,ii2 millions of which ^^482 millions were colonial or 22.8 per cent, of the whole. The total exports during 18^4-58 were ,/!657 millions of which /^i86 millions were to colonial possessions or 28.3 per cent, of the whole ; and in the neriod 1889-93, the total exports were ^1,^21 mil- lions of which British possessions took ;£438 millions or 134 TRADE AND THE FLAG. 28.8 per cent, of the whole. And taking the whole trade, the colonial share in the earlier period was 25.8 per cent, and in the later period 25.3 per cent.^ The variations within the period have been slight and there is little direct statiscical confirmation of the common opinion that British colonial trade has grown faster than British for- eign trade. Cons'dering the remarkable development of the colonies during the period since 1854 (the first year of the real as distinguished from the ofiicial values of exports and imports of the L'nited Kingdom) the steadiness of the pro- portions is remarkable. Lord Farrer in his pamphlet " The Neo-Protection Scheme " gives the proportion by five year periods down to 1895, the figures for 1895-98 being taken from the Annual .\bstract of the Trade of the United Kingdom. IMPORTS FROM FOREIGN COUNTRIES AND BRITISH POSSESSIONS, 1854-1898. Periods. Imports from Foreign Countries. Imports trom British Possessions. Million £. Per Cent, of Total Imports. Million £. Per Cent, of Total Imports. 1854 Annual Average. 1855-1859 1860-1864 1865-1869 1870-1874 1875-1879 1880-1884 1 885- 1 889 1 890- 1 894 1 895- 1 898 118 129 167 218 270 292 312 293 323 349 77-6 76-5 71-2 76*0 78-0 77"9 76-5 77-1 77-1 78-0 34 40 68 68 76 83 96 87 96 95 22-4 23*5 28-8 24-0 22'0 22 I 235 22-9 22-9 22"0 1 Canada Sessional Papers, No. 5B, 1894. TRADE AND THE FLAG. 135 EXPORTS OF BRITISH PRODUCE TO FOREIGN COUNTRIES AND BRITISH POSSESSIONS I 854-1898. Periods. Exports to Foreign Countries. Exports to British Possessions. Million c Per Cent. of Total Million £. Per Cent, of Total Exports. 1 Exports. i8S4 6.1 64-9 34 35" I Annual Average. •855-1859 79 68-5 37 3 '"5 1 I 860- I 864 92 66-6 46 33-4 ; 1 865. 1 869 •3' 72-4 .SO 27-6 ' 1870-1874 175 7^4 60 25-6 1875-1879 135 66-9 67 zr^ 1880-1884 I. S3 65-5 81 34*5 1 885- 1 889 147 65-0 79 35 'o 1 890- 1 894 156 66-5 78 33*5 T895M§9?~-^ •^■'*'fse***"' "^ro-y^ ■*■ ^'*w^;u-<-.=ra^;3i»w«4v, The variations- within this period have been slight, the only years which depart from the general average to any extent being those between 1865-1875. The impression that colo- nial trade is increasing much faster than foreign trade is due to a mistake in the use of the statistics. When public atten- tion began again, in the early eighties, to be seriously direc- ted to colonial trade, a comparison was made of the propor- tions between colonial and foreign trade in 1870 and 1880. And as Mr. Webster pointed out in the paper from which we have already quoted "the value of the total exports to foreign countries and to our colonies in 1871 and in 1880 was iden- tical ; but whereas in 1871 our colonies took 23 per cent, only of the total sum they received 2>Z P^r cent, in 1880.^ Sir iProc. Roy. Col. Inst.. Vol. XIII, page zo. 136 TRADE AND THE FLAG. Alexander Gait, speaking at Greenock,^ Jan. 29, 1883, used the same figures to draw the same conclusion ; and from that time dates the mistaken idea that colonial trade is more worth cultivating than foreign trade because it grows relatively faster. But it may be answeied there has been an increased de- mand in the colonies fcr British exports which these figures do not show. During the period there were two develop- ments of colonial policy which had the effect of seriously re- stricting British exports to the colonies ; and to maintain a stationary proportion shows in reality an increased demand. Imperial expenditure in the colonies was large at the beginn- ing of the period and is now practically nil. The colonies have been forced to provide for their own defence and, with a few exceprions, imperial forces have been withdrawn from the colonies. The colonial estimates in the Imperial Budget were large and to that extent the exports to the colonies were stimulated at the beginning of the period. In the second place, during the period the self governing colonies have ac- quired the right of controlling their own tariffs and have exer- cised this right to the extent of protecting against the mother country. Many colonial theorists regret that this rieht was cancelled, but as Lord Farrer insists, " Freedom of Trade is only one part of Freedom and not the most important.''^ The concession was granted, and wisely granted, and the effect has been to restrict colonial importations from the United Kingdom. A stationary proportion is thus again equivalent to an increased demand. But this latter consideration amounts merely for the fact that the amount of the imports has not increased faster than it has done. It does not account for the fact that the rela- tive proportions of foreign and colonial trade remain un- changed. For* foreign countries have not been behindhand '■ iProc. Royal Col. Inst., Vol. XIV, page 407. ' '^The Neo-Protection Scheme, page 14. TRADE AXD THE FLAG. 137 in following the colonial example. They, too, have protective barriers against British goods, and these barriers are, on the whole, higher than the colonial barriers ; and if the argument is valid in the one case it must be valid in the other that a stationary proportion is equivalent to an increased demand. Indeed this argument would prove that the foreign demand had increased faster than the colonial demand. "The colo- nies," said Mr. Foster, the Finance Minister of Canada, at the Ottawa Conference, "have all protected against the mother country but none of them have protected as the foreign coun- tries have protected against her. You can take them and make an average. You will find that the protection is far lower in the colonies of Britain against British goods, taking it on the average, than it is in foreign countries."^ There is one qualification which must be made regarding this analysis of the trade statistics. The early figures of colo- nial trade represent a period before the colonies had ac- quired or begun to exercise their right of protection against the mother country ; while the early figures of foreign trade are for a period prior to the spread of free trade ideas on the continent of Europe. In short it may be said we are com- paring two periods one free trade and one protective in the case of the colonies ; and two protectionist periods in foreign trade, one practically prior to the continual movement in the direction of free trade and one subsequent to the collapse of that movement. But except that we are thus enabled to ac- count for the variation in the proportions of colonial and of foreign trade the qualification makes no difference in the re- sult. The colonies fell earlier under the protectionist reac- tion. In 1859 Canada came into conflict with the Colonial Office over a protectionist tariff; but in i860 the greatest practical step towards universal free trade was made in Cob- den's Commercial Treaty with France. The protectionist re- iCanada: Sessional Papers, No. 58, 1S94. 138 TRADE AND THE FLAG. action was a decade later on the continent of Europe. During this decade the colonies took a less proportion of British ex- ports than they had done, and less than they were to take when the protection virus had again infected foreign natio'ns. When the reaction spread to foreign nations they discrimi- nated against English goods more severely than the colonies had done. Thus, on analysis, it appears that while the colonies ad- mitted British goods on easy terms and foreign countries taxed them heavily the proportion of British colonial export trade as compared with her foreign export trade was above ^t, per cent. During the decade in which the colonies began to dis- criminate, and foreigners lowered their duries, the proportion fell to 26 per cent. After the reaction set in, and the colcv- nies which still discriminating were yet imposing lighter duties than foreign nations were doing, the earlier proportion was re-established and has since been maintained. The sole vari- ation from the stationary condition can thus be accounted for, and we may take it as established that the colonial trade is not growing in importance relatively to British foreign export trade On the other hand, it is true that Imperial expenditure in the colonies has been largely diminished. And to this extent we may grant that colonial voluntary purchases have increased more than the figures show. But against this must be set the fact that in the period under investigation the colonies have been large borrowers of English capital which has been ex- ported largely in the shape of goods. The result of this investigation of the direct statistical evi- dence must be a verdict of not proven. The colonist is a better customer than a foreigner, a better customer, in some instances, than the native of the islands ; but, on the other hand, the colonists take but one third of British exports and are doing no better than they did half a century ago. But it TRADE AND THE FLAG. 139 must be remembered that the colonies in many cases are doing as well as could be expected and the most exacting could not expect them to buy more than 75 per cent, of their imports within the Empire. The maxim that trade follows the flag is frequently used to justify not the consolidation but the further expansion of the limits over which the flag flies ; and as a means to this end and sometimes as an end in itself, to justify an increase of armaments. Countries which have no navy, and conse- quently no colonies, must be content with a restricted market for their exports. Nations like Belgium, Holland and Den- mark admittedly do a large export trade, but this trade is con- fined to the markets of civilised countries where in theor\- at least the foreigner has the same chance before the law courts as the native. Belgium, for instance, imports largely from such countries as Roumania and Peru but her exports to these countries are small. This fact is explained by the im- potence of Belgium to protect her subjects. When Denmark wishes to sell butter to such nations as these it is compelled to employ British middlemen. There is no difficulty in sell- mg in the markets of civilised powers because there they have an assurance of equal justice. But merchants trading with semi-civilised communities have no such assurance land hence a weak nation must be content to miss the world's trade or share it only indirectly. But this argument proves too much. Belgium and Den- mark export but little to Australia which as regards civilisa- tion could not even by the most prejudiced Anglophobe of the continent be placed in the same category with Peru. Pro- bably Belgium exports quite a great deal to Australia but it does so indirectly ; and the cause of the roundabout trade is that the volume of exports i5 not considerable enough to justify direct shipment. The development of naval power is not without effect on foreign trade. Xo one pretends that 140 TRADE AND THE FLAG. goods can be sold at the point of the bayonet, and the navy will serve rather to maintain than to extend trade in bar- barous regions. The result of adopting this policy is less than the statistics may show it to be. A direct trade may be substituted for an indirect trade with the result of saving com- missions and arbitrage ; a saving which may be very small in comparison with the expenditure in subsidies, etc., necessary to effect it. But while goods cannot be sold at the point of the bayonet, armaments may lead merchants to show greater enter- prise and confidence in pushing trade in hitherto unexploited regions with a result of making the goods they have to sell better known. On the whole Adam Smith's dictum that while each nation has managed to engross the inconveniences of a colonial em- pire, the advantages it has been compelled to share with the whole world, is just as true to'-day as it was in the century before his time. New colonies founded to expand trade buy as largely from foreign nations as from the mother countries, while the imperial expenditures on them and in them often exceed the sum total of all their trade. The proof of the maxim, which is hardly possible by direct induction from statistics of trade, is sometimes sought by apriori methods. By general concession among economists, the apriori methods are alone productive of results in the consideration of trade problems. The conditions of commerce are so complicated that even the most devoted admirers of the inductive methods in economic study have had recourse toi apriori proof. The question whether trade follows the flag is ultimately a problem in the theory of foreign trade, and before a decision is made all the more important elements which enter into^ the equation of indebtedness should be con- sidered. And there are difficulties peculiar to the present problem which require solution. Why should trade follow the flag? One can understand TRADE AND THE FLAG. 141 why it should when there is compulsion or a preference given. But when there is none ? It may as well be conceded, once and for all, that the flag does not supersede the ordinary economic motives in buying and selhng. The motives thus symbolised must operate through, and modify or transform, the ordinary desire to make the best bargain. There may be many exceptions to the domination of the economic motive, but it is not wise to generalise from these exceptions. The flag may serve the purpose of advertisement, net in the way the patent medicine vendor uses it so much on the American continent, but because the officials of the govern- ment are directed, or expected, to urge those under their care or their influence to buy the products of the mother country. It is not merely because of discriminating duties that Madagascar buys more from France since the island became a French colony than it did before. French officers and civil servants are instructed to favour French merchants and to push French wares. This is more than an under- standing : it is a direct and official order : " I have also to request you to instruct the native authorities to "exert all their influence in favour of the objects at which we are "aiming [to introduce French Products]. It will be easy for them, " from the point of view now before us, to represent to persons living "under their jurisdiction, that tissues ot French manufacture are as "good as similar articles manufactured abroad : that it is only fitting " that the Malagasy, who have now become French subjects, should " conform to our national customs by using our products : that their " clothing thus becomes a distinctive mark of their new position. . . " But they must bear in mind that no obstacles should be placed in "the way of the sale and circulation of foreign merchandise. Your "part, as well as that of your native subordinates, consists simply in "making clear to our new subjects the benefit to be derived from " the purchase of French products, which will henceforward be more "suitable to their habits and wants, which have been mollified in the " last t-wo years by the introduction of French laws and customs. Such 142 TRADE AND THE FLAG. " a course is absolutely within our right and no one has any right to " take exception to it."' And in accordance with this policy advertisements of French goods are inserted, free of cost to the advertiser, in the columns of the Malagasy journal (the Vaovao.) This may be the French way, or part of the French way, of making trade follow the flag (and the Germans also take an eminently practical view of the uses to which government officials may be put), but it is not the way of the " nation of shopkeepers." His Excellency the Governor General of Canada and his aides and secretaries do not carry round with them pocketsful of business circulars advising Canadians to buy Plums' Soap in preference to Jones's Shaving Sticks, as being " more suitable to their habits and wants, which have been modified " by two centuries of English occupation. In British possessions the sale of British goods depends on individual exertion ; and the home government has done nothing to further its development. It may instruct its con- sular agents to advise home merchants of profitable open- ings ; but consular activity is confined to foreign countries and even in the crown colonies government agents are not required to imitate the " illustrious Gaudissart."' Certainly the home government does nothing either in the colonies or elsewhere to induce the native born to consume English goods. Those who put forward the answering epigram that trade follows the price fist may laugh at a policy which turns the civil servant into a salaried national tout ; but the policy cannot be devoid of effect. And even without such direct endeavours the flag may encourage trade. Trade follows the price list certainly, but the flag may serve to advertise the 1 Quoted by W. Ford : The Foreign Policy of the United States, pp. 128-129. The italics are by way of comment. TRADE AND THE FLAG. 143 price list ; and there may be circumstances when traders do not care to present their price hsts because of the lack of government protection to their enterprise. The modern divorce of producer and consumer has made advertisement of some kind an economic necessity ; and the fact that the goods in question, other things being the same, have been produced under the flag which the consumer reveres may give the goods that additional publicity which may be all that is needed to induce the consumer to prefer them. Com- mercial travellers, in their moments of candour, readily admit that in nine cases out of ten, as between rival houses of equally good standing, it is personal regard for the traveller that sells the goods. And in international trade personal or national regard may bring about the same result. Reference was made in an earlier chapter to the opinion that increased purchases of Canadian goods is Britain's quid pro quo for the Canadian preference ; and from this point of view the preferential tariff' was simply the crowning act of the long continued policy of advertisement which the Canadian government has been carrying on with a view to capturing the British market. There was, it is true, no prejudice against Canadian goods ; but there was an apparently invincible ignorance of their merits, the effects of which were the same. For many years after Canadian cheese had captured the market, it was sold in the United Kingdom as American, simply because Canada, to the English public, was not even a geographical expression. I remember hearing on one occa- sion a Yankee explain that the sea voyage greatly improved the quality of cheese. American cheese had never, he assured me, tasted so good at home as it did in England. In my innocence I thought it might be that the cheese did suffer a " sea-change " ; and I took occasion later to mention the fact to a British produce broker. He laughed and said the explanation was much simpler.. " All the American 144 TRADE AXD THE EL AG. cheese your Yankee friend tasted on this side was made in, Canada." But while the brokers knew it the consumers did not then. This ignorance of the merits of Canadian produce was in part dispelled by the act of Canada in 1897 ; and the flag, and the sentiment it arouses, while it might not induce the English consumer to pay more for an inferior article may induce him to look first at the Canadian price list. If by the maxim trade follows the flag it must be under- stood that people will prefer poor and dear goods to cheaper J and better goods simply because the former were manufac- tured under the flag, few would be found to defend it. Sen- timent undoubtedly has a strong influence on trade and patriotism is one kind of sentiment. But its influence is not exerted in this simple way. Its effect is more indirect. It may alter the estimates which people place on goods. Pre- judice and custom may so modify a man's tastes and inclina- tions that he prefers goods made( under the flag. But this is because goods made under the , flag are in themselves different goods from apparently similar articles made else- where. They are different because they satisfy a distinct . want. , 1 How far human wants are thus modified it is impossible ' \ to say. It is almost certain that when there is a distinct 1 economic understanding human wants are not so modified. The slight measure of success which has attended the efforts of national societies to encourage consumers to use home pro- ductions shows how little, even in retail buying, sentiment has to do with human wants. Under ordinary circumstances national sentiment counts for little in the buying of the re- tailer, and consequently for less in his selling. The un- expected effects of the law regarding the branding of goods " made in Germany " and elsewhere has furnished the starv- dard modern illustration of the incapacity of a legislature to protect trade interests. Under ordinary trade conditions the TRADE AND THE FLAG. 145 branding served as an unintentional advertisement which pro- bably had the effect of increasing sales. But in circum- stances out of the ordinary the effect may be different. During the crisis produced by Emperor William's telegram to President Kruger, goods marked " made in Germany " were in many places practically unsaleable. It is true that the trade reports do not show much evndence of a falling off in the demand ; but the crisis was short and traders accom- modated themselves to the conditions by obliterating the marks. Had the crisis lasted longer, the result might have been different. For the trader so long as he has a stock in hand cannot afford to be patriotic, although he may place his future orders as the patriotic sentiment of his customers demanded. But under ordinary circumstances the patriotic motive pure and simple does not materially alter economic conduct.^ In fact, in some instances, there is a positive prejudice in favour of foreign made goods, a prejudice which is fostered rather than discouraged by a protective tariff. In the wealthy centres of population, shopkeepers make a point of advertising their stock of English goods for instance, as one may see in Beriin and in New York, Under ordinary cir- cumstances, however, we may take it for granted that people will buy the goods which suit them at the lowest price avail- 1 Patriotic sentiment, however weak in the individual consumer, may influence the direction of a governments expenditure. The Hon. Mr. Playford, the South Australian representative at the Ottawa Conference, declared that his government felt bound to help other parU of the Empire, even at a loss to themselves " As Minister of Public Works, I have shown my practical sympathy to Great Bntam in the case when Belgian manufacturers offered to supply us with a considerable quantity of rails at a lower price than Great Britain. I recommended my colleagues to give the contract to Great Britain and pay the higher price in preference to giving it to Belgium.'-Canada : Sess. Pap. No 58. 1894. But this patriotic and uneconomical action was exceptional, for in the same speech he showed why his government bought locomotives from Messrs. Krupp. It must, moreover, be remembered that a govern- ment is expected to act as no individual citizen would act in the same circumstances. However, in spite of exceptions, governments wisely, in the interest of the general taxpayer, buy at the best bargain, irrespective of the country of origin. 146 TRADE ASD THE FLAG. able, and that those goods will be pressed on their attention which offer the trader the greatest chances of profit. And if trade follows the flag it must be because the flag has the effect of changing human wants or increasing the chances of profit. That it has, or seems to have, this effect is undoubted. The flag represents a very important element in modem commerce. It gives confidence, and thus encourages in- vestment. Capital has flowed more freely, and with smaller inducement in the shape of interest, to British colonies than to foreign countries, whose circumstances are similar. The British investor is more certain that his rights will be res- pected in a British colony under an implied, or assumed, Imperial guarantee of equal rights. British capital could not have been discriminated against to the same extent in Quebec as it has been in the Transvaal ; and less capital might have gone to the Transvaal had there not been some assurance that the Imperial government would see justice done to the British investor. Were it possible to determine how much capital is exported from the United Kingdom, it might be made to appear that trade follows the investment, and without doubt the flag influences the investment.^ But that is not all. The flag as a trade factor stands for more than trade confidence. It means also a freer out- let for surplus labour. And every emigrant, besides re- lieving an overstocked labour market at home, helps to create and maintain a demand for goods abroad. It mat- ters not where he goes, his prejudices and habits go with him ; and he demands in his new home the goods he was accustomed to use in his old ; and, if as often happens, he improves his economic position by the change, he may demand more of them It is possible that he may not be able to satisfy his desire by obtaining the goods he has been iV. Jour. Stat. Soc, Sept., 1899, P^8f6 524- TRADE AND THE FLAG. 147 accustomed to use. The goods may not be sold in that market, and his demand may be too feeble to call out the supply. But each emigrant is at least one unit towards creating that intensity of demand. He will not certainly pay more for home goods than for native or foreign made goods if the goods are the same. But the point is, that the goods are not the same, in fact, whatever they be in name. Each emigrant, to the measure of his influence, not only asks for what he has consumed at home ; but forms, so to speak, a centre which radiates prejudices in favour of the goods of the home country. So long as his character remains unchanged and he has not been perfectly assimulated by the new community, so long will continue his demand for the home goods. If he is obstinate in his prejudices, it may last a lifetime. If he is easily adaptable, the preference may vanish in a few years. If he stands alone in the new country, his demand may never be really effective; but if he goes to swell the number of fellow exiles, his demand will swell an existing demand. While his prejudices remain, the home goods are the goods which suit him, not on sentimental grounds but on the solid grounds of convenience. On a point like this an emigrant may speak with some authority. The adult immigrant brings with him habits and customs which are not the same as the habits and customs of the native born ; and he generally brings with him, too, a disposition to exalt everything that belongs to his old home from its climate to its manner of speech. If he can possibly afford it, after the first novelty has worn off, he Mnll use nothing he has not used at home. He will act as he acted there, clothe himself as he was clad there, and generally con- duct himself as if his conditions had not changed. If he cannot obtain through the ordinary course of retail trade the articles he has been accustomed to use, he will try to make 148 TRADE AND THE FLAG. use of what business connections he retains with his mother country; and when the advantage he thus secures is not pecuHar to one in his position, he may be the means of in- creasing the export trade of his old home. For in many cases trade follows the old channels rather than the profit- able channels. Canadians as a rule are content to pay the enhanced American prices for books and calculate on the basis of thirty-five cents, to the shilling. An open demon- stration that Enghsh books can be landed in Canada, duty and postage paid, at an average rate of twenty-two or twenty- three cents, to the shilling, has in many places helped to create a demand for purely EngUsh books. To take another instance, the writer found it impossible to buy Indian tea at his new home. Chinese tea, which then held the American market, was more or less unpalatable ; and he was forced to order directly from England. But now it is possible to buy Indian tea in every grocery store, and there is now no need to order except through the local retailer. In time, the immigrant comes to allow the storekeeper to do his ordering for him. Naturally and gradually he accom- modates himself to the customs of his new home; and in the same way awakens to the fact that the world is not bounded by Brighton Beach. His demands for the old goods becomes first indirect and then it begins to weaken. He finds, for in- stance, that EngUsh-made overcoats are not the best for a Canadian winter, and, above all, that the irksomeness of pass- ing goods through the customs does not become less with use. But though the intensity of his demand decreases, it continues in part to the end of his life. It is possible, and perhaps probable, that the demand he represents gains in extent as it loses in intensity. But that depends on the kind of man he is, the kind of position he fills in the community, and the attitude he takes to the native bom. He will seldom be able to transmit his solid preference TRADE AND THE FLAG. 149 to Ills chuldren. Ihey will carry on their father's demand only in so far as he has been able to modify the environment in which they live. They may retain a sentimental pre- ference ; but the goods which really suit them are those pro- duced in their native countrv'. The habits and the business methods of the second generation are the habits and the business methods of the country. It is, of course, possible that a continuous influx of settlers may keep the business methods, as well as the habits and customs, of the colony the same as those of the mother-land, especially when no other example is kept steadily before them ; and this may be part of the reason why Australia buys more from the mother country than Canada does. To' a large and increasing ex- tent, in matters of trade, Canadians are Americans. Cana- dian business methods are American rather than English, and when Canadian and Englishman trade there is apt to arise a certain irritation due to difference of business methods. American firms make no difficulty about sending goods on approrval or even on credit into Canada. English firms, in the absence of references, require cash with order; and at the moment of writing a first-class London furnishing house has had the writer's cash with order for twelve months and the goods are still undelivered.^ If one wished to enter into a competition in epigram it would be possible to contend that trade follows the citizen instead of the flag. And it follows him to the ends of the earth, no matter under what flag he may range himself. The German carries with him his German tastes and customs, and the delicatessen shop is as common in New York as in Berlin. The French in Mauritius continue to buy largely from France and the English in the United States are among the best customers for English manufacturers. ' 'This greater rigour is probably in part the cause of the fact that Canada imports nearly four times as much by parcel post from the United States as from England. 150 TKADE AND THE FLAG. The Dutch at the Cape and the French in Canada are ex- ' ceptions to the rule; but they are exceptions only because the simplicity of their tastes and their poverty prevent them from being consumers of the characteristic exports of the far distant and separated mother countries. French colonies which have long been French buy more largely of French goods than the newer acquisitions ; and the reason is that there is no such body of resident Frenchmen in Cochin China -' as in the island of Reunion. German trade with German colo- ." nies may be small ; but German exports to Germans under J foreign flags represent a large amount of trade. There has been a great deal of emigration from Germany to Southern Brazil and the La Plate Republics ; and as a consequence \ the trade of Southern Brazil is almost entirely in German hands. ^ But it is in German hands not so much because of the special aptitude of Germans for commerce but because the 250,000 settlers " welche durchweg ihre Naiionalita bewahrt haben " have retained their German tastes, unmodi- fied by the social environment of the lower races surrounding \ them, and modified only the differences of the physical en- | vironment. \ The conditions of trade are complicated, and it might be expected that this relation could not be demonstrated with ! statistical exactness. We have to take into account not only the industrial relations of the two countries and the movement of capital between them; but we must also consider the effects of hostile tariffs, of the nearness of other markets, and the modification of demand which arises from the proximity of other influences than those of the mother country. An ' Englishman in Canada is dwarfed by the proximity of the United States as an Englishman in Australia need not be. We must also consider how demand is affected by the volume of existing sentiment in favour of the goods of the mother | iSchonbergs Handbuch, II, pagre 1105. I TRADE AND THE FLAG. 151 country. The English emigrant who goes to the United States reinforces a larger demand for English goods than the Eng- lishman who goes to Canada. For there are six or seven times as many people of British birth in the United States as there are in Canada. Again, the wealth of the commu- nity has much to do with the goods it imports. The charac- ter of the exports from the United Kingdom to other civi- lised communities is in the main that of highly manufactured articles of comfort and luxury. The necessaries of life and in- dustry each nation and people supplies from its own resources or else imports them from less advanced nations. Therefore, a wealthy community will be likely to make an intenser de- mand for English goods. The French Canadian has few wants which it is possible for him to supply from France, be- cause the characteristic exports of France do not come within his means. But the French colony in British Mauritius, though even more completely isolated by distance from the mother France, does make a large demand because it can afford to buy largely of French goods to suit the tastes of the local French oligarchy. In spite of the sentimental inclination which French Canada has for France, there is but little in common between the French Canadian and the French. Canada may establish commercial treaties with France ; but she imports but little from France, barely half of what she takes from Germany. The relative volumes of imports from France and from Ger- many are as follows : — 1875. 1885. 1895. % of total % of total % of tola 1 Imports. Imports. Imports. France $1,941,298. i '68. $1,935,381. r88. $2,585,174. 2-46, Germany 748,423. 063. 2,121,269. 2-07. 4.794,159. 4-56. Mauritius buys largely from France, although France is not to 152 TRADE AND THE FLAG. any extent a purchaser of Mauritius products. Goods were imported in 1890 to the value of Rs.2,450,789 from France; or about one-seventh of a total importation of Rs. 16, 7 02,8 18. The imports from France were made up chiefly of Boots and Shoes, Dry Goods, Wines and Manures. It is possible that a portion of this volume of imports is re-exported to the island of Reunion, which is, as Leroy Beaulieu says (De la Coloni- sation, &c., p. 242), en quelle sorte dependante de Maurice pour sou commerce. Reunion takes about one-third of its im- ports from France, 1 873-1 882, annual average from France, 8,737,244 frs., and from foreign countries 15,858,000 frs. France reserves a preference for her own trade and besides expends about ;^i 70,000 per annum in the service of the island. It is perhaps both an effect and a cause of the large importations into Mauritius from France that the British colony is mainly dependent for her commerce on French steamship lines. But notwithstanding the number of conditions which have to be taken into account, it is astonishing how closely the figures of trade correspond to the maxim that trade follows the citizen. When we compare the imports of British produce, into New Zealand, Australia, Canada and the United States with the percentage of the British born inhabitants of these countries we find a considerable degree of correspondence, as the following table shows. The figures are for the last census year : — New Zealand. Australia. Canada. U. States. Total Imports ... £6,2^0,000 ^33, 555. ooo' $119,967,000 $844,196,000 Imports of British Produce ... 4,221,000 23,934,000 42,048,000 194,723,000 Per cent, of British to Total ... 66 71 35 23 Total Population 2,151,000 3,179,000 4,829,000 66 62j,ooo J British Born Population ... 626^000 475,000 2,772,000 Per cent, of Total 30 27' 9 4 1 Exclusive of Imports from other Australian colonies. -Partly estimated. TRADE AND THE FLAG. 153 The correspondence is not only close but it is easy to make allowance for disturbing causes. New Zealand is, to a cer- tain extent, economically dependent on Australia. She im- ports 17 per cent, of her total imports from Australia, while Australia derives but 5 per cent, of her imports from New Zealand. The disturbing influence of the proximity of Aus- tralia in the percentages is obvious. And in the case of Canada, the sam.e explanation is available to account for the fact that Canada takes less in proportion than the United States does. If further explanation of this difference between Canada and the United States is sought it may be found in the greater wealth of the United States. British- goods ex- ported to Canada and to the United States are toi a large extent expensive manufactured goods, textiles in large degree. But if it were possible to consider each country separately, at its different census periods, we might eliminate most of the causes of variation from the normal. Canada's position rela- tively to the United States and the United Kingdom changes but slowly, as manners and customs change and the means of communication are developed. The only changes of impor- tance from decade toi decade are tariff changes, and for these we can allow. Owing to the dearth of statistical information at hand it has been impossible for me to work out this idea with regard to Australia and New Zealand. But the irv- stances of Canada and the United States will sene to illus- trate further the maxim that trade follows the citizen. Changes in 'the percentage of British bom citizens are re- flected in changes in the imports of British produce. The average tariff rate in Canada in the various census years is appended as given in Maclean's Tariff" History of Canada, p. 47 : — Imports of Imports of British Prop, of .Average British B P. Total born British rate of Produce. per head. Population. Population. born. Tariff. I86I $20,386,000 $8-io 2,507,000 3.14.000 1330 20 187 1 49,286,000 '413 3,485,000 485,000 i3"9' 19.7 i88r 42,583,000 1077 4,324,000 470,000 10-87 24*5 1891 42,047,000 8 -80 4,833,000 475,000 987 3i"4 > Ontario and Quebec only. 154 TRADE AND THE FLAG. '4 The variations from the normal are but slight and no greater than may be fairly accounted for by the changes in the tariff. On the basis of the figures of 187 1, the importation of British produce into Canada should have been in 1881 $10.90 instead of the $10.77 per head which stands in the table. But, in the meantime, the tariff had risen from 19 to 24 per cent. Similarly in 1891 Canada should have taken $10.00 per head instead of merely 8.80; but in the twenty years the tariff had risen from 19.7 per cent, to 31.4 per cent. When we take the corresponding figures for the United States we get practically the same result: — kl Imports of B. P. per British head of Total Produce, total Pop. Population. Population. to Total. Taritt.i .^ i860 ;^22,ooo,ooo...$3-5o 31,443,321 1870 28,335,000... 3-60 38,55*^071 1880 30,885,000... 3-00 50,155,783 1890 32,068,000... 2*50 66,622,250 In this case, as might have been expected from the grow- ing weaJth of the country and the steadily growing influence of English ideas, the imports of British produce increase faster than the number of British bom population. If the consumption had been in strict conformity to the dictum that trade follows the citizen we should have found that the per capita consumption, on the basis of the figures of i860, in 1870 would have been $3.1 per head instead of $3.6: in 1880 $2.8 per head instead of $3.0 ; and in 1890 $2.4 instead of $2.5. But the variation is slight, although the increase in the tariff undoubtedly restricted importation and made the consumption of British produce per head of the p>opulation less than it would otherwise have been. The variation is in the direction one would have expected in a rich country with a growing nucleus of British born citizens. 'Taussig- : The Tariff History of the United States. Appendix, Tabic I. British Prop, of born Brit, born Average Population. to Total. Tariff.! 2,199,079 6-9 1967 2,626,241 6-2 47-16 2,772,169 5*5 43"<5 3,122,911 4-8 44 '4 TRADE AND THE FLAG. 155 It may seem little creditable to the English born Canadian that he takes but $io worth of English goods while the emigrant to the United States takes ^lo worth. But the difference is in part due to a difference in the relative wealth of Canada and the United States, and in part to the fact that the absolute, as distinguished from the relative! amount of British prejudice and custom and taste as embodied in British bom citizens, is much greater in the United States than in Canada. The difference, moreover, will not justify us in regarding it as a matter of congratulation thati the British emigrant seeks the United States rather than Canada; for it is to be hoped that we all have got beyond the notion that the sole object of a colonial system is to raise up a nation of customers. In conclusion, it may be said that trade follows the flag if the flag may be extended to cover both the capital and the labour which emigrate. Labour does not seem to follow the flag. It rather follows prosperity. Capital is more in- clined to keep within national boundaries ; and the greater mobility of capital in the direction of the colonies gives the maxim trade follows the flag whatever support it has in the facts. THE END. SOCIAL SCIENCE SERIES, SCARLET CLOTH, EACH 2s. (>a/cer. 38. Collectivism and Socialism. By A. Nacquet. Edited by W. Heaford. " An admirable criticism by a well-known French politician of the New Socialism of Marx and Lassalle."- Daiiy ChronicU. SOCIAL SCIENCE SERIES— {Continued). 39. Tho London Prograrama. Sfdnby Webb, LL.B. " lirinirul of excellent ideiS." — Anti-Jacobin. 40. The Modern Stata. Paul Leroy Beaclieu. "A mu3t iiilfre?',ing book; well worth a place In the library of every social iiKluirer." — A'. B. tconomat. 41. The Condition of Labour. He.suv Georqb. " \\ ritteu with striking aliility, aiiU sure to attract attention." — A>aca»(i< Chronicle. 42. Tho Revolutionary Spirit preceding the French Revolution. Felix KocQUAiN. With a Preface by Profeaaor Huxley. ' The student of tlie French Revolution will dnd in it an excellent introduction to the study of that catastrophe."— •ScoUman. 43. The Student's Marx. Edward Avelino, D.So. "One of tlie most practically useful of any in the Series."— O/aj^ow Herald. 44. A Short History of Parliament. B. C. Skottowe, M.A. (Oxon.). " Deals very carefully ami completely with this side of constitutional history."— Spti'tidor. 45. Poverty: Us Genesis and Exodus. J. G. Godard. " He states the problems with ^i:exi force and clearness '"- *V. B. Ecoaonntl. 46. The Trade Policy of Imperial Federation. Maurice H. Hervet. " Xn inteiestiiig oiicribution to the discussion. '—Pv-hliihtrt' Circular. 47. The Dawn of Radicalism. J- Bowles Daly, LL.D. " Forms an admirable picture of an epoch more presnant, perhaps, with political instruction than any other in the world's history "—Z)eu;^ TtU^;ra}li. 48. Tho Destitute Allen in Great Erltaln. Arnold White ; Montague Crackak- THORPE, Q.C. ; W. A. M'Arthur, M.P.; W. H. Wilkins, &o. "JIuch valuable information concerning a burning uuestion of the day."— Timi*. 49. Illegitimacy and the Influence of Seasons on Conduct. Albert Leffinowell, M.D. We have not often seen a work based on statistics which i» more continuously interesting."— lKes 61. The State and Pensions in Old Age. J. A. Spender and Arthur Acland, M.P. " A careful and cautious examination of the question. '—riiiifs. 62. The Fallacy of Saving. John M. Eobertson. " A plea for the reorganisatio.n of our social and industrial system "Speaker. 63. The Irish Peasant. Anon. 'A real contribution to the Irish Problem by a close, patient and dispassionate investigator."— Z)oi/i/ Cliromde. 64. The Effects of Machinery on Wages. Prof. J. S. Nicholson, D.So. "Ably reasoned, clearly stated, impartially written."— Lif«rari/ World. 65. The Social Horizon. Anon. " A really admirable little book, bright, clear, and unconventionaL"— £>aifj/ Chronicle. 66. Socialism, Utopian and Scientific. Frederick Enoels. "The body of the book is still fresh and striking."— KaiVj/ Chronicle. 67. Land Nationalisation. A. R. Wallace. "The most instructive and convincing of the popular works on the subject."— National Refnrmer. Sa The Ethic of Usury and Interest. Rev. W. Blissard. "The work is marked by genuine ability "—.Vo)-tA British Agriculturalist. 59. The Emancipation of Women. Adele Crepaz. " By far the most comprehensive, luminous, and penetrating work on this question that I have yet met ^tilh."— Extract jrom Jlr. Gladstone's Prrface. 60. The Eight Hours' Question. John M. Robertson. "A very cogent and sustained argument on what is at piesunt the unpopular side." — Times. 61. Drunkenness. Geokge R. Wilson, M.B. " Well written, c-jrefully reasoned, free from cant, and full of souml sense."— National Observer. 62. The New Reformation. Ramsden BALMFORxn. " A striking presentation of the nascent religion, how best to realize the person.-U and social ideal. " — Westminster Review, 63 The Agricultural Labourer. T. E. Kedbivw "A short summary of his position, with appendices on wages, education, allov ments, etc., etc." 64. Ferdinand Lassalle as a Social Reformer. E. Bernstein. '• A worthy addition to the Social Science Series."— A'ort/i British Bconomitl. SOCIAL SCIENCE SERIES— {Continued}. 81. 82. 83. 84. 87. 83. 89. 90. 91. 92^ 93. 94. England's Foreign Trade In XlXth Century. A. L. Bowlev,. " FuU of valuable information, carefully compiled." — TimM. Theory and Policy of Labour Protection. Dr. Schaffle. " An attempt to systematize a conservative programme of reform."— ^/an. Guard.. History of Rochdale Pioneers. G. J. Holioake. " Brought down from 1844 to the Rochdale Congress of 1892."— Co-Op. A'tico. Rights of Women. M. Osth.^oorski. "An aiimirable storehouse of precedents, conveniently arran;;ed" — Z)ai7|/ Chron. Dwellings of the People. Locke WoRTniNOToN. "A valuable contribution to one of the most pressing prcblems of the Jay." — Daily Chronicle. Hours, Wages, and Production. Dr. Buentano. "Characterised by all Pvotessor Brentano's clearness of style."— Economic Review. Rise of Modern Democracy. Ch. Bokgeaud. "A very useful little vnlume, characterised by exact research." — Daily Chronicle. Land Systems of Australasia. Wjr. Epps. " Exceedingly valualjle at the present time of depression and difficulty." — Scots. Mag. The Tyranny of Socialism. Y es Guvot. Pref. b}- J. H. Levy. "M. Guyot is smart, lively, trenchant, and interesting."— X)«.iiv Chronicle. Population and the Social System. Dr. Nith. " A very valuable work of an Italian economist."— West. Rev. The Labour Question. T. G. Spyeks. " Will be found extremely useful."— Tir/KJ. British Freewomsn, C. C. Stopes. " The most complete study of the Women's Suffrage question." --£rt(7'i3'i Worn. Rev. Suicide anb Insanity. Dr. J. K. Stbahan. " An interestesting monograph dealing exhaustively with the subject."— TinK*. A History of Tithes. Rev. H. W. Clarke. " May be recommended to all who desire an accurate idea of the subject."— 0. Chron. Three Months in a Workshop. P. Gohre, with Pref. by Prof. Ely. " .A. vivid picture of the statt, tjf mind of German workmen."— .Uaric^. Guard. Darwinism and Race Progress. Prof. J. B. Haycbaft. "An interesting subject treated in an attractive fashion." — Glasgoic^erald. Local Taxation and Finance. Perils to British Trade. The Social Contract. Labour upon the Land. Moral Pathology. Parasitism, Organic and Soci-"' Allotments and Small Holdings. Money and its Relations to Pric? Sober by Act of Parliament. Workers on their Industries. Revolution and Counter-RsYoIution. Over-Productiou and Crises. Local GoYcrnmant and State Aid. Anglo-American Trade. G. H. Blunden. E. BuRois. J J. PiuUfsEAU. Ec^ited by H. J. Tozer. Ivdited by J. A. Hobson, M.A. Arthur B. Giles, M.D., B.Sc. Ma«;sart and Vanuervelde. J. L. Green. L. L. Price. A. Mackenzu:. F. W. Galton. Karl Marx. k. eodbertus. S. J. Chapman. S. J. Chapjlan. F. lES, 3S. 6d. DOUBLE VOLUi 1. Life of Robert Owen. Lloyd Jones. 2. The Impossibility of Social Democracy: a Second Part of " The Quintessence of Socialism ". Dr. A. Schaffle. 3. Condition of the Working Class in England in 1844. Fkedebick Engels. 4. The Principles of Social Economy. Yves Guy'OT. 5. Social Peace. G. von Schultze-Gae\'ernitz. 6. A Handbook of Socialism. W. D P. Bliss. 7. Socialism: its Growth and Outcome. W. Morris and E. B. Bax. 8. Economic Foundations of Society. A. Lokia. SWAN SONNENSCHEIN & CO., Lim., LONDON. NEW YORK : CHARLES SCRIBNER'S SONS. 3 1158 01272 1915 ucsniiT HFRN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACIUTY AA 001 006 437 6