PUBLIC RELIEF OF THE POOR SIX LECTURES PUBLIC RELIEF OF THE POOR SIX LECTURES BY THOMAS MACKAY I AUTHOR OF "THE ENGLISH POOR," ETC. UNIVERSITY . LONDON JOHN MURRAY, ALBEMARLE STREET, W. 1901 PREFACE THE following pages are the substance of six lectures delivered at the Church House, West- minster, at the invitation of the "Joint Lectures Committee," during the winter 1900-1901. Although much has been written about the relief of the poor, no work, as far as the author is aware, covers the precise ground traversed in this volume. The treatment of the subject is theoretical rather than practical. If the author is right in his conviction that pauperism and dependence among the poorer classes are largely artificial and unnecessary conditions, certain practical conclusions naturally follow, but there is really no difficulty in adopting the policy indicated. What is wanting to secure the great reformation which lies within reach, is a reasoned conviction of the possibility of dispauperisation. The object of these lectures was to present the arguments which seemed to establish this proposition, and to leave its vi PREFACE practical application to the common sense of those who are responsible for the administration of public relief. A strong conviction of the justice of certain views naturally leads to a belief that a fair hearing will secure their general acceptance, and it is hoped that these pages may do something to overcome the indifference and prejudice of public opinion, which regards the whole question as incapable of amendment. In this sense, and in connection with this subject, a correct theory is the most practical thing in the world ; for if the possibility of dispauperisation be once established, the details of administration present very little difficulty. The details of a dispauperising administration have been set out in many handbooks, and have been shown to justify themselves by the results. To some minds the force of a general principle has more authority, and to them the following attempt to analyse the economic significance of pauperism and dependence is specially addressed. CONTENTS CHAP. PAGE INTRODUCTORY ... . I I. THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW l8 II. THE OLD POOR LAW ... 35 III. THE POOR LAW AMENDMENT ACT OF 1834, COM- MONLY CALLED "THE NEW POOR LAW" . . 69 IV. THE ADMINISTRATION OF THE NEW POOR LAW . . IOI V. THE RELATION BETWEEN LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY AGENCIES OF RELIEF 139 VI. THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 176 PUBLIC RELIEF OF THE POOR IN ENGLAND INTRODUCTORY BEFORE we can justly appreciate the importance of a good system of public relief, we must endeavour to understand how very limited an influence it has in_jpj^ompting a healthy orgaji- isation ___o_s.Qiety . The necessity of relief is evidence of stunted growth or social disorder. Medical treatment, skilfully applied, may remove the causes of physical disease, but relief is only a treatment of symptoms : it never touches, except to aggravate them, the economic causes of poverty and destitution. It is necessary, at the very outset, to insist on this subordinate importance of relief. Other- wise it is impossible to form a right judgment as to the true relation of social well-being to 2 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND public relief. For this reason, a fuller ex- position of this aspect of the subject will not be out of place. That admirable writer and thinker Dr Chalmers was fond of urging that there is what he called " a previous and better mechanism of society," that is to say, previous to, and better than, any system of public relief. Chalmers meant, first, that the ordinary economic exchange of services and property gives to members of society an honourable interdepend- ence and coherence with which a system of public relief tends to interfere ; further, that if this purely economic organisation fails at any point, there is a second line of defence, namely, the natural affection of the family and the benevolence arising out of ordinary human intercourse. To this " previous and better mechanism " Chalmers was anxious to entrust the treatment of social misfortune, and he deprecated altogether the recourse to elaborate systems of public relief; most emphatically of all he objected to compulsory levies for the relief of the poor. In the light of modern speculations on the origins of society, Dr Chalmers' definition may admit of amendment. The superior mechanism to which he refers is not perhaps earlier or INTRODUCTORY 3 previous in point of time. It is rather con- current in the sense of being competitive with a primitive condition which it is superseding. It is an illuminating generalisation of Maine that the progress of civil society has been, and still is, from a condition of status to one of contract* Our social organisation is the result of the struggle between these opposing influences. On the one hand we have the better mechanism, the new contractual basis of society, founded on personal liberty, property, and exchange ; on the other hand the feudal, and subsequently the parochial, status of de- pendence which the better mechanism is re- placing. Public relief is, in fact, a relic of the condition of status. We should vary, therefore, Dr Chalmers' language by describing the ordinary exchange of services and property, supplemented in case of need by family affection and natural benevolence, as a better mechanism which furnishes the modern economic alternative to the primitive dependence of a condition of status. As a preliminary to forming a judgment on systems of relief, we ought to make some study of the interaction of these two social principles. Even a superficial consideration will make us * Maine's Ancient Law, 8th edition, p. 170. 4 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND aware of influences which promote the growth of the independent industrial life, and of influences also which prevent the decay of the status of pauperism. We must, there- fore, follow this clue somewhat further, and regard our social organisation as a whole, its history, the principles by which it has grown, the primitive and less favourable conditions out of which it has been developed, and which still linger to the detriment of sections of the community. To state the line of study suggested, in terms strictly relevant to our present enquiry, we have to consider the causes, on the one hand, of the progress of wealth, and, on the other, of the permanence of poverty and other primitive disabilities. If we would understand the present, we must then, as Mr Bagehot has happily phrased it, study man as an antiquity. Time was when economic speculation overlooked this necessity, and dealt largely in plausible but unverifiable assumptions about the origin of society. There were days when men talked of the Social Contract and assumed the primitive perfection of the natural man. The position to-day is for the serious student entirely changed. The necessity of the historical method is everywhere acknowledged. Correct theory is indeed the most useful and INTRODUCTORY 5 practical thing in the world, but correct theory can only be reached by the aid of careful verifica- tion from the facts of history. Most of us if I may judge by my own experience were taught some little history in our youth, but for the most part in the anecdotal fashion. We read of the adventures of Alfred, of the wars of the Edwards, of the many marriages of Henry VIII., but the fact the most important fact that during the greater part of that time the poorer population were serfs, was very little obtruded on our notice. The Poor Law of Elizabeth is generally represented to us as a happy inspiration of the Queen and her coun- cillors, and not as what it undoubtedly was^ revival in a modified form of the then expiring *- * ~ * ff feudal system. We cannot, here, discuss in detail the village community, the feudal system, serfdom and the gradual emancipation of the serf. The inquiry must be pursued in the works of Seebohm, Maine, Stubbs, and other scholars. We are justified, however, in asserting that the primitive condition of society in England, as well as elsewhere, was by no means one of wealth and freedom, but rather of poverty and subjection, and by these terms we mean all the disabilities belonging to that condition. Men suffered not only from insufficiency of food 6 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND and raiment and shelter, but also from the fact that they were a prey to the elemental forces of nature, then unsubdued and little understood, as well as to the tyranny of their own superstition and of the rigid ordinance of custom. In their relation to their fellow-men, they were the victims of a reign of cruelty and antagonism un- redeemed by any appreciation of the advantages which subsequent generations have derived from a co-operation based on exchange of property and service and on the sub-division of labour. Too often the problem of poverty has been presented to us as one requiring an explanation of how the poor have fallen away from some original condition of comfort which existed in an earlier golden age. This view does not appear to rest on any solid foundation of fact or theory. Whether or not there is any perfectibility of society in the future, there has been no state of perfection in the past. What we have to explain is, how a portion of the population (if we are not justified in saying the whole population) has suc- ceeded in clothing its nakedness with the material advantages of civilisation ; and with regard to poverty, our inquiry is not how classes have become poor from having at one time been rich, but how classes have remained poor, unable to rise or at least to rise far above the proletariate INTRODUCTORY 7 life of ever imminent destitution in which once nearly the whole population was involved. Before, then, we can come to any opinion of the best methods to be adopted by the com- munity for the relief of the unfortunate, or of the claim sometimes put forward on behalf of the proletariate, that it has a right to help itself to the property of the richer section of society, two important lines of causality have to be con- sidered. I. What are the essential elements of that economic progress, such as it is, which has, with- out doubt, conferred on a large and probably an increasing portion of civil society so much prosperity and contentment ? II. What are the conditions which have retained another section in a state of primitive poverty ? There are, of course, many subsidiary ques- tions which might be raised at this point. Two only need be noticed and then set aside, as far as our present inquiry is concerned. Are the rich, it is asked, growing richer, and the poor growing poorer ? And, if so, do the revolutionary recon- structions of society, which are proposed as remedy, offer reasonable prospect of amending this deplorable condition of things ? In answer to the first of these questions, we can only 8 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND refer to the statisticians, who are unanimous in asserting that the material condition of the labouring class has been progressively improving without serious interruption within historical times. Here, for instance, is a recent pronouncement of Sir Robert Giffen, Economic Journal, September 1900, p. 299 : " The conditions of prosperity in this country are generally stable, and this view, it may be added, appears to be confirmed by experience. The conditions of our prosperity, such as they are, have existed for about two hundred years at least, in which national and individual prosperity have gone on increasing, and increasing apparently at an even greater rate in the most recent periods than at earlier dates." Then, in answer to a critic who suggested that the period of the Napoleonic wars was a period of retrogression, he says that, even admitting temporary fluctuations which I gather he thinks are generally exaggerated there is no room to doubt that on the average there has been no retrogression at the beginning of the century or any other time, and further, that the improve- ment has included all classes.* It is, perhaps, necessary to add that material * The subject is treated in great detail in Leroy Beaulieu's Repartition des Richesses, and the reader may judge very well for himself as to the nature and extent of the improvement by reference to such works as Ludlow and Lloyd Jones on The Progress of the Working Class, 1867, and to such Reports as that of Mr Chad wick on the Sanitary Condition of the Labouring Population, 1842. INTRODUCTORY 9 prosperity is not the same thing as happiness, and that if the question was : Are the poor happier ? it might be difficult to give a decided answer. Happiness is a thing strangely independent at times of material conditions, and it is these alone which we are now considering. In answer to the second question, as to the possibility of revolutionary change, obviously, if the statisticians are right, there is a strong presumption in favour of trusting to the slow tendency towards greater equality of condition which is already in operation, and against having resort to revolutionary experiment. If the statisticians are wrong, it may be that the imperfections which we notice are incapable of complete reformation, and that we ought to submit to them rather than destroy a fabric which, such as it is, does afford to many a great measure of prosperity and contentment. The projecting of Utopias has been a favourite pastime with the ingenious and benevolent in all ages, and we might unanswerably base our reluctance to embark in any wholesale experi- ment of the kind by pointing to the universal fate of all such attempts namely, failure. Our power to conceive Utopias is, indeed, entirely dependent on our appreciation of the happier conditions of life which already actually prevail io PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND among portions of the populations, as the result of social principles which are actual and not Utopian. We cannot permanently realise these happier conditions, arbitrarily and per saltum, without adopting also the principles on which they are founded, and in grasping by revolutionary devices at these higher ideals, we run the risk of losing the substance of much prosperity for a futile snatch at what will probably prove to be a shadow. Long ago Aristotle remarked that not the gods themselves could now alter the fact that Troy was sacked, and it appears to me that we are much in the same position with regard to the architecture and building of society. Whether we like it or not, the fabric of society has grown up round the support of certain fundamental principles. These principles are not, of course, absolutely rigid and immutable ; they have been, and are, subject to expansion and modification ; but viewing the history of their development as a whole, we find that their main tendency is definite and unmistakable. Society has moved through a long series of ages, slowly, but, as we can now trace, with unerring precision, from communism of property to private owner- ship, from slavery to personal liberty, and from the subordination of all ranks under the yoke INTRODUCTORY 1 1 of custom to the greater mobility of a society organised on the basis of contract and exchange. We could not attain, and even if we could attain, we could not permanently retain, the advantages resulting from the working of these social tendencies, if we discarded the principles which have given them birth. I make these observations because, in the inquiry on which we have embarked, we must decline to be led aside in order to consider proposals for revolutionary changes ; such changes, for instance, as the abolition of private property, the prohibition of private initiative, the substitution of a State monopoly in place of freedom of manufacture and commerce, or the levelling up of the condition of the poorer classes by devices designed to confer on the " have nots " the right to live on the taxation of the "haves." The whole history of society testifies to the deep- rooted repugnance which human nature has at all times shown to such schemes, when brought into practical contact with them, and it is not to be thought that we, in our brief flitting across the stage of life, can alter the verdict of all previous time. If, then, we must dismiss revolutionary recon- structions from our view, is it necessary for us to acquiesce in all the disabilities and wrongs of the 12 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND present situation ? This, of course, is not the view of any reasonable man. We are thus brought back to the twofold inquiry which we propounded a few pages back. Its importance warrants us, as we return from this digression, in restating the problem in slightly varied terms. I. What are the instruments and arts of economic progress which have reared the fabric of civilised society, and given to a portion of the community many indubitable advantages? II. What are the obstacles which forbid to the poorer class the use of these instruments and the practice of these arts ? This second question may happily be further qualified, for we shall find that already progress has been made, that the arts of thriving are not wholly unknown to the labouring class, that they have availed themselves of the privilege of personal liberty, the security of property, and the advantages of exchange. The problem, therefore, before us, in so far as our object is a practical one, is not to inaugurate any new social principle, but, on the one hand, to quicken and extend certain salutary lines of effort, and, on the other hand, to dissipate and remove certain prejudices and habits of primitive origin which stand in the way of a complete permeation of a proletariate class with the instincts of property. INTRODUCTORY 13 These considerations seem to suggest that if we regard this subject not merely as students, but as practical reformers, it will not do for us to confine our efforts to the administration of relief. We must devote some of our time and energy to understand and explain what are the arts of well- being. We must endeavour to vindicate their usefulness and equity, to make their practice attractive, to prove and teach that the conditions which give security (and security is the principal material element in civilisation) to the rich are capable of conferring the same benefit on the poor, and that the connection supposed by some to exist between poverty and manual labour is not a necessary one. By a neglect of this twofold aspect of the question we are apt to assume too readily that periodic destitution is an inevitable incident in the life of the labourer. Against this attitude of despair we most earnestly protest. Death and sickness are inevitable incidents in human life, but destitution is economically avoidable. Its avoidance depends on two things : the quickened economic competence of our in- dustrial population, and the relaxation of the primitive feudal status of servitude which, as the pauper habit, still lingers in our midst, arresting progress and development. 14 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND Even as things are at present, it would seem, if we may trust the conclusions of Sir Robert Giffen, that the progressive influences tend, on the average, to prevail over the retrogressive influences ; but it must be confessed that economic influences of improvement are little aided by intelligent assent and co-operation. It is our duty, we submit, to see that this favourable balance of power is maintained, and that, if possible, the attractiveness of the contractual economic life is increased, and that our system of public relief shall not become unduly absorbent of a dependent population. We must in fact recognise that there are constructive and obstruc- tive influences at work. For the great popula- tions and complex industrial interests of modern civilisation, well-being cannot rest on any system of public relief, but on ubiquitous, automatically working principles of social intercourse. Relief, then, cannot be socially constructive, and we must be at pains to see that it does not become an obstructive influence to the true line of economic development which, freed from its interference, would be more rapid and inevit- able. Before we can appreciate the uses and abuses of systems of public relief, we ought to get firmly into our minds the antagonism of these INTRODUCTORY 15 two principles. The keynote of the one is personal liberty, involving personal responsibility, property, and free exchange ; of the other, the irresponsibility of parochial status, the com- munism of the poor-rate, and the forced circula- tion of money by taxation and State monopoly. Each of these principles is creative or absorbent of a population appropriate to itself. Our busi- ness is to secure a free outlet for the true con- structive forces of social life, and to lessen the retentive paralysing power of man's primitive immobility and indolence, characteristics of mind which are apt to be impervious to the beneficent action of economic motive. So much is to be said for that concurrent and better mechanism which, if successfully developed, might, it is hoped, make systems of relief, if not altogether unnecessary, at least much less pro- minent elements in our social arrangements than unfortunately they are at present. I hope that in these pages it may be possible to keep in view this subordinate character of systems of public relief, as of a thing that is in course of being replaced by a better mechanism. The line of exposition which it is proposed to follow may now be mapped out. In the first chapter the origin of our English Poor Law, a very important 16 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND part of our system of public relief, is discussed. In the two following chapters (II. and III.), it is proposed to set out how the principle of a compulsory assessment for the poor was, in England, developed and extended till it grew into the abuses of the Old Poor Law, a state of things which called for drastic amendment in the year 1834. The New Poor Law, as it has ever since been called, was then introduced our present system. Some account of its history, its merits and dements, will be given in Chapter IV. Chapter V. will be devoted to considering the relations which obtain, or which ought to obtain, between legal and voluntary agencies of relief. In the sixth and last chapter an endeavour will be made to estimate the direction in which things seem to be drifting at the present time. We have already reached a position from which we can see that there is a concurrent and better mechanism which promises a fuller amendment of social evils than any system of public de- pendence. This requires to be quickened and safeguarded, and when we have considered, in the detailed manner proposed, the history and practice of our English system of relief, we shall be able to say how far this has been, and can be, kept in its subordinate place, and prevented from INTRODUCTORY interfering detrimentally with the healthy develop- ment of a society in which family and individual life must learn to be self-supporting and honour- ably interdependent. In the earlier chapters we shall have been encumbered with details, and the subject of relief will unavoidably appear to grow in importance. It will be an object of the last chapter, therefore, to bring back the various parts into proper pro- portion; to remind the reader when taking leave of the subject, as we do when we begin, that relief is not a constructive force of social well-being, and that, if not carefully ordered, it has been, and still may be, an obstructive influence to sound economic progress. B CHAPTER I THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW THE origin of our English system of Poor Law relief is to be found in causes, some of which are common to human nature, while others are special and peculiar to this country. In all societies there are inequalities of fortune, and when wealth has advanced to a certain point, there has arisen, on the part of the well-to-do, a desire to make some provision for the destitute. Feudalism, from which an integral part (the law of settlement,) of our Poor Law system is derived, is not of course a distinctively English institution, but the conversion of a rem- nant of the expiring feudal system into a Poor Law is peculiar to this country, and characteristic of the continuity of English polity. The facts which we must endeavour to divest of technicalities may be briefly stated. The manorial and other feudal courts which presided over the life of a semi-servile population 18 CHAP, i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 19 exercised incidentally certain powers of relief. Originally this jurisdiction was for the enforce- ment of a certain organisation of labour, based on the complete adscription of the labourer to the \ soil. In prescribing duties, it also prescribed 1 maintenance. For instance, one of the duties assumed by the manorial courts was the super- intendence of the re-marriage of widows. The object of this was, no doubt, to procure the perfor- mance of service-dues, but incidentally it brought about a provision for the widow and her children. Very early, however, the eleemosynary duties of the community were directed by the Church. From the earliest times there were charitable endowments, and by custom a portion of the parish tithe was devoted to the relief of the poor. In feudal times all England was mapped out into manors, and from the ecclesiastical and eleemosy- nary point of view, the manor was the parish, and ever since the days of Elizabeth the parish (or, as now, the union of parishes) has been the Poor Law unit of administration. Within the same areas there were, therefore, two jurisdictions : the manorial courts, repressing vagrancy and enforcing feudal servitude, and the ecclesiastical jurisdiction, ad- ministering certain charitable funds. In course of time these funds proved insufficient, and voluntary offerings were invited. The curate was then to 20 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. demand contributions. Then, as this plan was unsuccessful, the bishop was called in to admonish, and next the justices were directed to assess and enforce payment. Finally, at the end of the reign of Elizabeth, in 1597, and in 16,01 by. the -great i consolidating statute of the 43 Eliz. c. 2, the first / universal compulsory poor rate was enacted, and overseers were appointed who, with the church- wardens, became the authority for administering the relief of the poor. Side by side with this, the benevolent, aspect of the Poor Law, and applicable in the same area, the manor or parish, there was an expiring system of labour regulation, viz., the feudal labour organi- sation ; and here it is that our subject gains so much from the antiquarian labours of the his- torians of early custom and law. Early Poor Law legislation, prior to Elizabeth, was directed mainly to revive and enforce the expiring feudal laws.- The repression of vagrants, as the migrant labourer was called, the compelling the wanderer to return to his own place, the monopoly of trade claimed and enforced by the trade guilds of the towns, and the consequent exclusion of the migrant peasant, the forcible bringing back of the labourer to the place where his labour was due to some feudal lord, all these, though undoubtedly Poor Laws in the sense that they aimed at the " Management i.] * THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 21 of the Poor," are really attempts to revive the institution of feudal serfdom. The poorer popula- tion, which was thus "managed," had only recently been serfs, that is, persons incapable of owning property, of disposing of their labour, and of marrying and giving in marriage without the leave of their feudal superior in a word, they had been legally incapable of entertaining any economic motive whatsoever. Feudalism, in fact, forbade to the serf the use of those instruments and the practice of those arts which a few pages back we characterised as the instruments and arts of thriving. It is from this connection of the Poor Law with an older institution that we get that fatal attitude of immobility impervious to economic motive, which as we shall presently see is the characteristic of the pauper habit. The point at which the New Benevolence and the old System of Management completely coalesced is of somewhat later date, and a more detailed account of it is required. Earlier Poor Law legislation, as already said, was directed chiefly to maintaining the feudal polity. If a vagrant or a landless man was found in any manor or parish, he was not relieved ; he was punished, repressed, sent back to the place where his labour was due. There, according to the feudal ideal, it was assumed that he would 22 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. find work and maintenance, or at least be main- tained by the alms of the community. Time came, however, when a general commutation of labour services for money rents took place, a proof that servile labour, owing to changes of trade notably the rise of sheep-farming in Tudor times, was becoming inconvenient and unprofitable. It was then no longer an object with any landlord to bring back his fugitive serfs. The question then arose : Where and by whom was the emanci- pated but destitute serf to be relieved ? The answer does not at first seem to have been formulated with any definiteness, till, as the pressure on the maintenance provided by the Poor Law increased, great inconvenience arose from the uncertainty, and then the answer given was more mischievous than the former uncertainty. Dr Burn, in his History of the Poor Laws, 1764, p. 106, notes the "antiquity of settlements," erroneously supposed, as he says, to have been the invention of an Act of Charles II. (13 & 14 Charles II. c. 12). But the origin of settlements is, he shows, of much earlier date. By the Act of 12 Richard II. c. 7, the poor had been directed " to abide in cities and towns where they then were." Then, " if these cities and towns could not or would not maintain them, they were by subsequent acts of legislation to draw themselves i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 23 to other towns within the hundred, or to the towns where they were born. Next they were to abide in the hundred where they last dwelt, or were best known or were born ; then in the place where they were born or made their last abode by the space of three years. . . . And this continued for a long time. In the reign of King James I. they were to go to the place where they last dwelt by the space of one year, and if that could not be known, then to the place of their birth. Finally, by the 13 & 14 Charles II. c. 12, the place of a person's settlement was to be where he last dwelt for the space of forty days, either as a native, householder, sojourner, apprentice or servant." Forty days, Burn remarks, is a short period, and all subsequent legislation with regard to settle- ments is restrictive of this too easy method of obtaining a settlement. Indeed this very act contained provision for that purpose. It enacted that poor persons coming into a parish might be removed and taken back to their place of settlement, not because they had become, but because they might become, chargeable. This, it will be observed, is a revival of the principle of the old feudal law which provided for the complete adscription of the labourer to the soil, but with a difference in practice. Formerly the lord of 24 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the emigrant serf could have him brought back to his place of servitude. Now when that servitude was no longer profitable, the parish invaded by the immigrant serf claimed a right to drive him out. The adscription of the labourer to the soil was in both cases complete, but the interest which put the law in motion against him was different. Burn justly remarks on this law of removal that, though the chief interest centres in the Act of Charles II., it is, like the law of Settlement, of much older origin. The poor, he says, quoting a series of statutes, were first re- quired to remove themselves, to go, rest, and abide ; then, a penalty was ordained if they did not go, then they were sworn to go, and in Edward the Sixth's time they were to be conveyed. This, then, was the answer to the question : Where were the poor to be relieved ? They were to be relieved at the place of their settlement, and in order that this might be carried out conveniently, they were practically prevented from leaving the place of their settlement. They were thus formally, and by law, condemned to a complete adscription to the soil. The principle of settlement and removal, an integral and appropriate element of feudalism, was thus revived for the convenience of those who had i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 25 to administer the benevolent legislation of Eliza- beth, and it is to be observed that the economic movement which it endeavoured to repress was in reality the first stirring of the industrial era. This unfortunate conflict between a well-intended benevolence and the reorganising influence of economic motive is worth a closer examination. Just as it has been observed that slavery is a step in advance of the indiscriminate massacre of prisoners, suggested probably because of the advantage to be derived from slave labour, so also the decay of slavery has been occasioned not so much by religious and moral conviction, as by the fact that slave labour cannot compete success- fully with free labour. It is asserted on high authority (Morley : Life of Cobden, vol. i. p. 99), even with regard to modern instances of slavery, that no community has ever abolished slavery of its own accord until the institution had ceased to be profitable. This appears to be especially true with regard to the decay of feudal serfdom. It was the superiority of the new economic condi- tions of freedom of labour, contract and exchange, quite as much as religious sentiment, which disintegrated the old order of things. It is important in this connection to observe the happy results which follow from allowing the organisation of society to proceed at the bidding 26 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. of what we have termed the economic motive. On the other hand, in contrast to this purely economic development, to which we owe the ordered security of our modern industrial system, we have to consider the effect of legislation of which the motive was philanthropic, and which took the form of awarding maintenance to the status of pauperism. It will suggest to us the thought, that to follow the line of economic development with assent and co-operation is a truer philanthropy than a benevolent but empirical treatment of symptoms, which leaves untouched the deep-seated causes of arrested economic growth. The last years of the reign of Elizabeth witnessed a consolidation by statute of such a policy of frontal attack, if the phrase may be allowed, on the evil of destitution and poverty, and it is worth while to compare the results of this with the development on the lines of the economic order which it obstructed and at length brought to a stand-still. The temper of the time at the end of the sixteenth century was what we should call philan- thropic. In Sir Symonds D'Ewes' diary of Elizabethan parliaments it is narrated how sub- scriptions for the poor were collected in both Houses of Parliament, and so much compulsion i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 27 was used that the names of these who did not contribute were publicly read out (" they amounted to about forty-four "). Several Poor Law bills, and the scarcely less important Charitable Uses bill, were referred to a committee, on which Bacon, Cecil, and other Elizabethan statesmen were nominated to serve. This committee was responsible for the final shape taken by the great Poor Law statute, the 43 Eliz. c. 2, and also for the Statute of Charitable Uses, the 43 Eliz. c. 4, passed in the same year 1601. The legislature of the day clearly felt that the old feudal duties and maintenance could no longer be enforced, and that the statute of labourers and the ordinances designed to regulate wages, if operative at all, were no protection to the poorer class. Its remedy for the occasion was the Poor Law of Elizabeth (43 Eliz. c. 2). Further, in the complicated quarrel of the English nation with the Roman Church, there had been a great diversion of endowments from charitable as well as ecclesiastical uses to secular purposes. The confiscations of Henry VIII. and Edward VI. had not observed with too much nicety the distinction between the two. The legislation of the time suggests that while the ecclesiastical controversy was maintained, there was a disposi- tion to restore, and to prevent the further diversion 28 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAF. of, charitable endowments made by pious founders for various public objects other than ecclesiastical. It is always stated that the Elizabethan Statute of Charitable Uses was intended to apply to endowments for the poor only, though it is true that its protection was through analogy extended by subsequent decisions of the courts to all endow- ments, a policy which has in fact made the terms Charitable Use synonymous with Public Trust. Now it is a coincidence worthy of notice that these two statutes enacting a compulsory assess- ment for the relief of the poor, and the rigid pre- servation of endowments for the use of the poor, were passed contemporaneously, and that two centuries later an agitation was raised almost simultaneously against the abuses to which they had given rise. Contemporaneously with the discussion which led in 1834 to the reform of the Poor Law, a violent crusade, inaugurated by Lord Brougham, had been raised against the abuses of endowed charity. By that time it had become apparent that the perpetuity given by the Elizabethan Statute of Charitable Uses to the often very ill- considered wishes of pious founders was a source of abundant demoralisation and fraud. The contrast which inevitably suggests itself is, that on the one hand we have the philanthropic i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 29 legislation of Elizabeth growing in time into the intolerable abuses of the Old Poor Law, and into the frauds and demoralisation connected with endowed charity, as exposed in Lord Brougham's letter to Sir Samuel Romilly, and in the evidence brought before various commissions of inquiry. On the other hand, we have the break-up of feudalism, the new organisation of liberty and contract and free exchange forced upon us, not by sentimentalists, but by the inevitable, irre- sistible pressure of economic expediency.* The one has landed us in our present pauper system ; to the other we owe the material comfort, assured progress and security of modern civilisa- tion. In describing the complete amalgamation of * Note. By the term " inevitable, irresistible pressure of economic expediency," I mean the line of conduct resulting from the preference which men, and bodies of men, will always show for an attainment of their objects by the least effort. The " concurrence " of different policies of action makes the choice of alternatives a very important, though perhaps unconscious, episode in the lives both of individuals and societies. The economic motive, unless coerced by fraud or force, will generally be decisive at such crises of choice. The conclusion drawn is, that an intelligent following of the economic motive seems to lead most certainly to the wide-spread social satisfaction to which the sentimentalist seeks to lead us by short- cuts which too often, as in the case considered in the text, take us astray into an impassable quagmire. The ultimate identity of the ethical and economic motive is secured by the fact that the main instrument of industrial organisation is exchange, a process which gives profit to both parties. The reformation of Society requires that we shall appreciate and take advantage of this natural law. 30 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the old repressive police regulation of the poor with the new stream of benevolent relief pro- vided formally by the Elizabethan law, we named the 13 & 14 Charles II. c. 12 as the point of junction. By this Act the so-called Law of Settlements, the new relief legislation, was formally and finally grafted on to the old feudal conception of settlement, and the two lines of policy definitely coalesced. \ It is easy to understand how with the break- up of the old security of serfdom there were many houseless wanderers, and how the chari- table funds available for their relief were sub- jected to pressure. It is easy also to understand how a comparatively wealthy community agreed to tax itself to provide more funds. What might surprise us is, that this question of where and by whom each claimant for relief was to be relieved did not arise sooner, or, at all events, that no very serious attempt to deal with it was made till the time of Charles II. The explanation, I think, is, that though 1601 saw the principle of assessment made com- pulsory and universal, this law was not carried into effect with any great rapidity and certainty, and for long the sums given away were pro- bably very small. By degrees, however, the law was brought into operation, and the cir- i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 31 cumstances in which this took place are peculiar and special to England. They can be best understood by referring to the contrast of Scotland, where enactments for a compulsory assessment were passed about the same time. Even earlier than the Elizabethan legislation, i.e. in 1579, an Act, in many par- ticulars similar to the English law, was passed, and authority was given, " to tax and stent the whole inhabitants within the parish " ; but in Scotland the Act remained a dead letter, and it was not till quite modern times that a general assessment for the poor was made in Scotland ; indeed there are, even at the present day, parishes where the relief of the poor is managed without the aid of a rate. The administration of the law was confided to the Kirk- Sessions, and the weaker central administration of Scotland never enforced its execution in respect of a compulsory assessment. Many years afterwards, in 1817, a committee of the House of Commons (Sturges Bourne's Committee) was inquiring into the mismanagement of the English Poor Law, and sent to find out how such matters were conducted in Scotland. The following sentence occurs in their report : " The system (i.e. of a compulsory assessment) is peculiar to Great Britain ; and even in Scotland, where a law similar 32 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. in principle was about the same period enacted, the in- telligent persons to whom the administration of it has been intrusted, appear by a valuable report (for which your Com- mittee is indebted to the prompt exertions of the General Assembly of the Church of Scotland) to have had so much foresight and judgment as to its effects that they have generally and successfully endeavoured to avoid having recourse to a compulsory assessment." and the report of the General Assembly goes on to express its approval of the course followed. In England the central authority had more power, and " the judgment and foresight of the intelligent persons " to whom the carrying out of the law was committed, were not allowed to frustrate the intention of the legislature as de- clared by the letter of the law. Still, even in England, this Act was not got into operation without a struggle. The fact is noted in most of the books, and very fully in an industrious and interesting volume, The Early History of English Poor Relief, by Miss Leonard. Miss Leonard, I may observe^ in passing, seems to regard the Poor Law as a pretty piece of benevolence given to the country by those eminent philanthropists, Elizabeth and Charles I. a superficial interpretation, as I con- tend, of this grave economic episode ; but the i.] THE ORIGIN OF THE POOR LAW 33 facts that she chronicles are of great interest and importance.* Miss Leonard makes it very clear that great pressure had to be brought to bear on the local authorities by the Privy Council through the justices, in order to get the Act into operation. A pamphlet published in 1622, Grievous Grones for the Poor, complains that there has been no collection for the poor, " these seven years" in many parishes, especially in the country towns. Charles I.'s quarrel with his Parliament took place in 1629, and from that date began his term of personal government. One of his first acts, viz., on 5th January 1630, was to issue "Orders and Directions, with a Commission for the better administration and more perfect information of His Majesty how and by whom the laws and statutes tending to the relief of the poor " and kindred matters, "are executed throughout the Kingdom." This commission (see Nicholls' History of the Poor Law, vol. i. p. 254) was ap- pointed not only for inquiry, but for the purpose of enforcing the law. These " Orders and Direc- tions " were pressed with much insistence, and * I may also refer the reader to a paper published in the Charity Organisation Review for December 1900, on the " Gradual Introduction of the Poor Law." C 34 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. i. reports are still extant in the State papers proving that hitherto there had been much remissness in carrying out the law. Miss Leonard appears to be of opinion that we owe the English Poor Law quite as much to Charles I. and his Privy Council as to Elizabeth and her advisers, and there is much probability in favour of the correctness of this view. A considerable amount of evidence could be produced, showing that the systematic enforcement of a compulsory rate was occasionally neglected in remote parishes till after the middle of the 1 8th century. In many cases, as we may gather from the careful inquiries of Sir F. Eden, the amount collected and distributed was very small. It was not till towards the close of the 1 8th century that the appetite which comes in eating began to exert an inconvenient pressure on the puzzled and ignorant authorities who were charged with the administration of the law. In the next chapter we will assume that the principle of a compulsory assessment has been established, and we must then endeavour to follow the subsequent stages of its development down to the time when its abuses were so glaring as to render reform absolutely necessary, if society was to be saved from moral and financial ruin. CHAPTER II THE OLD POOR LAW WE may now assume that the. principle of a compulsory assessment for the poor has been duly established. The law, we have reason to believe, was only gradually enforced, and we took the year 1662, that is about sixty years after its first enactment, as marking the complete adoption of the principle. We selected this date, because in this year an Act was passed designed to control certain inconveniences and disputes which were bound to arise from a complete adoption of the principle of a compulsory assessment. We noted how the earlier so-called Poor Law enactments were directed to bringing back fugitive serfs to the place where their labour was due, how, when serf labour was no longer profitable, there was wanting any force to maintain the old feudal adscription of the labourer to the soil. There arose, therefore, doubt and uncertainty, in practice at all events, as to where and at whose charges the destitute but emancipated serf was to be 35 3 6 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. relieved. The parish to which he had come as an immigrant resented his intrusion, and various steps were taken to confine him to the parish of his settlement, culminating in the Acts 13 & 14 Charles II. c. 12, which systematised the power of Removal. By this law the parish authorities were authorised to prefer complaint to two justices, and, with their allowance, to remove any poor man coming into the parish to better himself, even though he made no application for relief. Now it is obvious that if this law took effect, and could not be evaded, the poorer population of England was practically tied to the soil by a fetter which it was impossible to break. The most interesting economic problem con- nected with the Poor Law is this doctrine of Settlement and v its consequences. It deserves, therefore, a fuller consideration. The position was as follows : Everyone had a settlement somewhere, presumably at the place of his birth. When changes of industry began, there were, of course, obvious inducements for labourers to acquire new aptitudes for work, and to move from parishes where there was a decaying em- ployment to new centres of industry. This move- ment, however, was practically prohibited by the earlier feudal custom, now revived and systema- tised in the Act which we have just mentioned, ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 37 and it is most interesting and important for us to note how far this legislation was enforced, and how far it was effective in procuring the stationary attitude of the poorer classes which seemed necessary for the convenience of the Poor Law administrator. We shall return to this point again, for it is the central and most important fact in all Poor Law history ; but for a moment it is necessary to go back to the Elizabethan statute and see who were the persons indicated therein as entitled to be brought within the scope of a law predestined to have such consequences. It is a commonplace often repeated in Poor Law literature, that if the terms of the Act of Elizabeth had been strictly interpreted, many, if not all, of the evils of the Old Poor Law would have been avoided. Strict interpretation, how- ever, though possible in a law court, is not to be expected (so all experience shows) in local ad- ministration, when confided to illiterate and often interested local authorities. Mr Twisleton, one of the most learned and able of the many able assistant commissioners appointed under the Act of 1834, has remarked on this generally received belief that strict interpretation would have saved the country from much evil ; but he adds, " I have found no trace in any old writings of this inter- 38 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND CHAP. pretation of the Act," a view which, I am bound to say, is entirely confirmed by all I have been able to learn on the subject. What, then, were the provisions of this Act which were so wise when literally interpreted, and so ruinous in the practice of the local administrator ? "The 43 Eliz. c. 2,"says Sir G. Nicholls, vol.i. p. 189, "the great turning-point of our Poor Law legislation, is still the foundation and text-book of English Poor Law. It is remarkable that this most important statute has no preamble setting forth the evils to be corrected and the good expected from it, as is the case with most of the other statutes ; but it goes at once to its object, and directs that in every parish, ' four, three, or two substantial householders shall, under the hand and seal of two or more justices of the peace be yearly nominated in Easter week, and that these, with the church-wardens, shall be overseers of the poor.' These overseers are 'to take order from time to time ' with the consent of the justices, for carrying the several provisions of the Act into effect. They are to raise ' weekly or otherwise, in every parish, by taxation of every inhabitant, parson, vicar, and other, and of every occupier of lands, houses, tithes impropriate, or propriations of tithe, coal-mines and saleable underwoods in the said parish, in such competent sum and sums of money as they shall think fit.' " The persons charged with the administration were 'to meet together (as provided by 39 Eliz. c. 3) at least once in every month, in the parish church, after Divine Service on the Sunday, to consider of some good course to be taken, and of some meet order to be set down in the premises.' Then at the end of the year they were to give an account of their office to the justices, and, in case of default, absence, or negligence, they were made subject to a fine of aos." ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 39 The point to be observed here is, first, the union of the ecclesiastical and civil jurisdictions. The church-wardens are to be associated with cer- tain new civil officers as overseers. They are to transact their business on Sundays, at the parish church, and they are put under the control and supervision of the justices, who in this way were made a sort of local authority for central control. The second point to be noted is, that the in- tention of the Act is clearly to rate all kinds of property and persons. The phrase runs, " In- habitants and Occupiers of lands, houses," etc. The occupier was to be rated in respect of his occupation ; but the inhabitant was to be rated in some other way not clearly specified. I think we may regard this order to rate in- habitants as betokening a recognition that land was not the only form of property which ought to contribute to the relief of the poor. The practice, however, was not carried out, notwithstanding the clear intention of the law. In certain districts where the clothing trade prevailed, it was cus ternary to rate stock-in-trade, and the same principle seems to have been carried out in certain shipping towns, but for the most part the burden was entirely laid upon land. The point has been the subject of some legal controversy. Lord Mansfield, one hundred and fifty years after 40 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the passing of the Act of Elizabeth, declared that it was impossible to rate personalty and stock-in- trade. Lord Kenyon, in 1795, considered it clear beyond debate that stock-in-trade was liable. The practice sided with Lord Mansfield. After the passing of the Poor Law Amendment Act 1834, i.e. in 1836, an Act was passed, the Parochial Assessment Act, regulating the sub- jects liable to the poor rate. No mention was made of stock-in-trade, and certain localities, where stock-in-trade had hitherto been rated, ceased the practice, and litigation ensued. It was decided in the case of Queen v. Lutnsdatne that stock-in-trade was still liable, and that a rate which omitted stock-in-trade might be set aside.* This practically made almost every rate in the country liable to be set aside, and in order to bring the law into conformity with the general practice, an Act had to be passed exempting personal property from the poor rate. The intention of the Act of Eliza- beth in this respect has been found impracticable. One other remark may be made on the poor rate. The poor rate, being the earliest rate for which a systematic levy was made, has become the model of all other local rates ; and all other local rates are either raised as parts of the poor * Regina v. Lumsdaine, 1839, reported in 10 Adolphus & Ellis, p. 157. ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 41 rate, or they are levied on the same persons and in respect of the same property as the poor rate. With this brief glance at the authorities to whom the duty of levying and administering a rate was intrusted, and the persons on whom it was to be levied, we come next to the class of persons for whose relief it was intended. It was, says Sir G. Nicholls, (1) " For setting to work the children of all whose parents shall not be thought able to keep and maintain them." (2) " For setting to work all such persons married and un- married having no means to maintain them, and who use no ordinary and daily trade of life to get their living by." (3) " For providing a convenient stock of flax, hemp, wool, thread, iron and other ware and stuff to set the poor on work." (4) "For the necessary relief of the lame, impotent, old, blind, and such other among them being poor and not able to work." The apprenticeship of destitute children, the \ relief of the impotent, and the setting to ] work of those who use no daily or ordinary I trade, these w r ere the objects of the Act. The two first objects call for no special remark at present. The point on which the Act finally broke down was the "setting to work of those who use no trade," or, if we adopt the view of those who accept the plenary inspiration of the Elizabethan lawgiver, it broke down be- cause of the neglect of the local administrators 42 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. to adhere strictly to the terms of this section of the Act. It is pointed out that the phrase, " persons who use no ordinary and daily trade of life," expressly excludes those who were afterwards termed "the industrious poor " that is, such persons as do use an ordinary and daily trade, but whose earnings at this trade may be inconsiderable. Before long the neglect of this distinction gave rise to the giving of relief in aid of wages to the able-bodied labourer, while he was able-bodied and in full work. This evil, once begun, was hurried on apace, both because of the pressure of the poor, who are naturally not prescient as to the effect of a system of relief which ministers to their immediate wants, and also because the system enlisted in its favour the sinister support of employers who were not above making a corrupt use of a fund from which could be paid a part of their wages bill. This, and all the evil con- sequences which we shall presently describe, might, it is said, have been prevented if the Act had been strictly interpreted, but I have found no evidence that this strict interpretation was ever put forward. On the contrary, there is much evidence to show that these safeguards, if safeguards they were, were never operative. One other comment must be made on the terms .] THE OLD POOR LAW 43 of the Act, as to the " providing of a convenient stock" to set the poor on work. Industry Ypursued under such conditions was not, and never could be, successful as industry. This was never realised and indeed I do not know that it is fully realised now by local administrators. Fuller experience has shown that the only good purpose served " by setting the poor on work " by a Poor Law authority is to institute a test of destitu- tion. The project was much debated in the time of Defoe, who, with his usual common sense, pointed out the weak spot in the policy of attempting to set the poor on work, as a device for promoting industry. In his Giving' Alms no Charity, 1702, there is an admirable account of how the Flemings, driven out of their own country by the tyranny of Alva, came and founded a great industry in England. They taught our people a new industry, and the wealth of the country was greatly increased, but, says our author, what is now proposed is not to teach a new industry. If those gentlemen (promoters of a bill to encour- age poor law industries) could obtain an order from the Czar of Muscovy that all his subjects should wear stockings who wore none before, it would be a great gain. "If they will employ the poor in some manufacture 44 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. which was not made in England before, or not bought with some manufacture made here before, then they offer at some- thing extraordinary. " But to set poor people at work on the same thing which other poor people were employed on before, and, at the same time, not increase the consumption, is giving to one what you take away from another, enriching one poor man to starve another, putting a vagabond into an honest man's employment, and putting his diligence on tenter-hooks to find out some other work to maintain his family."* The classical instance of the failure of this policy was at Bristol, where, under a local Act, a workhouse was built and a stock purchased to set the poor on work, " with great loss to the Cor- poration." The good craftsmen would not remain in the house, and the class that remained spoiled the material. Finally the Corporation "set projects of labour aside," and farmed out their poor to a contractor. This, presumably, they found cheaper, even though they had to pay relief over and above the wages which the contractor paid to his pauper labourers. The fact is, that it is not possible for the Poor Law to organise industry in the way that this clause of the Act has been thought to order. To use labour as a test of destitution, more especially when combined with the confinement * Defoe's Giving Alms no Charity, reprint in Charity Organisa- tion Review for May 1893. ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 45 and discipline of a workhouse, has been found a useful expedient, but the setting of the poor to work in the expectation that this would be profit- ^able, and that healthy industries could in this way jbe promoted, is a delusion, and very much for the reasons indicated in the Bristol experiment. If a profitable trade can be done, it will be done outside. The competent craftsmen will be employed there, and the Poor Law authority will be left with the incompetent ; and it is cheaper to maintain the destitute of this class with a safe- guard in the form of some simple task-work, than to allow them to waste material by pretending to carry on an industry. Experience of this difficulty, pointed out prophetically by Defoe, has induced authorities generally to neglect the setting of the poor on work as being really an impossible and extravagant policy. This Bristol experiment was begun in 1698, and a good many similar experiments were made under local acts, and also under a statute of 1722, which authorised the building of workhouses. They were temporarily successful in checking the increase of pauperism, just as far as they were used as tests of destitution. This condition, however, was rarely in the mind of the adminis- trator, and we learn from Sir F. Eden, who wrote at the end of the eighteenth century, 46 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. that the experiment had been adjudged a failure. The object of the comment just made on the terms of the Act of Elizabeth is to suggest that there need be no ground for surprise that the system did not work satisfactorily. It is usual to say that the Elizabethan Poor Law worked well till the time of the great French war, and the authorisation of bread scales, i.e. the regular supplementation of wages, authorised by the justices in the last decade of the eighteenth century. I have indicated, however, certain a priori reasons for thinking that, if this is correct, it would have been contrary to expectation. I do not think, moreover, that it will be difficult to show that it is contrary to fact. That the law never worked smoothly, can be very certainly traced through the preambles of many Acts of Parliament. The Act of Elizabeth was, we suggest, got into full operation by the time of the Settlement Act of 1662. Poor people were then pressing into parishes where there was good stock that is, good employment for them causing a fear to the parish that they might one day have to be maintained. This beneficent economic move- ment threatened to upset the whole policy of the Poor Law, and the remedy devised was to .] THE OLD POOR LAW 47 prevent them moving. Then, in 1670, we have an Act authorising workhouses in London to facilitate the policy of setting the poor to work, which, under the Act of Elizabeth, was altogether impracticable. Then, in 1685, in the i James II. r c. 17, after a recital that the poor at their first coming into a parish do commonly conceal them- selves, it is ordered that poor people so migrating must give notice to the overseers, and the forty days required for settlement are to be computed from the date of notice. Six years later (by 3 and 4 William & Mary, c. 1 1, 1691), it is ordered that this notice must be read in the church. The same Act recites that the overseers in their unlimited power have put a great many persons on collection on frivolous pretences and for their own private ends, and then enacts that lists are to be made out and produced to the parishioners met in vestry, and that no one else was to be put on collection without the order of the justices. The Act, in fact, was intended to check the corrupt profusion of the overseers, and the 8 & 9 William III. c. 30 is in the same sense. This check seems, however, to have been no check, for in the 9 George I. c. 7, 1722, it is recited that the justices have abused the power granted them, and, far from checking the pro- 48 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. fusion of the overseers, have themselves been granting relief on frivolous pretences. It is then enacted that no justice is to order relief until the pauper has made oath that he has applied to, and been refused by, the overseers, and till the overseers have had an opportunity of explaining. The Act is designed, in fact, to support the overseer, as the representative of the rate-payer, against the justices. This same Act authorises the building of workhouses, and makes the offer of relief therein a valid answer to a demand for relief. Sixty years later, the 22 George III. c. 83 (Gilbert's Act) seems to indicate that the pen- dulum of public opinion had swung back ; the overseers are blamed for their brutality, and the need of some higher control is declared. The Act, which is permissive, provides for the appoint- ment of a board of guardians to control the overseers. Then with regard to the setting of the poor to work, the Act contains the remarkable provision, that persons willing to work, but unable to find an employer, were not to go to a poor- house, where a labour test might be applied, but the guardians were to find work for them suitable to their capacity, or " to agree for their labour," in the parish and near to the place of their residence. The class for whom such a ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 49 *- guarantee was enacted were absolved from all economic responsibility. (This authority of the justices to set aside the decision of the overseers was extended and made universal in later Acts. Justices were authorised to order relief practically at will, and it is alleged that they made a very injudicious use of this authority. One or two such justices in a district were sufficient to involve whole parishes in con- fusion. The 36 George III. c. 23, 1796, repealed the provisions of 9 George I. c. 7, in respect of the workhouse test, and justices were authorised to order relief at the pauper's own home. This power was, in 1815, further extended by 55 George III. c. 137. But perhaps the strongest evidence that the Act of Elizabeth was an unworkable law is to be found in the fact, that almost every con- siderable centre of population had deemed it necessary to have recourse to a local Act. The local Act of Bristol, already mentioned, recites " the experience that the poor in the city of Bristol do daily multiply, and idleness and debauchery among the meaner sort doth greatly increase," and goes on to authorise workhouses for the better employing and main- taining of the poor. Many similar Acts, some D 50 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. of them containing this identical recital, were passed for other towns. Even in the country, resort was had to Acts of Incorporation. This was specially the case in the Eastern Counties, In 1782, Gilbert's Act was passed, that is, an Act which permitted parishes to incorporate themselves without a special Act, and to introduce some sort of public control of the overseers. Sturges Bourne's Act, 1819, and Hobhouse's Act, 1831, authorised the election of Select Vestries to control the overseers. In 1834, there were found to be 975 parishes under Gilbert's Act, and, in the period 1795-1834 alone, over 200 local acts were introduced. In fact, all sorts of devices had been em- ployed to reform the Act of Elizabeth, but no general legislation had been passed. Each locality did what it could to protect itself, but the general result cannot be said to have been very satisfactory. By a curious omission in the Poor Law Amendment Act, 1834, adequate powers were not given to the Poor Law Com- missioners to bring parishes which enjoyed local Acts or were incorporated under Gilbert's Act within the complete control of the Amendment Act. These partial and incomplete local amend- ments, in so far as they exempted the districts ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 51 in question from the benefit of the more complete Amendment Act of 1834, proved in a later generation one of the most serious obstacles to reform. These considerations are, I think, sufficient to show that in the opinion of all concerned, the legislation of Elizabeth did not work well. The pressure of the poor on the poor rate tended to grow with only occasional interruption, and the attempts of the legislature to control it were very little successful. From the point of view of the poor man, a disability had been fastened on him and his class, which, if enforced, was most detrimental to his interests. To be confined to his place of settlement, to be liable to be sent back, if he emigrated to a place where there was better "stock," was a most cruel imprisonment. It will be remembered that Adam Smith declared that there was no labouring man of middle age in England who had not been grievously injured by this ill-contrived law of settlement. So monstrous a law, however, could not be, and I expect was not, very fully carried out. Sir F. Eden has expressed this opinion, and it is recorded elsewhere that the humane magistrate would not lend himself to - this tyranny. The law, however, was on the 52 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. statute book, and universal evasion was not possible. The point, however, is of little importance, because, unfortunately, the adscrip- tion of the labourer to the soil was attained by a much more certain and insidious method. By the Act of 35 George III. c. 101 (1795), no poor person could be removed till he became chargeable. He was now free to migrate as he pleased, but it was found that the confine- ment of the population to the parish of their settlement still continued. They had been taught by the law that, if they remained in their place of settlement, following their primitive unskilled occupations, the overseer was bound to find them labour, suitable to their capacity, near their own place of residence. The result, which Adam Smith rightly declared to have been most detrimental to the best interests of the poor, had been attained not by exterior force, but by a system which, through a long course of mismanagement, had destroyed all initiative and sense of responsibility in the poor. There was no need to force them to remain : they had no wish or interest to move. The state of affairs which had actually arisen can perhaps be made clearer by an instance. Bledlow is a parish in Buckinghamshire. At the passing of the Poor Law Amendment Act n.] THE OLD POOR LAW ,53 the assistant Commissioner was sent there to advise the local administrative. He found the whole management in confusion, men lying about on the roads, or poaching in the woods. Rob- beries had taken place, the overseer's ploughs and farm implements had been maliciously broken up, and a bullet had been fired into his house. At Tring, fifteen miles distant, there was work for the able-bodied on the railway, but, despite all the efforts of the parish authorities, not a man would go. Instead, they went to the over- seer and received relief. The assistant Com- missioner met them, and asked if they were willing to work. They said they had already worked on the road that is, they had lain under the hedges. They would not, they said, work out of the parish, but they were willing to work in the parish. The Commissioner goes on to tell of his efforts to restore the circulation of labour, which had been so disastrously inter- rupted by the operation of the Poor Law. Finally, homes in the North were found for a number of these poor people, and with great effort a few were induced to move to a place where, to use the phrase of the old Act, " there was good stock for them." By this guarantee of Poor Law maintenance destroying in his breast all desire to move, not 54 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. only was the labourer bound to the soil, but he was actually rendered incompetent, unwill- ing to work, and useless within the parish of his settlement. The policy and practice of the Poor Law authorities had been to make the re- ward of the good and the bad labourer exactly the same. If a man did not receive for his labour the sum that was supposed to be necessary for his maintenance, he received the deficiency from the parish. He had no object to be a good workman. The less he earned, the larger was the gratuity given to him. This arrange- ment suited, or seemed to suit, the interests of the employer, whose wage-bill was thus in part paid by the public authority. The deterioration of the employer and the labourer went hand in hand. If proof were necessary to show that this congestion was entirely the result of our vicious Poor Law, we may remark, in anticipation of the fuller treatment of the subject given in the next chapter, that, with the abolition of the guarantee of work and maintenance for the able-bodied, which was the operative reform of the Poor Law Amendment Act, these evil con- ditions began at once to disappear. The con- ditions of trade required that men should leave their parishes in search of work. After a long ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 55 period of stagnation the circulation of labour was again set in motion, and it became an object with men to prove themselves good workmen. It then became easy for employers to employ men who now had some interest and pride in making their labour efficient. I make no concealment, therefore, of my opinion that the 43 Elizabeth c. 2 was an ill- conceived measure, and it is worth while to summarise the several points at which it has proved specially inept. I. The officers appointed by the law were, from the first, unequal to the task. The maladministration of the overseers had to be corrected by the jus_tices, and the justices, in their turn, introdjjced evils of their own devising. Vestries and local Acts and other expedients were introduced, but without much success. So it went on till what we may call the judgment day the day when the whole business was in- quired into by the famous Commission of 18.34. In its report every single person or body that had been charged with administration of the Poor Law was tried and found wanting. II. The order to rate personally for local purposes was so impossible, that practically no general attempt was ever made to enforce it. III. The difference of policy to be pursued 56 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. with regard to those who use an ordinary and daily trade, and those who do not, was so vaguely stated that it seems to have been generally over- looked, and the fact leaves us in doubt, whether the grave economic consequences which turned on this distinction were ever clearly present in the mind of the legislator. IV. The policy of setting the poor on work, so forcibly condemned by Defoe, and so fre- quently tried and found costly and inefficient at Bristol and elsewhere, all experience has shown to be an impossible policy. V. Further, the conception which underlies the whole Act, the right of the poor to a statutory maintenance, rendered necessary some plan of indicating where and by whom each applicant had to be relieved. This necessity resulted in making permanent the adscription of the labourer to the soil, a condition of things so opposed to the strong forces of economic progress that it would probably have been swept aside, had not the insidious guarantee of Poor Law main- tenance paralysed motives of self-assertion which express enactment could not subdue. VI. It remains to be shown how ineffectual was the Old Poor Law as a means of relieving the impotent, the sick, and the infirm. -^ Generally it may be said that the whole ir.] THE OLD POOR LAW 57 administration of the Poor Law had been broken down by reason of the large responsibility which the law_Jhjid^ssjmieji_Jbr the able-bodied and indusjrious poor. The care of the aged, sick, impotent and infirm was largely neglected. All the energies and thought of the administrator were turned to meeting the ever-accumulating pressure of able-bodied pauperism, and expended in en- deavours to stave off the bankruptcy of his parish. This state of things, the logical and inevitable result of the ordinarily received in- terpretation of the Act of Elizabeth, will be better understood by a few concrete examples, taken for the most part from the Report of the Commissioners of Inquiry. The policy of giving relief to all poor men in addition to their earnings in the south of England, became almost universal at the end of last century. This plan was systematised by the publication of what were called "Bread Scales." To quote the heading of one of the most famous of these " Bread Scales " " This shows at one view what would be the weekly income of the industrious poor, as settled by the magistrates for the County of Berks, at a meeting held at Speenhamland, 6th May 1795." The Table systematically sets out what the income of a man with one, two, and up to seven 58 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. children should be when the gallon loaf is at such and such a price. If the man did not earn this amount, and he had no object in so doing, while it was very much to the interest of his employer that he should not earn it, the parish had to make up the deficiency. The usual phrase in the mouth of the pauper was, " my money " (meaning the money indicated in the "Bread Scale") "is so and so it does not matter to me how I get it ; the less work done for it the better." Besides the money given for deficiency of earnings, is. or is. 6d. extra was given for each child. Un- married men and men with small families were told they might shift for themselves, for the farmer argued that it was cheaper to employ the family man, who was partly supported by the rate-payers. The system was a most ingenious premium on improvident marriage, and, what was equally unfair, a distinct penalty on unmarried men and men with small families. Five different systems are enumerated under which the able-bodied man was given the benefit of the Act of Elizabeth, as that Act was inter- preted by the local administrator. I. RELIEF WITHOUT LABOUR, either by way of test or by way of industry. (a) The labourer was given the smallest sum ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 59 possible, and told to shift for himself and give no more trouble. (b] Oftener he was called on to give up some of his time by standing in the pound or in a gravel pit, or by attend- ing a roll call. (c) Or relief was given because the labourer was said to have lost time, by reason of weather, or caprice of private em- ployer. II. ALLOWANCE SYSTEM. Relief was paid in aid of wages, and on account of number of children, as provided in the local "Bread Scale." III. ROUNDSMAN SYSTEM. By this plan the parish became in the first instance the universal employer, and hired out the labourers to the farmers, the parish agreeing to make up the difference between the scale and the wages paid. The labourers were let out by auction, and sometimes by ballot, or perhaps by both ex- pedients. There would be some bids for the labourer who was fairly tractable and sober, while the hopeless and incorrigibly bad work- man was disposed of by lot. He was worse than useless to his employer, but by the aid of the parish allowance he received the same reward as the industrious competent workman. IV. PARISH WORK. The parish authorities set 60 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. to work on the roads the so-called surplus labour. Superintendence, however, was very slack, and the condition of the pauper was often much better than that of the independent labourer. There was, moreover, no profit to any one in particular, and the farmers preferred the more corrupt allowance system. The Poor Law, by rendering an equitable bargain between employer and employed impossible, had created a surplus or unemployed population, and required to deal with it by inventing these fictitious and un- economic employments. Yet there was, as we shall presently see, more or less full employment available for the whole population in the current channels of industry. V. LABOUR RATE. Inhabitants were obliged to employ a certain number of men in proportion to their rating, the number of acres in their holding, or some other never satisfactory scale. Thus, the parson was often the highest rate-payer, yet he was not as a rule a farmer able to employ many labourers. By these and other expedients the whole able- bodied population was swept into the vortex of pauperism. Certainly and surely every vestige of self-respect was being obliterated. The economic result was, as already stated, .] THE OLD POOR LAW 61 to confine the able-bodied population to their parishes and to a helpless immobility of character, in order that they might enjoy the benefit of the Act of Elizabeth, and be employed under one or other of these types of pauper servitude. The summary of the Commissioners on this economic aspect is as follows : "Piece-work is thus refused to the single man, or to the married man if he have no family, because they can exist on day wages ; it is refused to the active and intelligent labourer because he would earn too much. The enterprising man who has fled from the tyranny of his parish to some place where there is a demand and a reward for his services, is driven from a situation which suits him, and an employer to whom he is attached, by a labour rate, or some other device against non- parishioners, and forced back to his settlement to receive as alms a portion only of what he was obtaining by his own exertions. He is driven from a place where he was earning, as a free labourer, 125. or 143. a week, and is offered road work, as a pauper, at 6d. a day, or perhaps to be put up by the parish authorities to auction and sold to the farmer who will take him at the lowest allowance. Can we wonder if the labourer abandons virtues of which this is the reward ? " "Can we wonder," it goes on, "if he abandons economy, diligence and prudence, or if he regards the law as his enemy ? " The immoral and anti-social characteristics which the system developed in all classes were hardly less remarkable. Population always seeks to expand along the line of least resistance, and in this country, during 62 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. that evil time, the maintenance to be acquired with least effort by the poorer classes was main- tenance from the parish. Let us note one or two of the characteristic qualifications for relief which were promoted and encouraged by the endowment derived from the poor rate. The case of a woman with an illegitimate child was a hard one, and an allowance from the rates, generally 2s. 6d. a week for each such child, was ordered (a larger sum than was given for the legitimate child). The result of this well-meant, but ill-considered philanthropy was that a trade was made in illegitimacy, and a woman with a long row of illegitimate children was sought in marriage because she brought to her husband a valuable dowry. So notorious was the fact, that I find this revolting practice made the subject of denunciation by a parish clergyman in a remote country village. Another abominable abuse was the pauper marriages corruptly promoted by overseers with the view of shifting the settlement of paupers from one parish to another. Some wretched man was given a sum of money to marry some still more wretched woman. The details of the bargain were sometimes debated even on the altar-steps. This chicanery and other disputes about settlement led to what one of the Com- .] THE OLD POOR LAW 63 missioners has happily called a dirty warfare, continually waged between upwards of fifteen thousand parishes, all trying to shuffle off their responsibility, and willing to resort at times to the meanest stratagems. Not only was the Poor Law used to build up a spurious and bestial imitation of domestic life, but it also tended to destroy and corrupt the domestic affections and graces which are to be found even among the most savage or uncivilised of men. Here is a passage from the Commissioners' report : " The worst results are still to be mentioned ; in all ranks of society the great sources of happiness and virtue are the domestic affections, and this is particularly the case among those who have so few resources as the labouring classes. Now, pauperism seems to be an engine for the purpose of disconnecting each member of a family from all others; of reducing all to the state of domesticated animals, fed, lodged, and provided for by the parish, without mutual dependence or mutual interest. Mothers and children will not nurse one another in sickness, unless their services are paid for. Boys of 14 when they become entitled to receive parish relief on their own account, no longer make a common fund of their income with their parents. They board with their parents, but buy their own loaf and bacon, and devour it alone. Disgraceful quarrels arise within the family circle from mutual accusations of theft." "At the time of my journey," says Mr Cowell, one of the assistant Commissioners, "the acquaintance I had with the practical operation of the Poor Laws led me to suppose 64 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. that the pressure of the sum annually raised upon the rate- payers, and its progressive increase, constituted the main inconvenience of the Poor Law system. \The experience of a very few weeks served to convince me that this evil, however great, sinks into insignificance when compared with the dreadful effects which the system produces on the morals and happiness of the lower orders^] It is as difficult to convey to the mind of the reader a true and faithful impression of the intensity and malignancy of the evil in this point of view as it is by any description, however vivid, to give an adequate idea of the horrors of a shipwreck or a pestilence. A person must converse with paupers, must enter workhouses and examine the inmates, must attend at the parish pay-table before he can form a just conception of the moral debasement which is the offspring of the present system ; he must hear the pauper threatening to abandon his wife and family unless more money is allowed him, threaten to abandon an aged bed-ridden mother, to turn her out of his house, and lay her down at the overseer's door, unless he is paid for giving her shelter; he must hear parents threatening to follow the same course with regard to their sick children; he must see mothers coming to receive the reward of their daughters' ignominy, and witness women in cottages quietly pointing out, without even the question being asked, which are their children by their husband and which by other men previous to marriage ; and when he finds he can scarcely step into a town or parish in any county without meeting with some instance or other of this character, he will no longer consider the pecuniary pressure on the rate-payer as the first in the class of evils which the Poor Laws have entailed upon the community." Two more quotations may be allowed, in- volving a contrast between the pauper and the independent labourer and also between the able-bodied pauper and a poor lunatic. They ii.] THE OLD POOR LAW 65 illustrate what we fear is an universal tendency. The benefit of a common fund or property, such as is the poor rate, does not go to the weak but to the importunate and strong. The law, as we saw, required that work should be found at the pauper's own door. Accordingly, near a certain house of industry, a brick work was set up for the employment of the pauper inmates, but the pauper labour locally available was not sufficient for the effective conduct of the industry, and it was thought desirable to hire men from a distance. The assistant Commissioner describes how, "these hard-working honest men walked four miles to their work each morning, worked hard all day, lived upon coarse fare, drinking water, and walking home at evening to their families, whilst the lazy able-bodied paupers lived on the spot, had good hot meat dinners, five pints of strong beer daily, and is. per week to spend on Sunday." In another parish he describes how he dis- covered in a so-called workhouse, " a most dismal, filthy-looking room, a coal cellar rather than the residence of a human being the sole tenant ... a poor distressed lunatic. His appearance was pitiable in the extreme ; his clothing was extremely ragged, his face as dirty as the floor, his head and face bruised. He sat listless and alone, without any human being to attend upon or take care of him. . . . To the very great shame of the parish officers, I found he had been in this disgusting state for years," E 66 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. In some of the so-called houses of industry pauper families had taken more or less forcible possession of the rooms. When they went harvesting they nailed up their door. Their children were born and brought up in these abodes, and presently went off and returned with wives and families of their own. Three generations of two such families were found in one Suffolk house of industry. The people, in a sense, lived very well in the workhouses that is, the strong and disorderly did ; but there was no classification, and no attempt to deal adequately with the impotent and the sick. The workhouse of Oxford was not an object of terror but of desire, and interest was made to get quarters in it. There was no confine- ment and no discipline. One guardian with a desire for popularity went round countermanding directions of another, and ordering drinks for the paupers. One-sixth of the population in this workhouse were women with illegitimate children ; in fact, the place was a pandemonium of the worst characters, and a most uncomfortable refuge for the impotent and the sick. Illustrations of this kind might be indefinitely multiplied, but enough has been said to indicate how legislation, framed with the laudable desire of relieving the impotent and persons who had i,.] THE OLD POOR LAW 67 no work, brought about results of an unexpected character. Part of the failure was inevitable, part was preventable. The fact of the failure is beyond dispute. A population just emerging from a condition of feudal servitude was thought to be the proper object of a system of relief. In order to administer this relief, some continuance of the system of the old territorial settlement was necessary. The express regulations enforcing this confinement might have been evaded, but the will and inclination of the poor man towards economic movement, towards the better dis- tribution of his services in the labour market, towards the modification of labour aptitudes required by the changing conditions of industry, were atrophied and destroyed by the guarantee of maintenance held out to him if he resolutely adhered to an attitude of economic immobility and incompetence. Not even the object of adequate and humane relief was attained, the weak and impotent were thrust aside, parishes were unable to meet the demand created by this vicious state of things, and, as at Cholesbury, land no longer able to bear the burden of the rate was allowed to go out of cultivation. Not only was the country carrying a vast mass 68 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. n. of labour unprofitably employed under the futile and sterile direction of the parochial authority, and maintaining large numbers of destitute people burdens from which no civilised community can perhaps be entirely free but its methods of dealing with this class had been so faulty, that the insolvent portion of the community was gaining on the solvent portion, and was fast hurrying the whole into a common ruin. This was the state of things when, in 1834, after an elaborate inquiry, Lord Grey's Govern- ment in the first reformed House of Commons brought in and passed the Poor Law Amend- ment Act, 1834, a subject with which we must deal in our next chapter. CHAPTER III THE POOR LAW AMENDMENT ACT OF 1834, COMMONLY CALLED " THE NEW POOR LAW " IN the last chapter I endeavoured to draw a picture of the social economy of the poorer classes in England, as it was affected by the administration of the Old Poor Law. The effect of the Old Poor Law on English social life is an object lesson, on the largest and most impressive scale, of the terrible evils which legislation can produce, if, as in this case, it runs counter to the essential principles of economic progress. The administration of the Old Poor Law ignored altogether that concurrent and better mechanism of society of which Dr Chalmers spoke. In its view the economy of the poorer class was a thing incapable of wholesome economic development ; it was, on the contrary, a thing to be " managed " and controlled at every turn by Parochial Providence. It is easy, no doubt, to be wise after the event. We know now that, whether we desire it or not, our lot is cast in a society which, notwithstanding the 70 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. strong retentive forces of the primitive static conception of life, has irrevocably elected to live by the aid of a sub-division of labour, and the exchange of mutual service. If, in such an organisation, labour is to attain the high position which true philanthropy desires to secure for it, it is absolutely necessary that men's aptitudes for service shall be cultivated, improved, and taken with the utmost rapidity to their best market. Such an organisation becomes one in which there lies on each unit a direct responsibility to bring his or her services to market in a high degree of efficiency. It is the cumulative effect of such individual improvements that makes a day's work, at the beginning of the twentieth century, productive of so much more magnificent a harvest than a similar day's work among a primitive people. The functions per- formed by capital in this organisation are exchangeable services. They require the same freedom of movement for their most successful development, and they conduce to the same beneficent result. The institution of capital is condemned by anti-social * writers, not, I * There is, we submit, much mental confusion in applying to persons who wish to subject Society to the State (the modern representation of the condition called by Maine, Status) the term " Socialists." They are in French phraseology ttatiste, not socialiste, or, as designated in the text, anti-social. HI.] THE NEW POOR LAW 71 apprehend, because we can dispense with it, but because being concentrated in comparatively few hands it has given rise to inequality. The remedy for this is not to be found in impracticable proposals for a common tenure of capital. The evil to be deplored and to be amended is the resolute proletariate habit, char- acteristically adopted by certain classes, which effectually prevents them from acquiring property, and, what is perhaps equally important, from acquiring the instincts of property. This we assert is due to the permanence of the static organisation of life, of which the Poor Law is in England the most important survival. Be this, however, as it may, we are convinced that it is quite impossible for society to go back perma- nently to any conceivable form of communism, such as that implied in the "taking over" of all industrial capital by the state. No true line of deliverance lies in that direction.* The con- * During the lectures of which the text is a substantial reproduc- tion, it was suggested to the lecturer by one of his audience, that the sufferings of the poor were due to the break-up of the feudal system and to the inequitable partition of the property of the old feudal community. This view has its plausible side, and seems to suggest that the remedy must consist in some return to some earlier form of communistic status. The answer, I apprehend, is as follows : 1. There is no evidence that the condition of the serf was so favourable, that a return to it would have satisfied the require- ments of the case. 2. The partition of the feudal estate, and the policy pursued 72 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. current, and as we believe preferable, alternative which lay before the legislator, if he could have perceived it, was to allow the exodus of the people from the bondage of primi- tive conditions to conduct itself under the guidance of what Chalmers has called, " the human exchanges." Under this guidance, members of a society, held together by exchange of mutual service, attain an honourable self- sufficient interdependence which does not exclude, but rather imperatively includes, some acquisition of capital by all classes, as a fitting complement to the fully developed labour ap- titudes of the industrial unit. If at a point this purely economic organisation failed, there remained a reserve of spontaneous benevo- lence, inseparable from family and associated life, subsequent to its break-up were influenced by the equity of the day such as it was. The Elizabethan Poor Law was the share allotted to the poor, and our main contention is that the equity of the slow grinding of the economic order has proved superior to the con- temporary conception of equity as represented by the substitution of parochial for feudal servitude. 3. More important, however, is the consideration that the break- up of feudalism, whether a good thing or a bad thing, was inevitable. Human nature, when it once came to perceive the advantage of what Chalmers calls the " human exchanges," will no longer put up with communism. Of course, if any one thinks that we can with advantage return to experiments in feudal status, he is entitled to his opinion. There are survivals, such as the English Poor Law, the system of caste in India, and that strange institution known as the Russian Mir, but it cannot be said that the results derived from them are encouraging. HI.] THE NEW POOR LAW 73 ready to come forward and bear the burden of the unfortunate. This reserve of force, whether fully adequate to discharge such a responsibility or not, was, and is, undoubtedly, in existence, and at least renders it unnecessary to erect, on an obtrusive and pretentious scale, concurrently with the more excellent way, and for the temptation of struggling weaker brethren, offers of a dependent maintenance, which, though insidiously attractive, reduces its victims to an altogether lower plane of existence. All this was, we will not say denied, but resolutely ignored by the Old Poor Law. The message of feudalism to the poor man, if we may so speak, was, " Serve here, and maintenance will be forthcoming." Then the Poor Law, addressing itself to the labourer emerging from this shell of servitude, varied the injunction, declaring : " Remain here where you are, and as you are, and the parish must maintain you." This policy obstructed the true exodus of the people, and created a monstrous growth of population, im- pervious to the distributing force of the economic motive, and threatening the moral and financial ruin of the nation. The merit of the reform which we are about to consider, consists in the fact that up to a certain point it restored society to the influence of 74 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the economic motive, which had so disastrously been excluded. The demerit of the reform was, in like manner, due to the fact that this restora- tion was only partial and incomplete. No apology will be needed for this somewhat theoretical analysis of the principles underlying our social organisation, if, as I believe, it puts us in a coign of vantage from which we can survey and predict the result of the many experiments which, under the name of poor laws, have been tried on the body politic. There is nothing, in such matters, so practical as a right theory. Given a right theory, the problem is half-solved, even though the detailed course of conduct which is required to bring reform within our reach is still a difficulty. The question was : What was to be done ? Not unnaturally the stupendous evils of the time suggested to some minds that there was nothing for it but to abolish the Poor Law, which seemed the source of all this mischief. The teaching of such writers as Malthus and Ricardo seemed to point in this direction. It was, however, obviously futile to take up such an attitude. It was clearly impossible, even if such a policy was to be adopted as the ultimate goal towards which we ought to strive, to lay at once the monster which the legislative Frankenstein HI.) THE NEW POOR LAW 75 had created. For centuries the law had been holding back in a condition of dependence a population which otherwise would have been absorbed in that better mechanism, and it was not just nor politic to destroy its maintenance in a moment, and without full consideration. The Government very sensibly said, Let us have an Inquiry, and accordingly, in 1832, they appointed a Royal Commission to inquire and to advise. In many respects, the work of this Commission, and of the Government which acted on its advice, was a great effort of statecraft. Consider what the elements of the problem were. The Reform Bill had just been passed, and one of the first duties of the new Parliament, elected on the wider franchise, was to sanction a proposal, made by the Government, for dealing in an unpopular and restrictive manner with a sum of some seven or eight millions per annum, which purported to be, in a sense, the property of the poor, or at least to be spent in their interests. It was, in fact, a very serious thing to ask the new democracy to perform on itself the painful surgical operation of cutting its lower members off from dependence on the poor rate. The situation was full of danger ; such an attempt by the Liberal Government was sure to be re- presented by the Tory Democrat of the day as 76 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHA?. the robbery of the poor. That it would be resented by the poor themselves was also certain, and the interest, as we have seen, of many employers was enlisted in support of the old abuses. The proper conduct of the affair re- quired the greatest tact and skill. The Commission included some eminent names. The Bishop of London, Blomfield, chair- man ; Sumner, Bishop of Chester, afterwards Archbishop of Canterbury ; Mr Sturges Bourne ; Mr Nassau Senior. In all, there were to the Report nine signatories, including Mr Chadwick, who at first was appointed Secretary, but during the course of the inquiry was made a Commis- sioner. It was a non-political body. None of its members were members of the House of Commons. The two men who guided the course of the inquiry, and were practically responsible for the Report, were Mr Nassau Senior and Mr (afterwards Sir) Edwin Chadwick. Mr Senior was a lawyer, and for many years a Master in Chancery. He had been Professor of Political Economy at Oxford, and was a Whig, a personal friend of the Marquis of Lansdowne and other members of the Govern- ment. Mr Chadwick was then a young barrister, a disciple and friend of Jeremy Bentham, who died in this year. The literary arrangement of ,.] THE NEW POOR LAW 77 the Report was the work of Mr Senior. Mr Chadwick collected a vast amount of the evidence, and was the author (following therein the teach- ing of his old master Bentham) of many of the practical details which were afterwards embodied in the Act. To give some idea of the extent of the Com- mission's labour, it may be mentioned that the evidence collected by their assistant Commis- sioners and the Report together amount to more than 8000 folio pages. The Commissioners, in all probability, very quickly came to the conclusion that it was im- possible to abolish the whole law. The next best thing to do was to abolish a part of the law, and we should remember in reading their Report that they had this limited practical object in view. After an historical survey of the course of legislation, the Commissioners proceed : " It is now our painful duty to report that in the greater part of the districts which we have been able to examine, the fund, which the 43rd of Elizabeth directed to be employed in setting to work children and persons capable of labour, but using no daily trade, and in the necessary relief of the impotent, is ap- plied to purposes opposed to the letter, and still more to the spirit of that law, and destructive to the morals of the most numerous class, and to the welfare of all." This gives a keynote to the practical recom- mendations of the Report. The principal object 78 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. of the attack was to be the relief given in sup- plementation of wages to persons who are variously described as those who use an ordinary or daily trade, or the industrious poor, or the able-bodied poor. We must return, so the language used seems to suggest, to the wisdom of Elizabeth, and to a literal interpretation of her Act. We may be inclined to doubt the wisdom of the Act of Elizabeth, but it was a wise stroke in advocacy to impute the abuses which had occurred not to the Act, but to a neglect of the terms of the Act, especially when all the reform, which the Commissioners thought practicable at that time, was an abolition of outdoor relief to the able- bodied. This object would be attained by a strict interpretation of the Act of Elizabeth. Such an interpretation, we may repeat, had never been given to it in practice, and it was the business of the Commission to suggest a plan by which their own interpretation of the Act of Elizabeth could be carried out. After the hint thrown out above, the Report proceeds to enumerate the evils of the old law, such as were narrated in the last chapter. They then meet by anticipation the objections likely to be raised by labourers, by employers, and by land- owners. They pointed out how the labourers 79 clung to their relief, how the employer tried to get a corrupt profit out of the system, and how the owner of cottage property was able to get a liberal and a certain rent from the overseer on behalf of his pauper tenants. Deep-rooted prejudices against reform were to be found in the breasts of those who were the victims, as well as those who were adminis- trators, of the system. This leads them to discuss the authorities who have hitherto striven and failed to control the effect of these sinister prejudices. Overseers ; Vestries, Open and Select; and lastly, Magistrates, all alike are shown to have been unequal to the task. The case against the magistrates is laboured more fully than that against the others. There seems to have been a fear in the minds of the Commis- sioners that proposals would be made for making the magistrates a local Board of Control, and, in order to get rid of a suggestion which they felt to be quite inadequate, they dwell with considerable detail on the maladministration of the magistrates. Mr Senior afterwards admitted that he thought more than their due share of blame had been imputed to the magistrates. They were no worse than any one else. Then, before giving their own remedies, they discuss certain proposals that had been made 8o PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. (i) For making the maintenance of the poor a national charge. In rejecting this suggestion, they assume, as axiomatic, that the administra- tion must still continue in the hands of local amateurs. Obviously, if this was necessary, a national rate to be expended by local empirics was a short cut to financial ruin. It is important, however, to notice that Mr Chadwick was strongly in favour of a centralised administration through subordinate and salaried expert officials. His views were not fully accepted by his col- leagues, and, as we shall presently see, his attempt to give effect to his views, by means of a Central Board and certain salaried local officials, was frustrated to a large extent by a continuance in office of local boards of guardians with authority far in excess of that which Mr Chadwick wished to entrust to them. (2) They considered a proposal for promoting the occupation of land by labourers. The sug- gestion that new and varied forms of relief should be invented in the vain hope that uneconomic forms of dependence would, contrary to all past experience, in some unexpected way prove salu- tary, was rejected as irrelevant. The occupation of land by poor men is in itself a good thing, but it must be reached by ordinary economic pro- cesses. When made a part of our Poor Law in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 81 procedure, it could do nothing but increase the pressure of population into the pauper habit of life. Occupation of land, moreover, was no general or universally practicable method of administering relief, and was best promoted without the interference of the parish. (3) A more lengthy consideration was given to what seems now the most impracticable pro- posal of all, viz. : a Labour Rate. The reason for this probably was that the principle had recently been embodied in a bill. To-day, the suggestion that every rate-payer should employ a certain number of men, altogether irrespective of his requirements, seems too ridiculous for discussion. Francis Place, the radical tailor of Charing Cross, a democratic leader, with a very real appreciation of true liberal principles, thought the proposal worthy of refutation, and was so much pleased with the Commissioners' criticisms, that he got a large number of copies printed and sent to persons who, he thought, were likely to agitate in its favour. This criticism was so effective that, as he tells us, "no more was heard of the mischievous bill, either within or without the House."* Then the Commissioners came to their own Remedial Measures. The most pressing evil * Life of Francis Ptace, by G. Wallas, p. 331. F 82 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. is that in connection with the relief of the able- bodied. " If we believed," they say, " that the evils described were necessarily incidental to the compulsory relief of the able-bodied, we should not hesitate in recommending its entire abolition. But we do not believe these evils to be its necessary conse- quences. We believe that under strict regulations adequately enforced, such relief may be afforded safely and even bene- ficially." The regulations, the argument continues, must be directed to making the situation of the person relieved, on the whole, less eligible than that of the independent labourer of the lowest class. They then point out that such regulation had already been introduced into various districts by the private initiative of the local authority, and for the most part by means of the workhouse test. This was done at Southwell, by Mr Nicholls, at Bingham, by Mr Lowe, at Uley, by Mr Barwick Baker, and at a variety of other places. The absorption of the able-bodied pauper, or rather his conversion into an independent labourer, had in the places enumerated been suc- cessfully carried out. The following recommendation therefore is made : " That, except as to medical attendance, and subject to the exception respecting apprenticeship hereinafter stated, all relief whatever, to able-bodied persons or to their families, otherwise in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 83 than in well-regulated workhouses (i.e. places where they be set to work according to the spirit and intention of the 43rd of Elizabeth), shall be declared unlawful, and shall cease, in manner and at periods hereafter specified ; and that all relief afforded in respect of children under the age of 16 shall be considered as afforded to their parents." Relief to the able-bodied was not to be pro-"" hibited, but to be given in such a way that the able-bodied recipient of relief should be put in a less favourable position than the independent labourer, a condition, which if the relief given was to be adequate, could only be secured by the detention and discipline and at the same time adequate maintenance of the workhouse. The value of an automatic test is set out at considerable length. The Commissioners dwell very forcibly on the uselessness of investigation. Such a barrier every day offers a more feeble resistance to importunity. Unless there is some automatic test, officers in large towns, where investigation on an efficient scale is practically impossible, have no alternative between indis- criminately granting and indiscriminately refusing relief. The offer of relief in a well-regulated work- house, on the other hand, frees the administrator from this dilemma. The relief is adequate, and it will not be accepted unless it is necessary. With regard therefore to the responsibility of 84 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. able-bodied persons and their families, the Commissioners are clear that no out-door relief should be given. They assume, it should here be pointed out, for it becomes subsequently a point of considerable importance, a somewhat narrow definition of the responsibility of the able- bodied man. He is responsible for himself and family, while he is able-bodied, but he is not responsible for his sickness, his old age, or for those who are dependent on him, in the event of his death. This limited definition assumed by the Commissioners does very well for the limited reformation at which they were then aiming, but obviously it is logically quite untenable. The able-bodied period of life of every community must be responsible for the unable-bodied period. The ideal of a free in- dustrial community is that each one shall be re- sponsible for his own unable period and for that of those who by common consent are dependent on him. The Poor Law can make (and to a certain extent has made) the community responsible. The evil of the Old Poor Law was that the community had accepted this responsibility on a scale which had led to the ruin and demoralisation of those whom it sought to benefit. The Com- missioners were now proposing to oblige the able- bodied to resume, or, perhaps more correctly, to in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 85 take up for the first time, a part, limited as above indicated, of the responsibility which, under the new economic order, clearly belonged to the individual. The change was effected, not by an absolute refusal of relief, but by means of the "workhouse test." The question, which to-day is, or, if people took any interest in the matter, ought to be, a practical one, is : Why apply the strict test of destitution solely to what we may call man's major responsibility, i.e. his own able- bodied period of life, and refuse to apply it to his minor responsibilities, viz., his old age, his sickness, and the similar periods of disability in those dependent on him ? If the use of this test has been successful in creating independence when applied to the one * Mr Chadwick always objected to the use of the term Work- house Test. The so-called workhouse has never, under the New Poor Law, been a place where serious work was a feature of its manage- ment. For the sick it is a hospital, and for the aged an asylum ; the able-bodied, for whom it might be a place of work, are not, as a rule, to be found there. The principle of the institutional relief system makes administrators take the position " We will relieve altogether, or not at all." This, Mr Chadwick was fond of pointing out, is the rule of the workman's own Friendly Society, which pro- hibits its members in receipt of benefit from earning wages. The Friendly Society is a mutual institution in which the esprit de corps is very strong, yet the difficulty in checking improper claims is well known. The poor rate is a common prey protected by no such considerations. There is no chance of mutual investigation, such as hardly serves to prevent imposture in the Friendly Society. The only way to insure observance of the principle, " all or nothing," is to fence the poor rate by the institutional test. 86 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. form of responsibility to which the Commis- sioners explicitly and formally recommended its application, why should it not be extended further ? To this point, in a later chapter, we shall have to return. Here we merely allude to the subject by way of protest against the assumption that the Commissioners deliberately, and for all time, limited the responsibility of the able-bodied to the one period of his life. You cannot, as John Bright once said, drive six omnibuses abreast through Temple Bar. The one particular omni- bus that the Commissioners had to pilot through Parliament was a bill curtailing the facilities of Poor Law relief to the able-bodied. They left something to be done for the full emancipation of the pauper to this generation, which, alas ! has done very little. The denial of out-door relief to the able- bodied, and the institution, for this class, of the Workhouse Test, was the operative reform in- dicated. The next question was : Who were to be the authorities ? Every single authority hitherto charged with this duty had failed. The parish area is declared to be too small. Contrary to the very generally conceived opinion, the smaller the area, the greater had been the tendency to corruption and mismanagement. in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 87 The small parishes, moreover, could not afford to do things properly. The idea of unions of parishes was accordingly set up. The tempta- tion to peculation would be less powerful. The aggregation of paupers would make it worth while to classify. There would be greater economy in wholesale management. This part of the plan was specially Mr Chadwick's contribution, derived, as I have said, from Bentham's teaching. This much was ulti- mately adopted, but there were other proposals put forward by Mr Chadwick, more or less essential to his own and Bentham's plans, which were rejected. This is a very important point, and one which is very usually overlooked by historians and critics of the Act. Bentham in his Scheme of Pauper Manage- ment, and Mr Chadwick now, deliberately wished to get rid of local and empirical administra- tion, or, at least, to reduce it to a minimum. Mr Chadwick was willing to see boards of guardians elected for the new unions, but he wished them to have nothing to do with relief. This was to be placed in the hands of salaried experts, responsible to a central authority. Relief, moreover, was to be entirely institutional, i.e. given within the walls of some Poor Law establishment. The guardians, locally elected, 88 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. were merely to inspect Poor Law institutions, as the visiting justices inspected prisons. It was, in fact, a proposal for a responsible bureaucracy. This was, as we all know, set aside. It is not even included in the recommendation of the Report ; but it is important to notice that only a portion of Mr Chadwick's scheme was adopted, and that he never ceased to complain of the mutilation of his plan. This part of the Report shows some traces of difference of opinion, or, rather, much of it seems to lead to a recommendation which is not there. The report alludes to a desire which they found among the most intelligent adminis- trators, " that the smallest detail should be unalter- ably prescribed by the legislature." They gather also, as an inevitable consequence, from the evidence that "the legislature should divest the local authorities of all discretionary power in the administration of relief ." This recommenda- tion, however, is not formally made. Their formal recommendation with regard to a central authority is as follows : " We recommend therefore the appointment of a Central Board to control the administration of the Poor Law, with such assistant Commissioners as may be found requisite, and that the Commissioners be empowered and directed to frame and enforce regulations, for the government of workhouses, and as to the nature and amount of the relief to be given, in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 89 and the labour to be exacted in them, and that such regulations shall, as far as may be practicable, be uniform throughout the country." This, of course, is a very large power to in- trust to any public body. Parliament, however, accepted the recommendation, and, feeling that the details were for it unmanageable, delegated its authority to three experts, who had to assume all the odium of enforcing an unpopular revolution. It was, however, a small power compared with that which had been exercised for centuries by the petty local officers who, practically at discretion, had administered the parochial relief system of the country. As events have proved, moreover, the authority of the Central Board, great as it nominally is, has never been equal to inducing the local bodies to accept its views. For long it kept up a running commentary of protest in favour of the principles of 1834. Not till the closing months of the last century has the Central Authority shown any sign of reaction.* It is to be hoped that boards of guardians will be as impervious to reactionary counsels, as they have hitherto been to counsels of reform. It is to his prescience of these difficulties that Mr Chadwick's objection to a divided authority may be ascribed. * See p. 190. 90 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. To create large local bodies, by means of popular election, for the administration of this difficult system, and then to subject them to the coercion of a board of experts sitting at Whitehall, was a very perfect receipt for making friction. It might control abuses, but it was certain ultimately to paralyse progress. Mr Chadwick's proposal was to put the local bodies in such a helplessly inferior position, as regards authority, that effectual opposition of local authorities to Central ideas of administration would have been impossible. The rejection of his advice has made Poor Law administration a sort of cockpit for contentions of the local and central authority, and ensured the continuance of abuses which a single responsibility, either local or central, might have reformed. At the same time and after all, the blame for this miscarriage rests not with the early Commissioners, who did what was practicable at the time, but with a later generation. The rest of the recommendations need not detain us ; they consist largely in advising that the introduction of the new Act, the forming of unions, the time of bringing the new rules into operation, and the details generally, should be left to the Central Board. A bill was introduced practically on these in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 91 lines. It was drafted by Mr Nassau Senior, and he attended the Committees of the Cabinet to explain the bill. He left a MS. account of these meetings, which I have been allowed to see. One of the points which struck me in reading this memorandum, and, I have no doubt, struck Mr Senior also in writing it, was the curious way in which some Cabinet ministers would come and suggest the introduction of a clause authorising the continuance of an old abuse, or perhaps suggesting a new one based on the old principle, apparently quite unconscious of the grave economic principles which were at stake. If even Cabinet ministers found it diffi- cult to legislate in accordance with principles which they were supposed to have accepted, it is obvious that we are incurring great dangers when large powers of discretion are placed in the hands of local administrators who cannot, on an average, be as well read and informed as Cabinet ministers. The bill, however, got through the Cabinet, and was introduced by Lord Althorp and passed through Parliament in the course of the session of 1834. It is very creditable to the Parliament of the day that it passed. I do not think that any Government of our own day would venture to bring in such a bill, and if they did, it would 92 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. provoke an amount of opposition which would, I believe, prove fatal to its passage. The circumstances were peculiar. The Whig ministries of the time are generally represented to have cut a sorry and timorous figure. Be this as it may, it was a time when Liberal principles wielded an undoubted authority. The Liberal of that day was guided by a belief in the salutary influence of liberty and in the possibility of working-class independence. Philosophical Liberalism was something above and apart from political party. It kept men like Francis Place from lending their influence and aid to the Socialist side of the Chartist agitation. In spite of his own party, it inspired Peel with those principles of fiscal reform which will ever entitle him to the gratitude of the civilised world. It has been well said that it is the only party of political opinion (as a party it was rarely, and only for a brief period, in office and in power) which has ever attempted to apply a definite body of doctrine to the business of government. The abolition of the worst abuses of the Old Poor Law and the repeal of the Corn Laws are instalments of reform which we owe to its exposition of the far- reaching economic doctrine of Free Exchange. A few of the extreme and less educated in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 93 members of both parties offered opposition, Cobbett, of course, opposed everything but there was really no serious opposition from that side of the house ; and the leaders of the Tory party, to their great credit, abstained from opposing the Act, while the Duke of Wellington, who here, as on many other occasions, rose above party, gave it his warm support. Sir Robert Peel remarked some years after- wards, when it fell to his lot as minister to defend the measure, which he did with complete conviction and loyalty, that such a bill could never have been passed by a Conservative Government. It was a measure which could only be successfully carried through Parliament by a party which was regarded as specially the exponent of popular sentiment. When the bill had got through the Commons, Lord Grey resigned, and for a moment its fate was doubtful. During the interregnum the subject was raised more than once, and its opponents, mainly among the Tories, urged that the bill should be dropped. It was at this crisis that the influence of the Duke of Wellington was exerted, and, in this respect, he probably did his country a service not less notable than that which he rendered in the Peninsula and at Waterloo. 94 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. The Government was reconstructed with Lord Melbourne at its head. Lord Brougham, the Chancellor, undertook the introduction of the bill to the Lords. With all his extraordinary ability and industry, his lordship was a danger- ous ally. Notwithstanding the protests both of Mr Senior, who was shown his notes, and of his own colleagues, he made a speech which was hostile to the principle of a Poor Law alto- gether, and his attitude alarmed timid supporters. Mr Senior's note on the matter is, that what he said was true, but injudicious, that the argument was admirably stated, and probably did no harm, even if it proved too much for the occasion. The Duke of Wellington dissociated himself from Lord Brougham's condemnation of all Poor Laws. The Duke had a constitutional dis- like of theories, but he supported this bill, which was not a bill, he said, for abolition of the Poor Law. When his followers began to complain of the lateness of the session and to propose postponement, he very curtly told them that it was their duty to stay and pass this measure. The most elaborate attack made on the bill was that of Mr Poulett Scrope in the Commons. The principal point which he made against the measure is of extreme interest, and in view of HI.] THE NEW FUUJK LAW 95 subsequent events deserves to be considered in detail. He pointed out quite truly that the bill was a departure from the principle of the Act of Elizabeth, which was to set the poor on work, and to provide work and stock for all who demanded it. " You profess," he said, "to be re- turning to the wisdom of Elizabeth : you are not so returning. A man asks you for work, you do not give him work, but you lock him up in a workhouse." This was a difficult line " of argument to answer for those who believed that there was any wisdom in the Act of Elizabeth. He then went on (and to this argument special atten- tion is due) : The duty of the legislature is to find work for all. If the legislature will perform its duty in this respect, there is no need to trouble about the aged, the sick, the widow and the orphan. They will be supported by the able-bodied of their family and class and possibly he might have allowed us to add, by savings made during the period of full employment. His argument was not listened to, it certainly was not answered. What he says is perfectly true, for if we can secure the independence of the able-bodied, there should be no need of large 96 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. measures of intervention in favour of those who are not able-bodied ; the able-bodied period of their own lives, and of those on whom they have a natural claim, should be sufficient to meet all ordinary emergencies. What Mr Scrope did not see was that the steps taken in the bill to cut off the able-bodied from all out-door relief was a much more effec- tual way of securing their independence and full employment than the procedure recommended by himself and by the vaunted wisdom of Elizabeth. The rest of his argument seems to me to hold. If the independence of the able-bodied can be secured (and it has been secured by the very measure which Mr Scrope condemned), there ought to be no difficulty in getting the able- bodied to assume a fuller responsibility for the rest of the risks of life. We shall see presently when we come to describe the working of the Act, how some Boards of Guardians have made use of the discretion allowed to them, and, by a policy of strict administration, have obliged the able-bodied to be responsible for the unable-bodied period of their own lives, and of those dependent on them ; and how, in every instance where this line of action has been followed, a higher range of inde- in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 97 pendence has been attained. Their experience proves, in fact, how entirely just the latter part of Mr Scrope's argument was, and, at the same time, how entirely mistaken as to the steps to be taken to secure the initial independence of the able-bodied. Of course, in addition to the criticism of Mr Scrope, there was a loud outcry among the sentimentalists. It was, they said, a monstrous thing to deprive the poor man of a fund which appeared to belong to him ; but the burden of pauperism had grown intolerable, and the country was ready, in despair, to give a trial to any plan recommended to it by high authority. It was not, therefore, till the Act got into operation, and till the Commissioners had to exert authority to get its provisions adopted, in places where the Poor Law had not been so badly mismanaged for example in the northern towns that the great outcry arose. They intro- duced the law first into the worst districts, namely, into the south, and their action here was welcome. It was only later that the outcry became violent, and then only in a few places. It is worth while to compare this crisis with the crisis which arose in the time of Elizabeth. At the earlier period the sentimental instinct prevailed, and the economic principle of liberty G 98 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. and exchange was neglected and set aside. Instead, the decaying principle of feudalism was revived in the Poor Law, and, as my subsequent narrative has been designed to show, the mistaken policy was adopted of attempting the solution of an economic problem by sentimental, empirical, and temporary palliatives. In 1834 the country was confronted by a similar crisis. The sentimental empiricism of Elizabeth's Act was discredited by the fearful abuses which it had created. It was perhaps easier on that account to get the uninstructed public to agree to a more scientific treatment of this malady. To the uninstructed the obvious remedy for distress is relief, and plenty of it. The folly of this treatment had become apparent, and the Whig Government of 1834 carried an Act which gave a wiser answer to the question than that which was given in 1601. Unfortunately, as we shall presently see, the reform has only gone a very little way, and our poorer classes are still doomed to spend a portion of their lives among the flesh-pots of parochial bondage. I have indicated already some of the causes which limited the reforms, and in the next chapter I shall have to point out how dispauperisa- tion, although practicable, has never been adopted as a policy. in.] THE NEW POOR LAW 99 Still, with all its imperfections, the new Act was a first instalment towards the emancipation of the poor from the Poor Law. Relief to the able-bodied was not prohibited, but it was to be given under conditions which, it was well known, would be severely deterrent. It was proved that this had been effectual in emancipating the able-bodied population at Southwell, Bingham, and elsewhere, and the legislature faced the unpopular duty of obliging other authorities to follow these salutary examples. When the pressure, which, as we have seen, was principally caused by the demand of the able-bodied, was reduced, the local administra- tions were able to turn to better methods for the relief of other forms of distress. Classifica- tion became possible, and a decent treatment of the young, the sick, and the aged was brought within the means of all, even the poorest local authority. This was the merit of the Act, but the merit of the Report goes a good deal further. In the pages of this memorable document there is to be found a most complete and irre- fragable statement of principles going to the very root of the matter. The recommendations, and the Act which was subsequently founded ioo PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. in. on them, are only an instalment of the reforma- tion of which the subject is capable. Regard had to be paid to what was practi- cable. A disease of long standing cannot be cured by subjecting the patient at once to the full regimen of health, but the approach to, and ultimate adoption of, such a regimen must ever be an object with each successive generation. It should be our business to complete, as far as circumstances may permit, the dispauper- isation of the remnant that still remains confined in a condition of parochial dependence. Wise methods of treatment can be learnt in the pages of the Report of 1834. CHAPTER IV THE ADMINISTRATION OF THE NEW POOR LAW WE have now to consider the results which followed from the introduction of the new Poor Law. The new Poor Law, while it did not abolish relief to the able-bodied, ordered that relief should only be given under conditions which were, in large measure, prohibitive. The offer of relief in a workhouse came very near to being a denial of relief. It practically freed the administrator from the most importunate class of applicants under the old law, and he was thus able to turn his mind to improving the relief arrangements for the sick, the aged, and for children. The Legislature had seen that it could not trust to the local administrator to initiate these reforms of his own motion. It had, therefore, created a new Board of Control, and left it to this body to choose the season and manner in which the new system was to be introduced. The new Board consisted of three Com- 101 102 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. missioners, who were, Sir Thomas Frankland Lewis, Mr J. G. Shaw Lefevre, and Mr George Nicholls, with Mr Chadwick as their secretary. This was a grievance to Mr Chadwick, who really was, in large measure, the author of the new law. He complained of being put in a subordinate position, under chiefs who did not fully sympathise with the policy of the new law, or, perhaps to speak more correctly, with his conception of what that policy ought to be. Mr Chadwick, as I pointed out in the last chapter, wanted to supersede local elected bodies altogether, and to replace them by a new service of salaried experts ; but though the Legislature gave very wide and almost despotic powers to the Central Board (which was supposed to be inspired by the principles of the Report of 1834), it also created new popular bodies in each locality who were not experts. These new bodies, whether it was intended or not, have been too powerful for the Central Board, and what Mr Chadwick re- garded as expert and responsible administration has never been generally adopted. On one point, and on one point only, the authority of the Central Commissioners did prevail, viz., in the abolition of out-door relief to the able-bodied. In the south the local iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 103 administrator had been reduced to despair, and eagerly sought the help of the assistant Com- missioners, who were sent round the provinces to introduce the new law. The evils which the Old Poor Law sought to remedy had been generally attributed to over-population. The work of Malthus had attracted great attention, and there were many symptoms which gave a plausible support to this view. There is, without doubt, a tendency in mankind to increase and multiply, and, if the con- fines of the world and of industry were rigidly fixed and incapable of expansion, there would be no escape from the melancholy prognostications of Malthus and his sect. Under the Old Poor Law the limits of industry were rigidly fixed. The labourer felt himself obliged to stay at his place of settlement, and to continue at his ancient calling. So at Bledlow, as described a few pages back, he insisted on having work found for him in his parish, useless work which was so absurd in its character that, instead of doing it, he lay and slept under the hedges, and refused to walk into the next parish, where the railway, a typical instance of the new industry that was then im- pending, was waiting to be made. The great merit of the new law was that, at a stroke, it struck these fetters from the energies io 4 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. of the labouring class. Full energy and in- dustrial competence does not follow at once on a mere legislative act of emancipation, and, even to this day, some of the old evil influence remains ; but the first important step in emanci- pation was taken by the New Poor Law, and, indeed, the change that was brought about instantaneously was almost miraculous. The three Commissioners published very careful annual reports of their proceedings. The interest of the situation turns mainly on the well-nigh instantaneous absorption of the able-bodied pauper population into the inde- pendent industrial community. I have been at pains in a supplemental volume to Sir G. Nicholls' History to set out the different ways in which absorption took place. Sometimes in a parish where previously there had been every appearance of congestion and of a surplus population, the prohibition of outdoor relief at once restored a natural order of things, the farmers were obliged to pay a full wage, and the labourer was ready to give a good day's work. Confidence was restored, and the " human exchanges," as Chalmers termed it, began again to perform their beneficent work. Without the migration of a single person, parishes which formerly appeared to be con- iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 105 gested with a surplus population were peopled again by an industrious and independent peasantry. The following is the sort of remark that passed in the hearing of the assistant Com- missioners : "In old days," said a farmer, " I would have given money to keep that man off my land ; now he gives me a good day's work for a good day's pay, and I would gladly employ a dozen such." Sometimes the alleged surplus walked into the next parish. There were new industries on every side, and it is to be observed that, in a parish where there may have been surplus, it was not necessary for the whole population to acquire the mobility which is appropriate to an efficient industrial community. All that is re- quired to give relief to the pressure is that a few shall move. A glass of water that is brimming over does not require to be emptied ; a few drops taken from the top will enable it to fulfil its purpose without spilling. The move- ment of population which took place at this date was not perceptibly great, still a healthy industrial temper, a thing in its way quite as important as freer migration, was created. A man, when his natural responsibilities are allowed to rest on him for the first time, finds it possible to do many things which he never tried before. 106 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. It was no longer his interest, now that relief in aid of wages and the allowance system were at an end, to avoid the appearance, and, with the appearance, the reality of industry and prosperity. Formerly no farmer could employ a labourer without setting some one to watch over him ; now he could trust him to work with a minimum of supervision. Labourers now became eager to obtain allotments, and added from this source to their slender wages. Another cause of improvement was the wiser expenditure of the poor. Mr Chadwick has pointed out how an income drawn from the tainted source of the poor rate, even when the condition of the pauper labourer was most de- pressed, seemed always to leave a margin for waste. Even in places where the entire annual value of the land had been swallowed up by the poor rate, there was still a great deal of unwise expenditure. Thus at Cholesbury, the unhappy parish where the overseers were at length forced to throw up their books, and where the rate could no longer be collected, there were still two public-houses. Many in- stances are given in the early reports of an improvement in this respect. The withdrawal of expenditure from the public-house under the pressure of the new law iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 107 is typical of the diversion of expenditure which follows every restriction of the Poor Law. The fuller responsibility thrown on the labourer does not interfere with his necessary consumption, but only with his superfluities. His superfluous expenditure is forced into better and wiser channels, and, apart from the benefit to himself, industry gains from the healthier direction which is given to working-class demand. Indeed, the best and most formidable com- petitor to the public - house is the natural responsibility which rests on every man, till it is intercepted by some device of the Poor Law, to make provision for old age, sickness, and the other risks of life. Notwithstanding the Commissioners' record of the benefit derived from the Act, as not unfrequently happens in such matters, the out- cry of a few, whose interests and prejudices appeared to be threatened, drowned the whispered acknowledgment that a great and salutary reform had been effected. Before long there arose a strong opposition to the Act, more especially in the large manufacturing centres of the north. The Times took up an attitude hostile to the law, a certain section of the Chartists, notwithstanding the protests of Francis Place, excited the populace, and the io8 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND TCHAP. difficulties of the Commissioners became very great. The Commissioners, moreover, were a divided body, as great differences of opinion had arisen between them and their secretary, Mr Chadwick. They did, however, succeed in issuing an order prohibitory of outdoor relief to the able-bodied to all, or nearly all, of the rural unions ; but in view of the strong opposition raised in the towns, they wavered, and issued to the towns an order which sub- sequently, after many amendments and modi- fications, became the Outdoor Relief Regulation Order. This order was much less stringent than the Prohibition order, and, in many places, the issue even of this- order was delayed. It permitted out-relief to be given under a labour test, which need not be exacted in a workhouse, and somewhat enlarged the exceptions which were exempted from the Prohibitory order. It was Mr Chadwick's contention (and, when the rupture became public, he was supported by Lord Brougham, Mr Roebuck, and some of the more extreme Radicals in the House of Commons), that this vacillation on the part of the Commissioners was fatal to their policy. Mr Chadwick and his supporters have it on their side, that all experience seems to show that, if this subject is handled firmly, the iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 109 difficulty is much less. The first introduction of a stricter system is always difficult, but once it has been introduced, it works much more smoothly than a lax system. The strict system works automatically, there is no favouritism, the relief given, if unpalatable in respect of the con- finement of the workhouse, is adequate. There is no room for importunate demands to secure increased allowances, nor for the canvassing, jealousy and disappointments which are charac- teristic of the laxer system. The truth is that the opposition was largely factious and political. The Commissioners were most unfairly placed under a cross-fire. Mr Chadwick and his Radical friends com- plained that they had not been strenuous enough in pushing forward the policy of the Report of 1834. On the other hand, the Chartists, the sentimentalists, Mr Disraeli, and the Tory Democrat of the day, attacked the new system on the ground that it was too severe. Whether, if the Commissioners had adopted the very strenuous line advocated by Mr Chadwick and persons like Place, they would have been able to ride out the storm, it is difficult to say. An incident, however, arose, of no great import- ance in itself which precipitated a crisis. At Andover there was an unfortunate scandal of no PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. administration. Sir James Graham, the Home Secretary, when questioned in Parliament, de- scribed it, truly enough, as a workhouse squabble in the South of England. It turned in the first instance on the propriety of bone-crushing as a labour test for able-bodied paupers. There were also accusations of immorality against the workhouse master. One of the assistant Com- missioners was sent to inquire into the matter. The inhabitants of the place formed themselves into factions on one side and the other. The assistant Commissioner was supposed to have unduly hurried over the inquiry, and endeavoured to compose the scandal. When public attention was called to the matter, the Commissioners and Sir James Graham condemned the conduct of their assistant, and asked for his resignation. His friends took the matter up, and that of another assistant who had been similarly called on to resign. Mr Chadwick then appeared as a hostile witness against his chiefs. The so-called Andover Inquiry developed into an inquiry into the management of the Commission generally, and the evidence of internal dissension, which was very maliciously brought out, did consider- able damage to its reputation. The result of it all was that the Government of Lord John Russell, which in May, 1847, iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW in succeeded the great Ministry of Sir R. Peel, brought in a bill to abolish the Commissioners. o and to appoint in their place a Poor Law Board. The Commissioners hitherto had had no re- presentative in Parliament, for it had been thought possible and preferable to make this office unpolitical. Now the argument was accepted that the friction which had arisen would be more easily removed if the head of the Poor Law Board was a member of the Government. The change was accordingly made, and the Poor Law Board was instituted. This, in 1871, was abolished in favour of the Local Government Board a change merely of name and the head of the Poor Law adminis- tration is now the President of the Local Government Board. How far the expectation of the Government that the change would make the law more work- able has proved correct, it is difficult to say. What has really made the law more workable seems rather to have been the much less aggressive attitude taken up by the Central Authority to the abuses of the Poor Law. Practically by 1847 the great battle against able-bodied pauperism had been fought and won. The able-bodied pauper had already been forced into a position of independence. The introduc- ii2 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. tion of Free Trade had begun to cause an unpre- cedented demand for labour of all kinds. In many various directions technical skill was being acquired. A large section of the labouring class was safely extricated from the slough of pauperism, and showed no tendency to return. The local authorities, though by no means expert, had, some of them, sense enough to see the danger of relapse. Even where a return to old abuses, with regard to the treatment of the able-bodied, was threatened, the authority of the Central Board had been sufficient to maintain the ground that had been gained. Since this date the change of attitude on the part of the Central Board has been very marked. In the early years of the Com- missioners' tenure of office their action was distinctly aggressive, and, if Mr Chadwick's policy had prevailed, they would have con- tinued to be aggressive, till they had obliged the local bodies to adopt their views. The over- rule of such a Board on a matter of this nature was a thing which local bodies in England were not likely to stand indefinitely, and the Poor Law constitution of 1834 has only been found workable, because, practically, the Central Board, in respect of Poor Law reform, has been content to take a subordinate iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 113 position in everything except the prohibition of outdoor relief to the able-bodied. Since then, as to the main principle of relief, it has been advisory rather than regulative. Possibly no other course was open to it. It has, in this later period, endeavoured to effect by persuasion and argument reforms which it had the power to effect peremptorily, and it has been moder- ately successful. As might be expected, it has succeeded in pushing forward popular reforms, more easily than those which, though equally necessary, are unpopular. The administration of the Poor Law has, or ought to have, two objects. One is to secure adequate, prompt, and appropriate relief for the destitute. That is a popular object, even though it is costly. The Local Government Board has had no difficulty in inducing the local adminis- trator to spend very freely for the purpose of building schools and infirmaries, and generally in trying to do this work well. This aspect of the question, I should say in passing, was deemed very important by Mr Chadwick and by his master, Jeremy Bentham. In Mr Chad wick's conception of the well-governed community, the treatment of disease and sanitation was to be entrusted to an expert bureaucracy, and he confidently expected very large reforms from this H ii4 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. policy. We have got the large system of treat- ment in our Poor Law infirmaries, schools, lunatic asylums, but in Mr Chadwick's view the subordination of the expert and salaried official to the inexpert and irresponsible local repre- sentatives mars its effectiveness. The danger attaching to the present system of Poor Law medical treatment, and to the even more effective system which Mr Chadwick would have liked to inaugurate, is, that it makes for fthe universal gratuitous treatment of the poor in sickness, a result not compatible with the ideal of absolute independence which alone is likely to satisfy the aspiration of the labourer. What Bentham and Chadwick would have done to check this tendency, we hardly know, as their views were never given a fair trial. This first object of Poor Law administration, the pro- vision of adequate institutional treatment for the destitute, promoted amid favouring popular breezes by the Central Board, has been readily accepted by the local authorities. The second object of the administration of the Poor Law is less popular. It is the task of dispauperisation. It has been well said that no Poor Law system is efficacious, unless its influence is centrifugal and not centripetal. This means that the Poor Law ought to be perpetually iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 115 putting pressure on the pauper class, urging it away from reliance on the rates, in the hope that much of it will naturally gravitate to the independence of the industrial life. In other words, the poor rate must never become a centre of attraction and expectation for the poor. I have endeavoured throughout to represent that the primitive condition of mankind is not only one of poverty, but of a certain impervious- ness to economic motive of all kind. Civilisation means the gradual organisation of society on the basis of the economic order. This is carried out and built up by allowing man to follow the teaching of what Chalmers has called the " human exchanges." Pauperism is the last remnant of that primitive condition of disability, of which already a great, perhaps we may say the greater, part has vanished, and given place to the honour- able interdependence of an industrial community. Now, the proper treatment of the evil that still remains with us requires something more than the endowment, by means of legal machinery of those who succeed in getting themselves accepted as destitute. Beyond elaborate and adequate systems of relief, we do require, in the cause of progress, the adoption of measures calculated to detach the poor, more or less forcibly, from a contented reliance on the poor rate. n6 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. It is supposed to be one of the great merits of the English Poor Law, as modified by the Amendment Act of 1834, that it fulfils these conditions. 'By means of a series of institutions it enables the administrator to offer, in every alleged case of destitution, adequate and appro- priate forms of relief. It is also supposed that the confinement and discipline of these Poor Law establishments will be such that no applicant will accept the offer, unless he is absolutely un- L able to live on his own resources. | Further and this perhaps is of more importance the pro- spective offer of relief under these conditions does not encourage a fatal acquiescence in dis- abilities which can be removed by a suitable admixture of energy and caution certain to be developed in the character of the poorer class by -the mere experience of lifeN This is the ideal that the framers of the Poor Law Amendment Act had in view. {^ In other words, it was to provide the country with an instrument that would serve the double purpose of relieving destitution, and of dissipating the moral and economic atmosphere which was favourable to the growth and permanence of the pauper habit/") Our business as students and critics is to consider how far the object of the framers o 1 iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 117 the law has been met, how far, in fact, the in- strument which they made has achieved its purpose. I have already indicated that, as far as the able-bodied labourer is concerned, he has, during the able-bodied period of his life, been more or less completely emancipated from parochial servitude. I have also pointed out that when this advance had been secured, the motive power making for administrative reform, viz., the authority of an expert Central Board, appears to have been exhausted. The principal authority then became vested in the local bodies. The members of these were by no means experts, and though elected for the government of a larger area than heretofore, they were still irresponsible and still liable to be influenced by the prejudices which had been so fatal in the period previous to the reform of 1834. The instrument of the New Poor Law logically applied might be admirable for effecting its purpose, but it obviously required to be handled by persons who understood its use, in fact by experts. The chances of having the matter handled in an "expert" fashion by locally elected administrators were very remote. It has been said, and the point deserves n8 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. notice, that the Poor Law Commissioners, whose words are often cited as sources of plenary inspiration, limited their expectation of reform to the case of the able-bodied daring their able- bodied period of life. It is true that during the pressure of controversy, language of this sort is to be found incidentally in the Reports. It is, however, necessary to distinguish the first great Report of the Commission of Inquiry, and the subsequent reports issued by the three Com- missioners after the introduction of the law. The Report of the Commission of Inquiry insists only on the abolition of outdoor relief to the able-bodied. It says, however, nothing to forbid the application of its principles to a wider area. We know, also, that it was in Mr Chadwick's mind gradually, and as occasion offered, to stop outdoor relief altogether. The Report of the three Commissioners, appointed in pursuance of the Act, has not the same authority as the Report of Inquiry. They wrote under great pressure, and with divided counsels, and, on one occasion at all events, they declare that they had no intention of pushing on the prohibition order to cover the case of the aged, unless circumstances and abuses render it necessary. At other portions of their reports they lay down principles, diametrically iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 119 opposed to this admission, which undoubtedly carry us much further in a policy of restriction than they thought it advisable to go. At this time of day, however, we are not absolutely bound by their conclusions. As their conclusions are contradictory, this is not possible. We have to decide whether we shall follow the Commissioners in their stricter and more scientific mood, or allow ourselves to be influenced by chance expressions of compromise wrung from them in the course of a bitter and critical controversy. We have to consider, as practical men of full age, whether further measures of dispauperisation are possible or not. In 1839, the three Commissioners were invited by Lord John Russell to make a report on certain suggestions that had been made as to their continuance in office, and as to the further amendment of the law. Their reply, known as the "Continuance Report, 1839," con- tains one of the most forcible statements of principles which is to be found in the whole range of Poor Law literature : "The fundamental principle," they say, "with respect to the relief of the poor is, that the condition of the pauper ought to be, on the whole, less eligible than that of the independent labourer. . . . The truth of this principle has either been generally admitted, or, at least, has not been disputed; but the difficulty has consisted in applying it to practice." 120 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. Elsewhere the situation has been summed up by saying that Poor Law relief should be con- fined to the destitute : that is to say, it is not intended for the poor, unless their poverty is so extreme that they are unable to maintain them- selves. As the Commissioners say in the above- quoted passage, the difficulty is in applying this to practice. How, in other words, are we to distinguish destitution from mere poverty. An answer is supplied by the passage which follows the above quotation : "A distribution of relief of money or goods, to be spent or consumed by the pauper in his own house, is inconsistent with the principle in question. Money or goods given to paupers, to be spent or consumed by themselves as they may think proper, is, in general, more acceptable than an equal value earned as wages, inasmuch as it is not accompanied by the painful condition of labour. " Supposing, again, that the persons charged with the duty of relieving the poor relieve them with money or goods at their own houses, but attempt to exact some labour in return, this mode of relief is found to be equally inconsistent with the principle in question. If the remuneration of the labourer is independent of his industry or good conduct ... he is exempt from the motives which ordinarily operate upon the independent labourer, and his condition resembles that of a slave whom his master is bound to maintain, but whom he cannot punish for idleness or misconduct. " In order, therefore, to carry the above-mentioned principle into effect, it is necessary that the pauper should be relieved, not by giving him money or goods to be spent or consumed iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 121 in his own house, but by receiving him into a public establish- ment. But a public establishment, if properly arranged, necessarily secures to its inmates a larger amount of bodily comfort than is enjoyed by an ordinary independent labourer in his own dwelling. For example, an inmate of a well- appointed Union Workhouse lives in rooms more spacious, better ventilated, and better warmed; his meals are better and more regularly served ; he is more warmly clad, and he is better attended on in sickness, than if he were in his own cottage ; moreover, all these things are supplied to him with perfect regularity, and without any forethought or anxiety on his part. Thus far, relief in a public establishment violates the principle above adverted to, and places the pauper in a more eligible condition than the independent labourer. And yet humanity demands that all the bodily wants of the inmates of a public establishment should be amply provided for. The only expedient, therefore, for accomplishing the end in view which humanity permits, is to subject the pauper inmate of a public establishment to such a system of labour, discipline, and restraint as shall be sufficient to outweigh, in his estima- tion, the advantages which he derives from the bodily comforts which he enjoys. This is the only mode, consistent with humanity, of rendering the condition of the pauper less eligible than that of the independent labourer, and upon this principle the English Union Workhouses have been organised." The Report then goes on : " With regard to the aged and infirm, however, there is a strong disposition, on the part of a portion of the public, so to modify the arrangements of these establishments as to place them on the footing of almshouses. The consequences which would flow from this change have only to be pointed out to show its inexpediency and its danger. If the condition of the inmates of a workhouse were to be so regulated as to invite the aged and infirm of the labouring class to take refuge 122 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. in it, it would immediately be useless as a test between indigence and indolence or fraud. It would no longer operate as an inducement to the young and healthy to provide support for their later years, or as a stimulus to them, while they have the means, to support their aged parents and relatives." It would be difficult to state the objections to outdoor relief more forcibly, and this is a statement of principles which we prefer to any expressions of a contrary tenor which may here and there be discovered in the writings of the Commissioners. If these views had been shared by the local administrators, there can be no doubt that out-door relief would have come to an end long ago ; but, as we all know, that has not happened. The violent opposition which had assailed the three Commissioners disappeared when the Poor Law Board was appointed in 1847. The period which followed may be described as a period of marking time. The Board published short reports, and endeavoured to avoid con- troversy. Its energies were directed to getting rid of some of the abuses of Removal, also to pushing the authority of the central office into places where there were local Acts. The most important legislation of the period was the Union Chargeability Act, 1865. Hitherto, in as much as the permissive clauses in the Act iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 123 of 1834 had only been utilised in one or two cases, there had been continued a separate parochial chargeability even for those parishes which were combined in Unions. Though the Union was the administrative unit, the chargeability was still parochial. This weighed very heavily on the poorer parishes, and gave rise to very undesirable practices with regard to cottage property. In what were called close parishes, i.e. parishes owned by one or two like-minded owners, in order to avoid liability for the relief of the poorer class of inhabitants, the building of cottages was curtailed, and the poor were driven into ad- joining parishes, where, by this means, both rents and rates were unduly raised. This system was now swept away, and the Union, which had been the area of administration, became also the area of chargeability. These, however, are technical details, and the scale on which we are considering the subject obliges us to pass over without notice many episodes of importance. It is more interesting and instructive to confine our attention to the different views which from time to time pre- vailed as to the principles of Public Relief. We therefore pass on to the new departure which dates from 1867-1870. I2 4 -PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. The Central Board ceased to be aggressive in 1847, and a period of acquiescence followed. About 1867, a fresh attempt was made to arouse interest in the scientific treatment of pauperism. Marking time was for the moment discontinued. The principle of the English Union Workhouse and its twofold purpose, as set out a few pages back, was again prominently brought into notice. By improved institutional treatment, instantane- ous, appropriate and adequate relief was to be insured in each case. At the same time, such a measure of discipline and confinement was to be preserved, that though adequate, the relief given was still to make for dispauperisation. In this connection we should mention Gathorne Hardy's Act of 1867. This applied to London only. It created the Metropolitan Asylums Board, and introduced the Common Poor Fund system, with the view of encouraging guardians in the poorer unions to incur adequate expendi- ture. By the Metropolitan Poor Amendment Act of 1870, the chargeability of the indoor poor in London Unions was to the extent of 5d. per head per diem transferred to the Metropolitan Common Poor Fund, a common rate levied on all London. This humanitarian side of Poor Law reform has been pushed forward with com- parative ease. Poor Law infirmaries, with their iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 125 staff of doctors and nurses, asylums, schools, etc., are lavishly, if not efficiently, carried on. At the same time, the other, the more difficult and unpopular side of sound Poor Law policy, was not ignored. In 1869, Mr Goschen, then President of the Poor Law Board, issued a Minute entitled, " Relief to the Poor in the Metropolis." This document urged greater care in the administration of out- door relief, and the desirability of co-operation between the Poor Law authorities and the re- presentatives of voluntary charity. The subject was taken up by the inspectors of the Board. Mr Woodhouse and Mr (afterwards Sir) Henry Longley published very instructive reports as to the mischief done, both in country and town, by the normal administration of outdoor relief. Professor Fawcett, in 1870, published his Cam- bridge lectures on Pauperism, in which he strenuously advocated the abolition of outdoor relief. As a result of this discussion, several Boards of Guardians determined to make an attempt to carry out the principles of the Poor Law Commissioners to their logical conclusion. In some half-a-dozen Unions the experiment has accordingly been made of administering our English Poor Law without any recourse to out- 126 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. door relief. The experiment has now gone on for about thirty years in several of these Unions. By those who are responsible, the experiment has been declared successful. This verdict has been confirmed, and the policy pursued recom- mended by the Reports of the Local Govern- ment Board and of its inspectors, and by more than one Parliamentary inquiry. The story has often been told, and I will not advert to it at any length here. The following is the statistical record of what has happened in Whitechapel : In the sixth week of the quarter ended Lady-Day 1870, there were 1410 indoor paupers, 5339 outdoor, 6758 total. Same period 1900 1510 indoor paupers, 23 outdoor, 1533 total. In Bradfield, in 1871, on ist January, there were OUTDOOR. INDOOR. TOTAL. -Q f i pauper to every 999 259 1258 < * I 13 inhabitants. On ist January 1900 OUTDOOR. INDOOR. TOTAL. is 121 i 39 / ' p au .p er to ever y I 129 inhabitants. Roughly speaking, in these two unions, pauperism has been reduced to one-fourth and one-ninth of its earlier proportions. This, I maintain, is exactly what we might expect from the precedents and arguments which have been narrated. iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 127 In 1834, the terrible burden of pauperism was relieved by a policy which made the able- bodied man responsible for his able-bodied period of life. The surplus population, which had seemed so burdensome, had been, almost at once, converted into valuable and independent labour force, a source of national and individual wealth. It was pointed out at the time by one, who bitterly opposed the new law, that an able- bodied labouring population, which, as a rule, was independent and fully employed, would be well able to minister to its own needs in those seasons when it was not able-bodied. The Poor Law Commissioners also, a body of men more profoundly versed than any others in the theory and practice of the art of social healing, had declared in the most explicit manner, that, by making the condition of the pauper less eligible than that of the independent, progress in dispauperisation could be confidently expected. They had added, moreover, the self-evident corollary that adequate relief, granted gratuit- ously to a pauper in his own home, does, in a material sense, put that pauper in a better position than his independent neighbour, who obtains an adequate maintenance only by pain- ful labour, by abstinence and self-sacrifice. And now again, from 1870 onwards, as might 128 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. have been expected, in every recorded experi- ment based on a further and more thorough appreciation of this principle, dispauperisation has resulted in a most marked degree. I cannot myself conceive any proof more cogent and more unanswerable. These views have, it is alleged, made some slight impression on the ordinary practice. A diminution of pauperism from four to two per cent, of the population in the last thirty years is put forward as a satisfactory rate of reduction. We must be thankful for small mercies, but it is open to us to remark that the improvement is so far short of what might be, that the position, re- latively to our increased wealth, is far from satisfactory. These dispauperising experiments have, as a rule, been made in places where formerly the rate had been exceptionally heavy. The two districts above-mentioned, from a variety of reasons, were the resort of a very poor population, the one, a poor district in a large town, the other, an agricultural union, remote from the manufacturing industry of the land. The effect of dispauperising measures, pursued in these unpromising localities, has been neutra- lised by the permanence of the older methods of administration in districts, in which, owing to more favourable economic surroundings, a iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 129 much more wide-spread emancipation would certainly have been secured by a more en- lightened policy. The statistical improvement, which can be recorded throughout the country generally, is due to the growth of the indepen- dent industrial population, and not to a decrease of pauperism. The fact that free industrial society is more absorbent of population than our pauper system is matter for congratulation, but it is no answer to those who affirm that our pauper system is still retentive and absorbent of population to a degree that is unnecessary and therefore malignant. The reason why so little progress has been made is obvious. It is precisely that anticipated by Mr Chadwick. This is a question requiring scientific treatment, and the New Poor Law is an instrument which, if properly used, enables the local administrator to relieve adequately, and yet to dispauperise. The local administrator, with only a few exceptions, has never accepted this view of his duties, and the reformation derived from the Act has fallen far short of the legitimate expectation of its authors. It is not for me to say that Mr Chadwick's idea, of administering by a responsible civil service a fund raised locally, was a practicable one. My object is only to point out that his plan i 130 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. was mutilated, and that an instrument, the in- stitutional system of relief authorised by the New Poor Law,* has not in the hands of the local empirics been used in the way its authors intended. If we read attentively the indictment which the Report of 1834 laid against vestries and other local administrators, we shall, I think, be forced to the opinion that much of it is still applicable to our local administration of the Poor Law. As it is, people who believe (on grounds which I have endeavoured to explain, and which might be indefinitely amplified and strengthened) that dispauperisation, a more or less complete emancipation of the poor from parochial depend- ence, is not only possible but easy, have to appeal to the local administrator. I have no wish to say anything disparaging of the local guardian, but I do not think that I am going at all beyond the truth when I say that he is not readily disposed to study this question in its historical and theoretical aspects. No one who has studied Poor Law electioneering literature can have much doubt of this. Very seldom is any definite policy put forward. Those who are in favour of a policy of dispauperisation are few, and knowing that this policy is unpopular, wisely * See note on p. 41 as to meaning of the term "Workhouse Test." IT.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 131 say nothing. The general impression left is that the majority of the candidates are attracted by the distinction which public office confers, and that very few indeed have any knowledge of or interest in the 'grave economic forces by which their work is controlled. Occasionally the can- didate descends to promises of outdoor relief, and plenty of it. More generally the addresses are remarkable for their irrelevancy. Candidates ask to be elected because they are Liberals or Conservatives, or because they have lived in the parish for many years, or because they are in favour of efficiency and economy which, if relevant, is also extremely vague. It is generally assumed that any fool can administer the Poor Law. Now, if there be any truth in the idea that the duties of a Poor Law Guardian, like the duties of a physician, have to be acquired by study, I think we must admit that the situation is not altogether satisfactory. If it was merely a question of administering a system rigidly prescribed by law, there would be no need of special training for the Poor Law Guardian. This, of course, is not the case. Within the discretion, allowed by the law and by the orders of the Local Government Board, there is room for such diversity of action, that whole districts 132 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. can be made or marred, in respect of dis- pauperisation, by the caprice of a local Board of Guardians. It is, however, to this somewhat fortuitous concourse of people who are elected as Poor Law Guardians that arguments have to be addressed. Here one is met by the difficulty that the majority of those to be addressed are not ac- cessible to argument. It is not for them to argue, they seem to say, but to administer the law within the full limits of the licence permitted by the statutes and orders which govern the subject. It requires a very strong conviction of the value of the reforms indicated to induce men or women to face the unpopularity involved. Persons desirous of pursuing a policy of emanci- pation must be prepared for much misrepresenta- tion and abuse. The chances of such success as would compensate are very slight under present conditions. We have fallen back again to the policy of marking time. The arguments put forward against dispauperisation by the methods here advocated are for the most part inarticulate. The mute prejudice which is practically in possession of the machinery of the law is quite unassailable. It occasionally puts forth an argument which is eagerly refuted, but its equanimity is not the least ruffled, and things iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 133 go on in their old way. We may notice some of these arguments, though we know it is use- less. They generally arrange themselves in two divisions. The first asserts that economy de- mands the use of outdoor relief. We can get rid of an applicant, they say, for 2s. 6d. outdoor relief, whereas if he comes into the house, he will cost us 6s. or 8s. The answer to this is, that, even if it were true, we want to do what is best for the poor, not what is cheapest. Further, ten will apply for and accept 2S. 6d., as against one who will accept an offer of the house a consideration which effectually disposes of the argument from economy. The second class of objection (and it takes many shapes) is that the policy of restriction is cruel to the poor. Of course, if we assume that there is no prospect or possibility of a further dissociation of the poor from the poor rate, it would be more difficult to meet this argument ; but I doubt if any one is so pessimistic as to attribute per- manence to the existing relations of the poor to the poor rate. Taking a sober and unim- passioned view of the progress made in the past, we contend that there is no reason to despair of the ultimate complete emancipation of the poor. And, that being so, we must not i 3 4 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. shrink from taking the necessary steps to secure their independence. I can myself see no flaw in the argument, based on history and actual experiment, which promises complete success to wise measures of dispauperisation. The difficulty is that very few administrators have sufficiently considered the history and theory of the subject, so as to be able to look beyond the apparent hardship to the individual cases with which they have to deal. It is, to my mind, as if the whole art and practice of surgery had been brought to a standstill, because the use of the surgeon's knife clearly, in many cases, inflicts pain. The difficulty raised, on the ground of the alleged inhumanity of the stricter system, is one entitled to the utmost consideration. The argu- ment from the hardship of the particular case appeals very strongly even to those whom their opponents are wont to call doctrinaires, and in most instances it will be found that the so-called doctrinaire advocates of restriction are willing to take some personal responsibility to deal by voluntary effort with exceptional applications. In this way, hard cases are not allowed to make bad law, and it is very important to add that, for reasons which will be given later, the liability assumed by such private persons has, in the IV.] 135 event, proved to be infinitesimal both in extent and amount. Still we must admit a feeling of great sympathy with those who say, " The general argument in favour of a stricter administration is all very well, but here is the case of old Mrs Jones, whose latter days have been made very happy by receipt of outdoor relief." I submit, however, that we must regard the question from a larger point of view. If, as I presume will be conceded, it is desirable that the aged of the labouring class should be maintained by a provision made by themselves or by those friends and relatives on whom they have a natural claim, as is the case in other ranks of life, it is obvious that this consummation is in- definitely postponed, so long as maintenance is forthcoming on easy terms from the poor rate. If we ask how it is that so many Mrs Jones are left destitute at this particular period of their lives, it is obvious that this is due to the inability or neglect of some one to fulfil his or her re- sponsibilities during the able-bodied period of life. It may not be possible to distinguish in- ability from neglect, but the result of legislating as if the inability was general and absolute, has had disastrous consequences to the independence of the poor. When an earlier generation, in 1834, demanded that the able-bodied man should 136 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. be held responsible for his able-bodied period of life, and if not that he should accept his relief under the institutional test, the same objection was raised. It was argued that it was cruel to oblige him to meet the responsibility. The result has proved that this assumption was erroneous. The failure to provide, which unfortunately is characteristic not only of a few individuals, but of a class, is not probably the result of inability or of a neglect that is in any sense culpable. It is the result of a perfectly common-sense calcula- tion that this is a risk provided for by a public rate. If this solution was a happy one for those most nearly concerned, we might be content to let the matter rest, but it is not. The abnegation and evasion of personal responsibility for their own maintenance at any period of life can not be arranged for systematically as it is at present, without causing grave economic injury to the poor. The expectancy of relief on easy terms has been an unbroken tradition for many genera- tions, yet, despite the greater independence of the labourer secured for him by the Poor Law Amendment Act of 1834, despite better wages and better conditions of toil generally, there still remains an artificial and unnecessary dependence iv.] ADMINISTRATION OF NEW POOR LAW 137 on the poor rate for those things which the poor rate will supply on eligible terms. What we have to do in order to complete the emancipation of the labourer is to break this tradition. We must imitate the courage of the reformers of 1834, and not be deterred by the fear of undue hardship to the passing generation. It must be remembered that hardship is un- fortunately inevitable in the life of the poor. It is not a choice between a system which entirely removes hardship and another that does not. The evidence is conclusive that where outdoor relief is given readily, the usual tendency is for the guardians to shrink from giving adequate relief. Under such a system applications are rapidly multiplied, relations and friends, who might otherwise assist, withdraw into the back- ground, and an ever-increasing amount of dis- appointment and discontent, as well as much hardship, is the result. The system is not even a safeguard against occasional deaths from starva- tion. Coroners' juries have returned verdicts of death from starvation in the case of persons who were actually at the time in receipt of outdoor relief. Paupers, moreover, know that outdoor relief is procurable. A refusal is rarely re- garded as final, and unfortunate applicants are induced to linger on, declining the offer of indoor 138 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. iv. relief, in the hope that their importunity will at length prevail. The hardship of this uncertainty is very real. On the other hand, institutional relief is cer- tainly adequate, while it throws the responsibility of accepting parish relief on the poor person, and re- lieves him from the partiality and injustice which, even when guardians are most desirous to be fair, must frequently occur. The greater humanity of the strict system, however, consists in the fact that it deliberately is aiming at placing the poor on a higher level of existence altogether. There is every reason to believe, moreover, that its influence is conducive to that end. Our last argument is, that if there are hard cases, a point which we do not wish to deny, they should be dealt with by voluntary action, and not strained in order to make bad law. The matter of the relation of voluntary agencies of Relief to the legal machinery of the Poor Law, must, however, be reserved for the next chapter. CHAPTER V THE RELATION BETWEEN LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY AGENCIES OF RELIEF HITHERTO we have discussed principally the legal side of our Public Relief system. In this chapter we have to include in our survey the relief given by public charity. At the outset, I think it will be convenient to make a distinction. Relief arising from endowed charitable funds, from subscriptions gathered by institutions and societies, and from the gifts of well-to-do people made to persons who are not known to them, otherwise than as persons requiring assistance, I propose to call Public Charity. The term private charity, I propose to apply to the good offices which pass between relations, friends, neighbours, employer and employed, acts of personal kindness and help which cannot with advantage be systematised and controlled by considerations of public policy. It is a matter of considerable domestic interest how far it is wise for a man to help a member of his own family, an old servant, a poor neighbour 139 1 40 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. or tenant, whose conduct may not have been exemplary, and who very possibly may be en- couraged by such help to persevere in reckless courses. It is, however, very important for us to observe that the presence of the personal element is a factor differentiating such action from what I prefer to call Public Chanty. I do not make this distinction with any desire to contract the answer to be given to the question : Who is my Neighbour ? On the contrary, I assume that we regard the whole world as our neighbour, and that our desire is to do, according to our ability, what is kindest and best for all. That being so, we have to recognise that personal relationship and personal inter- course confers certain privileges, and one is that acts of personal kindness and help may pass freely without loss of self-respect on either side, between persons who are, or have been, bound together by some personal tie. When, however, subscriptions are demanded on behalf of those with whom we have no personal connection, those who wish to consider the poor, and to be wise as well as good neighbours, must recognise that the question has now become one of public policy. The personal element, which, like the antiseptic spray, frees acts of private charity from poisonous after-effects, is v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 141 here absent, and our conduct must be governed by other considerations. We may be justified in overlooking social infirmities and errors in some one who has a personal claim on us, till seventy times seven, but it is generally recognised that, even in such cases, probably the kindest, certainly the most self- sacrificing, course to follow is to make any relief given subservient to some scheme of reclamation of conduct and character. This can, as a rule, only be done by exercise of personal influence. The amount of personal influence at one man's disposal is limited, and when he wishes his alms to go beyond the sphere of his own personal surroundings, he must look about for other in- fluences to correct the enervating and dangerous properties which are inherent in all forms of social dependence. When a man becomes a subscriber to, and an administrator of, public charity, he must have regard to the principles of social justice ; and knowing that the reformatory power of personal influence cannot wholly safeguard the administra- tion of such funds, he must occasionally stand aside and allow the corrective discipline which follows on social error to exert its purifying and educative influence. It is, of course, difficult, perhaps impossible, i 4 t PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. to draw a clearly defined line at the point where the personal element grows so faint as to be no longer wholesomely operative and preventative of the sinister effects of dependence. The only remark to be made is, that the good neighbour is inclined to stretch a point, and by personal supervision make his gifts to his poorer neigh- bours really neighbourly and personal in their character. He will not, of course, be blind to the injury that may be done to persons of weak character by the over-indulgence of their friends, but giving candid and careful consideration to the subject, he will find, that private charity is helpful, just as far as, and no further than, it can be followed by personal interest and supervision, and that, when he begins to get his charitable "diligence" done vicariously through societies and institutions (as of course many busy and rich men must do), his conduct becomes a question of public policy, and must be guided by considera- tions which apply to the whole problem of Public Relief. This distinction which I have drawn is, I venture to think, of some importance, and it has not been sufficiently realised in the discussion of the subject. If borne in mind, it will explain a good deal that otherwise may appear puzzling. The ideal method of relief would of course be v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 143 that there should be no system of Public Relief at all, and that the relief of the unfortunate should be attained by a more perfect development of the natural benevolence which is inherent in family, social and industrial relationships. With an abolition of public systems of relief, the burden to fall on this private benevolence would be much lightened by the more rapid development of the self- regarding virtue of thrift, mainly, in all probability, by the expedient of insurance in many forms. It may seem a bold assertion to make, but this consummation is not, perhaps, so far out of our reach as we generally suppose. The only body as far as I am aware, which has made it its object to influence and improve the administration of relief, not itself being a relief agency, is the Charity Organisation Society, and in the work which it is attempting to do, we may see, I think, the relevancy of this distinction between private and public charity appearing in various ways. When an application for relief is made to this Society, its first object is to discover whether there is any one on whom the applicant has some personal claim. The most successful way of disposing of an application for relief is to find some one who is willing to undertake to do what is necessary on personal grounds. 144 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. As a rule, however, when an applicant has to apply to a public institution, with a view of discovering for him persons on whom he has a natural claim, there either are no such persons, or they have been exhausted and wearied out. In other words, the case in question is obviously drifting away from the resources of private charity, and is rapidly becoming one which, if it is to be dealt with at all, must be dealt with by public charity or by the Poor Law. As far as possible, however, the Society tries to have each application met by private charity, in the belief that the personal element which is thereby introduced will restrict to a minimum the enervating influence of all relief. When we have to look further afield and call in the aid of in- stitutions and strangers, this personal element can only be retained with great difficulty, and by such artificial and doubtful means as appointing a visitor for the occasion. The Society recognises very fully the value of the personal element, but recognises also that this is not always available. Again, I notice, there is a disposition among the members of the Society to resent the use of the term " deserving " and "undeserving." These words, they say, ought not to be used as relevant to the business of relief. The answer which may be wisely given to an applicant for relief v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 145 does not turn on desert, but on the means and resources which are at the administrator's disposal for dealing with the particular form of distress. Let us take an extreme instance. A man whom, on inquiry, we find to be a habitual drunkard applies for relief. Now if the adminis- trator has at his beck and call a number of devoted persons who make it their business to keep the habitual drunkard sober and to labour for his reformation, he is justified in referring his drunkard to one or more of such persons ; and relief and kindness, coupled with strict super- vision, might perhaps be part of the treatment which would be followed. As far as I know, however, there is no such body of reformers, and it is very questionable whether the task of reclaim- ing the habitual drunkard can be usefully under- taken in this way. What I want to point out is that if the administrator of charitable funds de- clines to do anything for such a man, it is not because he is undeserving, but because he (the administrator) has no means at his disposal to effect the necessary reformation of character. The forlorn hope that there is for such a man is that the sharp suffering which he brings on himself and family may at the eleventh hour pull him up and set him on better courses. This is K 1 46 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the only way in which relief is likely to reach him ; and from the administrator's point of view, the best way to give permanent relief may be to refuse the temporary relief which is asked for. There are two aspects, therefore, to the work of those who seek to organise charitable relief in the best possible way. On the one hand, we are deeply committed to a belief in the efficacy of personal kindness, personal sympathy, and in the need of cultivating the benevolence which naturally arises in family, social and industrial intercourse. There is no limit to the difficult experiments which may be tried within this sphere of personal influence. Even that most difficult enterprise, the reclaiming of the drunkard, may be successfully attempted. On the other hand, the wise administrator of charitable funds must recognise that there comes a point, where it is not always possible to evoke the spontaneous benevolence that is personal, and therefore wholesome, between the applicant and the giver of relief; and that when, as is then necessary, appeal is made to public charity, a vast number of considerations arise which do not apply to the good offices which pass between persons, who may be described as friends. At once, when we are dealing with public charity, there presents itself to our minds the v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 147 whole history of the Old Poor Law, and the hideous abuses which resulted from too great a facility of relief. It then becomes our duty to consider charitable administration as an adjunct to the legal agency which has been created for the same purpose. In our examination of Poor Law administration we came to the conclusion that the Poor Law was historically and economically a continuation of older forms of servitude, which were gradually yielding to more honourable con- ditions ; that the progressive emancipation, begun in 1834, was capable of being accelerated and extended with every prospect of success ; that by a policy of careful and well-timed restriction of relief, a more or less complete independence could be brought within the reach of the manual labouring class ; and also that the hard cases, which were apt to be made precedents for bad law, could be best met by voluntary effort. It seems to follow, therefore, first, that careful administration of charitable funds is necessary, because a careless administration may produce on a minor scale the evils which resulted from a careless and unwise administration of legal funds ; and secondly, that a definite function is suggested for charitable agencies in the struggle for the emancipation of the poor from dependence on public relief. 148 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. I have said thus much by way of distinguish- ing private and public charity, as I wish to avoid the reproach of seeming to undervalue a quality which is undoubtedly a Christian virtue. No one wishes to put a stop to acts of kindness passing between rich and poor, but it is necessary to point out that, even in a man's own family, kindness may degenerate into indulgence, with a result most detrimental to the objects which he has in view. Each man, as regards his own family, must judge for himself at what point the sterner require- ments of justice should supersede the more indul- gent dictates of affection. He has, or he can insist v on having, a full knowledge of the circumstances of the case, and his own common sense must guide him. The transaction is private, it evokes gratitude and appeals to the recipient's better nature, and no dangerous public precedent can be established by any error that he may make. On the other hand, when alms are given by '* legal compulsion, or vicariously through charitable institutions, there can be no gratitude. There is no appreciation on the part of the recipient that the aid given involves some sacrifice on the part of the donor, and there is, therefore, no sense of shame restrictive of renewed application. Every act of public charity, moreover, becomes a precedent. Private charity rightly enough goes v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 149 by favour, but in public charity the same treat- ment must be meted out to all, and we have to consider what would be the result of each act if it had to be multiplied by thousands. Setting aside, therefore, the region within which a purely personal charity may be expected to operate, and leaving it to the only form of control which can apply to it, namely, the common sense which each man carries about with him in his own head, we pass to what I have described as public charity, that is en- dowed charities, subscription charities, and the personal gifts which well-to-do persons are often willing to make to individuals who otherwise are strangers to them. Obviously, the relation of this sort of charity to the Poor Law is that it is a voluntary effort to do that which the Poor Law is also doing, and it is a plain matter of common sense that when two or. more agencies are endeavouring to do the same thing, some co-operation or division of labour between them is desirable. The object of Poor Law and charitable relief is the same, viz., adequate and appropriate relief of destitution, and that emancipation of the pauper from the pauper habit, which we have called dispauperisation. First a few words as to the history of the question which is for the most part modern. i5o PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. I called attention in the last chapter to Mr Goschen's Minute of 1869, in which, as President of the Poor Law Board, he urged the guardians to invite the co-operation of charitable agencies in the work of Public Relief. His action was no doubt part of the same movement which came from the life and labours of men like Edward Denison, and the closer attention which their example and influence gained for the subject of Public Relief generally. Elsewhere this move- ment resulted in the foundation of the London Charity Organisation Society, a body which had certain executive and administrative objects in view, but whose principal service has been the arousing more sustained and scientific interest in the whole problem of Public Relief. The terms of Mr Goschen's Minute were somewhat tentative. It laid down the sound maxim that Poor Law relief should only be given to the " actually destitute." The weak part of the Minute is that no practical means of distinguishing the destitute from those who are merely poor is suggested, and, in the absence of this, the whole subject is left floundering about amid vague generalities. The Poor Law Com- missioners had long ago pointed out that the only satisfactory test of destitution was an automatic test. A man is destitute, if he is willing to re- v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 151 linquish the maintenance which he derives from his own resources, in exchange for one which is offered to him in a Poor Law establishment If this, the only practicable test of destitution, is accepted, it follows that the Poor Law should confine itself to institutional relief, and that domiciliary or outdoor relief should be left to charitable agencies. Mr Goschen's Minute does not definitely re- commend this, and the answers to the Minute which were sent in by various metropolitan unions show how difficult, if not impossible, co- operation is where no such rule is enforced. Some boards write in approval of the suggestion, and state that a beginning had been made. Subsequent history proves that these begin- nings, for the most part, came to nothing. Other boards, such as that of the City of London, say that they see- no necessity of appealing for charitable co-operation. Notwith- standing the law, and the orders of the Poor Law Board which the Minute pointed out forbade the purchase of tools, payment of rent, and certain other forms of relief the city guardians never shrink, they said, from giving all the relief which they think desirable, and then, with a complacency which is very characteristic, they proceeded to attribute the permanence of the i 5 2 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. pauper habit, and the admitted demoralisation alluded to in Mr Goschen's Minute, to " indis- criminate charity," and to a Houseless Poor Act, which did not recommend itself to the wisdom of these city fathers. There is something highly diverting in the City of London Guardians, as at that time constituted, complaining of indis- criminate relief. It is a case of the pot calling the kettle black. If indiscriminate relief is a bad thing, the predominant partners in the system of indiscrimination, namely the guardians, are the persons to bear the blame. Comments from other boards are to this effect : " We only do what the law allows, and, unless the Poor Law Board is prepared to pre- scribe our action more definitely, we intend to use the powers of patronage which we possess." The Minute had recommended that no charitable relief should be given to persons in receipt of Poor Law relief. That, the guardians declare, would upset their whole system. The outdoor relief given by them is not adequate, and it is not intended to be adequate. One board goes so far as to say that if they gave adequate relief, no body of rate-payers could stand it. As for the recommendation that relief should not be given in aid of wages, they find this also absurd and impracticable. All relief, v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 153 they quite truly point out, is in aid of wages. This seems to be Mr Scrope's point arising in a new form ; if we have, or are aiming at having, an independent wage-earning class, their wages clearly must provide for all emergencies. We may hold with Mr Scrope that independent wage- earners will be equal to this responsibility, but these Poor Law guardians did not think so, and saw no reason why they should not give out- door Poor Law relief in aid of wages. In effect their answer to this recommendation of the Minute is : "It is absurd to tell us not to give relief in aid of wages. All relief is in aid of wages, and you must give us some more precise indication of the distinction you wish to draw, for we can see none." If Mr Goschen had cared to dot the i's of his Minute, he would have said, "Adopt an automatic distinction. Relief, in aid of the objects which wages ought to provide, you must give, but give it under an institutional test the offer of maintenance in a Poor Law establish- ment." These dialectical passages on paper between the Board and its subjects came to little ; but in three London unions where by some strange accident the boards were captured by men anxious to try a scientific policy Whitechapel, 154 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. Stepney, St George in the East, the outdoor relief system was about this time brought practically to a close. To this policy it has generally been supposed that the local Charity Organisation Society gave great assistance. The statement, however, requires some qualification. In the earlier stages of the reform the organisation of the Society was very incomplete. One committee was responsible for the whole of the East End of London, an unmanageably large area. The reform in every case was originated by the guardians themselves. The Society, as represen- tative of voluntary charitable funds, was pledged to nothing but to the general proposition that, if the guardians adopted a definite and well under- stood division of labour, there would necessarily be a better and more concentrated application of voluntary funds. Its services, moreover, were promised not to raise fresh funds, but to promote the better administration of existing funds, which existed, it was thought, in sufficient quantity to meet all demand. We shall see presently that the burden imposed on the charitable agencies of the district by the discontinuance of outdoor relief was not heavy. The question is often asked (it may have occurred to some of my readers, though the answer, I hope, is so obvious that it is already v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 155 plain to them) : What is the advantage of transferring the liability for domiciliary or out- door relief from a legal to a voluntary source of income? And the objection is superadded, that the operation throws the burden on the liberal and open-handed, and relieves the churlish cur- mudgeon. No one wishes, of course, to favour the churlish curmudgeon, if there be such a person ; but we must not, for the sake of trounc- ing some unknown and possibly non-existent sinner, fasten on the poor of this country a system of legal relief which has been proved detrimental to their best interests. We proposed two points as conclusive tests of a good system of Public Relief: first, that it should make for dispauperisation ; second, that it should be adequate. Let us submit the point at issue to these tests. First, as to dispauperisation. A charitable fund, in so much as it is less extensive, less widely advertised, and not to be claimed as a right, exercises much less influence and fascination over the mind and conduct of the poor than a fund derived from a public rate, which is often re- presented as a provision to which they have a right. All experience shows that the poor do not apply with the same eagerness and importunity to charitable as to legal sources of relief. The 156 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. decreased facility for obtaining legal relief, re- sulting from a discontinuance of outdoor relief, throws a certain number of persons on their own resources. This, every precedent in Poor Law history shows, is the first step to reform. What is perhaps more important, it removes pros- pectively, in the interest of all future genera- tions, from the young and able-bodied, the expectation that at all crises of life relief from an ubiquitous poor rate on favourable terms may confidently be reckoned on. What, then, will become of the burden that formerly was carried by the poor rate? It will not be taken up, so experience has proved, by charitable agencies. The increase of charitable expenditure in the three East End Unions has been infinitesimal, if indeed there has been any increase at all. In one union, where some .14,000 was being yearly expended in outdoor relief, the recorded expenditure of the representative charitable agencies was only a few hundreds, and this not money for the first time brought into the district. Nor will the burden remain on the poor rate in another form, for there has been no increase in the number of persons accepting indoor relief. The people have not been driven into the work- house. Such fluctuation in the numbers of the indoor paupers as has since occurred may with v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 157 confidence be assigned to attractive improve- ments in the internal management of the poor law establishments generally. The greater part of the previous burden (and under favourable con- ditions, as at Bradfield, a country union isolated from the temptations of a great town, an in- creasingly greater part) is taken up by an extension of self-maintenance, by the growth of more provident habits, by a more adequate sense of personal responsibility, by the better discharge of filial duty, by a fuller exercise of the virtue of neighbourliness among all classes. Only a very small margin of responsibility is, in the event, left to fall on the voluntary agencies of relief. Such complaint as has arisen has been evoked by the action of outside agitators. In most of the unions which have adopted the system, the Poor Law elections have sent back for thirty years the same or a like-minded board, and there can therefore be no ground for saying that great hardship has been caused, or that the charitable agencies have failed in their under- taking to intervene in favour of the " hard cases." Even if the charitable agencies had in some respects failed, the increased independence of the poor the first step in a rise to more material prosperity should in itself be sufficient to vindicate the wisdom of the reform. 158 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND ICHAP. Then, as to the second test that of adequacy it is enough to say that no form of relief can be more adequate than one which has transferred, and is transferring, the poorer population from maintenance on a rate to self-maintenance. The most adequate and permanent form of relief that can be conferred on any community is a method of administration that extends, protects and stimulates the independence of the poorer class. Nor is there any evidence to show that it has increased the hardship of those who still remain below the level of self-support. The term work- house is really a misnomer for the modern Poor Law establishment. For the aged they are asylums, for the sick they are hospitals, and for the young they are schools. The assistance given, in what have been termed hard cases, by charitable agencies, is made more valuable by the personal superintendence of sympathetic almoners, and is much more easily adapted to circumstances than the official action of public authorities. Moreover, as has been pointed out on an earlier page (p. 137), the alternative system of out relief is much more liable to miscarriage and inadequacy than the stricter system for which we seek to obtain the co-operation and support of an intelligent administration of chari- table funds. v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 159 When the Poor Law authorities determine to restrict their operations, and to leave a definite field to charitable agencies, a certain organisation of charitable effort becomes inevitable ; and it is important to notice the fact, and not to impute too large a responsibility to a body like the Charity Organisation Society. In places where its work has been most useful, it is the result, not the cause, of improved Poor Law administration. At Bradfield, where the poor have been more effectually emancipated from pauperism than anywhere else, and in country unions where reformed Poor Law administration has been introduced, there has been no attempt to make a systematic organisation of charitable effort. In the country, rich and poor live in closer proximity to each other. It is possible, therefore, for private charity to go further afield, without the danger of re-introducing the evils of indiscriminate public relief, and for this reason an organisation of public charity has been the less necessary. This action on the part of the three East End Unions is the most practical answer which has been given to Mr Goschen's Circular ; and it may serve to indicate the identity of the real difficulty of all this problem, if we notice that the method adopted is virtually the same as that suggested in the long quotation set out on page 1 1 9 from the Con- 160 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. tinuance Report of the Poor Law Commissioners. In this, it will be remembered, they indicate where the practical difficulty lies viz., How is the condi- tion of the adequately relieved pauper to be made inferior to that of the independent labourer of the humblest class ? or, as it is otherwise stated, How are we to distinguish between destitution that condition where a man's own resources and the good-will of his friends are unable to support him and the poverty which, if it is to be relieved at all, must be relieved by voluntary and eleemosynary agencies? The answer given by the Commis- sioners, and now by the practice of these reformed boards, is that the inferiority must be imported by the discipline and restraint of a public institution, and that the responsibility of deciding where the line is to be drawn between destitution and poverty must be left to the applicant, who alone can know when self-support is no longer possible, and when it is necessary for him to accept support in a public institution. In view of the great development of indoor relief not as a substitute for, but in addition to a very lavish system of outdoor relief it is perhaps necessary to state that, of course, an institutional system of relief is not absolutely and in itself a cause of dispauperisation. It only becomes so when it is made a substitute for the much more v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 161 pauperising system of outdoor relief, and when a certain discipline and restraint is enforced. The difficulty of observing these conditions, more especially in the institutional relief of sickness, is very great, but, unless we are prepared to adopt a general policy of gratuitous sick relief, and the ultimate discontinuance of Friendly Society Sick Insurance, a protest against the uni- versal pauperism of the poor in sickness must be maintained. For this reason some boards make a practice of granting the relief of the infirmary as a loan in cases where repayment is possible. The question is considered a few pages further on in connection with the work of Voluntary Hospitals. To return to the understanding which has been made in the above-mentioned places between the representatives of legal and volun- tary agencies of relief, it may be worth while to analyse its characteristics more fully. The plan which has recommended itself as most intelligible and most logical is, that the two parties accept the principle of a complete division of labour. That is to say, one form of relief institutional should be given by the rates. Out-door or domiciliary relief should be given by charitable agencies. This plan has been adopted in very few 1 62 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. places. Generally there is no plan. Few Boards of Guardians will consent to forego their patronage in respect of outdoor relief. Many of them, by giving inadequate relief on the plausible assumption set out by boards in reply to Mr Goschen's Circular, encourage paupers to beg for the remainder of their maintenance in other quarters, and too often the administrator of public charity yields to this vicious suggestion. Even if charitable agencies refuse to yield, the situation is very unsatisfactory. The Poor Law, by public advertisement as it were, under- takes to grant domiciliary relief whenever this is desirable. There is nothing left, there- fore, for the charitable agencies to do. Some- times they say, "We will deal with the more ' deserving ' class of applicants " ; but this is precisely the class which the guardians profess to be anxious to relieve, and there is no in- telligible reason why charitable agencies should wish to compete with them. Sometimes it has been gravely stated by guardians that they will take the more deserving cases, and relieve them out of a fund which is a public fund a rate to which the poor have con- tributed, and out of which they are entitled to draw according to their requirement ; while the less v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 163 deserving should be dealt with by public charity, on the ground that, by misconduct, they have forfeited their right to the more eligible relief given by the rates. At another time the administrator of a charit- able fund will say, " Let us relieve the ' deserving,' because the deserving ought to be relieved ade- quately, and we know that the guardians never relieve adequately." This seems a policy of despair, but perhaps it is the best that the chaotic confusion of the situation will allow. The main objection to each and all of these forms of parochial chaos is that such systems have no dispauperising effect. This overlapping of relief jurisdiction probably also gives rise, on the part of guardians, to the grant of much relief that is unnecessary, because of the want of proper test, and to much relief that is inadequate, because guardians always assume, and in most cases rightly, that applicants do not fully disclose their sources of income. In such cases, they are, therefore, obliged to guess, and even guardians cannot always guess correctly. Occasionally, as at Paddington, Birmingham, and Manchester, a very careful system of in- quiry is instituted by the guardians. This at once reduces applications. In Birmingham and Manchester official visitors have been appointed to supervise outdoor relief. This also has reduced 164 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND ICUAP. the outdoor list. In Paddington the rule is, that when an applicant who is deemed suitable for outdoor relief has been discovered, relief is not granted till endeavour has been made to obtain the needed relief from a voluntary source. A great diminution of pauperism has been secured by this method ; and as there is no sugges- tion that it is otherwise than adequate, it is highly to be recommended. At the same time it is beset with many difficulties. Notoriously the onerous calls on the time of a relieving officer make a really efficient system of investigation in populous districts an impossibility. The first step to be taken, then, is to establish a system of efficient investigation. This, in Paddington, has been secured by an elaborate system of record papers ; and elsewhere, by the appointment of special officers for the superintendence of outdoor relief courses of action not always easily obtained in the normal Board of Guardians. The plan appears also to put the voluntary agencies in a subordinate position, with a humiliating necessity laid on them merely to endorse the recommendations of the Board of Guardians. In some districts the ar- rangement would not work well. Moreover, if a large demand was made by the guardians on charitable agencies, the plan would defeat its own object, and re-introduce under a new name the v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 165 old abuse, which mainly consisted in setting up a publicly-advertised system of outdoor or domi- ciliary relief. That which is most successful in reducing the incitements to pauperism is best ; but I have always thought that the absolute and exclusive division of work adopted in the three East End Unions is the most logical and the most easily intelligible. The two agencies are there quite independent, and do not interfere with each others' decisions, and each have mutually exclusive departments of work. Obviously the initiative in every method of reform lies with the guardians. They have power and, unfortunately, they generally use it to make all co-operation impossible. On the other hand, if they take what I have been en- deavouring to show is a right view of their duties, the matter becomes very simple. If guardians confine their action to offering institutional relief, the field of action for voluntary charities is thereby at once defined, and a certain organiza- tion of charity is at once established. Moreover, if guardians take this view of their duty, it means that some of them and some of their supporters are appreciative of the possibilities of dispauper- isation, and aware of the great assistance which may be rendered by an organisation of voluntary agencies. I am inclined to think that the advan- 1 66 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. tage of a highly centralised organisation may be exaggerated. A wise management of local charities by administrators responsible to a sound public opinion probably would be a better arrange- ment than a centralised local authority. This last tends to officialise what ought to be unofficial and spontaneous, and also to make the voluntary relief agencies assume exaggerated dimensions in the calculations of the poor. Unfortunately there is comparatively little sound public opinion on the subject, and, in default of this controlling influence, a central organising body for each locality has in London been thought desirable ; but elsewhere, as we have noted, no such institution has been thought necessary. One noticeable point deserves to be recorded with regard to some of these districts where im- proved methods have been introduced. The division of labour has greatly simplified adminis- tration, not only for guardians, but for persons who are connected with voluntary agencies for relief. A new departure has therefore been found possible by some of those persons whose occupa- tion, with regard to relief, has happily been diminished, if it is not entirely gone. They have begun to interest themselves in the provident associations of the poor, to canvass their districts for Friendly Society recruits, to organise Collect- v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 167 ing Banks, and generally to constitute themselves ministers of that better and concurrent mechanism, the expansion of which alone offers a permanent and satisfactory solution for the economic dis- abilities of society. It is no necessary part of our argument to insist on the details ; we are concerned only with principles. If we can win acceptance for these, detailed methods of reform offer little difficulty. There is no need of an absolute uniformity of procedure. Our crusade is still in its propagandist stage. We have to con- vince people that pauperism is, to a large extent, an unnecessary and artificial evil. If we can make them converts, we must leave it to them to carry on the war against pauperism in the manner which they consider is most likely to be crowned with success. Something, perhaps, should now be said on the policy of the Charity Commissioners with regard to Endowed Charities. It is worth while to advert again to the curious coincidence already noticed. The same year, 1601, which saw the establishment of our Poor Law, saw also the passing of the important statute of Charitable Uses. The one provided a legal common fund for the use 1 68 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP of the poor, the other took steps to preserve to the use of the poor the benefactions of pious founders. In the first half of the nineteenth century both of these laws had given rise to widespread abuse, and it fell to the lot of the same generation to agitate for their reform. We have described the reform of the Poor Law which took place in 1834. Though the agitation for it began at least as early as 1818, the reform of charitable endowments did not take place till 1853, when the Charity Commission was appointed. The duty prescribed for it was to control and reform the administra- tion of Endowed Charities, just as the Poor Law Commissioners had to reform the adminis- tration of the endowments derived from the poor-rate. The subject-matter was of course different ; but, in principle, the needed reforms were not dissimilar. Mistakes of legislation had created a " community of property," or communism in \ I . the poor rate, and had given rise to a mass of artificial and unnecessary pauperism. So, too, the benevolent intentions of pious founders had set apart property, sometimes of great value, for purposes which a later age often found obsolete, useless, and even mischievous. The powers possessed by the Charity Com- v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 169 missioners are, unfortunately, very limited, and also very intricate. They have power to inquire into the administration of charitable trusts, to compel the production of accounts, to supplement the powers of trustees, to secure safe custody of property, to extend the doctrine of cy pres that is, of diverting funds devoted to obsolete or mischievous purposes to useful objects akin to the intention of the founder and to control legal expenses. Their powers are considerable over trusts of which the income does not exceed ^50. When the income exceeds this sum, the consent of trustees is required. Subject to these con- ditions, they are empowered to promulgate schemes for the administration of endowed funds. The Commissioners, as official controllers of national charitable funds, have in recent years pursued a policy of diverting, as far as they can, dole charities to the provision of open spaces and institutions more or less devoted to technical education. At the present time, however, this last object has seemed sufficiently provided for under the Technical Instruction Act, and, to quote the words of the Commissioners' own Report : "In the case of doles, other applications are now more iyo PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. favoured, as for instance, to old age pensions, which have the recommendation of being nearer in object to the present ap- plication, and do not tend, if rightly safeguarded, to pauperise the recipient." Report of 1894, p. 42. The schemes for old age pensions sanctioned by the Commissioners, as a rule, contain a clause prohibitive of giving pensions to persons in receipt of Poor Law relief. As far as I am aware, no attempt has yet been made to ap- portion additional funds to localities where guardians are restricting their outdoor relief. In unions where outdoor relief is freely given to the aged, it is a mere accident whether the applicant is relieved by the Poor Law or by an endowed charity, if such be available. The rule of the Commissioners may prevent the same person being relieved by both authorities, but it does not prevent the two authorities from dealing with the same class and in the same way. The rules also usually insist that the pensions shall be adequate, and, as a matter of fact, the scale adopted by the Commissioners is considerably higher than that observed either by guardians or by unendowed charitable agencies. Public advertisement for candidates is also enjoined. Such notice does not neces- sarily come before the poorest class who might become applicants, but it attracts attention among v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 171 the more respectable poor and their friends. The claimants, therefore, are generally of a superior class, many of them persons who would not apply unless their friends brought pressure to bear on them. The pensions accordingly go, in a good many cases, to persons who, though poor, are not in any actual distress, and who, failing to get a pension, would still be under no necessity to apply to the Poor Law. It may be a good thing that these pensions should be given, not to persons who are in danger of being destitute, but to worthy poor people of small income, who have the backing which is required to bring their claims to the favourable notice of the trustees. It has, however, this result : that the schemes now being promoted by the Charity Commission will not, in all probability, have much effect on the adminis- tration of the Poor Law and public relief generally. One other question of great importance re- quires to be briefly noticed that of Medical Relief. The subject is now approaching a critical stage. There is a strong momentum, bearing down all opposition, and leading to an almost universal gratuitous treatment of sickness. It is said that no one will become sick for the sake of gratuitous 172 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. treatment. The point rather is, whether persons are not encouraged to think of sickness as a time in which they are justified in being destitute. The gratuitous system does not encourage sickness ; but it may, and in some cases it certainly does, encourage destitution in sickness. There are various interests concerned in the matter that of the poor, that of the hospitals as the seats of medical training, and, lastly, that of the local medical practitioner. The interest of the poor is not only their need of adequate medical treatment, but also their strong desire to be independent both of the Poor Law and charity at all periods and crises of life. Their Friendly Societies are a standing monument of the sacrifices and efforts which they are prepared to make for this purpose. What the poor man really wants is not gratuitous treatment, but a better development of medical insurance, so that he may obtain, as a matter of honourable con- tract, suitable treatment of his maladies. Let us consider how far our present system conduces to this legitimate demand. It is obvious, in the first place, that a universal system of gratuitous relief, whether in Poor Law infirmaries or volun- '. tary hospitals, must operate unfavourably to the ex- tension of Friendly Society insurance. Inasmuch as the adequate and gratuitous treatment of sick- v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 173 ness in Poor Law establishments puts the pauper"- in a better position than the man who pays, either directly or through subscription to a provident medical association, for his own medical treatment, the plan of granting medical relief as a loan has been adopted with much success. In one union it is stated that the result of this policy has been that well-nigh every man, woman, and child is medically insured. If this plan were generally followed, provident medical associations would enable poor people to receive adequate medical treatment, and yet remain independent. The same considerations supply valid objections to a universally gratuitous hospital system. Except in so far as the requirements of the medical school demands it, there is no occasion for a hospital treatment of trifling maladies. In nine cases of sickness out of ten, what is needed is care as to diet, rest, and a proper regimen of health. Advice on such points can best be given by the local practitioner who knows his patients, and can be secured by an extension of the medical insurance which is already so popular with the wording class. The free doctoring which goes on in the out-patient department of our great London hospitals does not admit of the individual attention which the sick require. It is hurried, and attended by great hardship on 174 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the part of those who have to wait many weary hours before their cases can be considered. Hospital treatment, says a high authority (Mr Timothy Holmes), ought to be, in the main, consultative ; and as hospitals are also schools of medicine, it is possible to secure gratuitous advice from the leading men in the profession for poor persons who are not able to pay the high fees which are legitimately demanded for the valuable time and services of the specialist. This is a privilege of the greatest value, and it ought not to be abused or frittered away by imposing on the hospitals the duty of treating gratuitously the minor illnesses of vast populations. It ought not to be beyond the ingenuity of reasonable men to arrange that (i) Poor Law infirmaries should, when necessary, be able to refer some of their difficult cases to the hospitals ; (2) the local practitioner in the poorer parts should be allowed to obtain hospital treatment and advice in cases where a second opinion or special surgical treatment is required ; (3) "privileges of a similar nature should, on honour- able terms, be put at the disposal of the members of Friendly Societies and other medical provident associations. We are very far, unfortunately, from any such system. The hospitals are now treating exactly the same class of persons and v.] LEGAL AND VOLUNTARY RELIEF 175 for the same maladies as are treated in our Poor Law infirmaries and dispensaries. The action of both is detrimental to the just claims of the local medical practitioner, who loudly complains of the unfair competition, more especially of that of the large hospitals. The present system is also a standing discouragement to the spread of sound medical insurance, and of the Friendly Society movement generally, and it is to the development of such institu- tions that we have principally to look for a solution of the difficulty. Throughout this and every other branch of the subject, the same principles ought to guide us. What the poorer classes want is not only adequate medical treatment, but also inde- pendence ; and we ought so to regulate our administration of medical relief as to secure both objects a consummation which, though difficult, is by no means impracticable. CHAPTER VI THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF IN speaking of the future, it is proverbially un- wise to prophesy. There are, however, some developments for which we may hope, others which we fear. Change of one kind or another there is certain to be. First, as to administration. A very important change was recently made by the Local Govern- ment Act of 1894. Rural Boards of Guardians have been amalgamated with the Rural District Councils. In urban districts and in boroughs there is still a distinct body of guardians ; but it was, I believe, generally understood that this amalgamation of authorities was likely to be carried further. Lately we have had a re- arrangement of Metropolitan Local Government, and it is generally felt that the multiplicity of public bodies is an evil that ought to be remedied. Will it be found possible to amalgamate Boards of Guardians with the general administrative local 176 CHAP, vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 177 authority in town, as has already been done in country? and, if so, what will be the result? It is impossible to speak positively, but there un- doubtedly are causes making for a further unifica- tion of local authority. To begin with, this has been done in the rural districts already. In matters other than the Poor Law, the recent creation of Borough Councils in the metropolis is a step in the same direction. Another reason is to be found in the way in which the financial liability has been gradually rearranged during the last forty or fifty years. It is an old and time-honoured maxim that representation and taxation should go together. In other words, the spending body should be responsible to the persons who contribute the rates. This, with regard to the Poor Law, has to a considerable extent ceased to be the case. For, roughly speaking, one-quarter of the sum expended in the maintenance of the poor comes from national, as opposed to local sources of taxation, and the amount seems likely to in- crease. A word may here be said on the history of this drift from local chargeability to national chargeability. When Sir Robert Peel was abolishing the Corn Laws, he let fall the opinion that, as a tax supposed to be in the interest of M 178 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. the land was being repealed, it was only fair that the burden of local rates, which then, as now, fell exclusively on land and houses, should be reconsidered. The difficulty of giving relief to local taxa- tion by allocating fresh sources of income to local rate-raising authorities, is apparently insuperable. We have noted how the clear intention of the Act of Elizabeth to rate personalty was frustrated by the sheer impracticability of the proposal. Land and houses are stationary, they are susceptible of geographical definition, and, when such and such a field or house has been decided to lie in such and such a parish or union, the raising of the necessary supplies is a mere question of valuation and assessment. Stock-in-trade is a thing here to-day and gone to-morrow. Much of it never comes into the parish of the various owners in whose possession it temporarily vests. It passes from owner to owner by notes of delivery. Hitherto the collection of such a rate has been generally found impossible. A rate levied on income has been suggested ; but the same objections seem to apply. How, for instance, could we make a local distribution, say, of Lord Rothschild's income-tax ? Is he to pay at all the places where he sometimes vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 179 resides in the city, in his London house, in his various country seats ? As yet the owner- ship of wealth is not a criminal offence, and it would be inequitable to call on him to pay an income-tax in all the rateable areas where he happened to hold property. If he was allowed to choose, he might elect to pay where there is a low rate ; but it would clearly be unjust to assess some farmer for a local income-tax, in addition to, or instead of, his present rate, and excuse Lord Rothschild at his country seats, because he had elected to pay in the city. Nor could it be left to the different localities to wrangle as to which of them was entitled to the spending of Lord Rothschild's local income- tax. The thing, indeed, is impossible ; at least hitherto it has always seemed so, though every one has been anxious to discover new sources of local taxation. The reconsideration which Sir Robert Peel promised was given to the subject, and the con- clusion (if we may judge from the measures placed on the statute-book) has been that the subjects on which local taxation falls are en- titled to some relief. This has been effected in what was probably the only practicable manner, short of a rearrangement of authority between local and centralised authority viz., i8o PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. by grants in aid of local taxation from the national exchequer. This policy began, in accordance with Sir Robert Peel's pledge, immediately after the repeal of the Corn Laws. Grants in aid of teachers' salaries and for improvements in medical relief were made in the same year, 1846. The amount at first was small, but the policy has been continuously extended. By the Local Government Act, 1888, the plan of dis- tribution has been slightly altered, and, instead of specific grants in aid, the proceeds of certain taxes (certain licences and a share of the death- duties) are handed over through the County Councils to the local authorities. This Ex- chequer contribution amounts to about seven or eight millions per annum. Of this from two to three millions are devoted to Poor Law purposes, constituting, as I have said, about a quarter of the total expenditure on the poor. In addition to this, we had recently an in- dication of policy in the Agricultural Rates Act, which, in view of the alleged depression of agriculture and the heavy burdens which it bore, ordered that agricultural land should be excused one-half of the rate paid by other land, and that the deficiency should be made up from national sources. vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 181 In London, it is also to be observed, the direct financial responsibility of the electors of each administrative district is still further con- fused, if not removed, by the operation of the Metropolitan Common Poor Fund. That, as we know, throws a large proportion of the establishment charges on a fund raised from all London, and not exclusively from the electors who elect each particular Board of Guardians. Again, a further irresponsible element is introduced by the institution of the compound householder. A very large, probably a pre- ponderating number, of the electors, both in town and country, do not directly pay any rates at all. Their landlord compounds with the rating authority, and pays the rates of his cottages and houses, receiving a liberal com- mission on the transaction. The tenants, how- ever, are constructively considered as paying these rates, and entitled to exercise any fran- chise which may be connected with them. Again, there is a further divorce of local representation and taxation arising from the disfranchisement of corporations, such as dock companies, railways, and limited liability com- panies generally. The local franchise is the personal privilege of an inhabitant or occupier, and cannot be exercised by a corporation or a 1 82 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. company as such. About one-thirteenth of the local taxation of the kingdom is paid by the railway companies alone, but they have no local representation whatsoever. Yet, with all this relief, the local rate-payer is not satisfied. Political busy bodies are casting about for fresh sources of local taxation, in order to relieve their clients from present and impending burdens. Much of this is merely the predatory instinct of politicians seeking to mulct those who are not of their party a line of action which leads, of course, to retaliation. The desire to relieve one set of rate-payers is blended with the wish to launch out into new expenditure at the cost of a larger circle of contributories, as in the pro- posal to put outdoor relief in London on the Common Poor Fund. We have moved some way, and, as I do not think there is much chance of discovering new local rateable sources of income, it is probable that we may move a good deal further in the direction of a national poor rate. The general argument, such as it is, in favour of a national rate is obvious enough. Just as the old parish chargeability was unjust and inconvenient, because it threw a heavy burden on poor parishes, so, though of course in a less degree, the burden now falls heavily vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 183 on unions inhabited by poor people, and com- paratively lightly on unions in more fashionable quarters. This inequality is not entirely re- dressed by the subventions in aid paid through the County Councils and through the Metro- politan Common Poor Fund. On the other hand, the objections to a national rate with the present local administration are equally obvious. It would be impossible to allow local bodies to administer national funds. Even as things at present are, the Common Poor Fund in London and the subventions from national sources act as a stimulus to extravagance, and are not wholly satisfactory. If the whole charge- ability was placed on the national exchequer, it would be impossible to continue our system of local administration. If we are well advised, we shall resist any further nationalisation of the poor rate, unless it is accompanied by national- isation of administration. This, practically, was the plan recommended by Sir E. Chadwick, and may or may not be a possible solution. There seem, therefore, to be several ten- dencies making for a national rather than a sectional administration of public relief. (i) There is a disposition to unify in one reputable and responsible public body all local jurisdiction. 1 84 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. (2) On grounds of equity there has been a disposition to enlarge the area of chargeability from the parish to the union, then from the union to a larger body of contributories e.g., the metropolitan area and to the national area by these subventions in aid. (3) As a result of this, it is evident that the electing body pays a fractional, and probably diminishing, amount of the monies raised and expended a condition of things reversing the salutary rule that taxation and representation should go together. When we have unified our local administra- tion in towns, as has already been done in the rural districts, it will probably be found that the duties of these bodies are very extensive, very multifarious, and very difficult to over- take. Moreover, their expenditure is sure to grow, and they will be called on to undertake more and more duties. It will then be said that they have too much to do, and that some rearrangement of responsibility is desirable. It is to be hoped that, when this arises, we shall not go back and create a number of smaller authorities to vex the land, but that we shall consider whether a more intelligent division of labour cannot be made between the Central and the Local Authority. We should vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 185 then ask ourselves which, if any, of these duties now overburdening the strength of the local authority would be as well or better discharged by the central authority. If the subject is so considered, it seems not improbable that Poor Law administration may be selected as one of those public services which might with advan- tage be carried on by a more centralised body (1) Because the charge is more fairly a national than a sectional responsibility. (2) Because already great lengths have been gone to divorce representation and taxation, and the present system of a local body spend- ing funds to a large extent derived from national taxes does not tend to economy and careful administration. (3) Because the office of guardian is really a judicial office, requiring for its proper discharge a considerable amount of technical training and knowledge. Whether these considerations will lead the country to relegate Poor Law administration, as Sir E. Chadwick wished it relegated, to a staff of salaried experts, it is impossible to say. In suggesting that this might be a solution of many difficulties, one must not be held to make any attack on democratic institutions, for 186 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. it is very fully recognised that there are many public services which democracy, if well-advised, will specially exempt from popular and elective management. For instance, the appointment of a judicature, the management of the army, the navy, and the police, currency, and many similar questions, the democracy has very wisely ad- judged to be unsuitable for the arbitrament of popular canvassing ; and it may appear to some that this is a category in which Poor Law administration might very well be included. As a further indication of the way things are drifting, it may be pointed out that the manage- ment of prisons has recently been taken away from the county authorities, and, with a view of lightening local financial burdens, the cost, as well as the administration, has been placed on the Central Authority. It seems also probable that one of the changes recommended by the Local Taxation Commission now sitting will be the transfer of lunatic asylums from the county to the imperial jurisdiction. It is, therefore, not improbable that at some time proposals may be made to treat Poor Law administration in the same way. Such a change may be a good one or may be a very bad one, according to the way in which it is managed. That which is best administered is vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 187 best. We can only hope that, if the change is made, the interests of dispauperisation will not be neglected. Change, in this as in other branches of public business, is inevitable, but it is not possible to look forward with any confidence to the treatment which this difficult and important subject will re- ceive if dragged into the political arena. We may have no doubt as to the overpowering weight of argument on the side of a wisely restrictive policy ; but those who understand political manoeuvres are apparently unanimous in thinking that this is a policy which they dare not put before the constituencies. On the contrary, many per- sons who take a leading part in political business, either because they have never considered the subject, or because, having considered it, they are indifferent and reckless, have made liberal offers of Public Relief an item in their electioneering programme. Take this recent agitation on Old Age Pensions. An influential politician, without thinking out the practical difficulties of the question, makes a proposal, and thus sets the ball rolling. The proposal creates great enthusiasm among the groundlings. Other politicians follow suit. The party managers think that there are votes in it. Electioneering cards are printed wholesale, which even get distributed in support 1 88 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. of candidates who afterwards find it necessary to disavow the policy attributed to them. The Opposition dare not oppose. They either ignore, or offer to go further than the original proposal. Even those on both sides who know that the pro- posal is mischievous and impracticable dare not denounce the whole transaction. They confine themselves to saying that they are in favour of the principle of increased public relief to the aged, but that they have not seen any practical scheme. Several commissions and committees of enquiry have been appointed. The first, a royal commis- sion, presided over by the late Lord Aberdare, in its majority report declared in effect that the proposal was mischievous and impracticable. A minority, composed principally of promoters of old age pension schemes, insisted that this verdict had not given sufficient consideration to popular aspiration a strange criticism to come from a body specially selected to consider and advise in a judicial spirit as to a certain novel economic proposal. When the party, to which the most active section of the old age pension promoters belongs, came into office, they were asked to redeem their too rash pledges. Another committee (Lord Rothschild's committee) of experts was appointed to examine proposals, and, if necessary, suggest vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 189 a plan. This committee reported that no work- able proposal had been put before them, and that they were unable to suggest a plan. Then Mr Chaplin stepped into the breach, and became chairman of a select committee of the House of Commons, which, after rejecting the sensible advice of Mr Chaplin to consider the question as a matter of Poor Law administration, drew up what they called heads of a scheme. Mr Chaplin, with the zeal of a new convert, publicly committed him- self to a statement that some two millions, or a is. duty on corn, would meet the expense. The committee which drew up the heads, for some strange reason, declared it was not their business to calculate the cost of their proposals ; so a second committee of experts was appointed. The wearied expert, who, like Balaam, had so often been dragged forward to bless this proposal, was, on this occasion, by the terms of reference, debarred from cursing it again. He was enjoined to confine himself to calcu- lating the cost. The committee found that the cost of giving 55. or 75. a-week pension, accord- ing to the scale of living in each locality, to the aged poor whose incomes were under ics. a week, deducting persons very vaguely defined as unthrifty, aliens, paupers, etc., would be ten millions at once, rising in twenty years' time to fifteen millions. The prospect of such an i 9 o PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. expenditure at the present time seemed to render the whole proposal impracticable. Mr Chaplin, presumably recognising this, went back to Whitehall, and reverted to his original idea. The pension question was clearly a branch of Poor Law administration, and, by way of re- deeming the pledges of his colleagues, he issued a circular, recommending guardians ^ to return to the old panacea of outdoor relief, and plenty of it a practice against which his predecessors at the board had been protesting for the last sixty years. This result of the agitation is perfectly logical and inevitable. If a political party promises to provide at the public expense for the aged poor, it is clearly proposing an addi- tion to, or alteration of, the Poor Law. Mr Chaplin's circular is frankly a Poor Law circular, and the policy no longer disguises itself under the alias of a pension scheme. The agitation was begun lightly at a critical election, but its subsequent development has taken place without any pressure. The pro- gressive contagion of reactionary views as to Poor Law relief is certainly very remarkable. Mr Chaplin's circular was to most people as unexpected as a bolt from the blue. The approaching general election of 1900 was vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 191 obviously to be decided on quite other issues. The circular was not needed for electioneering purposes, and must be referred, presumably, to Mr Chaplin's ardent desire to redeem Mr Chamberlain's pledges. If these things are done in the dry leaf, one is prompted to ask what will be done in the green leaf of a popular agitation on the subject. If people can be found ready to support the policy of old age pensions at the public charge, there is absolutely nothing to prevent them becoming equally enthusiastic over proposals to put the other risks of life on the same basis. It is a curious fact, and an evidence of the unprincipled nature of the proposal (the term is used in a colourless sense namely, that it is based on no intelligible principle), that, as far as I know, no single promoter of an old age pension scheme has shown us why we should select old age as a disability specially entitled to this treatment. If, without injury to that economic inde- pendence of the individual on which the public welfare rests, we can make old age a public, and not a private and personal responsibility, why should we confine this comforting policy to old age ? Why not extend it to widowhood, 192 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. sickness, orphanage,- and want of work ? A far more pathetic interest can be roused in favour of a widow left without provision for a young family, for a man struck down prematurely by sickness in early life, or the labourer who is left without employment, owing to trade fluctuations over which he has no control. The case of an old man, who presumably has had forty or fifty years of able-bodied manhood during which he has had his opportunity of making provision, is by no means the most pathetic figure that our imagination can conjure up. Of course, if we thought that, without detriment to public policy, every one should be given gratuitous public support on honourable terms, the aged and every one else would be welcome to share in this general system of largesse. Such an opinion seems to us mistaken, but it is logical and consistent What we cannot understand is the frame of mind of those promoters of old age pensions who prescribe this public gratuity for one form of distress and not for all. If distress can be relieved in this way, without detriment to public policy, surely we ought to apply the cure all round. This, we may be very sure, will be pointed out, if the whole question of Poor Law Relief is once brought into political controversy. vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 193 Politicians generally have committed themselves, without visible reluctance, to this plan of exceptional treatment for the aged. It has resulted, of course, in nothing, beyond Mr Chaplin's authoritative recommendation that the aged are to be given greater facilities for pauperism, and the most favoured terms. It is difficult, therefore, to gather any reason why this same reactionary policy should not be urged as applicable throughout the whole of our Poor Law administration. The shame-faced statement of those who have op- posed this new departure, that they are in favour, on principle, of making old age a public, and not a private responsibility, but that no work- able plan has as yet come under their notice, is not the robust sort of negative which the situation requires. We cannot, therefore, regard the principles of political parties as a very effec- tive safeguard against reactionary legislation. To avert the calamity which might result from the attitude of politicians to questions of relief, we have to look to an improvement in public opinion. The day when statesmen led public opinion seems to be, for the moment at all events, past. Among the educated classes of the community, the number of those who take an interest in the administration of the Poor N 194 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. Law is very small relatively, and their political influence is infinitesimal. Fortunately, or per- haps unfortunately (for undoubtedly it was financial pressure, rather than any conviction of social demoralisation, that has brought about reform in the past), the burden of Poor Law Relief is not heavy, and is not increasing. Relatively to the wealth and population of the country, it is a diminishing burden. The only persons who are really aggrieved are the paupers themselves, but they, of course, make no complaint ; it is part of their ailment that they do not complain of their servitude, but demand its extension. It is, therefore, among the higher stratum of the working-class that we have to look for the motive-force which will prevent reaction, even if it does not bring about reform. They approach the subject from a point of view different from that which we have been considering. By those who may be considered representative of the more intelligent working-class, such, for in- stance, as the members of Friendly Societies the Poor Law is regarded with a certain amount of impatience. With a true instinct, they hate and abhor the Poor Law and all its works. They recognise, and at the same time resent, the fact that receipt of relief from the Poor Law vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 195 does inevitably entail a certain position of inferiority. Many of them join in the outcry against those who, often against their own will, are, by the force of circumstances, obliged to administer the Poor Law, so that the position of the pauper is inferior to that of the independent. The pauper, they observe, is either subjected to the confinement of the workhouse, or he is given outdoor relief, which is generally entirely inadequate. They bitterly complain of this in- evitable position of inferiority, which necessarily is the lot of those who, whether by fault or misfortune, are reduced to live at the public expense. They shrink from the remedy of a strict administration, which, it is pointed out, would force, with a perfectly legitimate pressure, a much larger number of the working population into their provident associations, and they im- patiently turn away, declaring, with considerable justice, that the whole administration of the Poor Law is unsatisfactory. Here and there a board is captured by enthusiastic reactionaries. They set to work to make their own experiments. The safeguards and discipline which fence the distribution of relief are relaxed. Pauperism, of course, increases. The weak side of human nature is prominently displayed. Even to the fanatical sentimentalist 196 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. (and there is no class so sentimental as the working-class) it becomes apparent that those who descend most eagerly into the maintenance provided by the Poor Law, are not the most estimable of mankind, and that the policy followed is dragging down those who otherwise might have prospered. This gives rise to reflection. Un- fortunately, the experience so gained does not necessarily inform the electorate, and a due supply of reactionary administrators is always forthcoming. The position is closely suggestive of a body of Christian Scientists set to control the management of an hospital. The delegates of reaction might occasionally be taught by ex- perience, but the mass of prejudice in the back- ground is not to be reached by scientific views of surgery and medicine. It is, however, an ill wind that blows no one any good ; and this agitation in favour of old age pensions has done a certain amount of good, by obliging the leaders of Friendly Society insurance to look into the question of the Poor Law. It is notorious that the Old Age Pension movement, or, as Mr Chaplin's circular entitles us to call it, the Old Age Pauperism movement, has hitherto been defeated mainly by the opposition of the Friendly Societies. In their interest it has always been considered a vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 197 necessary condition of a pension scheme that it shall not interfere or compete unfairly with Friendly Society insurance. This condition has really proved fatal, for it is obvious to the meanest intelligence that, if we are going to give gratuitous allowances to aged persons, it is an unfair competition with organisations whose principle has always been that adequate provident insurance must be paid for by adequate contribu- tions. The impossibility of making gratuitous public maintenance, accorded to persons or classes on the plea of poverty, an honourable and highly esteemed estate of life, has been pressed home to the intelligence of working-class leaders, who realise now, perhaps more firmly than before, that every extension of Poor Law maintenance removes their class farther from the attainment of their legitimate aspiration namely, complete independence. We are not surprised, therefore, to find Mr John Burns, M.P., addressing to his constituents, in February 1894, the following remarks : " Every man who has been out of work cheers the man who is in favour of outdoor relief. I have always been against it, except when administered with the greatest rigidity, and given to the right people. ... It means the complete prostitu- tion and degradation of those whom we ought to raise and educate by better means." 198 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. Mr Burns's methods are rhetorical rather than argumentative, and we are not aware that he has taken any steps to secure the adoption of his views by the local guardians of South London. It is a difficult line for a popular politician to take, unless he is convinced that the question is of more importance than any other. Mr Burns has his hands full ; he has shown no disposition to act the crusader in this matter. Signs are not wanting, however, that the subject is attracting attention, and that its importance, from the working-man's point of view, is being more adequately appreciated. In proof of this statement, and as an instance of the very thorough and drastic criticism which can be applied to our present pauper system, we cannot do better than append a few quotations from a carefully-reasoned paper, written by Mr Shelley, a prominent member of the Ancient Order of Foresters. Mr Shelley, unlike the majority, who think they can form an opinion on this subject by the light of nature without reference to history and experience, seems to have studied the subject closely, and he comes to the conclusions which every candid inquirer ultimately reaches viz., that pauperism is to a large extent an artificial and unnecessary evil, and that there are great possibilities of reform within our easy reach. vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 199 After quoting the dispauperisation of Bradfield Union by the restrictive methods which we have described, he exclaims : " What a boon to the workers ! What an immense step toward independence of the true calibre ! . . . I should urge all true friends of Friendly Societies, and as many Friendly Society workers as possible, to obtain seats upon the Board of Guardians, and thus see that the great thrift institutions are not prevented from getting as members those, who in the proper course of events, would belong to them, but, owing to the ease with which relief is obtained, failed to see the necessity of making any personal effort toward thrift. . . . Remem- ber that we are reaping greater benefits than any of our fore- fathers better wages, more healthy conditions of life and labour, together with an absolute freedom never before enjoyed ; and yet we have failed to raise from the mud of Poor Law reliance those who have for decade after decade been bred and will die in an atmosphere of Poor Law relief." Mr Shelley's paper contains much more in a similar vein. In fact, he recognises that the Poor Law is a most formidable enemy to the Friendly Societies ; and this, coming from a representative of these associations, is a very important pro- nouncement. Mr Shelley's paper was read to an audience composed partly of Friendly Society men, and partly of persons interested in the adminis- tration of the Poor Law. The discussion which followed was of great interest. The position taken up by Mr Shelley was defended by him and some of his colleagues with considerable vehem- 200 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. ence, and in a much more uncompromising spirit than the Poor Law reformer often ventures to show. It was obvious that, if this opinion ever was adopted by the working-class, very short work would be made of the abuses of outdoor relief and of the baneful competition of the poor rate with provident insurance. It was more difficult to judge how far such views were likely to be adopted and carried into action by working- class electorates. As far as could be gathered from the opinions expressed, Mr Shelley's views were not as yet shared by many of his colleagues ; but it was confidently asserted that such opinions were making progress, and that, as a rule, if any one took the trouble, as Mr Shelley had done, to go into the subject, there was only one conclusion to which he could come. Unfortunately, very few did take the trouble, and the majority was still influenced by prejudice. Mr Shelley's very thorough appreciation of the true grounds of an alliance between a policy of dispauperisation and the progress of provident insurance is very en- couraging. If such voices obtain a hearing, they cannot fail to carry conviction to candid minds. The question of Poor Law administration is a very difficult one on which to conduct what our American cousins call a campaign of education. vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 201 Reverting once more to the analogy already noted between the treatment of bodily and economic infirmity, we may express a doubt whether the most enlightened public opinion would be wise to do more than relegate the management of such matters to properly-qualified practitioners. It is possible, nay, it is essential, to obtain from public opinion a general assent to the principles of surgery, amounting, perhaps, to no more than an admission of the occasional use- fulness of the surgeon's knife ; and in the kindred province of social therapeutics it is equally necessary, and, we hope, possible, to obtain accept- ance for the proposition that pauperism is a disease which can be indefinitely reduced by the proper economic remedies. In neither the one case or the other does it appear to us convenient that the popular voice should go beyond this attitude of general acquiescence, and seek to usurp executive authority by subjecting a deliberately-adopted scientific treatment to the control of a fortuitous local sentiment. It is admitted that public opinion has pro- nounced no very definite view on the subject. We have, however, no fear of the verdict if the issues are fairly joined. What we do fear, and, as the experience since 1834 proves, with reason, is the difficulty of getting correct verdicts 202 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. on innumerable individual cases from some 6000 fortuitous boards triennially elected to administer a most elastic body of law. If public opinion ever does become seriously interested in the treatment of pauperism, it may, as in 1834, come to the deliberate adoption of a scientific policy. If, however, it wishes to have such policy carried into effect, it must avoid the error of 1834, and make sure that the administration of its views is entrusted to properly-qualified and responsible persons, whose training and terms of engagement would prevent them falling back into the plausible but fallacious methods which have wrecked the fair promise of the legislation of 1834. We have now discussed two important factors of the situation firstly, the possibility of legisla- tive changes such as may lead to a rearrange- ment of responsibility between local and central authority ; and, secondly, the possibility of the subject attracting a closer attention from the class which is politically most powerful namely, the working-class. To these two considerations a third may now be added, based on the evidence, which is readily forthcoming, as to the rapid increase of working- class property, the outward and visible sign of vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 203 the passage of the poorer population from the status of pauperism to economic independence. In calculating the chances that there are for the emancipation of the people from pauperism, we must have regard to two things : (i) The attractive and retentive qualities of the pauper maintenance ; (2) the expansive and absorbent nature of the independent and industrial life. With regard to the first, we have said that, though far larger than it need be, the pauper population does not increase. Relatively to the solvent population, it actually decreases. On the other hand, the natural increment of population (about 1 1 per cent, in the decade of the census) is silently absorbed into the in- dependent economic section of the community. If we ask how that portion of the increase which belongs to the manual labouring class is supported in those inevitable crises of life during which formerly they came upon the poor rate, the answer can best be indicated by pointing to the rapidly-increasing amount of working-class property. A computation made with regard to 1877 disclosed a sum of a hundred and eleven millions, tabulated in various official documents, as specially working-class investments. In 1891 a similar calculation showed the sum to be two hundred 204 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. and twenty millions. In his excellent little book, Provident Societies and Industrial Wel- fare, 1898, Mr Brabrook, the Chief Registrar of Friendly Societies (exclusive of the important item of insurance companies which are included in the above computations), names three hundred millions as the sum which comes within the cognisance of his office as for the most part the property of the labouring class. Few persons have any conception as to the enormous development of insurance and saving among the weekly wage-earning class. The reference submitted to the last departmental Committee on the Aged Poor involved a calcula- tion as to the numbers who should be excluded from the benefit of a pension scheme, on the ground that they could not show "proved exer- cise of reasonable providence by some definite mode of thrift." As a contribution to the solution of this calculation, a memorandum was submitted from the Registry of Friendly Societies, in which the authorities commit themselves to the opinion that, accepting membership in some provident association as a fulfilment of the test, " the general inference to be drawn from this branch of the inquiry is that few of those who are qualified under the previous six heads will be vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 205 unable to show some ground of qualification under the seventh." Of the six previous heads the only important ones were freedom for last twenty years from crime and from pauperism up to the age of sixty-five. If we add to this general statement that in one Insurance Company alone viz. the Prudential which does business almost exclusively with the wage-earning class, there are fourteen million policies in force, insuring the lives of about a third of the whole population of these islands, we may realise how important an element is insurance in the domestic economy of the working class. The most popular forms of insurance, we are credibly informed, are still the old-fashioned whole-life policy ; though of late the endowment policy (assuring a sum pay- able at death or on reaching a given age), with a guaranteed surrender value, has very much increased. Deferred annuities, the form of in- vestment which pension schemes have sought to popularise, are, on the other hand, entirely neglected. Those of us who have leisure to turn over the advertisements which arrive by the daily post must have been struck with the great variety of proposals that are made to us with regard to insurance. Many objects, which formerly people only thought of obtaining by 206 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. saving, pure and simple, can now be secured by insurance. This is obviously an enormous convenience to the professional man, (and if these companies think it worth while to advertise, we may safely conclude that business is being done), e.g. in insuring an income at a given age (I am quoting from a prospectus before me) for the family after death, endowment for a child on reaching twenty-one, and indeed for every con- ceivable object. The offices practically offer to do their "capitalisation" for the professional class, and the same is being done for the work- ing class. It is, of course, true that a portion of these insurances is merely for what is called "burial money"; but there is abundant evidence to show that the portion of it devoted to the more serious object of provision for widows and old age is rapidly increasing, and that it is being effected on reasonable terms. The important point is that the idea of insurance is already very familiar, that its methods are improving, and that its convenience, so obvious for those whose incomes are not derived from realised savings, is to a large extent appreciated by the wage-earning class. It is frequently said that this is the age of large capitalists, and that small tradesmen are vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 207 being crushed out. Whether this is true or not seems very questionable ; but, so far as it may be true, it involves the great increase of a salaried and wage-earning class, and for them these offers of insurance are calculated to meet a want. It is, however, questionable whether small tradesmen are being crushed out. A very interesting paper by Prince Krapotkine was recently published in The Nineteenth Century Review on the small industries of Great Britain, in which he showed from official statistics that it was very far from being the case that small industries were dying out. On the contrary, the greater part of British industry is still in the hands of small tradesmen. Even in America, the home of the Trust, there are still many trades in which small undertakings more than hold their own against large combinations of capital. The capital values of many indus- tries have been unduly inflated, and the conditions of success are, by a sort of re- action, coming within the reach of the practical tradesman with a small capital, derived partly from savings but more largely from credit. The cycle trade, it is said, is an instance in point. The big companies, with an inflated share capital, cannot compete with the industrious 2o8 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP. skilful mechanic. He purchases some of the component parts and manufactures others, and fits his machines together skilfully and cheaply. The banks find it to their interest to lend money to such persons on mutually advantageous terms. This accords with the experience of our Scottish Banking system, which did so much at the beginning of last century in developing the industry of Scotland. It also explains the principle on which rests the great success of the Popular Banking inaugurated in Germany by Raiffeisen, and introduced by Signer Luzzatti and others into Italy. A small but encouraging beginning has been made in Ireland by Mr Horace Plunkett's Agricultural Association, and the principle is certainly suitable for adoption in the many quarters where small industries still exist. The story of this popular and economic success is admirably told in Mr Wolffs book on Peoples Banks. A successful organisation of popular credit would do much to open a career to talent of all kind, and would give an immense encourage- ment to endeavours to rise out of that purely proletariate life which is so readily converted into pauperism. In other words, it would add greatly to the absorbent power of the con- current and better mechanism of society, to vi.] THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC RELIEF 209 which we have already so frequently made reference. The evidence as to what the poor are doing for themselves is a profitable field of study for those who are interested in the administration of public relief. It is an encouragement to them to persevere in the unpopular task of opposing too facile systems of relief. It affords good ground for hoping that, though the pressure against them is still considerable, it will probably diminish as time goes on. It serves also to remind the charitable that too exclusive thought should not be given to systems of relief. Attention must also be paid to the already imposing developments of work- ing-class thrift. The most useful line of action for the charitable will be to restrict the one, and to increase the popularity and efficiency of the other. Well - to - do people take great liberties in offering advice to their poorer neighbours, and in many cases it is accepted gratefully. But are they all qualified to offer advice ? Undoubtedly not, if they insist in ignoring the work done by working-class provident institutions. If charitable persons will qualify themselves to offer advice on such subjects, it will be advantageous in two ways. First, they will o 2 io PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND [CHAP, vi, see clearly the close connection and competition which exists between systems of relief and the progress of provident institutions, and this know- ledge will make them better administrators of public relief. Second, the criticism and greater publicity which would thus be brought to bear on provident associations would be most valuable, for, like all other human institutions, they are capable of improvement. From a survey of this aspect of the subject, our conviction will be confirmed that the in- dependent economic life has inexhaustible absorbent powers, and that a policy of emanci- pation in respect of Public Relief is wise, practicable, and humane. THE END. BIBLIOGRAPHY SELECTED LIST OF AUTHORITIES THE FIRST REPORT OF THE COMMISSIONERS FOR INQUIRING INTO THE ADMINISTRATION AND OPERATION OF THE POOR LAWS IN 1834, oct. 301 pp. [Under this title the Report of the Commissioners of Inquiry, appointed in 1832, has frequently been reprinted. The original Report, with Ap- pendices A-F, contains 8196 folio pages]. This is the most important document in connection with the subject. A valuable list of authorities, previous to 1834, is con- tained in an Appendix to the REPORT OF GEORGE COODE, ESQ., TO THE POOR LAW BOARD, ON THE LAW OF SETTLEMENT AND REMOVAL OF THE POOR, pp. 193-352. 1851. For the period previous to 1834. The following may be mentioned. THE HISTORY OF THE POOR LAWS, WITH OBSERVATIONS, by RICHARD BURN, LL.D., etc., 1764. THE HISTORY OF THE POOR, THEIR RIGHTS, DUTIES, AND THE LAWS RESPECTING THEM, by THOMAS RUGGLES, ESQ., etc., 1793- TRACTS ON POOR LAWS AND PAUPER MANAGEMENT, by JEREMY BENTHAM, vol. viii. of his collected works, 1843, originally issued about 1797. [The source from which perhaps unconsciously Mr Chadwick derived many of his ideas]. 211 212 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND THE STATE OF THE POOR, by SIR FREDERIC MORTON EDEN, Bart, in 3 vols, 1797. [A most remarkable storehouse of facts]. CONSIDERATIONS ON THE POOR LAWS, by JOHN DAVIDSON, M.A., etc., 1817. A SECOND LETTER TO THE RIGHT HONOURABLE ROBERT PEEL, ON THE CAUSES OF THE INCREASE OF PAUPERISM, etc., by ONE OF HIS CONSTITUENTS (BISHOP COPLESTONE). 1819. THE PRINCIPLE OF THE ENGLISH POOR LAWS, ILLUSTRATED AND DEFENDED, by FREDERICK PAGE, Esq., etc., 1822, 107 pp. [An able philosophical treatise]. EIGHT LETTERS ON THE MANAGEMENT OF OUR POOR, ETC., IN THE TWO PARISHES OF SOUTHWELL AND BINGHAM, by AN OVERSEER (Sir GEO. NICHOLLS), 1822. [Reprinted from the Nottingham Journal ; a detailed account of successful manage- ment under the Old Poor Law]. A LETTER TO SAMUEL WHITBREAD, M.P., ON HIS PROPOSED BILL FOR THE AMENDMENT OF THE POOR LAWS, by the Rev. T. R. MALTHUS. Second edition, 1807. THE SUFFICIENCY OF THE PAROCHIAL SYSTEM WITHOUT A POOR RATE, by THOMAS CHALMERS, D.D., n.d. CHALMERS ON CHARITY, a selection of passages, etc., edited by N. MASTERMAN, 1900. [This volume has gathered in very convenient form the teaching of Chalmers as expounded by him in a great many publications]. For the period after 1834. A HISTORY OF THE ENGLISH POOR LAW, etc., by Sir GEORGE NICHOLLS, K.C.B. New edition, edited by H. G. WILLINK. 2 vols. 1898. A HISTORY OF THE ENGLISH POOR LAW, etc., vol. iii., from 1834 to the present time. A supplementary volume to the above, by THOMAS MACKAY. 1899. BIBLIOGRAPHY 213 PAUPERISM AND POOR LAWS, by ROBERT PASHLEY. 1852. [Mainly a denunciation of the evils of the law of Settlement and Removal]. HISTORICAL AND PHILOSOPHICAL ESSAYS, by NASSAU W. SENIOR, Esq., 2 vols. 1865. (Vol. ii., "Essay on English Poor Laws"). A DICTIONARY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, by HENRY DUNNING MACLEOD. 1863. (Article :" Edwin Chadwick "). THE HEALTH OF NATIONS : A REVIEW OF THE WORKS OF EDWIN CHADWICK, by BENJAMIN WARD RICHARDSON. 1887. ON THE EVILS OF DISUNITY IN CENTRAL AND LOCAL ADMINISTRATION, by EDWIN CHADWICK, C.B. 1885. PAUPERISM : ITS CAUSES AND REMEDIES, by HENRY FAW- CETT, M.A., M.P. 1871. LETTERS AND OTHER WRITINGS OF THE LATE EDWARD DENISON, M.P. for Newark, edited by Sir BALDWYN LEIGHTON, Bart. 1872. DISPAUPERISATION, by J. R. PRETYMAN. 1876. THE POOR LAW, by T. W. FOWLE. 1881. (Macmillan's " Citizen Series " ). THE BETTER ADMINISTRATION OF THE POOR LAW, by W. CHANCE. 1895. CHILDREN UNDER THE POOR LAW, by the same. 1897. OUR TREATMENT OF THE POOR, by the same, n.d. (1899). THE ENGLISH POOR LAW SYSTEM, by Dr P. F. ASCHROTT. Translated from the German by Herbert Preston-Thomas, 1888. LA Loi DES PAUVRES ET LA SOCIETE ANGLAISE, par EMILE CHEVALLIER. 1895. THE EARLY HISTORY OF ENGLISH POOR RELIEF, by E. M. LEONARD. 1900. SOME POOR RELIEF QUESTIONS, WITH THE ARGUMENTS ON BOTH SIDES, by Miss GERTRUDE LUBBOCK, 1895. 214 PUBLIC RELIEF IN ENGLAND PLAIN WORDS ON OUT RELIEF. ANON. Knight & Co., 1894. [An argument in favour of outdoor relief; see also a correspondence in the Charity Organization Review, Feb., April, June and July numbers 1894]. THE BOOK OF THE BASTILES ; OR, THE HISTORY OF THE WORKING OF THE NEW POOR LAW, by G. R. WYTHEN BAXTER. 1841. [A compilation of the adverse criticisms directed against the New Poor Law]. THE PRINCIPLES OF THE ENGLISH POOR LAW : A Paper read by MR G. LANSBURY at the Central Poor Law Con- ference, 1897. Report No. n of Series 1896-97. [An ex- position of the Socialist's attitude towards the Poor Law]. On the Special Subject of the Growth of Working Class Savings. ENGLISH ASSOCIATIONS OF WORKING MEN, by J. M. BAERNREITHER ; translated from the German. 1889. PROVIDENT SOCIETIES AND INDUSTRIAL WELFARE, by E. W. BRABROOK, C.B., Chief Registrar of Friendly Societies. 1898. PEOPLE'S BANKS, by H. W. WOLFF. Second edition. 1896. The Reader is also referred to the REPORTS OF THE POOR LAW CONFERENCES, and to the ANNUAL REPORTS OF THE POOR LAW COMMISSIONERS, of the POOR LAW BOARD, and of the LOCAL GOVERNMENT BOARD. Special attention is drawn to the "CONTINUANCE" REPORT OF THE POOR LAW COMMISSIONERS, published in 1839. The Reports and Evidence published by various Com- missions and Committees of Inquiry should also be consulted. PRINTED AT WORKS BY THE SAME AUTHOR. Methods of Social Reform Essays, Critical and Constructive, Price Js. 6d. John Murray. 1896 " A very clear and persuasive exponent of what may be called the orthodox school of Poor Law reformers." Spectator. " An excellent chapter on People's Banks will command attention, and Freedom of Exchange v. the Collective Bargain is ably reasoned." St James Gazette. " C'est un veritable service qu'il rend en soumettant a une critique tres serree la methode et les resultats de MM. Booth, Hunter, etc." Le Sitcle. ' ' In the paper called the ' Abuse of Statistics,' which is reprinted from the Quarterly Review, he makes a rather formidable attack on Mr Charles Booth." The Times. "Whether we agree or disagree with Mr Mackay, it will be readily admitted that he writes with a sincerity and a strength of conviction which command respect." Manchester Guardian. WORKS EDITED BY THE SAME. A Plea For Liberty An Argument against Socialism and Socialistic Legisla- tion, consisting of an Introduction by HERBERT SPENCER, and Essays by Various Writers. Edited by THOMAS MACKAY. New and Revised Edition, price 2s. John Murray. 1892. "This collection of essays . . . prefaced by weighty observations, by Mr Herbert Spencer, and the work of a group of able writers, gives expres- sion, and not too soon, to a deep though rarely articulate feeling." Times. A Policy of Free Exchange Essays by Various Writers on the Economical and Social Aspects of Free Exchange. Edited by THOMAS MACKAY. Price 12s. John Murray. 1894 " The present volume is concerned with the discussion of economic and social problems, and is written from the point of view of those who hold that the principle of Free Exchange is capable of inspiring a constructive policy. . . . The book, in its general aspects, may be described as a power- ful exposure of the vapid talk, inconclusive reasoning, and cloudy sentiment which enter so largely into the Socialistic contentions," Standard. OTHER WORKS BY THE SAME AUTHOR. The State and Chanty Price 2s. 6d. Macmillan 6 Co. 1898 " The State and Charity ... is a valuable and instructive contribution to the well-known ' English Citizen ' Series ... is all the more edifying, because while full of suggestive and impartial criticism, it is not in the least dogmatic. " Times. A History of the English Poor Law From 183410 the Present Time : Being a Supplementary Volume to " A History of the English Poor Laws," By Sir GEORGE NiCHOLLS, K.C.B. Price 2 is. P. S. King & Son. 1899 "Every reader who has tramped with Nicholls along the highways and byways of Poor Law history will be grateful for the easier and more attractive route provided in the philosophic treatise of Mr Mackay. . . . Mr Mackay has been able to make a really valuable contribution to what may be called the history of Poor Law thought. . . . There is a side to this fascinating book which suggests various reflections of a supplementary or critical nature, viz., the many scattered paragraphs upon the structure and working and interworking of the central and local bodies which are or have been employed in carrying out the English Poor Law. . . . Mr Mackay provides an indispensable and valuable framework for the philosophic reformer of the future, and he knows how to combine in an attractive form the work of the lawyer, the pamphleteer, the statesman, the Blue-book maker, and the statistician." Speaker. "The work of a man most fully qualified both by grasp of economic principle and by practical experience. Whether he is writing on the theory of the Poor Law, or the effect of Poor Law relief on wages, or whether he is describing the actual position of the problem of dispauperisation, the reader feels that he is in the hands of a clear thinker, open-minded, who is at the same time master of his facts." Spectator, r>AY USE -STANFORD 07 '94 . Gen LD 21A-407n-ll,'63 (El602slO)476B General Library University of California Berkeley YD n/ / U. C. BERKELEY LIBRARIES /3OO59 A\25 THE UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA LIBRARY