JC 11 J42 f^DWARD JENKS, M.A. LIBRARY ' UNIVERSITY OF CALirORNIA SAN DIEGO < \ r. ^^?:- NEW YORti E. P. DUTTON & COMPANY 681 FiftK Avenue l^gggjyUgiglBOHafill Copyright, 1900 By the MACMILLAN COMPANY Set up and electrotyped April, 1900 Reprinted September, 1902 January, 1907, January, 1909 July, 1918 PREFACE Some ten years ago Sir Frederick Pollock published a valuable and interesting little book on the history of politi- cal speculation.* But the author is not aware that any one has yet attempted to summarize in a brief, popular form, the record of political action. It has occurred, therefore, to the promoters of this Series that such a summary might prove interesting, if only by way of comparison. These pages profess to give, then, a brief account of what men have done, not of what they have thought, in that important branch of human activity which we call Poli- tics, or the Art of Government. But if it should be ob- jected that what men do is really always the outcome, more or less perfect, of what they think, the answer is, that we recognize, for practical purposes, a distinction between what the world, in theory at least, believes to be best, and that which it actually succeeds in achieving. And a com- parison of the two objects can hardly fail to be instructive. To the other, and inevitable objection, that it is impos- sible, within the narrow limits of a popular sketch, to deal with such a subject as the History of Politics, the author * "An Introduction to the History of the Science of Politics." By (Sir) Frederick Pollock. London, 1890. A new edition has recently been published. (v) Vi PREFACE will reply with the doctrine which, paradoxical as it may sound, is yet maintained by very able writers, that the greater the subject the smaller the space in which it can be treated. Readers who care to see parts of the subject worked out in greater detail may be referred to the author's "Law and Politics in the Middle Ages" (Murray, 1898). Oxford, January, 1900. CONTENTS INTRODUCTORY CHAPTER PAGE I. Types of Society i TYPE I— SAVAGE SOCIETY II. Savage Organization 6 TYPE II — PATRIARCHAL SOCIETY III. Patriarchal Society in General i6 IV. The Domestication of Animals 23 V. Tribal Organization 32 VI. Agriculture and the Clan 44 VII. Industry and the Gild 62 TYPE III — MODERN (POLITICAL) SOCIETY VIII. The State and Feudalism 73 IX. Early Political Institutions 84 X. The State and Property 97 XI. The State and Justice 112 (vii) vfii CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE XII. The State and Legislation 124 XIII. The State and Administration 140 XIV. Varieties of Political Society 151 List of Authorities 165 Index 167 Glossary 173 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS INCTRODUCTO RY CHAPTER I Types of Society Politics. — By Politics we mean the business of Govern- ment: that is to say, the control and management of people living together in a society. A socie^, again, is a group or mass of people, bound together by a certain common priu' ciple or object. A mere chance crowd is not a society ; it has no definite object, it collects and disperses at the whim of the moment, its members recognize no duties toward one another. It has no history, no organization. Society. — Societies are of many kinds. They may exist for purposes of religion, commercial profit, amusement, education, or a host of other objects. A good specimen of a religious society is, of course, an ordinary church congre- gation, or a missionary society ; of a commercial society, an ordinary trading company ; of an amusement society, a West-end club ; of an educational society, an university or a college. And the management and organization of any such society may in strictness be considered a branch of Politics. But it is convenient to reserve the term politics for matters concerning one particular and very important class of societies, those communities, namely, which are not formed for any special or limited objects, but which have (I) 2 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS grown up, almost spontaneously, as part of the general his- tory of mankind, and which are concerned with its general interests. Men, as a rule, live in these communities, not because they choose to do so, but because they are bom into them ; and until quite recently, they were not allowed to change them at their pleasure. In their most advanced forms, we call these communities States ; Great Britain, France, Holland, Germany, Spain, Russia, etc. , are undoubt- edly States. And these States are the proper subject matter of Politics, in the modern sense of the term. But, as we study their history, we become aware that these communi- ties have gradually developed out of societies of quite another type, organized on different principles. ModePM social groups. — Now-a-days, the principle which binds together these communities of the modern type is the tie of military allegiance. In the States which practice conscription, or universal military service, this is very obvious. The most heinous political offence which a Frenchman or a German can commit is attempting to evade military service ; or, possibly worse, taking part in military service against his own country. But even in Great Britain, where conscription is not practised, the tie is really the same. It is unquestionable that the Queen, through her Ministers, has the right, in case of necessity, to call upon everyone of her male subjects to render personal military service ; and any British subject captured fighting against his country would be liable to suffer death as a traitor. In the older conditions of society, however, to which allusion has been made, the tie was not that of military allegiance, but kinship, which was at first, no doubt, based on actual blood relationship, but was afterwards extended by fictitious methods. To men living in such a community, the inclusion of strangers in blood would have appeared a monstrosity. The mere facts that these strangers were settled in the same neighbourhood, or carried on trade with the community in question, or even were willing to fi?ht its battles, would TYPES OF SOCIETY 3 have seemed to such a community no arguments at all for admitting them to membership. The most conspicuous example in the world of a community organized on such principles is, of course, the Jews, who, in spite of their world- wide dispersal, still maintain intact their tribal organization, at least in theory. The same ideas were at the bottom of the famous struggle in early Roman history between the patricians * and the plebeians; and it is possible that some- thing of the same kind may be unconsciously at the root of the trouble between the Boers and the Uitlanders in the Transvaal. The Welsh and the Irish before the Norman Conquest, the Scottish Highlanders two or three centuries ago, undoubtedly lived in communites of this type, which we may call patriarchal, or tribal. Still older groups. — Until quite recently it was be- lieved that this patriarchal type was the oldest type of human community. Speculators on the history of society started from the patriarchal household, and worked down- wards to the modem State. But the brilliant discoveries of the last half century have revealed to us a still more primi- tive type of society which, so far as the writer knows, has never been described in a popular book, and which it takes some considerable effort to realize, even when it is stated in the simplest language. It is intensely interesting, both as adding another whole province to the domain of scientific history, and as revealing another step in the path by which man has moved onward and upward. At present too little is known of its details to warrant more than a brief descrip- tion ; but, thanks to the labours of devoted students, who have faced discomfort and hardship in order to examine this type of society in its few surviving examples, the out- lines are now fairly clear. Unfortunately, it is hard to find a good name by which it may be distinguished. Its scientific name of Totemistic is too elaborate and technical for popu- * A " patrician " is one who has a " pater," or chief of kindred. 4 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS lar use. Perliaps it will be best to call it the savage type ; though it must be clearly understood that the term implies neither contempt nor Jslame. It merely signifies that the type in question is \ (try primitive or rudimentary. Here, then, we have our three historical types of human society — the savage, the patriarchal, and the military (or "political" in the modern sense). And it will be the business of " A Short History of Politics " to describe each of them in turn, beginning with the oldest, and, if possible, to point out the causes which led societies to abandon the older for the newer types. To do this, we shall not require to describe the histories of particular societies ; that will be the task of other writers in the Series. But we shall en- deavour to trace a normal course for the development of societies, a course which every community tends to follow, unless deflected from its natural path by special circum- stances. It is the fashion to scoff at such attempts, and, doubtless, there is a danger in "general views." But there is, likewise, a danger in specialization; and a man who uses the microscope only loses the treasures revealed by the telescope. It is a wase ideal of study: to know something of everything, and everything of something. OUP plan. — But, if we start on a story of this kind, it is quite evident that we must have something in the nature of a plan. To plunge recklessly into the facts of universal his- tory would be to invite failure. To what pathway shall we trust to bring us safely out of the forest ? Institutions. — There is a large part of the history of every community which seems to leave no permanent traces upon it. No doubt the results are there ; but they are too vague and too subtle to be easily described. On the other hand, the effects of other parts of the community's history are plainly discernible in the permanent and visible results which they leave on the community itself. These results we call institutions : i. e., the machinery by which the business of the community is carried on. Perhaps it would be better TYPES OF SOCIETY 5 to call them limbs or orgatts of the community, for they resemble natural growths far more than artificial creations. They correspond in the body social with the litnbs or organs of the body natural: i. e., with those instruments by which the business of the body — its absorption, digestion, de- fence, attack, etc., are carried on. And so we use the meta- phor organization, to describe the development of institu- tions in the body social, or community. Theip relative importance. — These institutions may not really be the most important part of the body social, any more than the limbs and organs are the most important part of the body natural. The really important thing in each is that indefinable existence which we call life. But as no one has yet succeeded in explaining what life is, even in the natural body, still less in the social body, we shall be wiser to describe the institutions of society, to show, if we can, how they appeared, grew, and gradually changed, till they assumed the shape in which we know them now. Only, as every fully developed society has many kinds of institu- tions, political, industrial, religious, educational, and so on, with all of which it would be impossible to deal, we must remember that this is a book on politics, and deals only, or chiefly, with those institutions which are concerned directly with the business of government. This, then, will be the plan of our work : to describe, as briefly and clearly as possible, the origin and development of the institutions of government. Type I — Savage Society CHAPTER II Savage Organization Savagres. — in spite of the constantly increasing inter- course between the most remote parts of the world, and the civilizing influences of commerce, there remain quite a con- siderable number of peoples who still live under primitive or savage conditions. Among them may be reckoned the Andamanese of the Bay of Bengal, the hill tribes of Madras, the Juangs of Orissa, the Veddahs of Ceylon, the Bushmen and Akkas of Africa, the Colorado Indians of North America, the Caribs of the centre and the Brazilians of the south, the Dyaks of Borneo, and the Eskimos of Green- land and Labrador. The Tasmanians of Van Diemen's Land were, until their recent extinction, perfect specimens of unadulterated savagery. But by far the most important examples, because the most remote from admixture and the most scientifically and recently studied, are the aborigines* of Australia, who, in the centre and north of that vast con- tinent, still roam untouched and unreclaimed. Their num- bers are considerable, and, though they are probably des- tined to disappear at no distant date, they are at present in full possession of their primitive organization, Owing to the praiseworthy efforts of a generation of students, promi- *The reader is cautioned that the term "Australian Native" is by local custom reserved for the descendants of the white colonists, and is rarely extended to the " blackfellow." (6) SAVAGE ORGANIZATION 7 nent among them being Mr. A. W. Howitt, the Rev. Lorimer Fison, Professor Baldwin Spencer and Mr. Gillen, who have braved the hardships of the AustraHan desert, and won their way into the confidence of the savages by consistent kind- ness, we are now able to form some tolerably correct ideas of savage life. Their accounts may be profitably supplemented by the studies of the late Mr. Lewis Morgan, who, in the Red Indians of America, found a people just emerging from sav- agery into the patriarchal stage of society, and whose book on "Ancient Society " will ultimately be recognized as one of the great scientific products of the nineteenth century. Savagre life. — The material side of Australian existence may be best described in a series of negatives. The savages understand neither the cultivation of the land nor the rearing of sheep and cattle, 'nrerr only domestic animal (if " domes- tic " it can be called) is the dog. They have no idea of dwel- lings more advanced than a rude bough hut ; for the most part they take shelter in caves, and behind pieces of bark propped up against trees or rocks. They have no food but the scanty game of the "bush " or forest, such as the wallaby and the opossum, and the natural products of the earth. The art of fire-making, in a very primitive form, is known to them ; but their notions of cooking are of the crudest. Still less have they the knowledge of working in metals, either by hammer- ing or by melting. The recently adopted iron tomahawk is an article of barter, obtained from the enterprising traveller, in exchange for natural products. The indigenous weapons are the flint-headed spear and axe, and the wooden boom- erang or throwing-stick. Australian legends go back to a time when even the use of stone knives was unknown, and operations, even on the human body, were performed with a charred stick. The "pitchi," or bark-basket, and the dig- ging-stick of the women appear to be almost the only articles which can be classed as "tools." The clothing of the Australians may be described as purely ornamental. It consists, in fact, of certain decorations used in religious 8 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS ceremonies ; in ordinary' life they are stark naked. The appalHng feature of this miserable existence, always border- ing on starvation, is that it seems to have gone on during countless ages. The fauna and flora of Australia are, it is well known, of a thoroughly archaic type ; the naturalist discovers in its forests and rivers forms which have long since been extinct in other parts of the world. And as there is no evidence whatever of any intercourse between Australia and other lands during the period of recorded history, as, in fact, Australia was, until three centuries ago, an unknown land, we can only suppose that the Australian has led his present life during thousands of years. His isolation has been, no doubt, 'the chief cause of his stagnation. Savage institutions. — This view is entirely confirmed by a study of the non-material side of Australian life. Crude and primitive as it seems to us, its elaborateness of detail and complexity of ceremonial point to a history of great, but unrecorded, antiquity. When we consider the terror which all novelty has for the savage, especially in religious matters, we are bound to think that the elaborate ceremonies described in Messrs. Spencer's and Gillen's valuable book * must have taken centuries, perhaps even thousands of years, to work out. We may be very sure that no sudden change was made ; but that only little by little was the elaborate ceremonial in- troduced. We cannot here do more than describe its leading features. "Tribe" op "pack." — It is the custom to speak of the Australians and other savages as living in "tribes." But the term is most misleading; for the word "tribe" always suggests to us the notion of descent from a common ancestor, or, at any rate, of close blood relationship. Now there is, as we shall see, a most important stage in human progress, in which descent from a common ancestor plays a vital part in social organization. But the Australian "tribe " ♦"The Native Tribes of Central Australia." London, 1899. SAVAGE ORGANIZATION 9 does not really play a very important part in savage life, at least on its social side. It appears to be mainly a group of people engaged in hunting together, a cooperative or com- munal society for the acquisition of food supply. It would really be better to call it the "pack;" for it far more resembles a hunting than a social organization. All its members are entitled to a share in the proceeds of the day's chase, and, quite naturally, they camp and live together. But they are not sharply divided, for other purposes, from other "packs" living in the neighbourhood. On the con- trary, they frequently mingle with them ; and a social free- masonry extends over vast areas of the continent. Totem group.— The real social unit of the Australians is not the "tribe," but the totem group. The word ^"^ totem'''' is not, of course, Australian ;* but it is generally accepted as the name of an institution which is found almost universally among savages. The totem group is, primarily, a body of persons, distinguished by the sign of some natural object, such as an animal or tree, who may not intermarry with one another. In many cases, membership of the totem group is settled by certain rules of inheritance, generally through females. But among the Australians, new-born or (in some cases) unborn infants are allotted by the wise men to partic- ular totems ; and this arrangement has all the appearance of extreme antiquity, for the savage has no idea of principles ; he requires hard and fast rules. No mappiage within the totem.— The Australian may not marry within his totem. "Snake may not marry snake. Emu may not marry emu. ' ' That is the first rule of savage social organization. Of its origin we have no knowledge ; but there can be little doubt that its object was to prevent the marriage of near relations. Though the savage cannot argue on principles, he is capable of observing facts. And *It sems to have been first used, in a slightly different form, by the Ojibway Indians of North America. lO A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS the evils of close inbreeding must, one would think, have ultimately forced themselves upon his notice If so, we can understand the rule, "Snake may not marry snake." But this is conjecture. Marriage with another totem.— The other side of the rule is equally startling. The savage may not marry within his totem, but he must marry into another totem specially fixed for him. More than this, he not only marries into the specified totem, but he marries the whole of the women of that totem in his own generation. Thus, all the men of the Snake totem are husbands of all the women of the Emu totem in the same generation ; and, as a natural consequence, all the women of Snake totem are wives of all the men of Emu totem. Of course, it must not be supposed, that this condition of marital community really exists in prac- tice. As a matter of fact, each Australian contents himself with one or two women from his marriage totem. But it is a fact that an Australian would see nothing wrong in a man living as the husband of any woman of his marriage totem, provided she were of his own generation. And if an Au- stralian is travelling from "tribe" to "tribe," he will, as a matter of course, find a wife waiting for him in every "tribe " which contains women of his marriage totem. It is facts such as these which scandalized early missionaries, and often caused them to shut their eyes to what was really a most valuable object lesson in social history. No unmarried people. — It will be obvious that, under these arrangements, there are no bachelors or spinsters among the Australian savages ; but that, as Mr. Fison has well observed, marriage is, among them, "a natural state into which both parties are bom." Different generations. — It has been hinted before that some classification is necessary to distinguish the different degrees or generations within the totem group ; and this is one of the objects of the mysterious corroborees, or cere- monial gatherings, which play so large a part in the life of SAVAGE ORGANIZATION II the savage. Though it is extremely difficult, owing to the unwillingness of savages to reveal the secrets of their rites, to ascertain precisely the details of these ceremonies, it is fairly clear that they serve more than one object. In the first place, as was frankly admitted by an Australian mystery man of repute, they effect the useful result of impressing the ordinary members of the totem group with a sense of the importance and power of the ' ' Birraark ' ' or sorcerers, usually old men, who conduct them. In the second, they undoubtedly seem to keep alive the legendary history of the totem group, and thus to bind its members closer together. The songs and dances of the ceremonies in many cases are supposed to represent great events which have occurred in the " Alcheringa," or distant past. Finally, at the cere- monies, often lasting for several days, the youths and maidens who have attained to maturity are initiated into some of the mysteries of the totem, often to the accompani- ment of painful rites, such as circumcision and other lacera- tion. It is possible that, on such occasions, the initiated are subjected to tattooing, with a view of establishing their identity, and of allotting them to a certain totem, and to a certain generation within that totem. System of relationship. — By this, or some other artificial means, the curiously simple system of Australian relationship is constructed. All the women of his marriage totem in his generation are a man's wives ; all their children are his children ; all the members of his totem in the same generation are his brothers and sisters (whom he may not marry) ; all the members of his mother's totem are his parents (for descent is nearly always reckoned through females). Parent, child, brother and sister are thus the only relation- ships recognized. Rudimentary as this system appears to be, it is widely spread throughout the Malay archipelago, and Mr. Fison tells an amusing story of a missionary who, to increase his familiarity with his native converts, was made by the pro- cess of adoption the brother of his man-servant. Happening 12 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS to meet the man's wife, the missionary pleasantly explained that he was now her brother. Whereupon the lady instantly corrected him by saying, ' ' Oh no, you are not my brother, you are my husband." Mr. Morgan, indeed, who has studied the natives of Hawaii and Honolulu, as well as his own Red Indians, thinks that there are traces of still older systems, in which marriage between brothers and sisters, and even between lineal relations, was practised. Be this as it may, the Australian system prevails widely among savages, and even, with certain modifications, among some highly civilized people, e. g., the Chinese. Totem questions. — Whether the totem serves any other purpose than that of prohibiting intermarriage of near relations, and what is the precise connection which the sav^ages believe to exist between themselves and their totems, are much disputed questions. With regard to the latter, it has been suggested by recent observers that the Australian believes himself to be, in some mysterious way, the offspring of his totem. There can also be little doubt that, in some cases at least, the totem is an object of worship, a fetich which will deal destruction if the rule of the intermarriage is not rigidly observed. And, if this be so, we get an interest- ing glimpse at the rudiments of two of the most powerful factors in human progress — Religion and Law. It has been said that the progress of religious ideas follows three stages. In the first, Man worships some object entirely external to himself, a stone or an animal. In the second, he worships a human being like himself, usually one of his own ancestors. In the third, he has risen to the idea of a God who is both divine and human, unlike and distinct from himself, and yet like to and connected with himself. The Australian totem would answer to the first of these three stages. But it is somewhat significant to notice that the savage's view of his deity is usually that of a malevolent Power, dealing disease and death, and thirsting for human blood. It is to be feared that this view is largely the reflection of the savage's only SAVAGE ORGANIZATION 13 means of reasoning ; viz. , by experience. He sees that any one of his fellows who happens to be exceptionally strong and clever is apt to show his power by the exercise of crueltj'. He transfers this character to his god. Savage Law. — Closely connected with this view is the savage's rudimentary notion of Law. With him it is a purely negative idea, a list of things which are prohibited, or taboo. The origin of these prohibitions is often ludicrous, but they are generally found to be connected with the appre- hension of danger. A man is walking along a path, and is struck by a falling branch. Instead of attributing the blow to natural causes, he assumes it to be the result of the anger of the Tree-Spirit, offended by his action in using the path. In the future, that path is taboo, or forbidden. A rude log bridge is made over a stream. It gives way beneath a passenger, and the man is drowned. That (the savage thinks) is the vengeance of the Water-Spirit, incensed at the insult ofifered by the existence of the bridge, which deprives him of his due number of victims. But the convenience of the bridge is so great that men are tempted to build it again. And then a cunning man suggests that, if a victim be sacrificed before the bridge is used, the Water-Spirit will be satisfied. And so some poor wretch is bound hand and foot and thrown into the torrent. Probably the bridge is better built this time, and does not break. The charm has worked. In such a way arises the notion of sacrifice, whicn has played such a ghastly part in history. Jacob Grimm, the great German scholar, found the practice of bridge sacrifices in use in northeastern Germany, happily only in a mock form, as late as the beginning of the present century. The practice of bur>'ing alive a victim in the foundations of a house, as a sacrifice to the Earth-Spirit, whose domain is being invaded, is widely spread in savage countries. Doubt- less it had a similar origin. Whether the totem bond also serves the purpose of unit- ing its members together for offence and defence, is also a 14 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS disputed question. There are traces of such a state of things, and its existence would certainly explain the develop- ment of a conspicuous feature of the second or patriarchal stage of society, the blood-feud group. But the relations of one group of savages to another are obscure and uncertain. Doubtless the members of a group, whether it be the "tribe" or hunting unit, or the totemistic marriage group, do not recognize any duties towards strangers. But their actual attitude is probably determined by the state of the food supply and the amount of elbow-room. If game is abundant, and hunting-grounds large in proportion to the population, distinct groups of savages may exist side by side in a given area without conflict. But if game is scarce, and the land thickly peopled (in the savage state the two things would probably go together), wars and murders are, prob- ably, frequent. Even the revolting practice of cannibalism probably originated in hunger ; though there are some races which seem unable to abandon it, even in times of plenty, and plausible reasons are invented for its continuance. But it is one of the surest laws of progress that, with each for- ward step, the same area is able to maintain an ever- increasing number of people. And so the temptations for war, or at least the excuses for war, are happily ever diminishing. Summary. — It is a somewhat dark picture that we have had to draw of the life of primitive man. And indeed the noble savage, who passed his days in a sort of perpetual picnic, surrounded by his family, who sported in the flowery meads while he discoursed sweet music, was a last century fiction which did more credit to the hearts than to the heads of an unhistorical generation. The actual savage is usually a miserable, underfed and undersized creature, naked and shivering, houseless, in constant terror of dangers seen and unseen, with no family ties as we understand them, with no certain food supply, and no settled abode. And yet even the savage life contributes something to the total of civiliza- SAVAGE ORGANIZATION 15 tion. The savage hunter, dependent for his very existence on success in the chase, learns to endure hardships without murmuring, in the pursuit of his prey. Constantly on the lookout for danger, he develops powers of observation which are the admiration of his more civilized brother. He can trace the footsteps of an enemy in a thicket where a modern detective would declare it impossible to read any sign. He can foretell the approach of a storm from warn- ings which would escape a scientific weather prophet. He can hear sounds which to a civilized man are simply inaudible. He has infinite patience, provided only that the prospect of reward is palpable and immediate. These are no mean contributions to the store of civilization. Type II — Patriarchal Society CHAPTER III Patriarchal Society in General Distinguishing features. — We now approach the consideration of the second stage of social development, in which the binding ties are more distinctly marked, and the organization more perfect, than in the preceding stage. All patriarchal society is characterized by certain well- marked features, which distinguish it from earlier as well as from later types of society. These features are : 1. Male kinship. — We saw that, in the savage type of community, while something that might be called kinship prevailed, it was so arbitrary and artificial that it might be regarded as a superstition rather than a fact. So far as there was any recognition of blood relationship at all, it was rela- tionship through women, not through men. But, in the patriarchal stage, paternity is the leading fact. Men are counted of kin because they are descended from the same male ancestor. Sometimes, no doubt, the relationship is fictitious rather than real ; as when deficiencies in a family are made up by adoption or fosterage. But the very exist- ence of such devices shows the importance attached to descent through males. Leaving for the present the ques- tion of how this important change came about, we notice another feature of patriarchal society closely connected with it. 2. Pepmanent mappiage.— Without such an addition, Cl6) PATRIARCHAL SOCIETY IN GENERAL 17 the first feature could hardly develop. In a state of society such as that of the Australians {ante, p. 10), no one could be certain who his father was. It is not until a woman becomes the wife of one man only that anything like cer- tainty of fatherhood appears. But it must not be assumed that marriage, as we understand it, i. e., permanent union of one man with one woman, is a feature of all patriarchal society. On the other hand, polyg'a-my, 1. e., the marriage of one man to several women, is very characteristic of patriarchal society in its earlier stages. Only in its later developments does it approach to the modern system of marriage. But the existence of polygamy is no bar to the recognition of kinship through males ; on the contrary, it renders it increasingly certain, by providing against a superfluity of unmarried women. Finally, a third essential feature of patriarchal society must be mentioned. 3. Paternal authority. — The principles upon which patriarchal society is conducted require, as we shall see, the existence of groups presided over and controlled by the well-nigh despotic authority of a male ancestor. This ancestor controls not only the business affairs of the group, but its religion and its conduct. He alone is responsible for it to the larger group of which it forms a part. The pre- cise limits of this authority differ in different stages. In early Rome, as is well known, the patria potcstas extended to all the descendants of a living ancestor, no matter how old they were, and even survived, in a modified form, over the female descendants after his death. Moreover, it com- prised even the power of life and death, to say nothing of control and chastisement. In later forms of the patriarchal system this power becomes greatly modified, but an inter- esting record of Welsh society at the end of the patriarchal stage says of the Mab, or youth under fourteen : (He is) "at his father's platter, and his father lord over him, and he is to receive no punishment but that of his father, and he is not to possess a penny of his property during that time, l8 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS only in common with his father." In fact, for legal pur- poses, he has no sej^arate existence. Actual examples. — These are the universal features of society in the patriarchal stage, whether we look at it among Jewish tribes, or the early Greeks (e. g., the Homeric heroes) or Romans, or among the Arabs of the desert, or the Hindus and Mohammedans of northern India, or the Afghans of the frontier, or, better still, among our Teutonic forefathers in their German homes, or, perhaps best of all, among the branches of the Keltic race, the Welsh, the Irish and the Highland Scotch, with whom it lingered until a comparatively late period. Two stages of patpiarehal society. — But the study of patriarchal society has, until quite lately, been rendered very difficult by the practice, adopted by writers and speakers, of treating all patriarchal society as though it were of one kind. As a consequence, the picture has been confused, inconsistencies and difficulties have arisen, and impatient critics have been tempted to regard the patriarchal stage of society as an ingenious fiction. Tribal. — As a matter of fact, a patient study of the evidence soon reveals the truth that patriarchal society falls into two subordinate stages, represented by two different groups or social units. The first of these may properly be called the tribe, the second the cla7i (or sept). The former (the tribe) is a large group, consisting of several hundred individuals, the fully qualified among whom certainly believe themselves to be descended from a common male ancestor, and are certainly bound together by the ties of kinship through males. But, in most cases, if not all, the common ancestor of the tribe is a fictitious person, invented to satisfy the etiquette which has now come to regard descent from a common male ancestor as the only true basis of society ; and, as a matter of fact, the lawfully bom children of all male members of the tribe are entitled to be classed as tribesmen. PATRIARCHAL SOCIETY IN GENERAL 19 Clannish. — The clan, on the other hand, is a much smaller body, consisting of some three or four generations only, in descent from a perfectly well-known male ancestor, and breaking up, automatically, into new clans or septs when the proper limits have been reached. Mistaken (oldeP) theory. — This distinction has been perceived by many writers, who, however, have failed to understand its true significance, and, consequently, its value as a help to the study of patriarchal society. They have been misled by the old theory, now definitely exploded, that the beginnings of society are to be found in the single house- hold, or group of descendants of a living man. When such a house-father died, they say, his sons would set up house- holds of similar pattern for themselves, and these house- holds, remembering their relationship, would form a clan; when the clan grew so big that its actual relationships became obscure, it would become a tribe. To the Scottish his- torian, Mr. W. F. Skene, may be attributed the merit of having shown, by actual demonstration, that this account really reverses the historical order of things. The tribe, or larger unit, is the oldest ; as it breaks up, clans are formed ; and the break up of the clan system leaves as independent units the households formerly comprised within it. Finally, but not till long after patriarchal society has passed away, the household is dissolved, and the individual becomes the unit of society. Supported by evidence of savage society.— This view, put forward by Mr. Skene in his " Celtic Scotland " (vol. iii), has been strengthened, in the most remarkable way, by the discoveries concerning the nature of savage society described in the preceding chapter. By these discoveries it has been proved that the earliest social group, so far from being a small household of a single man and his wives, is a large and loosely connected group or "pack," organized for matrimonial purposes on a very artificial plan, which alto- gether precludes the existence of the "single family." If it 20 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS were necessar>', it could easily be shown that the origin of society in "single families" is inherently impossible; but it is sufficient to point out that the evidence is against it. Origin of the distinction. — Although, however, the author acknowledges his debt to Mr. Skene for the estab- lishment of the true relationship between the tribe and the clan, he is not aware that the causes of the appearance of either have been stated anywhere in brief form. He thinks it better, therefore, even at the risk of anticipating matters a little, to state clearly his own view, which is this : thai the domestication of animals converted the savage pack into the patriarchal tribe ; and that the adoption of agriculture broke up the tribe into clans. Distinguishing marks of patpiapchal society.— If this view be correct, obviously the first thing to do in attempting the story of patriarchal society is to consider the domestication of animals and its immediate results. But, as this will require a chapter to itself, it will be well once more to emphasize the distinction between patriarchal society, and modern or political society, in the strict sense, in order that the reader may realize that he is going to deal with ideas completely foreign to his own. Patriarchal society, then, is distinguished from modem society by four leading qualities. Personal union. — i. It is personal, not territorial. Although, as has been said, the basis of modern society is military allegiance, the great factor which determines that allegiance is residence in a fixed area. Doubtless, for cer- tain purposes, a citizen of State A may reside in the terri- tory of State B ; yet he is looked upon as an alien, and he takes no part in the political life of State B. On the other hand, if a man qualifies as a citizen of a State by residence, we ask no questions about his blood or race. "Everyone born in France is a Frenchman," says the Code Napoleon ; and, broadly speaking, that is the rule in civilized countries at the present day. But patriarchal society cares nothing for PATRIARCHAL SOCIETY IN GENERAL 21 residence or locality. To be a member of a particular group, a man must be of the blood of that group. If he is not, he may pass his whole life in its service, but he will not be a member. In fact, the whole group itself may move its quarters at any time without affecting its constitution in any way. At least, this is so in the earlier stages of patri- archal society. Exclusiveness. — 2. It is exclusive. Modem society believes in large numbers. In spite of certain grumblings about " immigrant aliens," modern States are really anxious to increase their numbers as much as possible, because they know that an increase of numbers means an increase of wealth and of fighting-power. To a community in the patriarchal stage, an Immigration Bureau would appear to be a monstrosity. To its members the immigrant is simply a thief, who comes to stint the pasture and the corn land ; a heathen, who will introduce strange customs and worships. If he is admitted, he is admitted only as a serf or slave. Communal eharaetep. — 3. It is ccmtmunal. In a modern State, the supreme authority deals directly with each individual. Of course there are intermediate authori- ties, but they act only as subordinates or delegates of the supreme power, which can set them aside. But, in patri- archal society, each man is a member of a small group, which is itself a member of a larger group, and so on. And each man is responsible only to the head of his immediate gi'oup — the son, wife or slave to the housefather, the house- father to the head of his clan, the head of the clan to the tribal chief. The practical results of this principle are vitally important, as we shall see later on. No competition. — 4. It is non-competitive. We are accustomed to a state of society in which each man works at what he thinks best, and in the way he thinks best. Sub- ject to certain laws, mostly of a police character, each man "does as he likes." If a farmer thinks he can get a better crop by sowing earher than his neighbours, he does so. If 22 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS a carpenter thinks he can make a better box by using nails where screws have hitherto been employed, he does so. If a draper thinks he can attract customers by selling tea, he does so. But patriarchal society would have looked on such practices with horror. Its life was regulated by fixed custom, to deviate from which was impiety. How this idea arose, and how it gradually disappeared, we must inquire hereafter. At present we must simply bear it in mind in thinking of patriarchal society. In patriarchal society, everj'one found his duties in life prescribed for him ; and not only his duties, but the way in which he should perform them. Any devia- tion from customary rules was looked upon with disfavour. We now come to deal with the great discovery which made patriarchal society possible and inevitable. CHAPTER IV The Domestication of Animals The art of taming wild animals and making them serve the purposes of man is one of the great discoveries of the world. Just as it is quite certain that there are some races, e. g., the Australians, who have never acquired it, so it is equally certain that many other races have learnt it, with results of the greatest importance: But as to the man or men who introduced it, we have no knowledge, except through vague and obviously untrustworthy tradition. Like many of the greatest benefactors of the human race, they remain anonymous. In all probability, the discovery was made independently by many different races, under combi- nations of favourable circumstances. Origin of domestication. — But, if we cannot speak with confidence of names and dates in the matter, we can make certain tolerably shrewd guesses as to the way in which domestication of animals came about. We start with the fact that the most valuable of the world's domestic animals, the sheep, horse, ox, goat, etc., are known to exist, or to have existed, in a wild state. It is practically impossible to suppose that these wild animals are (except in rare cases) the result of the escape from captivity of tame animals. It follows, therefore, that the start which a pack of savages could obtain in the matter of domestication would depend upon the character of the wild animals in its neigh- bourhood. For it is fairly obvious by this time that many wild animals are not suitable for taming. Thus, it is hardly (23) 24 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS possible that tlie lion, tiger or bear will ever really become domestic animals, in spite of the fact that their strength and endurance would prove valuable qualities if they could be used. And so some peoples may have remained utterly savage, because of the fact that their country does not pro- duce animals capable of domestication. Again, some races, like the Eskimos, appear to have had only the wild ancestors of the dog and the reindeer, and thus to have been very limited in their opportunities. Other races have been able to tame the sheep, one of the most valuable aids to civiliza- tion ; others, again, have had the still more valuable ox. Superfluity of game.— But still the question remains — How was the process of domestication discovered ? Here, again, we can only proceed by speculation ; but a most valu- able account of his experiences in Southern Africa (Damara Land), published by the late Sir Francis Galton in the middle of the century, affords us most suggestive hints.* Two of the most striking features of the savage character are recklessness and greed. Being quite unable to make pro- vision for the future, or even to realize the wants of the future, the savage consumes in disgusting orgies the produce of a successful hunt. A stroke of luck, such as the capture of a big herd of game, simply means an opportunity for gorging. But even the savage capacity for food has its limits ; and, in exceptionally good seasons, there is a super- fluity of game. A civilized man would strain every nerve to store the surplus away against future wants. The savage simply wastes it ; partly because he knows that meat will not keep, partly because he cannot realize the needs of the future. The "pemmican" or sun-dried meat of the Red Indian, and his "caches," or buried hoards, are the limits of the savage capacity for storing up against a rainy day. Pets. — But, if the savage is reckless and greedy, he is often affectionate and playful. If he has had as much food ' Narrative of an Explorer in Tropical South Africa." London, 1853 THE DOMESTICATION OF ANIMALS 25 as he can eat, he will amuse himself by playing with his captives, instead of killing them. At first, no doubt, there is a good deal of the cat and the mouse in the relationship ; but, in time, the savage comes positively to love his captives, and even to resist the pangs of hunger rather than kill them. In other words, the earliest domestic animals were pets ; pre- served, not with a view of profit) but for sport or amuse- ment. And it is most important to observe that animals so selected would naturally be the handsomest and finest of the catch, whose appearance would delight the eye. The history of the process is neatly summed up in the two meanings of the English verb "to Hke." In the primitive sense, "to like" means "to like to eat ; " later on, it means "to like to keep," or have by one. "I like mutton," or, "I like my dog."* Food supply. — But, of course, feelings of affection would be bound to give way in the long run to feelings of hunger. And then the tame animals would be slaughtered for food. And so it would ultimately dawn on the savage that the keeping of pets was really a profitable business, because it afforded some protection against /amine. Gradu- ally it would become more and more common. Finally, the savage would learn by experience that, even without destroy- ing them, his pets could be put to valuable use. Thus the wool of sheep, the hair of goats, the milk of cows, would be to a savage like a gift from an unknown Power. Still more, the young of his captives would add to his delight in his possessions ; and his forest lore, his keen observation of the habits of animals in their wild condition, would come in most usefully for his new occupation as a breeder and keeper of flocks and herds. But, when he had got thus far, the savage would have ceased to be a savage ; he would have become a pastoralist. *It has been suggested that the reverence of the savage for his totem may also have had something to do with the preservation o{ animals. 26 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS Results of change. — We must now notice the chief effects upon social arrangements produced by the adoption of pastoral pursuits. Kinship through males.— In the first place, it is not very difficult to see how it would lead to the establishment of kinship through males. In the savage, or hunting stage, the hunting was chiefly done by the men ; the women, though in many cases they took part in the chase, being employed chiefly in carrying weapons, setting traps, and other sub- ordinate offices. Their real tasks were to mind camp, dress the food, and, what has always and inevitably been woman's work, to look after the children. Quite naturally, though not, perhaps, very justly, the superfluous animals which were left over after the hunger of the camp had been satisfied, were looked upon as connected in some special way with the man who had captured them. And he, therefore, would have the training and management of them ; and, in course of time, they would come to be looked upon as his property. In speculations as to the origin of the important institution of property, it is often said that capture is the first title to ownership. This is hardly true ; for accounts of savage so- cieties generally show that the captured animals, so far as they are required for food, are treated as the common stock of the camp. But, when the claims of hunger have been satisfied, the actual captors are allowed to retain the re- mainder as pets ; and, as they become fonder and fonder of them, they resent more and more any interference with them by other people. It is just what happens with children, who are, in many respects, very like savages. What a child thinks of is not, hoiu the toys came there, but who uses them. "I always play with this doll, so it is mine." That is the feeling of the savage for his ox or sheep. Pastoral pupsuits.— And then, as all the advantages of the rearing of animals come to be realized, the savage "pack" gradually changes into a society of shepherds or herdsmen, in which the men are engaged in tending cattle, THE DOMESTICATION OF ANIMALS 27 sheep, or goats, while to the women fall the subordinate offices of spinning the wool, milking the cows and goats, and making the butter and cheese. The men drive the flocks to pasture and water, regulate the breeding, guard the folds against enemies, decide which of the animals shall be killed for food, and break in the beasts of burden. Value of labour.— But in these tasks it gradually be- comes apparent to the men that labour is a valuable thing. A man who has been very successful in cattle-rearing re- quires a number of "hands" to keep his herds in order. Besides the domestic labour performed by women, he requires the outdoor labour of men, to prevent the cattle from straying or being stolen, to drive them to pasture in the morning and bring them back at night. To this demand for labour we probably owe two of the great institutions of the pastoral age : permanent marriage and slavery. There is really, as we shall see, nothing out of place in taking these two together, odd as the connection may sound to modem ears. Permanent maPFiage has been alluded to before as one of the essential features of patriarchal society. By superficial writers its appearance is often attributed to some vague improvement in morality or taste. Unhappily, the facts point to a much less exalted origin ; viz., the desire of the man to secure for himself exclusively the labour of the woman and her offspring. If the change had come about from exalted ideas of morality, we should probably have found two features in the new system — (i) equality of num- bers between the man and the woman ; (2) free consent to the marriage on both sides. It is notorious that just the op- posite are the facts of the patriarchal system, at any rate at its earlier stages. Polygamy, or plurality of wives, is the rule ; and, while the husband is not at all particular about the conduct of his wife with other men, he is intensely strict about appropriating the whole of her labour ; and all her offspring, no matter who is the real father, belong to him. a8 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS Again, the ancient forms of marriage ; viz., marriage by capture and marriage by purchase, point irresistibly to the conclusion that the woman had little or no voice in the matter. In the case of marriage by capture, the husband carried oflf his wife by force from a neighbouring tribe ; and, long after the reality of this practice has disappeared, it sur- vives, as is well known, in a fictitious form all over the world. It is considered barely decent for the girl to come to the marriage without a show of force. Even in polite modern society the "best man" is said to be a survival of the friends who went with the bridegroom in ancient days to help him to carry off his bride, while the bridesmaids are the lady's companions, who attempted to defend her from the audacious robber, and the wedding tour is a survival of the flight from the angry relatives of the bride. In the more peaceful form of marriage hy purchase, the lady has become an article of marketable value, whose price is paid, usually in cattle or sheep, to her relatives or owners. It is a refine- ment of modern days that the "bride-price" should be settled on the lady herself, or contributed, in the form of marriage gifts, to stock the future home. In ancient times it was paid, if not in hard cash, at any rate in solid cattle, to the damsel's relatives, who, by the marriage, lost the value of her services. Jacob, we know, paid for his wives by labour ; but this was probably an exception. In patriarchal society, the father of a round dozen of strong and well- favoured daughters is a rich man. Slavery arises from the practice of keeping alive captives taken in war, instead of putting them to death. In savage days, wars are usually the result of scarcity of food, and, as was pointed out previously (p. 14), result in the killing and eating of members of a stranger "pack." But, with the increasing certainty of food supply, resulting among other benefits from pastoral pursuits, cannibalism becomes unnec- essary, and captives are carefully kept alive, in order that they may labour for their captors. It may sound odd to THE DOMESTICATION OF ANIMALS 29 speak of slavery as a beneficent institution, but one of the first lessons which the student of history has to learn is, that things which to us now seem very wicked may have really been at one time improvements on something much worse. Slavery is an ugly thing, but it is better than cannibalism. Again, however, we notice that the upward step was due, not to exalted morality, but to practical convenience. Morality is the result, not the cause, of social amelioration. The pastoral tribe.— Thus we have seen that pastoral pursuits have converted the savage "pack," with its loose system of association and marriage, into the pastoral tribe with its fixed marriages and its relationship based strictly on kinship through males. The woman leaves her own tribe or household, and becomes a member of that of her husband. The clumsy expedients of capture and purchase are resorted to in order to continue the instinct, developed (as we have seen) in the savage period, which forbids intermarriage be- tween near relations. The precise distance of relationship required probably settles whether the woman is to be cap- tured from a neighbouring tribe or bought from another household of the same tribe. And this rule probably varies according to circumstances. But in either case the husband is the sole authority in the household. His wives, children, slaves and animals are under his absolute control, and all stand pretty much on the same footing. Mode of transition. — The precise steps in the mo- mentous change from the loose marital relationship of sav- ages to the definite (if somewhat brutal) institution of the pastoral household are very hard to trace. The process has been very ingeniously suggested by the late Mr. Robertson Smith in his " Kinship and Marriage in Early Arabia,'' where the author points out the clear traces among the patriarchal Arabs of the former existence of a savage state of society. It is there suggested that the existence of a long condition of war and disturbance would have had a similar result, by drawing together the fighting males into groups for military 30 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS purposes, each male jealously guarding; his own women and children. But there are inseparable difficulties in the way of such an explanation. The patriarchal household would have been the last thing that a warrior would have cared to en- cumber himself with ; and times of military license are hardly times in which the permanence of the marriage tie is developed. On the whole, it seems tolerably certain that the budding institution of property has been the main factor in creating the patriarchal tribe and family. Our very word "family" is said to be derived from an old Italian word fainel, meaning "slave." Other results of pastoral pursuits.— To conclude this chapter, we may just hastily mention one or two other important contributions made to the progress of civilization by the domestication of animals. Obviously it would tend largely to increase numbers and to improve physique, by the greater abundance and regularity of food supply and the in- crease of clothing and shelter. But also it would have the important effect of differentiating in strength and impor- tance one tribe from another, and one family from another. Savages are, in the main, very much alike ; one savage tribe is a good deal like another. But circumstances of climate, and skill in breeding and rearing animals, would soon pro- duce differences in the pastoral age. One tribe would become wealthy, while another would remain poor. Even in the same tribe some households would become richer than others, according as, by superior strength or skill, one housefather acquired more cattle than another. Early Irish society was elaborately organized into classes, which dis- tinguished between the ordinary freemen {NcmS) and the rich cattle owners {Boaire), and between the various degrees of wealth among the latter. And the primitive uniformity of membership ultimately became quite broken up by the practice, adopted by the rich Boaire, of lending their super- fluous cattle to the poorer tribesmen in return for rents or regular payments, as well as /eastings or occasional enter- THE DOMESTICATION OF ANIMALS 31 tainments of the cattle-owner, who visited his borrower from time to time, no doubt under the pretence of seeing how his cattle were getting on. New ideas. — Once more, the domestication of animals is responsible for two very important ideas, without which civilized society could not hold together in its present form. These are the ideas of profit and capital. The former is now looked upon as the net gain in any commercial trans- action. Originally it was the offspring of domestic animals. The household which had a dozen goats in one year might find itself, without any further captures, in possession of twenty in the following. The idea gradually spread, and all modem industry is based on it. Again, even if there were no births in his flock, the pastoralist would find that, at any rate for a time, he could go on living on the produce of his animals, the milk of goats and cows, the wool of sheep, without reducing his numbers. This discovery would tend very powerfully to induce him to save his animals, i. e., not to slaughter them, in order that they might produce constant income. That is precisely what we mean by the term capital. It is wealth saved to produce future wealth. But there was no room for these great ideas in savage society. They are the direct outcome of pastoral pursuits. So we see that the lazy and overfed savage, who amused himself by taming and petting his superfluous captive animals, was really beginning a revolution in the world's history. It is rather curious that the power of taming new animals seems to be almost extinct among civilized men. Is this because all the tamable animals have been tamed, or because civilized man has become so unlike wild animals that he has lost the art of understanding them ? CHAPTER V Tribal Organization Wb now come to deal with the way in which society organizes itself to satisfy the requirements of this pastoral existence which we have tried to describe. And, in dealing with this subject, by preference we will borrow our illustra- tions from the Keltic peoples of the British Islands, who, untiJ comparatively recent times, occupied the patriarchal stage, and from those subjects of our Indian Empire, such as the natives of the Panjab, who, even at the present day, afford most valuable opportunities for the study of patri- archal institutions. Occasionally we may refer to other examples, such as the Homeric Greeks, the ancient Romans, the Maoris of New Zealand and the Arabs, in order to broaden our horizon, and to realize how widely spread is this phase of development. But we shall gain in vividness by keeping close to one model. The tPibe. — In society of the patriarchal type the im- portant group is, as we have said, the tribe, or body of people believing themselves to be descended strictly in the male line from some far-off ancestor. We say "believing themselves," advisedly; for if our account of the origin of the tribe be correct, the rule of male succession only de\'eloped after the group had been in existence, perhaps for thousands of years. But the intense belief in the exist- ence from the beginning of the so-called agnatic* rule of •The term is derived from Roman Law, which contrasted agnatio, or connection through male ancestors, with cognatio or ordinary blood relationship. (32) TRIBAL ORGANIZATION 33 succession, is evidenced by the amusing attempts of the tribesmen themselves to discover a single male ancestor, or, as he is called by scientific writers, an eponym, for their tribe. Thus, we find the chroniclers of British history deriving the descent of their tribe from Brutus of Troy, the grandson of ^neas ; the Cymry of Strathclyde are, in an early document, said to be all descended from one Coel Hen, whose name is supposed to survive in various place names in Ayrshire ; each of the Teutonic tribes which settled in Britain alleged its descent from the Scandinavian hero Odin ; the Behichis of the Panjab profess to be the offspring of Mir Hamzah, an uncle of the prophet Mahomet ; while the Pathans of the same neighbourhood claim descent from Saul, the first king of Israel ! Membership of the tPibe.— Such being the importance attached to male kinship, it is not surprising to discover that, in tribal society, no one can be regarded as a full member of the tribe unless he is the lawful child of a full tribesman. Such a person is alone entitled, as of right, to a share in the tribal possessions ; he alone can take part in the religious ceremonies of the tribe. But, as a matter of fact, all patriarchal tribes are found to have living among them considerable numbers of strangers, who, though separated by a great gulf from the full tribesmen, yet rank in various degrees of social importance. There are, for example, the mere "strangers," the Fiiidhir (as the Irish called them), the Alltiids (as they are called by the Welsh Laws), who appear to be broken men from other tribes, adopted or protected on more or less hospitable terms. Along with these, probably, go the offspring of the tribes- women through marriages with such resident strangers. Occasionally, in return for very great services, or after a residence of many generations, such persons are fully adopted into the tribe. Serfs. — Then there were the various degrees of serfs or bondmen ; for, as we have said, pastoral society was anxious 34 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS to secure cheap labour. These were, probably, the results of forays upon neighbouring tribes, or people whom we should call "convicts," who had become such through failure to pay compensation for injuries committed by them, according to the system to be afterwards explained. These aervile persons were either employed as herdsmen or (some- what later) as farm-labourers, such as the Sencleithe of Ireland, or the Tceogs of Wales ; or they were treated as domestic slaves {Bothachs or Caeths). Ranks within the tplbe.— But it must not be supposed that, even among the full tribesmen, equality of ranks was the rule. True it is that every free tribesman was entitled to his share of the grazing land, to his hunting in the waste, to his oath of kindred (i. e., the protection of his immediate relatives), and to his armour. But it is probable, as we have said (p. 26), that, from the very first, the chief wealth of the tribe; viz., its cattle and sheep, its camels and goats, were looked upon as individual property ; and the tribesman who was not fortunate enough to inherit or to capture a stock of these was in a somewhat unenviable position. As the Irish Laws put it, he was only a Fer Midba, or "inferior man," not a Boaire, or "lord of cattle." In fact, he was very much in the position of the modern "free" workman, who often finds that his boasted freedom means freedom to starve. The nobles. — In this state of things he very frequently resorted to an e.xpedient which is intensely interesting, as being the earliest development of an institution which was destined to play such a large part in the world's history: the institution of landlordism. Only it was not, in these early days, applied to land, which was not regarded as capable of appropriation by individuals, but to cattle. The rich Boaire loaned some of his cattle to the poor Fer Midba, who agreed to take some of them for a certain period, and to pay an annual Bestigi or food rent, being part of the produce, and to feast the Boaire and his friends a certain number of times TRIBAL ORGANIZATION 35 in the year. Having the right to feed a certain number of cattle on the tribal land, the borrower of cattle (or Ceile, as he was called) could probably make enough to live on out of the transaction. If he had some cattle of his own, he was called a Saer Ceile, or free tenant ; but, if his whole herd was borrowed, he became the Daer Ceile of the owner ; not, technically, an unfree man, but a man in a very inferior position. Degrees of nobility. — Among the rich men, or nobles, of the tribe, there were also many social degrees, according to their wealth ; these, however, are not of great impor- tance, except in relation to the system of blood fines, of which we shall say something later. Officials of the tribe.— But, besides these divisions into free and unfree, nobles and ordinary freemen, the tribe had a very important official organization. I. The Chief, who was understood to represent the founder of the tribe, and who was usually the oldest male in a particular branch. Messrs. Spencer and Gillen have pointed out that among the Australians, whom we have taken as our types of savage society, there is nothing that can be called a chieftainship, though there are, doubtless, often certain individuals who, from their physical strength or supposed wisdom, have great influence. But in patriarchal society, there is always a representative of the tribe. The Irish call him a Ri, the Welsh a Pen, the Scotch a Mormaer, the Teutonic tribes a Cyning (whence our "king"), the Bilijches a Tumanddr, the Pathans a Khan. He was heredi- tary, not in our sense, but in the sense that the eldest male An the privileged line was entitled to the office, unless dis- qualified by feebleness or disease. The Welsh Laws pictur- esquely describe him as "the oldest efficient man in the kindred to the ninth descent, and a chief of household ; " and they go on to enumerate his duties thus : — (a) He must speak on behalf of his kin, and be lis- tened to ; 36 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS (5) He must fight on behalf of his kin, and be feared ; (c) He must give security on behalf of his kin, and be accepted. In other words, he must be eloquent, brave, and honest ; and if a candidate for the position did not manifest these qualities he might be set aside. This is probably all that is meant by certain writers, when they say that the tribal chief is "elective." Of course it was long before the days of votes and ballot-boxes. But, by an arrangement which shows a good deal of wis- dom, some patriarchal tribes do not wait until the death of a chief before accepting his successor. Amongst many of them there is — 2. An Heip-AppaPent, called by the Irish the Tanist, by the Welsh the Teisbanteuleu, who is the person who will next succeed to the chieftainship, in the ordinary way, after the death of the existing chief. After the break-up of the tribes into clans or septs in Ireland, this practice continued in the smaller bodies ; and it was its existence which did more than anything else to scandalize the Elizabethan statesmen who tried to bring the Irish to English notions. In Russia, the institution lingered for a long while in the person of the Veliki Kniaz, or Gravid Prince, the eldest male of the house of Rurik, the chief of the Varangian or Norman tribe which conquered Russia in the ninth century. Still longer it con- tinued to be a feature of the Holy Roman Empire, which, in addition to its head, or Emperor, had of right also his destined successor, the " King of the Romans." During the life-time of the chief, the heir-apparant acted as his deputy, and was, so to speak, " learning the business." 3. The Champion. — This person, called among the Irish and Scotch a Toisech, among the Welsh a Dialwr (or "avenger"), among the Teutonic tribes a Heretoch (or "host-leader"), is very interesting, both on account of his ultimate destiny, as well as because he is an early instance of what is called " specialization of functions." Originally, as TRIBAL ORGANIZATION 37 we have seen, the hereditary chief was also the head warrior of the tribe. But, as the chief was hereditary, it would often happen, in spite of the power of rejection claimed by the tribe, that the chief was unsuccessful as an actual warrior. He might be wise and venerable, much respected and loved, but no soldier. In times of stress the tribe would naturally turn to one of its members who had shown great bravery and skill in fighting, and, by a sort of informal election, ap- point him to lead them in battle, much as the Romans did, at a much later stage, with their Dictator. Apparently, after this event had occurred two or three times, the champion or head warrior became a recognized insiitutio7i. All these three officials, the Chief, the Heir- Apparent, and the Champion, seem to have been provided for by the en- dowment of special rights in the tribal land, by an extra share of the booty captured by the tribe on its plundering ex- peditions, and by customary presents made on certain days of the year by the members of their tribes. The first of these three privileges is of special importance in the History of Politics. 4. The Council, or group of seniors, called by the Irish Brehons, by the Welsh Henadwr, by the Teutons Rachim- burgs, by the Mahommedan inho^sjirgah, and by the Hindus Panchdyat. This seems to have been a body of persons gradually formed from the heads of the subordinate gp-oups in the tribe, by a process which we shall have to explain in dealing with the formation of clans. Its great function was to record the custom of the tribe, and regulate its cere- monies and religion. It was, obviously, a most necessary institution after the tribe had become numerous, and in days which could boast no written records. It is most interesting as the germ of future constitutional government, and may be regarded, historically, as the mother of Law Courts, Cabi- nets, and even of Parliaments. Sometimes, as amongst the Welsh, and some of the Teutonic tribes, it seems to have consisted of a small number (seven) ; at others it was ob- 38 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS viously larger, and may have consisted of all the heads of households within the tribe. Later on, its members appear to have developed individual functions, as pedigree-keepers (called by the Irish and Scotch Synnar/iies), priests (possibly, among the Welsh, Druids), medicine men, and so on. But it is with the elders as a body or cauncil, that we are most concerned : and the mention of it brings us to the considera- tion of two closely connected topics; viz., Tribal Religion and Tribal Law, with an account of which this chapter may fitly end. Tribal Religion is a striking testimony to the truth of the view previously quoted (p. 12), that the second stage of religious thought is that in which Man worships as his gods beings who are, or have been, men like himself, who are, in fact, his deceased ancestors. Ancestor worship, which, even at the present day, is the religion of multitudes of the human race, especially in the East, seems to arise from two sources. The one is a profound belief in the existence of the spirit world, in which the dead live and move as in life ; and which may, therefore, be fairly claimed as a crude form of belief in the immortality of the soul. The second is the profound deference to parental authority rendered during life to the head of the patriarchal household, and which, after his death, takes the form of ceremonial worship. In its more cruel shape, this worship is celebrated with sacrifices, either by way of vengeance upon the men who have caused, or are supposed to have caused, the death of the ancestor, or by way of providing him with comforts in the spirit-land. In its more refined form, it is a continuance of domestic worship, as exhibited, for example, in the picturesque ceremonial of the offerings of cake and water, the sacrificial meal and the commemoration hymns, of the Code of Manu and other Hindu rituals. The centre of ancestor worship is \.\\Q/amity hearth, with its sacred fire and solemn festivities ; and its continued practice is thus calculated to keep alive, in the most vivid way, that spirit of kinship which is the very TRIBAL ORGANIZATION 39 essence of patriarchal society. It may, perhaps, be doubted whether ancestor worship plays quite such an important part in the daily life of the Hindu as the Sacred Books would lead us to believe ; but it is undoubted that its existence ac- counts for much that is otherwise obscure, not only in Oriental Society, but in the history of the early Greeks and Romans. Readers who are interested in pursuing this line of thought may be advised to consult the late Mr. Fustel de Coulanges' famous book "La Cit^ Antique;" here it will be sufficient to state, by way of contrast, two or three of the leading features in which the ancestor worship of patriarchal society differs from religion as understood by the modem world. 1. It is not proselytizing.— The great religions of the modem world — Christianity, Mohammedanism, even Buc^- dhism — profess to be of universal application, and their mis sionaries seek to make converts in all lands. To an ances- tor worshipper such a course would appear not merely ridiculous, but positively treacherous. His gods are for him and his kindred alone; he looks to them for favour and pro- tection, as one of their devout descendants. How could strangers possibly have any share in their worship? As a consequence, the patriarchal man who wandered away from his kindred found himself not only among strange people, but among strange gods. To him, expulsion from the tribe meant the break up of religious as well as social ties. An Englishman of the present day who settles in France, Ger- many, Italy or Spain, enters a place of worship, and finds the same God worshipped, under slightly different forms and in a different tongue (unless he be a Catholic), but by wor- shippers of the same faith. To an ancestor worshipper, such an experience would seem incredible. 2. It is not theological. — That is to say, it does not profess to account for the origin and constitution of the uni- verse. No doubt the patriarchal man had certain crude ways of explaining the existence of the world and its con- 40 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS tents. But these were not part of his religion. It was not until the later speculative spirit, introduced into Europe by the Greeks, attempted to link intellectual belief with religious duty, that the modern kind of religion began. Even then, as we learn from more than one passage in the New Testa- ment,* concerning "meats oflfered to idols," some of the early Christian converts considered it quite possible to com- bine an intellectual acceptance of Christianity with a con- tinuance of their ancestral rites. Ancestor worship, in fact, was a purely practical religion, imposing a code of duties on its followers, but making no demands upon their belief. 3. It Is secpet. — The view that their ancestors belonged to them alone naturally made the tribesmen very jealous of strangers acquiring any knowledge of their forms of worship. Consequently, the most rigid care was taken by each tribe, and, after the tribe split up into sections, by each section, to prevent a knowledge of these ceremonies leaking out; and many of the most dramatic stories of ancient history turn upon the vengeance taken upon interlopers who had succeeded in penetrating the mysteries of religious celebra- tions. In each household, the particulars of its sacred rites were passed on from father to son in the greatest secrecy. The secrets of the tribe were in the custody of the elders or wise men, who, in somewhat more advanced times, formed themselves into hereditary bodies, or colleges, for their preservation and practice. The very existence of the tribe was believed to depend upon the safeguarding of these mysteries ; and, if a disaster happened, one of the readiest suggestions to account for the mishap was that the ancestors were offended, because "strange fire" had been offered on their altar. Tribal Law.— Closely connected with Tribal Religion, in fact originally part of it, was Tribal Law. One of the direct results of ancestor worship was a religious adherence *E. g., Acts XV. 29. TRIBAL ORGANIZATION 41 to ancestral custom: that is, to the practices observed in life by the revered ancestors. And this was the main idea of Law, as conceived by patriarchal society. The notion of Law as the command of an absolute ruler, whether an individual or a body, was yet far in the future. Law was not a thing to be fnade, but a thing to be discovered. The old savage notion of taboo, which, as we saw, was purely negative, had been largely superseded by the positive notion of custom. What was customary was right, what was uncustomary was wrong. The desperate tenacity with which patriarchal society clung to a practice, merely because it was a practice, is illustrated, among hundreds of other examples, by the well- known Roman custom of examining the entrails of victims to ascertain the prospects of an expedition. Originally, no doubt, it was a practical expedient adopted by the nomad tribes from which the Romans were descended, in their wanderings through unknown country. To test the fitness for food of the new herbs with which they came into contact, they caused a few of their cattle and sheep to eat them, and then, by a sort of rude post-mortem, judged of the result. The real origin of customs is often very hard, however, to discover. Sometimes it seems to have been mere accident. The ingenious account of the origin of roast sucking pig, given by Charles Lamb in his well-known Essay, though intended by him as a joke, may really be a brilliant guess at the truth. In other cases, no doubt, an exceptionally able man deliberately made an innovation, which was afterwards copied by others, as it was found to be useful. But such enterprise must have been very dangerous. The first man who drank the milk of his cow probably paid for his luxury with his life. In patriarchal society, innovation and crime are almost co-incident. So little, indeed, is deliberate de- parture from custom anticipated, that there seems to be no regular punishment for it. The chief or elders will declare the custom ; that is, or ought to be, sufficient. But if an offender persists in his impiety, the outraged community will 42 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS banish him from its ranks. In the expressive language of the Welsh Laws, he will be a " kin-shattered man," an outlaw, in fact. If the tribe lives near the sea he will probably be set adrift on an open raft ; this was the method with the South Welsh. Other codes speak of turning the offender " into the forest." In either case, the result would be much the same. The blood feud. — For injuries to individual fellow- tribesmen, the universal remedy was the lex talionis, admin- istered by the blood feud. Barbarous as such an institution seems to us, it is probably one of the most important steps ever taken towards civilization. A man is killed. Instead of the murder producing indiscriminate slaughter, it gives rise to an ordered scheme of vengeance conducted by the immediate relatives of the slain man against the murderer and his immediate relatives. If there be any doubt about the facts, certain rough tests are applied, which to us would appear very unsatisfactory. The accused brings a certain number of his relatives to swear to his innocence, or some rude sort of ordeal is used.* If the accused is deemed guilty, the feud goes on, unhappily for a very long time. Blood fines. — A great step further is taken, when, for the right of vengeance is substituted the payment of compen- sation. The circumstances of pastoral society permit of this. The existence of cattle and sheep form a standard of value, by which the life of a man can be measured. Starting with the simple idea that a man is worth what he owns, and taking the ordinary free tribesman as the unit, the tribe sets up an elab- orate scale of money fines (the eric of the Irish, the galanas of the Welsh, the cro of the Scotch, the wer of the Teutons), carefully graduated according to ( i ) the importance of the injured party, (2) the extent of the damage. Apparently, ♦One of these probably survives, in backward countries, to the present day. Each of the mourners touches the body at a funeral. The ancient belief was that if the touch was that of the murderer the corpse would bleed afresh. TRIBAL ORGANIZATION 43 the proceedings begin as before. The marks on the dead man's body are examined, the bloody weapon is traced, the trail of the stolen cattle is followed until it leads to the thief's hut ; and then, just as the feud is going to begin, the elders intervene and urge the acceptance of a fine. At first, it would seem, the acquiescence of the injured party is volun- tary. Until quite late in history, the ultimate right to battle cannot be denied. But every effort is made by the elders to induce the parties to "swear the peace." In the world-wide habit of shaking hands, we probably have a dim survival of a practice insisted upon by the early peace-makers, as a guarantee that the parties would not use weapons against one another, at least till all other remedies had been tried. For if the hand is clasped in another's, it can hardly strike a blow. No grenepal rules of Tribal Law.— It is obvious from what has been said that, while we may describe the general character of Tribal Law, no enumeration of its rules can be made. Each tribe has its own Law, binding only upon members of its own tribe. General principles will, no doubt, be found running through it all ; inheritance in the male line, prohibition of marriage outside the tribe (or inside, as the case may be), relationship of classes, rights in pasture land, and so on. But in details these will differ from tribe to tribe, and even in branches of the same tribe. The investiga- tions of the British Settlement Officers show, for example, that there are at least several hundred different systems in force in the British Panjab alone, though the population of that country is a little less than the population of England. Long before there is a Law of the Land, there is a Law of the Tribe ; and by his own Law alone will a tribesman con- sent to rule his actions. CHAPTER VI Agriculture and the Clan Origin of agPieultUPe.— As in the case of the taming of wild animals, so in the case of tilling the ground, we are left in the dark as to the benefactor who first made the priceless discovery. Such scanty legends as exist on the subject are evidently the work of later times, or refer to an importation rather than to a discovery of the secret. But, if we have no evidence on the subject, it is one on which we may fairly indulge in scientific speculation. Although the Australian aboriginals know nothing of agriculture, they gather the seeds of a wild plant known as iiardoo, and, after bruising them in a rude mortar, make them into cakes. Let us suppose, in some country endowed with greater natural wealth than central Australia, that a pack of savages, having gathered a greater store of wild seeds than it could possibly consume, buried the surplus in some earth-heap or mound, and left it in the summer camp till the return of spring. Suppose an unusually wet winter, or an exceptionally early spring. Returning to its summer quarters, the pack might well discover that the stored-up grains had sprouted and assumed something like the shape in which they had known the ears when they had gathered them in the forest the previous autumn. .Such an object- lesson would hardly be lost, even on the savage mind. The same thing might well happen to the wild yams or other edible roots which are some of the earliest food of man. Charaetep of agpieulture. — Whenever the savage (44) AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 45 had begun to act upon the idea this suggested, agricuhure, in its most primitive form, would have come into existence. The rest was only a question of time. And it is quite pos- sible that agriculture, in a ver>' imperfect form, was prac- ticed as early as pastoral pursuits, at least in the majority of cases. But it is not difficult to see why agriculture takes rank as a development of human industry distinctly later than the tending of cattle and sheep. It is very much more laborious ; and man, especially primitive man, has no love of work for its own sake. Compared with the hard toil of the husbandman, the life of the shepherd is easy and enjoy- able. The capture and breaking-in of wild animals is, to the savage nature, a fascinating task ; the one gratifies his love of excitement, the other amuses his hours of idleness. Even the driving abroad of flocks and herds to daily pasture is no exacting task. The milking, the dressing of skins, and the spinning and weaving of the pastoralist's life are chiefly done by the women and children. But the primitive curse is upon the tiller of the soil : " in the sweat of thy face shalt thou eat bread." Reasons for its adoption. — Agriculture, therefore, remains for ages, even after its rudiments are known, a mere supplementary pursuit, practiced for the purpose of pro- viding a few luxuries, rather than the substantial occupation of Man. It is not adopted on a large scale till the increase of population (always the result of a step forward in civiliza- tion) begins to press upon the means of subsistence. One of the most striking facts about agriculture is that, though its service is hard, its produce is infinitely greater than that of pasturage. A learned German writer. Dr. August Meitzen, who has devoted his life to the study of questions connected with land settlement, calculates that an area which, used as a cattle-run, will maintain one hundred people, will, if brought under the plough, feed three or four times that number, and leave a substantial margin over. Probably the practice of agriculture, on a large scale, began in the Delta 46 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS of the Nile and the Mesopotamian countries, where the barren desert afforded little pasturage for cattle, but the rich alluvial valleys of the great rivers rendered agriculture easy and profitable. From thence it spread through Asia Minor, northwards and westwards, till it became known throughout Europe, and was gradually adopted as the needs of the population demanded it. When Cassar says of the Germans that they do not "study" agriculture,* he probably does not mean that they had never heard of it, but that they found it easier to satisfy themselves with milk, cheese and flesh, the produce of pastoral pursuits. There is a very interesting passage in the "Book of the Abbey of Clonmacnoise," which tells of Ireland that "there was not ditch nor fence nor stone wall round land till came the period of the sons of Aed Slane (seventh century A. D. ), but smooth fields. Because of the abundance of the households in their period, therefore it is that they introduced boundaries in Ireland.'''' Some writers (e. g., Mr. Seebohm) take this passage to refer to the breaking-up of open arable fields into small enclosed holdings. But there seems little doubt that what the chronicler is really referring to is the general adoption of agriculture in the place of pasturage, because of the abun- dance of the households. There is, in fact, plenty of evidence to prove that Ireland was once a purely pastoral country. Early methods of agriculture. — But we must not suppose that the adoption of agriculture meant the adoption, all at once, of farming as we understand it. Perhaps it will be interesting to give a hasty sketch of the different stages through which the cultivation of the ground has passed. Afterwards we may pass to the still more important subject of the results of the adoption of agriculture. I. Forest clearings. — The beginnings of agriculture nearly always involved clearing the ground, for the simple reason that the most fertile land is sure to be covered with , *"AgricuUur8e non student." ( De Bello Gallico, vi. ai.) AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 47 the rank growth of ages. Doubtless, much land had already been cleared for pasture ; but people are unwilling to sacrifice this for the apparently uncertain prospects of harvest. Sometimes the forest is cleared by burning, the ashes being used as a sort of primitive manure, and the seed being simply thrown in and left to come up with the forest weeds. In other places, the axe is used, and the ground, when cleared, broken up with the mattock, or primitive hoe, which seems to have been an early modifica- tion of the savage's digging-stick. Extensive cultivation. — The ground thus cleared is cropped year after year, until one of the fundamental laws of nature begins to assert itself ; viz., that a repetition of the same crop on the smne land tends to produce barrenness. The returns are less and less each year, till the ground is abandoned in despair (probably being deemed accursed), and a new patch is taken into cultivation. This agriculture is technically called extensive, and is, of course, very ex- travagant, both in labour and land. 2. Field-grass system. — Although the clearings are thus abandoned for purposes of sowing, they act as a sort of rough pasture, or fallow, for the cattle of the community, who pick up a scanty subsistence from the shoots and weeds remaining after the reaping of the last crop. In tropical countries, such as India, and even in subtropical lands, such as the fertile districts of southern Australia, abandoned patches speedily become again converted into "jungle" or "bush," and explorers of later generations are startled to find, in the depths of the forest, traces which point indis- putably to the existence of former cultivation.* Alternations of CFop and fallow.— But, in temperate zones, the land is not covered again with trees, and, after the newly-reclaimed patches have been themselves ex- hausted, the tribesmen return to their old patches and * No doubt this fact accounts for a good many of the so-called " dis- coveries of pre-historic races." 48 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS plough these again, to save tliemselves the trouble of fur- ther clearing. Then is discovered another great secret of Nature; viz., that, though successive crops of the same kind will exhaust a piece of land, yet, if that same piece is left to lie fallow for a time, it will recover its fertility. This discover}' lead? directly to — 3. The two-field system, in which the community keeps two distinct patches of land at work, sowing one in each alternate year, and leaving the other to lie fallow. This .system of agriculture is widely prevalent in backward coun- tries at the present day. 4. The three-field system. — This, which is really an improved variety of the last system, is due to the still further discovery that, although a continuation of the same crop on the same piece of land exhausts it very quickly, an alterna- tion of crops will not exhaust it so quickly. The plan is, therefore, to have three fields and two different crops going on at once, the third field lying fallow once in every three years, instead of once in every two. Thus, in a course of three years — 1st year— Field A = oats B = beans C = fallow and " — " B = oats C = beans A = fallow 3rd " — " C = oats A ^ beans B = fallow and so on for each triennial period. Question between the two-field and the three- field system. — The advantages of this plan, in the in- creased variety of crops, was early perceived ; but, for a long time, people preferred to work it with the two-field system, by dividing the ploughed field each year into two parts. In fact, they were afraid that the other s\'stem would require too much ploughing. During the later Middle Ages this was a "burning question" in western Europe. But the three-field people won the day, as they were bound to do; and their argument is so triumphant and so neat that it is worth while to set it out. We take first an imaginary area of 180 acres, divided into two fields, one of which lies fallow AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 49 every year, while the other is partly under oats and partly under beans or peas. Thus — A (90 acres). B (90 acres). A I. (45 acres.) Bi. (45 acres.) A 2. (45 acres.) B 2. (45 acres.) Now take an imaginary course during any one year. September. Plough A i , and sow oats = 45 acres March. Plough As, and sow beans = 45 acres June. Plough B (whole) twice* and leave fallow =j8o acres Total ploughing 270 acres Now take the same area divided into three fields. A (60 acres). B (60 acres). C (60 acres). Again a year's ploughing : September. Plough A and sow oats = 60 acres March. Plough B and sow beans = 60 acres June. Plough C twice, and leave fallow . . = 120 acres Total 240 acres ♦This is necessary after the crop, to get rid of stubble. D go A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS i. e., actually 30 acres less of ploughing. But that is not aO. For, if we look back we see that, if we have worked our lands on the two-field system, we have only harvested the crops of 90 acres ; but, if we have used the three-field sys- tem, we have taken the produce of 120 acres. Thus, the three-field system beats the two-field, hands down ; and it is not surprising to find that, in medieval Europe, it became the rule in the most progressive countries, and developed a regular set of names. Thus, in England, the autumn- sowing was called the iilth grain, the spring sowing the eich grain, and the idle field the fallow ; and there are corresponding terms in many other countries. 5. Convertible husbandry. — The three-field system reigned supreme in western Europe, until, at a compara- tively recent date, it was abandoned in favour of a still more economical plan, by which fallows are practically abolished, and, by a great increase in the number and variety of crops, and the use of artificial manures, the land is never (in good hands) allowed to get exhausted. This change, which came about in England in the eighteenth centur>', and which was greatly due to special circumstances, such as the Dutch connection and war prices, is, however, closely connected with an important change, not merely in the methods, but in the orgatiizalion of agriculture, that is to say, in the institu- tions by means of which agriculture is worked.* To this we must now turn our attention. Organization of agpieulture. — At the end of the Middle Ages (as we call them), that is to say, when the revival of learning in Europe and the Reformation began to break up the old order of things, the typical agricultural unit, not only throughout Europe, but among the vast popu- lations of India, Egypt and Persia, was the village or town- ship. At first sight, a village appears to be merely a collec- ♦All these five stages of agricultural method may be observed at work in Sweden at the present day. AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 51 tion of farmers and labourers, cultivating pieces of land which happen to be near together. And such, in fact, the modern village of western Europe generally is. The In- habitants are, in fact, merely neighbours, nothing more. But the medieval village was a great deal more ; and the differ- ence is usually expressed by describing it as a village com- munity. There has been a good deal of nonsense talked about the village community, as if it necessarily meant a socialistic group of people, who do their work and hold the proceeds in common. Such an assertion cannot possibly be made of historical times. Whatever may be our view of the origin of the medieval village, it is quite clear that, in his- torical times, we have practically no evidence of an agricul- tural group (larger than a single household) cultivating its field in common and dividing the proceeds. So far as our evidence goes, each farmer has his own land, and reaps and stores his own harvest. Nevertheless, there is a real mean- ing in the phrase village community, and we shall best bring out that meaning by enumerating half a dozen points in which the average village of the sixteenth century differed from the average English (or French or German) village of the nineteenth century. 1. Open fields. — In the first place, we notice a purely physical difference. There were practically no hedges in the medieval village. The arable land of the village lay in great open fields, many hundreds of acres in extent, sepa- rated from one another and from the meadow and waste only by balks, or banks of unploughed turf, on which grew trees here and there. The beautiful hedges of the modern English countrj'^side are the result of the great enclosure m.ovement, of which we shall have to speak later on. This difference, of course, need not have been connected with a difference in the methods of agriculture. As a matter of fact it was so connected. 2. Equality of holdings. — In a modern village, the farms will be of all sorts of sizes, determined by the circum- 52 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS stances of the case. But if we examine the terrier, or ground-plan, of a medieval village, in which the lands worked by each farmer are distinguished, we shall notice a curious thing. We shall see that there is a tendency towards equality of holdings. There will be a great many farmers with about thirty acres of plough-land each. There will probably also be one or two much larger holdings, e. g., 120 acres, also more or less equal among themselves, and, what is still more curious, bearing a fixed proportion to the smaller holdings, usually of four to one. There will also be a number of people, obviously in an inferior position, hold- ing little plots or patches cleared from the waste. Finally, there will probably be a great man, who has a big house and park (or enclosure), as well as a great deal of land in the open fields. 3. Forced labour. — Corresponding with this strongly marked division of classes, there will be found, if the affairs of the medieval village be further investigated, a curious system, by which the two poorer classes in the village render labour services to the richer, not, as agricultural labourers do now, for wages, but as part of the terms on which they hold their land. The poorer class, or cottagers, will, prac- tically, be working almost entirely for the lord, as he would be called in Europe, for the agha in Persia, for the zatnindar in India, possibly also for the few rich farmers, if such ex- isted. But the ordinary small farmer, the yardling, as the English called him, will also have to work for the lord, though probably only a comparatively small part of his time. Indeed, in many cases, he will probably have coni- poimded for his labour dues by payment of a fixed money rent, and so will be what we should call an ordinary tenant farmer. Nevertheless he will clearly at one time have been a serf ; i. e., a man who has to work for another, whether he likes it or not. 4. Intepmixed plots. — Now-a-days, the land of each farmer in a village lies in a more or less compact mass. The AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 53 farmer would consider it a great hardship and waste of time if it did not. But the farmer in a medieval village not only had his holding divided amongst the two (or three) great fields into which the arable land of the village was marked off (for cultivation according to the rotation of crops pre- viously described), but, even in each of these three fields, his holding was not compact, it was split up into a large num- ber of small strips (usually about half an acre each) scattered all over the field. Besides his 30 acres or so of arable, he would also have the right to turn so many cattle and sheep into the meadow of the village, except at the time of hay growth, when the meadow would be temporarily enclosed with hurdles, and then he would get the hay of a small plot. Finally, he would have the right to turn so many inferior beasts — donkeys, geese, swine — on to the waste, or uncul- tivated land of the village, and also to cut turf and wood therefrom for fuel and repairs. Thus we see that his holding, which always included a house in the village, was a complete outfit, so far as land was concerned. Closely connected with the " intermixed " character of the farms was the practice of shifting, or redistributing, the plots held by a farmer at stated intervals. This practice had ceased in the more progressive parts of Europe long before the end of the Middle Ages ; but in Sweden and Denmark there were clear traces of its existence ; in India, under the name of vesh, it was well known, and in Persia, even at the present day, it frequently takes place under the management of the headman of the village. 5. Customary management. —This feature which, perhaps, distinguishes the medieval village more clearly than any other from the modern village, was a necessary result of the system of intermixed holdings. All the work of the village was settled by a rigid system of rules, handed down from remote ages, which prescribed exactly when and how each operation should be begun, done, and ended. Now-a-days each farmer manages his lands as he thinks 54 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS best, subject to the terms of his agreement with his land- lord. If fanner Jones thinks it wise to cut his hay on Mon- day, he is not obliged to wait for farmer Smith, who thinks that Thursday will be better. Each farmer cuts his hay when he thinks best. But this sort of independence would have been impossible when the lands of all the different farmers were mixed up together. The village was fixed in the grip of custom, and one of the chief reasons why agri- culture was for so many centuries unprogressive, was just because the enterprising farmer could not act without con- vincing the whole of his fellow-villagers. 6. Officials. — Now-a-days the ordinary village perhaps has its policeman, and maybe its tnaire or chairman of parish council ; but the policeman is probably appointed and paid by a distant authority, and the maire or chairman has very little real power. In the Middle Ages, each village had an elaborate staflf of officials, whose duty it was to work for the whole village. First, there was the headman or reeve, chosen from or, it may even be, by the villagers, who repre- sented the villagers as a whole, was responsible to the lord for their labour dues, enforced the customs, and was the mouthpiece of the village in its dealings with the outside world. The position, though it doubtless carried (as it still does in India and Persia) certain privileges, was not without its drawbacks ; and there are some traces of a rule that its acceptance was compulsory. Then, too, there was a constable or beadle, whose duty it was to carry messages round the village, to summon the villagers to meet under the sacred tree, and generally to enforce the orders of the reeve and moot, or meeting of the villagers. Then there was thepomid- keeper, who seized straying beasts and kept them in custody till their owners made fine to the village chest ; the parker, or common-keeper, whose duty it was to tend the cattle and sheep in the meadow, and to see that no one put in more than his proper share or stint; the swine-herd, who led the swine of the village daily to the wood to grub for acorns ; AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 55 the goose-herd, and so on. In many villages, all over the world, it was the duty of the village to provide watchmen, at least during certain times of the year, to guard the flocks at night. We find our English Edward I., in his great Statute of Winchester, insisting that the custom should be kept up ; and the "Watch" were a standing joke in Shakespeare's time. In India and other Oriental countries, even at the present day, the village carpenter, potter, blacksmith, cobbler, etc., are real officials, provided for, like the other officials, by an allowance of land, which is plowed and sown for them by the farmers, while they, in return, must give their labour to any villager who may require it. Doubtless it was so at one time in Europe. Opigin of the village.— This description will have been sufficient to show that the medieval village, though not that socialistic community which platform orators have delighted to describe it, was a very highly organized and closely compacted body, something utterly different from the mere groups of independent farmers in modern Europe, usually held together, if at all, only by the fact that they are tenants of the same landlord. Two views. — Now, concerning the origin of this village community, a conflict fierce, and, it is to be feared, somewhat acrimonious, has raged. For, whilst we have had great con- troversialists, such as Mr. Seebohm, Professor Vinogradofl, Professor Maitland (who can hardly be called a controver- sialist at all), and M. Fustel de Coulanges, who have all combined great learning with perfect courtesy, we have also, unhappily, had inferior controversy from apologists of par- ticular theories, who have not always observed the courtesies of scholarship. Briefly speaking, and putting aside minor details, the rival views are (i) that the typical village was originally a h2Lndt.oi kinsmen working for themselves; (2) that it was originally a group of serfs (or slaves) working for a master. Mr. Seebohm and M. Fustel de Coulanges take the latter view; Professor Vinogradoff and (with reserva- I 56 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS tions) Professor Maitland take the former. It is so ex- tremely unlikely that the views of any of these eminent and learned men are totally baseless, that is a pleasing task to the author to suggest a solution of the difficulty which shall combine the views of both sides. Glancing back for a moment at our account of Tribal Organization, we shall remember, in the first place, that, though what may be called the average tribesmen were free- born kinsmen of each other, there was also attached to each tribe a body of strangers, in a more or less inferior and servile position. Furthermore, we shall remember that, among the Irish and kindred races, the rich tribesman fre- quently loaned out part of his cattle to poorer freemen, in return for an annual payment or rent, and certain feastifigs or entertainments. Finally, we shall remember that each tribe had its chief or head, who was endowed with special privileges, and who received various gifts and offerings from the tribesmen. Here at once we have a division of patri- archal society into ranks, which correspond in a most curious way with the divisions in an ordinary village com- munity, as described in this chapter. The tribal chief cor- responds with the village lord or agha, the rich tribesmen with the holders of large farms, the poor tribesmen with the yardlings, or thirty -acre men, the "strangers" with the cottagers or serfs of the village. Similapity between tribal and village opganiza- tion. — But, after all, such a coincidence may be merely casual. We have no right to say that it proves the connec- tion between the tribe and the village. As a matter of fact, there are substantial differences to be accounted for ; and it is by the neglect to explain such differences that historians claiming to be scientific incur ridicule. For example, in the tribe, the poor Ceile, or holders of stock, pay their rents, not to the chief, but to their individual cattle- owners, while, in the village, the labour services of t\\e yardlitigs are rendered almost wholly to the lord. As a matter of fact, there is an AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 57 important transition step between the tribe and the village, namely, the clan; and it is for evidence of the nature and origin of this body that we must look. The Flaith.— Fortunately, it is not very hard to find. If we look once more at our "Ancient Laws of Ireland," we shall find an important person known as the Flaith, who is permanently connected with a definite territory upon which are settled — (a) His Ciniud, or agnatic kinsmen, grouped together in an apparently artificial way, known as Fine; {b) His Ceile, or, as we should call them, tenants, who, though tribesmen, have accepted stock from him in manner before described ; {c) His Fuidhir, or strangers, who, apparently, have become his peculiar charge, either by some kind of distribution within the tribe, or by voluntary arrangement. Apparently, in order to attain this position of Flaith, or landlord, the ordinary Boaire, or rich cattle-owner, must have held his position for three generations. The third in descent from the Boaire, if he is still rich and has main- tained his position on the same land, becomes a Flaith. But how did he come to be settled permanently on this land? No subdivisions of land in the pastoral pepiod.— It is fairly clear that, during the purely pastoral epoch, there were no permanent divisions of the land within the tribe. Each man's share of the tribal land was reckoned, not in acres or other land measurement, but vcC cattle and sheep. It was, obviously, much easier to reckon this way than to go to the trouble of measuring out the land and allotting a portion to each man. The cattle wandered about, according to the season of the year, followed by the tribesmen with their tents and scanty goods ; and it is probable that this is all that a good deal of the so-called nomadism amounted to. But now we have to suppose the practice of agriculture slowly 58 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS adopted, "because of the abundance of the households.'* Gradually this wandering existence became more and more impossible. Granted that, at first, the cultivators of the soil cleared and broke up any part of the forest land not actually occupied by their fellow-tribesmen, sooner or later the improvements in agriculture described at the beginning of this chapter rendered people unwilling to abandon their land. But who were the earliest cultivators of the soil? Obviously, the strangers attached to the tribe, upon whom the rough work of the community fell, and who would be the first to suffer from scarcity of food. Gradually the tribal territory thus got broken up among the rich tribes- men, each with his Ceile or dependents and his Fuidhir or strangers ; and, after three generations of holding, he could not be dispossessed. This view is strikingly suggested for Ireland by the famous poem of Finntann on the battle of Magh Lena. He tells us that of old Ireland was divided into one hundred and eighty-four Tricha Ceds, i. e., tribal territories, that each of them was subdivided into thirty Ballys, or clan lands, each maintaining three hundred cattle, and having twelve seisrighs, or ploughlands, each of one hundred and twenty acres. We are not bound to suppose that the poet was entirely accurate in his figures ; but he was not likely to have made a glaring misstatement of ob- vious facts. We may accept his general description as true, the more so as it is substantially supported by the evidence of the Welsh Laws. The Welsh evidence. — For, in the Welsh Laws, we have not only the kin^ or tribe, settled in its cantred, but we have a subdivision known as the gwely, under a breyr, or uchelwr, who is a sort of minor patriarch, at the head of a living family of three generations. The term gwely, which literally means a bed or couch, is strongly suggestive of family ties ; and, as a matter of fact, we have in the Welsh Laws a very interesting description of the ancient Welsh patriarchal house, which seems to have been much of the AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 59 same type as the ordinary Gothic church. Behind the pillars (gavels) which supported the roof and formed the nave, were what we should call, in modem architecture, the "transepts," but which the Laws call the gwelys, or couches ; and the Tir Gwelyawg, or ancestral land, is, like the Irish Orba, the land of a family which has remained in possession of the same district for three generations, and has tenants and serfs under it. In the Welsh evidence, too, it is also worth noting that, primarily, the agriculture is supposed to be done by the Alltuds, or strangers ; the free tribesmen occupying themselves principally with cattle- rearing. The Scottish evidence. — Lastly, in the Scottish evi- dence, especially that part of it which relates to the High- lands, we find the clan, or section of the tribe, permanently settled as a land-occupying unit engaged in agriculture. Thus, even after the feudalizing process, which began in the fourteenth century, had made some little way, the davoch is found to consist normally of four parts ; viz., the thaneston, or lord's demesne, the tenandries, or holdings of the superior class, significantly known as "kindly tenants," usually on very profitable terms, the steelbow lands, occu- pied (usually in holdings of two oxgangs, or a husbandland of about twenty -six acres), by small farmers who receive their stock from the thane, or lord, and the servile lands, occupied in small patches by cottagers who spend most of their time in working on the lord's demesne. This looks extremely like the Orba of the Irish Laws, and the Tir Gwelyawg of Wales. Kinship in the village.— Thus, we have seen, if our account be correct, that those writers who contend for the origin of the village in a group of kinsmeji, have a good deal of truth on their side. And their contention is in- directly supported by many significant, if indirect, survivals. One of these is the widespread practice oi fosterage in early agricultural society, i. e. , the practice of the richer members 6o A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS of the community putting out their children to be brought up by the poorer. As is well known, fosterage ties were looked upon in early times as almost equivalent to kinship ; and it would seem that by this practice the community wished at least to pretend that all its members were of kin. Then, too, there is the equally widespread practice of the "maiden fee" {Merchet, as the Saxons called it ; Amobyr, as it was known to the Welsh). This consisted of a payment made to the chief or lord on marriage of a villager's daughter, and represents, no doubt, the ancient "bride- price" received by the wife's kindred. Finally, expressions such as the "brotherhood," to signify the village in certain parts of India, and the known unwillingness in primitive countries at the present day to permit a stranger to acquire lands in a villae:e, all point to the same conclusion. Lor-dship in the village.— On the other hand, the writers who assert the origin of the village to be in lordship rather than in kinship have much on their side. To say nothing of the important part which, as we have seen, was played by the subject stranger in the clan, we must not forget that, wherever we find primitive agricultural society, we always find something in the nature of dues or rents paid by tlie farmer. Even if we put aside such obviously later introductions as the Danegelt in England, and the KJiiraj of the Mahommedan conquests, about which we must speak at a later stage, we have still the food-retits and /castings (see p. 34) due from the receiver of stock to his lord, and from the latter to his chief ; while from all lands something in the nature of tribute is paid to the tribal chief The latter also, as well as the heads of clans, has his special allotment of land for his support, and this he frequently loans out to people who pay him part of the produce in return, just as, in the earlier pastoral days, the rich cattle- owner took food-rents and feastings from his Ceile, or receivers of stock. Once more, there can be little doubt that, whilst land was still plentiful, any enterprising clansman AGRICULTURE AND THE CLAN 6l might colonize the waste lands of the clan, and found a new village with a band of followers whom he collected round him ; and in such a case he would, doubtless, become the lord of the new village. The fact is, that in kinship and lordship we have two very early and very powerful principles of association. The former appeals more to sentiment, and tends to produce harmony ; the latter is founded upon respect for superior strength and masterful qualities, and tends to produce obedience. Both harmony and obedience are essential to the successful ordering of a social unit, such as the agricul- tural village. CHAPTER VII Industry and the Gild Metal-WOPking. — By a somewhat unfair use of the term, the word "industry" is usually appHed only to pur- suits other than hunting, cattle-tending and agriculture. In a sense, therefore, there is "industry" even in the savage epoch, when the women of the pack skin and dress the captured animals in the cave or bark hut ; still more so in the pastoral epoch, when the wife and the daughters of the shepherd weave the wool of the flocks into garments, and make the milk of the herds into butter and cheese. But the great spur to industry comes with the development of agri- culture, when there is a demand for ploughshares, reaping- hooks, spades, mattocks and hoes ; and this is itself con- nected with one of the most important subjects m the history of civilization : the art of working in metals. The primitive implements of husbandry are, no doubt, made of wood and stone ; but no great progress in agriculture can be made until metal tools are employed. Use of iron. — Now it is tolerably clear that even pastoral races have some knowledge of working in metals. The brazen helmets and corselets of the Homeric heroes, their swords and spears, the uncoined money (reckoned by weight) of the Jewish patriarchs, the gold and silver orna- ments of the African tribes, and the numerous bronze relics of great antiquity constantly dug up, all point to the fact that the art of working in metals is very ancient. But it is to be noticed that all these are soft metals, which can be C62) INDUSTRY AND THE GILD 63 worked with the stone hammer, and beaten out, whilst cold, into the required shape. The real revolution comes when men learn to work in iron^ which can only be molded by being smelted in the fire, but which, when so worked, is infinitely harder than the older metals, and can produce results which they could never have produced. There is a good deal of ground for conjecturing that this important art of smelting metals did not originate in Europe, but was imported from the East, possibly from Egypt, where iron was worked in very early times. A brilliant German writer, who has endeavoured to draw a picture of primitive Aryan society from the evidence of language, has pointed out that there is no general or widely- spread word for "iron" among the Aryan-speaking races. And from this fact he draws the conclusion that the knowl- edge of iron was acquired by the European nations after their migration into western Europe. Be this as it may, it is quite certain that the European races have long ago surpassed all the rest of the world in the art of working in iron. The smith. — It is evident, then, that industry (in the modern sense of the term) begins with the important craft of the smith, from which, indeed, almost all other crafts may be said to have sprung. The smith it was who forged and mended the ploughshares and reaping-hooks of the vil- lage, and, still more important, its swords and spears. He it was who, as later improvements came, made the iron nails which took the place of the old bone and wooden skewers, and the metal knives which superseded the old stone axes and sharp flints, who substituted the iron ham- mer for the rude lump of quartz with a shaft stuck through it. If any one with the necessary knowledge and patience would write a history of the craft of the smith, tracing its development in all ages and in all countries, he would do yeoman service to the cause of social history. What little is known is very significent. For example, it seems toler- 64 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS ably clear that for many ages in Europe the craft was in the hands of travelling stranglers, perhaps the ancestors oi our modern (gypsies, who jealously guarded their valuable secrets and made no end of mystery of their calling. The many legends which have grown up round the calling of the smith (of which the Wayland Smith episode in Scott's Kcnilworth is a skilful adaptation) are fertile matter for a thorough investigation. The gypsy idea is, of course, quite in accordance with the suggestion, that the art of smelting iron was brought into Europe by strangers. Specialization of industry.— But, as might have been expected, the Indo-European peoples, with that capacity for adaptation which has been one of the great secrets of their brilliant success in the world, ultimately acquired the art ; and the numerous families of the Smith name {Schmidt in German, Favre in French, etc.) testify to the popularity of the pursuit. Some other crafts branched off from it; e. g., the carpenter, who worked in wood with the smith's nails, hammer, and chisel ; the cobbler, who borrowed his needle and his knife ; the tailor, who adopted his shears and his needle ; the loriner (or leather worker), the turner, the zvheelwright, the cooper, and so on. Even the older crafts felt the tendency towards specialization, and, instead of each family doing its own weaving, thatching, baking and brewing, we get these crafts undertaken by special bodies, the iveavers, tilers, bakers and brewers* Commerce. — But, in remembering the makers or pro- ducers, we must not forget another equally important class of industrial workers; \\z.,\.\\e merchants or exchangers. Indeed, there is some reason to believe that exchange pre- cedes production in the order of ideas. The Australian savages do not make anything worth speaking of, but they exchange certain of their natural advantages for others *It is an interesting fact that, in England at least, the earliest pro- fessional brewers (or should we say breweresses ?} were Women. INDUSTRY AND THE GILD 6$ which they need. Thus, a pack which hunts a country abounding in a peculiar green stone, greatly valued for the purpose of stone axes, will send some of its young men with lumps of the precious articles, to exchange against the feathers of certain birds collected by another tribe, which are greatly valued for decorative purposes. These primi- tive merchants observe certain formalities in their approach to the stranger camp ; and are, by immemorial custom, entitled to be treated as guests, not as etiemies. The custom of making presents on approaching an African chief as a stranger is said to be a survival of this ancient practice ; for, it is to be noted, the chief always observes the etiquette of offering return gifts. At any rate, we get here the earliest appearances of the law of the market^ which is again a notable factor in the history of civilization. Barter and sale. — Trade is, of course, for long ages conducted in its primitive form by means of barter, i. e., the exchange of one article against another. The disadvantages of such a form are obvious. One tribe or clan may have plenty of ostrich feathers, for example, to dispose of, but may not require the only articles which another has to offer. It is clear that no business can be done between them. Inside a community the matter could be adjusted by a sort of debtor and creditor account ; but between stranger, pos- sibly rival communities, such a course would not be pos- sible. Occasionally some toketi, such as the African cowry shell, is adopted as a stajidard of value, in which payments can be made. But the objection to this course is that these articles are not really in themselves valuable, and may, therefore, involve the community which takes them in a loss. A great advance is made when some article of universal demand, such as the ox, is adopted as a standard of value. We then get the difference between barter and sale. The community which requires the ostrich feathers, but which has no article specially required by the other community to dispose of, pays so many oxen in 66 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS exchange for the feathers. The oxen are thus the price, which, as economists tells us, is value expressed i?i lertns of money. A curious testimony to the truth of this account is found in the fact that, when oxen are super- seded as money by the precious metals, which, as being more portable and less easily subject to depreciation, are really more suitable, the earliest coins are often found to be stamped with an ox^s head. But we must not suppose that coined money at once takes the place of oxen. There is an intermediate stage of uncoined money, which passes by weight. Abundant evidence of this fact survives ; but we need not look farther than our own word pound, which may mean either a weight or a coin of a particular value. Organization of industry.— Having now seen some- thing of the way in which industry, in its two branches of production and exchange, arose, we turn, in dealing with agriculture, to examine how industry was organized, i. e., what institutiojis were developed to work it. Village CPaftsmen.— There can be little doubt that, at first, there was an attempt to fit industry into the village system. Although the smith, as a stranger, would not readily be absorbed in a group of kinsmen, although, as a matter of fact, we generally find the smithy at a little distance from the village, yet the "village blacksmith" became, and, indeed, still is, a recognized village institution. So also with the other early crafts. The carpenter, cobbler and tailor, the weaver, tiler and baker, are in Oriental countries at the present day, and formerly in European countries were, integral parts of the village system. As for the primitive merchant, we find him in the humble guise of the pedlar, or huckster, going about with his pack from village to village, and so being, if not a villager, at least a connecting link between villages. The market. — But, as industry became more and more specialized, as new crafts developed out of the old, it gradually became clear that more rapid progress was made INDUSTRY AND THE GILD 67 and better work done if the workers in a particular craft collected together in a centre, perhaps specially suited for the particular industry; and thus we get the beginning of that tendency for industry to gravitate towards towns, which is so marked a feature of modern industrial life. It may be that the gradual collection of craftsmen formed the town, or it may be that the existence of a fortified town attracted the craftsmen. That is a much-disputed question. But it is tolerably certain that one of the earliest institutions in con- nection with towns was the tnarket, and that the existence of the market was closely connected with the development of industry. The neighboring villages would not want to come to market for agricultural produce ; but they would want to come for the produce of what is specially known as "industry." Now, the very essence of the market is that it is neutral growtd, on which the members of different communities can meet without trespassing on one another's territories. As its name implies, it was frequently on the tnarch or boundary of two or more districts. And, whether it was so or not in any particular instance, it was essential that it should be a place of peace. The existence of the market cross in later days shows that the Church took the market under her special protection. And, also later, kings and emperors made a special point of protecting the peace of their markets. How the peace was guarded in the ancient days before Church and State, it is difficult to say. In savage times the essential point is that seller and buyer shall never actually come into contact. The seller brings his article near the strange camp, lays it down on the ground in full view, and retires. The intending purchaser comes out, inspects the article, places beside it what he is willing to give in exchange, and also retires. The seller once more comes up, inspects the proffered exchange, and, if satisfied, takes it away, leaving his own article to be fetched by the purchaser. If he is dissatisfied with the offer, he takes his own article away. 68 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS Needless to observe, savage barter is a trifle tedious ; but time is of no value to savages, who, indeed, do not under- stand what it means. In patriarchal times, the "gods of the market place" probably are supposed, in some mysterious way, to guard the peace of the market. At any rate, the bazaar, which is the Oriental market, is a typical feature of town life in patriarchal countries at the present day. The gild.— But it is totally contrary to the ideas of primitive man to live as an individual, isolated and unpro- tected, in a large society. We have seen that pastoral pursuits developed the tribe, with its strong blood bond, its mutual protection of its members by the blood feud and its ancestor worship. We have seen, too, that agriculture led to the existence of the clan, with its strongly organized family system, its elaborate arrangements of land occupation, and its reciprocal duties of protection and service between chief and followers. Just in the same way, the appearance of industrial pursuits produced the gild. The craftsman, finding himself in a strange place, cut off from his own kindred, formed with his fellows an association resembling as closely as possible the association of kindred which he had left behind him. Perhaps at first it was merely a peace- association, a. frith-gild, as the Saxons called it ; then it took on a religious character, doubtless in imitation of the old ancestor worship of the clan. The medieval gild always had its patron saint ; and, if its members did not really believe themselves to be descended from their patron saint, they often spoke as if they did. Finally, the gild became more industrial in character ; busying itself more and more with such matters as the regulation of work and prices, the inspection of workshops, the fixing of measures and qualities, the exclusion of strangers, and so on. But the more we study the gild, the more we see its likeness to the old clan. Like the clan, it was strongly hereditary. The best title to admission to the full privileges of a gild was the fact that the applicant's father was, or had been, a member. Failing INDUSTRY AND THE GILD 69 birth, apprenticeship was the only alternative. But appren- ticeship is very like adoption. In the days of gilds, the apprentice lived in his master's house, fed at his master's table, shared in his worship, was clothed and taught by him, just like a son. Just as the member of a clan took the name of the founder, and put before it or after it some sound which indicated "son of," so the member of the gild called himself by the name of his craft. While the clansman called himself " i'J^.rDougall," or "Bill/«^," or ap Tudor," or "^i?«hadad," the craftsman called himself "Smith," "Turner," "Carpenter," and so on. In fact, it is said by some competent observers that the Indian caste system is merely an elaboration of hereditary craft-gilds. Moreover, the gild in later days provided schools and orphanages for the children of its members, attended their funerals, pro- vided masses for their souls, spoke of its members as "brethren," had an "elder man" {Ealdorman) for chief, settled disputes amongst its members, and forbade its members to compete with one another, just as a well- conducted association of kinsmen would do. Finally, on its strongly developed social side, in its frequent drinkings, feastings and merrymakings, the medieval gild strongly resembled a great family group. Thus we have seen that patriarchal society had succeeded, more or less completely, in making provision in its own way for the needs of advancing civilization. As each new de- velopment of human ingenuity brought a new occupation to light, patriarchal society was equal to the task of organizing itself to receive and carry it on. Obviously, patriarchal society rested on principles which are, or were, very deep in human nature, very capable of making themselves felt under all sorts of circumstances. Once more, as we are leaving the subject, it will be well to summarize briefly the distinctive features in which patriarchal society differed from modern or political society, the consideration of which lies 70 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS immediately before us. We cannot too clearly realize the contrast ; the more clearly we realize it the more shall we really understand modern conditions. 1. PeFSOnal basis. — Now-a-days we regard /^rrj/cry or locality as the great basis of society. But, as we have seen, despite the fact that nomadism or wandering life practically ceased with the adoption of agriculture, patriarchal society always considered itself as a body constituted by race, not by territory. Even the gild, as we have seen, regarded itself as a brotherhood, not as a mere neighbourhood. Though, doubtless, the members of a particular gild often lived near to one another in the same town, they lived together because they were members of the gild ; they were not members of the gild because they lived near together. Still more obviously are the clatt and the tribe personal, not territorial associations. 2. ExelUSiveness.— This feature of patriarchal society is a natural result of the former. Normally speaking, the only means of obtaining membership of a race is by being born into that race. Patriarchal society went so far as to admit the case oi adoption, or fictitious birth, under carefully guarded rules. But it would have recoiled in horror from the casual hospitality which a modern State extends to all tolerable immigrants. Modern States believe in large num- bers ; patriarchal communities do not. Some people are inclined to think that patriarcal society was right. It is a question of whether it is preferable to maintain purity of race and be extinguished as an independent community, or to admit alien blood and prosper. The history of the world shows that these are the inevitable alternatives. Racial exclusiveness wrecked the so-called "City State" of the Greeks ; it very nearly wrecked the budding destinies of Rome. All the world over the rule applies ; the pure- blooded races are weak, the mixed races are strong. 3. Fixity of Custom.— Custom plays, as we shall see, a large part in modern life ; but modern custom is continually INDUSTRY AND THE GILD 7T being modified and changed. The custom of patriarchal society is rigid. No doubt it changes a Httle ; but a society whose chief moral duty is to continue the traditions of its ancestors is hardly likely to admit novelty if it can help it. Sir Henry Maine tells a delightful story of an Indian village which had had a water supply provided for it by a paternal British Government. The villagers were notified, as a matter of course, of the official regulations laid down for the proper use of the water. An East End district of London would be only too glad to get a good water supply on such terms. But to the patriarchal society of India the notion that cus- toms could be manufactured by an official pen was simply incredible. And it was not until a wise official induced the village elders (by what means is not stated) to persuade the rank and file that the rules in question were really of immemorial antiquity, though their existence had only just been discovered, that the difficulty was solved. Even the gild prided itself on the antiquity of its statutes, though the gild is, of course, the most modern form of patriarchal society. The caste system of India is the extreme outcome of the rigidity of patriarchal custom. When we speak of the "unchanging East," we allude to countries which are still in the grip of patriarchal principles. As a consequence of its unchanging character, patriarchal society is also, to a great extent, non- competitive. Competition involves innovation at every turn ; the successful competitor usually succeeds because he does things in a superior way of his own. Doubtless it is also possible to succeed by doing things in the same way as one's rivals, but doing them better. And to this extent, presumably, patriarchal society is com- petitive. But the trade offences known as " engrossing " and "forestalling," which are recognized in quite the last stage of patriarchal society, are amusing illustrations of the limited extent to which that society allowed competition. "Fore- stalling" merely means buying earlier than your neighbours, in order to control the supply of commodities and get 72 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS better prices. As its name implies, it is an attempt to buy goods before they reach the market. "Engrossing" is simply dealing in a large number of articles, instead of observing the customary restrictions, in order to be able to sell cheap, and so attract custom. It is pathetic to think that the harmless and indeed useful "grocer" of modern times is, in origin, a member of a criminal class. 4. Communalism.— Observe, we do not say Com- fnunisnt. Patriarchal society is not communistic, \. e., it does not refuse to recognize individual rights, nor does it pool the productions of its members and divide them equally. But it is communal, in the sense that it is always organized in groups. The smallest group of which it takes direct notice is the household, which is probably very much larger than our modern household, and may contain two or three gen- erations, with wives, apprentices and serfs. Within that household the higher authority does not penetrate. The same rule is observed in an ascending scale. What the household is to the clan or gild that the clan is to the tribe. With us, the supreme authority can control directly the actions of any individual. The reason for that change will shortly appear. But in patriarchal society the tribal chief, after the break-up of the tribe into clans, communicates directly with the clan chiefs only, except that he probably has a clan of his own of which he is tribal head as well as clan chief. The clan chief, likewise, communicates only with the heads of households within his clan ; to the heads of households belongs the control over the dwellers within their walls. But we really err in comparing the position of any patriarchal authority with that of a modern State official. The latter is wielding the power of a despotic ruler, whether that ruler be an individual or a parliament. The former is merely administering the customs of his race. Type III — Modern (Political) Society CHAPTER VIII The State and Feudalism The origin of the State, or Political Society, is to be found in the development of the art of warfare. It may be very sad that this should be so ; but it is unquestion- ably true. Historically speaking, there is not the slightest difficulty in proving that all political communities of the modern type owe their existence to successful warfare. As a natural consequence, they are forced to be organized on military principles, tempered, doubtless, by a survival of older (patriarchal) ideas. Happily, there is a good side, as well as a bad one, to military life. Development of wapfare.— The question may natur- ally be asked at this stage — How came military principles to receive such a startling development after society had, apparently, succeeded in organizing itself on more peaceful lines ? Fighting there had always been, of course ; wars between tribe and tribe, clan and clan, even between village and village, town and town. But this was more in the nature of a feud, a sort of standing quarrel which broke out again and again, and then slumbered for a while ; it was nothing like the organized and determined warfare which resulted in the formation of States. It may be described as amateur rather than professional fighting. Inepsase of population.— Although we cannot speak with certainty as to the causes of this development, it is (73) 74 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS not difficult to suggest one or two facts which may have led to it. First and foremost comes the increase of popu- lation^ with its consequent pressure on the means of sub- sistence. This increase is always, under normal circum- stances, steadily going on ; and it is dealt with in various ways. Sometimes a pestilence breaks out ; and the super- abundant population, enfeebled by short allowance of food, is swept away by disease. Sometimes wholesale migra- tions take place to less thickly populated districts ; this may be regarded as a real remedy, though perhaps only a temporary one, for the trouble. Sometimes, again, a great new invention enables a largely increased food supply to be produced ; the changes from hunting life to pastoral life, and again from pastoral life to agriculture, are examples. Finally, war may break out on a large scale ; and the weaker peoples may be either exterminated or (more probably) reduced to subjection by the stronger. Increase of wealth. — Another cause may have been the great increase of realized wealth attendant upon suc- cessful agriculture, and, still more, industry. Pastoral wealth has this advantage, that it can be moved about with tolerable ease. A weak tribe can fold up its tents, and drive its cattle and sheep out of harm's way. But the wealth of the husbandman cannot be so disposed of. His wealth is in his fields, which he has patiently culti- vated, and in his bams and presses which he has filled with corn and wine. He has built himself a permanent house, and he will not leave it while a chance of safety, or even of existence, remains. He is a very tempting bait to the military adventurer. Still more is the craftsman, with his rich store of wealth, a tempting object of plunder. The sack of an industrial town, with its shops and its stores of goods, is the dream of the freebooter. Wass fiir Plunder! was Bliicher's exclamation when he was shown London from the dome of St. Paul's. It was the old instinct of the professional soldier. THE STATE AND FEUDALISM 75 ImpPOveraent in weapons.— Once more, it is natural to suppose that the improvement in the art of working in metals did much to stimulate the military spirit. The superiority of iron, still more of steel weapons and armour, over the old wooden bows and arrows and leather shield and corselet, would give a natural impetus to warfare. Above all, with the tendency towards specialization which, as we have seen, is one of the master principles of develop- ment, this improvement in the means of warfare would tend to produce a special military class, the professional warrior of the modern world. In primitive times every man was a soldier ; as civilization progressed, the bulk of people became interested in other things, and fighting became the work of specialists. This fact is directly con- nected with the origin of the State. The German wap-bands.— In the interesting account given by Tacitus of our Teutonic forefathers in their ances- tral homes, we notice one very significant feature. Not only does the historian distinguish between the princeps, or tribal chief, who was chosen for his noble birth, and the dux, or war leader, who was chosen for his valour ; he shows us the latter surrounded by a band of adventurous companions, who took no part in the ordinary pastoral life of the tribe, but were constantly engaged in warfare, either in defense of their own tribe or in plundering expe- ditions against strange tribes. These "companions," as they are called, were fed at the leader's table, were furnished with food and garments by the women of his household, and shared the booty of their leader's expedi- tions. The devoted loyalty which they displayed towanis their leader is described in a spirited and well-known pas- sage. They counted it a disgrace to leave the field alive if he was dead ; their dead bodies were found thickly piled around his in the disastrous day of defeat. It is probable that, at first, this band of companions was com- posed mainly of the kinsmen of the leader, his gesiths, aa 76 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS the Saxons called them ; but ultimately they became simply volunteers who joined the band from love of adventure and a military life. They were the thanes (or servants) of the heretoch (or host-leader.) Foundation of states.— A Stale is founded when one of these host-leaders with his band of warriors gets perma- nent control of a definite territory of a considerable size. And, practically speaking, this always occurs in one of two ways. Consolidation. — The host-leader, after firmly estab- lishing his position as ruler of his own tribe, extends his authority over neighbouring tribes, until he becomes ruler of a large territory. This is what seems to have happened in the England of the ninth century, when the so-called "tribal kingdoms" of the Heptarchy, after fluctuating for many years between the Bretwaldaship of the various tribal chiefs, became more or less consolidated by conquest in the time of Egbert. The same movement showed itself also in the neighbouring country of Scandinavia, where, also in the ninth century, the innumerable tribes became gradually consolidated, as the result of hard fighting, into the three historic kingdoms of Norway, Denmark and Sweden, under Harold Fairhair, Gorm the Old, and Eric of Upsala, who, as the Heimskringla strikingly puts it, subdued all rival chiefs "with scatt (taxes), and duties, and lordships." Much the same appears also to have been done in the gradual consolidation of the Celtic tribes of Scotland under the line of Malcolm Canmore, and of the tribes of Wales under the hereditary Princes who were found to be ruling the country at the Norman Conquest. In Ireland the trouble was that no successful warrior succeeded in making permanent a powerful dynasty. And, in central Europe, the too ambitious efforts of the Prankish warriors, Clovis and his successors, though brilliantly suc- cessful at first, resulted finally in a similar period of anarchy, which is known by the expressive name of the THE STATE AND FEUDALISM 77 "Dark Ages." In fact, the State formed by consolidation is always rather liable to break up into its former elements. MigPation. — Or a State is founded by the successful migration and conquest by a band of warriors to and of a strange country. This was the history, in very early times, of the foundation of the kingdom of Lombardy (a Teutonic conquest of a Latin land) ; likewise of the Visigothic king- dom of Spain. Somewhat later it was the brilliant history of the Normans or Northmen, who, in the ninth century, became the ruling power in Russia ; in the tenth founded the practically independent Dutchy of Normandy ; in the eleventh the new kingdom of England ; in the twelfth the kingdom of the Sicilies, and the short-lived kingdom of Jerusalem. Charaetep of the State. — The new type of community formed by these events differed fundamentally from that which preceded it. In the first place, it was essentially territorial in character. Though its rulers for some time continued to call themselves by tribal names ("Kings of the English," " Kings of the French," and so on), in reality the limits of their authority were the limits of their territories. Whosoever lived, nay, whosoever happened to be, within their dominions, was their subject, their subditus, or subdued man, bound to obey their commands, and especially bound to obey their call to arms. The life of the new community was military allegiance, that faithful obedience to the orders of a commander which had enabled the conqueror, with the aid of his devoted followers, to place his foot on the necks of the conquered tribes. Race feeling, no doubt, long counted for much ; no prudent ruler could afford to neglect it. But it was no longer the essential bond of unity. To begin with, the ruler and his chief followers were probably of different blood, perhaps even of different religion and speech, from the mass of the subject population. Apart from this fact, the successful warrior, knowing the value of numbers, was always trying 78 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS to import new followers, about whose race he cared little, provided only that they could be relied on to do good service, either with the sword or the pen. Finally, being generally a man of superior enlightenment, the new ruler was often anxious to throw open the country to foreign adventurers, whether merchants, ecclesiastics or teachers, believing that his fame and wealth would thereby be increased. This policy was, as is well known, the cause of much trouble in the early days of the State ; but the new spirit ultimately got its way. New type of religion.— Again, the exclusiveness of the old tribal systems was rudely broken down. It had rested mainly, as we have seen, towards the end of its history, on the system of ancestor worship. But the estab- lishment of the western State was curiously coincident with the triumph of a new type of religion, the chief character- istic of which was universality. It may sound, at first hearing, ridiculous to associate the meek religion of Christ with the aggressive military institution of the State. Yet it is quite certain that Christianity had a great deal to do with breaking down tribal prejudice, and with the estab- lishment of great political communities. To take the first and most glaring example which presents itself: The con- version of Clovis to Christianity was intimately connected with the formation of the brilliant, if short-lived, Prankish empire. The heathen Burgundians and Saxons were over- come by the Christian Franks. In the name of Christianity, Charles the Great rolled back the tide of Saracen invasion from the Pyrenees, and established the frontiers of Chris- tendom. Though Christianity in its earliest days had been a mission to the poor and lowly, its great conquests in northern and western Europe were due to the conver- sion of kings and princes. The conversion of ^thelbirht of Kent was the signal for the conversion of England. Christianity passed from Court to Court of the Heptarchic kingdoms. And Christianity well repaid the favour of THE STATE AND FEUDALISM 79 princes. Under the cry of "one church and one king," the older tribal divisions were ultimately wiped out, and England became one nation ; with Church and State in intimate alliance. Even more obviously had Mahom- medanism the result of breaking down tribal divisions, and establishing mighty kingdoms, like the kingdom of Akbar in India, the kingdom of Ismail in Persia, and the kingdom of Mahomet at Constantinople. The new nobility.— Once more, the new political organism, the State, no longer regarded custofn as its guid- ing star. By its very nature militarism is competitive ; for competition means strife, and strife is of the very essence of war. Mimic warfare may be conducted according to fixed tradition ; but, in that case, it is rather sport than war. Real war is a death-struggle, and each combatant will strain every nerve to gain the advantage. If any one will show him a new dodge for defeating his enemy, he will take it and be thankful. He will not ask if it is consecrated by the wisdom of his ancestors. Even the very modern humanitarian spirit has only succeeded in making slight inroads upon the fierce competition of war ; and if it succeeds in making further or serious inroads, it will destroy war, or reduce it to the level of a sport, which is, of course, its object. The founders of the State were, as we have seen, all successful warriors, who had won success by new combinations, new methods, daring disregard of tradition. It was hardly probable that, under their regime, the old traditional, customary life would be continued. Their watchword was ability, not custom. If they saw a man who could fight well, or write well, or sing well, they called him to their courts, regardless of his race or social rank. They knew that their position was pre- carious ; they could not afford to leave any stone unturned to ensure their safety. And one of their surest measures was to surround themselves with the ablest men on whom they could lay their hands. All over Europe the break-up of patriarchal society is marked by a striking change in the 8o A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS idea of nobility. The old nobility of birth, and zvealth, the members of the sacred families of the tribe and clan, the great lords of cattle, are replaced by the royal nobility, whose hall mark is the choice of the king. In the Barbarian Codes which tell us so much of early Teutonic society, the Atheling, or hereditary noble, is displaced by the antnistion, or royal servant. The latter may even have been at one time a slave ; it is enough that the king has recognized him as a conies, a member of his band of followers. In England the tribal ealdornian, in Scotland the Ri or Mormaer, give way before the Earl or simple thane. Doubtless, in many cases, the change was more apparent than real. Doubtless the tribal chief was willing to accept a title of nobility from the king ; just as the Irish chiefs of the fifteenth century, the O'Donnells and the O'Neills, became the Irish earls of the sixteenth century, the Tyrconnels and the Tyrones. But the difference was none the less significant ; and it paved the way for further change. It marked the triumph of the State over the older patriarchal society- Feudalism. — And, finally, the State was individual, not communal. Again we must be careful not to misunderstand terms. The dream of the despot, who would like to govern every man in his dominions by the immediate action of his caprice, is, happily, never realized. But the tendency of the State, from its very inception, was to break down all inter- mediate barriers between itself and its individual subjects. Every wise ruler is, however, aware that this can only be done by degrees. The warriors who founded successful States, whether they were alien adventurers or enterprising war leaders of neighbouring tribes, found various degrees of authority in existences among their subjects, exercised by men who had been accustomed to deference, if not actually to obedience. These men were rarely dispossessed by the conqueror, unless they persisted in refusing all overtures. The conqueror merely insisted that they should acknowledge their authority to be derived from him. This seemed to be THE STATE AND FEUDALISM 8l such a purely theoretical matter that the transaction was usually attended with little difficulty. Even where the demand of fealty or faithfulness was accompanied by a demand for tribute, there was little practical difficulty ; the conquered chief reckoned with shrewd accuracy on getting the money out of his followers, the humbler members of his tribe or clan. If the conqueror chose to regard the land oc- cupied by his tribe or clan as a gift or trust for the conqueror himself, it did not seem to matter much ; the important point was that the tribe or the clan still kept its land. Where the native chief was irreconcilable, or had been killed in the struggle, the conqueror put one of his own "companions," his comes or thane, into his place ; and thus, of course, obtained a really stronger hold on the conquered territory. Quite naturally, the conqueror's immediate vassals (as we may now begin to call them) found it convenient to repeat the same process with their inferiors. We have seen, in fact, that there were the germs of such a relationship in the practice of cattle lending practiced by patriarchal society (p. 34). But then the adoption of agriculture made land the important factor in society ; and so loans of land became the signs of subordination. Sometimes the transaction was genuine ; as where one man loaned to another land which he was really entitled to keep for himself Very often, however, it was merely fictitious ; as when the inferior yielded up his own land to his superior, and received it back again from him as a loan. The practice, known technically as commendation, was very common in Conti- nental Europe in the Dark Ages, and was primarily due to the fact that, in times of disturbance, the best chance for the weak man is to acknowledge himself the vassal of a strong man, who will protect him. But the tendency spread beyond cattle and land. The customs of a gild, or a number of gilds, their cherished rights of controlling their own members and excluding strangers from the town, came to be held as privileges granted by a ruler ; and so town 82 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS life was brought within the same idea. Finally, even such a thing as spiritual ofiice (with the emoluments attaching thereto) was held as a gift or loan from a superior ; and so indeed the technical name for such a gift or loan, a benefice, came to be specially associated with spiritual oflice. Thus the whole social organism gradually assumed what we call a feudal aspect, in some respects resembling the old patriarchal organization of groups within groups, but differ- ing from it in the important principle that the rights of the individual were no longer acquired by birthright, by membership of a social group, but were at least deemed to be the grant of a superior, in return for promised service. In the higher ranks, of course, that service was military ; and in this the new system showed its connection with the newer type of society. But in the lower ranks money and labour service were more common. The peasant rendered labour or paid rent to his lord, in return for his land ; the craftsmen of a town paid an annual sum to the king or earl for the charter of their privileges. Even the beneficed clerk owed to his patrofi the duty of saying prayers for the good of his soul. Evidence. — We shall see more, as we go on, of the nature and consequences of /^z^o'a/mw. Here it is sufficient to notice its place in the History of Politics. // is the con- necting link between purely patriarchal a?id purely political society. The brilliant historical labours of M. Longnon have, to all intents and purposes, established the geographical identity of the great fiefs of the West Prankish Empire with the tribal settlements of early Gaul. Mr. Skene has been equally successful in showing that the Scottish earl- doms and thanages of the eleventh century were really the old tribal and clan chiefships in a feudal dress. Could we but get sufficient evidence, we should no doubt find that the same was the case in England and other countries. Feudal society has often been reproached with vagueness and inconsistency. These are precisely the qualities whicti THE STATE AND FEUDALISM 83 we should expect in a phase of development which is not in itself essential or universal, but which is an easy and convenient means of softening a change. In the popular form of entertainment known as "dissolving views," one picture is not suddenly replaced by another; but the old picture gradually melts into the new by a nebulous and misty process, rather fascinating to watch but not conveying any very clear ideas. In the panorama of History, feudalism represents the blurred outlines and uiotiey colours of the "dissolving view." CHAPTER IX Early Political Institutions Following our accustomed plan, having seen how tbe State came into existence, we proceed to examine its organ- ization, that is to say, the institutions by which its business is carried on. Foremost amongst these institutions stands, of course — I. The kingship.— It is a simple historical fact that the kingship of the modern State is the direct outcome of that process of conquest and migration which founded the State itself. Till the general break-up of things established, which followed immediately on the French Revolution, many of the descendants of the original conquerors of Europe continued to sit on the thrones which their ancestors had established. Now that the chain of hereditary succes- sion has, in most cases, been rudely broken, the position established by the founders of the modem State still exists under other names. Kingship is perhaps the most suc- cessful institution of Politics. But we must be careful not to suppose that the first kings were institutions; they were merely individuals. The earliest kings were, as we have seen, successful military adventurers, who had managed to conquer territories of con- siderable size. By their own personal skill and prowess they maintained their position, and enforced what they considered to be their rights. What these rights were we shall enquire a little later ; here we are concerned to notice that the com- munities conquered bv the early host-leaders probably (84) EARLY POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS 85 regarded the latter as temporary nuisances, who would in due course be removed by the hand of death. Their posi- tion was totally opposed to the old ideas of society; they were much too stern, much too enterprising, much too neglectful of time-honored practice, to suit the easy-going ways of patriarchal society. They represented the future, as the dying patriarchal society represented the past. Permanence of the kingship.— The kings them- selves were perfectly aware of this view. Probably, from the very fact that they were successful warriors, they were men of exceptional ability, not merely in war, but also in the management of men. Leaders like Clovis, and Theodoric, and Alaric, and Egbert, were not likely to make the mistake of supposing that they could permanently maintain their positions by the mere force of military prestige. And so, although they clung tenaciously to their military powers, although the military origin of modern kingship has never really been forgotten, they began to buttress up their authority by appeals to other sanctions. Absorbs the chiefship.— One of the most skilful of these appeals was the appropriation by the kings of the character and attributes of the tribal chief whom they had conquered or dispossessed. It is possible that, in a few cases, they were, really and truly, members of tribal aristoc- racies, though probably not of the aristocracies of the tribes whom they had conquered. In most cases, they were simply adventurers, who had obtained their positions by sheer hard fighting. But they soon, by a series of fictions which could only have been accepted in a simple age, persuaded their subjects that they really were members of the ancient families whom they had overcome. The pedi- gree of an early European king generally led up to some well-known Hero, who had long been regarded with rever- ence as the mythical ancestor of the tribe or tribes over which he was ruling. A simpler method by which a con- queror attached himself to the tribal instincts of his subjects 86 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS was by marrying the daughter of the greatest of the conquered chiefs. Although by strict patriarchal law none of the rights and privileges of a patriarch could go in the female line, theunion was valuable for sentimental purposes ; and such a policy undoubtedly helped, as it has often done in later times, to strengthen the position of an intruder. The great result of this skilful borrowing of patriarchal ideas was that the kingship quickly became hereditary. We have seen that the position of host-leader was originally elective, not, of course, in the sense that it was balloted or even voted for, like the chairmanship of a modern committee, but in the sense that no one was entitled to it by right of birth. The host-leader was chosen by the informal adherence of those who admired his valour. But it was essential to the success of kingship that it should become hereditary ; and, fortunately, the desire to hand a great position over to one's children is one of the deepest instincts of average humanity.* So all the energies of the early kings were bent towards this end ; and their success was due chiefly to their skilful borrowing of patriarchal ideas. The dream of an elective monarchy is one of the chimaeras of the political Utopian. According to his amiable theory, freedom of election secures the best possible man. In sober truth, as evidenced by the facts of history, it results in one of three consequences. Either the country is torn in pieces by contending factions — the fate of Poland ; or the kingship is gradually shorn of its rights and possessions, which are given away as bribes to important electors by ambitious candidates— the fate of the Holy Roman Empire; or, finally, the electors deliberately choose a nonentity, who has no enemies, and who will be an obedient puppet in the hands of wire-pullers. This is the fate of the electoral Presidency of the modern Republic, which is a kingship in *Modern instances, of course, are to be found ; e. g., Cromwell and Napoleon, both of whom tried to make their positions hereditary. EARLY POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS 87 all but name. Only in times of extreme and obvious danger, and even then only when the electors are thoroughly honest, does an election produce a really good king. Traces of elective monarchy.— As a matter of fact, in the great majority of the European monarchies the tradition of an elective leader lingered for a few generations, with just sufficient vitality to show that it had once been genuine. It resulted, practically, in the notion that an heir- apparent might be rejected for positive infirmity, whether of body or mind. But, though the hereditary principle was accepted, it was not the modem but the ancient or patri- archal form of it which for a long time prevailed, and which gave the succession to the eldest male of the royal house, not to the son of the last occupant of the throne. This older form of hereditary succession lingered in Russia until the seventeenth century. Becomes peligious.— By these means the kingship became an institution, or permanent machine for carrying on the business of government. People came to look upon it as natural and inevitable that a king should rule over them. But the early kings made another admirable move when they assumed a religious position, by allying themselves with the Church. We have seen something of the origin of this alliance (p. 78) ; here it is only necessary to call attention to the well-known fact of the close connection between the kingship and the Church in the early days of the State. Throughout all Christendom, bishops and priests were the most intimate counsellors and the most enthusiastic supporters of the Crown ; and the rich gifts of the kings were amply repaid by the halo of sanctity which the grateful Church threw around the person and office of the king. From the day of his accession, when the sacred oil was poured upon his head, to the day of his death, when his grave was blessed by the Church, the monarch was surrounded and guarded by ecclesiastics. In Oriental countries, in Mahommedan States, the union is even closer ; for there the 88 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS Head of the State is also Head of tlie Church. But there is actually an example in outlying Christendom in which the archbishopric of the Church has become hereditary in the line of secular rulers ; and ev^en in Europe the intimate connection between the king and the Church was the best possible safeguard against any revival of patriarchalism, in connection with ancestor worship. 2. The Council.— We have seen (p. 75) that in the rude beginnings of monarchy, the host-leader is found always to be surrounded by his followers ox companions, men devoted entirely to his service, on the terms that he shall provide them with maintenance and opportunities for distinction. As the host-leader developed into the king, this body of followers became the council of the kingdom. Placed in the midst of a hostile country, the king and his followers were absolutely essential to one another's safety. Without their support, the king could not hold his conquest ; without his master mind, they would fall victims in detail to racial hostility. The success of the king meant the enrichment of his followers ; the contentment and prosperity of his fol- lowers meant the safety of the king. We may put aside as premature any definite theories about the right of the council, in those early days, to control the actions of the king. All our accounts of the relationship between the early king and his council go to show that the former, if he chose to run the risk of becoming unpopular, could do what he liked. Although, perhaps, the council gained somewhat in the eyes of the king's subjects by being regarded as the successor of the old tribal council of elders, yet, in reality, it was the body of the kirig's servants, chosen by him at his pleasure. Nevertheless, the existence of the council did soon undoubtedly become a substantial check on the despotic tendencies of the king. A theory grew up that a good king consulted his council frequently, that he listened to its advice. And from this point the step was compara- tively short to the doctrine that the king ought to consult, EARLY POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS 89 and, finally, that he imist consult his council. And thus, in reality, the council is the germ of what we call constitutional government. But, long before it became a bulwark of popular liberties, the council had rendered invaluable service to the kingship as an institution, and this in at least four ways. (a) It ppesepved the continuity.— Kingship may be perpetual ; but, in fact, the individual king dies. And, between the death of one king and the succession of another there lies a critical moment. The forces of anarchy are ready to break out. "The king died on the following day . . . then there was tribulation soon in the land, for every man that could forthwith robbed another," says an old chronicler. There is always the chance that old ideas may revive, and set people longing for the good old days when every one did that which was right in his own eyes. We must remember that a successful monarchy really does run counter to a good many cherished practices. It does not, for example, permit of blood-feuds or tribal forays ; it probably has incurred the resentment of old religions ; it has sanctioned practices which ancient prejudice regards as monstrous ; it has, probably, exacted a good deal of tribute. So there are always people waiting for a good opportunity to revolt against it. But the existence of the council tides over the dangerous moment. Though in strict theory the death of the king dissolves his council, in fact the members of council hold together, in hopes of being appointed by his successor. And, in the meantime, they keep the political machine going. {b) It ppesepved the traditions.— One of the greatest dangers to the newly-established kingship is the risk of offending its subjects by exhibitions of caprice. It has to deal with a community living according to immemorial custom. It is bound to effect alterations to a certain extent ; but, if it is wise, it will do so as little as possible. Above all, it must avoid unnecessary changes. It is almost better, 90 A SHORT HISTORY OF POLITICS under some conditions, to persevere in a bad policy than to change it for a good one. The average man, especially if he be of a patriarchal type, suspects and hates change. But a body of councillors is far less likely to be capricious than a single ruler ; its members will possibly have something to lose by a change of policy. Its influence will, in the vast majority of cases, be against change. (