VAR AT OD SSS OOS hn hhihhinhn nnn» . LLM, ify ties SRSA OANA SSSAOMON“nn~wwweo AGE SS AS LOAN ESAS oe SSS Yitiys ty Mitte a a a a a a eT eT le earning and Pubor. LIBRARY Universi, of Illinois. CLASS. VOLUME. 330.4 (56522 A COessienw NOs ee ey | Soleil eee eee mes te US Lge te ate eee eee Te Oe 2) SBOP =O Oe B20 a a i q 7 ? 7 a O HS SAY. S Pep lTICAnL HCONOMY. ESSAYS POLITICAL ECONOMY. BY THOMAS EDWARD CLIFFE LESLIE, LL.D. SECON EDLLLION. DUBLIN: HODGES, FIGGIS, & CO., GRAFTON-ST. LONDON: LONGMANS, GREEN, & CO., PATERNOSTER-ROW. 1888. P a a } : %5 | | ‘ YRAKHIS ‘ LOUIS IPR O YVIRRSVIVY = Al Te * i oN AVER RY | i t DUBLIN: PRINTED AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS, BY PONSONBY AND WELDRICK. - t we : a ee i a rh r ” * o Commerce 14g '02 Siechert. QA. 0 moO A ee a ee PREFATORY NOTE, THE present Volume is a new edition, modified in certain respects, of the ‘ Essays in Moral and Political Philosophy,’ originally published in 1879, and now for some time out of print. The alterations in the present Edition consist of— (1), omissions; (2), additions; and (3), changes in arrangement. To render the Work more suitable for Students of Economics, those Essays which dealt mainly with the non-economic aspects of social life have been omitted. It is not thereby intended to depreciate their merits, which are, in our judgment, of a high order; but their preservation having been secured by the publication of the former Edition, it has been thought. desirable in the present, which is specially designed for University use, to aim at greater unity of subject. Seven Essays, published after the appearance of the former edition, have here been added. In the opinion of the Editors, they bear all the distinctive marks of Mr. Lesuiz’s best work, and deserve to appear in a permanent form. 52018 v1 Prefatory Note. A different arrangement has been adopted for the purpose of bringing together Essays of a similar character. The guiding conception has been to group —(1) the Critical Essays ; (2) those which are ex- pository of the Author’s general view of Economics; and (3), those dealing with the interpretation of actual phenomena, or with economic policy. In the first group are comprised Essays 1.—xui.; in the second, Essays xiIv.—xvul.; and in the last, Essays XVIII.-XXVI. : The Student who desires to trace the development of Mr. Lxsiin’s views can obtain the dates of publica- tion of each Essay from the footnotes appended to the titles. JOHN K. INGRAM. C. F. BASTABLE. July, 1888. CONTENTS. eres PAGE PREFATORY NotE, . : ; : ‘ : : ; ; : Vv BrogRAPHIcAL Novick OF THE AUTHOR, . : : : d ; ix I. THE Love or Money, . - : : : : : F 11. THE WEALTH OF NATIONS AND THE SLAVE PowER, q ; 9 vy 10. THe PotiricaAt Economy or ADAM SMITH, . ; : abaya Iv. ‘Some Leapine Principles oF PotrtTicaL EcoNomMY NEWLY EXPOUNDED.’ By PROFESSOR CAIRNES, . 7 ; ie Al y. JoHN STvaRT WEE, o; : : : , : : . 4 vi. PRoFEssoR CAIRNES, . 2 - : : : : OU vit. Mr. BaGEHOT, . : ! : : : ; : geass: , Vu. JEvons’ ‘ THEory oF PorrricaL Economy,’ . : : ee OU 1x. MarsHatt’s ‘ Economics oF InpustTRY,’ : : ‘ a x. THE History oF GERMAN PoLiITIcAL ECONOMY, . : Oe x1. RoscHEr’s ‘ PrincrpLes oF Poriticat Economy,’ : ane to XII. Lionce DE LAVERGNE, d : : : i - HOE __ xm. PoriticaAL Economy IN THE UNITED SraTEs, : . 126 ~ xiv. Economic Scrence anv Statistics, : : : " . 155 xv. On THE PHiILosopHicaL Metnop oF PoriticAL Economy, . 163 Sxvr. Poxrrican Economy anp SocroLoey, . ‘ . , lot xviI. THE KNOWN AND THE UNKNOWN IN THE Economic WoRLD,. 221 xvi. THE History AND FUTURE OF INTEREST AND PROFIT, . . 243 Vlll Contents. PAGE x1x. Tur DISTRIBUTION AND VALUE OF THE Precious METALS IN THE SIXTEENTH AND NINETEENTH CENTURIES, . . 269 xx. Tor New Gortp MInzEs AnD PRICES IN EUROPE IN 1865, . 301 xxI, Pricks In GERMANY IN 1872, _.. : ; ; é . 332 xx1r. Prices In ENGLAND IN 1873, : ; : : : . 9356 Xx1II.. THe MoveMENTS OF AGRICULTURAL WAGES IN EUROPE, . 364 xxtv. THE INCIDENCE OF IMPERIAL AND LocaL TAXATION ON THE WoRKING CLASSES, : : 5 : : : . 384 xxv. British CoLuMBIA IN 1862, ; 4 ‘ : ‘ . 409 XXVI. AUVERGNE, . ; 5 : : : : , : . 414 BIOGRAPHICAL NOTICE OF THE AUTHOR Tomas Epwarp Cuirre Lestin, one of the ablest and most original English economists of the present century, was born in the county of Wexford, in (as is believed) the year 1827. He was the second son of the Rev. Edward Leslie, Prebendary of Dromore, and Rector of Annahilt, in the county of Down. His family was of Scotch descent, but had been connected with Ireland since the reign of Charles I. Amongst his ancestors were that accomplished and energetic prelate, John Leslie, bishop first of Raphoe and afterwards of Clogher, who, when holding the former See, offered so stubborn a resistance to the Cromwellian forces, and the bishop’s son, Charles, the well-known non-juror. Cliffe Leslie received his elementary edu- cation from his father, who resided in England, though holding Church preferment, as well as possessing some landed property, in Ireland. By him he was taught Latin, Greek, and Hebrew at an unusually early age. He was afterwards for a short time under the care of a clergyman at Clapham, and was then sent to King William’s College, in the Isle of Man, where he remained until, in 1842, being then only fifteen years of age, he entered Trinity College, Dublin.t He was a distinguished student there, obtaining, besides other honours, a Classi- eal Scholarship in 1845, and a Senior Moderatorship (Gold Medal) in Mental and Moral Philosophy at his Degree Examination in 1846. He became a law student at Lincoln’s Inn, was for two years a pupil at a conveyancer’s chambers in London, and was called to the English Bar. But his attention was soon turned from the pursuit of legal * Reprinted, by permission, from the Encyclopedia Britannica, 9th ed. TIt is noteworthy that John Elliot Cairnes, William Edward Hearn (author of Plutology, 1864), and Richard Hussey Walsh (author of an Elementary Treatise on Metallie Currency, 1853), were in the same Junior Freshman Class of 1842-3. b x Biographical Notice of the Author. practice, for which he never seems to have had much inclination, by his appointment, in 18538, to the Professorship of Jurisprudence and Political Economy in Queen’s College, Belfast.* The duties of this Chair requiring only short visits to Ireland in certain Terms of each year, he continued to reside and prosecute his studies in London, and became a frequent writer on economic and social questions in the principal Reviews and other periodicals.t| In 1870 he collected a number of his Essays, adding several new ones, into a volume, entitled, ‘Land Systems and Industrial Economy of Ireland, England, and Continental Countries.’ J.S. Mill gave a full account of the contents of this work in a Paper in the ‘Fortnightly Review,’ in which he pronounced Leslie to be ‘one of the best living writers on applied political economy.’ Mill had sought his acquaintance on reading his first article in ‘Macmillan’s Magazine.’ He admired his talents, and took pleasure in his society, and treated him with a respect and kind- ness which Leslie always gratefully acknowledged. In the frequent visits which Leslie made to the Continent, especially to Belgium and some of the less known districts of France and Germany, he occupied himself much in economic and social obser- vation, studying the effects of the institutions and system of life, which prevailed in each region, on the material and moral condition of its inhabitants. In this way he gained an extensive and accurate acquaintance with Continental rural economy, of which he made excellent use in studying parallel phenomena at home. The accounts he gave of the results of his observations were among his happiest efforts. ‘No one,’ said Mill, ‘was able to write narratives of foreign *In the Preface to the former edition of this work Mr. Leslie has clearly explained the way in which his economic doctrine was formed :—‘‘ Whereas Mr. Mill, in his youth, attended the lectures of Mr. Austin, the author had the good fortune to attend those of Sir Henry Maine at the Middle Temple, and to learn first from them the historical method of investigation, followed with such brilliant success in Ancient Law, Village Communities in the East and West, and the Lectures on the Early History of Institutions. Holding a Professorship of both Jurisprudence and Political Economy, he was led to apply that method to the examination of economic questions, and to look at the present economic structure and state of society from Sir Henry Maine’s point of view, as the result of a long evolution. Further investigation has convinced him that the English economist of the future must study in the schools of both Mr. Stubbs and Sir Henry Maine, as well as in that of Mr. Mill.” t In 1869 he was appointed Examiner in Political Economy to the University of London, which post he held for five years. Biographical Notice of the Author. Xl visits at once so instructive and so interesting.’ In these excur- sions he made the acquaintance of several distinguished persons, amongst others of M. Léonce de Lavergne and M. Emile de Laveleye. To the memory of the former of these he afterwards paid a graceful tribute in a biographical sketch (Essay x11. in the present volume), and to the close of his life there existed between himself and M. de Laveleye relations of mutual esteem and cordial intimacy. Two essays of Leslie’s appeared in volumes published under the auspices of the Cobden Club, one on the ‘Land System of France,’ containing an earnest defence of la petite culture, and still more of la petite propriété; the other on ‘Financial Reform’ (1871), in which he exhibited in detail the impediments to production and commerce arising from indirect taxation. Many other articles were contributed by him to Reviews, including several discussions of the history of prices and the movements of wages in Europe, and a sketch of life in Auvergne in his best manner; the most important of them, however, related to the philosophical method of political economy, notably a memorable one which appeared in the Dublin University periodical ‘Hermathena.’ In 1879 the Provost and Senior Fellows of Trinity College published for him a volume in which a number of these articles were collected, under the title of ‘Essays in Political and Moral Philosophy.’ These and some later essays, which ought one day to be united with them,* together with the earlier volume on ‘ Land Systems,’ form the essential contribution of Leslie to our economic literature. He had long contemplated, and had in part written, a work on English economic and legal history, which would have been his magnum opus—a more substantial fruit of his genius and his labours than anything he has left us. But the manu- script of this treatise, after much pains had already been spent on it, was unaccountably lost at Nancy in 1872; and though he hoped to be able speedily to reproduce the missing portion and finish the work, it is feared that but a small part of it, if any, has been left in a state fit for publication.t What the nature of it would have been may be gathered from an Essay on the ‘ History and Future of Interest and Profit’ (Essay xvii. in the present volume), which is believed to have been in substance an extract from it. * The later Essays, here spoken of, are included in the present volume. t+ The fear expressed above has since been confirmed; no part of the work was left in such a state as would admit of its publication. X11 Biographical Notice of the Author. That he was able to do so much may well be a subject of wonder, when it is known that his labours had long been impeded by a painful and depressing malady, from which he suffered severely at intervals, whilst he never felt secure from its recurring attacks. To this disease he in the end succumbed at Belfast, whither he had gone to discharge his professorial duties, on the 27th of January, 1882, in the fifty-fifth year of his age. A ed Ca Fp ESSAYS IN POLITICAL ECONOMY. I. THE LOVE OF MONEY.* Tue Love of Money has always been in more or less disrepute with moralists. They have almost universally assigned to it nearly the lowest place in the scale of human affections. We say of human affections, for it is one which distinguishes man from all other animals, however intelligent. ‘You call me dog,’ said Shylock to the Christian merchant; ‘hath a dog money?’ Phrenologists have indeed laid down that all the propensities—combativeness, destructiveness, philoprogenitive- ness, alimentiveness, love of life, &c.—are ‘common to man with the lower animals;’ but we are suprised that they have not discovered a peculiar protuberance on the outside of the human head corresponding with a peculiar propensity for money inside it. It is the more to be regretted that they have not - ascertained the locality of this organ, since a claim has been set up on behalf of the lower animals to a close relationship to the human family. Ifa bump of philargyriveness or philonomis- mativeness could be shown on the human head, a conspicuous absence of this manifestation on the cranium of the former would enable us to disprove the connection, to the satisfaction at least of believers in phrenology. It would not, however, enable us, without further inquiry, to determine whether the love of money, which distinguishes us from the brutes, * This Essay was published in November, 1862, in a periodical which has ceased to exist. \ B 2 7 The Love of Money. places us above or below them in moral character. To satisfy ourselves on this point, we must begin by inquiring what this thing ‘Money,’ of which men, and men only, are so fond, consists of. Sir Robert Peel’s celebrated question—‘ What is the meaning of that word, a Pound, with which we are all familiar ?’—was answered by himself in terms to the effect that a pound of money is a fixed quantity of gold or silver. But this answer, though highly appropriate to a discussion on the currency, is irrelevant to our present inquiry, whether money is a good or an evil; and whether the love of it is a good or a bad quality in mankind. Sir Robert Peel very justly ridiculed the definition given by one writer on the currency of a pound, as ‘a sense of value in reference to currency as compared with commodities.’ Yet in practical life this is really something like what men generally mean and want by money. ‘They mean so much goods; so much of the commodities for sale in the market of the world. A pound to a ‘navvy,’ for instance, is so much beer and tobacco; to his‘mother it is so much tea and sugar. But these two cases are sufficient to show the extreme difficulty of pronouncing any moral judgment whatever upon the love of money, considered as a general human propensity ; for the love of tea and sugar is universally admitted to be in itself an innocent affection, while the love of beer and tobacco is often condemned as combining two most pernicious desires. The love of money is really only a phrase for the love of a vast number of different things, which may be good, bad, or indifferent, regarded from a moral, religious, eesthetical, political, or medical point of view, but which are alike in one respect—namely, that they are all to be had for money, and are not to be had without it. As Solomon said, ‘A feast is made for laughter, and wine maketh merry ; but money answereth all things.’ The love of money is that universal desire for wealth from which political economists have deduced a theory of commercial values, along with several important truths respecting the conditions of industrial energy and prosperity. Everybody wishes for some kind of wealth, and money is convertible into every other kind; and therefore every- body loves money for some purpose or other, from which we get The Love of Money. 3 the laws of competition, prices, wages, profits, and rent. Yet this general principle of pecuniary interest or love of riches by no means explains all the phenomena of the economic world. Tor it is, as we have said already, only a single expression for a great variety of wants, wishes, and tastes, which are not always the same from age to age, or from country to country, nor felt alike by every individual in any one age or country, and which, moreover, lead to very different consequences as regards the nature, amount, and distribution of wealth, and as regards the material as well as the moral welfare of human society. That disease of language which metaphysicians call the realism of the sehools still infests many of the terms and phrases which philosophy must employ. —I am. ‘2374. Do you farm your own land ?—I do. ‘2375. Have you given attention to the subject of rating ? —lI have. * * * * * * On the different rates of wages of agricultural labour in England and their causes, see the present writer’s Land Systems of Ireland, England, and the Continent, pp. 853-4, 357-79. On the Working Classes. 397 ‘2432. Is this a fair way to state your opinion, that the owner does not reduce the rent in consequence of the rise in the rates P—Certainly he does not; I believe that during the last thirty years, when the rate has nearly doubled, nearly the whole of the increase has been paid by the occupier. ‘2433. Because there has been no readjustment of the rent ? —LExactly; rents are not readjusted very often. Farming is one of those fluctuating businesses that an owner does not read- just his rent very often, perhaps not even for one or more lives. 2435. ‘Then you have this curious result, that though a farmer’s profits must be enormously affected by a rise in the rates, which you have described as 100 per cent., nevertheless it has had no influence on the rent >—Very little indeed. ‘2445. Have the farmers’ profits diminished generally in your neighbourhood ?—No; I think not.’ But more general incidences of the rates, both in country and town, have to be considered. In the first place, on whom do the rates on the houses occupied by working people, both in country and town, fallP Secondly, what is the effect of the poor-rate on wages? It would save a world of trouble to follow, in respect to the first question, the formula that the builders of houses and investors in house property must get the average rate of profit, and therefore the rates must fall on the occupiers, whether working people or not. It gives, too, an air of com- plete command over the subject, and of rigorous logic, to argue strictly from assumptions such as the equality of profits. But there are really no such short cuts to the end of economic inquiries. In one of the excellent articles on finance which M. Leroy-Beaulieu, an economist of very high reputation, and editor of the Economiste Francais has recently contributed to that useful journal, it is shown that there are no external character- istics by which the State can measure, for the purpose of an income-tax, the profits of business. ‘The system is in its very nature defective. One of its principal faults is, that it can throw no light on the individual profits of each trader : it has, in fact, for its base the supposed average profit which each class of traders may reasonably obtain. In this system, therefore, 398 The Incidence of Imperial and Local Taxation individual injustices must alway sbe numerous.’»—(Hconomiste Francais, December 20, 1873.) Nevertheless, the State has a thousand times better means of ascertaining the actual profits of every business than any private person in business can have, inasmuch as it can make it the business of a large staff to collect information on the subject in every locality, while each man in business must mind his own business, instead of the business of other people all over the country. What would be thought of a project to assess the taxpayers under Schedule D to the income- tax, on an assumption that every man actually makes the same percentage of profit on his capital? Such, verily, is the assump- tion on which the common theory of the incidence, alike of local rates, of customs, and excise duties, is based: a theory which suits large and successful capitalists, no doubt ; it justifies both low wages and high prices; and it serves as a screen for enor- mous profits from the competition of ‘low men’—to borrow the language of a high authority in such matters—who would ‘ cut in’ if they knew the real state of affairs. A flagrant ignoratio elenchi in economics has arisen from this readiness to ‘cut in’; it is put forward as proving that profits are, by consequence, equalized. ‘The fact that capital deserts losing businesses for others in which extraordinary profits are made, proves only that profits are actually very unequal. The new capital, moreover, often comes in only for a loss at the turn of the tide, after the earlier men in the trade have doubled their capitals, and a fresh inequality is the real consequence. Take the common case of building-ground to be let for ninety-nine years, and consider for one moment the nature of the assumption that the profit on houses is determined by the knowledge which capitalists have of the profits of all investments, and the consequent equalization of building with other profits. The profits of each occupation vary, as we have seen, with different individuals, from immense gain to utter ruin, and vary at different times in the case of the same individual. We are told by Mr. Brassey’s biographer that there were times when he would have died a poor man; and he might have died a poor man had the economic assumption been well founded, and had other people known the real state of his On the Working Classes. 399 business. The same capitalist, in several cases known to myself, is making profits on different investments under his own management, varying from upwards of 100 per cent. to a balance on the wrong side. Adam Smith, writing at a time when the number of employments for capital was com- paratively insignificant, when the modes of carrying on business were almost stationary, when speculation was a much less active element than now, and when all the conditions of an estimate of the profits of different businesses were comparatively simple, said :—‘ It is not easy to ascertain what are the average wages of labour even in a particular place, and at a particular time. We can, even in this case, seldom determine more than what are the most usual wages; but even this can seldom be done with regard to the profits of stock. Profit is so fluctuating that the person who carries on a particular trade cannot always tell you himself what is the average of his annual profit. It is affected not only by every variation of price in the commodities he deals in, but by the good or bad fortune both of his rivals and of his customers, and by a thousand other accidents to which goods, when carried either by sea or land, or even when stored in a warehouse, are liable. It varies, therefore, not only from year to year, but from day to day, and even from hour to hour. To ascertain what is the average profit of all the different trades carried on in a great kingdom must be much more difficult ; and to judge of what it may have been formerly, or in remote periods of time, must be altogether impossible.’ The doctrine by which eminent economists of our own day affect to determine the incidence of rates assumes much more than the knowledge of which Adam Smith demonstrated the impossibility. It assumes that capitalists not only know the past and present profits of all occupations and investments, but foreknow them at remote periods—to the end of a long building- lease, for example. Yet it is clearly impossible for persons contemplating the building or buying of new houses to foretell, even for twenty years, the profits that single investment will yield. The movements of business and population, the demand for houses and other buildings, the increase of wealth and 400 The Incidence of Imperial and Local Taxation money, and the general range of incomes and prices, the supply of new houses on the spot, the means of locomotion bringing other districts within reach, all defy calculation. The under- ground railway defeated the expectations of many house-owners. in London. There are indeed house-agents who will affect to tell you the rate of profit on houses, just as there are actuaries who profess to be able to capitalize and assess to the income-tax the profits of every man in every business, though of two men assessed at the same rate, one will be bankrupt within the year, and the other will make money for half a century, and die richer than Mr. Brassey. The truth is that the profits of house property, the rents that can be exacted from occupiers, and the incidence of rates, depend on no such fiction as ‘the average rate of profit,’ but on the demand for and the supply of houses, and these conditions vary from time to time, and from place to place. The house-builder, having cast in his lot with house and ground, and covenanted to pay a ground-rent, determined, not by any knowledge of the profits of all occupations, but simply by the local demand for and supply of building-ground, afterwards makes such terms as he can with his tenants. And the constant increase of population, the narrow limits of distance from their business within which it is convenient to most people to live, and the cost and trouble to existing occupiers of removal, give the owner, in most cases, the stronger position, and enable him to throw any increase in the rates on the occupier. But, on the other hand, if rates were abolished, house-owners in most places might exact some addition to their rent, and to that extent they may be said to pay a part of the present rates in reduced rents; their power of raising the rent on the abolition of rates being limited, not by any ‘ average rate of profit,’ but by the supply and demand for houses, and the encouragement to building which the prospect of higher rents might occasion. No universal or strict rule, therefore, can be laid down on the subject; but, generally speaking, the occupier is the weaker party, and the chief burden of the rates can be laid upon him. In the case of occupiers of the working class, the inquiries I have been able to make lead to the conclusion that, generally On the Working Classes. 401 speaking, the bulk of the rates falls either directly, or indirectly in rent, upon them; but as rent usually could and would be somewhat raised, were rates to be done away with, a part may be said to fall on the houseowner. It would be unfair, at the same time, to take no account of the fact that on some large estates, owing to the liberality of the landlords, the payment of the rates on the cottages of labourers falls altogether on the former. So differently, indeed, are labourers circumstanced in respect of both house-rents and rates, as well as of wages, in different places, that in one parish I know of, belonging to a large proprietor, the labourer pays only £2 12s. for a decent cottage and garden, and nothing for rates; while in neighbouring parishes, in which the rate of wages is the same, he pays £6 for a worse house without garden, and the rates in addition. The estate of the great landlord is, to speak fairly, in most cases, the best estate for the labourer to live on. Where great landlords and great estates injure the working classes, are as buttresses of a system which keeps land out of the market, obstructs agriculture, manufactures, and trade, and causes the very notion of little farms to appear a chimera to the untravelled Englishman. The only conclusion we can come to with respect to the incidence of rates, as between owner and occupier, is that generally the working man, as occupier of a house in country or town, pays (sometimes to a man as poor as himself) all the rent that can be screwed out of him. A little more could be screwed out of him were there no rates, and to that extent the rates may be said to fall on the owner, the remainder being borne by the workman. Even where the local authorities exempt the occupier from the payment of rates on the score of poverty, the rent is often raised in proportion. But it must not be forgotten that, whatever may be the incidence of the rates, as between owner and occupier, working men are now, in a considerable number of cases, the owners of the houses they occupy, and bear the whole burden of the rates, even where _ their houses are mortgaged. In not a few cases, moreover, the owners of the cottages occupied by workmen are themselves 2D 402 The Incidence of Imperial and Local Taxation working men; and here, too, whatever the incidence of the rates, as between owner and occupier, working men pay the entire amount. It is estimated that there are 2000 building societies in England, and although the English building societies do not build, they advance money to working people both to build and to buy houses, and the number of houses consequently owned by men and women of those classes in some places is truly prodigious.* ‘We have,’ says a witness connected with some of the chief building societies in Birmingham, in evidence be- fore the Friendly and Building Societies’ Commission, ‘ 13,000 houses in Birmingham belonging to our working men. We have streets more than a mile long, in which absolutely every house belongs to the working classes.” The value of a working- man’s house, and the amount of the rates on it, are sometimes considerable. ‘'T'o-morrow,’ says another witness before the Commission, ‘I have to settle an advance to a workman on the Metropolitan Railway ; we are to lend him £360 ; he has bought a house for £420.’ The amount of local taxation on a town workman’s house is, in short, sometimes actually not far below the amount paid by a millionaire, who keeps only an office in town, and livesin a parish where rates are low. But it is not town workmen only who pay rates as owners of houses. The famous Mr. Joseph Arch, for example, has long been a village ratepayer, as owner of a house left to him by his mother. Two other classes of working people ought not to be left unnoticed, who are neither owners nor occupiers of whole houses, but letters of lodgings and lodgers. The vestry clerk of St. Leonard’s, Shoreditch, gave the following evidence before the Poor-rates Assessment Committee of 1868, with respect to inhabitants of houses of £10 a-year rateable value in eats parish :— ‘2543. Do you know in what way those people are employed * A useful Essay on English Building Societies has been published by Mr, Ernst von Plener (lately First Secretary to the Austrian Embassy in London, now a Member of the Austrian Parliament), the author of a History of English Factory Legislation, of which an English translation was procured by Mr. Mundella. On the Working Classes. 403 who live in those houses? —A great many of them have stalls in the street, and they go out with hearthstones, and there are a great many birdcatchers and brickmakers. ‘2544. Are there many bricklayers and masons’ labourers in your parish P—Yes, there are a good many bricklayers, and a good many cabinet-makers. ‘2546. Do those people chiefly take in lodgers in their houses P—A. great many of them take a house—for instance, widows, and those sort of people—and let it out to lodgers.’ The vestry clerk of Bethnal Green also gave evidence :— ‘2707. Are the people who occupy a £10 house, even though they pay a weekly rent, unable to pay their rates P— In many instances they take in lodgers, and with that they are scarcely able to get along.’ It may be assumed, for the reasons given above respecting occupiers, that in such cases the letter of the lodging in the first instance generally pays at least the greater part of the rates in rent, but the question follows—Is it finally paid by the lodging-letter or by the lodgers? The stoutest advocate of ‘the average rate of profit,’ as the key to the incidence of taxation, will hardly contend that costermongers, sellers of hearthstones, birdeatchers, bricklayers, and poor widows in Shoreditch are accurately informed respecting the rates of profit to be made in every trade and investment. ‘The case, indeed, falls within one of the exceptions which Adam Smith emphatically made to the doctrine of a tendency of the gains of different occupations in the same neighbourhood to equality— exceptions which deprive the doctrine of all application to the profits of English trade at the present day. There is no general principle to determine the incidence of rates in the case of the lodgings of poor workpeople. We can only assume that the letters of such lodgings get as much rent as they can, but its payment is precarious; and even if they succeed in shifting both their own rent and the rates on their lodgers, they pay themselves for the exemption in discomfort and injury to health. And whether they or the lodgers are the real ratepayers, the rate falls on a working class. Nor does the incidence of local 2D 2 404 The Incidence of Imperial and Local Taxation taxation on the working classes end there. Both as consumers and as producers, they are likewise contributors to local rates levied on shops and other trade premises, and to tolls and dues for roads, bridges, canals, ferries, fairs, markets, and harbours. They contribute as consumers, like other classes, when the price of the commodities they use is enhanced by such local taxation. And they pay much more heavily as small producers and dealers, when their business is unremunerative, and they fail to recover their outgoings. It has been demonstrated already that so-called indirect imperial taxes are often crushing direct taxes on poor working men and women with a small stock in trade; and local taxation, too, is sometimes the last straw that breaks the back of the petty trader. It is, therefore, certain that, on the whole, the working classes bear out of their scanty incomes an amount of local taxation in rates which forms a heavy addition to their imperial taxation. What, then, if nearly one-half of the whole amount levied in rates is applied in a manner which makes it, in fact, to a great extent a deduc- tion from wages? What if, in addition, a great part of the remainder of the local revenue is applied to purposes from which the owners of property derive the chief, and, in some cases, the whole advantage, as in the case of various permanent local improvements, and other objects of local expenditure which raise the value of land and buildings? | Out of nearly twenty-two millions of local taxation in Eng- land and Wales, between seventeen and eighteen millions are raised directly by rates, and of this amount about eight millions are applied, directly or indirectly, to the relief of the poor. But that the relief of the poor cheapens labour, and is to a considerable extent taken out of wages, as Mr. Purdy and Mr. Thorold Rogers have argued, appears incontrovertible. I by no means go the length of saying that its operation in that respect can be nicely calculated, or that the whole of the fund raised for the relief of the poor—who must not in that sense be confounded with the working classes, many of whom never get any relief, and who are not the only classes relieved—is prac- tically a deduction from wages. But it is certain that, were On the Working Classes. 405 it not for the poor-rate, there would be a smaller supply of labour, and a higher rate of wages Both the preventive and the positive checks to population would act in inereased force. There would be fewer improvident marriages and more emi- gration, on the one hand; and more deaths from sickness and want, more vagrancy and mendicancy, on the other hand. If the poor-rate were abolished, the difference would not all go into the pockets either of landlords or farmers in the country, or of owners or occupiers in towns; for wages would certainly rise in both country and town. And it follows that many members of the working classes contribute in poor-rates to a fund from which they not only derive no advantage, but which is so applied that it diminishes their own earnings. They are taxed, therefore, twice to the poor-rate; and they are taxed further for local improvements, from which a wealthier class derives the chief benefit. It is not, indeed, possible to measure exactly the amount of benefit derived by different classes from the objects of either imperial or local taxation. And few falser maxims of finance have ever been propounded than that of the great French economist, M. Say, which Sir William Harcourt appears to follow, that ‘the best system of finance is to spend little, and the best taxation is that which is least in amount.’ On the contrary, as Mr. Wells observes in a Report on the local taxation of New York, ‘ probably there is no act which can be performed by a community, which brings in so large a return to the credit of civilization and general happiness, as the judicious expenditure, for public purposes, of a percentage of the general wealth raised by an equitable system of taxation. It will be found to be a general rule that no high degree of civilization can be maintained in a community, and indeed no highly civilized community can exist, without comparatively large taxation.’ Mr. Wells cites, in the same Report, the wise remark of Mr. Jevons:—‘There is sure to be a continuous increase of local taxation. We may hope for a reduction of the general expenditure, and we shall expect rather to reduce than raise the weight of duties; but all the more immediate needs of society—boards of health, medical officers, public 406 The Incidence of Imperial and Local Taxation schools, reformatories, free libraries, highway boards, main- drainage schemes, water supplies, purgation of rivers, improved police, better poor-laws—these and a score of other costly reforms must be supported mainly out of local rates.’ The working classes undoubtedly share the benefits of such in- stitutions, but a much larger share often accrues to a wealthier class, whose contribution, in proportion to their ability, is immeasurably smaller. Local improvements in towns, for ex- ample, whether made by municipal authority or by great com- panies, often raise prodigiously the value of the property of the: rich, while causing only loss and distress to working people, whom they disturb from their dwellings, whose rents they raise, and who do not remain long enough to participate in the ulti- mate advantages. As in the case of imperial, so in the case of local taxation, I make no pretence to offer an exact estimate of the relative burdens imposed on the working and other classes. But the candid reader who has followed the investigation which my limits have narrowly circumscribed must, I think, be convinced that, on the one hand, imperial taxation falls with enormously disproportionate weight on the working classes; and, on the other hand, local taxation, in place of redressing, greatly ag- gravates the inequality. I will venture only to add that, under these circumstances, to abolish the income-tax on Schedule D (which includes many of the wealthiest and least taxed men in the world), instead of repealing the duties on sugar and tea, would be a monstrous injustice. In a debate in the House of Commons on local taxation, in 1872, Mr. Rathbone, M.P. for Liverpool, said: ‘ Local taxation, as at present levied, pressed heavily on labour as compared with capital, and the wealthiest classes were allowed to escape from paying anything like their fair share of the rates. In the case of London, or any other sea- port where merchants were the wealthy class, and their visible personal estate consisted mainly of ships and stock-in-trade of great value, the anomaly became apparent. It was this class who directly or indirectly derived benefit from the labouring classes, so long as they were earning wages, and escaped almost On the Working Classes. 407 entirely when they became chargeable. From inquiry into a number of cases he had ascertained that many large merchants and brokers were only paying one-half to two per cent. (in rates), while the labouring men in their employ were paying twice to seven times as much in proportion to their income. In a word, a merchant, or shipowner, deriving an income of £15,000 a-year from a capital of £150,000, paid £62 in rates on his counting-house and warehouses, and £65 on his suburban residence assessed at £450 a-year. The young doctor or solicitor paid £14 out of his income of £600 a-year on his £60 house; and the labourer £2 8s. 9d. out of his £1 4s. a-week on his 4s. cottage. Thus an income of £15,000 a-year paid less than 1 per cent. ; an income of £600 a-year paid 24 per cent. ; and an income of £1 4s. a-week paid 4 per cent.’ Lake also the evidence of a witness before the Select Com- mittee on Local Taxation :— | 2792. You are a Justice of the Peace at Liverpool P—I am. ‘2793. Have you been a member of the Town Council at Liverpool P—Yes, for many years. £2938. ...