A FEW REMARKS ON THE EVIDENCE RECEIVED BY THE IRISH TAXATION COMMITTEE. A FEW EE MARKS ON THE EVIDENCE EECEIVED BY THE IRISH TAXATION COMMITTEE. TOGETHER WITH 21 brief rebtefo of tfje subject. THE O’CONOR DON, M.P. (9 ' cJLa^ jJIsLa (bus-tr DUBLIN: JOHN F. FOWLER, 3 CROW STREET, DAME STREET. 1865. PEEFACE. Although the subject with which I propose to deal in the following pages may, to an ordinary reader, appear uninteresting; yet, as it is one which at all times has provoked much discussion, and has latterly occupied much public attention, I venture to think that a short record of the main facts elicited by the Committee of Inquiry may not be quite useless. It is true that a record of these facts can be found in the Blue Books published by parliament; but still, so few would take the trouble of wading through the great mass of evidence therein contained, I have endea- voured to abstract what seemed to me the princi- pal points of interest. I am not at all blind to the difficulties at- tendant on dealing with this question, and to the objection, that the whole inquiry by the Committee was useless or futile, as taxation at 11 the present day must be guided by the general interests of the empire, and cannot be made dependent on transactions completed more than half a century ago. Yet, admitting this principle to the fullest ex- tent, it may not be uninteresting or wholly use- less to examine how far the different theories re- lating to those transactions are really correct. It is constantly said, and I do not dispute the truth of the statement, that equality in bearing im- perial burdens is the only true claim to equality in imperial privileges. Nevertheless, we may with profit consider how far the former equality has been attained, and in what it consists. To give a short review of the main features of the case up to 1817, — to follow the progress of taxation towards equality since that period, — to show the various effects of the remission and imposition of taxes, — and to examine the relative positions of Great Britain and Ireland at the present day as regards taxation, — are, then, my principal objects in the following pages. For the figures which I quote, I rely chiefly on the returns presented by Mr. Chisholm on behalf Ill of the Treasury. Into the dispute relative to their accuracy I do not at all enter. In some instances, on account of the different forms in which almost similar returns have been drawn up, I have found it difficult to determine which to select; but, on the whole, I trust my quotations are in the main correct. That many grounds existed for the appointment of the Committee, I fully believe; that its labours have not been fruitless, I equally trust; and that it elicited many curious facts worthy of the con- sideration of those to whom is entrusted the ma- nagement of the public finances, I hope to show. Should I succeed in establishing any of these points, I will not have written fruitlessly; and I must now ask such of my readers as take an in- terest in the question, to bear with me for a time, whilst endeavouring to place before them the results of an investigation into what I trust they will not consider a tedious, wearisome, and barren subject. CHAPTER L GENERAL VIEW OF THE SUBJECT. The Report of the Irish Taxation Committee, and the evidence on which it is founded, have now been, for a short time, before the public, and with regard to the merits of both, very contradictory views seem to be entertained. The report has been made the subject of various articles both in the British and Irish press, and from the frequent allusions to it, the topic is evidently one which, although dry and uninviting in its general cha- racter, yet commands a considerable amount of interest. Whether Ireland has been overtaxed, undertaxed, or justly taxed; whether she received a financial benefit from the Act of Union and the proceedings which followed it; whether the trans- actions of those days have anything to do with the present taxation of the empire; or whether we are now justified in looking to anything but abso- lute similarity in taxation, are all questions on which the most contradictory opinions have been held. To a great extent, since the amalgamation of the exchequers and the thorough financial union 1 / 2 in 1817, Ireland has had no separate financial history. Since that period, Great Britain and Ire- land have, for practical purposes, formed hut the one kingdom, and yet, when dealing, even with the taxation of the present day, it is necessary to refer to the past as something more than historically interesting. That complaints have been and are made on the part of Ireland that taxation there is excessive, we know to be a fact; that those com- plaints are backed up by a reference to the trans- actions between 1800 and 1817, we know to be equally true; and although the justice of those complaints is denied, and this reference to past transactions disputed, yet such a reference cannot be banished from any investigation into the sub- ject. Since the year 1817, according to some, Ireland ceased to have any claim to separate financial existence, or to exceptional treatment. At the present day she is politically, legislatively, and financially as much an integral part of the United Kingdom as any English county, and, according to this view, has as little claim for separate consi- deration as Yorkshire or Lancashire. Conse- quently, it is said, in considering the taxation to which she is subject, we have only to examine whether it is exceptionally oppressive, or whether there is any burden on any Irish manufacture or industry from which a similar manufacture or industry in any other portion of the empire is free. That this theory is not universally admitted, I 3 need hardly mention; but, before entering on the consideration of the facts on which the different views are supported, it may be well clearly to understand the essence of the difference. Assuming no ground for exceptional consider- ations to exist in the fact of Ireland’s former in- dependent condition, and banishing altogether from our view the transactions subsequent to the Union, yet there are many who would be far from admitting that similar taxation over the whole United Kingdom must be equal, or that it is a matter of indifference to the various portions of the empire in what that taxation consists. Were the condition of the people everywhere alike; were their habits, wants, and mode of living similar; had they the same manufactures and commerce, and were there no difference in the natural productions of the soil and the mineral treasures of the earth, then, no doubt, similar taxation would everywhere produce similar results. But so long as this is not the case, it is a mistake to argue that nothing has to be looked to but similarity in the nature of im- posts, and it is equally erroneous to hold that similar taxes must necessarily equally affect the different portions of the empire. Even, then, those who are ready to disregard all reference to the former relations between Great Britain and Ireland, may not be ready to admit that taxation at the present day, because similar throughout the United Kingdom, is not more oppressive on Ireland, or that a comparison as to 4 the relative burdens on each country is absolutely futile. If this be the case with regard to those who are willing to forget the fact of Ireland’s former independent existence, how much more is it true in regard to those who hold that that financial independence was lost through over- taxation and unjust treatment ! To understand the subject properly, it is, then, absolutely necessary we should turn to a consideration of the relations which existed between Great Britain and Ireland immediately after the Union in 1800; and hence a great portion of the time of the Committee was devoted to this point. In connection with this it is worthy of remark, that in all the discussions which have taken place as to the taxation of Ireland, whether conducted by word of mouth or through articles or letters in the public press, it is practically admitted by all sides, that reference must be made to what took place in the seventeen years succeeding the Union. Those who hold that Ireland is only fairly taxed, do so on the grounds that after the Union she failed to meet her engagements; that,' failing to meet them, and getting involved in debt, she bene- fited by the Amalgamation Act; and that now she is not subject to any tax from which Great Britain is exempt. On the other hand, those hold- ing the opposite view, maintain that the engage- ments into which Ireland entered in 1800 were practically too onerous ; that, in spite of this, she held up to them; and that even admitting that the 5 advantages which in 1800 she possessed, were, by subsequent events, forfeited; yet the mere fact of their being no exceptional tax on Ireland is no proof that that country is not more heavily bur- dened than Great Britain. We thus at once perceive that in the various views which have been put forward regarding Imperial taxation, there are two essential points of difference: differences as to facts, and differences as to principle. Differences as to the facts of the case between the years 1800 and 1817, differences as to principle in regard to the taxation of the present day. When we examine closely the grounds of what I may term the Irish side of the case, we will find that they mainly rest on the assumption that the principle of the Act of Union, viz. taxation in pro- portion to resources, ought still to be the rule. A fixed proportionate contribution with dissimilar taxation, may not be claimed; it may even be ad- mitted that the advantages which, in 1800, Ireland possessed, in being subject to a smaller debt, have since been forfeited; but still the main principle of the Act of Union, though not clearly and openly, is yet not the less decisively, insisted on, and the complaints that Ireland is overtaxed, are really complaints that this principle is not adhered to. With some, the complaints go even further. The advantages lost to Ireland through the transac- tions between 1800 and 1817 are not admitted to have been justly lost, and, therefore, before pro- 6 ceeding to the consideration of taxation at the present day, we would do well to look for a moment to the main features of the case up to the year 1817. Before the year 1800, Great Britain and Ireland were financially and legislatively two distinct and independent kingdoms. In that year a legislative union was brought about, but in consequence of a difference in the pressure of debt on the two countries, a financial union was not effected. An arrangement was entered into under which each country was to provide for its own debt, and to contribute towards the Imperial expenditure in certain fixed proportions, supposed to be adjusted according to the relative ability of each. As the debt of Ireland at that time was comparatively smaller than the debt of Great Britain, Ireland, so far, possessed an advantage. This advantage, according to the theory of the Act of Union, she was to retain. She was to contribute to the gene- ral expenditure only in proportion to her resources, and had to meet besides only the charge of her own smaller debt. In addition to this, it was provided that, should the two debts at any time come into the same proportions as the resources, the system of separate contribution might be abolished and general tax- ation established in its stead, always supposing that this general system would affect the two countries similarly; and as the principle of a sink- ing fund was then in full operation, the equaliza- 7 tion of the two debts through their partial or entire liquidation, did not then seem an impossi- bility. Such were the principles embodied in the treaty of union, and with regard to their abstract fair- ness, I do not believe much dispute has ever been entertained. In form, the treaty was loosely drawn up, and as events turned out, some of its provisions are difficult of interpretation. It is not, however, to these forms or principles that we are chiefly to look, but rather to the results produced by this financial arrangement. However just in the abstract a system of pro- portionate contribution might have been, its prac- tical fairness of course consisted in the proper selection of the proportions in which the contribu- tions were to be made. These were fixed by Lord Castlereagh at two parts for Ireland to fifteen for Great Britain, or, of every £100 required, Ireland was to furnish £11 15s., and Great Britain £88 5s. That these proportions were ever just is denied by many; that, if at first just, they soon ceased to be so, is generally maintained; but, no doubt, they were originally selected, because it was supposed that the resources of the two countries were in the same proportions. In the year 1800, before the arrangement was inaugurated, the funded unredeemed debt of Great Britain was about 420,000,000,* and her un- funded debt about £37, 800, 000, f whilst her gross * Ap. to Report, 1864, p. 396. t Ibid., p. 396. 8 revenue after deducting drawbacks amounted to £84,979,727.* * * § In the year ending January, 1817, her unredeemed funded debt had risen to £682,5 20,03 3 ;f her unfunded debt was valued at £44,650,600,J and her revenue or receipts from taxation amounted to £64,577,839.§ In the year 1800, the Irish funded debt amounted to £26,841,219, the unfunded debt to £1,699,938, and the revenue to £3,159,214. || At the end of the year 1816 this was all changed, and then the account stood as follows : funded unre- deemed debt, £113,680,158 unfunded debt about £5,000,000;** and gross revenue after de- ducting drawbacks about £6,000,000. It thus appears that in those sixteen years the debt of Great Britain had increased more than 62 per cent., and its taxation more than 84 per cent., whilst the debt of Ireland had increased more than 320 per cent., and its taxation more than 100 per cent., and the debts of the two countries, which in 1800 were to each other in the propor- tion of about 1 to 15, were in 1816 in the pro- portions of about 1 to 6. With such results as these, it is not a subject for wonder that great dissatisfaction should have * Return No. 110, session 1865. t Ap. to Report, 1864, p. 402. I Ap. to Report, 1864, p. 410. § P. 344, Ap. to Report. This sum is calculated by deduct- ing from gross receipts within the year drawbacks and pay- ments from Ireland. |l Return No. 110, session 1865. ^ Ap. to Report, 1864, p. 402. ** Ibid., p. 410. 9 been felt on the part of Ireland, or that a belief should exist that she was unfairly treated. To the Irishman the conclusion that his country was grossly wronged was almost irresistible. Look- ing to the Act of Union, he found indications that Ireland would be a great gainer by its being passed; he saw in it the existence of surpluses pro- vided for the extinction of debts contemplated. He found there special provisions for keeping all post union debts as joint debts, and also other clauses, ambiguous to be sure, which perhaps he interpreted as preventing the increase of separate debts after the union. Looking to the results, he found that, instead of a surplus, there was always a deficiency; instead of debt being extinguished, it had enormously increased; and that, in some minor particulars at least, the Act of Union had not been strictly adhered to. Hence he probably, and not unnaturally, concluded that, not only had the Act of Union placed an unjust burden on his country, but that act had been fraudulently carried out. To the Englishman, or one approaching the subject with different feelings, perhaps a different conclusion presented itself. He could not, indeed, deny that the results were very disastrous to Ire- land ; that year after year she was sinking lower in financial infirmity; and that, if things went on much longer in the same way, she would have to succumb to national bankruptcy. Finding, how- ever, that during that period Ireland was free from 10 many taxes to which Great Britain was subject, he concluded, perhaps, that the unhappy position in which the former country found herself was due to her impatience of taxation. To him it seemed that Ireland resembled the reckless spend- thrift, who, disregarding the future, preferred in- curring disastrous obligations, to undergoing, for the moment, any self denials; and if this course in the case of Ireland, as in that of the individual, led to difficulties and proximate bankruptcy, Ire- land, like the individual, was alone to blame. Moreover, he found that in the year 1817, the Imperial Parliament stepped in, saddled Great Britain with the entire of this Irish debt, and established full and perfect equality between the two countries, at a time when the Irish debt was comparatively excessive; from which he concluded that it was Great Britain, and not Ireland, that had reason to complain. To these two very different conclusions may be traced all the disputes and discussions which have taken place both in parliament and elsewhere as to imperial taxation; and as the truth or false- hood of either conclusion rests on the facts of the case up to the year 1817, I purpose in the follow- ing chapters briefly to examine them. 11 CHAPTER II. PROBABLE CAUSES OF INCREASE OF DEBT AND TAXATION BETWEEN 1800 AND 1817. Before entering on the examination of the finan- cial details on which rest the truth or falsehood of the different views referred to in the preceding chapter, it may not he uninteresting to consider those political transactions which during the same period produced such marvellous effects on the finances of the two countries. We have already seen that between 1800 and 1816 the debt of Great Britain had increased from £420,305,944 to £682,520,033, and the debt of Ireland, from £26,841,219 to £113,680,158, whilst at the same time the annual levy of taxation had progressively advanced year by year from £34,979,729 for Great Britain to £64,577,839, and for Ireland from £3,159,214 to £6,000,000. The debt of Great Britain we thus perceive was increased nearly two. thirds, the debt of Ireland was more than qua- drupled, and this with an addition to the annual burdens of taxation in almost similar proportions in the two countries. Looking to the terms of the act of union, quite a different state of things would seem to have been anticipated. The framers of that act evidently ex- pected a steady and perhaps rapid reduction of the debt, and took great care to provide for the distri- bution of a surplus arising out of the receipts 12 from ordinary revenues. In the 7th article of that Act we find the following clauses : — 11 That if at the end of any year, any surplus shall accrue from the revenues of Ireland after defraying the interest, sinking fund, and proportional contributions, and separate charges, to which the said country shall then be liable, taxes shall be taken off to the amount of such surplus , or the sur- plus shall be applied by the parliament of the United King- dom to local purposes in Ireland, or to make good any de- ficiency which may arise in the revenues of Ireland in time of peace, or may be invested by the Commissioners of the National Debt of Ireland in the Funds, to accumulate for the benefit of Ireland at compound interest, in case of the contribution of Ireland in time of war, provided that the surplus so to accumulate shall at no future period be suf- fered to exceed the sum of £5,000,000”. And again : “ That if at any future day the separate debt of each country respectively shall have been liquidated , or if the values of the respective debts shall be to each other in the same proportion with the respective contributions of each country respectively, it shall be competent to the parlia- ment to declare”, etc. On the other hand neither in this nor any other article of the Act of Union is it easy to find any adequate provision for the eventualities which really arose, and hence the great doubts and dif- ficulties thrown on the interpretation of the financial sections of the treaty of Union. Reading this treaty together with the speeches of the statesmen who supported it, and then look- ing to the results which it produced, or rather to the state of things which existed after it had been 13 i in operation sixteen years, we cannot help asking ourselves, how it was that the views so confidently put forward by the most eminent statesmen in 1800, were doomed to be so sadly disappointed, and how it was that a financial treaty professedly arranged on the principle of proportionate equa- lity of burden, very nearly terminated in the financial bankruptcy of Ireland? To answer these questions, it is absolutely neces- sary we should turn for a moment to the conside- ration of the great political events which have ren- dered those sixteen years memorable in the world’s history. During those sixteen years one of the greatest struggles ever recorded was going on; more thrones were overturned, more new dynasties formed, to be dissolved after a brief existence, than, in a like period, the world had ever before seen. Commencing with a directorate,. the French nation had passed under the almost supreme power of a consul, who in a short time changed its constitution into that of an aggressive em- pire. The ephemeral republics of the continent of Europe, formed through French influence, and supported by French power, successively merged into dependent monarchies, and with each and every one of the great powers of Europe did Napoleon in turn wage war. Nor was Great Britain exempt from taking part in those great conflicts. Protected to a great extent by her insular position from direct aggressive attack, no power in Europe was more mixed up with the 14 struggle against French aggression. From first to last, she maintained the defence against France, and, unlike the other powers, was never found the one day the opponent, the next the ally, of the French ruler. Scarcely a year passed which was not made memorable by some great battle or decisive disaster to some of the great powers of Europe. In the year 1805 a confederacy was formed between Great Britain and some of the con- tinental powers, to resist the aggressions of the French, and the same year witnessed the battles of Ulm and Austerlitz, in the former of which the Austrians, in the latter the Russians and the allies, were completely defeated. In 1806 Prussia, who stood practically neutral in the preceding year, when her neighbours were engaged in. a struggle for existence, had to pay the penalty of her inaction, and by the battle of Jena was placed almost at the mercy of Napoleon. In 1807 the battle of Friedland shook the power of Russia, and forced her into alliance with France. In 1808 Joseph Buonaparte was pro- claimed king of Spain, and the tremendous penin- sular struggle commenced. In 1809 the Aus- trians saw their capital occupied by French troops, and after the battle of W agram the humiliating peace of Vienna had to be signed. The years 1810 and 1811 witnessed the great con- flict of the British and French in Spain and Portugal, and the first blow was given to French 15 power by the triumphant defence of the lines of Torres Yedras. 1812 witnessed the campaign of Moscow, and the disastrous retreat which com- pletely turned the tide of prosperity against Napoleon. In 1813 by the battle of Yittoria Joseph Buonaparte was driven out of Spain, and by the battle of Leipsic, in the same year, Napoleon himself was forced to retreat ; the year 1814 saw his downfall and abdication; 1815, his return and final overthrow at Waterloo. In all these eventful proceedings Great Britain took a prominent part. Where her soldiers or sailors were not engaged, there were her warlike stores and her supplies of money, and the armies which assembled on the Elbe and the Danube were at times as dependent for their support on the United Kingdom as those under the command of Wellington in the Peninsula. Nor were British exertions confined to the Continent of Europe. During the same period a war had to be main- tained in America, and though of shorter duration and much less magnitude than the European con- flict, yet through the injury it did her commerce, it tried England’s resources even more than some of the struggles with Napoleon. Considering, then, the vastness of the enterprise undertaken by Great Britain during those fifteen years, we cannot wonder that her expenditure largely increased, and that with a considerable increase of taxation a large addition had still to be made to the national debt. 16 That the great European conflict was not anti- cipated in 1800, is evident from the statements then made, and from the condition in which Europe then was. The French Republic had at that time been in existence about thirteen years, during which it had been in constant warfare with its neighbours; but a term to those conflicts seemed close at hand. France had evidently suffered much both from her own internal commotions and her disagreement with foreign nations, and there was every prospect that before very long some arrangement would be entered into by which the peace of Europe would be restored. The realization of this expectation was not long delayed, and towards the close of the year 1801 negociations were commenced which terminated in the peace of Amiens, by which, ap- parently, the long desired restoration of tranquil- lity was accomplished. The existence of peace, or at least the cessation from any expensive warlike proceedings, in the earlier years after the passing of the Act of Union, made a sensible impression on the condition of the finances of the empire, and accordingly we find that in the first few years, the proportions between debt incurred and taxation levied on Great Britain and Ireland, did not vary very much from the proportions fixed by the treaty, the enormous disproportionate increase in the debt of Ireland being reserved for later times. The hopes, however, raised by the treaty of Amiens were not destined to be of long duration, and, as we have 17 seen, Europe, before the year 1805, was fully en- gaged in that destructive war to which we have alluded. It must not, however, be supposed that the events which occurred in Europe during the period of the war were, in a financial point of view, of unmixed evil to Great Britain. On the contrary, if on the one hand she had to pay largely for the prosecution of the war, on the other, through its instrumentality her trade and commerce received a great impulse. To injure that trade and destroy Britain’s maritime supremacy, was Napoleon’s pet idea; but in this he altogether failed, and although successful in shutting, through what was termed the “ Conti- nental system”, many of the' European ports to British ships, yet any loss consequent on this was more than made up by the development of British colonial power. Moreover, during the entire time Great Britain was internally at peace; no foreign invader disturbed her insular tran- quillity; and, almost the only country in Europe free to cultivate the arts of peace without distur- bance, she became the workshop of Europe. In spite of all the endeavours of Napoleon, the carry- ing trade of the world passed into her hands, and British merchants, manufacturers, and traders, became undoubtedly the great gainers by the paralysed state into which Europe was thrown. Thus, if her taxation were doubled and her debt increased by two-thirds, yet at the end of the 2 18 period she was in a more flourishing financial state than at its commencement. The same unfortunately cannot be said with regard to Ireland. Her commerce was very con- tracted, her trade and manufactures very limited, and although having to contribute her proportion to the increased expenditure, she did not receive similar compensating advantages. As we have seen, the enormous expenditure attendant on the Napoleonic war was not anticipated at the time when the proportion of contribution was arranged, and although Ireland, under ordinary circum- stances, might have been able to contribute two- seventeenths of a peace expenditure, she entirely failed to contribute that proportion by revenue, ■$dien the expenditure had so enormously in- creased. The great European war and the expenses attendant on it, may then to a certain extent account for the fact, that the expectations held out in 1800 were never realized, and that the debt and revenue increased with such rapid strides between 1800 and 1816. 19 CHAPTER III. SEPARATE TAXATION BORNE BY GREAT BRITAIN BETWEEN 1800 AND 1817. In the preceding chapter some of the causes which led to the heavy burdens imposed on the United Kingdom between 1800 and 1816 have been alluded to, but, as before remarked, those burdens were not similarly supported in Great Britain and Ireland. In the former country a far larger proportion of the annual charge was met by revenue than in the latter country, and many taxes were imposed on Great Britain from which Ireland was free. This separate taxation on the part of Great Britain has led to many curious deductions, and, as the most erroneous views seem to have arisen from it, I purpose briefly to examine what appears to me to be the only com elusion which it proves. It is quite clear, in the commencement, that had Ireland met her contribution by revenue in the same proportion as Great Britain did, it would have been a matter of perfect indifference in what way she met it. Whether the taxes she paid were similar to those in use in Great Britain, or whether they were not, she would have equally fulfilled her obligations, and would not have been open to any charge of exemption from taxation. But this was not the case. Ireland’s revenue 20 failed to meet her contributions, a failure ascribed to her exemption from many British taxes; and as the amount contributed by those taxes in Great Britain was very large, the exemption enjoyed by Ireland is set down as being also very consider- able. The amount levied by separate taxes in Great Britain has been variously estimated, and is not very easily arrived at, and to ascertain it now with perfect accuracy would be almost an im- possibility. According to Mr. Chisholm’s re- turns,* it would appear that nearly two-thirds of the revenue of Great Britain was raised by taxes peculiar to that country. Out of a revenue of £888,000,000, he calculates that £582,000,000 were raised by taxes not imposed on Ireland; and this no doubt, at first sight, would lead one to the belief that Ireland must have been very lightly taxed as compared with Great Britain. As some writers have gone so far as to estimate the whole of this £582,000,000 as excessive taxation on the part of Great Britain, it may not be useless to examine in detail how far it really can be con- sidered as such. Before entering on this, however, we must remark that this calculation of £582,000,000 of separate taxation paid by Great Britain, is only an estimate, and that it is an estimate formed on principles which have never been explained, and which therefore it is not easy to follow. * Ap. to Report, session 1865, p. 143. 21 In the year 1834 a return* was presented to parliament purporting to show the gross receipts from excise and taxes levied in Great Britain, but not in Ireland, during the thirty-three pre- ceding years. This return did not particularize the amount received each year, nor did it give in any separate form the receipts between the years 1800 and 1816. In it also appeared a calculation of the separate taxation of Great Britain under the head of customs duty, a calculation, however, based not on the receipts in Great Britain, but on the receipts in Ireland, an estimate being made of what the receipts in the latter country would have been, had the rate of the duty been assimi- lated to the British rate. On this return Mr. Chisholm founds his estimate, with this difference, that he calculates the customs duties, “ as far as can now be ascer- tained”, on the same principle as that followed in the return regarding the excise, and makes an average of the amount contributed each year, which he multiplies by sixteen to discover the receipts between 1800 and 1816. With the cor- rectness of this return, or of Mr. Chisholm’s cal- culations on it, I hardly desire to deal, but still it is necessary to remark that the return itself does not profess to give a correct account of the actual nett receipts from separate taxation in Great Britain, and in the next place, that the system of taking an annual average cannot give Session 1834, No. 194. 22 us anything but a rough idea of the state of things, as the same taxes were not in operation all the time. It is on the principle of the argument arising from the apparent results of this calculation that I wish to dwell, and therefore, for the time being, I will not dispute the correctness of the figures. Assuming then that a large sum, say £500,000,000, was raised in Great Britain by taxes not imposed on Ireland, does this prove that Great Britain paid £500,000,000 of excess as compared with Ireland, or that the latter country was propor- tionately leniently treated? Certainly it does not. In the first place, it does not at all follow, had the taxes through which this large sum was collected, never been imposed, that none of the £500,000,000 would have found its way into the exchequer. On the contrary, we may very con- fidently assert that, in all probability, a very large portion of it would have been received through increased receipts from the other branches of revenue. Moreover, a considerable amount of this £500,000,000 is made up from a calculation of the higher rate of duty charged on certain articles in Great Britain over that charged in Ireland, and to conclude that the entire of this amount was due to the increased duty is clearly a fallacy, as there is scarcely a principle in finance more generally admitted, than that that a reduc- tion in the rate of customs and excise duties does not lead to the loss of the entire revenue con- 23 tributed by the higher duty, a great portion of the loss consequent on the reduction being made up by increased consumption at the lower rates. Therefore, even so far as Great Britain was con- cerned, it would be a most erroneous conclusion to draw from the figures given us, that she paid £500,000,000 in taxation which she would never have raised had the taxation been similar with that of Ireland. Proceeding, however, in our investigation, and assuming that, had her taxation been assimi- lated to that of Ireland, she would have been relieved of £500,000,000 of payments, does this show that the payment of this sum was, as com- pared to Ireland, excessive taxation ? Certainly it does not, unless we assume that the mode of living of the people of the two countries, their habits and customs, the trades in existence there, and the productions of the soil were all similar; because, unless all this be granted, no argument can be derived as to the excessive taxation of Great Britain when compared with Ireland, from a calculation of the amount contributed in the for- mer country by taxes specially levied there. I hardly know whether it is necessary to attempt any illustration of this, but an example may not be useless. Suppose we take two countries, in one of which the common beverage of the people is beer or ale, and in the other wine or spirits, and suppose a common tax on wine or spirits is imposed on 24 both, will this affect each similarly? According to our supposition, in the first country, which we will call A, very little wine or spirits at all is drunk, its use being substituted there by beer or ale, whilst in the second country, B, wine or spirits is the ordinary beverage of the people. Is it not clear that this common tax on wine or spirits presses far more heavily on B than on A, and that with this similar taxation A really is enjoying an exemption, whilst B, as compared with it, is ex- cessively taxed? W ell, supposing that, to meet this inequality, a tax is imposed in A on ale and beer, but that this tax is not imposed in B, how do things then stand? A then may be over-taxed as compared with B; but which does that over- taxation arise from the tax on the beer or the tax on the spirits ? From the preceding comparison it is evident that the tax on the beer was absolutely necessary to put A and B on an equality, and if A has now anything to complain of, it is not the tax on the beer, but the tax on the spirits — a tax on a commodity corresponding to that one which in the other country still remains free from taxation. If then any one were to assume that the whole amount contribu- ted by A under the tax on beer was excessive, because that tax was not extended to B, it is clear that he would assume what in point of fact was completely erroneous. Well, this is exactly what is done when it is assumed that all the revenue raised in Great Britain by separate taxes was 25 excessive taxation. A great amount of these taxes were taxes on articles of almost purely British consumption or production, such as beer, printed calicoes, etc. As they formed the staple articles either of consumption or production, it cannot be said that by a tax on them Great Britain was unduly burdened, unless it can be shown that on corresponding though not similar articles no tax was borne in Ireland. If then it cannot be assumed that the total amount contributed by separate taxes in Great Britain was excessive taxation on that country, still less can it be argued that to a proportionate amount Ireland w~as leniently treated. The ex- emptions enjoyed by Ireland cannot in any pos- sible way be calculated on the basis of the amounts contributed by Great Britain. For instance, be- tween 1800 and 1834, according to the returns of 1834, £40,000,000 were raised in Great Britain by a tax on printed calicoes, from which tax Ire- land was exempt: but surely from this fact it is not possible to ascertain what exemption Ireland enjoyed. Indeed, it is possible, and even probable, that from the non-imposition of certain British taxes the Irish revenue suffered no loss whatever. Had many of these taxes been extended to Ire- land, they would scarcely have paid the cost of collection, whilst on the other hand such an extension, by diminishing the receipts arising from other duties, might rather have injured than in- creased the public income. 26 I think I have therefore shown that from a vague, indefinite, and even incorrect estimate of the amount contributed by Great Britain in separate taxes, no possible conclusion can be drawn either as to the over-taxation of that country, or the under-taxation of Ireland; because equality of taxation in no way depends on simi- larity in the actual taxes, nor can the amount contributed by certain taxes in the one country give us any criterion by which to judge of the amount which would have been contributed by the other, had the same system been adopted in it. I have dwelt particularly on this topic, and gone perhaps into too much detail, because I was anxious carefully to consider an argument often used, and referred to in a preceding chapter, viz., that Ire- land failed to meet her liabilities, and became involved in debt, because she was impatient of taxation and never bore many of the burdens im- posed on Great Britain. Whether this argument is true in fact or not, I do not undertake here to determine, but I think it is pretty clear that it cannot be proved from the fact that a certain large amount of taxation was levied in Great Britain by taxes not extended to Ireland. Had those taxes been made general over the United Kingdom, it is possible that the revenue raised from Ireland might have been less than it was, and at least the actual amount contributed by these taxes in Great Britain affords us no criterion by which to judge of the exemption enjoyed by Ireland. 27 Equality in taxation, or more properly, simi- larity in the taxes imposed, might have been brought about in two ways; either by absolving Great Britain from all those taxes which were not extended to Ireland, or by extending them to the latter country. Had the former system been adopted, and were the calculations concerning the amount realized by those taxes correct, the only result would have been, that at the end of the six- teen years Great Britain would have been involved in far more heavy debt than Ireland. According to Mr. Chisholm, nearly two-thirds of the British revenue was raised by these taxes, and if we are to presume that their remission would cause a loss of these two-thirds, of course it follows that the deficiency would give rise to an increased debt, and thus, though Ireland would not be directly affected, Great Britain would be in a much worse position than before. On the other hand, were the similarity established by the extension of all the British taxes to Ireland, it is impossible to say what would have been the result. The revenue of Ireland might have been increased — it might have been left as it was— it is even possible to sup- pose that it might have been diminished. As, therefore, the establishment of similarity in the first way would not have affected Ireland at all, and the result of its establishment in the second way cannot by possibility be accurately ascer- tained, it is hardly necessary to urge that no prac- tical conclusion can be drawn, as to the exemption 28 enjoyed by Ireland, from a consideration of the amount of revenue contributed in Great Britain by taxes not extended to the sister country. Whether Ireland was comparatively undertaxed between 1800 and 1816, may be judged of by other tests, and with some of these I purpose to deal in the succeeding chapters. CHAPTER IV. THE PROPORTION FIXED ON IRELAND EXCESSIVE. It by no means follows from the argument used in the last chapter, that Ireland did not enjoy cer- tain exemptions from taxation during the period from the Union to the amalgamation of the ex- chequers. We know as a fact that many taxes were not imposed on her, and although the amount contributed by these taxes in Great Britain cannot give us any criterion by which to judge of the ac- tual exemption enjoyed by Ireland, yet it is possi- ble, and at first sight seems probable, that the resources of the latter country were not so severely taxed as those of the former. Whether such was the case or not, and whether the propor- tions of two to fifteen were in reality too heavy for Ireland, depends altogether on different con- ditions, to which I purpose now to proceed. Examining more in detail those years during which the war expenditure existed, and dividing it 29 into three parts, we find that the revenue of Great Britain successively advanced from £35,262,508* in 1801, to £50,228,236 in 1805, being an increase of about 42 per cent., from which there was a still further advance in 1810 to £68,573,702, or an in- crease of 36 per cent., and in 1815 to £76,869,272, or an increase of 12 per cent., whilst the total ad- vance in the revenue raised in the last year over that raised in the first, amounted to 117 per cent. Meanwhile the funded unredeemed debt had risen from £420,000,000 to £524,000,000, £552,000,000, and £700,000,000, respectively, showing an in- crease on the whole of about 66 per cent. As far as the revenue was concerned, almost similar results took place in Ireland. In the year 1805 the Irish revenue was 22 per cent, over what it was in 1800; in 1810 it was 20 per cent, over what it was in 1805; and between 1810 and 1815 it in- creased 40 per cent., whilst the total advance on the whole period was over 107 per cent. As to the Irish debt, it had, as before remarked, been quadrupled. We thus perceive that the actual increase in the Irish revenue was greater than that which took place in the British; and when we examine the nature of the taxes imposed in the two countries, we will find that the Irish permanent revenue had increased in far greater ratio than that of Great Britain. On this point the committee that inquired into the subject in 1815, report : * Ap. to Report, 1865, p. 140. 30 “ Ireland has advanced in permanent taxation more rapidly than Great Britain herself, notwithstanding the immense exertions of the latter country, and including the extraordi- nary war taxes. The permanent revenue of Great Britain having in- creased from the year 1801, in the proportion of 16£ to 10, and the revenue of Ireland in the proportion of 23 to 10”. Although, therefore, Ireland was exempted from many taxes imposed on England, it is clear this did not result in a diminished call on her resources. The enormous and disproportionate increase in the Irish debt has been before alluded to ; but this does not give us the actual loss sustained by this borrowing. Many of the loans were negociated on very disadvantageous terms, and although the stock created on account of loans for Ireland during the period amounted to £113,000,000, yet the amount received was only £76,000,000. How- ever, of the money thus required for her service, she was scarcely able to supply any herself, most of the loans for the service of Ireland being ne- gociated in England. The proportionate amounts of the different loans furnished by Great Britain and Ireland, are given in tables presented to the Committee by Mr. Chisholm; and from these it appears that, of the whole amount raised for the service of the United Kiugdom, Ireland furnished only 4 5 per cent. Of the amounts raised for the service of Ireland, Great Britain furnished 75*5 per cent, and Ireland only 24*5, whilst Mr. Chisholm goes on to say:* * Ap. to Report, session 1865, p. 141. 31 “ There is evidence to prove that it was the inability of Ire- land to raise money from her own resources, which alone compelled her thus to fall back upon the more abundant and increasing wealth of Great Britain”. If Ireland therefore was unable to furnish more than so small a proportion of the money required for her own service, and if, contemporaneously with an enormousdncrease in her debt, her taxation was increasing as rapidly as that of Great Britain, we can hardly avoid coming to the conclusion that the contributions fixed at the time of the Union, though perhaps at that time just, had subsequently become much too high, and pressed too heavily on the resources of Ireland. This conclusion is borne out by the expressed opinion of very high autho- rities, both in parliament and elsewhere, many of which will be found quoted in the appendix to the Taxation Committee Report. Mr. Chisholm him- self concludes his remarks on this branch of the subject with the following observation : “ It appears to be impossible to reconcile the assumed fact of the ability of Ireland to contribute two-seventeenths, or 11' 7 per cent, of the imperial expenditure with the ascer- tained fact of her inability to contribute from her own resources more than £4 5s. per cent, of the money required to be raised by the creation of debt for the largely increased war expenditure during the sixteen years from 1801 to 1816”.* Although it thus appears that, notwithstanding the non-imposition of certain taxes on Ireland, * Ap. to Keport, session 1865, p. 142. 32 her resources were as severely tested as those of Great Britain, and although the proportion of two to fifteen would clearly seem to have been too high for Ireland, yet it is sometimes urged, that as this proportion was never actually raised by taxation from Ireland, and as Great Britain undertook the entire of the Irish debt at the time of the amalga- mation of the exchequers, no real injury was done to Ireland from the nominal imposition of a bur- den which was really never exacted. Is it, however, perfectly correct to argue that the proportion of contribution fixed by the act of union was not exacted ? It is, to be sure, true that this proportion was not raised by taxation from Ireland, but up to the year 1817, though the reve- nue failed to meet it, we have seen that Ireland did actually pay her contribution, # and that she paid it by adding largely to her debt. It may be said that this did her no wrong, as the debt was subsequently adopted by Great Britain, but then it seems to be forgotten, that at that time Ireland also was sub- jected to the liabilities consequent on the British debt. In fact, what took place in 1817 was simply this: the two countries were placed on perfect equality, both as regards debt charges, and ordinary general expenditure, a course which might have been adopted at the time of the act of union, were it not that Ireland then possessed an advan- * According to Mr. Chisholm’s accounts, Ap. to Report, 1864, p. 394, the final balance due by Ireland to Great Britain, that is to say, the amount by which Ireland failed to meet her con- tributions during the sixteen years, was only £2,001,457. tage, inasmuch as her debt was comparatively smaller than the British debt. This advantage she lost between 1800 and 1817. In the latter year her debt was even in a greater proportion than the British debt, and if the advantage she possessed in 1800 was lost, and her debt unduly increased through having too high a proportion of contribu- tion fixed on her, it is hardly fair to argue that it was merely a nominal imposition, because never raised by taxation. In the year 1800 Ireland had a claim to be less heavily taxed than Great Britain, a claim recognized as a right by the act of union ; in the year 1817 she had lost that right, and if we admit that the proportion of two-seventeenths was excessive, we can hardly deny that the claim or right, which existed in the year 1800, was lost to Ireland through her having to make up an excessive amount of contribution. Without calling in question, then, in any way the motives of those who passed the act of union, or ascribing to them any other desire than that of benefiting the two countries, we have seen that the events which subsequently occurred were of such an extraordinary character, and the expenses of the United Kingdom increased to such an un- precedented degree, as altogether to falsify the predictions and expectations held out in the year 1800. Nor is it necessary that we should impute any inaccuracy or inconsistency to the accounts kept between Great Britain and Ireland. No doubt, those accounts are very intricate, and have, 34 at times, bedft presented in forms that would, at first sight, justify us in believing them contradic- tory; but inmost instances those apparent contra- dictions, on examination, are capable of explana- tion, and without at all entering in detail into their examination, or expressing an opinion as to their accuracy, there appear sufficiently strong reasons explanatory of the very unexpected turn events took, without impugning their correctness. That Ireland was the chief loser by what oc- curred during the fifteen years with which we are dealing, can, I think, hardly be doubted. We have seen that her taxation had more than doubled, that her debt had increased beyond all proportion, and that her resources had fallen off to such a de- gree that she was unable to furnish more than one-fourth of the loans required for her own ser- vice. Her poverty at the end of the period was universally admitted, and as a country in which taxation was pressed beyond reproductive limits, Ireland has been quoted in works on political economy. This being the case, can it justly be said that Great Britain was a loser by the Amalgamation Act, or that she then undertook responsibilities which were not justly hers ? If during the sixteen years that the exchequers were separate, Ireland contributed by taxation as much as she was able, and if to meet the balance of the contribution fixed on her, she was obliged to borrow to such an ex- tent as to lose the advantage which at one time 35 she possessed over Great Britain in having a smaller debt, in what way can it be shown that unduly heavy burdens were thrown on Great Britain? Of course if Ireland had been treated leniently in taxation, if the revenue which her resources could easily have yielded had not been raised, and if her falling into debt was due to this, then there might be some ground for complaint on the part of Great Britain. But everything leads us to the opposite conclusion, and although it is impossible to prove it with mathematical pre- cision, yet all the facts to which I have, in the fore- going, alluded, seem to show that Ireland’s re- sources were as heavily taxed as those of Great Britain, and that the proportion of two- seven- teenths fixed by the Act of Union was too much for her to bear. The contract entered into in 1800 was, to be sure, by its terms, to have lasted unchanged for twenty years, but if it were found unfair and leading to the bankruptcy of Ireland, it would not have been consistent either with the principle of the act of union or with justice, to continue it, and its alteration before the legally fixed period cannot be regarded as any great concession to Ireland. On the other hand, we must not overlook the fact that, if Ireland’s resources in the year 1800 were over-estimated, the difference between the pressure of her debt and that of Great Britain must have been over-estimated also. As before remarked, the advantage which Ireland possessed in the 36 year 1800 was, that her debt was in a much lower proportion to the British debt than her resources compared with British resources; but if the Irish resources were over-estimated, of course it follows that this advantage did not really exist to the ex- tent that was supposed, and that the loss which she sustained on being deprived of this advantage was not so great as otherwise might be imagined. The main facts, then, which we collect from the evidence on this part of the subject are, 1. That in the year 1800 Ireland had an advantage over Great Britain, in as much as she was subject to a proportionately smaller debt; 2. That the pro- portion of contribution fixed on her, whatever it was at the commencement, subsequently proved to be too large, and that in making it up Ireland’s debt was unduly increased, and her advantage lost; and lastly, that having thus increased her debt, and lost her advantage, the principle of pro- portionate contribution was abandoned, and the new principle, the one at the present day disputed, was established in its stead. 37 CHAPTER V. PROGRESS OF TAXATION UP TO THE PRESENT TIME. With the report of the committee in IS 15, recommending the amalgamation of the British and Irish exchequers, came also the termination of the great European war, and the previous enormous expenditure of Great Britain was no longer required. The natural result of this was a very large diminution in taxation, and thus we find that immediately after the thorough financial union of the two countries, a considerable number of taxes were repealed. It has been be- fore remarked, that during the war Great Britain received a large amount of revenue by special or war taxes, many of which, by the terms of their imposition, ceased with the termination of the struggle. Taxes of this description, however, had no exis- tence in Ireland. All the imposts there, or such a near approximation to the entire as to render the exception not worth noticing, were laid on as permanent burdens, and consequently no absolute source of revenue ceased with the cessation of hostilities. From this we might naturally expect to find, after the amalgamation of the exche- quers, that the remissions of taxation would be greater in Great Britain than in Ireland. Such in fact was the case, and to an extent perhaps greater than would have been warranted by 38 the mere fact of the additional war taxes pre- viously borne by Great Britain. The amount of taxes remitted and imposed in the United King- dom subsequent to the year 1817, appear in several parliamentary returns, and have been very succinctly given by Mr. Chisholm in the following tables, handed in by him to the Taxation Committee : TAXES REMITTED. TOTAL REMITTED. _ . Great Britain. Ireland. Amount. Proportion per cent. [ Proportion to 2. Amount Proportion per cent. Proportion of 2. 1816-1841 - - £ 28,580,548 918 22*4 £ 2,549,159 8-2 2 1842-1852 - - 12,405,610 94*45 34- 729,051 5*55 2 1853-1864 - - 31,493,692 93-44 286 2,210,769 6 # 56 2 1816-1864 - - 72,479,850 93* 26-5 5,488,979 7* 2 From Return No. 1 10, of Session 1865. TAXES IMPOSED. 1816-1841 - £ 6,671,914 86-6 13- £ 1,039,010 13-4 2 1842-1852 - 5,887,589 93-8 so- 390,774 6-2 2 1853-1864 » 23,170,336 86-7 is- 3,551,239 13-3 2 1816-1864 - 35,729,839 87-76 14-3 4,981,023 12-24 2 From Return 286, of Session 1865. BALANCE OF TAXES REMITTED OR IMPOSED. 39 CO 00 CO 00 o O 53 co co < Eh O EH Great Britain, - - - 58,428,850 17,342,839 41,086,011 98*1 103*3 40 From these tables it appears that of the total amount of remissions, Great Britain received ninety- three per cent., and Ireland only seven per cent. ; whilst, on the other hand, the per-centage of new impositions amounted to 87*8 per cent, for Great Britain, and 12*2 per cent, for Ireland; and of the balance of remissions, after deducting the imposi- tions, Great Britain enjoyed 98*6 per cent., and Ireland only 1*4 per cent. In round numbers, Great Britain was relieved from seventy-two and a half millions of old taxes, and subjected to thirty- five and a half millions of new ones, leaving a clear balance of remissions amounting to about thirty- seven millions, whilst Ireland was relieved from five and a half millions, and subjected to nearly five millions, leaving a balance of remissions of only half a million. As before remarked, of course a great deal of this was due to the fact that in Great Britain a large amount of war taxes fell to the ground on the restoration of peace; but then, it must be remembered, that during the war a great many new taxes were imposed on Ireland, and that the fact of their having been imposed without being restricted to the duration of the war, did not in any way lessen the burden which they placed on the country. If then Ireland was proportionately as heavily taxed as Great Britain during the continuance of the war, there seems no reason for supposing that the great preponderance of remissions of taxation enjoyed by Great Britain after the restoration of peace, 41 can be justified on the ground that British taxes were made dependent on the continuance of the war, whilst Irish taxes were imposed without any such condition. Moreover, it must also be borne in mind that the remission of taxation in the years subsequent to the amalgation of the exchequers, was not altogether due to the falling in of the war duties or the reduction of the war expenditure. A considerable diminution in taxation resulted from the abandonment of the sinking fund and the charges consequent upon it. However, it does not appear that either from the reductions in the war expenditure or from the temporary ease en- joyed by the nation from the abandonment of the sinking fund charges, Ireland received anything like the same diminution of burden which was accorded to Great Britain, at least if we may judge by a comparison of the remission and im- position of taxes. The general result, then, of the changes in tax- ation between 1817 and 1864 shows a large balance of remissions in favour of Great Britain, and only a small balance in favour of Ireland; but it is curious to remark that within the last ten years of this period, whilst the balance of remis- sions in favour of Great Britain was still large, things had entirely changed in Ireland, and there the balance was on the side of the taxes imposed. During this period the income tax was for the first time extended to Ireland, but excluding it 42 from our calculation, we find* that contempora- neously with its imposition, other taxes to the amount of £2,074,239 were imposed, and only £996,767 remitted. In Great Britain, on the contrary, excluding also the income tax, the re- missions had amounted to £16,442,692, and the additions to taxation to only £9,883,326; so that, excluding all consideration of the income tax from both sides of the account, we get the re- sult that during those ten years additions were made to the taxation of Ireland more than double the amount of remissions, whilst the remissions received by Great Britain were nearly double the impositions placed on her. Subtracting the re- missions in the case of Ireland from the impositions, we find a balance of £1,079,472 of additional tax- ation, whilst in Great Britain there was a balance of remission amounting to £6,559,356. As some objections may be made to deductions drawn merely from a consideration of the receipts or estimated receipts from taxes imposed or re- mitted, it may be well also to consider the actual, absolute, and relative changes in taxation between 1817 and 1864. Starting with the year 1817-18, the first after the amalgamation of the exchequers, we find that the revenue of Great Britain then was £51,614,484, and that of Ireland £5,285,654, and that in the year 1861-2 these sums had changed respectively f to £61,366,747 and £6,792,606, * Ap. to Report, 1865, p. 145. f Ap. to Report, 1864, p. 413. 43 showing an increase of 18*8 per cent, for Great Britain, and 28 per cent, for Ireland. Dividing this period into three parts, the first terminating with the year 1842, the second with the year 1852, and the third with the year 1862, we find still more interesting results. In the first period the taxation of the two countries had decreased from £51,000,000 to £46,000,000, and from about £5,000,000 to £4,000,000. In the second period it again rose to £52,400,000 and £4,400,000 re- spectively; whilst in the third period the increase continued, and the amount of taxation then stood, as before stated, at £61,360,749 for Great Britain, and £6,792,606 for Ireland. This last increase is very remarkable, and to it, to a great extent, must be attributed the general outcry in Ireland of late years respecting taxation. Whilst, during those ten years, the taxation of Great Britain increased only 17 per cent., that of Ireland increased 52 per cent., and it cannot be a subject for wonder that such an increase as this should have excited the greatest attention in Ire- land, and should have produced the complaints which of late years have been so general. The proportions which the Irish bore to the British taxation during the periods alluded to, are, one-thirteenth in the first period, one-twelfth in the second, and one- ninth in the third; thus showing that since 1817 there has been a pro- gressive increase in the proportions of revenue contributed by Ireland. 44 In looking to the question of imperial taxation, of course we must not confine our view to any par- ticular portion of the empire, and if we find any system which contributes to the benefit of the nation at large and to the increase of its general wealth, it would not be fair to characterize that as unjust because through all the portions of the empire the benefits were not equally divided. In drawing attention, then, to the remarkable advan- tages which Great Britain has derived from the system of taxation adopted during the last fifty years, I am far from wishing to make it appear that that system has been unjust. Indeed, the remarkable fact, that with such large remissions of taxation the revenue continued to increase, would, in itself, be sufficient justification of the course adopted. I, therefore, desire merely to point out that during this period Ireland did not receive the same advantages as Great Britain, and that, if claims are put forward on her behalf, they are not altogether without foundation. Ireland no doubt is benefited by anything which benefits the empire, and a development of the resources of Great Britain, which renders it pos- sible to raise a larger amount of revenue without any increase in the rate of taxation, must without doubt also benefit Ireland : but still it is clear from the facts contained in the foregoing tables, that those benefits have not been equally divided, and on the conclusion which ought to be drawn from this 1 may have hereafter to dwell. 45 To enter fully into a detailed examination of all the taxes repealed, and of the effect of their repeal, would require an extension of this sketch far beyond the limits I assigned to it, and could not be properly undertaken except by some one more competent to deal with it than I am. With these remarks, then, I would close this chapter, were it not that, having seen the increase in the taxation of the empire, it may not be uninteresting to con- sider for a moment the probable increase in its wealth. Unfortunately it is difficult, when we desire to make a separate estimate for the two countries, to ff nd any sure standard by which this wealth can be arrived at. The imports and exports might be taken as a test, were it not that since 1812 no ac- count has been kept of the cross-channel trade, and hence no distinction between British and Irish imports and exports can really be made. The in- come tax, or the value of property assessed to it, might be selected, but of it we are unable to avail ourselves, except during the last ten years of the period with which we are dealing, for before 1853 there was no assessment to an income tax in Ire- land. There is therefore no test, which during the entire period can serve as a standard by which to judge of the actual and comparative increase or decrease of the wealth of Great Britain and Ire- land. But, although there does not appear to be any one standard, which during the entire period can be selected for estimating the increase or de- 46 crease of the national wealth, yet during the last ten years we are not without such, and in the as- sessments to the income tax, have perhaps as fair a criterion as can possibly be found. The increase in the values assessed to the income tax, as a test of the increase in the value of the general wealth of the country, has, moreover, in its favour, the high authority of the present Chan- cellor of the Exchequer, for in his famous budget speech in 1860, when alluding to the enormous in- crease in the public expenditure, and showing the comparative increase in the resources of the nation, he selected the values assessed to the in- come tax, and the variations which took place in them, as fair tests of the variations which took place in the national wealth. In order to be strictly correct, we should exclude from these values those appearing under schedules C and E of the income tax, the one representing funded pro- perty, the other representing pensions or salaries from the state, as neither of these can be said justly to have any connection with the wealth of the countries: however, as their retention does not make any material alteration in the comparison, it may be hardly necessary to exclude them. Taking, then, the average value assessed in the three first years after the extension of the income tax to Ireland, and the average value in the three years ending 1863, we find* that the increase in * Ap. to Report, IF 65, p. 161. 47 Great Britain under schedule A, was 22 per cent., under schedule B, 15*9 per cent., and under sche- dule D, 23*8 per cent,, whilst under all the sche- dules together it was 21*6 per cent.; and deducting the income under schedules C and E, which, as before remarked, are properly no tests at all, the increase of the worth of Great Britain during these ten years, as estimated by the values assessed to the income tax, would be about 21*8 per cent. During the same period the increase in Ireland under schedule A, was 13 per cent., under sche- dule B, 11*8 per cent., and under schedule D, 2*3 per cent., or under the three schedules about 10^ per cent. From this it appears that the increase in the wealth of Great Britain during these ten years was about 21*8 percent., the increase in the wealth of Ireland was only 10*5 per cent., whilst, as before noted, these were the ten years during which the taxation of Ireland had increased 52 per cent., and the taxation of Great Britain only 17 per cent. 48 CHAPTER VI. PRESENT IMPERIAL TAXATION OF THE UNITED KINGDOM. As before remarked, there does not appear to be very much difference of opinion as regards the facts connected with the present imperial taxation of the United Kingdom, the difference, here, being one rather of principle. Nevertheless, it is still desirable briefly to state the facts, and as other burdens press on the people of the two countries besides those which are usually placed in the category of impe- rial taxes, I purpose in the succeeding sections to consider these which are commonly placed under the head of local taxation, confining this to a con- sideration of the general revenue as voted by par- liament. In the year 1863-4 the gross revenue of the United Kingdom amounted to £68,115,300,* of which 90*5 per cent, was contributed by Great Britain and 9*5 per cent, by Ireland. Of this amount £64,167,271 were raised by general taxes, similar throughout the United Kingdom, whilst £3,948,029 were raised by taxes peculiar to Great Britain. Imperial taxation, then, is at the present day in form identical throughout Great Britain and Ireland, with the exception of the assessed, railway, and some other minor imposts peculiar to Great Britain, which, on the whole, yield a sum Ap. to Report, 1865, p. 145. 49 somewhat under £4,000,000. With this similar taxation, however, the question has arisen, whether the one country is not more heavily burdened than the other, or whether a greater proportion of the resources of the one is not absorbed by taxation than of the resources of the other; and here of course we find ourselves at once at issue on a ques- tion of principle. I know it is held, that it is an error to speak of countries being taxed; that countries are not taxed; that it is the individual who is taxed; and that the mere locality in which he resides can in no way affect the justice or injus- tice of the impost placed upon him. This is an argument often used, and although I desire care- fully to abstain from any discussion on questions of abstract justice or injustice, yet as such an argument cuts at the root of any comparison being made between the pressure of taxation on Great Britain and Ireland, it is absolutely neces- sary fairly to consider it. It is no doubt perfectly true, that individuals, not countries, are taxed ; but as the wealth of a country is in the hands of the individuals compos- ing its population, anything which diminishes their wealth diminishes the wealth of the country, and it is but an idle discussion to argue a diffe- rence between the taxes on a country, and those on the individuals who live in it. Again, it is said the locality in which the individual taxpayer lives is not an ingredient in the lightness or heavi- ness of the burden; the man worth £200 a year 4 50 in Ireland is just as well able to pay his income tax as the man worth £200 a year in Great Britain; and the taxes on tea, sugar, and tobacco are not more oppressive on the small traders, struggling farmers, and poor labourers of Ireland, than on individuals similarly circumstanced in Great Bri- tain. IFnquestionably this, in the abstract, is also true; but can it with equal truth be said, for in- stance, that the indirect taxes above mentioned, such as those on tea, tobacco, etc., do not press more heavily on the poor than on the rich, or that our taxation is so nicely adjusted that it presses with equal or corresponding severity on all classes or individuals in the community. It is held by some, and, I think, not without reason, that the pressure even of a direct tax pro- portionate to the amount of income, is unequally felt a and that those possessing small incomes feel a deduction of a fixed proportion in a much greater degree than those of more ample means; but whether this is true or not as regards direct taxes, it cannot be denied in dealing with taxes in the indirect form. These are not levied in proportion to the means, but rather in proportion to the wants of the taxpayer, and unquestionably press more heavily on some classes of individuals than on others, abstracting a larger proportionate amount of the income of the former than of the latter. As the consuming power of an individual or a class is not limited exactly in proportion as his or their income is diminished, nor indefinitely 51 increased with an increase of income, taxes on ar- ticles of ordinary consumption will invariably be found to press more heavily on the poorer than on the richer classes of the community. That in the abstract this is the case, cannot be doubted, but how it affects localities or countries may not be so apparent. The consuming class in Great Britain is similarly taxed with the consuming class in Ireland, and all classes or individuals similarly circumstanced are similarly taxed ; yet it is, nevertheless, possible, indeed I believe it is cer- tain, that out of the annual wealth or income of Ireland a larger proportion is paid towards state expenses than is paid by Great Britain. As before stated, the wealth or income of a country is the wealth or income of its inhabi- tants, and if that wealth be divided in smaller por- tions over a greater number of individuals, a greater proportion of it will be taken by a tax on articles of general consumption. If it be true that such a tax takes away a larger proportion of the incomes of persons possessed of small means, it follows that the country whose inhabitants possess the lowest average wealth will pay the largest pro- portionate share towards the national expenditure. This, then, is what is meant when it is said, that Ireland contributes a larger proportion of its wealth to the national expenditure than Great Britain, and this also is what is meant when it is said that Ireland is more heavily taxed than Great Britain. There can be little doubt, I believe, taking the 5 2 annual income of Ireland and comparing it with the revenue raised there, and adopting a similar course with regard to Great Britain, that the taxa- tion of Ireland will show a larger per-centage on her resources than the taxation of Great Britain on hers. To prove this with mathematical correctness is not, however, very easy; for, although we have an accurate account of the taxation, we have none of the resources of the two countries, and can judge of them only by approximation. In the as- sessments to the income tax we have indeed very fair tests, but still against them objections have been raised, and in all respects they are not strictly accurate. According to these assessments, it would appear that of the wealth of the United Kingdom Ireland possessed about 7*2 per cent.,* and Great Britain 92*8 per cent., whilst of the taxation, Ireland con- tributed 9*5 per cent, and Great Britain 90*5 per cent.; or, according to another return, f Ireland and Great Britain on every pound of income contri- bute in the proportions of 6s. 8|d to 4s. Ofd. If then the income tax returns can be taken as safe tests for ascertaining the respective resources of the two countries, it would be self-evident that the inhabitants of Ireland as a body pay a greater proportion of their income in taxation than the inhabitants of Great Britain, Ireland’s income * Ap. to Report, 1865, p. 161. f Return 452, Session 1863. 53 being about one-thirteenth of the entire, and her taxation about one-tenth. Against the income tax returns, as valid tests of the resources of the two countries, two objections are generally made. The test would be unobjec- tionable, if the assessments were made on the same principle in Great Britain and Ireland, and if they included all incomes, whether above or below £100 a year; but neither of these is the case, and hence the objections. In the first place, it is said that the income tax under Schedules A and B is assessed differently in Great Britain and Ireland, in the former country the assessment being on the gross rental, in the latter on the net receipts; and in the next place, as incomes below £100 a year are excluded from the returns in both countries, a large amount of annual receipt is omitted, an amount, however, proportionately much larger in Ireland, as property in that country is more mi- nutely subdivided. On the first objection it is sufficient to say that, although in principle the assessments are different, yet in practice the results are said to be very similar. Taking a series of years and making allowance for the increased expense of the collec- tion of Irish rents, and the frequent failure of Irish tenants, there is probably as much difference between the real net receipts from the ownership of land in Ireland and the valuation on which the tax is assessed, as there is between the gross and net rental in Great Britain. Even admitting, how- 54 ever, that the difference which exists in principle had existence also in practice, and that in conse- quence of it some deduction should be made from British returns, yet this would not alter to any appreciable extent the proportions above stated. The second objection, if used as an argument against believing that a greater proportionate amount of the income of the inhabitants of Ire- land is absorbed by taxation, entirely fails to show this, as it tells rather in the contrary sense. If it be true, as before argued, that taxes on articles of ordinary use, such as tea, sugar, tobacco, etc., which enter into the consumption of the poorer classes, press more heavily on those with small than on those with large incomes, surely anything tending to show that a larger proportionate amount of incomes under £100 exists in Ireland than in Great Britain, tends also to the conclusion that of the income of Ireland a larger propor- tionate amount is paid in taxation than of the in- come of England. Indeed, if it be once admitted that the average individual income is lower in Ireland than in Great Britain, and that in the former country the population is comparatively poorer, there is no necessity for recurring to the income tax assessments in order to show that similar taxation, in the indirect form at least, is heavier on the resources of Ireland. So far, then, from the second objection being an argument against believing in the results shown by the in- come tax returns, it is in fact an argument which? 55 in the absence of these returns, would lead us to the same results. • In addition to the value of property assessed to the income tax, there are other tests which have sometimes been used for estimating the compara- tive resources of the two countries. Several of these appear in the report of the Taxation Com- mittee, and are chiefly the following: Deposits in public savings’ banks, which are nineteen times greater in Great Britain; deposits in post office savings’ banks, which are twenty -three times greater; money orders, fourteen times greater; railway receipts, nineteen and a-half times; interest on public stocks, seventeen times; and legacy and probate duty, sixteen times as much in Great Britain as in Ireland. All of these then bear out the conclusion indicated by the income tax returns, viz., that the resources of Ireland do not constitute more than one-thirteenth or one-fourteenth of the resources of the United Kingdom, whilst, as before remarked, her contribution to the imperial reve- nue is about one-tenth. None of these tests, taken separately of course, would prove much, but the remarkable coincidence that they all tend in the same direction, cannot but lead us to the con- clusion that beyond doubt the resources of Ireland are comparatively much lower than her present proportion of contribution to the imperial revenue. So far, then, as regards the actual and compara- tive gross taxation of the present day, it appears that in the nature of the imposts, with some trifling 56 exceptions, taxation is similar, whilst in the pres- sure of this similar taxation the burden is propor- tionately greater in Ireland than in Great Britain. * From the assessed taxes which make up the greater portion of the four millions of separate taxation now borne by Great Britain, Ireland is free, but it may not be uninteresting to estimate in a rough way the amount of this exemption. The chief taxes from which most of this revenue is derived are the taxes on inhabited houses of £20 value and upwards, on horses, on dogs, and on carriages. As to the remaining ones, on servants, hair powder, and armorial bearings, their receipts in Ireland would be so trifling that it is hardly necessary to mention them. The amount of house duty paid in Great Britain in 1863 was £788,471, and the number of houses on which it was raised was 577,671, whilst it ap- pears that there were in Ireland in the same year 33,763 houses of £20 value and upwards. As- suming, then, that the average value of each house was the same in Great Britain and Ireland, had the tax been extended to the latter country, it would have produced only about £46,000. Cal- culating the duty on horses in a similar way, it would not have amounted to more than £23,000 or £24,000; and as to that on dogs, although those animals are now numerous in Ireland, yet a tax of twelve shillings would so diminish their numbers that the revenue derived from it would be ex- ceedingly small. Of the principal assessed taxes 57 there remains but that upon carriages. What this would produce in Ireland we have no means of judging, but we may safely assume it would not differ very much from the others in its results. On the whole, then, the exemption enjoyed by Ireland in freedom from the assessed taxes cannot be considered anything but trifling. Although the taxation of the United Kingdom is thus practically similar, the proportions contri- buted by Ireland to the different branches of the revenue are not in all cases alike. As might naturally be expected, in that country where the population is greater in proportion to its wealth, the receipts from indirect taxes on commodities which are in fact taxes on population, are much greater in proportion than the receipts from the other branches of revenue.* In the three years ending March, 1864, the revenue from articles of general consumption was contributed in the fol- lowing proportions: 87*3 per cent, by Great Britain, and 12*7 per cent, by Ireland; the revenue from the income tax in the proportions of 93*3 per cent, by Great Britain, and 6*7 per cent, by Ireland; the total indirect taxation being 88*3 per cent, by Great Britain, and 11*7 per cent, by Ireland; and the total direct taxation being 93*5 per cent by Great Britain, and 6 '5 per cent, by Ireland. The proportions of the revenue of each country which were contributed under the different heads appear to have been the following. Of the entire * Ap. to Keport, 1865, p. 147. 58 revenue of Great Britain, GOG per cent, was con- tributed by taxes on articles of general consump- tion, 76*1 per cent, by indirect taxes generally, and 23*9 per cent, by direct taxation. Of the entire amount of revenue raised in Ireland, 7 5 per cent, was raised by taxes on articles of general consump- tion, 85*9 per cent, by indirect taxes generally, and 14*1 per cent, by direct taxation. As direct taxes may be considered as taxes on wealth, and indirect taxes as taxes on population, this still further corroborates the view before taken as to the comparative condition of the wealth of the two countries. The remarkable fact that of the Irish revenue 7 5 per cent., or three-fourths, is contributed by taxes on articles of general consumption, leads one to examine what these articles chiefly are. The first and prin- cipal is spirits, which in 1863-4 yielded a revenue of £2,300,000; then come tobacco, tea, sugar, etc. The revenue contributed from Ireland under the tea and sugar duties, viz., about £700,000, though large, does not indeed at all amount to the actual duty paid by the Irish on those articles, for the greater proportion of the duty, especially on the sugar consumed in Ireland, is paid in Great Britain and credited to her account. However, by the duty raised in Ireland on these four articles, more than two-thirds of the Irish revenue is con- tributed. The changes which have taken place during the last twenty years in the consumption of some 59 of these articles, are also deserving of some notice. In the first place, as regards tea, it appears* that the average annual consumption, as calculated on the three years ending 1860, has increased in Ireland during the last twenty years from 4,107,7141bs. to 10,944,9941bs., being an increase of over 100 per cent., whilst the average con- sumption per head of the population is more than treble what it used to be, being now about 1 Jib. per head, whereas in the year 1840 it was but ^lb. In Great Britain a somewhat similar in- crease has taken place as regards the entire quan- tity entered for home consumption, but the aver- age consumption per head of the population, in- stead of having trebled as in Ireland, has not quite doubled. Moreover, it must be remembered that a great deal of the Irish tea trade is carried on through Great Britain, and all this of course is set down as consumption in Great Britain, and not in Ireland. With regard to sugar, somewhat different results appear from the parliamentary returns, there being an actual decrease in the quantity on which duty was paid in Ireland, whilst the amount in Great Britain had increased from 3,482,101 cwt. to 8,497,672 cwt. This again, however, is attribu- table to the fact, that nearly all the sugar used in Ireland comes in, duty paid, from England, there being no sugar refineries in Ireland. Yet, on the small portion on which duty is paid in Ireland there has been an increase of about one-fourth on the Return No. 14, Session, 1865. 60 average consumption per head of the population, this having in 1840 been about 4 lbs. and in 1860 about 51bs. In tobacco the increase in Ireland has been from 5,221,0001bs. to 5,891,3181bs., and in Great Britain from 17,800,0001bs. to 28,706,0001bs. In spirits there has been in Great Britain an increase from 14,700,000 gallons to 16,600,000 gallons, whilst in Ireland there has been a diminu- tion from 7,400,000 gallons to 4,714,000 gallons, and the average consumption per head of the population has decreased in both countries. But whilst this is the case, the actual revenue received has, in consequence of the higher rate of duty, largely increased, the actual amount per head contributed by the spirit duty being now in Ire- land 8s. Old., whereas in 1840 it was only 2s. 6d., and being now in Great Britain 6s. 4d., whilst in 1840 it was only 4s. 6d. Such then seems to be the general analysis of the present imperial taxation in the United King- dom. In its nature it is almost identical through- out the kingdom; but, pressing more heavily on the poor than on the wealthy, it apparently absorbs more of the resources of Ireland; whilst the exemption enjoyed by the latter country in freedom from the assessed taxes, seems to be but very trifling. On the other hand, with the exception of the high duty on spirits, it cannot be said that there is any principal tax which interferes specially with any Irish manufacture or enterprise. No doubt 61 the great increase in the consumption of tea and sugar amongst the population of Ireland has ren- dered the duties on those articles rather heavy burdens; and, inasmuch as tea and sugar are more heavily taxed than beer, the tea drinkers of Ireland contribute proportionately more than the beer drinkers of Great Britain. That there is a disposition to rectify this is evidenced by the Budget of last Session; and, on the whole, if Ireland has not equally benefited by the alterations in taxa- tion during the last twenty years, this is chiefly due to her comparative want of commerce and manufactures. CHAPTER VII. LOCAL TAXATION, AND GRANTS IN AID OF SUCH. In considering the question of the local taxation of Great Britain and Ireland, especially in a com- parative point of view, we are met with the diffi- culty of defining accurately what really constitutes a local tax. There are many imposts annually raised, which are of such a nature that it is diffi- cult to determine whether they can really be classed under the head of taxation at all. Many of these duties are levied for services directly ren- dered, and resemble more a portion of the cost of 62 certain enterprises than those charges which, ordinarily speaking, are considered taxes. More- over, the services for which those charges are made are in some places rendered by public bodies, when the charge appears as a tax ; in other places by private individuals, when a similar charge appears only as the cost of the under- taking. Thus, even if we were of accord as to the classification of charges raised by public bodies as taxes, yet, when we institute a comparison be- tween two localities where different systems are carried out, our comparison will not be fair. To a great extent the charges on railways for the conveyance of passengers and goods differ little in principle from the charges on turnpike roads — both are mainly paid for the use of the road, for the expense of making it and keep- ing it up; both are paid in proportion to the use made of the road; and both are paid to com- panies or individuals who expect to make a profit out of the transaction. Tet the one is usually considered amongst the expenses necessarily atten- dant on the production and distribution of wealth, the other usually as a tax. But were we on this account to exclude from the category of local taxes the payments made on turn- pike roads, should we equally exclude from that category the payment of highway rates and road cess, which take the place of turnpike tolls in those localities where the roads are kept up by a public rate instead of by charges on the conveyances pass- 63 ing over them? To be sure, the turnpike toll differs from the road rate in this, that the one is paid for a direct service rendered, and only in pro- portion to that service, whilst the other is paid for public utility, without any necessary connec- tion between the amount paid by the individual and the benefit to himself derived from it. Tet both are payments to a similar object, but under different forms, and both are mainly paid by and for the benefit of the inhabitants of the localities through which the roads pass. Again, are we to consider harbour dues, rates for conveyance on canals, etc., in the light of local taxes, or even as taxes at all ? They are all paid to meet the expenses necessarily attendant on keeping up the harbours, canals, etc., and, espe- cially in the case of harbour dues, are in no sense locally contributed. Nor do the difficulties o f arriving at a proper classification of local taxes end here. What are we to say to the charges for public worship and the maintenance of religion ? In these countries a compulsory charge is made for these purposes, but then it is confined to the maintenance of one worship and one religion. Tithes, Church Rates, etc., were, no doubt, origin- ally intended to supply a public want, to afford to the people houses of worship and ministers ^of religion on a definite, secure, and fixed principle; and, if the people were all of one faith, no difficulty would arise as to their classification. This, how- ever, is not the case. Whilst the members of the 64 Established Church have their religious wants supplied by means of a public tax, the Roman Catholics and Dissenters find the want unsupplied, and have to supplement their payments towards the state Church by additional payments towards the support of their own clergymen and churches. If, then, we are to consider Church Rates, for instance, as a local tax in Great Britain, where it supplies the majority of the inhabitants with the requirements of their worship, how can we insti- tute any fair comparison between it and Ireland without bringing in with the latter country the sums paid by the Roman Catholics, who form the bulk of the population, in keeping up their churches and chapels? Church Rates in Great Britain, and the voluntary subscriptions of the Roman Catholics in Ireland, both accomplish a similar purpose; they both secure for the majority of the people the requirements of their worship, but the one being compulsory and the other voluntary, the former is included in, the latter ex- cluded from, the category of taxation. But this exclusion, on the ground of the voluntary ele- ment, does not render the charge the less real or the less burdensome on Ireland, and consequently presents the case for comparison in an unfavoura- ble light. Indeed, a parallel may be drawn between Church rates and road cess, on the one hand, and the subscription towards Catholic churches and turnpike tolls, on the other, which will not, perhaps, be at all extravagant. Turnpike tolls and the payments by the Roman Catholics to their churches are both, to a certain extent, voluntary. You need not pay the toll if you do not use the road, and you may be prevented from using the church if you do not pay the subscrip- tion or entrance fee; for, although the latter course is not adopted, still the legal right to it exists. Again, both the turnpike tolls and the payments towards Catholic and Dissenting houses of worship are payments towards purposes which, in some localities and under some circumstances, are considered deserving of being provided for by a compulsory rate. Thus we have seen that the roads in some places are so maintained, whilst in like manner the expenses of the houses of worship of certain classes of the community are similarly provided for. I need not say that I have not brought forward this argument to show that the voluntary sub- scriptions of the Roman Catholics or Dissenters should be included in the local taxation returns, but I have noticed it merely to show that no absolute bona fide comparison as to the burden of local taxation can be made whilst these anomalies exist. The British churchman of course pays his church-rate and his tithe, but, if he does, he has his religious wants supplied without further cost. The Irish Catholic, on the other hand, though he pays tithes, and in it church-rate, has still, in ad- dition, to supply the requirements of his religion, 66 and therefore the burden in the one case is not similar to that in the other. Subject, however, to these remarks, it may be desirable to give, as far as possible, a statement of the amount of local taxation in the two countries. On this point, Mr. Chisholm has given us in- formation, and according to his returns,* the amount of local taxation in Great Britain in 1845 was £12,653,213, and in 1864, £17,848,875; and in Ireland in 1845, £1,636,966, and in 1864, £2,031,264, In these returns, however, many items are included, the amounts of which could not be accurately ascertained in both countries. For the purpose of a comparative statement, the following, also supplied by Mr. Chisholm, f may be taken as substantially accurate : 1 Great Britain, Ireland, United Kingdom, 1845. 1863-4. Amount. £11,190,820 1,490,681 Per cent. 88*24 11-76 Amount. £13,765,853 1,816,275 Per cent. 8824 11-76 £12,681,451 £15,582,128 We thus see that the local taxation of Ireland is even higher in proportion than the imperial taxation, although, of course, as before remarked, no very substantial conclusion can be drawn from this fact. A more important item for consideration may be what are called the grants in aid of local tax- * Ap. to Report, 1865, p. 119. t Ibid., p. 120. 67 ation, and those for charitable and literary pur- poses, etc.; that is to say, the amounts granted out of the public revenue for purposes more or less local in their character. These, according to the Report of the Taxation Committee, appear to be the following : 1801. 1817. 1845. j 1863-4.' » Amount. Per cent. Amount. Per cent. Amount. Per cent. Amount. Per cent. , Great Britain, 77,898 34 158,607 37 609,679 53 2,722,675 67 Ireland, 146,976 65 268,257 62 537,942 46 1,297,988 32 From these tables, at first sight, it would seem that the grants in aid of local taxation are, pro- portionately to the general taxation, much greater in Ireland than in Great Britain ; but, if examined into, it will be found that more than two- thirds of the sum granted to Ireland is to meet the expen- diture upon the Constabulary force, and that in connection with this grant many peculiar circum- stances have to be taken into consideration. In the first place, the origin of this grant was as a compensation to the owners of land for the abolition of protection. Mr. Chisholm, in his paper, states :f “ In 1846, when proposing the * Ap. to Report, 1865, p. 129. t This table is taken from the report of the Committee. The per-centage does not appear to be exactly accurate, but is so very nearly so that I have thought it better to quote it as given, rather than to alter it by correction. 68 abolition of the corn laws, and avowedly as a relief to the burdens on land, on the ground that Ireland especially might suffer from a withdrawal of protection, Sir Robert Peel proposed that the entire expense of the Irish Constabulary should be paid out of the public treasury, and that, to prevent the possibility of all interference by local bodies, the Constabulary force should be placed completely under the control of the Executive Government”. In the next place, the Constabu- lary are not only completely under the control of Government, but to a great extent they act in a sort of military capacity, and are in their con- stitution a semi-military body; and lastly, they are employed for revenue and other purposes of purely imperial and not local character. No doubt, in addition to these duties, they do discharge also the duties of local police, and so far as their pay- ment for these services is concerned, the counties in Ireland do receive an advantage. Although, on the whole, including the charges for the Constabulary, a larger proportionate amount is received in Ireland than in Great Britain, yet it is curious to observe, that since 1845 the proportion received by Ireland has greatly diminished. Taking in all the grants in- cluded in the above tables, it appears to have fallen off from 46 to 32 per cent. Yet, during this period, the free trade system came into opera- tion, from the effects of which it was not sup- posed that Ireland would benefit in the same pro- 69 portion as Great Britain. As before remarked, Sir Robert Peel, when introducing the repeal of the corn laws, believed it necessary to lighten in some way the burdens then pressing on land, and believed this specially necessary with regard to Ire- land. With this view, many local expenses in addi* tion to the Irish Constabulary were transferred to the imperial charge ; but it is rather singular that the result of this should be, that Ireland, the coun- try which peculiarly stood in need of this compen- sation, should receive actually a smaller proportion of assistance from the State than she did before. Several local charges were, in Great Britain, transferred from being a burden on the land to the imperial exchequer, but some of these were not so transferred in Ireland. Amongst them we find the half-payment of medical officers of work- houses and dispensaries, the half-payment of union schoolmasters and schoolmistresses, etc., charges from which the land was relieved specially on account of the withdrawal of protection. As yet these charges remain on the land in Ireland ; but it is to be hoped that, next session of Parliament, what was evidently the intention of Sir Robert Peel will be carried out, and these charges placed on the same footing in the two countries. I have now done with the question of local taxa- tion, and the grants in its aid. The fullest informa- tion on each of these grants in particular will be found in Mr. Chisholm’s papers, which, on this as on other points, are most instructive and interesting. 70 CHAPTER VIII. GRANTS AND ADVANCES FOR WORKS OF PUBLIC UTILITY. Having now considered both the financial policy of the past and the present burdens on the United Kingdom, as well imperial as local, I might per- haps at once close this sketch. There is, however, another topic intimately connected with the fore- going on which I should wish to say a word, viz., the grants or advances at various times made by the State for works of public utility in the coun- try. During the existence of the Irish Parliament, and before the Union, it seems to have been very much the policy of that body to make grants of this description, and in the annual votes of that period we find sums regularly set apart for such purposes as inland navigation, wide streets, etc. Several of these grants were bequeathed to the Imperial Parliament at the time of the Union, and for many years afterwards we find them ap- pearing in the votes. It is not, however, with these old grants that I now purpose to deal, but rather with those of a more modern date, and with those advances by way of loan, of which so much advantage has been taken in Ireland. Strictly speaking, the sys- tem of grants for public works has long ago ceased > and although within the last thirty years Ireland has received many such, yet originally they were given, not as grants, but as advances, and were 71 subsequently converted into grants, generally in consequence of some mismanagement in their ap- plication, which would have rendered it unjust to have insisted on their repayment. Advances for works of utility are now chiefly made through the following channels — either through the Exchequer Loan Commissioners, the Enclosure Commissioners in Great Britain, or the Board of Public Works in Ireland ; and all are supplied from certain funds set aside by Parlia- ment for the purpose. For the better under- standing of the subject, it may be well to consider these systems separately, and then to take a general view of the special advances which were made to Ireland in cases of emergency, and most of which have since been converted into grants. In the first place, as regards the advances made by the Exchequer Loan Commissioners, it appears from the evidence of Mr. Barnes, the solicitor to that commission, that the total sum advanced to Great Britain was £13,000,000,* of which about £8,000,000 has been repaid, whilst the amount advanced to Ireland, exclusive of a sum for the erection of Union Workhouses, was £ 2, 72 6, 000, f of which £1,200,000 has been repaid. Of the balances yet unpaid in both countries, a certain amount may be considered lost. Amongst these may be included the advance for the Caledonian Canal, Battersea Park, Chelsea Bridge, in Great Britain, and the Ulster Canal in Ireland. The * Report and Evidence, 1865, p. 21. f Ibid., p. 18. 72 greater proportion of the balance in both coun- tries will probably be repaid, and is still in regular course of payment. Although the State can itself borrow money at about three per cent., or, perhaps, a little more, yet the loans under the Exchequer Loan Commis- sion are given only at five per cent. There is, consequently, in all these loans a per-centage of gain to the Exchequer; and, except where a loan is specially provided for by act of parliament, the commissioners grant none without being fully satisfied of the adequacy of the security on the strength of which the loan is contracted. Indeed, so adequate has been the security in every instance required, that the commissioners have never suf- fered any loss, or had the slightest difficulty in enforcing the repayment, except in certain pecu- liar cases where the loans were granted under special acts of parliament. Under this last class comes a loan of £1,422,680, granted by the Exchequer Loan Commissioners for Union Workhouses in Ireland, which must be added to the sum of £2,726,000 above quoted. Of this sum £1,323,266 was remitted in what were called the Consolidated Annuities, to which I pur- pose shortly to refer, and £52,145 was repaid.* Next to the advances by the Exchequer Loan Commissioners, which are made at five per cent., come those through the Board of Public Works in Ireland. These advances have been made for * Report and Evidence, 1865, p. 19. 73 various purposes, but chiefly in connection with the improvement of land, drainage, etc., and are made on the principle of a terminable annuity, a portion of the principal, with interest at 3^ per cent., being annually paid. Of these loans £2,243,265* have been advanced for arterial drain- age and navigation, of which £1,190,559 has been remitted, leaving a balance of £970,725, principal, and £418,670, interest, to be repaid. Of this balance £669,524 has been already cleared off, leaving the present balance in course of repay- ment £719,870. In addition to the advances for arterial drainage and navigation, the Board of Public W orks has advanced to private proprietors, under the Land Improvement Acts, sums amount- ing to £1,804,467, and of these none have been remitted. The rent-charge created on this ac- count, including principal and interest, amounted to £2,516,549, and of this sum* more than half, or £1,460,178, has been already repaid, whilst the balance, £1,056,371, is in regular course of repay, ment, without any apprehension of loss in its re- ceipt. The total amount, therefore, advanced for drainage and land improvement was £4,047,732; of this £1,190,559 was remitted, and £2,211,682 principal and interest repaid. Besides these ordinary loans, several sums have been advanced on extraordinary occasions by spe- cial acts of parliament, such as the large advances at the time of the famine in Ireland. The greater Ap. to Report, 1665, p. 78. 74 proportion of these were subsequently remitted, and, in point of fact, ought to have been grants rather than advances. These were not all made at the same time or for the same purpose; but all that remained unpaid or unremitted in the year 1850 were, by act of parliament, formed into what were called the Consolidated Annuities. These Consolidated Annuities amounted in the year 1853 to about £4,000,000, and involved an annual payment of £245,000. In the year above mentioned Mr. Gladstone brought in his famous Budget extending the income-tax to Ireland, and increasing the spirit duties in that country, at the same time blotting out those £4,000,000 of ad- vances. The remission of these loans was at the time represented as a set-off for the imposition of the income-tax and the increased spirit duties, and as the former tax was then imposed merely as a temporary burden, which was expected to diminish annually, and at length expire in 1860, it was calculated that Ireland, by the remission of the Consolidated Annuity charge, would gain more than she would lose by the imposition of the new taxes. These calculations, I need hardly say, have proved altogether fallacious; for under the income tax alone Ireland has already contributed over £9,000,000 since 1853; and without alluding to the spirit duties at all, this in itself would have been quite sufficient, not only to pay off the en- tire of the advances, but to leave a large balance behind. 75 These, then, appear to be the principal advances made' to Great Britain and Ireland for works of public benefit; but to them must be added £3,741,000, advanced by the Inclosure Commis- sion for drainage purposes in Great Britain, the payment of which is in progress. On the whole, if we except certain large sums advanced on ex- traordinary occasions to meet certain emergencies, the State has been no loser by these advances, whilst it cannot be doubted that the country has much benefited. In the advances made through the Exchequer Loan Commissioners, as I have already mentioned, there is an actual money gain to the Exchequer, inasmuch as the State raises money at 3J per cent, and lends it at 5 per cent, interest; and on the other advances, although the interest is not equally high, yet it is always equal to that paid by the State itself for a loan. Of these advances, Ireland, no doubt, appears to have had even more than her proportion, but not more than the circumstances of the country seemed to require. 76 CHAPTER IX. SUMMARY. Having now come to the conclusion of the de- tailed examination of the principal facts elicited by the Committee, it may not be undesirable briefly to review the whole, and to consider what points they seem to establish. It has been shown — 1st, That in the Act of Union the principle of payments towards the general expenditure pro- portionate to the resources of the two countries was clearly recognized. 2nd, That it was so recognized and laid down as the basis of the Union, because at that time the liabilities of the two countries in the way of national debt were not considered to be respec- tively proportionate to their resources, the debt of Ireland being comparatively lower than the debt of Great Britain. 3rd, That the contributions of each towards the general expenditure were settled in the pro- portions of 2 for Ireland to 15 for Great Britain, this being the estimate then made of the relative resources of the two countries. 4th, That at the time of the Union a reduction in taxation and a diminution in debt, through the instrumentality of the sinking fund, were appa- rently confidently expected, and the heavy charges 77 consequent on the great European war seem not to have been anticipated. 5th, That these heavy charges were to a great extent instrumental in falsifying the expectations of the framers of the Union, and that under them Ireland completely broke down, not being able to meet by revenue the amount of her proportion of contribution, partly from the fact of her not reaping the same collateral advantages from the war as Great Britain, and partly also because the proportion was, perhaps, originally too great. 6th, That during the continuance of the war the taxation of Great Britain increased more than 100 per cent., and her debt nearly 70 per cent.; whilst, with an almost similar increase in her taxation, the debt of Ireland had been quadrupled; this undue increase in her debt arising from the fact that she failed to raise by revenue as great a proportion of her contribution as was raised by Great Britain. 7th, That in consequence of this failure she lost the advantage which in 1800 she possessed, and at the end of the war was subject to a larger proportionate debt than Great Britain. 8th, That this result having taken place, the ex- chequers were amalgamated, and all distinctions arising out of the proportionate contribution of revenue were done away with, one general finan- cial system for the United Kingdom being estab- lished, although, under it, exact similarity in taxes was not adopted. 78 9th, That, since the amalgamation of the ex- chequers, taxes have been repealed to the amount of £77,968,829, and taxes imposed to the amount of £40,710,862, leaving a balance of remissions of £37,257,967; but of this balance Ireland enjoyed only 1*36 per cent,, and Great Britain 98*64 per cent. 10th, That through these remissions the trade, commerce, and prosperity of the United Kingdom have largely advanced ; but that in those benefits Ireland has not participated to the same extent as Great Britain, probably in consequence of her comparative want of trade and manufactures. 11th, That during the last ten years a large increase in the taxation of the kingdom has taken place, but the increase has been proportionably greater in Ireland than in Great Britain. The in- crease in Ireland having been, since 1855, 52 per cent., and in Great Britain only 17 per cent. 12th, That during the same period the increase in the wealth of the two countries, as estimated by the returns to the income tax, was 10 per cent, for Ireland, and 21 per cent, for Great Britain. 13th, That thus, whilst there has been an ab- solute increase in the taxation of Great Britain, there has been a comparative decrease, the advance in her resources being at a more rapid rate than the advance in her taxation ; but that in Ireland there has been both a comparative and absolute increase in taxation, the advance in wealth being there in a lower ratio than the advance in taxation. 79 14th, That these contrary results from a similar system of taxation seem chiefly to be due to the extraordinary elasticity of British resources, and to the great development which her trade receives on the reduction of taxes afiecting it : an elas- ticity and development unfortunately not enjoyed by Ireland. 15th, That at the present day Ireland is subject to no tax from which Great Britain is free, but Great Britain is subject to certain imposts, making a revenue of about £4,000,000, from which Ireland is exempt ; but that it does not appear that, were those imposts extended to Ireland, they would yield a considerable amount of revenue. 16th, That under this system of almost identical taxation Ireland contributes about 10 per cent, of the general revenue, whilst her wealth, as tested by the income tax returns and other data, does not appear to be more than 7 per cent. 17th, That of the entire revenue of Great Britain, 59*9 per cent, is contributed by taxes on articles of general consumption, which, in the main, are taxes on population, and 21*8 per cent, by direct taxes or taxes on wealth; but of the revenue of Ireland, 75 per cent, is contributed by taxes on articles of consumption, and only 14 per cent, by taxes on wealth. 18th, That with the exception of the tax on spirits, there does not appear to be any tax pressing peculiarly on any branch of Irish industry, and the comparative greater heaviness of taxation in that 80 country appears to be due to the comparative poverty of its inhabitants. 19th, That the local taxation of Ireland, as far as such can be ascertained, bears a still greater proportion to that of Great Britain than the imperial taxation of the one country does to that of the other, the proportions of local tax- ation being 11*7 per cent, to 88*3 per cent., whilst imperial taxation, as above stated, is con- tributed in the proportion of 10 per cent, to 90 per cent. 20th, That as regards grants in aid of local taxation, including in them the grant for the Irish Constabulary, the proportion received by Ireland is considerable, but is now lower than before the repeal of the corn laws, many grants having been since made to Great Britain in consideration of the supposed injury done to the landed interest through the abolition of protection. 21st, That on this ground also the payment of the entire expense of the Irish Constabulary was placed on the Consolidated Fund, notwithstanding which, the proportion now received by Ireland is smaller than before, although it cannot be . said that she derived more benefit than Great Britain from the establishment of free trade. 22nd, That at various times sums have been set aside for grants or advances for works of public utility, and as a rule it does not appear that any loss to the State has arisen from this practice, although, at some exceptional periods, such as 81 that of the Irish famine, sums were advanced, the repayment of which had to be remitted. 23rd, That under the Land Improvement Acts £1,804,467 has been advanced in Ireland, none of which has been remitted; that of this, £1,460,178, principal and interest, has been repaid, and the rest is in regular course of repayment. 24th, Finally, that in all these grants and ad- vances Ireland seems to have fairly participated; and that, according to the reports of the Commis sioners of Public Works, she seems to have been greatly served by them. These seem to me the principal results esta- blished by the investigation with which I have endeavoured to deal, and with this recapitulation I might be content to close, were it not that a sketch of this description would be imperfect if some consideration were not given to the various schemes proposed for the amelioration of Irish taxation. To the consideration of these I purpose to devote one section more, and in the next chap- ter will briefly consider the various proposals made as to the remission of taxes, and the other indirect methods in which a readjustment might be brought about. 6 82 CHAPTER X. CONCLUSION. From the facts narrated in the preceding sections it is evident that, although there are no peculiar taxes pressing on Ireland, and although she is free from certain taxes borne by Great Britain, yet, out of the aggregate wealth of her inhabitants, a larger proportionate amount is contributed to the public revenue than in Great Britain. We have seen that within the ten years commencing 1853 the taxation of Ireland increased 52 per cent., and her resources, as estimated by the income tax, only 10 per cent.; whilst the taxation of Great Britain increased only 17 per cent., and her re- sources, similarly estimated, increased 21 per cent. We have also seen that within these ten years many taxes were remitted, but chiefly those which pressed peculiarly on British trade and • manufactures, and from the withdrawal of which that trade and those manufactures immensely benefited. Nor can it be denied that Ireland did not derive from these remissions equal advantages. In the first place, the amount of the remissions was less in Ireland, as, from the want of com- merce and manufactures, she had not previously contributed largely to several of these taxes; and, in the next place, through the same comparative absence of trade and manufactures, her resources 83 did not receive commensurate development on the withdrawal of those commercial shackles. From these facts, then, what is the conclusion we ought to draw, or what are the conclusions which have been drawn by others ? I know perfectly well that these comparisons, as stated in the com- mencement, are held by some to be based on an entirely wrong principle, and to be worthless as far as leading to any practical conclusion. They say taxation in the empire ought not to be geo- graphically estimated. If there be no tax pecu- liar to any locality, nor any tax peculiarly oppres- sive to any trade or manufacture, there is no ground for complaint nor ground for remission in the mere fact that the inhabitants in some dis- tricts are poorer than those in others. Or, if you admit this as an ingredient in the levying of taxa- tion, in justice you must not confine it to a dis- tinction between Great Britain and Ireland, but must also distinguish between the richer and poorer districts of Great Britain herself. In theory, I admit, it is not easy to answer this argument, and w^ere Great Britain and Ireland essentially the one country, corresponding to two counties in England, I believe it would be almost unanswerable. But in point of fact we know the case is altogether different. Let us theorize about it as we will, we know that there is something more than a mere geographical distinction between Great Britain and Ireland. The habits of the people, their mode of living, the productions of 84 the two countries, and their sources of wealth, are not at all similar; and though separated only by a narrow expanse of water, there is perhaps as great a difference between them as between nations at different extremities of the globe. In addition to this, we cannot forget that until the com- mencement of the present century these two countries were financially and legislatively inde- pendent, that they then became united on the clear understanding of contributing to the general expenditure only in proportion to their resources, and that although the system of proportionate contribution was subsequently abolished, yet at no time has exact similar taxation been estab- lished, there being some trifling exceptions to it even at the present day. That dissimilar taxation ought to be the rule is not the conclusion which I desire to draw from this, nor do I mention it with the view of showing that the natural distinctions between the two coun- tries ought to be perpetuated or increased, but merely to account for comparisons being made, and to justify an inquiry into them. Of course, if we start with the premiss, that similar taxation, no matter of what nature, must be equal ; if we hold that it is sufficient to show that there is no tax pressing on any particular industry in the one country which does not also press on the same in- dustry in the other ; and if all geographical and natural distinctions must be cast aside as unten- able, then, as before remarked, there is no ground 85 for argument or inquiry. But in spite of these general propositions, into the truth or incorrect- ness of which I do not desire to enter, we must still be aware that comparisons will be made, and made by both sides. We know as a fact that they have at all times been made, and are made at the present day, and that whilst the Irish have com- plained of over taxation, a very prevalent idea in Great Britain has been, that Ireland did not at all bear equal burdens with the rest of the empire, and that, in point of taxation, she was leniently treated. To meet these different views, the in- quiry of last session can hardly have been useless; but in considering its results we must not overlook the various proposals made for the readjustment of taxation, and the reasons why the Committee do not seem to have accepted them. From the foregoing I think it is tolerably clear that, were the principle of the Act of Union — viz., contribution in proportion to resources — now in force, Ireland would have a strong claim for a remission of taxation. Let us then, for argument sake, adopt this principle, and in what way, for the greatest benefit of the country, could it, under existing circumstances, be put in force? We have already seen that the description of taxation which presses most on Ireland is that on articles of general consumption. To remedy this would necessitate differential customs duties between Great Britain and Ireland, and would give rise to all the annoy- ances and expense of a foreign cross-channel trade, 86 the disadvantages of which would far more than counterbalance any supposed advantages likely to arise from the establishment of differential duties. This description of alteration in taxation may, therefore, be set aside as almost impracticable. The abolition or reduction of the Income Tax in Ireland has been proposed by some as a simple and easy way of bringing about a readjustment. No doubt this would be feasible and simple in its operation, but then, with regard to it, we must remember that this is not the description of tax- ation which presses most heavily on the inhabitants of Ireland. As far as the tax-payer himself is con- cerned, there seems no reason why the individual with a certain income in Ireland should be free from the tax to which the individual with similar income in England is subject. No doubt there is some force in the argument, that the productive capital of Ireland may, as. a whole, suffer more from the absorption consequent on the income tax, than the amazingly prolific capital of Great Britain, yet it is hardly sufficiently strong to justify the selection of this description of taxation as that, the reduction of which, would be the most beneficial to the country. Again, with the exception of the spirit duty, there is no tax peculiarly oppressive on any Irish manufacture or trade. The spirit duty, to be sure, is an exception, and its reduction has been proposed. On the other hand, so far as such reduction would lead to increased cheapness in the commodity, and 87 increased cheapness to increased consumption, it is doubtful whether the reduction would tend to the moral and material benefit of the country. The reduction, probably, is advocated moreTor the sake of the producer and manufacturer than for the sake of the consumer, and, no doubt, in this respect, many strong arguments may be urged in its favour. Like the malt tax in Great Britain, it is represented as a tax on the agricultural interests of the country, and there can be little doubt that, should the anti-malt-tax agitation succeed in Eng- land, the reduction or abolition of the duty on Irish spirits must accompany the change. If not, the present inequality of imperial burdens will be still further increased, and further confirmation will be given to the theory, that similarity in taxes by no means implies equality in burden. If, then, indirect taxation cannot be altered, peculiarly for Ireland, without such inconvenience and so many disadvantageous results as would render it more hurtful than useful ; if direct tax- ation be not that which presses most severely on Ireland; and if the spirit duty — the only principal tax which presses on Irish manufacture — be not selected for reduction, must we conclude that no- thing can or ought to be done in the matter ? In the first place, one very obvious conclusion which seems to me to arise from the facts we have considered is this : that in any reduction of taxation which may hereafter take place, such imposts should be selected for remission 88 as press most heavily on Ireland; and, on the other hand, in the imposition of new taxes, such as would press least heavily on her should be chosen. Should the general interest of the empire require a departure from this rule, and should the imposition or remission of taxes in a different ratio from that indicated above, appear expedient, then Ireland would have a claim to be exceptionally treated. Perhaps, to a certain extent, this claim at present exists, for such has been the course of remission and imposition of taxes during the last twelve years, that whilst it undoubtedly tended to the development of British trade and British re- sources, it decidedly increased the proportion of the national burdens thrown on Ireland. But besides the direct readjustment of the tax- ation of the country to which I have just alluded, something also in an indirect form might be effected. Here I may refer to one of the most im- portant proposals brought before the House of Commons during the late session of parliament, viz., the proposed interference of Government in the regulation of railway tariffs. I have before incidentally compared railway fares with certain taxes; and if we examine carefully their nature and effects, we shall find their resemblance very strong. The cost of conveyance of goods from the place of production to that of consumption is now chiefly represented by railway fares, and this cost of conveyance affects the producer and consumer 89 exactly in the same way as a tax to a similar amount. It is, moreover, a tax of the indirect description, and, for the most part, one on articles of general consumption, and, therefore, a tax of that description which is found to press most heavily on the Irish population. Had railways been originally constructed by the state, and were they under Government control and management, the tariff would generally be considered a tax ; but its effects do not alter from the fact that it is now regulated by private companies. Indeed, its evil effects are only aggravated by this, for it is the business of a company to look mainly to making large profits and to having large dividends, and to frame their tariffs to this end; whilst a government might be supposed to frame them for the general benefit of the country. In whatever light we regard the nature of rail- way fares, it is clear that their effects are similar to those of similar taxes, and their reduction would be accompanied with similar results. In their effects they resemble taxes on production, taxes on consumption, and taxes on trade ; they are levied, as 1 mentioned before, in the indirect form, and yet are of such a character that they can be easily remitted or reduced in one por- tion of the empire without a similar reduction in all; and the benefit which would arise from their reduction is not one which would be confined to any individual, to any class, or to any locality, but is one which would be felt by the general 90 producing, consuming, and trading population of the whole kingdom. Wherever any of the articles conveyed would be consumed, there would the benefit be felt; and a reduction of the fares on Irish railways, for instance, might make its effects known in the great consuming populations of Liverpool and Manchester. It may be said, indeed, that railway fares have nothing to do with state taxation. These charges, after all, are not taxes; their effects may be similar, but still they are but tariffs of private companies, guaranteed to them by the state, with which we have no right to deal. But is this strictly correct ? Railway companies practically possess a monopoly of the modes of conveyance in the country, but this monopoly has been given to them subject to certain conditions, and one of these conditions, subject to which all railways made since the year 1844 have been constructed, is, to a right on the part of the government to step in and purchase them for the benefit of the nation. The time appointed for putting this right into force was also laid down in the year 1844, and has just now arrived, and into the desirability of its exercise a commission is now inquiring. Last session of parliament a proposal was made that an experiment on the state purchase and the lowering of fares should be first tried with regard to the Irish railways. It was urged by the advo- cates of this proposal that the reduction of rail- way fares would not lead to any ultimate loss in 91 the receipts. They argued that, like a reduction in the rates of certain taxes, the increase in the number of payments at the lower rate would more than counterbalance any immediate loss consequent on the reduction; they showed the very great difference between the rates charged in Ireland, and those charged in foreign countries where the railways were in the hands or under the direction of the government; and they also * pointed to the very great increase in the receipts where the low fares were adopted. The state of the case, then, at present is simply this. The government have the power of taking possession of the Irish railways and of lowering the fares, and consequently they have the power of remitting to Ireland charges similar to so much indirect taxation. The exercise of this power, some say, would cause no loss to the exchequer; but even if it did, has Ireland no claim to the re- mission? We have already seen that to free the commerce of Great Britain from the shackles of indirect taxes, to open up her trade, and to ex- tend her manufactures, the taxation of Ireland has been proportionately largely increased; yet this has been held as a fair, wise, and reasonable proceeding, and surely if for similar purposes in Ireland some calls have to be made on the national exchequer, the demand is not unrea- sonable. If to the Irish producer and trader, and to the consumer, in whatever portion of the king- dom he resided, advantages could be given by the 92 reduction of railway fares, similar to those arising from the remission of so much indirect taxation; and if this could be given without any loss, or, at all events, without the entire loss of the revenue remitted, are there not very strong reasons in favour of its being tried? We have before seen the difficulties attendant on any attempt to bring about a readjustment of Irish taxation. We know that that taxation has enormously increased; we may feel pretty certain it is higher in proportion to the resources of the country than the taxation of Great Britain; we know that it is in the indirect form it is chiefly contributed, and that three-fourths of it arise from duties on articles of general consumption; but to remedy this in a way that would affect all classes generally is the difficulty. In the reduction of rail- way fares we have a clear, simple, and efficacious method of accomplishing this. We know that these reductions would operate in the same way as remissions of indirect taxation to a similar amount, and yet would be attendant with none of the disadvantages and inconveniences which, as before mentioned, render every special reduction of indirect taxation for Ireland almost an impossi- bility. The reduction of railway charges would add to the receipts of the landowner, of the manufac- turer, and of the trader, just in the same way as the remission of a tax on the produce of the land, on manufactures, and on trade, would operate, and, by diminishing the cost of conveyance, would so 93 far diminish the difficulty of distance, and place the lands of Ireland, as it were, in close proximity with the consuming centres of Great Britain. Moreover, we must not forget, that all at present proposed regarding the railways of Ireland is as an experiment. There cannot be any question of the fact, that could railway tariffs be lowered through governmental interference, without any loss to the exchequer, this would be of immense benefit to the nation, and the system under which it arose should be extended to the whole United Kingdom. But, in the first instance, before any- thing is known by experience on the subject, the railway system of Great Britain is so extensive that it would be a hazardous undertaking to deal with it all at once, yet to deal with it by piece- meal would be very difficult. An experiment on a small scale is absolutely essential in the com- mencement, and this is what Ireland offers the facility for attempting. Any detailed examination of the merits or other- wise of the proposed assumption of the railways by the State would, of course, be quite foreign to the purpose of this sketch, and would open up a subject of entirely too great magnitude. I refer to it here only in its financial aspect, with the view of showing that should it, in the first in- stance, involve a call on the national exchequer, yet this ought not to be an insuperable difficulty, as, for other reasons, Ireland would seem fairly entitled to a remission of taxation if such could 94 be given consistently with the general well-being of the whole empire. Besides remissions of taxation, other means for bringing about a readjustment of the national burdens, through the instrumentality of public expenditure, have been proposed. Into a consider- ation of these I do not purpose to enter, as my object is rather to clear away the difficulties which shroud the facts of the case, than to discuss the in- tricate points of political economy connected with the employment of the public revenue. I may, however, briefly state, that it seems to me that the public expenditure should be guided by rules quite irrespective of considerations as to the locality where the money was raised, and that the only valid argument in favour of public ex- penditure in any locality is, that in that locality the object for which it is expended can be best accomplished. Of course this does not so strictly apply to grants or advances for works of public utility. To extend the usefulness of these, and to give to Ireland a full participation in this benefit, * seems to be the general desire ; but still they can be regarded only as supplementary to, and not forming a part of, the financial system of the empire. With these remarks l now close this little sketch, and can only say, that if I have succeeded in put- ting this subject in a clearer light, and in placing more prominently before such of the public as take an interest in it, the principal points of in- 95 terest laid before the Taxation Committee, I have accomplished all I desired, and have to thank such of my readers as have followed me through, per- haps, dry and uninteresting details of a rather intricate subject. John F. Fowler, Printer, 3 Crow Street, Dame Street, Dublin. 4