L I B R.AFLY OF THE U N I VERS ITY Of ILLI NOI5 y y THE GAME LAWS. BY G. SHAW LEFEYRE, M.P. • LONDON: WILLIAM EIDGWAT, 160 PICCADILLY, W. 1874. Price Six;pence. PREFACE. Apology is scarcely needed for presenting to the public, at the present time^ any observations on the Game Laws, inasmuch as the numerous Bills brought before Parliament in successive Sessions, and the Report of the recent Committee of the House of Commons, shew that while there is great and pressing desire for legislation, there is still greater diversity of views as to the best mode of giving relief from the evils complained of, and which to a great extent are admitted on all hands. Whatever may be thought of the conclusions at which I arrive, I hope that the historical and legal illustrations may not be without their value in determiaing the views of those who are interested in this subject. I have dealt mainly with the law of England and Wales, and have only mentioned incidentally IV some of the points in respect of which the law of Scotland differs. There are other points of difference in the Scotch law, but I believe that substantially the general scope of my observations and conclusions will apply equally to Scotland as to England. The question, however, of Deer Forests is a distinct one, and is not touched upon in the following pages. G. S. L. The group of statutes which constitute the pre- sent Game Law of England dates no further back than the year 1831, when, with one exception, all previous enactments relating to Game were re- pealed, and the right to take or sell game was based on a new principle. Previous to that year no person was permitted to kill game unless qualified either by the possession of freehold or leasehold property of the annual value of £100, or by hold- ing the status of esquire. Landowners by virtue of this qualification and irrespective of agreement, practically exercised the exclusive right of sporting over their lands let to farming tenants. Lords of Manors still claimed the right to game on the lands of the copyhold tenants of their manors, and the sale of Game was wholly illegal, and was punishable by severe penalties. These laws may be traced without difficulty to the feudal principles which were introduced into this country by the Norman conquerors. Under the older Saxon law every freeholder had the full liberty of sporting over his land, provided he abstained from the King's forests. The Eoyal forests were, doubtless, even then of great extent, but the prerogative of the Sovereign did not ex- tend beyond their limits, and in no way interfered with the free exercise of rights by other land- owners. We find; for instance, that Canute set bounds and limits to the Eoyal forests^ and the B better to have liis own preserved from offenders, he made this law at Winchester in the first year of his reign : — " Volo lit omnis liber homo pro libito habeat venerem sive viridem in planis suis super terras suas sine chacea tamen et devitcnt omnes nieam ubicunque earn habere voluero." This was also the ancient law of the Scandina- vian continent whence Canute probably derived it : " Cuique enim in proprio fundo quamlibet feram quo mode venari perraissum." And in the laws of Edward the Confessor it is laid down: — " Sit quilibet homo dignus venatione mea in sylva et in agris propriis et in dominio suo ; et abstineat omnis homo a vena- riis regiis ubicumque paeem eis habere voluerit." After the Norman conquest, however^ a new doc- trine was asserted, and the right of taking all beasts of chase or venary, wherever they might be found, and without regard to the ownership of the soil, was claimed by the Sovereign for himself, or for such only as he should duly authorize. These restrictive laws relating to forests and game had been introduced generally in Europe, at the same time and by the same people, who were the authors of the feudal system. The conquering Generals of the northern invaders, when they settled the economy of the countries they had subdued, and partitioned them among their chiefs and feudatories upon the condition of military ser- vice, found it necessary to keep the natives of these countries in as low a condition as f)Ossible, and espe- cially to prohibit them the use of arms. Hunting and sporting were therefore prohibited, and the generals reserved these rights to themselves or to those chiefs immediatelv below them, to whom they thought it safe to entrust such rights. The Norman kings introduced this principle to England after the conquest, and being themselves mighty hunters, carried it out not only as matter of state policy but of personal enjoyment. In later times the Norman lawyers vindicated this claim of the Sovereign, partly on the principle that the King was the ultimate proprietor of all the lands in the kingdom, which were held of him as Lord paramount of the fee, and that therefore he had the right to enter on any estate and take all wild creatures at his pleasure, and partly on a maxim of the law that such creatures were " bona vacantia," and having no other owner, belonged to the King by virtue of his prerogative. . Bracton states the Royal prerogative thus : — " Habet etiam Eex de jure gentium in manu sua quaa de jure naturali deberunt esse communia; sicut feras bestias efc aves non domesticos." And Manwood, an early writer on the Forest Laws, says: — " In like manner wild beasts of yenary and beasts and fowls of chase and warren being things of great excellency, they are meetest for the dignity of a prince for his pastime and delight, and therefore they do most properly belong unto the king only." It is probable, however, that these were rather the after-thoughts of lawyers anxious to obtain royal favour, than the true explanation of the ori- gin of the claim asserted by the feudal sovereigns, B 2 and that the more probable cause is that already alluded to, namely, that as conquerors of new ter- ritory, they found it expedient as matter of state policy to enforce this claim, a policy which also co- incided with their predilections for the chase. Whatever its origin, the prerogative thus claimed on behalf of the Crown was exerted with the ut- most vigour by the earlier Norman Kings, not only in the ancient forests, but in new forests which the Conqueror and his sons made, by laying together large tracts of country, depopulated for this pur- pose, and without the consent of the owners or any compensation for the damage done. In these forests great oppression and tyranny were exercised by virtue of special forest laws, for the sake of preserving the beasts of chase, and the killing of any animal was punishable in the same manner as the killing of a man. In the Anglo-Saxon Chro- nicle of the year 1087 there is a piteous descrip- tion of the result of the Forest laws of William the Conqueror : — " He made large forests for the deer, and enacted laws therewith, so that whoever killed a hart or a hind should be blinded. As he forbade killing the deer, so also the boars ; and he loved the tall stags as if he were their father. He also appointed concerning the hares that they should go free. The rich complained, and the poor murmured; but he was so sturdy that he recked nought of them. They must will all that the King willed, if they would live or would keep their lands, or would hold their possessions or be maintained in their rights." Ordericus Yitalis, in the time of Henry I., said of that monarch, " Omnem ferarum venationem totius Anglia) sil^i peculiarem vindicavit et vix paucis nobilioribus ac familiaribus privilegium in propriis saltibus venandi permisit." Until the reign of King John this prerogative applied only to four-footed game, but that monarch extended it equally to winged game. In the words of Matthew Paris, Anno 1209, " Rex Anglorum Johannes ad natale Domini fuit apud BristoUeum et ibi capturam avium per totam Angliam inter- dixit." The hardships, vexations, and cruelties resulting from these laws became at last wholly insupportable to the general body of landowners, and they pressed for a relaxation of the Forest laws and for a limitation of the King's prerogative of game with equal pertinacity as for Magna Charta itself, and by the Charta de Foresta (9 Henry III.) A.D. 1225, confirmed by Edward I. a.d. 1299, all the lands which had been afforested by Henry II. Richard I. and John, except the proper demesnes of the Crown, w^ere disafforested and freed from the Forest laws, and the Royal forests were stripped of their most oppressive privileges and regulations. The principal clauses of this famous charter are worthy of attention, as, better than any description, they shew what must have been the evils they were intended to remedy. Chap. 1. — First, all forests which King Henry our grand- father afforested shall be viewed by good and lawful men, and if he had afforested any other wood than his own demesne to the damage of him whose wood that was, it shall be disafforested, and if he had afforested his own wood it shall remain forest, saving the common of herbage and of other things in the same forest, to them wlio before were accustomed to have it. 6 Cliap. 3 extended the same measure to forests which had been afforested by * King Richard our uncle, and King John our father/ Chap. 10. — No man from henceforth shall lose either life or member for killing our deer. But if any man be taken and convict for taking our venison he shall make a griev- ous fine if he have anything thereof; and if he have nothing to lose he shall be imprisoned a year and a day, and after a year and a day expired, if he can find sufiicient sureties he shall be delivered, and if not he shall abjure the realm of England. Chap. 12. — Every freeman may henceforth without hin- drance make in his own wood or on his own land which he hath in the forest, a mill, a fish pond, a pool, a marl pit, a dike or arable land without the covert in arable land, so that it be not to the annoyance of any neighbour. Chap. 13.-— Every freeman may have in his own woods ayries of hawks, sparrow hawks, faulcons, eagles and herons, and shall also have the honey that may be found in his woods. Chap. 15. — All persons outlawed for our forest only from the time of King Henry our grandfather, until our first coronation, may come to our peace without let, and shall find good sureties that henceforth they incur no forfeiture unto us concerning our forest. From the time of the Charta de Foresta, follow- ing closely upon the more imj^ortant Magna Charta, the prerogative of the Sovereign sensibly declined. The right of the Crown to game over all lands, irrespective of ownership, was still maintained as a principle of law, but practically the Sovereign no longer exercised this right, except in the ancient forests and on his own demesnes, and it was no longer legal for him to create a chase or forest over the land of a subject without his consent. It was still held, however, that no right of chase or free warren could be created witliout the sanction of the Crown, and during the reigns of the first three Edwards an infinite number of such grants were made to the principal nobility, from which it may be inferred that, by law^, the game still belonged to the Crown. These grants appear to have extended not only to the demesne lands of the feudal lords, but also to all the freehold lands and copyhold or customary holdings within their manors ; and gradually it became understood that a grant of a manor from the Crown, or a grant of a tract of land with jurisdiction constituting it a manor, carried with it the right of sporting; and for many genera- tions it was held that this right of sporting vested in the feudal lord, extended over the freehold and copyhold lands within the manor. After the Charta de Foresta however, it does not appear that the Sovereign ever created a forest or chase for himself without the consent of the owrier of the soil, nor cauld he grant right of chase or free warren to a person over the lands of another in a separate manor. It is recorded that Henry VIII, before making a chase at Hampton Court, obtained the consent of the freeholders or copyholders over whose land the chase was to extend ; and although in later years Charles I. endeavoured to extort money by the enforcement of the Forest laws, extending the limits of the Royal forests by high-handed pro- ceedings, under the colour of inquests, for the recovery of the Crown forestal rights, w^hich had been allowed to sleep, and imposing enormous fines 8 on those who were declared to have infrino-ed on those rights, Parliament again interposed, and in the 16th year of his reign an Act was passed which remedied this evil, and finally settled the extent of all royal forests according to their boundaries in the 20th year of James I, annulling all the peram- bulations and inquests by which they had been subsequently enlarged. The feudal Lords, who had so successfully as- serted their own rights as against their Sovereign to kill game in their seignories, were not the more inclined to be lenient to those below them. As already explained, they obtained grants from the Crown of chase and free warren in their manors, and as against the freehold and copyhold tenants, they exercised, until a much later date, the same rigour, against which they had themselves rebelled. Sir W. Blackstone, after tracing the origin of the game laws, and explaining the early claims of the Sovereign, adds — " rrom this root has sprung a bastard slip, known by the name of the Game Law, now arrived to a wantoning in its highest vigour, both founded on the same unreasonable notion of permanent property in wild creatures, and both productive of the same tyranny to the Commons, but with this difference, that the forest laws established a mighty hunter throughout the land, the game laws have raised a little Nimrod in every manor," As the feudal system gradually passed away the rights and duties of feudal lords, or lords of manors, almost imperceptibly diminished, the freehold tenants of manors emancipated themselves from the jurisdiction of their lords, and copyhold 9 tenants by degrees acquired a right to their hokl- ings, subject only to the payment of customary rents, fines, or services. It was not, however, till the reign of Queen Anne that a doubt was raised as to the right of a lord of a manor to the game on the lands of the freeholders of his manor, and it was then said by some of the judges that a lord of the manor could not enter on the freehold estate of another, though situate within the bounds of his manor, for the purpose of sporting. The ques- tion, however, was never fully argued or finally adjudged. Neither was the right of the lord to sport over the copyhold lands within his manor decided, but till a very late time the better opinion was that the lord retained this right. Mr. Cruise, one of the ablest lawyers of his day, said on this subject : — '' As to copyhold estates tliey still form a portion of the demesnes of the manor of which they are held, and therefore I presume that the lord has a right to huat over them unless barred by a non-user. For considering the original baseness of the tenure, it cannot be supposed that the lord relinquished that royalty over these lands or that a right of hunting could have been given to a mere villein. It is however very extra- ordinary that this point has never been settled." It was not till 1831 that the question was finally decided. The Act amending the Game Laws pro- vided that lords of manors should have the ri2:ht of sporting over the wastes of their manors, and by implication this has been held to negative any right of sporting over the freehold or copyhold lands within the manor. Unless, therefore, the lord of a manor can show that midcr the special 10 customs of his manor he is clearly entitled to the game on the copyholds within it, he cannot now under the general law make claim thereto. Landowners, however, have ever maintained, either by law or by contract, the right to sport over the lands of their ordinary farming tenants. Till 1831 it was considered that this right was irrespective of any reservation of game in the lease or aofreement. The Act of 1831, however, reversed this presumption, and in the absence of any reser- vation, gave the game to the tenant, leaving the parties free to make what agreement on the subject they should think fit. The Act fully recognized the power of the landlord to reserve the game and the exclusive right of sporting, and the law has from an early time recognized the possibility of a separate estate being created in the game and the land. Not only can the landlord reserve the game in letting his land to a farmer, but he can separate the right of sporting altogether from the ownership of the land, and let or sell the one apart altogether from the land itself. From a very early date the rights thus vested in the principal landowners by the Crown were sup- ported by legislative enactments, which took the form of requiring a property qualification as a condition to the right of killing game. The earliest trace of such qualification being- required is to be found in the 13 Richard II, chapter 13th, which provided as follows :— " Eorasmuch as divers artificers, labourers and servants and grooms keep greybouiids and other dogs, and on the Holy days 11 when good Christian people be at Church hearing divine service, they go hunting in Parks, Warrens and Connigeries of Lords and others — to the very great destruction of the same, and sometimes under such colour they make their assemblies, con- ferences, and conspiracies for to rise and disobey their alle- giance — it is ordained and assented that no manner of artificer, labourer, nor any other layman which hath not lands or tene- ments to the value of £iO by year, nor any priest nor other clerk if he be not advanced to the value of £L0 by year, shall have or keep from henceforth any greyhound, hound, nor other dog to hunt — uor shall they use fyrets, keys, nets, harepipes, nor cords, nor other engines for to take or destroy deer, hares, nor conies, nor other gentleman's game, upon pain of one year's imprisonment." This statute is important in more than one respect. The canting reference to attendance at Divine service, the desire to make it appear that the meeting of people in pursuit of game led to dangerous assemblies, the description of ' gentle- man's game,' are indicative of the state of public opinion at the time, and of the necessity for justify- ing the new law. This statute was followed by many others in the same direction. The 21 Edward I, c. 2, provided that foresters, porters, and their assistants, should not be troubled if trespassers were killed by them withm their liberty in cases of resistance. The 19 Henry VII, c. 4, provided that no man should shoot with a cross-bow without the King's leave, except he be a lord or have 200 marks land ; and in the 7th year of the same reign is the first mention by statute of pheasants and partridges, and a special provision wa>s passed for their preservation, 12 which was subsequently strengthened by statutes of Elizabeth and James I. Even in the revolutionary days of the Common- wealth no attempt appears to have been made to reduce the harshness of the game laws, and the only law passed relating to the subject, was one putting a further penalty on the illegal killing of deer. A statute of Charles II. continued the monopoly in favour of the landed gentry, and subsequent Acts assisted in carefully shutting out not only the persons who cultivated the soil as tenants, but likewise inferior tradesmen and other persons not endowed with a sufficient degree or estate to war- rant them in pursuing beasts or biixls of game. It is to be observed that from a comparatively early time the qualification to pursue and kill game was based upon property and not upon birth, as was the case in many parts of the Continent, where the feudal system was more rigidly followed to a later date. In France, for instance, the privilege of sporting was, until the Eevolution of 1789, reserved exclu- sively to the nobility. Ordonnances of the years 1395 and 1515 inflicted heavy penalties on the ' roturiers ' who should indulge in the pleasure of killing game, a privilege reserved solely to the seigneurs. If the offence was committed in a royal forest the delinquent was flogged at the gate of the prison ; if the ofl*ence were repeated he was sent to the galleys ; and if, after return, he shewed himself incorrigible, he was subjected to capital punishment. 13 In 1669 fin Ordonnance of Louis XI Y. declared that the right to game belonged exclusively to the King ; it gave permission however to seigneurs to kill game on their own lands, provided these lands were not inconveniently near to the royal forests, and it forbade ' roturiers ' to indulge in any method of killing game even on their own property. De Tocqueville, in describing the Feudal Rights which existed in France before the Revolution of 1789, says: — " The right of the chase was not allowed to be farmed out like that of fishing. It was a personal right arising from the consideration that it belonged to the King, and that the nobles themselves could not exercise it in the interior of their own jurisdiction without the permission of the King. " The right of shooting and hunting was more interdicted to the non-noble than any other right. The fee fief of the non- noble did not even bestow it. So closely observed was the principle, and so rigorous was the right conside^^ed, that the Seigneur was not allowed to give any permission to hunt. Tlie Seigneur, Haut Justicier, possessed the faculty of hunting and shooting on any part of his own jurisdiction, but alone. He was allowed to make regulations and establish prohibitions upon matters relating to the chase throughout its extent. Every Seigneur de Fief, although not having the feudal power of judicial courts, was allowed to hunt and shoot in any part of his fief. Nobles who possessed neither fief nor jurisdiction were allowed to do so upon the lands belonging to them in the immediate neighbourhood of their dwelling houses. It was decided that the non-noble possessing a park upon the terri- tory of a Seigneur Haut Justicier was obliged to leave it open for the diversion of the Lord. Nobles alone were allowed to keep pigeons and even ferrets." Arthur You.ng, in his description of the state of French agriculture before the Revolution, has told 14 us that the most important operations of agricul- ture were fettered and prevented by these game laws. Wild animals, such as boars, and herds of deer, roamed at large through districts called * capitaineries,' where no enclosures for the pro- tection of the crops were permitted. In many parts of the country hoeing and weeding was prohibited, lest the young partridges should be killed; mowing hay, lest the eggs should be de- stroyed ; taking away the stubble, lest the birds should be deprived of shelter ; manuring with night soil, lest the flavour of the game should be im- paired. Complaints for the infraction of these laAvs were tried by the manorial courts, where every species of oppression and fraud were practised. These privileges and abuses were put an end to in 1789. In the memorable sitting of the Assembly on the 4:th of August the noblesse were constrained to abandon their exclusive privilege of sporting, with all other feudal rights. Even the rights of the Crown were not excepted, notwithstanding the favour in which Louis XVI was then held by the Assembly. The Royal monopoly of sport extended for twenty leagues round Paris, and was the cause of most crying iniquities. After a powerful speech from Mirabeau, and on the motion of the Duke of Orleans, all Capitaineries, whether royal or not, and all reserves for sport, under whatever denomination they may have been, were from that moment abolished. The seignorial right to Pigeons, which had been one of the most hated of feudal privileges, was at 15 the same time abolished, and it was provided that thenceforward every person might keep pigeons, subject to the rule, that the birds should be shut up in their dovecotes during the seasons prescribed by the Communes, in the interest of agriculture, or if allowed to be at large during the seasons, might be treated as game by others. The decree which abolished the feudal privileges to game appears to have intended that thencefor- ward game should be property of the owners of the soil, but it provided no remedy against those who should trespass in pursuit of it. For a time, there- fore, no game laws existed, and there resulted over the whole of France a scene of confusion and disorder. Crowds of artizans and mechanics issued from the towns, and, joining the labourers in the agricultural districts, spread themselves over the fields in search of game. Enclosures were broken down, woods were destroyed, and houses were broken open. The disorder which resulted from unrestrained trespass was so great that in a few months it was found necessary to repress it ; and in 1790 a moderate game law was passed, based upon the principle that every owner of property was allowed the exclusive right of sporting on his own land, sub- ject only to rules laid down in the general interest. The principles adopted in 179(J were confirmed in 1844 by the present Game Law of France; and the bulk of the cultivators of the soil being owners of the land, these laws, which in many respects closely resemble our own, have not proved 10 to be oppressive either to tlie cultivator of the soil or to the public. In Germany the same feudal laws prevailed until a much later period. The right of sporting was generally reserved from the proprietorship of the land, and was vested in the feudal magnates. The exercise of this right created the greatest dis- content, and in 1848, the game laws, and all enact- ments as to fence seasons, were abolished throughout Germany by the Frankfort Parliament, which however left the legislative bodies of the different states to decide as to the mode in which the new principle that the shooting should go with the land, should be carried out. In a few states some little compensation was given to the holders of the old seignorial rights of shooting, in others, as in Prussia, none. There followed a brief period of lawlessness, during which any peasant at any time of the year was free to kill game. After a short experience of disorder the several states separately proceeded to re-enact game laws, the general effect of which was that, whilst the sporting over large estates was reserved to the proprietors, the sporting over small estates was vested in the local communes, to be let for the joint benefit of all. In this country the feudal principle, modified in favour of property as distinguished from birth, sur- vived to a later period than in France. It was not till 1831 that a successful effort was made to reform the Game Laws. The enquiries and debates which took place in the House of Commons for many 17 years previous to 1831 show how intolerable had become the burthen of these laws. The change then made was one of the first results of the great Reform movement. The Game Law of that year which swept away all the previous laws based upon privilege, was passed by the Parliament which had been elected under the popular agitation for reform, and before the Reform Act itself became law; but it was a Parliament in which Tenant farmers were not represented ; the Liberal element of the Country was mainly to be found in the County representatives elected by the freeholders, and not by tenants ; and the law bears evident trace of the absence of the voice of the tenant farmers in its preparation. It is much to be re- STetted that at the time when the outburst of feeling against the old laws was so great, the in- terest of farmers was not better represented in the measure which was passed as a substitute. There were not wanting some who predicted that not less evils would result from the Act of 1831, who foresaw that while it abolished privilege and swept away many cruel and arbitrary laws, it would lead to much greater preservation of game, and to the practice of subletting the right of sporting which had previously been little known. It is probable that had the revision of the Game Laws been postponed till the Reformed Parliament had come into existence, and when under the well known Chandos clause, the tenant farmers had a preponderating influence in County elections, the amended Game Laws would have differed much 18 from those which we now have. For although the Act of 1831 abolished privilege, and opened the door to tenant farmers, who were previously dis- qualified as a class, it will be seen that it gave great facilities for the reservation of game by landlords, and by permitting the sale of game, it gave the sanction of property to game in a sense which was previously wanting, and gave further inducements to that over-preservation of which we now hear so many complaints. It also led to a great extension of the practice of subletting game by the landlords to game tenants, w^ho have no common interest with the farming tenants, a practice more opposed to the interests of farmers, and more hateful to them than the exclusive privileges of their landlords under the old system. Previous to 1831, also, little or nothing was known of battue shooting, which if not having its origin in the desire for profit by the sale of game, at least owes much to the possibility of such sale, and which in its present exaggerated form is in a great measure due to the fashion set by the luxu- rious and lavish Court of the Second French Empire. Whatever may be the defects of the Act of 1831, it made bold and sweeping changes. It entirely abolished all property qualification for the right of sporting ; it repealed a great number of statutes by which these property rights were enforced, and by which the sale of game was prohibited. In lieu it substituted a moderate day trespass 19 law, directed only against persons wrongfully in pursuit of game. It definitely settled the law as to the rights of Lords of manors, giving them the right to shoot over the wastes of their manors, and by implication refusing them the right to shoot over the lands of their copyhold or freehold tenants. Eecognizing the fact that hitherto tenant farmers had no right to kill game, and that landowners as a rule exercised this right over their lands, it re- served to landlords the exclusive right of sporting over all lands held under existing contracts, except where the right had been expressly granted to the tenant. On the other hand, however, it provided that in future lettings the right of sporting was to run with the land, except where reserved by deed or agree- ment. Whenever such reservation was made by the landlord, it enforced the right of the landlord by im- posing penalties of £1 for every head of game killed by the tenant in contravention of such contract. It gave permission for the first time for the general sale of game ; but required that persons should take out a license for such sale, and there- fore retained a certain control over those engaged in the trade in interests of game preservers. It provided a close time for certain kinds of game, excluding hares and rabbits from this cate- gory, and finally it required licenses or game certi- ficates from those who should in future shoot game. The most important provision of this Act, how- ever, is undoubtedly that which substitutes for pre- c 2 20 ^ ■T vious laws a moderate trespass law directed against persons who should trespass in the day-time in pursuit of game, and enforces it by a penalty of 4O5 and costs of the conviction; if five or more persons should commit the trespass the penalty is increased to £5. Power is also given to require trespassers to give their names and places of abode, and in the event of their refusing, to arrest them for the purpose of taking them before a justice of the peace, where upon conviction the penalty is in- creased to £5. The penalty is further increased by £5, where five or more persons, any of whom being armed with guns, endeavour by violence or intimidation to prevent any authorized person from approaching them for the purpose of requiring them to quit the land or of ascertaining their names and abode. This Act left unrepealed the Night Poaching Act of 1828 (9 Geo. IV. c. 69). Under this Act, which is still in force, any person unlawfully taking game by night may, upon conviction before two magistrates, be committed to gaol for three months with hard labour, and at the expiration, in default of finding sureties for not offending again for the space of one year, may be imprisoned for a further six months with hard labour. The pe- nalties are doubled for a second offence, and for a third offence, penal servitude for five years may be awarded. Owners and occupiers of land or their servants are empowered to arrest offenders, and if resistance is made, the punishment may be increased to penal servitude for five years ; and if three or 21 more persons, any one of whom be armed, unlaw- fully enter land for the purpose of taking game or rabbits, they are liable to not less than five years or more than ten years penal servitude. Lastly, in the year 1862 the Act known as the Poaching Prevention Act was passed by the united support of the County members, and against the strongest protest and opposition of the then Secre- tary of State, Sir George Grey. This Act enables policemen to arrest and search men going along the high road whom they have reason to suspect of having been illegally taking game, and gives power to Magistrates to convict if they think that the accused have wrongfully obtained the game which is found upon them. The object aimed at by this Act was to break up the gangs of poachers, who were well known by the police to make a trade of poaching, and who were frequently met by the police on their return from a raid on some neighbouring preserve, with all the loot upon them, but who from want of evidence could not be arrested and punished. From this statement it will be seen that what are called the Game Laws, now consist of three groups of enactments. 1. Those in the interest of preserving the species, forbidding the killmg and sale of certain species during the breeding season ; the policy of this has been greatly extended by the Act of 1869, which made a close season for Sea Birds, and by the Act of 1872, which made a close season for a great variety of small birds. 22 2. Those protecting the right of sporting. (a) By making trespass in the day time in pur- suit of game, inckiding rabbits, punishable by a fine of 405, the penalty to be increased to £5, if five or more persons commit the offences, and an additional £5 if any of them were . arrested. (5) By making trespass at night in pursuit of game, punishable by three months imprison- ment with hard labour, to be increased for second and third offences, and further in- creased to five or ten years penal servitude, if three or more persons, of whom one be armed, commit the offence. (c) By making the breach of contract between landlord and tenant for the reservation of game, punishable in the case of the tenant killing game, by a penalty of £1 for every head of game (not, however, applicable to rabbits). (d) By giving power to the police to arrest and search persons whom they suspect of having been trespassing in pursuit of game, and power to magistrates to convict where they have reason to believe that such trespass has been committed (applicable to rabbits, equally as to game). 3. Those requiring licenses, partly in the interest of the Excise and partly in the interest of pre- serving game by restricting the number of persons killing or selling it. a. License required for sale of game. 23 h. License required to shoot game. c. The Gun Tax. These various enactments do not all apply to the same kinds of game, some include hares and rabbits, others exclude them or either of 'them. Before proceeding further to comment on the policy and general results of these statutes, it may be well to say a few words upon the legal status of game, and to point out in what respects it differs, on the one hand, from beasts or birds, which having been appropriated and domesticated, are invested with the attributes of property, and on the other hand, from those which are so wild, use- less, or noxious, that they have not even the pro- tection afforded to Game. It need hardly be pointed out that domesticated animals, such as oxen, sheep, and poultry, have all the true attributes of property. They have been appropriated, bred, and reared, and can always be fully identified. If they stray from the land of their owner they do not cease to be his property, nor can the occupier of adjoining land to which they stray appropriate or kill them, even if they be doing damage to his property ; he must drive them back or pound them, and he can recover from the owner any damage done by them. The really wild beasts or birds on the other hand, such as the Fox, Badger, Rat, or Carrion Crow and Rook, have none of these attributes. They have never been appropriated, they cannot be identified, 24 they are not recognized as of any value, but rather as destructive and noxious. The law therefore declines to regard them as property, or to afford them any protection, and if for the sake of the sport of hunting, the fox has a fictitious value, and receives a certain protection, in order that it may afford sport to those who follow the hounds, it is not such a value as is in any way recognized by law. Midway between these and the domesticated creatures lie those species which are generally included in the term 'game.' They differ from the domesticated species in. that they have not been appropriated and cannot be identified. They differ from the species at the opposite end of the scale in that they have a value when captured. More closely, however, to the domesticated creature lies the pigeon or dove. The wild pigeon does not come under the head even of game. The domesticated pigeon, or dove, closely approxi- mates to the condition of poultry. The law however which applies to the latter is not altogether free from difficulty and doubt. In feudal times pigeons were, like game, the special right of the Feudal Lord ; the erection of a dovecote was a ' liberty seignorial ;' and it was not till a comparatively late period that even a freeholder or a copyholder could erect one without the consent of the Lord of the Manor ; it followed that pigeons, often kept in such numbers as to be a positive nuisance to the neighbourhood, were fed at the expense of the neighbouring farmers. Under the present state of the law, pigeons are the property of the person 25 who breeds them, they are for the most part capable of identification, they frequent the same dovecote, they fly in flocks together, they can be the sub- ject of larceny, if taken in the dovecote, even where they have the full opportunity of getting out and enjoying themselves in the air ; if they wander ofl" the land of their owner, they do not cease to be his property, nor is it the right of any person on whose land they light to kill and appropriate them. If they do injury by taking his seed or corn, he may drive them away, and only in the event of their doing repeated and serious damage to an extent which becomes a positive nuisance would it be right in him to kill them, and even in such case the dead birds remain, it is believed, the property of their owner. The live birds do not appear to have acquired fully the status of property so as to be treated as personal property on the death of the owner. They descend to the heir- at-law with the land. It is not lawful for a man to keep pigeons at the expense of his neighbours, to feed on their crops and their recently sown corn ; but if he keeps no more than is reasonable, having regard to his own steading, and if he provides them with food at home in reasonable sufliciency, he has a right to expect that when they light on his neigh- bour's land they will be treated as still his j^ro- perty, and not be sacrificed either to a love of sport or to the unreasonable alarm of petty damage. It is doubtful, however, whether, except when in the dovecote, they can be the subject of larceny, and a special statute was passed (7 & 8 Geo. IV. c. 39) 26 imposing a penalty upon persons who should unlaw- fully and wilfully kill or take house doves or pigeons under such circumstances as shall not amount to larceny at common law. It appears also that the excessive breeding of pigeons may be a common nuisance, and be indictable as such. The case of pigeons is the more worthy of attention, and has been explained at length, because in many respects pheasants, when reared by hand, as is now so often the case, very closely approximate to them. The Swan is another bird nearly allied to the domesticated creature. If swans be reduced into possession of a private person, they become his property, but if the swans be at liberty on a river, they are the prerogative of the Crown, and in some cases have been granted by ancient charter from the Crown, as in the case of the swans on the Thames, which are the privilege of the Corporation of London, although they have been bred on the land of private owners and are often astray on such land. If a swan the property of a private person be astray, but shows an intention of returning to its own water, it is deemed to be private property. It may be doubted, however, whether it can be the subject of a larceny, except where it is taken from the land of its owner under circumstances which make it certain that it had been appropriated. The case of Deer, again, presents some difficul- ties and anomalies. In their wild and unappro- priated state they are not property ; neither are they game within the meaning of the game laws ; 27 but they are the subject of special laws, directed against persons who unlawfully kill them. If, how- ever, they have been reduced into possession, and tamed and reclaimed from their wild state, they acquire the status of property, and will pass to the executors of the deceased owner, or on his bank- ruptcy, can be seized by his assignees and sold away from the land, and in such case they are the subjects of larceny. In large parks, how- ever, where the deer are not tamed or reclaimed, they cannot be said to be property; in such cases they pass like rabbits in a warren, or like pigeons in a dove house, with the land itself to the heir at law, and cannot be treated as personal pro- perty distinct from the land. Ducks when domesticated are the subject of property in the same manner as poultry, but in the wild state, do not even come into the category of game. It appears, however, that a decoy for ducks is recognised by the law as a kind of trade, giving to the owner a certain right, on the ground that although it tends ' to spoil gentlemen's game, yet it brings money into the land ' ; it is, therefore, unlawful to fire off guns or otherwise to disturb and injure a decoy, and whoever does so is liable to an action at law for civil damage. On the other hand Rooks are not recognized at law as birds entitled to any protection, even under the game laws. It is said of the rook, '' that it is not supposed to cost anything for its main- tenance ; its attributes are ' fera natura ' and de- structiveness, and neither by common law nor by 28 statute is it deemed as a profitable food." Rooks are elsewhere spoken of as ' noyful fowl/ and though, in modern times, a rookery has come to be con- sidered as a pleasing accessory to a gentleman's park, affording a certain amount of sport at the time when the young rooks are just coming off the nest, yet it does not appear that it has acquired any status in the eye of the law, and no action will lie for the disturbance or destruction of a rookery, however wilful pr wanton. Passing now to the further extreme, the law gives no protection to such creatures as Squirrels and Hedgehogs ; they are not property, and have no protection under the game laws. Badgers and Ferrets are considered such noxious animals that not only is no protection afforded to them, but it is held that no action of trespass is maintainable for foUomng them on to the land of a stranger, digging them out and killing them. So, also, it has been held of the Fox ; but no more should be done than is necessary to kill the fox, if it be followed into the land of another ; and this law can only hold good now in those parts of the country where the fox is still considered to be a nuisance and not the subject of the so-called noble sport of hunting. It was endeavoured, on the same ground, to sus- tain the right to follow the hounds over the lands of those who objected to hunting; but Lord Ellen- borough directed the jury, in an action for civil trespass against a gentleman who was hunting the fox for his own pleasure, that if they were satisfied that the good of the public had not been the sole 29 object, they should find for the plamtiff ; thus negativing the right to follow the hounds over another man's land. And in another case of the same kind, where an action for trespass was brought against the huntsman of the Berkeley hunt, it was held that the damages for which he was liable, did not extend merely to the individual act of the huntsman himself, but to such mischief as had been occasioned by those who followed him in the hunt. Of the smaller birds not included under the term game, with the exception of ' woodcock, snipe, and quail,' the law till recently took no notice. Mr. Auberon Herbert, however, in 1872 persuaded ParHament to give protection during the breeding season to a certain number of the feathered tribe, such as robins, finches, and to most of the rarer varieties of small birds ; but Parliament excluded blackbirds, thrushes, sparrows, and even larks from this protection. In respect, however, of both classes, no other protection is given. They are in no sense property, they have no protection under the game laws, and no criminal proceedings can issue for their destruction by trespassers during the open season. We now come to those birds and animals included in the term game. Properly speaking the list is a small one, and the definition of game in the Act of 1831 includes only hares, pheasants, partridges, grouse, blackgame and bustards ; and does not include rabbits, woodcock, snipe, and quail. These latter, however, are included in the principal pro- 9 vision which imposes a penalty for trespassing in pursuit of game. Rabbits are also included in the terms of the Night Poaching Act and the Poaching Prevention Act of 1862 ; they are not included, however, in the clause which imposes a penalty on farmers who in breach of their agree- ment with their landlords kill game on their farms. It may be inferred that any civil contract also which only specifies game does not include rabbits. In this, therefore, and in the exclusion of rabbits from the provision directed against farmers, con- stitutes the onlv difference between rabbits and other game. To all intents, therefore, rabbits may be treated on the same footing as game, for prac- tically they are accorded the same protection. Now although game, and also rabbits, snipe, quail, &c., are recognized by the law as of a certain value, and are protected under the game law, they are equally with the baser species already alluded to and for the same reasons, not considered as property by the law of England. They differ, it is true, in this respect, that they have value when killed, but they are wanting in the essential elements of pro- perty, namely, appropriation and identification. Game, in its wild nature, has ex hypotliesi not been appropriated ; it wanders from field to field, regard- less of ownership ; it cannot be identified. No gamekeeper can swear to the identity of hares, rabbits, partridge, or even, except in very rare cases, of pheasants. The law, therefore, has rather of necessity, arising from the stubborn facts of nature, declined to recognize them as property, 31 and a poacher who has wrongfully taken game cannot be indicted for larceny. Game in a qualified sense is the property of the owner of the land on which it is taken, and not of the person who kills it ; and under the Act of 1831, as already stated, the remedy for wrongfully taking game is not larceny, but trespass for going upon land in pursuit of it. But for the fact that it appears to be so little known, even to many who are in the habit of dis- cussing the game laws, and that it is often suggested that the trespass laws would suffice in lieu of game laws, it would scarcely be necessary to point out that by the law of England simple trespass is not an offence for which a person can be subjected to any criminal process, however small. To constitute a criminal offence, trespass must be accompanied by some malicious damage to property, such as breaking down fences or trampling cropSj and the offence then consists rather in the damage to the property than in the trespass. The only means landowners or occupiers have of dealing with tres- passers is to warn them off their property, and if the trespassers neglect or decline to go, it is then permitted to the landowners or occupiers to eject them forcibly, using such force only as is necessary for the purpose. There is also a civil remedy against a trespasser, but only the value of the damage done can be recovered. So careful indeed has the law been not to allow harm to be done to innocent trespassers so long as they do no damage to property, that it has been held to be illegal to set spring guns or dangerous traps in woods or 32 elsewhere in the hope of injuring trespassers, and therefore of deterring others from entering. The Act of 1831 is in the main a discriminatinor trespass law. Trespass, otherwise not criminal, becomes so if the person be in pursuit of game, and is punishable, if in the day time, by a penalty of 4O5, and, if in the night time, by imprisonment with hard labour. It is important to observe that the offences against the game laws are not in the nature of public offences, but rather of private wrongs. It does not at all follow because a man is in pursuit of game on another man's land, that he is therefore committing an offence against the law ; the offence is in his doing so against the will of the occupier or landowner ; the occupier or landowner, if he does not preserve game, may be careless on the point whether his grounds are entered or game taken or not ; and if he cares not to enforce the penalty, it is certainly not the duty of any other person to prosecute for the trespass. It is an affair between the landowner or occupier and the trespasser, and it is not one in which the public are interested ; and this is so far recognized that the information for trespass must issue at the instance of the person aggrieved, or by his authority, and the costs of prosecutions under the game laws form an excep- tion to nearly all other cases, and are never paid by the public. The game laws, in fact, afford the means of enforcing private rights, and the ^v^rong committed by a trespasser in pursuit of game is not in the nature of a public wrong which the com- 9 3 munity is much interested in detecting, preventing, or paying for. The Poaching Prevention Act of 1862 appears to have made an exception to this rule. It gave for the first time power to the Police to act in game cases, and has made them, to some extent, game preservers. Under this Act the police are entitled to arrest and search persons on suspicion that they have been illegally upon land in search of game. It also enables the justices to convict without any direct evidence that the accused have actually been trespassing on the land of some person who objects, and practically throws the onus of proving his innocence upon the accused. If, for instance, tAvo or more men are observed by the police going along the road, in the early morning, under any circumstances which raise the suspicion that they have been engaged in poaching, the police may arrest and search them, and if game be found on their persons, the justices are entitled to convict them, upon the same grounds of suspicion, if the accused should not be able to show that they law- fully obtained possession of the game. The power thus given to the police and to the justices is very great, — greater than in the case of any other pro- perty ; with the exception of a few cases in the interest of the Revenue, or in the interest of the public, such as that of Naval Stores, where the accused may be called upon to prove his ignorance, by shewing where he obtained the articles, the law requires in all cases proof of guilt to be tendered by the prosecutor, and does not put the accused to proof D 34 of his innocence. In this respect, therefore, the Poaching Prevention Act has extended a greater sanction to game than is given to most other pro- perty. In Scotland, however, the judges have interpreted the law differently, and have held that neither the arrest nor the conviction is justified, unless there be evidence to show that the accused has been trespassing illegally on the land ot some person who objects to it. Under this ruling of the judges the Act has proved to be quite inoperative in Scotland. It might perhaps be presumed that as game is not property, and as the only process, under which it can be preserved against destruction by un- authorized persons, is that of trespass, it would follow the land on which it is to be found and on whose crops it feeds, and that no right could be asserted in it independent of the occupier of the land^ who owns also the growing crops. It is not so, however. The law fully recognizes the possi- bility of severing the game from the occupation of the land, and the right of sporting from the right of cultivating the soil. It has already been pointed out that by the Act of 1831, in the absence of any reservation by the landlord in his lease, the game and the right of sporting is the privilege of the occupying tenant, but it is also possible for the owner of the land, in any lease or contract for letting the land, to reserve to himself the right or privilege of entering upon the land for the purpose of killing the game and rabbits, to the exclusion not only of the public but of the occupier, lessee, Q 5 or tenant himself, and he can also assign this right to any other person; thereby creating two tenants in respect of the same holding, the one a farming tenant, the other a game tenant, without any privity between them or community of interests. The Act of 1831 has also enforced this right of reservation by making it a penal offence for a tenant or occupier, where the landlord has reserved the game, to take or destroy game upon his holding, punishable by a fine of £1 for every head of game then taken, or by imprisonment in default of pay- ment. In this provision it has been already pointed out that rabbits are not included. A tenant farmer therefore may destroy rabbits on his farm without being subject to any criminal proceedings, and sub- ject only to the civil remedy which, under the terms of his lease or holding, the landlord can resort to if rabbits are named in the agreement which reserves the game. As regards the labourers at work on the farm, who cannot be said to be there as trespassers, it is held that if they neglect their duty and snare or destroy game, they become ipso jacto trespassers, and can be proceeded against under the Act of 1831, by the occupier of the land or by the landlord if the right of sporting be reserved. Kot only, therefore, can the landlord prosecute an outsider for trespassing in pursuit of game on land which is in the occupation of his tenant, but he can prosecute the labourers at work on the farm if they take game upon it, and he can prosecute the occupying tenant himself for killing game bred D 2 o G upon the land and fed upon tlie result of his own farming. What the law thus permits and has thus for- tified by unusual precautions (for in very few cases can a breach of contract be punished crim- inally) has become the custom. It may be said that the all but universal practice throughout the country is, that farming land is let with a reserva- tion of game in favour of the landlord and with more or less stringent covenants on the part of the tenants, binding them to preserve the game or to enforce the law against outsiders who trespass in pursuit of game. Judging from the tenor of the debates on the Act of 1831, it would seem that it was intended, by the passing of that Act, to benefit the tenant farmers by securing to them the game on their farms where there was no reservation, and it was evidently ex- pected that in the majority of cases there would be no reservation of game by the landlords. But custom has prevailed against the intention of the legislature and the all but universal rule is for landlords to reserve the game on letting their lands. In many parts of the country it is almost im- possible for a farmer to hire a farm where he has control over the game; he would be shut out from his profession if he insisted on this. The severance of the enjoyment of game from the occupation of the land is a well recognized fact and almost a condition of the existing relations of landlord and tenant. It may be traced directly to the '37 influence of the feudal laws, under which the right of sporting was a seignorial privilege. The feudal lords for long strove successfully to maintain their hold over the hunt, the hawk and the sport, and even when the feudal system was on its decline, the right of sporting was for many centuries confined to the gentry and their servants ; and although it can no longer be claimed as aright by landlords independent of contract, yet the custom w^hich had its origin in right in former days has been stereotyped in our social habits, and in the relations of landlords and tenants. The prevalence of large landed properties, and the all but universal custom for land to be cul- tivated not by its owners, but by tenant farmers, a class comparatively little known in any other country than Great Britain, whether in the old or new world, has also tended to sustain the custom of game preserving and of game reservation by the landlords, and has prevented the more natural combination of occupation of the land and control of the game over it. To complete this review of the legal position of game, it should be added, that the law of England gives no remedy to the tenant farmer against his landlord for damage done to his crops by game re- served under the lease^ however great the damage, and however much the game may have increased beyond what it was at the commencement of the tenancy, unless there be a special agreement on this point. In the absence of such agreement the land- lord or his game tenant may allow the game to increase to any extent, and to do any damage to 38 the crops of the farming tenant without fear of having to make redress. In Scotland the law is dif- ferent, and the tenant can claim compensation where the game has increased beyond what it was at the outset of the tenancy. The cases, however, where such claims have been made good are most rare, and there is admittedly the greatest diffi- culty in estimating the damage done to growing crops by game. The damage by game is not confined only to the actual value of food consumed by it, hares and rabbits spoil much more than they con- sume, and the farmer is deterred from doing his best to obtain produce from the soil by the fear that he is only adding to the food for game and wasting his capital and time. In no case does the law recognize a claim against an adjoining proprietor for damage done by his game, unless it amounts to a common nuisance; short of this, the only remedy is to shut out the hares and rabbits by wire netting or to kill them. The silence of our law on this most important point is in striking contrast to the jurisprudence of the Continent. In France, and in other countries, where the Code Napoleon has been adopted, the provisions of the Code have been construed, so as to give most ample protection to landowners and occupiers against damage done by game coming from the lands of their neighbours. It is fully recognized that it is the obligation of the proprietor of a wood dr forest to keep down the game, and especially rabbits, by all reasonable means, so that his property may not become the 39 harbour, from which the game may make incursions upon the crops of neighbouring proprietors. If the proprietor, by preserving the game, by abstain- ing from shooting it, by putting down rabbits and other game to breed, or by allowing old warrens and rabbit holes to exist where rabbits may be harboured, allows the game to be in excess, he must pay the penalty by recompensing his neigh- bours for any damage done by it ; and the game tenant of a wood or forest stands in this respect in the same position as his landlord. It is recognized, however, that a certain quantity of game is a necessary incident to a wood, and that even extraordinary exertions will not entirely remove the evil. To relieve himself of all possible responsibility, it is advisable that the proprietor of a wood should give leave to his neighbours to follow the rabbits into the wood and there destroy them, or should invite them to join in battues for their destruction. As between landlord and tenant the law is equally explicit and just. If the farmer, by his lease, has agreed to reserve the game to the pro- prietor, he has no ground of complaint against the latter, if the game, of which he complains, comes from the land let to him, or the hedges or little covers comprised in his holding ; but on the other hand, the reservation of the right of sporting to the proprietor does not prevent the farmer from destroying the game which comes from beyond his holding to ravage the produce of his land, and the farmer may employ engines of destruction against 40 such game, during the harvest time, without com- mitting an offence against the game laws, or infringing the contract with his landlord. If on the other hand the game, of which he com- plains, comes from woods in the hands of his landlord, not included in his lease, he has the same rights against his landlord as against any other neighbouring landowner, with whom he has no relations. It would appear also that even where the game is reserved, if the landlord does not take reasonable steps to keep it down, the tenant has a claim against him for damage done to his crops ; and even where, under his lease, the farmer has renounced any action against his landlord, either in respect of game bred on his farm, or in respect of game coming from adjoining covers, yet if the landlord, or his game lessee, does nothing to prevent the ravages of the game, and the damage assumes a great proportion, the law holds that the farmer could never have consented to so terrible a con- dition, which would make his position insupport- able, and enables him to sustain a claim against his landlord, notwithstanding the clause in his lease excluding such claim. Numerous cases have also established the prin- ciples on which the measure of damages, in the case of destruction of crops by game, is to be assessed^ so as to cover not only the actual loss, but the amount which would have been realized by the farmer, if his land had not been overrun by game. In Belgium a special law provides that the indem- nity to be recovered by the farmer, in the event of 41 damage to his crops or fruit by rabbits, shall be estimated at double the actual loss. The subject of the damages caused by game, as treated by the French law, hns been ably dealt with in a treatise by M. Sorel, which is well worthy of the attention of those who interest themselves in this branch of the subject, with reference to this country. Such being, briefly stated, the present law on the subject of game audits historical derivation, we may proceed to examine into its results. This task is the more easy as twice within recent years Committees of the House of Commons have taken evidence on the subject at great length, and we have the fullest and most comprehensive view of all the evils which are complained of, whether by the tenant farmers looking at the question from their own point of view, or from others in the in- terest of the general public. The latest Committee sat throughout the sessions of the years 1872 and 1873, and comparing the evidence taken before it with that taken by the Committee of 1845, it is impossible not to come to the conclusion that the preservation of game has increased in the interval, and that all the evils complained of in the earlier year have since been aggravated. The complaints are twofold, those in the interest of the tenant farmers and those in the interest of the more gene- ral public. The complaint of the tenant farmers is to the effect that preservation of game presents 42 great and increasing obstacles to good farming and to agricultural improvements, and that it is highly unjust that game should be fed at their expense, especially in the case of hares or rabbits, which spoil far more produce than they consume. The complaint from the more general public view is, that preservation of game leads inevitably to poaching, that the labouring class do not and will not be persuaded to regard poaching as a crime, and that consequently large numbers of young men are tempted to break the law, and are subsequently led on to more serious offences ; and further, that by the obstruction to good farm- ing, caused by over preservation of game, the gross produce of the soil of the country is much less than it ought to be. Making every allowance for the highly coloured statements of many of the wit- nesses, it must be admitted that there is much ground for these complaints. It is matter of common knowledge that the pre- servation of game is on the increase, that the reser- vation of game by landlords is almost universal, and that leases contain often elaborately devised co- venants, binding the tenants not only to refrain from killing game themselves, but to assist in pre- venting poachers coming upon the land for that pur- pose ; it is also certain that the fashion for battues has greatly extended, and that where some years ago it was thought a good day's sport for a party of gentlemen to kill 100 or at the utmost 200 head of game, at the present time such bags are considered below the average, and not unfrequently upwards 43 of 1000 head of game are killed within the day. The increase has undoubtedly been mainly in the direction of winged game, and a tendency has been manifested in many quarters to discourage the ex- cessive preservation of ground game. The Com- mittee of 1872-3, in which game preservers were largely predominant, state that " They are satisfied that the practice of keeping up an ex- cessive quantity of grouud game is by no means general either in England or in Scotlaod, and the evidence goes to show that during the last few years there has been in parts of the country a considerable diminution of both hares and rabbits on culti- vated grounds." They proceed to condemn in the strongest terms the practice of keeping up a stock of ground game on cultivated lands : — " There can be no question that the existence of a large number of hares and rabbits upon an arable farm is most pre- judicial to its profitable occupation, and your Committee cannot too strongly reprobate the practice of some landlords and their shooting tenants of keeping up a large stock of those animals on cultivated lands, to the injury of the crops of the farming tenants." They recommend also the exclusion of rabbits from the laws protecting game, and hares were only saved from the same treatment by a majority of one. A careful review of the evidence will convince most readers that the Committee were over san- guine in their belief that the excessive preservation of hares and rabbits has been much diminished. It 44 is true that many of the best landowners have waged war upon their hares and rabbits, and that some game preservers have devoted their energies mainly to winged game; but it is clear that there is still great ground for complaint on the part of the tenant farmers, and the growing neces- sity for improved and more scientific farming has rendered the nuisance of ground game and of excessive preservation yearly more felt. It is also certain that the practice of letting the shooting by the owner of the land has increased of late years, and is the cause of greater complaints on the part of the tenants. As between themselves and their landlords the tenant farmers do not always raise or feel the same objections. They retain the hope that the interest of their landlords where not obscured by an exces- sive love of sport, may protect their tenants from an overplus of game, but where the shooting is let by the landlord, an outsider comes in who has no relation with the tenant, who looks only to his sport, to whom it is matter of indifference what happens to the crops provided he gets his game, and it need hardly be said that the farmer views with aggravated bitterness the destruction of his corn and turnips by the rabbits and hares bred for the amusement, not even of his landlord but of an outsider with whom he has no relation or sympathy. Mr. Read, M.P., says there is no community of interest between the game tenant and the agricul- tural tenant, whose land is generally speaking his means of livelihood. Colonel Robertson, the Chief 45 Constable of Hertfordshire, alliuling to this subject, said : — " 278. Too many covers are let to extraneous people,who come from all parts of the country, mostly from London, who do not care one single pin about the farmer or his crops. If you could do away with that there would be no complaint about the game," It is to be feared that the last statement must be taken cum grano salts ^ but it is undoubtedly the fact that the letting of the shooting by landlords to game tenants is a great cause of discontent among farmers. On this point the Committee of 1872-3 speak as follows : — " In parts of Scotland it is a common practice for a landlord (who, in addition to the reservation of game by law, reserves rabbits by agreement) to let to a stranger the right of shooting over cultivated farms when they are adjacent to his moors. The shooting tenant, between whom and the agricultural tenant there is no common bond of interest, having generally to pay a considerable rent, not unfrequently keeps up an excessive head of game, and the farmer whose crops are in- jured by their depredations has no redress except by the distasteful process of suing his landlord, and leaving him in turn to recover from the shooting tenant. The same ground of complaint exists in England where the shooting is let to a third party, and in such case the grievance is aggravated by the fact that the tenant has no legal claim against his landlord except under special agreement." The Committee appear to have been anxious to throw the onus of the charge upon the Scotch owners, but in fact the evil is by no means confined to Scotland, it is equally prevalent in some parts of England. 46 It is not as it used to be in olden time, when country gentlemen were more at home and had less facilities for travel. Then the squire was content if he could go out with a friend and shoot a mode- rate head of game over his tenant's land, and take the opportunity of talking with his tenants and looking at their crops. In these days shooting has become a more serious affair. The fashion of battues has given a taste for blood, and in many parts of the country sportsmen are not satisfied unless game by the hecatomb fall to their guns ; and it has resulted that not only pheasants, part- ridges and" grouse are strictly preserved with a view to secure these great bags, but in order to fill up the day's sport hares and rabbits must be equally prolific. But for hares and rabbits the balance of evidence is to the effect that but little complaint would be made by farmers. Partridges, it is admitted, do little or no harm ; they probably do more than an equivalent good in destroying insects. Pheasants can only do harm during the very short interval when the harvest is ripe ; at other times if they are to be preserved in any number they must be well and frequently fed in the covers. Grouse only come down to the culti- vated grounds for purposes of mischief during a late harvest. The true enemies to the farmer are the hares and rabbits. The rapid multiplication of rabbits is well known, and has been from the earliest times the subject of complaint by farmers. Pliny tells us that the inhabitants of Minorca peti- tioned the Emperor to send them troops to aid in 47 ridding their island of the rabbits, who destroyed their trees and undermined their houses ; and even in these days on some soils the pest of rabbits can only be kept, down by constant exertions and by using every implement of destruction against them. Not only is the amount of food they eat very considerable, but they destroy a great deal more. Where a farm is overstocked with hares and rabbits, no excellence of farming will avail. That farmers themselves are not averse alto- gether to game is abundantly clear not only from the evidence but to every one who has any know- ledge of the class. In the rare cases where, holding under corporations or under non-preserving land- lords, they have the right to shoot over their own farms, they generally become game preservers ; but with this difference, as is alleged, that while maintaining sufhcient for sport, they do not allow their farms to be overrun with game. There is also every diiFerence between the feeling that your own game is eating your own crops and the feeling that the crops which you raise fall the prey to the game of others^ suggestive of the old line ; ** Sic vos non vobis vellera fertis oves." As a further illustration of this, it is stated that where the farmer has a right to the game no man looks better after the poachers ; in fact, no poacher dare venture upon such farm. Poaching is mostly done by the people in the immediate neighbourhood of the farm. The farmer very soon finds out who the poachers are, and can guard against them, and 48 he can make it the interest of his own Labourers to protect the farm against trespassers. It is also admitted that where the game is reserved under the farmer's lease, whatever covenant there may be as to preserving the game and warning off poachers, the farmers, as a rule, trouble themselves very little about it. No one ever hears of a farmer prosecuting a poacher for killing the game of the landlord, he leaves all this to the gamekeeper. In many parts of the country the farmers look upon the poachers as their friends, as the natural corrective to an overtendency to accumulate game. The fact is, that in the artificial condition of things, where the occupation of land is severed from the right of sporting, the interest of the person best able to watch and preserve the game is lost ; the duty falls to the gamekeeper, while the increase of game, the result of his exer- tions, ends in increasing the number of poachers. The more keepers, the more game; the more game, the more poachers, and the less interest taken by occupiers in resisting their attacks. Such is the vicious circle which results from high preservation of game, under the condition of its complete severance from the land on which it is bred, and on whose produce it is fed. Looking at the effect of the Game Laws from the more public point of view, it can scarcely be denied that there is some truth in the complaint that they lead many people into a course of crime who would not otherwise be tempted. The same feeling which is the essence of sport with gen- 49 tlemen, which sanctions the kilhng of gfime when it does not sanction the killing of domesticated creatures, except wdth some eccentric tastes m the case of pigeons, is also at the root of that which makes the labouring classes, as a rule, look upon game as a fair subject of capture. The taking of game is not, in the public opinion of those classes, a serious offence. The better class of w^ork- men will generally refuse to work with a man who has been convicted of theft. They do not consider conviction for poaching in the same light. Poach- ing, therefore, presents many attractions to the active young men in the country districts. It is restrained, not by any public opinion, but only by the fear of detection and punishment. It leads many men, therefore, into a course of action which ends in worse company, and in the gaol ; and once in gaol, they speedily become contami- nated by contact with men of criminal habits. The number of commitments to gaol, however, is not so large as is often represented. The Statistics laid before the Committee show that in England and Wales on the average of three or four years — 7000 persons are annually fined for simple day trespass in pursuit of game. 1500 are imprisoned for short periods of under three months duration. 70 are imprisoned for uj^wards of six months. 10 are sentenced to penal servitude. In Ireland the convictions under the Game Laws average under 500 a year. The convictions in England and Wales appear to E 50 be very steady in iiiiinber, and the Poaching Pre- vention Act of 18G2^ whatever its other effect^ has not reduced the number of these convictions. Another serious result of the game laws, or rather, it should be said, of excessive preservation of game, is the very large number of persons who, during many months of the year, successfully prac- tice poaching as a means of livelihood. In the County of Herts alone, there are stated by the Chief Constable to be not fewer than 300 men who for several months of the year, maintain themselves in a great measure by the illegal taking of game. If this be a fair specimen of other parts of the country, the number of professional poachers must be considerable. • If hares and rabbits were kept down, by far the greater proportion of the present cases of poaching would not take place. If other game were only preserved in moderation, it would certainly not be worth while for men to make a living out of poaching ; while if the sympathies of farmers were enlisted on behalf of the game on their farms, we should hear little of the poaching which is due to the neighbouring labourers, and which could not be carried on if the farmers were really in earnest to prevent it. Many of the ulterior effects of game preserving in its exaggerated form are also very mischievous ; it leads to cases of local tyranny, such as forcing men out of the country w^ho are known or suspected to be poachers. There is also some ground for complaint of the administration of the law by the 51 unpaid magistrates, who are so often themselves pre- servers, and who at times impart into judgments on the subject of game a degree of acrimony and prejudice which results in injustice. A further ulterior effect of exaggerated game preserving is the impetus it gives to the aggrega- tion of properties and to the squeezing out of small freeholders. There is nothing so hateful to the game preserver as the small freehold, where the game may be taken in transitu. It is therefore a great object with such men to buy up such small freeholds even at extravagant rates wherever it be possible, and this action accounts to some extent for the diminution of the number of small freeholds. Another indirect evil of the present state of game preserving is that so many men of the upper classes are brought up in the belief that sporting is the great end and object of civilized life. Hundreds of young men of the present generation have been ruined by this folly. This country is not large enough for them ; they ransack the world for fresh fields for their gentle prowess; they roam over the world to the centre of Africa or the hills of India in search only of game ; and all this enterprize and activity is thrown away upon the most useless sport without leaving a trace of any benefit to the actor or the world. It may be doubted whether the sportsmen of England have contributed a single fact of any importance to science or to natural history. The same fashion has also created a false ideal of life. It is considered by many engaged in industrial pursuits that one of E 2 52 the highest objects of ambition which can be aimed at in life, is to become a game preserving landowner on a great scale. The conclusion which is justified on review of all that has been written and said about the Game Laws, and especially from the evidence taken before the Select Committee, is that the grievance of the Game Laws is first and mainly a farmer's grievance. In Ireland, where the practice of strict j)reserva- tion has never been followed, probably on account of the very small extent of the farms and the number o^ persons always on the land, there is no game question. Game is by no means extinct, but no com- plaints are made either by farmers or by the public. In England, however, it is very different, and there is strong ground for the Legislative inter- ference. Excessive preservation has become a great impediment to good farming, and therefore to the production of food, while it has greatly in- creased the inducements to poaching, aud the putting in force of laws, some of which are still very severe, and too often administered with harsh- ness or carelessness. To point out an evil, and to devise a remedy, are two very distinct tasks, and to many the difficulties of interfering with the existing Game Laws have appeared so great, that it has seemed to them pre- ferable to leave the question to the force of public 53 opinion, acting slowly upon the customs and habits of landowners and game preservers, rather than attempt legislation which might, in its result, dis- appoint those who are most interested. The question, however, has passed beyond this stage, and as the Select Committee has proposed many and important, though it is believed inexpedient changes, and as other schemes of legislation have been proposed, and will doubtless be again proposed in substitution for that of the Committee, it is necessary to submit them to a careful scrutiny. The proposals to deal with the Game Laws may be ranged under three heads : — 1. — The repeal in whole or in part of the Game Laws. 2.^The giving to game the status and sanction of other property. 3. — The amendment of the Game Laws so far as they affect the relations of landlord and tenant. 1. — Proposal to repeal the Game Laws, It is uncertain how far those who advocate the total repeal of the Game Laws wish to see the entire extinction of game, and whether they include in their objects the repeal of those provisions which protect game time during the breeding season. It may be presumed, however, that they contem- plate at least the repeal of those provisions which make it penal for any person to trespass on the land of others in pursuit of game, whether by day 54 or night, and whether with or without guns, nets, or other implements of destruction. It is not difficult to foretell what would be the effect of such a measure. The experience of France and Germany has already been adverted to. It can scarcely be doubted that the same results would follow in this country. Multitudes of people from both urban and rural districts would avail them- selves of the license, and would wander freely over the cultivated districts, woods and moors, in all directions, with guns and other implements of de- struction. If, within a reasonable time, all species of game could be totally extinguished, this free spirit of trespass might come to an end, and the or- dinary trespass laws might suffice in the future ; but, in fact, game is not likely to be wholly extinguished, however great the number of persons in pursuit of it. There are parts of the country where it is impossible to exterminate rabbits ; there are some species of game birds, such as snipe, w^oodcock, and wild duck, which are only birds of passage, and which, bred in remote countries, only visit our shores for a brief season. It is also not pro- bable that partridges would soon become extinct, however great the exertions made to destroy them. It would ther^^fore result that some of the induce- ments to sport would remain; and we must look forward to an indefinite prolongation of the dis- orders which would result from unrestrained tres- pass in pursuit of game. Some would pursue game only for the sport, others for gain; and we might expect to see gangs of unauthorized persons beating 55 covers or netting fields in such numbers, as to amount to a nuisance, not only to farmers, but also to the rest of society. There would also still remain the ordinary law of trespass. The law, though it doe^ not visit upon an ordinary trespasser who does no damage to property, any penal consequences, gives full power to the owner or occupier of the land to drive trespassers off the land by the exercise of such force as may be necessary for the j)urpose. He might therefore still by manual force eject the poacher from his ground, and it might be possible in many of the more thinly-peopled districts, by increasing the number of watchers and by arming them with guns and life-preservers, to keep strangers off the land, or to make it dangerous for them to attempt a naid. It is^ however, certain that such action would lead to constant and dan- gerous conflicts, and the remedy might -therefore soon prove worse than the disease. It would still be possible for landlords to require covenants in their leases, forbidding their tenants to kill game or rabbits, and requiring them to drive off tres- passers. The tenants might therefore find them- selves in the condition that, while debarred them- selves from killing game on their farms, they could not prevent any number of disorderly persons from coming on their land in pursuit of it. To legalize the universal destruction of game it would be necessary to do more than simply repeal the existing game laws ; it would be neces- sary to provide expressly that all the world might 56 trespass anywhere and everywhere in pursuit of game, so long as they should not do damage to other property, and it would be further necessary to make illegal, by express enactment, any contract between landlord and tenant respecting game. The Game LaAvs, as now constituted, not only pro- tect game, but act as a very moderate trespass law. It is a general presumption, that persons tres- passing in woods or at night with nets and guns are in search of game; and magistrates, not without reason, refuse to believe that they are in search only of sparrows, crows, or any other non- valuable species, but under the new regime, persons would have free license to trespass in pursuit of any kind of bird or animal not included in the term property* It is, doubtless, in view of these probable results of an unconditional repeal of the Game Laws, that almost all those who advocate it, are also prepared, when questioned on the point, to admit the necessity of adopting a more stringent general trespass law, as a sequel to the repeal of the special game laws. Mr. Arch, whose opinion, upon all subjects affecting the interests of the agricultural labourers, is worthy of the utmost respect, after stating his conviction that the game laws should be abolished, added, that he was quite prepared to enact a more stringent general trespass law. His answers on this point to the late Mr. Win- terbotham, in the Committee of 1872, were as follows : — 57 " 8225. Supposing the game laws were abolished to-morrow, and supposing that I am right in saying that they cannot punish you for merely walking across the land, do you think that it would be good to pass a law that an occupier should be able to punish you and send you to prison for going across his land if you did no harm to it ? — I do not see what right people have to go trespassing across other people's grounds, or why there should be that looseness in the law of the country to allow a man to walk about just where he pleases without restriction. " 8183. Do you think it is necessary if you did away with the Game Laws that the owner should be able to punish you if you go across his land ? — He should be able to punish me if caught trespassing on his land ; I think that is right ; I have no right to go upon any man's land, unless I have his consent, and should not presume to do it. " Do you think there is no disposition on the part of labour- ing men to go upon land unless they have business there ? — No there is not. I believe that hares and rabbits tempt men to go on to land by seeing them on it, who, if they had not seen them, would not have gone there." Evidence to the same effect was given^by many other determmecl opponents to the Game Laws. It has not, however, occurred to these witnesses that a more stringent general trespass law would in fact be a game law under another name. With a stringent trespass law, game, as well as any other product of the soil would be protected ; but there would be this addition, that whereas at present trespassers doing no damage cannot be punished, under a stringent trespass law, innocent persons, merely walking over open fields and meadows, or wandering off a footpath, without doing damage to any property, would be equally liable to prosecution. It is not conceivable that such 58 a law would be maintained ; if passed, it might be the engine of greater oppression than the game laws themselves, and would be a dangerous power to put into the hands of an unpaid magistracy. The Law of England most Avisely holds that a person trespassing over land without doing an}^ damage to property, is not liable to any penal action. To alter this law and to subject sim- ple and innocent trespassers to fine and imprison- ment might be very agreeable to some landowners and even farmers, and would give great facilities to game preservers, but it would lead to much local tyranny, it would be oppressive to the general public, and it is not too much to say that it would not long be endured. It should never be forgotten that the essential feature of the present game law is that it is a tres23ass law directed against those trespassing on land in pursuit of game ; as the greater contains the less, a general trespass law would include the main portions of the present game law, and would also include a hundred other cases which are not now subject to criminal process. On the one hand, therefore, the repeal of the Game Laws if coupled with a more stringent tres- pass law would lead to intolerable strictness. On the other hand, if without a tresj)ass law, it would lead equally to intolerable license. The same objections apply with more or less force to the proposals of the Committee of 1872-3 : " 1. That the Day Trespass clauses should be repealed, and in lieu thereof a power should be given to an owner or occupier 59 to apply for an interdict against any person trespassnig on the land, which when once obtained could be enforced at any sub- sequent period against such person by penal process in the nature of contempt of court. " 2. That rabbits should be excluded from the game laws." The Committee do not propose to repeal the Night Poaching Act or the Poaching Prevention Act ; the concession, therefore, in the first proposal, as regards day trespassing, is illusory. The change in the form of proceeding would not really disguise the real nature of the process, while it would create a new remedy against ordinary trespassers for which there is no demand . It has not been shown that there is any ground for taking more severe measures against ordinary .trespassers. It may be further asked by whom this interdict is to be applied. Are landowners to be permitted to use this new weapon against all trespassers on the lands in the occupa- tion of their tenants ? Are they in future to* decide who shall come upon their tenants' farms ? Another serious objection which has been urged against this proposal is, that as the interdict could only be obtained after a first trespass, it would be possible for organised bands to sweep the game off particular districts, avoiding a repetition on the same land. The proposal to exclude rabbits from all men- tion in the Game Laws will probably be equally illusory. It is not proposed that they should cease to be the subject of contract between landlord and tenant. It would still be open to a landlord to forbid the destruction of rabbits by the farmer and his men ; and when men shoidd thereafter be found 60 trespassing on land with nets and guns, it is not probable that magistrates will consider that their object was only rabbits and not other game. It is probable, therefore, that the Game Laws would continue to give protection to rabbits as well as to other game. 2. — Proposal to make Game jproperty. It is thought by some that to make game pro- perty, would give it a greater sanction in the public estimation, and lessen the inducement to take it unlawfully. The question, however, at once arises, whose property is it to be ? Is it to be considered the property of the person on whose land it is bred, or on whose land it is found ? is it to be the property of the owner of the land, or of the occupier ? Game is now, in some sense, the property of the person on whose ground it is found, but it is not vested with all the sanction of other property. To call it property while it changes ownership in going from one person's land to another, and to give it the same sanction as other property, would involve changing the game trespass law into a game larceny law; in other words it would greatly strengthen the penalties for taking game. If, on the other hand, game is to be the property of the person on whose land it is bred, we are met at once by all the difficulties of identification. Pheasants that are reared by hand, and afterwards turned out into a wood for «port, closely approxi- 61 mate to the condition of domestic [>igeons, and might possibly be so treated. They would then continue the property of the person who bred them, although wandering on to the land of a neighbour ; but if the neighbour were himself a breeder and preserver of pheasants, there would at once arise the difficulty of identification. It would generally be impossible to distinguish the pheasants of the one from those of the other, and disputes of a serious difficulty would occur. If difficult, however, as regards pheasants, how much more so with other descriptions of game, such as partridges, hares, and rabbits. The idea of treating these creatures, as pigeons are now treated, may be at once discarded as impossible. In a speech delivered at an agricultural dinner, in the course of the past winter, Mr. Walter, M.P., is reported to have said — " A good deal was said in the Keport of the Committee about the impossibility iu the nature of things of attaching any proprietary rights to game. In his opinion, the whole mischief had arisen from the old feudal theory that ferce natures were incapable of being made the subject of property. He could never see the justice of this theory. Could any quality whatever that pertained to an animal constitute so good a proprietary right as the feeding of it ? If you saw a number of hares eating your turnips, and running off with your turnips in their bellies, they were running off with your property, and the man who took them, took your property. He contended that game was the property of the person upon whose land it was for the time being. It might belong to this landlord to-day and to another landlord to-morrow, but quite clearly could not belong to a person who had no property in land and with nothing to feed it." 62 The premises are sound, hut they appear to justify a very different concUision, namely, that hares and rabbits should be the property of the person who feeds them, that is, of the farmer whose crops they eat, and not of the landowner. The argument used would also justify the giving permission to the farmer to follow the hares and rabbits which are gorged with his turnips into the neighbouring wood from which they issued forth to feed, and there to kill and appropriate them. If, however, it is really intended by the speaker that game is to be the property of the landowner on whose land it happens to be, the only effect of such a proposal would be to increase the penalties of the game laws, and to make game the subject of larceny, notwithstanding that it cannot be identi- fied. 3. — Proposal to amend the Law of Game as between Landlord and Tenant. It has already been shown that the main objec- tion to the Game Laws from the public point of view is not so much due to their existence as to their abuse — to the multiplication of game to such an extent that good farming is hindered, and the inducements to poaching greatly increased. It has also been shown that the practice of exces- sive preservation has greatly increased, and is mainly due to the complete separation which exists in this country between the right of sporting and the occupation of land ; that this separation is the cause of wrong to the farming tenant, in that the 63 produce of his labour is consumed by the game wliich is for the benefit of another. It can scarcely be doubted that if the farmers, as a rule, had control over the game, there would be no complaint of over preserving, they would preserve only so far as was consistent with their farming interests, and they would also protect the game against unauthorized trespassers in a far more effectual manner than any keeper could do ; and the preservation of game being less, there would be less inducements to poach. The question therefore arises, whether, by any legal process, the game may be annexed more closely to the land, and whether it is just or expe- dient to take this course ? The law, undoubtedly, now recognizes a separate estate and interest in the game apart from the ownership and occupation of land. It has been shown that this is itself an inheritance of the feudal laws. It is enforced by the penalties which the Act of 1831 imposes on the tenant who, in breach of his agreement under which the game is reserved by the landlord, takes game when feeding on his crops. It is recognized in the validity of all con- tracts reserving the right of sporting, and it is further confirmed by the power which the law gives to the owner of the land, or his assignee, who has parted with the possession of the land, to prosecute a poacher for trespassing on the land in pursuit of game. Although, therefore, the owner has parted with the possession of the land, the law enables him to G4 retain dominion over it so far as tlie game is con- cerned ; and it fully, therefore, recognizes a sepa- rate estate in the game and the land, in the farming produce and the game produce. It would be possible in many ways to legislate so as to prevent this separation, or at all events to give no legal sanction to it. It would not be inconsistent with legal principles to forbid the separation of the game from the ownership or occupation of ground, on the ground of public policy, or on the principle that the sepa- ration of these two interests results in bad culti- vation, in over preservation of game, and in the consequent increase of oiFences. To effect this object in the most complete manner, it would be necessary to enact that the sale of land and the letting of a farm should always carry with it the game, that no interest in the game separate from the land should be acknow- ledged by the law, or be the subject of any con- tract. It might be further necessary to enact that any prosecution under the Game laws should issue at the instance only of the occupier of the land; and it would further follow that the penalty by which the Act of 1831 enforces the reservation of sporting should be repealed. It would be said, of course, that such enactments would be opposed to the freedom of contract; but Mr. Read, M.P. (4233), when arguing in favour of applying this jDrinciple to hares and rabbits only, pointed out with great force that the law inter- feres ali'eady in a multitude of cases with the 65 freedom of contract, between parent and child, master and servant, solicitor and client, debtor and collector, guardian and ward, agent and principal, buyer and seller^ carrier and consigner, doctor and patient, innkeeper and tippler, pawnbroker and pledger, patron and presentee, captain and seamen, sailors and ships, mortgagor and mortgagee, and, in the case of Ireland, between landlord and tenant. No general dictum, therefore, of inter- ference with contracts can be opposed to such a measure. It must be dealt with on general prin- ciples of expediency, and though we may be unwilling to interfere with contracts, where other remedies are applicable, yet where, in the public interest, an end has to be aimed at, contracts between individuals are not so sacred or inviolable as that no action in constraint of them can be entertained. In the present case it would be for the law to say that no such right or property can exist separate from the land itself as the right of sporting, and that therefore no contract for its enforcement can be good or valid. To admit the contract is to create the property or right independent of the soil ; and if it be desired to prevent the separation of the right of sporting from the right of farming, the only mode of securing this is to prevent the en- forcement by law of any contract having this object. It would not follow that the landlords would lose all sport over their lands. It is probable that the tenants would in many cases continue to agree with their landlords to reserve for the latter the right of CG sporting, or to allow them to shoot over their farms ; but these agreements would not be binding at law, and the tenants would have this security, that they would retain dominion over their farms, and control over the game on them ; and could at any time interfere to prevent an excessive quantity of game. It may be that in many cases landlords would succeed in controlling their tenants, by declining to continue the tenancies if the game were inter- fered with or reduced; but the law prescribed by the State would rule at least on those numerous estates in the hands of trustees, in the Court of Chancery, in the ownership of Corporations, or where owners are under disabilities, and from these there would gradually gi'ow up a different relation between landlord and tenant on the subject of game which would powerfully and speedily affect the whole country. It may also be presumed that if, notwithstanding the change proposed, it was still found that the habit of excessive preserving was maintained to the damage of good farming, it would become hereafter necessary to adopt wider and more stringent measures. A change of this nature, although, it must be admitted^ af a radical character, would be in har- mony with the historic changes which have been made in times past, as illustrated first by the decay and destruction of the King's prerogative of sport over the lands of his subjects ; secondly, by the emancipation of the freehold and copyhold tenants from the same pretensions of lords of manors ; and lastly, by the abolition of privilege and qualifica- 67 tion. These changes have been all m the dh'ection of preventing the separation of game from the ownership of land. It is but a step further in the same direction to prevent the se]3aration of game from the occupation of land. It would appear then that the ultimate end which should be aimed at in any modification of the Game laws is the annexation of game to the land, the preventing of any severance at law be- tween the occupation of land and the right of ^porting. There are, however, degrees of legis- lation short of this, though in the same direction, which are worthy of consideration; and as in this country compromises are often come to between rival principles, it is not improbable that some half measure may be found more acceptable to all parties than the more complete and logical one sub- « mitted above. The tenant farmers of England and Scotland have not generally put forward a claim to all the game on the farms they occupy, but to the hares and rabbits only ; and they appear to be content that their landlords should have the power to sever the right of sporting in respect of winged game from the occupation of land. They ask that they may be invested with an inalienable right, concurrently with their landlords, to take and de- stroy hares and rabbits on their farms. It is from these animals that damage accrues to their crops ; and their special grievance is confined to them. On farms of moderate size the partridge shooting would not be of much value from their narrow limits ; and the sport could scarcely be enjoyed except over F 2 G8 an extent of land which embraces many farms of moderate size. Pheasants are not commonly reared except in woods and plantations, which are usually in the hands of the landlords ; without the plan- tations the farmers would not be able to breed or retain pheasants, while the landlords on the other hand could not secure their pheasants from wan- dering out of the woods on to the fields of the tenants. The tenant farmers, therefore, do not lay much stress upon the winged game, they rest their case mainly upon the grievance of hares and rabbits. It would then be quite consistent with the principles already indicated, and would be a long step towards the full realization of them if legislation as between landlords and tenants were confined in the first instance to hares and rabbits. Instead, however, of making illegal any contract between landlord and tenant respecting rabbits and hares, the better course would be to define strictly what species of game could be reserved by the landlord and severed from the occupation of land, and to pro- vide that while the right of killing hares and rabbits may be reserved, such right shall only be in exclusion of other persons, but not of the occupying tenant or his servants. The effect of such a provision would be to give to the landlord, where the right of sporting is reserved, the exclu- sive right to winged game and the concurrent right with the tenants to hares and rabbits, and the latter would retain the right to kill and destroy these animals, notwithstanding any contract. 69 Such a remedy, if adopted, would have this fur* ther advantage, that it would bring the law into harmony with the existing practice on the best managed estates. There are many Landlords who do now concede to their Tenants the right of killing hares and rabbits, reserving only the exclusive right of winged game, and this practice is decidedly on the increase among these Landlords, who have the interest of their estates and of their tenants really at heart. There is no safer guide for legis- lation than the growing practice, which a higher morality, or better experience is inculcating among those for whom it is intended to legislate. But, as in the case of the Irish Land Act, those who most honestly and rigidly follow the practice which they feel to be imposed on them by the dictates of morality or expediency, often most strongly object to its being enforced by law, and imposed upon those who have not followed the practice or recog- nized the moral obligation. The concurrent right of Landlord and Tenant would have this further advantage, that the land- lord could prevent the undue multiplication of rabbits and hares upon the holding of any of his tenants, which might result either from the negli- gence or love of sport of such tenant, or which might, in its turn, become a nuisance to neighbour- ing tenants or an obstruction to good farming. The Committee of 1873-4 deal with this ques- tion as follows : — " They consider that no landlord should object to the in- eci'iion of such engagements in his leases or agreements as will 70 ensure the keeping down of ground game within moderate limits, and that no tenant should enter upon a farm without securing protection from loss by such engagements on the part of the landlord, and they are satisfied that no means so efficient for the purpose can be devised as the concession to the tenant of the power to kill the ground game upon his farm either exclusively or concurrently with his landlord. " The opinion has been strongly pressed upon us by some witnesses that a concurrent inalienable right to kill hares and rabbits should be given to the tenant by law. They are con- vinced, however, that means would be found of evading such a law by some understanding between the parties ; and in corro- boration of the inadequacy of such a remedy, they would call attention to the evidence of Mr. Matthews, who stated to us that he quitted his farm owing to the damage done to his crops by rabbits and hares, notwithstanding that he had the privilege of killing the former, and that for years he did not exercise that privilege because he thought that his landlord would not approve it." The weakness or submissiveness of one tenant farmer is hardly sufficient ground on which to gene- ralize for the whole class ; nor have the Committee stated the reasons which induced them to think that the law would be evaded. Even if the majority of farmers were as submissive as Mr. Matthews, it is impossible not to believe that many would avail themselves of the new law, and, having experienced benefit, it would soon become the general custom of farmers to follow the law rather than evade its benefit by secret contract or through fear of their landlords. Having the power at law to destroy hares and rabbits, it would at least be no longer open to them to complain if they should not avail themselves of it. The arguments produced by the Committee could 71 be used with far greater effect against their own proposals, and are therefore no reason for preferring a remedy which is admittedly less perfect. A considerable minority of the Committee were not satisfied with these arguments, and suggested the following amendment : — " I^early all the English tenant farmer witnesses, and many of those from Scotland, are agreed in recommending that such a right (an inalienable right to kill hares and rabbits) should be given by law to the tenant. The difficulties of enforcing such a statutory provision are no doubt considerable, but by no means insuperable. Against it is the natural repugnance to interfere with freedom of contract between landlord and tenant, and the opportunity which may exist for evasion of the provisions by collusion between the parties interested. On the other hand, your Committee have already recognized the advantages of such an arrangement, when voluntarily entered into, and have recommended it as the best means of amicably settling the question; and in the belief that this remedy for the existing grievances meets the wishes of the class most seriously affected and most directly interested in the operation of the Game Laws, and recognizing the fact that the Legislature has already interfered by law with freedom of contracts in many other relations of life, they are of opinion that it should be enacted that no contract by lease or other- wise, by which a tenant purports to forego the privilege of killing or taking hares and rabbits on lands in his own occupa- tion, shall be valid or enforceable by law." Had these members of the Committee approached the question from a slightly different point of view they would not perhaps have felt the difficulty of what is called interference with freedom of contract. The question is what should be the subject of contract apart from the land ? Should the law recognize an interest in hares and rabbits apart from the land, 72 or should these creatures be considered as essentially a product of the land which should pass with the land under any deed or agreement, whether of sale or hiring? Supposing a custom were to grow up under which in contracts for the letting of farms covenants were inserted that no hoeing should take place, could it be contended that such contracts should not be forbidden in the interest of the gene-, ral public. It may as a general rule be unwise to interfere with the freedom of contract, but there are already many exceptions to the rule, and where the public interest is directly in the opposite direc- tion, or where an ancient custom of a hurtful cha- racter has prevailed, it may be very expedient and proper to put an end to it by interfering with the right of contract. In every case it must be a question of broad and general expediency. If this partial remedy should be adopted, the main provisions of the existing Game Law would still remain. The law would still prohibit trespass on land in pursuit of game against the will of the owner or occupier. The day trespass law would remain unaltered. The Night Trespass Act would need a careful revision ; the penalties attached to it are too severe. It is reasonable enough that men who go about in armed bands at night should be punished with more severity than simple unarmed trespassers in the day time ; but the punishments of the Act are too severe, and should not be administered by justices. The Poaching Prevention Act of 1860 should also be repealed. The Act is founded on a wrong 73 principle. It enables the Police to act on suspicion, and authorizes the magistrates to condemn on sus- picion only. It introduces a principle novel to the law, in throwing the onus of proof of innocence on the accused. If the principle be worthy of trial, game offences are not those which should be se- lected for the experiment. Further, there is the great objection that it turns the County police into gamekeepers. It is most important that the prin- ciple should be maintained that it is no part of the duty of the State to preserve game for landowners. It does not at all follow that all landowners object to their game being taken, or would desire to pro- secute trespassers. The offence should in no way be treated as one of public interest. It is true the Act as construed and applied in England has effected its purpose. It has to some extent put down the larger gangs of poachers. It has resulted that game preserving is carried on to a far greater extent than before. The true re- medy for the wholesale poaching was reduced pre- servation, or better watching ; with better watching the offenders could be identified and followed; with less preservation there would be no employ- ment for such gangs. The new " Charta de Foresta" would then em- brace the following changes in the existing law. 1. The severance of the right of sporting from the occupation of land should be confined to winged game ; and contracts for the reserva- tion of hares and rabbits should be declared illegal as between landlord and tenant. 74 2. The penalties under the Night Poaching Act should be reduced. 3. The Poaching Prevention Act of 18G1 should be repealed. 4. The Police should be prohibited from acting in any way as game preservers. 5. The law with reference to damage caused by undue multiplication of game, and especially of rabbits, to the crops of adjoining owners or occupiers, should be carefully reviewed and placed on a more satisfactory footing. 6. The right of sporting should be made incap- able of permanent severance from the owner- ship of land. 7. Power should be given to landowners to re- deem the right of sporting over their lands where now permanently severed from them, upon payment of an amount to be decided by a jury. In what has been hitherto said care has been taken to avoid any expression of opinion as to the merit of the institution known as sport. It is sufficient for the purpose to acknowledge that game now exists in large quantities, that numerous persons are interested in its preservation and derive great pleasure in searching for it themselves or by their beaters, and in destroying it. It is also a not unimportant article of food; though hares and rabbits, if excessive in number displace a greater value of animal food of better quality, and phea- 75 sants as a rule cost more to rear than they sell for when dead. It is scarcely possible to justify the maintenance of the Game Laws on the ground put forward by Lord Airlie before the Committee that sport is necessary to the preservation of health of our leading politicians, who require the relaxation and bracing air of the moors, after the hard work of a session, a theory which is not quite con- sistent with the fact that out of nine members of the late Cabinet in the House of Commons, only one was a sportsman. Equally impossible is it to accept the theory of others that the game laws should be maintained on the ground that game is the only inducement to country gentlemen to live in the country. Considerable numbers of gentle- men do now contrive to pass their time and to enjoy themselves in the country without sport, and all ladies are not less fond of country life^. It may, however, be admitted that sport, as it used to be indulged in, or such as it is now for the most part on the moors, consisting in the search for game aided perhaps by dogs, and which is only obtained by considerable exertion and the exercise of some skill and knowledge of the country, that such sport has exerted no bad influence, but has given a taste for active life, which may have reacted to advantage upon the habits and life of many families. But when for sport of this kind is substituted the modern battue, with its army of beaters, its massacre of hares, or its bouquet of pheasants, and where the sportsmen line the wood and have all the labour done for them, it is difficult to avoid the 76 conclusion that true sport has vanished, and that the pastime has become little better than that described by an eminent novelist and statesman as the tour- nament of doves. The element of sport has passed away. There is no longer the uncertainty of the chase, or the exercise of skill in finding the game. It has degenerated into a system where the sports- man can prescribe the number of head of game he wishes to be driven into the shambles, and where the only skill is in killing in rapid succession at what is called a hot corner. On behalf of such sport the public is little in- terested in giving any great facilities for preserva- tion. On the contrary, there are strong reasons for not giving protection to property which is allowed to be so exposed in such profusion. If householders were to expose their purses on their door steps, they would not be surprised if their property should speedily disappear ; nor would the State be interested in placing a police- man before every door specially to guard such property so rashly exposed. Similarly, game preservers who stock their woods and fields with thousands of head of game, have no great claim for protection on the part of the State. They offer too great a temptation to wrong-doers. They have no right to call upon the State to fill its gaols with people who give way to such temptations, or to treat their hares and rab- bits as it treats sheep or oxen. The onus of pro- tection must rest with themselves. That the craze for sport of this kind will con- 77 tinue we cannot believe. It is contrary to the better instincts of English gentlemen and true sportsmen. The fashion came to us from the Con- tinent, and is known under foreign names. Let us hope that the fall of the Empire in France may tend to bring this, and many other fashions of the same level into disrepute. It has often been said that Shakespeare has, in the course of his great dramas, left nothing unno- ticed of the varying phases of life, and of the customs of his days ; not the least happy among his descriptions is that where he expresses his manly contempt for the battue shooting of his period, which was directed against deer. In "Love's Labour Lost," the Princess of France goes out for a day's sport, and says to the Forester — " Shew me the bush Where I may stand and play the murderer. The Forester. — Here by upon the edge of yonder coppice, A stand where you may make the fairest shoot. The Frincess. — Come for the bow, now mercy goes to kill, And shooting well is here accounted ill ; Thus will I show my credit in the shoot, Not wounding, pity would not let me do it. If wounding, then it was to show my skill, That more for praise than purpose meant to kill ; And out of question so it is sometimes, Glory grows guilty of detested crimes. When for fame's sake, for praise, an outward part, W^e bend to that the working of the heart. So I, for praise alone, now seek to spill The poor deer's blood, that ne'er my heart meant ill.'* 78 The irony of these lines was not improbably directed against Queen Elizabeth, who was much addicted to killing deer which were driven past a stage, specially erected for her and her retinue. Her butcheries on these occasions must often have shocked public opinion, as they did still more the sensitive mind of Shakespeare, himself a sports- man of a truer type, who has shown in his touching and beautiful description of the hunted hare in Venus and Adonis how keenly he could feel for brute nature. The rebuke he thus administered to the ignoble sport of the day would apply equally in the present day to those who indulge either in tournaments of doves or in battues of pheasants or hares. Whatever theoretical views, however, may be entertained by the few as to sport, it is certain that the great majority of Englishmen have no wish to see the extermination of game. The Act passed in 1872, with general assent, for the protection of wild birds during the breeding season, is proof of this. They have equally little objection to, if not a love of true sport. They will not however treat with much consideration that right of sporting which is carried to excess at the expense of suffer- ing tenants, to the discouragement of good farm- ing, and resulting in diminished produce of the soil. The public it is equally certain will not readily give up any freedom which they now prac- tically enjoy, of wandering freely over land where they do no damage, or agree to substitute a severe general trespass law, for a game law which is di- 79 rected against trespassers who are in pursuit only of game. It is therefore in the relation of landlord and tenant that we must look for a remedy of ad- mitted evils. The ground for such change will not be any theoretical objection to game laws in the abstract, but the more solid one that as now constituted they do grave injustice to a great body of tenant farmers, not only in causing destruction to their crops, but in making it impossible for them to put forth those exertions to increase the produce of the soil, from which we may hope for increased results to labour in this country, and for the consequent improvement of the condition of the labouring class. THE END. ■^r^i^^W 'v^'"" .1 k. ]^^,J$, '/ 'r-*r!^ ^if'^ ^S*fc ^ [A-^ ^s^-^t AJ4.J