THE RELATION OF THE PUBLIC LANDS TO THE LABOR PROBLEM DURING THE PERIOD FROM 1830 TO 1860 By WILLIAM ALBERT McCONAGHA B. S. Muskingum College 1917 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS IN THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS, 1922 \ URBANA, ILLINOIS N\V5 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS THE GRADUATE SCHOOL -192 I HEREBY RECOMMEND THAT THE THESIS PREPARED UNDER MY SUPERVISION BY l/Jsl ^ f ENTITLED. / no ) ■i _ * rx ; , . ' . ' ■ ' • , ' • > -i >‘i : . -• -2 other hand, such a coalition means, "Raise our wages or we go to the West. "(3) Secretary Walker in his treasury report for 1845 declared that "The reduction of the price of public lands in favor of the settlers and cul- tivators would enhance the wages of labor. If those who lived by the v/ages of labor could purchase 320 acres for $80, 160 for $40, 80 for $20, or 40 for $10, the power of manufacturing capitalists to reduce the wages of labor would be greatly diminished, because when the lands are thus reduced in price those who live by the v/ages of labor could purchase farms at those low rates and cultivate the soil for themselves and families, instead of working for others at twelve hours per day in the manufactories . (4) John R. Commons in his History of Labor in the United States writes that "The condition that seems to distinguish most clearly the history of labor in America from its history in other countries is the wide expanse of free land. As long as the poor and industrious can escape from the conditions which render them subject to other classes, so long do they refrain from that aggression on the property rights and political power of others, which is the symptom of a labor movement." (5) Hart suns up perhaps the general attitude of writers on the subject and casual thinkers also when he says, "The wilderness ever opened a gate to the poor, the disconsolate and the oppressed." (6) That the extent to which land is accessible in any country does have a vital bearing on its social and economic problems seems to be a logical assumption, and it is the purpose of this study to inquire into the significance of the fact that during the period from I 83 O to i860 v/e were in constant contact with a great unbroken frontier which moved steadily westward with the flew of population. ’.I/hat seems to be the popular conception of this relationship has been suggested. Observe now the extent to which the history of the period vin- dicates or vitiates that idea. . > . , mi: ... . ; ■: . J 0 , • ' o i . ■ • ' ( • C / i .. 3 ■ - 1 - , J. ' 0 1 . . I - 3 - Chapter I In I83O the total area of the United States was 1,793,4-00 square miles, which was occupied by 12,617,000 people, including free blacks and slaves. Three- fourths (approximately) of this population still lived along the seaboard, leaving little more than one- fourth to occupy the vast trans-Appalachian coun- try extending west to the Rocky Mountains. Only 628,000 square miles were in- cluded in the then settled area bounded by the Atlantic Ocean, the Gulf of Mex- ico, and a tortuous frontier line some 5,300 miles in length, which ran across the central part of Maine, along the international boundary from New Hampshire to Detroit, across northern Indiana and Illinois, and down the west bank of the Mississippi to the Gulf, thus leaving still, large unsettled tracts in northern Maine, New York and northv/estern Pennsylvania. Much of the middle v/est had scarcely passed the frontier stage, and the great mass of the Louisiana Territory was comparatively untouched. For the purpose of this study it might now be profitable to turn from this brief survey of the extent of the unoccupied land areas to a consider- ation of the social and economic conditions that prevailed in the already settled portions of the country adjoining them. One of the best general descriptions of this condition is given by McMaster. Speaking of the conditions that prevailed among the poor and laboring class during the period from 1825 to I83O, he says, ( 7 ) "The influx 'of paupers to partake of the benefits of many charitable socie- ties, the overcrowded labor market, the steady increasing numbers of unemployed, the congestion of population in limited areas and all its attendant vice and crime and the destitution produced by low wages and lack of constant employment , have already become a matter for serious consideration. An unskilled laborer was fortunate if he received 75^ for twelve hours' work and found employment for three hundred days a year. Hundreds were glad to work for 37£ and even 25$ . . .. .. - .. i'i } - , a . . . • . o ! . - . ■ . - ' > il . t A. n , < . . . , . , , • v *'J 'j : . : . - 4 ' a day in winter, who in spring and summer could earn 62 -g 0 or perhaps 87 - 2 ' by toiling fourteen hours on the turnpikes and canals. Fifteen dollars a month in summer and board was considered good pay. In winter it was not uncommon for men to work for their board. If the earnings of men were low, those of women were lower yet. Many trades and professions now open to them had no existence or were confined to men. They might bind shoes, sew rags, fold and stitch books, become spoolers or make coarse shirts and duck pantaloons at 8 or 100 apiece. "To the desperate poverty produced by such wages many evils were attributed. Intemperance was encouraged, children were sent into the streets to beg and pilfer, and young girls were driven to lives of shame to an extent that seems almost incredible in more modern times." The editor of the New York Commercial advertiser in an appeal in behalf of the impoverished population of the city in January, 1829, said, ( 8 ) "It makes my heart bleed to look at the hundreds and thousands of shivering, hungry applicants for charity v/ho have thronged the old almshouse in the park this afternoon." A correspondent to the New York Times speaks of thousands of industrious mechanics v/ho, unable to provide food and clothing for their fami- lies, were applying for assistance. The significant fact, however, is that pointed out by Hr. Commons, namely, that not only was there at times a great deal of unemployment but that the unskilled at least suffered constantly from low wages and long hours. In 1829 the Eoston Prison Discipline Society reported that about 75,000 people in the United States were annually imprisoned for debt. In I 83 O the same society estimated on the basis of returns from nearly one hundred prisons in different parts of the United States that the number annually im- prisoned for debt in Massachusetts was 3,000; in New York, 10,000; in Pennsyl- vania, 7,000; in Maryland, 3,000, and in the other northern and eastern states nearly as above in proportion to the population. They reported furthermore that the number imprisoned for debts of less than one dollar was very great, the number imprisoned for debts between five and twenty dollars was greatest, while the number imprisoned for more than twenty and less than one hundred dollars is not one-third as great as the number imprisoned for less than twenty dollars. "A report by the citizens of Rochester, New York, shortly before this time showed that in Monroe County during a single year about one person in every ten families had been imprisoned for debt. One of these cases w as for 25 cents.” The number of persons imprisoned for debt as compared to the number imprisoned for other crimes was everywhere very high, in some instances at a ratio of eight to one. The jails in which debtors were confined were often overcrowded and terribly unsanitary. Fuel and bedding and food too, with the exception of a daily ration of soup, were sometimes lacking. In some instances debtors re- ceived much worse treatment than common criminals. A consideration of these conditions, together with the insignifi- cance of the debts that compelled people to submit to them, seems again to indi- cate the existence of a wide-spread condition of wretchedness and poverty among the lower and laboring classes at this time. Not only does it appear that wages were low and employment uncertain during this period, but under employment hours were exceedingly long and irksome. Significant in this connection is the following extract from the Pennsylvanian. ( 9 ) "The excessive labor which the mechanic is forced to undergo saps his con- stitution and either cuts him off at a period of existence which should be the prime of life, or leaves him linger out a few years more, a miserable wreck of humanity. Humanity requires us not to abuse the brute creation by over labor, and surely our fellow man is entitled to as much consideration. (Exhaustion of . . . .. . ■ I ' . 1. ■ . . - '1 . .. . : . ■ . : J . > ■ ■ . , . • . ■ - J* *■ _ . i . • . . / . - . . 1 . . > .... 5 ... ' i. J . w . 1 . •> . . . - 6 . the frame requires for its removal excitement fully proportional to the depres- sion, and it is too often sought in alcohol. It has been ascertained and truly that excessive labor has been the cause of more intemperance than all other causes combined.) Although this may seem to smack somewhat of journalistic propoganda, it certainly has a basis of fact. M The system of labor from sun to sun had been taken over from agri- culture where conditions were entirely different, and even out-door mechanics worked from sunrise to sunset all seasons. In winter this meant comparatively short hours, but as wages were paid by the de.y regardless of the season, every inducement existed to concentrate all possible work in the late spring and sum- mer and early fall when the days were long and men could be required to work twelve to fifteen hours. As a result not only was there great physical strain during the summer months, but during the short winter days hundreds of building trades mechanics were unemployed." (10) In discussing the hours of labor in the cotton mills at Lowell, the cotton manufacturing center of the United States, during the decade of the thirties, James Montgomery says: (11) "From the first of September to the first of May, work is commenced in the morning as soon as the hands can see to advantage, and stopped regularly during those eight months at seven-thirty in the evening. During the four summer months, or from the first of May to the first of September, work is commenced at five o’clock in the morning and stopped at seven in the evening. Forty- five minutes is allowed for dinner during the summer months and thirty during the other eight. About 73§- hours per week may be regarded as the average hours of labor in the cotton mills at Lowell and generally throughout the whole eastern district of the United States. In many, perhaps the majority, of the cotton factories in the middle and southern dis- tricts, the hours of labor in summer are from sunrise to sunset or from half . I . . -«• : •: « 1 * . ■ > ' ' i , . 1 ( - . -7- past four in the morning till half past seven in the evening, being about thir- teen and throe-fourths hours per day, equal to eighty-two and one-half hours per week.'* In contrast to these conditions it might be noted that at this time "in Great Britain the hours of labor per week were limited by Act of Parlia- ment to 69 or 11 -g- hours per day, but the general regulation in all factories is nine hours on Saturday and twelve hours on each of the other five days." One American workman, lately arrived from England and quoted in the Mechanics Free Press for August, I 83 O, avers that in America after paying for board and washing he had $4.63 per week left, while in England he would have the same amount left, whose buying capacity would be one-third more, which would be earned with fifteen hours per v/eel; less labor. Thus far our attention has been directed to a consideration of the conditions that prevailed among the working classes near IS 30 or about the time of the beginning of the period of this study. That these conditions should have remained during all the subsequent years of this period equally unfavorable would be, as we shall try to show', illogical to expect, and we believe as a mat- ter of historical fact, quite easy to deny; and yet a few random observations tend to impress one v/ith the fact that the condition of labor in the United States throughout the entire period remained somewhat inconsistent with the idea that an abundance of cheap public land precludes the idea of a labor problem in so far as that problem is a question of freeing the laboring classes from op- pressive working conditions or capitalistic exploitation. For example, (12) in 1845 we find the women of New York City work- ing for from ten to eighteen cents per day, some of the most proficient receiv- ing twenty-five, an amount on which it was impossible to live decently and honestly. "The wages of unskilled laborers in New York, generally Irishmen just - 8 - from the old world, was sixty-five cents a day. Unable to live and procure lodging on three dollars and ninety cents a week, a number of them employed in Brooklyn were allowed to build shanties on land near where they were employed. The Massachusetts legislature when it met in 1844 received a petition from twenty-one hundred and thirty-nine operators who complained of long hours and unhealthy rooms. The hours complained of were from five in the morning until seven in the evening with an hour and a quarter off for meals. In 1850 we hear a representative of the German immigration saying, "We came here because v/e v/ere oppressed, and what have we gained? Nothing but misery, hunger and oppression." ( 13 ) The New York Herald for February 7, 1852, declared that laborers on public works v/ere often discharged and could not collect wages, sometimes months over due, that they were forced to work from sunrise to sunset for from fifty to seventy- five cents, and that they v/ere compelled to take part 0 ? this in trade at small liquor and victualing stores erected along the line of public works. (14) The last item of evidence dealing with laboring conditions during this period is from the writings of Trollope. Speaking of conditions in the middle west just before the Civil War, he said, (15) "The laboring Irish in these towns eat meat seven days a week, but I have met many a laboring Irishman among them who has v/ished himself back in his old cabin. There is, I think, no task master over free labor so exacting as an American. He knows nothing of hours and seems to have that idea of a man which a lady alv/ays has of a horse. He thinks he will go forever. I wish those masons in London who strike for nine hours’ work with ten hours' pay could be driven to the labor market of western America for a spell. American workmen are driven forward at this work in a manner that to an English workman v/ould be intolerable." - ' I ■ , J > . Ti t ' . > ■' •- r.it . • . . . ; ; - ) •- . * •: . ' : > ' - i ■ 1 „ 1 -9- One might continue almost indefinitely in this fashion. If, how- ever, the testimony offered is worthy of consideration, this should be suffic- ient to help to some conclusion. If worthless, continuation would be equally useless. It must be admitted that much of the evidence presented in this chapter has centered around the very beginning of the period, and yet there is nothing to indicate that those were abnormal times, certainly not abnormally depressed, for the country was just entering on that period of abnormal activity that precipitated the crisis of 1837. It is admitted also that part of this material has been somewhat controversial and tinged with prejudice doubtless and should be taken according- ly "cum grano salis," and yet enough remains, we believe, to amply justify the conclusion that during the first part especially of the thirty years' period from 1830 to i860, distress existed among the laborers of America to an extent that is quite amazing, especially to the uninformed, and seems somewhat at var- iance with the original assumption that an abundance of land offered an alterna- tive always to the conditions existing within the industrial sections of a country and thus precluded the possibility of widespread poverty or exploitation. That ordinarily or ultimately the welfare of the laboring class is conditioned largely by the possibility of their escape to the soil, seems too evident to need discussion or demonstration. That the abundances of public land that existed during this period failed to give effective relief during the whole of the period, seems from the foregoing data equally obvious. The next endeavor then will be to discover why this was true. - 10 - Chapter II Many conditions might be mentioned that acted as a check to the natural tendency to migrate from the older industrial sections of the East to the unoccupied territory of the West during the earlier part of the nineteenth century, thus tending to vitiate also the idea that these lands formed an easy method of escape from any conditions that became unsatisfactory in the original settlements. First, it might be v/orth v/hile to consider to what conditions one escaped who left the mills of Mew England or the Middle States to take up life in the frontier districts during the early part of the century. Roosevelt in hi spinning of the West” states it concisely when he says,(l6) "To push the frontier westward in the teeth of the forces of the v/ilderness was fighting work such as suited well enough many a stout soldier who had worn the blue and buff of the continental line, or who with his fellow rough-riders had followed in the train of some grim partisan leader." Stirring as this picture may be to a man, what appeal, one might ask, could such conditions have to women and girls, ever, tho they were being worn out in the cotton mills at Lowell. The frontier home with its "hole in the roof to let out the smoke and its hole in the door to let in the pigs" could scarcely have been said to be very appealing to them, "A fine place for men and dogs," testified the wife of one pioneer, "but a poor place for women," many of whom doubtless "accompanied their husbands from a sense of duty or necessity while secretly pining for the quie^ , orderly , friendly society to which they originally bade reluctant farewell." ( 17 ) Harriet Martineau, writing her impression of frontier life (1834 -6) says, (18) "None of the graces of fixed habitation had grown up. The success of his (the settler's) after life can hardly atone to him for such a destitution - 11 - of comfort as I saw him in the midst of." Not only did the pioneers suffer the discomforts of privation, but often from sickness brought on by their manner of life and the unhealthful con- dition of much of the new country. "Too often," observes Trollope ( 19 ) "the pioneer bore on his lantern jaws the signs of ague and sickness." Indeed, it is well known that "throughout large portions of the western country fevers and agues and stomach troubles beset the settlers. As to remedies, the pioneers had vigorous constitutions, otherwise they could hardly have survived the com- bination of disease and cure. (20) Another repressive influence which prevented a ready movement of population from centers of redundancy or conditions otherwise unfavorable was that utter lack during most of the first quarter of the century of transporta- tion facilities, which not only made the unsettled west difficult of access but made of those who entered it virtual exiles from the older portion of the coun- try and left them without adequate market for their products. The remoteness of the Mississippi Valley from the Atlantic seaboard before the influence of the campaign for internal improvements, that was so active for a decade following the completion of the Erie Canal, had made itself felt, presents a serious obstacle to the poor, especially from New England. (21) To relieve, partially at least, this situation a "rage" for turn- pikes struck the country following the westward expansion after the Revolution- ary War. New York alone in 1811 chartered one hundred and thirty-seven compan- ies to build 4,500 miles of road. This general movement by no means solved the difficulty. Roads on the wholo were unspeakably poor.- sloughs of mire during the thawing days of winter and spring and thick with dust in the summer. As late as 1835 Miss Martineau defies "pen, pencil or malice to do justice to the wreccnedness oj their condition. Transportation costs, as a consequence, re— - 12 - mained enormous. To haul a ton from Philadelphia to Pittsburgh on an all land route cost $ 125 . To move a bushel of salt three hundred miles over any road cost $2.50. For wagoning one hundredweight of sugar three hundred miles the tariff was $5.00* Taking the country through, it may be said that to transport goods cost $10 per ton per hundred miles. The cost of long carriage so far as many products were concerned v/as simply prohibitory. (22) Those who lived near the sea-coast found it much easier and more economical to ship by New Orleans such articles as were not needed on the road, especially if they intended to settle on any of the navigable waters of the Mississippi system, than to carry such freight overland with them. (23) In traveling at this time passengers were reckoned as so much freight, so that travel was not only difficult but very expensive. This barrier was particularly effective in the case of the v/ould-be emigrant from New England. (24) As the civilization of the East with its products was effectively cut off from the Y/est, with equal completeness v/as the West cut off from the potential market of the seaboard states. "Peltries, ginseng, and whiskey were almost the only products that could pay their cost of transportation overland to Philadelphia, and the proceeds derived from the sale of these were suffici- ent only to purchase things of first necessity, as salt and gunpowder and in- dispensable articles of iron. (25) The early western farmers were thus per- force self-sustaining. "The women made the clothes from the wool, the flax, or the skin, the men of the family helping in the heavier work, as of boat making." (26) Prices of produce were very low. At Edwardsville in Illinois, corn sold for from twelve and a half to twenty cents a bushel. Farther inland, the con- ditions were much worse. In 1824, corn might be bought in any quantity in Cin- cinnati for eight cents a bushel. Wheat yielded twenty-five cents, while flour sold for a dollar and a quarter a barrel. (27) A cow and a calf might be -13- obtained in exchange for a bushel of salt. Clearly, the settlement of the West was largely conditioned by the possibility of finding ways and means of trans- portation. (28) Coincident almost with the realization of this need comes an era of improvement in this line, such as has never been equalled. In l8ll Fulton's new invention was introduced on Western waters, and in 1817 the first steamboat voyage was made from New Orleans to Louisville. The ability of this new instru- ment of commerce to breast the current of the Mississippi being once established, traffic grew with wonderful rapidity. In 1834 the number of steamboats on the Mississippi and Ohio Rivers and their tributaries was ascertained to be 230, with an aggregate carrying capacity of 39,000 tons. In 1842 the number of boats had increased to about 450, with a carrying capacity of something more than 100,000 tons. In the meantime steam navigation of the Great Lakes had begun. In I8l8 the first steamboat was built on Lake Erie. By 1833 eleven small steamers were plying on the upper lakes. This number had grown to sixty in 1845, sup- plemented by 320 sailing vessels of from 1,000 to 1,200 tons each. (29) Following in chronological order, the next important step in the train of events that was to open up the West was the completion in 1818 of the Cumberland Road from Cumberland, Maryland, to Wheeling, West Virginia. Well graded and constructed of stone and gravel, Gallatin's prophecy that over it "ten thousand tons would be carried westward annually and 100,000 barrels of flour brought back" (30) seems quite justified. Immediately after its opening it did become one of the chief avenues of the West, and Wheeling was made for a time the entrepot of the Ohio Valley. Its importance, however, as an artery of trade was soon eclipsed by the most epoch making event of the series - the opening of the Erie Canal. -14- "Thanks to the ability and persistent endeavor of DeWitt Clinton, the problem of transportation between the East and the West was at last solved." (31) No other single work in the United States has ever exerted a greater in- fluence on the prosperity of internal trade. Freight rates between Buffalo and Albany were reduced 90 percent, almost immediately. An idea of the volume of trade may be gathered from the fact that tolls of half a million dollars were collected immediately upon its completion, and before a decade has passed it had paid the cost of its construction. ( 32 ) The indirect effects of the Canal were no less remarkable, Pennsyl- vania, awakened by the danger of the total loss of western trade, began in 1826 an extensive system of canals to connect Philadelphia with the Ohio River and Great Lakes. Not to be outdone, Maryland and Virginia agreed in 1828 upon the construction of a canal from tide-water on the Potomac to the Ohio, while at the same time, dubious of the success of a canal over such a route, some Balti- more financiers, "putting their confidence in a new and almost untried transpor- tation device", inaugurated the plan of building a railroad across the mountains to win for Baltimore a share of the commerce of the West . (33) By I 83 O it was evident that easy communication between the East and the West was assured. There v/ere 1,348 miles of canal completed; 1,828 miles were under construction; 44 miles of railroad had been completed; 697 had been projected, and 422 were in the process of building. So great was the transfor- mation wrought by these improvements that Dunbar speaks of those who lived dur- ing the early decades of this century as "the last pioneer generation." (34) -15- Chapter III It must not be assumed that with the passing of the problem of transportation and communication, all barriers to free emigration to the West had been overcome, for such was not the case. By the action of the various states the land to be occupied had become a public domain under the control of the National Government , and without its approval, not one foot of this land might be occupied. The history of the attitude of our Government toward the dispotition of its public lands is a varied one. "The primary use of fo eland, according to Bedes' celebrated spistle to Egbert, was to reward soldiers." True to this traditional policy, it appears that the earliest use made by Congress of the pub- lic lands was for military bounties. As early as August, 177 6 , it promised land bounties to deserters from the British Army, and a month later passed an act promising land to officers and soliers of the Continental army and endeavored by this means to induce men to enlist. With the end of the war and the cession by the states of the whole of the conquered domain west of the Alleghenies to the National Government, the land policy of Congress seemed naturally to resolve itself into two alternatives. Namely: Shall the public lands be administered from the standpoint of settlement or from the standpoint of finance? A know- ledge of the condition of the country at that time makes the answer obvious. The Revolutionary War had wrecked the finances of the states. Commerce had s. faint life. Manufactures had not come into being. State contributions were often attended with technical difficulties. Loans accumulated while credit was small. Continental paper was of little or no value. Under such conditions as these it seems natural, if not almost inevitable, that Congress should view the public domain primarily as a source of revenue. That this is true may be judged by the very tone of the resolution urging cession by the states from - 16 - which the following is quoted. "They (the states) be urged that the war now being brought to a happy termination by the personal services of our soldiers, the supplies of property by our citizens and loans of money from them, as well as from foreigners, these several creditors have a right to expect that funds shall be provided on which they may rely for indemnification; that Congress shall consider vacant territory as an important resource." (35) This, Hinsdale observes, was almost distinctly a new idea. "In colonial days waste land had not proved a source of income to either the col- onies or the crown." (36) A small quit rent was reserved but scarcely ever paid. "Virginia imposed an annual rental of two cents per acre upon her waste lands and then threw them open to indiscriminate locations. Whole states, as West Virginia, Kentucky and Tennessee, were disposed of without affording any public revenue whatever. It is therefore somewhat difficult to understand how the idea that the overmountain land would be a source of large income became current. But so it was." Without precedent, evidently, but under the necessity of relieving somehow the pressing financial burden incident to the Revolution, relief was sought from the public lands. That this entire domain be sold or mortgaged to foreign states, re- ceived but scant consideration. That would be, saidpeletiah Webster, "like killing the goose that laid the golden egg every day, in order to tear out at once all that was in her belly," (37) It was decided rather that first of all the ceded territory should be carefully marked off from the unceded and intrus- ion on it should be rigidly prohibited. It was in pursuance of this policy that Congress twice in 1737 instructed the military to move against the unauthorized settlers. Under these instructions, a detachment of troops moved up and down the right bank of the Ohio River, driving out the settlers and burning their log cabins. ( 38 ) -17- Since the public lands then were looked upon by all the financiers of this period as an asset to be cashed at once for payment of the current ex- penses of government and for the extinguishment of the national debt, land legislation began to shape itself accordingly. (39 ) The Ordinance of 1785 provided for the sale of land in large lots only, to first purchasers, to be resold by them to the settlers in lots more suitable to their convenience. Certainly a discouraging condition of sale and tenure when viewed from the standpoint of the settlors, who, if they availed themselves of the opportunity offered, v/ere compelled to expose themselves to possible disaster through the ignorance or trickery of the capitalistic pur- chasers. (40) About one-half of the state of Ohio was made up of large blocks of land, ranging from 1,000,000 to 4,209,800 acres in size. The desire being for immediate revenue, no credit was allowed for land purchases. "Payments could be made either in specie or in loan-office certificates reduced to specie value on their scale of depreciation, or by certificates of the liquidated debts of the United States, including interest. In case immediate payment was not forthcoming, the land was to be again offered for sale." (41) Attractive as this may have been to the speculator for whom the West had long been a favorite field of endeavor, (The Ohio Co. was formed in 1742) it ignored entirely the wishes of the men who were moving toward that region and had the greatest inter- est in the lands. What they desired was cheap lands in small tracts without delay, whereas the system in favor called for expensive surveys, taking much tine for execution. No land offices existed in the West itself except the one at Pittsburg; the smallest tract obtainable was 640 acres at one dollar per acre, plu3 the cost of survey, and only half the townships were offered in this way. Furthermore, since rivers were the only highv/ays of the interior, easy - 18 - access to then was of greatest importance. The surveys left this fact entirely out of consideration. The Seven Ranges extended forty-two miles inland at one point. It is scarcely to be wondered at, that the sale of land to actual set- tlers under the Ordinance of 1785 was insignificant. (42) The next important change in the land system after 1785 was the law passed in 179&, the first land ordinance of the National Congress. (43) There is little in this law that is original, nor is there much evident weaken- ing from the old financial policy, in fact, the price of land is increased to two dollars per acre, without the repeal of any of the restrictive measures of the original act in compensation. Even yet, as pointed out by Treat, section lines were not run, which made it difficult for the purchasers of a section to locate it, as well as for the government to compute the size of the fractional township and sections. In fact, they were but roughly computed and sold at the buyer’s risk. That under such conditions the typical pioneer would or could pay f 1,280 for a section (the minimum amount at the minimum price) is too much to expect. The act of 179& was "of importance mainly as a statement of prin- ciples, for little land was sold under it,” It was evident that if Congress insisted on selling land in large tracts it must either reduce the price or extend the credit, and if it wished to sell to the settlers it must reduce the price or the size of the minimum tract. So poor had been the sale in the period passed that the new act passed in 1800 showed some important developments in this direction. (44) They were principally the establishment of land offices, the extension of credit and the reduction of the size of the tracts. The land offices, located at Cincinnati, Chillicothe, Marietta and Steubenville, brought the place of sale within the reach of the would-be purchaser. (45) The credit system extending over a period of four years, (later extended to five) coupled with a reduction of the . r o o . * . r i . ... , v. •i ... - . . , < • *. •; . ‘ : , . • , ' , • . - ' " " y . , . ■ ■ • , •> > ■ .. >,.1 , • . ’ . : . \ ; . , •; > - 19 * minimum tracts offered to 320 acres, made it possible for settlers to have the use of that amount for five years for $ 160 , even tho they might not be able to hold it ultimately by paying the balance. This credit feature seemed quite alluring, and the land system under this act became a real factor in the west- ward movement. It regulated the sale of public land for twenty years, being modified only as to the computation of interest charges, by the introduction of quarter-section tracts in 1804, and a limited number of eighty-acre tracts in 1817 . Throughout the whole of its existence thus far, the public domain had been administered as a source of revenue primarily, the wishes of the settl- ers being of secondary importance. That this attitude, so strong at first, should have persisted, is not unnatural. National legislation was being domina- ted by eastern influence. Land values in the East were being endangered by the competition of the opening West. It was also feared that cheapened lands with the resultant flow of population from the seaboard states would cause a scarcity of labor and a rising wage scale in the industrial sections. The credit policy of the Act of 1800, while passed doubtless for the special benefit of the settlers, was of doubtful value. Too often it in- duced them to expend their last cent in making the first payment, under the im- pression that by means of the produce of the lands they would be able to meet the balances as they came due. In this they were disappointed. This new land was not immediately highly productive. Many of the settlers consequently found themselves unable to meet their later installments. On September 30, I 8 I 9 , more than $21,000,000 was to be collected for these lands. More than $500,000 had already been forfeited to the Government. Speculators, too, were taking advantage of the credit provisions to gain an option on the better land. A change was becoming necessary. ( 46 ) , . - , . . K . ... . \ . * - , . . ... . ’ . 1 3 . . . ■ - 20 - A new act ’was drawn up and signed on April 24 , 1820 , "The most important piece of land legislation since the Congress of the Confederation laid down the principle of the American land system in 1785 ." ( 4 7 ) This act provided for the abolition of credit and the establishment of ca3h sales arter July 1 , 1820 , for the sale of eighty-acre tracts, and for the reduction of the minimum price to $1.25 per acre. By this act the speculators found their dreams of fattening on the unearned increment of a growing country curtailed, while the settler for $100 could now purchase a farm outright, which under the old system would have furnished little more than the first payment on a quarter- section tract. While the old revenue attitude toward the public domain continued in the older sections, that its force was steadily weakening is evidenced by this law of 1820, the beginning really of a new era in the history of our land policy. The question of the welfare of the settlers had risen much in relative importance, end from this time on may be safely said to have had equal, if not first, consideration. This change of attitude is revealed again by a series of relief acts, beginning March 2 , 1821 . As has been already suggested, many pioneers, under- estimating the difficulty of realizing a quick return from the products of their western farms, were finding themselves unable to pay the final installments of their purchase. If arrears were not paid, the lav/ had to take its course, and the land reverted to the government. "To eject unfortunate settlers from their lands and log cabins must have seemed to the pioneers an inhuman thing." ( 48 ) The lav/, however, had to be executed until relief came. Beginning with March 2, 1821, eleven different acts were passed in as many years to ease the terms of credit to the bankrupt western farmers. A discrimination in come respects against the faithful purchasers, and a concession to the speculators, these acts - 21 - nevertheless prevented almost half the land perhaps settled under the act of 1800 from reverting back to the government, rendering its occupants landless and homeless . There is finally a changing attitude on the question of pre-emption to take care of the long and insistent demand of the squatters. The squatting evil, for such it was in the eyes of those who held a revenue policy at least, represents one of the oldest things in American life, going back to the very first years of colonial history. Squatting on waste land was a right and the squatter's point of view was that laws interfering with this right were unjust and of no effect. It is a v/ell known fact that the tide of immigration always preceded the surveys and land sales authorized by the Government, and the cry for pre-emption was the cry of those hardy pioneers to have more of the benefits of their enterprise secured to them. The attitude of 3tern repression at first adopted toward them has been already mentioned. Here again the public mind was undergoing evolution. (49) Pre-emption, quoting from the "Public Domain", "is a premium in favor of and condition for making a permanent settlement and a home. It is a preference for actual tilling and residing upon a piece of land." It was not a free grant of land but the giving to a settler of the privilege of purchasing land as against competition. "It amounts simply to the exclusion of competition and the purchase of land at a minimum or double minimum, as the case may require. The first general pre-emption act was passed May 29, 1830. By this act every settler or occupant of the public lands after giving due proof of settlement or improvement was allowed to enter in the register of the land office any number of acres up to a quarter section at the established minimum price of $1.25 per acre. This act, however, was but a temporary measure. The first general and permanent pre-emption act was not passed until 1841. This act marked the last , . . y "3 > J - . . ■ X - . « - 22 - great step in the evolution of legislation from the purely revenue attitude to the idea of free grants of land to actual settlers, which was realized with the Homestead Law of 1362. (50) The change witnessed thus far had been very gradual, the result of experience as well as of changed conditions. The suffering of land purchasers under the credit system, the failure to realize any considerable revenue from the cash sale, the increasing prosperity of the country from commerce and manu- facture, all these causes combined to mould public opinion and shape the ultimate policy of homesteads for the actual settlers. The extent to v/hich the flow of population toward the West was checked by this unfavorable early legislation cannot, of course, be accurately determined. (51) That it had a deterrent in- fluence certainly could not be denied. A comparison of the 1820 population of nine 'western states settled under the acts that have been mentioned with the population of two which escaped those restrictions should prove enlightening. Under national regulation: Ohio .... 581,295 Indiana Illinois .... 55,162 Michigan .... 8,764 Mississippi .. .... 75,448 Alabama .. .. 127,901 Louisiana . . . . .... 152,923 Missouri Arkansas .... 14,255 Total . 1,229,484 States independent of national regulation: Kentucky 422,771 Tennessee 564. 135 Total 986,906 Relative to this situation, Treat says that altho settlers were mov- ing into the public domain north and south of the Ohio River and west of the -23- Mississippi, that it must be remembered, that only a portion of these people were holding lands purchased at the land offices, and that of the settlers west of the Appalachians in 1820 fully one-half had taken up lands in regions that had never come under the land system - notably Kentucky and Tennessee. And of the settlors in the public land states and territories, the greater part were located on land which had not been surveyed and sold under the general land system. (52) Another set of figures from which it is possible to make some de- ductions is the record of receipts from land sales during a large part of this period. (53) Year Amount Year Amount 1801 $168,125 1822 $1,803,581 1802 188 , 628 1823 916,523 1803 165,675 1824 984,418 1804 487,526 1825 1,216,090 1805 540,192 1826 1,393,785 1806 765,245 1827 1,497,053 1807 466, 163 1828 1,018,308 1808 647,939 1829 1,517,175 1809 442,252 1830 2,329,356 1810 696 , 548 1831 3,210,815 1811 1,040,237 1832 2,623,331 1812 710,427 1833 3,967,631 1813 835,655 1834 4,857,600 1814 1,135,971 1835 14,757,600 1815 1,287,959 1836 24,641,979 1816 1,717,985 1837 6,770,036 1817 1,991,226 1838 3,081,939 1818 2 , 606,564 1839 7,076,447 1819 3,274,442 1840 3,292,220 1820 1,635,871 1841 1,363,090 1821 1,212,966 Signal as xne victory of 1841 may have seemed, it soon became evi- dent that it was not by any means complete. The evil of speculation, so preva- lent under former systems, while somewhat mitigated, was not by any means de- stroyed. Through his superior financial resources and ability to employ shrewd men to locate the choicest lands, the speculator sill had an advantage over the -24- settler that could scarcely be overcone. (54) "Hi3 agents were instructed to select those tracts most likely to advance most rapidly in value, due to advan- tageous situation, excellence of soils, minerals, water power, or with reference to settlements already made; and as a result when the land sales opened, he knew exactly what tracts were unoccupied and of greatest value." The St. Anthony (Minn.) Express said in 1852: We have a set of speculators, land sharks, Shylocks, in this Territory who have bought all the land in close proximity to the villages and refuse to sell it except at a consid- erable advance on government price. As a result of the general acquisition throughout the West of large tracts of land by non-residents, settlers who wanted cheap land had to go farther still into the wilderness, away from society and market where their lot, normally a hard one, became increasingly burdensome. One of the contributing causes to this speculation was the general practice on the part of the Federal Government of issuing land grants as bounties to soldiers. Since many of these could not or would not locate in the West, these warrants were sold, ordinarily to land speculators, and became an article of commerce, bought and sold on the market just as railway stocks are today, and in anticipation of the opening of a new land office were "salted down" in large quantities by this same class of men. (55) The scope of their activities may be judged from the following extract from the St. Anthony Express: "Nearly 200,000 land warrants yet remain to be located. If assign- able, not more than one-third of one- fourth of these will be located by the original holders. Land sharks will swallow all the rest and disgorge them, pol- luted by their blighting touch, upon the fairest portions of our Territory. Instead of boats swarming with an energetic, hardy and industrious crowd of far- mers and mechanics, they will be encumbered by the agents of eastern millionaires, their pockets stuffed with warrants, who like the flies that come upon the borders -25- of Egypt will cause the land to stink.” Greeley, writing from Wisconsin Territory in 1849, emphasizes the same condition. Wherever, he says, upon a natural harbor, a bay, a head of navi- gation, or a waterfall, a village began or promised to spring up, the speculator or his agent pounced upon all the unoccupied lands within a circuit of a mile or two. "This he would hold for a price, treble or sixty-fold what he had paid for it.” (56) There is no reason to suppose that the conditions described were peculiar to Wisconsin or Minnesota. Against the aggressions of eastern capital, the home makers were fighiing a discouraging, often a losing, battle, for often the necessary amount had been expended by them in building cabins and in stock- ing farms, most of them were penniless. And if the claim happened to be located in a section that had been proclaimed for sale, it was likely to be purchased after a year by anyone who chose to buy it, unless protected by public opinion or a claim association. Such conditions as these, it is obvious, would not be tolerated willingly and so an insistent demand began to arise for a law that would reserve the public domain for actual settlers. (57) On January 3, 1845, a petition was presented to Congress, asking that it pass "with all convenient haste, a law by which every citizen who may be desirous of cultivating the earth for a living shall be enabled to enter upon the public lands and occupy a reasonable sized farm thereon, free of cost.” During the first session of the Twenty-ninth Congress three men introduced independent homestead bills, authorizing every poor man in the United States who is at the head of a family to enter 160 acres of public domain without money and without price. The history of the appearance and reappearance of homestead bills in Congre33, of how the land question became merged into the greater problem -26- of slave soil or free, and how it wa3 finally passed largely as a sectional anti- slavery issue - all this would be perhaps somewhat irrelevant to our discussion. Suffice it to say that the pre-emption law of 1841 with its attendant evils, already briefly described, governed the method of land disposal in the West for more than two decades and that in this time no relief was given from the activities of land sharks and speculators. On the other hand, when it became known that in every congress from 1847 until the close of the Civil War general bounty bills were presented and that four of them became laws, it appears that through part of this period at least, the field for this evil machination was being extended. - . *' , , . - 27 - Chapter IV Reflected by and from the legislative activities that have been considered, and playing always, if somewhat intangible, yet, an important part in this whole problem was the degree to which the rank and file became alive to the possibilities offered by the West as a solution for their social and indus- trial ills. To us from the vantage ground of a later period, this connection seems so evident that one would be led to assume that its significance had al- ways been a matter of general recognition. This is not strictly correct, how- ever, for altho it was doubtless patent to some, yet it is evident that if realized at all by the great mass of people, throughout a very considerable part of our early history, it was in a very vague and passive fashion. Until this idea became an active motivating one, it is evident also that the evolution of transportation or legislation or the removal of any other barrier to the west- ward flow of population must have remained quite useless. The awakening of this active interest and its spread in scope and intensity presents itself as a part of the general field for investigation in our general problem. Two forces are at once observed at work here, each almost equally active. The one, the social reformer of the East who upholds and propogates the idea of cheap lands made available to actual settlers, for its effect on social conditions among the working classes. The other, western men who would induce a flow of industrial population from the East to hasten the growth of that section of the country. There is evidence that already in the late twenties social reformers were beginning to contend for free access to the public lands in order to amel- iorate the condition of the working man. The sale of lands, they began to see, was injurious to the laboring classes because few of them possessed sufficient capital to buy it. If, in place of selling the land, it were to be given free - 28 - to actual settlers, it would, they contended, bring a freehold and independence within reach of all. As early as 1828, the Mechanics Free Press contained a memorial to Congree proposing that Public land should no longer be sold but sug- gested to Congress "the propriety of placing all public lands without the delay of sales within the reach of the people at large by title of company only . . . and therefore pray your honorable body to enact a law authorizing a grant to any individual who shall apply for it, of a free use of so much of the public land as you in your wisdom shall deem sufficient." Two years before this tine, Thos. H. Benton expressed the attitude of the West toward the repressive revenue attitude of the East (in Congress) when he said, "I speak to statesmen and not to conpting clerks; to senators and not to quaestors of provinces; to an assembly of legislators and not to a keeper of the King’s forests. I speak to senators who know this to be a Republic, not a Monarchy; who know that the public lands belong to the people and not to the Federal Government.” (58) John R. Commons, in his discussion of this question, suggests that it was during the time of hardship to labor as a result of the rapidly rising prices just prior to the panic of 1837 that the importance of the public lands dawned upon the workingmen, and it began to be evident to them that one reason why their wages did not rise and their strikes were ineffective was because they were cut off from escape to the land by existing conditions. Speaking of the importance of this growing sentiment, he further says, (59) "In their conventions and papers, therefore, they (the workingmen) demanded that the lands should no more be treated as a source of public revenue to relieve taxpayers, but should be treated as an instrument of social reform to raise the wages of labor." And when we in later years refer to our wide domain and our great natural resources as reasons for higher wages in this country, it is well to remember that access to ' -29- these resources was secured only by agitation and act of legislature. Not merely as a gift of nature, but mainly as a demand of democracy have the nation's re- sources contributed to the elevation of labor. And it was in the events of 1827 to 1837 with their futile immediate results that the lesson was learned which in a later day led the nation's industrial democracy even to civil war in order to establish the freedom of the public lands. Responsible doubtless in a large measure for the beginning of this heightened interest in the public lands among the working people and helping to mark therefore the beginning of the general agitation, was the appearance of the Workingman's Advocate in 1825, published by George and Henry Evans. This maga- zine, published in New York City during the five year period from 1825 - 1330, may perhaps be said to be the first appearance of a representative of the labor press in the United States. It was succeeded by "The Daily Sentinel" and finally by "Young America." The demands of the representatives of labor printed in Young America, altho extremely radical, were endorsed by some six hundred papers and have since in some instances been granted. An enumeration of some of them will show how thoroughly its readers were being impressed with the relation that exists between land and conditions of labor. (60) First of all was: The right of man to the soil, "Vote yourself a farm." Another was, "Freedom of public lands." Another, "Homesteads made inalien- able." Still another was, "Land limitation to 160 acres." Four out of twelve demands dealt with the land situation. To deal in a comprehensive fashion with the spread of this agitation until its climax is reached and its goal attained in the Homestead Act of 1862 is beyond the scope of this endeavor. Vfhat follows is rather random bits of in- formation that tend to mark here and there its progress. At the convention of the "National Trades Union," held in 1834, -30- wit h delegates from Massachusetts, Pennsylvania, New Jersey and New York, the following resolutions were offered: (ol) ’’Resolved, that this convention depre- cate the system now practiced in the disposal of the public lands because of its violation of the inherent rights of the citizen, seeing that the v/hole of the unseated lands belong unto the people, and should not be disposed of to the prejudice of any class of society. Each and every citizen having a just claim to an equitable portion thereof, a location upon which being the only just title thereunto "Resolved, that this convention would the more especially reprobate the sale of the public lands because of its injurious tendency, as it affects the interests and independence of the laboring classes, inasmuch as it debars then from occupation of any portion of the same unless provided with an amount of capital which the greater portion of them who would avail themselves of this aid to arrive at personal independence cannot hope to attain, owing to the many incroachments made upon than through the reduction in wages of labor consequent upon its surplus quantity in the market, which surplus would be drained off and a demand for the produce of mechanical labor increased if these public lands were left to actual settlers." It has been suggested that throughout this whole period one of the principal agencies for fostering and disseminating the idea that free access to the public lands furnished a remedy for the ills of which labor was complaining, was the various publications of the Evans Brothers. The following, quoted from the Workingman* s Advocate for July 6, 1844, will show the tenor of their writing: "Let an outlet be formed that will carry off our super- abundant labor to the salubrious West . In these regions thousands and tens of thousands who are now languishing in hopeless poverty will find a certain and speedy inde- -31- pendence. The labor market will thus be freed of its present distressing com- petition; and those who remain, as well as those who leave, will have the op- portunity of realizing a comfortable living." It was in the latter part of 1845 that Horace Greeley, Editor of the Hew York Tribune, began to notice the homestead movement, and in a discus- sion of the National Reformers gives qualified approval to their scheme of a homestead lav;. Five months later, he comes forth with a whole-hearted vindica- tion of the movement in the following editorial. (62) "The freedom of the Public Lands to actual settlers and the limitation of future acquisition of land to some reasonable amount are measures v/hich seen to us vitally necessary to the ultimate emancipation of labor from thralldom and misery. What is mainly v/anted is that each nan shall have a chance to earn, and than an assurance of the just fruits of his labors. We must achieve these results yet; we can do it. Every new labor-saving invention is a new argument, an added necessity for it. And so long as the laboring class must live by working for others, v/hile others are striving to live luxuriously and amass wealth out of the fruits of such labor, so long the abuses and sufferings now complained of must continue to exist or frequently reappear. We must go to the root of the evil." The influence of Greeley in promoting the cause of free land can hardly be estimated. Many readers of the Weekly Tribune looked upon it as a kind of political bible . "In the homes of the wage-earners of the East and the set- tlers' cabins of the West it was prized and cherished." ( 63 ) A western editor, writing in 1853, said, "The influence of The Tribune upon public opinion is greater than its conductors claim for it. Its Isms with scarcely an exception, though the people may reject thorn at first, yet ripen into strength insensibly. A few years since, the Tribune commenced the advocacy of the principle of Free . ■ . . I -32- Lc.nd for the Landless. The first bill presented upon that subject by Mr. Greeley was hooted out of that body. But who doubts what the result would be if the people of the whole nation had the right to vote upon the question today?" Effective in the manner of its appeal was "Vote yourself a farm," an article that appeared in The Workingman for January 24, 1846, and as a circu- lar or handbill was distributed in hundreds of thousands. To quote some of its striking passages: "Are you an American citizen? Then you are joint owner of the public lands. Why not take enough of your property to provide yourself a hone? Why not vote yourself a farm?" ( 64 ) "Remember Poor Richard's saying: 'Now I have a sheep and a cow, everyone bids me good morrow.' .... The bare rights to a farm, tho you should never go near it, v/ill save you from insult. Therefore, vote yourself a farm." "Are you a party follower? Then you have long enough employed your vote to the benefit of scheming office seekers; use it for once to benefit yourself. Vote yourself a farm." "Are you tired of slavery - of drudging for others - of poverty and its attendant miseries? Then, vote yourself a farm." "Are you endowed with reason? Then you must know that your right to live hereby includes the right to a place to live in - the right to a home. Assert this right so long denied mankind by feudal robbers and their attorneys. Vote yourself a farm." "Are you a believer in the scriptures? Then assert that the land is the Lord's because he made it. Resist then the blasphemers who exact money for his work Vote yourself a farm." "Are you a man? Then assert the sacred rights of man - especially your right to stand upon God's earth and till it for your own profit. Vote yourself a farm." -33- "Would you free your country and the sons of toil everywhere from the heartless, irresponsible mastery of the aristocracy of avarice? .... Vote yourself a farm." The first clause of a proposed bill for Congress appeared in Young America in September, 1348, and reads as follows: An act to establish the equal rights to the use of the land and its natural products; to afford a refuge to the landless population of the United States; to secure homesteads to individual families and associations; to provide for the increase in population; to make labor the master instead of the slave of capital, and to perpetuate the republic. (6 5) The Industrial Congress, held in Boston in 1846, marks the beginning of a series of such meetings; New York in 1847; Philadelphia in 1848; Cincinnati in 1849; Chicago in 1850; Albany in 1851; Washington in 1852; Wil- mington in 1853; Trenton in 1854; Cleveland in 1855, and New York in 1856. At each of these the land question proved to be the leading subject for discussion. (66) Another factor in the turning of attention toward the public land situation and that helped to influence public sentiment was the infusion, during the latter part of this period, of a great number of German and Scandi- navian immigrants into our population. Anti- capitalistic by instinct almost and with a deep interest in the land, they began to combat existing methods of land disposal. The Volks Tribune and the Social Republic played no small part in this general movement. With all this agitation by social reformers in the East supple- menting the efforts of the land reformers in the West, it is small wonder that the question of the possible significance of the western land in our social and economic life was raised from obscurity to universal recognition and concern. "The Providence 'American' called it the most important subject to be acted on by Congress. The Richmond 'Enquirer' declared that 'these public lands are - 34 - beginning to present some of the most serious questions which have ever agitated our public councils.' The Philadelphia Gazette affirmed that the disposition of the public lands was the most dangerous subject of legislation before Congress. In the New York 'Evening Post* the situation was described as follows: 'But the public lands - the public lands - this is the exciting theme which brings every man to his seat, and every other question - tariff, roads, revenue, education, - all insensibly slid into this."' (67) After reviewing in this way a history of the evolution of those factors that v/ould make for the promotion of retardation of the settlement of the public lends, and after noting also the coincidence that existed in the time of establishing a favorable condition of communication, of legislation, and of pub- lic interest, those things which most vitally affected the movement, it might be profitable to observe what change, if any, in distribution of population actually occurred. The following figures are compiled from the census reports for the years indicated and show the population of fourteen states of the eastern group as it varies during the period and also fourteen states falling within the public domain. Of particular interest and significance is the change to be observed in the rates of growth of population that occurs between East and Y/est in the de- cade of the thirties. -35- i8oo 1810 1820 1830 1840 1850 i 860 The We Ohio 45 230 581 937 1519 1950 2339 Indiana 5 24 147 343 685 988 1350 Illinois 12 55 157 476 851 1711 Missouri 20 66 140 383 682 1182 Kentucky 220 406 564 687 779 982 1 x 55 Tennessee 105 261 422 681 829 1002 1109 Alabama 127 309 590 771 964 Mississippi .... 8 40 75 136 375 606 791 Wisconsin 30 305 775 Michigan ....... 4 8 31 212 397 749 Louisiana 96 153 215 352 517 708 Texas 212 604 Arkansas 30 97 209 435 Minnesota 6 172 1800 1810 1820 1830 1840 0 00 •H i860 The East New York 589 959 1372 1918 2428 3097 3880 Pennsylvania . . . 602 810 1049 1348 1724 2311 2906 Virginia 880 974 1065 1211 1239 1421 1598 Massachusetts .. 422 472 523 610 737 994 1231 Georgia 162 252 340 516 691 906 1057 North Carolina . 476 555 638 737 753 869 992 South Carolina . 245 415 502 581 594 668 703 Maryland 341 380 407 447 470 583 687 New Jersey 211 245 277 320 373 489 672 Connecticut .... 251 261 275 297 309 370 460 New Hampshire . . 182 214 244 269 284 317 326 Vermont 154 235 235 280 291 314 315 Rhode Island ... 69 76 83 97 108 147 174 Delaware 64 72 72 76 78 21 112 Population by states for the years indicated. (000 omitted) Table shov/ing the comparative growth in population of the East and West from l800 to i860. 1800 1810 1820 1830 1840 1850 i860 East .... 4650 5910 7082 8707 10079 12577 15111 West .... 393 1093 2190 3666 6347 9578. . . 14044 (000 omitted) ] Table showing the c omparative gains in population of the East and West from 1800 to i860 1800-10 10-2C 20-30 30-40 40-90 50-60 East .... X260 1172 1625 1372 2498 253* West .... 867 1079 1476 2681 3.231 4466 (000 omitted) -36- Chapter V What then has been the relation between the public lands and the labor problem in the thirty year period from I83O to i860? Were conditions such as to vindicate the popular idea that where abundant public land exists oppres- sive laboring conditions and wide-spread poverty are obviated? A study of the economic and social conditions that characterized the industrial sections of the country in 1830, as pointed out before, revealed a condition of general distress that was scarcely surpassed during the depression of I9O7-8, when public land had practically ceased to be available. In an attempt to vindicate the popular conception of this relation- ship, it is scarcely sufficient to show that the normal effect of the land v/as counteracted by those conditions of transportation, legislation and general apathy that rendered than unaccessible to the masses. Since it has been shown that these conditions did not always obtain, one should be able to show con- ditions bettering in proportion to the extent to which these hindrances were re- moved. This, we believe, can in a measure be done. It is significant, first of all, that there was a turning from those practical demands which v/ere charact eristic of the decade and a half fol- lowing 1825 and which had to do mostly with decent relief from the general suf- fering, to indulge in the "hot air'* of the forties, that period of "unbounded loquacity," which found expression in transcendentalism, abolition, and such idealistic ventures as the Brook Farm experiment. (68) In addition to this type of thinking which does not reflect the grim poverty of the earlier period, there seems also a lack of that dissatis- faction and unrest that characterized the labor history of the early part of the century. At no time, certainly during the latter part of this period, even dur- ing tne depression of 1857 , would that well-known observation of 1835 that -37- " strikes were all the fashion" apply. More convincing still perhaps would be a study of the movement of wages and prices throughout the period. The progress in money wages is indi- cated by the following table. (69) Compari son of wages by periods: 1830 and i 860 Av. daily wage Av. daily wage Percentage for period i"or period of increase end ,ing I 83 O ending i 860 or decrease Agricultural laborers ... $0.83 11.01 25.8 % Elacksmiths 1.12 I .69 50.9 Carpenters 1.07 2.03 87.7 Clock makers 1.29 1.96 51.5 Clothing makers 1.27 1.43 12.6 Cotton mill operatives .. .886 1.03 16.3 Glass makers 1.13 2.96 161.9 Harness makers 1.13 1.65 46 Laborers .756 .975 22 Masons 1.22 1.53 25.4 Metal workers 1.23 1.35 9.8 Millwright 1.21 1.66 37.2 Painters 1.25 1.85 48 Paper mill operatives ... .666 1.17 75.7 Printers 1.25 1.75 40 Ship & boat builders .... 1.40 3.65 160 Shoemakers 1.06 1.70 60 Tanners and curriers .... 1.13 1.67 47.8 Wooden goods workers .... 1.25 1.72 37.6 Woolen mill operatives .. .946 .873 - 7.7 It is not, however, the rate of money wages that most nearly con- cerns the workman, but rather the real wage. If this increase in money wages has been more than counterbalanced by an increase in prices, the workman' s real wage has, of course, declined. In an effort to show the variation of the real wage, a table of prices paid for the leading articles of household consumption during the same period is shown also. -38- Compariaon of prices by periods: 1830 and i860 ( 69 ) Article Basis Av. price for period ending 1830 Av. price for period ending i 860 Percentage of increase or decrease Apples bu. $ .439 § .995 126.7 % Beans qt . .085 .088 3.5 Corn bu. .817 .992 21.4 Potatoes bu. .369 .86 133.1 Boots pr. 4.75 2.21 - 53.5 Shoos pr. 1.26 I .09 -13.5 Slippers pr. .935 .945 1.1 Butter lb. .186 .262 40.9 Cheese lb. .089 .117 31.5 Eggs doz . .15 .22 46.7 Milk qt . .044 .052 18.2 Cotton cloth yd. .21 .118 -43.8 Flannel yd. .57 .405 -28.9 Linen yd. .453 .531 17.2 Flour bbl. 7.08 8.92 26 Indian meal lb. .016 .021 31.3 Coffee lb. .206 .163 - 20.9 Salt qt . .063 .029 -54 Sugar lb. .16 .12 -25 Tea lb. .825 .529 - 35.9 Beef lb. .076 .126 65.8 Cork lb. .088 .114 29.5 From the foregoing comparison it appears that prices have increased to a certain extent, but not uniformly. Certain staple articles, chiefly those produced under the factory system. of labor, as boots and shoes and cotton and woolen cloth, dry goods and dress goods, show a constant decline. A fev; of the staple groceries also have declined, while flour, fish and meal have risen. Consolidating and averaging the wages shown in the former table, it appears that for those occupations compared the general average increase in wages for the decade ending i860, as compared with that ending in I 83 O, is 52.3 percent. Comparing the price changes of the same period by a consoli- dation of the percentages which shov; either an advance or a decline in price for the articles represented in the comparison, the general average percentage of increase is found to be 9.6 percent. If averages are considered rather than -39- percentages, the average increase is found to be 15.7. The mean of these two, 12.7 percent, represents perhaps as nearly as possible the increase in prices for the decade ending in i860 with that ending in 1830. Without budgets show- ing the expenses of workingpen, the percentage of increase in the cost of living cannot, of course, be accurately determined. However, a comparison of the two advances, that of wages and that of prices, indicates material gain on the part of the former and express more clearly than words the change that took place in the period from I83O-6O in the pecuniary status of the workingp&n. It should be remembered too that this was not the progress simply of a static population. The population of the United States had increased from 12,866,020 in I83O to 31, 4-4-3, 321 in i860, a greater percentage of growth than during any other thirty year period in our national history. To have maintained our standard of living in the face of such a rapid increase, a large percentage of which represents an immigrant population, would have been an achievement, had the public lands not furnished a field for expansion. To have raised that standard without this help seems almost impossible. They played a double part. Not only did they furnish field for expansion, lessening thus the possibility of redundancy of labor and low wages, their large production by keeping down the cost of living helped to boost the real wage. If it were possible in this investigation to go a step farther and compare conditions in America as they existed during this period with those of a country similar in all respects with the exception of the existence of public lands, the relationship might be judged more accurately. Altho such ideal con- ditions for study do not exist, yet some comparisons with other nations less advantageously situated in this respect may not be without merit. The following table presenting a comparison of wages in the United States, England and France in 1825, shows that even then with immigration into the public lands scarcely -40- begun, that the condition of the American laborers was more favorable than that of their European brethren. Comparative Wages in England. France and U. S., 1828 Employments Basis England France U. S. Common laborer day $0.74 $0.37 -.40 $1.00 Carpenter day • 97 .55 -.75 1.45 Mason day 1.10 .60- ,80 1.62 Farm laborer (with board) ..... mo . 6.50 4.00-6.00 8.00 - 10. CO Domestic (female with board) .. v/k . • 67 1.00 - 1.50 Machinists & forgers (best) ... day 1.54 1.50 - 1.75 Machinists & forgers (ordinary) day 1.10 .92 1.25 - 1.42 Mule spinners (cotton) day 1.02 .80 -.50 1.08 - 1.40 Spinners (woolen) dday • 94 .40 -.50 1.08 Weavers (on hand looms) day • 74 .37 -.50 .90 Boys (age 10 - 12) wk. 1.30 •85-1.00 1.50 Females ( in cotton mills) .... wk. 1.96 1.48-2.00 2.00 - 3.00 Females ( in woolen mills) .... wk. 1.56 1.50 2.50 Complete statistical data for this period seems to be lacking and so some dependence must be placed in other forms of evidence. The following is a contemporary description of conditions in England as they prevailed before the Factory Act of 1832. "The facts we collected seemed to me to be terrible, almost beyond belief, Not in exceptional cases, but as a rule, children of ten years old worked regularly fourteen hours a day with but a half-hour interval for the mid- day meal, which was eaten in the factory. In the fine-yarn cotton mills they were subjected to this labor in a temperature usually exceeding 75 degrees. . . . . In some cases we found that greed of gain had impelled the mill owners to still greater extremes of inhumanity, utterly disgraceful indeed to a civil- ized nation. Their mills were run fifteen, and in exceptional cases sixteen, hours a day with a single set of hands, and they did not scruple to employ children of both sexes from the age of eight Most of the overseers openly carried stout leather thongs, and we frequently saw even the youngest children severely beaten In some of the factories from one-fourth -41- to one- fifth of the children were cripples or otherwise deformed or permanently injured by excessive toil, sometimes by brutal abuse." ( 71 ) The Niles Register for April 21, 1832, commenting on the condition of the working class, says: "We have several times alluded to the amount of wages paid in England and severely rebuked a disposition maintained by some to reduce the working people of the United States to the same horrible conditions." (72) Extracts from the Manchester advertiser afforded some idea of the price of labor in the neighborhood of Manchester. A man with his wife and two children in that district was earning 9 s, lOg- d per week; another man with a family of nine workers was cited who collectively earned 20 s per week. While it is pointed out that wages may not have been quite so low in the woolen manufactur- ing districts, the supposition, it affirms, is that there was little difference in the laborers’ circumstances. (73) Webb says that in 1831 the boys in the Northumberland nines who were paid by the day were kept at work from fourteen to seventeen hours a day. The hewers, however, paid by the ton had restricted theirs to ten or twelve hours each. By 1837 "the ten hour day was becoming generally established. Over time, however, was common, and half holidays on Saturday was unknown. So far as the money wage is concerned, conditions on the Continent seem to have been even worse. "In Saxony a man employed at his own loom work- ing diligently from Monday morning until Saturday night, from five o'clock in the morning until dusk and even at times with a lamp, his wife assisting him in finishing and taking the work, could not possibly earn more than about sixty cents per week, nor could one who had three children aged twelve and upwards, all working at the loom as well as himself, and his wife employed in doing up the work, earn more than $1.00 weekly. (74) A wider view of the general wage level of foreign countries in 42- 1843 may be gotten from the following statistics on the wages of common laborers. France Germany . . . 4& - 8 II II North Italy . » , ...3-4 VI If Italy It II England ...9-15 II If Scotland ... 8 •1 It Ireland ....... ...4-6 II II Russia ....... ...3-5 H tl Spain , . . ... 3-6 II II Portugal . . . . . tl It Norway ...3-5 If If Sweden ........ ...2-5 19 II Engel in his description of the working class in England in 1844 depicts a depth of misery that is widespread and certainly beyond anything that America ever experienced. Bowley in a more scientific treatment of wages in the United Kingdom says, "The study of the period from 1830 to i860 has been much neglected. In its wages, the cotton industry increased about two shillings on ten, although there was a falling off until 1845-8. Building and town arti- sans did not improve their earnings by so large a percentage. The wages of sea- men increased over ten percent between 1840 and i860, but the percent of in- crease between I 83 O and 1840 cannot be accurately measured except for one part, when it appears to have been stationary. Compositors' wages in small towns in- creased rapidly but in large towns were stationary, and the average increase was ten percent; those of agricultural laborers increased from 10 s to 11 s 7 d, and miners' diminished." ( 78 ) Fragmentary as are the data available, it seems safe to conclude that neither in money nor in real wages did England or any continental country keep pace with the upward movement of the wage level that characterized the whole of the period in America, and never at any time during the period was the condition of the laboring classes in America so miserable as at various times and places in Europe. The claim that the public lands are responsible for the I I < i i 1 f -43- v/hole of the variation in favor of the country where they existed, could not perhaps be easily substantiated. That they played some part, however, certainly no one will attempt to deny. In conclusion then it seems that one might safely say that the assertions as to the relation which exists between abundant land and the wel- fare of laboring classes, quoted in the beginning of the thesis, are on the whole true. In the period from I83O to i860 the public lands certainly exerted an uplifting influence on laboring conditions in America, functioning not how- ever as a safety valve in that the moment depression was felt or industrial conditions became oppressive, escape was made to the "wilderness , " the impres- sion which writers, as has been observed, often tend to convey. The coordina- tion of those physical, political and psychic conditions which would be neces- sary for such deft manipulation of population, seems scarcely probable under any circumstance. That it did not exist in the United States was evidenced in the fact that poverty and unemployment became serious problems at intervals during the period from I83O to i860, and by the further fact that population movement failed to synchronize in any definite fashion with these periods of depression. It was not the immediate or periodic effect but rather the long time effect of the public lands that deserve most recognition. Absorbing, as they did in a more or less regular and gradual manner, the redundant population of the industrial sections, they created a general condition of supply of labor that gave the wage level an upward tendency and without doubt was in a large measure responsible for the fact that the scale of wages which then prevailed was the highest in the world. -44- REFERENCES 1. Annals of the Fourth Congress, First Session, page 12. 2. Progress and Poverty, page 260. 3. Callender, Economic History of the U. S. 4. Annals of Congress, reprinted in Bogart and Thompson Readings in Economic History, page 455. 5. J. R. Commons, History of Labor in the U. S. Vol. 1, page 4. 6. Hart, History of the U. S. Vol. 14, page 68. 7. McMaster, History of the U. S. Vol. 5, page 121. 8. Documentary History of the American Industrial Society. Vol. 1, page 170. 9. Commons, History of Labor in the United States. Vol. 1, page 384. 10. Documentary History of the American Industrial Society. Vol. 5, page 33. 11. Montgomery, Cotton Manufacture in Great Britain and America. 12. McMaster, History of the U. s . , Vol. 8, p ages 98-99 13. McMaster, History of the u. s., Vol. 8, page 104. 14. McMaster, His to ry of the u. s . , Vol. 8, page 107. 15. Callender, Economic History of the U. S., page 716. 16. Roosevelt, Winning of the West. Vol. 3, page 4. 17. Callender, Economic History of the U. S., ; page 605. 18. Callender, Economic History of the U. S., page 655. 19. Callender, Economic History of the U. S., page 637. 20. Channing, History of the U. S. Vol. 5, page 106. 21. Turner, Rise of the New West. 22. McMaster, history of the U. S. Vol. 3, page 463 . 23. Bogart and Thompson, Readings in Economic History, page 399. 24. Turner, Ri3e of the New West, page 82. -45- 25. Johnson, History of Domestic and Foreign Commerce. Vol. 1, page 206. 26. Channing, History of the U. S. Vol. b, page 106. 27. Johnson, History of Domestic and Foreign Commerce. Vol. 1, page 218. 28. Roosevelt, Winning of the West. Vol. 1, page 121. 29. McGill, History of Transportation in the U. S., page 16. 30. Gallatin, Adams Edition, pages 334-5. 31. Johnson, History of Domestic and Foreign Commerce. Vol. 1, page 220. 32. Turner, Rise of the New West, pages 34-97. 33. Johnson, History of Domestic and Foreign Commerce. Vol. 1, pages 221-2. 34. Dunbar, History of Travel in America. Vol. 2, page 656 . 35. Sato, Land' Question in the U. S., page 138. 36. Hinsdale, The Old North-West, page 255. 37. Treat, The National Land System, page 16. 38. Cutler, Vol. 1, page 133. 39. State Papers, Public Domain, page 888. 40. Hinsdale, The Old North-West, page 301. 41. Sato, The Land Question in the U. S., page 138. 42. Treat, The National Land System, page 375. 43. Laws of the U. S., Vol. 2, page 533 . 44. The Land Question in the U. S., page 143. 4b. Treat, The National Land System, page 379* 46. State Papers, Public Lands, Vol. 2. 47. U. S. Statutes. Vol. 3, page 866. 48. The Land Question in the U. S., page 199. 49. Stephenson, Political History of the Public Lands. bO. Sato, The Land Question in the U. S., page 159. 51. Sato, The Land Question in the U. S., page 120. t -46- 52. Treat, The National Land System, page 372. 53. Hunt's Merchants' Magazine. Vol. 2, page 119. 54. Chicago Tribune, Feb. 3, 1859. 55. Stephenson, Political History of the Public Lands, page 101. 56. New York Tribune, July 17, 1847. 57. Stephenson, Political History of the Public Lands, page 99. 58. Wellington, Political History of the Public Lands, page 6. 59. Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Vol. 6, page 35. 60. Ely, Labor Movement in America, page 41. 61. Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Vol. 6, page 207, 62. Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Vol. 7, page 33. 63. Stephenson, Political History of the Public Lands, page 113. 64. Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Vol. 7, page 305, 65. Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Vol. 8, page 21. 66. Stephenson, Political History of the Public Lands, page 113. 67. Wellington, Political Influence of the Public Lands, page 10. 68. Carleton, History and Problems of Organized Labor, Chapter III. 69. Wright, History of Wages and Prices, page 308. 70. Wright, History of Wages and Prices, page 29. 71. Young, Labor in Europe and America. 72. Niles Register, April 21, 1832. 73. Webb, Labor in the Longest Reign. 74. Niles Register, Jan. 25, 1842. 75. Niles Register, Nov. 11, 1843. 76. Eowley, Wages in the United Kingdom, page 125. -47- BIBLIOGRAPHY Adams, T. S., and Sumner, Helen L. Labor Problems New York The MacMillan Co., 1S14 American State Papers Public Lands Annals of Congress Fourth Congress, First Session Bo gart , E . L. . Economic History of the U. S. New York Longmans, Green & Co., 1912 Bogart E. L., and Thompson, C. M. Readings in the Economic History of the U. S. New York Longmans, Green & Co . , 1916 Bowley, Arthur L. Wages in the United Kingdom Cambridge, the U. press, 1900 Callender, G. S. Selections from the Economic History of the U. S. Bo ston Ginn and Co., 1909 Carlton, F. T. The History and Problems of Organized Labor Bo ston D. C. Heath & Co . , 1911 Carlton, F. T. Organized Labor in American History -46- Channing A History of the U. S. New York The MacMillan Co., 1905 Coman, Katherine Industrial History of the U. S. Chicago B. H. Sanborn & Co., 1917 Commons, J. R., and Sumner, Helen Documentary History of the American Industrial Society Cleveland A. H. Clark & Co., 1910 Commons, J. R. History of Labor in the U. S. New York The MacMillan Co., 1918 Donaldson The Public Domain, its History and Statistics Washington U. S. Land Com., 1884 Dunbar, Seymour A History of Travel in America Indianapolis The Bobbs Merrill Co. Ely, R. T. The Labor Movement in America New York T. Y. Crowell Co. Engels, F. Condition of the Working Class in England in 1844 London Swan Sonnenschein and Co., 1892 -49- Flint, Timothy Recollections of the Last Ten Years Boston Cummings, Hilliard and Co., 1826 Flint, Timothy History and Geography of the Mississippi Valley 1832 Gallager, W. D. Facts and Conditions of Progress in the North West Cincinnati H. W. Derby & Co.,. 1850 George, Henry Progress and Poverty New York Doubleday, Page & Co . , 1879 Hall, James Statistics of the West Cincinnati, 1837 Hart, A. B. The American History New York Harper & Bros., 1904-8 Hildreth history of the U. S. of A. New York Harper Bros., 1852 Hinsdale The Old North West New York Townsend Mac Coun, 1888 Hunt's Merchants' Magazine * - - i . . . ■ -50- Johnson, E. R. History of Domestic and Foreign Commerce of the U. S. Washington The Carnegie Institution, 1915 Luther, Seth An Address to the Workmen of New England Philadelphia, 1833 Laws of the U. S. Vol . 2 McMaster, J. B. A History of the People of the U. S. New York D. Appleton & Co., 1913 MacGill History of Transportation in the U. S. before 1860 Washington Carnegie Institution, 1917 Martineau, Harriet Society in America Saunders and Otley, 1837 Montgomery, James The Practical Details of Cotton Manufacture in the U. S. Glasgow Jno. Nevin Jr., 1840 Myers, Gustavus History of Tammany Hall New York Author, 1901 New York Tribune Niles Register -51- North American Review Peck, J. M. A New Guide for Emigrants to the West Boston, 1836 Pelzer, L. The Public Domain as a Field for Historical Study Iowa State Historical Society, 1914 Poor, H. V. Manual of Railroads Roosevelt, Theodore The Winning of the West New York G. P. Putnam’s Sons, 1889-96 Sato, Shosuke History of the Land Question in the U. S. Publication Agency of Johns Hopkins U., 1886 Stephenson, G. M. The Political History of the Public Lands from 1840 - 1862 Boston Richard G. Badger, 1917 St. Anthony Express (Minn.) Thompson, C. M. History of the U. S. Chicago Benj. H. Sanborn & Co . , 1917 Thv/aite, R. G. Early Western Travels Cleveland A. H. Clark, Co. -52- Treat, P. J. The National Land System New York E. B. Treat & Co., 1910 Trollope North America Leipzig Eernard Tauchnitz, 1862 Turner, F. J. The Frontier in American History New York Holt & Co., 1921 Turner, F. J. Rise of the New West New York Harper & Bros., 1906 U. S. Census Reports U. S. Statistics, Vol. 3 Webb, Sidney Labor in the Longest Reign London G. Richards, 1879 Wellington, R. G. Political and Sectional Influence of the Public Lands Riverside Press, 1914 Wright, C. D. History of Wages and Prices 1752-1860 Bo ston Wright & Potter Co., 1885 Young, Edward Labor in Europe and America Philadelphia Edw. Young, 1875