RAILWAY FREIGHT RATES THE LEGAL, ECONOMIC, AND ACCOUNTING PRINCI- PLES INVOLVEli/^i^ 'WfifRffjiifa'f^lIj^AL, DETERMINATION. MAURICE H. ROBINSON of the University of Illinois Yale Economic Papers The Yale Publishing Association, 135 Elm Street, New Haven, Conn. This article is reprinted from the Yale Review, a Journal for the Scientific Discussion of Economic, Political and Social Questions. Published Quarterly by the Yale Publishing Association, New Haven, Conn. Antiual Subscriptions Three Dollars. Extra copies of this reprint, ten cents each. OAK ST. HD^'^ ^ ^ "^ UNIVERSITY OF HLWOIS UBRAITir o u. -f OCT 3. 1916 P o f* RAILWAY FREIGHT RATES. The Legal, Economic, and Accounting Principles Involved in their Judicial Determination. CONTENTS. Economic importance of freight rates, p. i ; nature and effects of rates based upon what the traffic will bear, p. 6 ; the cost of the service principle, p. 8 ; legal principle governing freight rates, p. lo ; general accounting principles involved, p. ii ; earlier methods adopted by the Interstate Com- merce Commission, p. I2 ; tendency towards use of the cost of the service principle by the Interstate Commerce Commission, p. i6; cost of the ser- vice principle as applied in the Spokane case, p. i8 ; the cost of the service principle as inaugurated and used by the Wisconsin Railroad Commission, p. 21 ; the Talcott method of cost accounting, p. 29 ; comparison of the Wis- consin and Talcott methods, p. 31 ; the universal freight unit method, p. 32; the cost of the service the ultimate basis toward which freight rates are tend- ing, p. 32. I. A S compared with the passenger service, the work of the -^"^ freight department of a railroad is not only much more important, from the economic point of view, but it is also of such exceeding complexity in its operations as almost to defy the skill of the highest accounting talent adequately to present those opera- tions in the form of accounts. As stated in a previous article,^ in their passenger service the railroads are able to depart from the equal mileage principle in so few cases that questions connected with discrimination between passengers very seldom arise. Pas- senger rates may be fixed too high as a whole to meet the existing legal and economic conditions, but only in extraordinary cases is there likely to be discrimination between individuals, classes, or localities. Freight rates, on the other hand, may be in some cases higher than economic conditions justify, and yet too low in all other cases, thus bringing about a condition where, even while charging too high rates in certain instances, the railroad is financially ruined. The reason for this peculiar situation lies in 'Yale Review, February, 1908. 2 Yale Review. the nature of the business and in the conditions under which it is conducted. In the first place, competition between railroads for the freight business available varies from the phase of the keenest rivalry to that of complete monopoly. Even under the usual economic conditions, therefore, freight rates vary from a figure barely sufficient to cover the actual cost of moving the goods to one under which quite unusual profits are returned to the railway stockholders. Industries located at competing points enjoy an advantage over those located at non-competing points which is equal to the difference in rates. When competition between the various manufacturing establishments becomes keen and active, those located at non-competing points are necessarily bankrupted unless they are able to secure reductions from the railroads suffi- cient to counterbalance their economic disadvantages. The very existence of any unfortunately situated industrial establishment is thus at the mercy of the railway officials. Where this power is exercised with discretion and sympathy, no serious economic harm is likely to follow; but the danger that it may be used wantonly, or in a spirit of ignorance or revenge, is so great that some control over rates is uniformly entrusted to the public authorities.^ In the second place, certain shippers of freight are absolutely dependent upon the railways for the transportation of their goods, while others are in a position to provide means for carrying their own products whenever rates are advanced much above the average cost of transportation. The shippers in the first-named class, comprising all small manufacturers and all of the com- mercial classes, must in general pay the rates made by the rail- roads or go out of business.^ So long as the rates actually in '"Railway officials free from restrictions could make or unmake mining and manufacturing concerns in those days [1860-1880] and could do so still had we not at last a court of appeal and laws against obvious discriminations. "The Interstate Commerce Commission is to become one of our greatest safeguards." — Andrew Carnegie in "My Experience with Railway Rates and Rebates." Century Magazine, March, 1908. • It is, of course, conceivable that every community might become self- supporting, manufacturing its own goods from materials grown on near-by farms or taken from local mines and forests, and transporting the same with its own teams. Such a condition, while conceivable, is, of course, not possible so long as railroads exist. Railway Freight Rates. 3 force permit business to be carried on even at a small profit, there remains an economic incentive for men to engage in such under- takings, although, of course, free capital will gravitate toward those industries where there is opportunity for self -protection through the establishment of direct transportation facilities. Rates cannot, therefore, be profitably carried above what the traffic is able to bear and still continue to maintain itself in a fairly prosperous condition. Shippers in the second class possess, however, a tremendous advantage over those of the first class when dealing with the question of railway rates. Carnegie used this power with telling effect in making terms with the Pennsyl- vania Railroad for the shipment of iron and steel products from the Pittsburg district to the Atlantic coast.* The Steel Corpora- tion has followed out the policy originated by Carnegie, until at the present time it owns and operates an extensive system of railways and steamship lines, rendering it practically independent of all outside facilities in the transportation of its ore and coal from the mines to the mills.^ The Standard Oil Company adopted the same policy in its early history, through the purchase and construction of pipe lines for the transportation of oil*; it has also an extensive fleet of ocean steamers especially con- structed for the transportation of oil to foreign countries. It has thus been able to secure railway and ocean rates at all times and between all places at about the actual cost of the service to the transportation companies. The same principle has been applied in many other lines, and always for the same purpose and with the same results : the anthracite tide-water canals were projected and developed to secure low cost transportation for coal to the factory towns'^; and in more recent years a large number of railways* have been built by manufacturing, mining, and lumbering com- panies, partly at least, for protective purposes. * Carnegie, "My Experience," etc. 'U. S. Steel Corporation, "Annual Report," 1908. 'Report of Commissioner of Corporations on the Petroleum Industry, Part I, pp. 51, 122. ^ Jones, "The Economic History of the Anthracite Tide Water Canals." 'Senate Document No. 37, 6ist Congress, ist session, decision of the Supreme Court in the Interstate Commodities clause. A Yale Review. In the third place, the cost of transporting freight in its various forms and under the many different conditions under which it is offered for shipment has never been worked out in a satisfactory way by railway officials. Rates are made not on the cost of transportation, but on the principle known as "what the traffic will bear." Since some commodities will not be shipped at all except at a very low rate, and since at a low rate their returns more than cover the known direct expenses incurred on account of such shipments, rates are made in such cases far below the average rate. Other commodities move freely and in large quantities at a relatively higher rate, and as a consequence higher rates are maintained by the railroad companies. Rates are there- fore generally made on the basis of benefits conferred rather than on the cost of the service. Traffic officials watching the flow of various classes of commodities under changing rates, become experimental philosophers of no mean ability in dealing with the economic life blood of the nation. As railways give more atten- tion to cost-accounting in its application to various classes of freight, many of the lowest rates are absolutely sure to be raised and some of those relatively high will undoubtedly be lowered; this in itself will bring about greater uniformity in the burden imposed by freight transportation upon the commodities which it moves. In the fourth place, even though all the railroads were consoli- dated into one system, even though the science of accounting were fully developed in its application to the railway service, and even though shippers had no way of securing transportation except by means of the railways, certain rates would yet be much lower than the average and others much higher ; — the result being discrimination between persons, places, and commodities even where the conditions under which the service is undertaken are substantially similar from the railway standpoint. This state of affairs is the result of the unequal ability of such persons, places, and commodities to pay railway charges, and of the effort of the railways to secure from each all the traffic is able to bear. To illustrate : the cost of raising wheat, omitting from consideration for the moment the rent of the land, varies somewhat at points in the wheat lands of Manitoba, the Dakotas, Kansas, and Railway Freight Rates. 5 Oklahoma. The selHng price in the central market of Chicago is, owing to the presence of active competition, the same for the same grade of wheat. Assuming that the cost of transporting the wheat to the market from each of these fields is practically- identical, the lands where the cost of raising wheat is lowest will increase in value up to a point where the earnings to the wheat farmers becomes practically equal so long as the railways charge rates that are based upon the cost of the service. The railways, however, discovering that the cost of raising wheat is low in certain districts and that therefore the farmers in that locality are able to pay a higher rate, establish and maintain rates consider- ably higher for this locality than for those where the cost of raising the wheat is higher. Such a system would, of course, if carried out universally, completely nullify the economic rent of land so far as the farmers are concerned and convert it into an added profit for the railway service. Again, the cost of manufacturing articles of the same character varies considerably at different points in the United States. When the transportation rates on such goods are on the same basis, the manufacturers at the points most favorably situated earn a higher rate of return on their actual investment. Manu- facturers located at such points can pay a higher rate of trans- portation and still maintain their position in competition with less favorably situated competitors. The railways, by adopting the principle of charging what the traffic will bear, are able to take from the better situated manufacturers the larger part of this advantage, thus reducing all competing manufacturers in the same line to a common plane of profits. The same principle will apply, of course, to competing merchants. Thus the railways, by eliminating competition between themselves, are in an economic position to depart from the cost of the service principle ; they can adopt and enforce that of charging what the traffic will bear and thus absorb all differential profits that arise from superior loca- tion and superior business management in every domain of busi- ness activity. Yale Review. II. The freight service ought as a matter of economic poHcy to be self-supporting, and accordingly the railways should make their freight rates sufficiently high to secure that end. In view of the economic conditions described in the preceding section, it is evident that this result may be secured by charging compara- tively high rates in certain cases and comparatively low rates in others, or by charging an average rate based upon the cost of the service sufficient to pay operating expenses and yield in addition a fair rate of return upon the investment. In the first case the railways adopt and enforce the policy of rate- making known as "charging what the traffic will bear," so ably set forth by Hadley^ in this country and Acworth^^ in England. From the commercial point of view, this system of rate-making is an application of the ordinary principles of taxation, enforced through a quasi-public institution with private parties^ ^ as the beneficiaries. From the standpoint of accountancy, this method involves, theoretically at least, the separation of railway transpor- tation expenses into two distinct categories, viz., operating expenses and fixed charges. In the determination of any specific rate, the railway first finds the actual cost attributable to this particular shipment, and then adds whatever in its judgment such traffic is able to bear as a contribution toward the general expenses. The second portion of the charge is the tax element. In certain cases the tax is light, in others heavy : the combination of operating expenses plus a light tax makes a low rate ; that of operating expenses plus a heavy tax, a high rate. This system not only has the weight of years of successful experience behind it, but has also been approved by many of the ablest students of economic progress. Nevertheless, the economic unrest, as evidenced by interminable litigation over railroad rates in the States and in the Nation, indicates that the system is open to certain fundamental objections. These may be stated as follows : First : The system subsidizes certain industries, and industries located in certain districts, while taxing other industries and •Hadley, "Railroad Transportation," Chapter VI. "Acworth, "Railway Economics," Chapters VIII-XI. " Where railways are privately owned. Railway Freight Rates, 7 other localities; and so the subsidized industries and localities are stimulated into an abnormal growth while those not so favored are unduly checked. Since the subsidized industries are those in which the prices are relatively low, a country is thus encouraged to use more of the goods which it needs less because its wants are more fully satisfied, and less of those which are in greater demand. On the other hand, rates are made low to pro- ducers in localities where the cost of production is already above the average and high where the cost of production is low. The normal tendency to concentrate production in those localities which are most highly favored by nature is checked, and the result is a somewhat higher average cost of production than would have been in evidence had the railways based the rates in each and every case upon the cost of the service. The result of the policy of charging what the traffic will bear, even when applied with the highest type of wisdom and discretion, is thus : (i) to prevent the normal increase in the production of those commodities for which the community has the most urgent need ; and (2) to thwart the natural tendency to concentrate produc- tion in those localities where the cost of production is lowest, and so to maintain a higher cost of production than otherwise would have resulted. Evidently misdirected production and unsatisfied wants are the natural results of the system. Second : Owing to the inherent difficulties experienced in determining what the traffic will bear, errors of judgment, ignor- ance, and actual fraud so warp and distort the system that the beneficent results conceived in theory are never realized in actual practice. Rates fixed above what the traffic will bear not only dwarf the industrial development in particular lines and bar the consumers from the normal satisfaction of their wants, but at the same time make it impossible for the railway to earn a reasonable return upon its capital. On the other hand, rates fixed below what the traffic will bear have the same effect upon the earnings while directing the industrial activities of the country into lines of development where the social benefits are likely to be diminished. Moreover, since the power to tax is the power to destroy, the rail- ways may not only prevent the development of new industries and new territory, but — what is of more importance — they may 8 Yale Review. actually destroy industries already in existence. Of course it must be conceded that even if they had the liberty to do so, the railways would not consciously check the general industrial development of the country they serve. Most railways, however, serve many industries and many distinct geographical districts, and it is a well-known fact that in the exercise of the rate-making power they have abnormally stimulated the growth of certain industries and localities and at the same time have dwarfed, if not entirely destroyed, others. Fortunately the system has never existed in any complete form, except as a theoretical figment, owing to the combined influence of competing railways, com- peting centers of production, competing markets and the activities of State and national commissions and courts. With the rail- roads of a country completely consolidated and left free to make and enforce rates without public regulation of any sort, the real significance of the system would be felt and appreciated.^^ In the second case, the railways adopt the cost of the service principle as the basis of the rates. Such a system preserves to every locality the natural advantages of its position, to every entrepreneur the results of his skill in management, and to laborers the most favorable conditions for work and wages. Its rigorous application in all cases and under all circumstances is of course impossible and would not be economically desirable if possible. It may with beneficial results be modified in favor of existing establishments when the onward march of industrial development would otherwise ruthlessly apply the issue of the survival of the fittest to the existing manufacturing plants ; it may also be modified with equally good results for the sake of hasten- ing the occupancy of new agricultural land or outlying suburban districts, and so of effecting a more equal distribution of the popu- lation, preventing congestion and thus modifying to a slight extent " From the economic point of view the system of charging what the traffic will bear resembles in many respects the protective tariff system. In each case the natural development of the country affected is prevented and an artificial development is promoted and fostered. In the one case the develop- ment is shaped to augment railway revenues; in the other, to foster the protected industries. In both cases the public suffers for the benefit of private interests. Under one condition alone can either system be justified from the purely economic point of view, and that condition involves the fixing of the rates or duties by an all-wise Providence. Railway Freight Rates. 9 the rigorous application of the law of rent. But these exceptions are, on the whole, of small importance when wide territorial areas and long periods of time are taken into consideration. The indus- trial world is at best full of uncertainties, and whatever tends to increase the risks that must be borne checks the normal industrial development. The cost of railway transportation varies very little from year to year and from place to place under similar conditions ; "what the traffic will bear" varies much more widely; and therefore the former system ensures business stability while the latter tends to make business even more risky than would otherwise be the case. That the cost of the service principle as a basis of railway rates is neither the dream of a closet philosopher nor the ideal for a future economic society may be seen from an examination of the rate question in trunk line territory.^^ After years of experience with the principle of "what the traffic will bear," as it must of necessity be applied under competitive railway conditions, the trunk line railways, occupying the territory north of the Ohio and east of the Mis- sissippi,^'* adopted in 1876 what is essentially a cost of the service system of rates. The economic benefits of this system, as modi- fied in 1879, are too well known to need examination in this paper; its defects as actually adopted are connected with viola- tions of the cost of the service principle, due to water transporta- tion and the influence of western and southern lines, rather than to the system itself. The cost of the service principle is thus not only in accordance with economic principles, but has been some- what imperfectly applied on a large scale with the most gratifying results. The legal principles governing the regulation of railway rates were in a general way discussed in the preceding article^^ on pas- senger rates. Under our system of dual control, the Federal Government has supervision, so far as supervision is entrusted to any government, over interstate railway traffic, while the several State governments have control over the intrastate business. By the Fifth Amendment to the Constitution, the railways are, it is "Ripley, "The Trunk Line Rate System: A Distance Tariff." Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XX, 1906, p. 183-210. "With the exception of the larger part of Wisconsin and Minnesota. " Yale Review, February, 1908. '** Yale Review. thought, amply protected from the power of the Federal Govern- ment should it attempt to force interstate rates below a point where that part of their business would yield a reasonable return upon the mvestment devoted to this class of traffic The Four teenth Amendment, on the other hand, forbids the State govern- Zm T; ''''"''"^ "■"'' '° '°^ "'^' "^^ P"^^'y State business would fa,l to earn a normal rate of interest and profits upon the State mvestment. Whether the governments. State and Federal may reduce rates between particular points on certain articles o; certam classes of articles below the general level of rates, so long questL "'"T r ' T'"'' " P^'^'^"^' '^ ^' y^' - ""-"lef question. Such a pohcy would result in rate discrimination by act of the government, not only between commodities but between Peaces wherever commodities so discriminated between are h'^r ...'"'"'"' '°^^"""- S'"'^^ discriminations are for- b^den by the interstate commerce act for interstate traffic and by Z f theT °1''^\''^"^^ f- '"'-^'^'e traffic, it may be assumed that .f he law be mterpreted in the spirit in which it was enacted without regard to existing industrial and commercial conditions such commodity discriminations would not be sanctioned by"S the State legislatures is one based upon the cost of the service one in which each class of traffic pays its own charges; wTere there are no favored classes of commodities or localitie^ on the one hand, and no parasites on the other. III. r.TT.7 '^''' '"'''' "P°" '"^ '^"'^°'' i" proportion to the cost of the service are, we have seen, not only in accord with tie gneral principles of economic policy, but are also in conf^ •; with the spint of the law of the land. Federal as well as State ifneTeX'^r ^"^ '" '" ^ ''""'' "^^ '^^" '" '»- '" ^^ esults °7an^' I ^™"'"°" """ '"'"' ^'^'=^"^"' -^onomic of t Iffi. ^PP'"^^"on to particular cases, or to particular classes of traffic m any exact scientific way, presents so many serious R^rr;;,. """"•' '^' "'""■• '^■- ^""= "■ «■ * o. r. cc, s i. c. c. Railway Freight Rates. il difficulties from the accounting standpoint, that our courts and commissions have quite generally avoided any reference to the system. As shown in the article on railway passenger rates,^'^ the following steps are necessary to its successful use in connec- tion with any specific rate: (i) the valuation of the railway investment as a whole and the further division of such valuation by classes of services undertaken ; (2) the fixing of a proper rate of return upon such valuations; (3) the actual separation of all receipts and expenses by classes of operations, and the apportion- ment of joint expenses to the same classes in accordance with the standards of cost accountancy. In the article above referred to, the principles governing the separation of freight and passenger receipts were discussed at some length. As a result of this process of separation, the accounts of the freight department of a railway are isolated from the accounts of all other departments and may therefore be treated exactly as though the railway were devoted exclusively to the business of transporting freight. Owing to the division of powers between the State and Federal governments, a second separation must be made, viz., the accounts for the intrastate freight traffic must be separated from those for the interstate business. As a result of this second step, the financial affairs of the freight department are divided into two sections, each of which must again be treated as the accounts of an entirely distinct railway company. The problem in accountancy which must now be solved, if we are to make practical use of the cost of the service principle in the determination of a particular rate, may be stated as follows: given (i) a railroad within the exclusive jurisdiction of a government having authority within constitutional limits over its service and rates; (2) a system of rates built up under semi-competitive and semi-monopolistic conditions and there- fore constructed so far as possible upon the principle of charging what the traffic will bear; and (3) a specific industrial establish- ment or locality entering, through its chosen representative, a complaint before the proper tribunal of such government, charg- ing that the rates upon the commodities in which they are particu- larly interested are either extortionate (that is, unreasonably high " Yale Review, February, 1908. 12 Yale Review. in themselves), or discriminatory (that is, higher than other industries under similar operating conditions are charged by the same or other railway companies) : state the accountancy prin- ciples which, if properly applied to the case in question, will deter- mine whether the authorities may properly order a reduction of rates or whether the existing rates are reasonable and fair. (i) The principles upon which such cases have quite generally been decided in the past have no connection with the practice of accountancy. In other words, the commissions and courts have not, except in the most cursory way, considered the revenue and expenditures caused by the traffic when rates are before them for judicial determination. Usually cases are decided by comparing the rates upon the specific commodity over the particular railway line in question with the rates charged by the same or other railways upon similar goods under somewhat similar circumstances. If the conditions are dissimilar — owing either to traffic or operation, or to the competition of rival rail- ways'^ or water routes'^ — the railway rates are allowed to differ as much as in the judgment of the public authorities seems proper. Thus a low volume of traffic per mile of line, unfavorable operating conditions such as grades and curvatures, the absence of competition from other railways or means of water transporta- tion, are generally held to justify somewhat higher rates than are permitted when the conditions are the reverse. The assump- tion is that light traffic means a higher cost of transportation; and it is of course true that unfavorable operating conditions necessitate a higher cost of transportation per ton-mile, since the two methods of expression are practically synonymous. It is one of the functions of railway accountancy to determine the actual cost of transporting goods under dissimilar conditions of traffic, equipment, and roadway ; the railways are making more and more use of the accounts for this purpose, both in self-pro- tection and for assistance in the wise administration of the work. And yet until within the last two years, one may search among the opinions of the Interstate Commerce Commission and the several State- commissions in vain for even a casual reference to "I. C. C. vs. Alabama Midland Ry. Co., i68 U. S., 144. "The Chattanooga Case, I. C. C. Reports, X, p. in. Railway Freight Rates. 13 this fundamental principle in connection with the judicial deter- mination of cases of the most vital importance to the railways and their patrons. The commissions seem to have invented and applied in many cases a new principle of rate-making which for want of a better name may be designated "What the railway officials will bear." In other cases they have acted as a board of arbitration between the railways and the shippers.^® The orders made often have the appearance of a compromise, without any adequate investigation into the merits of the case. The remark of Commissioner Prouty in the Danville, Va., case is an excellent illustration of the views of the various commissions when dealing with important rate questions : "It is impossible to apply to the solution any definite rule. Each case has to be considered upon its own peculiar facts. It is difficult in every case to determine what ought to be done in justice to the public and to the carrier, and it is even more difficult to state the reasons for that deter- mination."^^ (2) By the Hepburn amendment to the Interstate Commerce Act the Commission was, in addition to its former powers, authorized and empowered to prescribe a system of accounts, and upon complaint and after a hearing, to establish a maximum rate which it should be lawful thereafter for the railways to charge. In accordance with the first provision the Commission, under the immediate direction of Professor Henry C. Adams and with the active cooperation of the American Railway Association and the Association of American Railway Accountants, has prescribed a system of accounts giving in detail the classification of operating expenses, revenues and expenditures for road and equipment, and also locomotive miles, car miles, and train miles. This system of accounting is exceedingly well adapted to the purpose which the Commission apparently had in mind, i. e., the comparison of expenses and revenues of the same general nature on the various lines of railways in the United States. It is not, however, partic- ularly well adapted to finding the cost of the service ; thus while "Prouty, a commissioner, observed in one case: "Probably the true solu- tion of this controversy is to be found in a mesne between the contentions of the two parties," thus virtually assuming that both must be wrong. I. C. C. Reports, VII, p. 458. " I. C. C. Reports, VIII, p. 409-442. 14 Yale Review. passenger and freight revenue is kept separate, there is no particular attempt made to keep the expenses of these depart- ments separate according to sources. Moreover, no consideration is given to the problems of fundamental importance in determin- ing the cost of passenger or freight traffic or classes of freight traffic, namely, how the common expenses shall be pro-rated between the several departments and how both the revenue and expenses shall be apportioned among States. Such being the case, it is perhaps hardly to be expected that the Interstate Com- merce Commission in determining the reasonableness of par- ticular rates should give much attention to the cost of the service. Notwithstanding this fact, it is desirable to examine briefly into the Commission's method of procedure when a cost method is absolutely necessary to make a decision anything more than a guess. The Commission has, on many occasions, asserted that "there is no standard by which either the cost of the service or the reasonableness of these rates can be fixed with any certainty. "^^ It has on several occasions stated that elaborate computations were offered in evidence by the railroads,^^ but it does not appear from an examination of the cases that the Commission has either scrutinized the correctness of the railroads' method of apportion- ment of common expenses or made any computations of this character for their own information. Indeed, the Commission apparently gives very little weight to such methods, and in one case distinctly rejects the cost of the service for any particular commodity as a just or proper basis of the reasonableness of the rate. 2* In fact, it has definitely stated that "where particular rates on a particular commodity between particular points are challenged, the question of net earnings on the particular lines involved is not so important unless it be shown that the margin •* The Creamery Cases, Opinion 969, I- C. C. Reports, p. 132 ; also Kindel vs. Express Company, April 14, 1908, p. 496; Opinion 698, p. 503; Opinion 760, p. 57; Opinion 809, p. 319; Opinion 874, p. 17. " Opinion 698, p. 53 ; Opinion 809, p. 319 et seq. "Opinion 874, p. '17. "To divide the system into its constituent elements and to require that each shall show a surplus commensurate with that yielded by the business of the system as a whole in justification of a particular rate on one commodity is not the usual, and it is not believed to be the proper, basis upon which to measure the justness of such rate." Railway Freight Rates. 15 of profit is so small on the system's business as a whole that a reduction in the particular rates would reduce the whole income below the reasonable profit point." In short, when the earnings are more than sufficient to pay a reasonable return upon the investment as a whole, the Commission will reduce any rate that seems to be out of harmony with the rate system in general with- out regard to the profitableness or unprofitableness of this particular class of traffic. This attitude of the Commission appar- ently explains the fact that almost without exception, when rate questions are involved, the Commission uses the comparative method of determining the proper rate. While the Commission gives great weight to the influence of competitive conditions in the adjustment of rates, it does not believe that, because low rates are brought about in' this way, high rates on other parts of a railroad are necessarily justified; nor is a high local rate approved because of a low proportional rate on shipments through the same point.^^ Again, the Com- mission will not accept it as conclusive argumentation that because rates are low over one line, they therefore ought to be low over every other line; nor does a voluntary reduction in rates prove that the former rates were unreasonably high. The Commission approves of the policy generally adopted by railroads of extend- ing the competitive area of manufacturers by making rates to distant points relatively lower than to near-by points^^ ; and within certain limitations the railroad may consider the conditions under which the industries on its line and in the same general territory with other industries are conducting their business.^^ The Com- mission also holds that it is proper to make rates in proportion to the value of the goods, giving low cost goods low rates and goods of higher commercial value higher rates ; it also expresses the opinion that the most satisfactory comparison available to ascertain whether a relative injustice is being done one section as against another or one commodity as against another, is through the earnings per car.^^ ** Opinion 874, p. 16. "Opinion 875, p. 24; Opinion 919, p. 203. *' Opinion 875, p. 24. "Opinion 895, p. 114. 1 6 Yale Review. Notwithstanding this evident disregard of the cost of the service principle, the Commission, since it was definitely empowered to fix rates, has been giving more attention to the cost of transportation, although in a very general way and with- out the application of scientific accounting principles. This movement has in some cases been introduced by the railroads in self-protection ; for example, when certain ice companies brought an action before the Commission to secure a reduction of rates on ice transported over the Erie and the Delaware, Lackawanna & Western from points in New York and Pennsylvania to the New York and Philadelphia markets, the railroads introduced accounts for the purpose of showing that this service was being conducted at only a little above its actual cost, and that therefore the reduc- tion of rates would cause an actual loss.^® The Erie Railroad Company presented data showing, according to their method of distributing expenses, that the cost of the ice service over a particular line for the season was as follows: maintenance of way, $3,000; maintenance of equipment, $7,000; transportation expenses, $5,000.^^ The Commission in examining this state- ment observed that, according to the figures presented by the Erie Railroad Company, the cost of the maintenance of way amounted to 20 per cent., maintenance of equipment to 46^ per cent, and transportation expenses to only 33 >^ per cent, as compared with 18 per cent., 29 per cent, and 48 per cent, for these items respec- tively for the whole railroad. The Commission held that the cost of maintenance of way in the ice service was fixed too high because it was computed upon a mileage basis while the trains were comparatively light and also since "this [expense] must have been incurred almost or quite in toto if this ice train had not run." The Commission also thought the cost of maintaining equipment higher than it ought to be on the ground that part of the expenses was estimated and the "basis of the estimate is mani- festly wrong"; it does not, however, state its reasons for so thinking. The Commission, therefore, concludes that the fair " Opinion 809, p. 316. "In addition to the above expenses there was a haul of over four miles from another branch line not included and the terminal expense at Jersey City was not stated. Railway Freight Rates. 17 cost of doing this business under normal conditions would not exceed $10,000, and therefore a small reduction in rates would not render the business unprofitable. The method used by the Lackawanna Railroad Company was somewhat more scientific. The actual movement expenses of a train of thirty cars, empty one way, was found for the round trip ; the "indirect line cost" per car was computed by distributing expenses between the passenger and freight departments, and then the average cost per ton-mile was calculated for the whole road. The cost of the ice business was then computed per car and an arbitrary added because the empty car movement was greater in this business than the average for the system. The terminal expenses were found by dividing the total freight terminal expenses by the number of cars handled. By this method the movement expenses were found to be $2.29 per car, indirect line expenses $9.63, indirect terminal expenses $7.28. To this was added the sum of $0.35 per car on account of the extraordinary cost of maintaining ice cars. The total cost per car for the round trip was thus found to be $19.55, while the revenue, $0.85 per ton, amounted to $22.95, leaving a profit per car of $3.40. The Commission rejected the cost accounting submitted by the Lackawanna Railroad Company chiefly on the ground that there is no warrant for the assump- tion that either the indirect line expense or the indirect terminal expense per car was as great as it was for the average traffic. "On what theory," it asks, "can it be assumed that the traffic shall pay in proportion to the number of tons exactly the same contribution to the fixed charges that all other traffic pays?" It therefore concluded that, since there was a wide margin between the movement cost of $19.55 P^^ car and the revenue $22.95 P^^ car, there was little doubt that the rates might be materially reduced and still leave a fair profit. In all of the cases decided by the Commission previous to February 9, 1909, even where the cost of the service was con- sidered, that factor was an unimportant element in its effect upon the decision. That is, the cases were decided with reference to the "general situation," taking into account all factors — the competition of railroads, of commodities, markets, etc., etc. In the Spokane case three questions were raised, namely : 1 8 Yale Review. First. Do the rates of the defendants unduly discriminate against Spokane in favor of coast points? This includes the further inquiry whether these rates are in violation of the fourth section. Second. Do the defendants improperly allow certain privileges to coast traffic which are denied Spokane, like the mixing of carloads, lighter minimimis, etc? Third. Are the rates applied by the defendants to Spokane inherently tmjust and imreasonable?*^ After a review of the facts and the law the Commission decided that in the first and second issues Spokane had no cause for complaint. The real question, it was stated, was as follows : Are the rates unjust and unreasonable in themselves under the first section of the act? In the determination of this question, the Commission accepted without discussion the general principle that a railroad is entitled to charge rates sufficiently high to enable it to earn a fair return upon its investment. In applying this principle to the case, two subsidiary questions of the greatest moment were immediately raised, viz.: (i) May the rates be reduced to a point where only that line whose lowest total operating cost is the lowest may earn a fair return upon its investment, or must the rates be sufficiently high so that the road least favorably situated may earn a living F^^ After citing the Charles River Bridge case and the Brunswick and Topsham Water cases and discussing their bearings upon this case, the Commission decided that regard must be had not altogether to any one particular railroad, but to the "whole situation, "^^ and therefore they considered the effect of their proposed order upon all the railroads directly interested. It was further inquired: (2) What is the value of the investments upon which the rail- roads are individually to be permitted to earn a fair return? After quoting in full the principles laid down by the court in " City of Spokane, et al. vs. N. P. Ry. Co. et al, I. C. C Reports, Opinion 820. " In this case, it was argued that the Northern Pacific was a more expen- sive road to build and operate than the Great Northern. Consequently, if rates were forced down to a point where the Great Northern could earn only a fair return upon its investment, the Northern Pacific, since it would have to observe the same rates of fare on its through business, would be bankrupted. Opinion 820, p. 391-2. "Opinion 820, p. .394. This opinion was in accordance with a previous opinion foimd in 9 I. C. C. Reports, p. 382. Railway Freight Rates. 19 Smith vs. Ames,'* it was stated that the Commission had certain information more or less complete on the following points : (a) an estimate of the cost of reproducing both the Northern Pacific and the Great Northern railways ; (b) some information as to the actual cost of each; (c) the present capitalization of each; and (d) the gross and net earnings for a series of years for both roads, together with the estimated reduction in the earnings for the same amount of traffic under the proposed rates. Each railroad submitted a detailed statement of the grading, tunnels, bridges, culverts, rails, ties, and the other items of con- struction, together with the amount of land used and the entire equipment ; and applying present day prices, it was found that the cost of the Northern Pacific and Great Northern was each approximately four hundred million dollars. These estimates were submitted to Mr. Gillette, the engineer of the Washington State Railway Commission, who reduced the cost of construction items by $69,ooo,cxx) for the Northern Pacific and by $80,000,000 for the Great Northern. The Commission, in reviewing these estimates, made the wise but somewhat trite observation that "as usual, the truth undoubtedly lies somewhere between these rather wide limits. "^'^ The Commission then reviewed the evidence submitted by the railroads showing the cost of original construction, but on examination of this evidence found that the books and records had been so inaccurately kept that no reliance could be given to this data. The capitalization, it was found, had little relationship to either cost or value, and this criterion was therefore abandoned as showing the value of the investment. Even in its attempts to find the earnings of the two railroads for a series of years, the Commission was far from successful. It was found that for the past ten years in the case of the Northern Pacific and since 1891 for the Great Northern, interest on all of the bonds issued and dividends on the stock had been regularly paid. In addition each railroad had accumulated in the form of surplus and permanent •* Smith vs. Ames, 169 U. S., 466. "Opinion 820, p. 396. 20 Yale Review. improvements taken from earnings over fifty million dollars.'® The statement of earnings as presented was further complicated by the fact that both the Great Northern and the Northern Pacific either directly or through subsidiary companies owned valuable coal and iron mines. In the case of the Northern Pacific, coal was sold both to the railroad company and to the public at a price which enabled the subsidiary company to pay interest upon its $7,cxx),ooo of bonds and a dividend of 629 per cent, upon its capital stock of $2,775,000, giving the Northern Pacific stock- holders an extra dividend of $11.26 per share.^'^ On the data substantially as presented in the brief outline given above, the Commission held that while it was both legally neces- sary and economically advisable to permit rates that would attract capital to invest in railway securities, both railroads had been earning at an excessive rate and therefore it was decided that a reduction of rates to Spokane should be ordered. To further substantiate its conclusions the Commission presented a number of tabulations showing the rates for similar commodities for approximately the same distances in other parts of the United States. The Commission, it should properly be added, appreciated the fact that its methods were unscientific and therefore unsatisfac- tory; it was stated at one point that "there is no absolute test of a reasonable rate and the government has supplied none."^^ It might have added with very great propriety the following pro- position, viz. : The Interstate Commerce Commission was created for the purpose of considering in a reasonable and intelligent way the very question which it here confessed had not yet been solved. It is to be hoped that following the inauguration of a systematic and comprehensive system of accounts for all the railroads in the United States, the Commission will give less attention to legal "•The data presented in the opinion of the Commission is so meager that it is impossible properly to interpret the actual conditions as to the net earnings of either road. It is, of course, necessary to present a balance sheet as well as a statement of earnings in order to determine the true financial status of a railroad company. In this case a very incomplete statement of earnings alone was presented by the Commission. " Opinion 820, p. 97. •• Opinion 820, p. 416. Railway Freight Rates. 21 precedent and more to the principles of economics and of account- ancy, and thus of its own motion inaugurate a reasonable test of a reasonable rate.^^ IV. The Wisconsin Railway Commission was the first to break away from the unscientific method which has been employed by the Interstate Commerce Commission since it began its work in 1887 and by all of the other State commissions. The Wisconsin Commission has therefore been obliged to blaze a new path through the wilderness of conflicting methods of accounting and of theories of railway rates. It fortunately began to apply its theories and methods in passenger rate cases where the condi- tions are simpler and where, therefore, the principles are more easily applied. Having begun thus fortunately, and also scien- tifically, and finding that it was possible to introduce system where chaos formerly reigned supreme, it was a foregone con- clusion that the Commission would make the attempt to introduce the same scientific methods into the determination of freight-rate cases. Indeed, in one of the first cases on freight rates which came before it for decision, the general principles upon which the Commission has since acted were stated as follows: "We think it a basic principle that all persons desiring to use the quasi public highways of our country should be accorded the privilege of doing so on payment of a reasonable compensation for the service performed and that no greater compensation should be exacted from one than from another for a like service. ... It seems to us to be alien to the purpose of a Public Service Corporation to refuse to abide by this principle and to dictate who shall and who shall not do business on its line of road."*® In its first attempts to apply these general principles to specific cases, the Railroad Commission of Wisconsin gave considerable attention to relative rates, making elaborate comparisons between **In a still later opinion, No. 874, rendered April 12, 1909, the Commission further considered the accounting problem involved in the determination of freight rates on the basis of the cost of the service, with the same unsatisfactory result. •"'Reports of the Wisconsin Railway Commission," Vol. I, p. 88. 22 Yale Review. the rates for the same class of traffic in Wisconsin and in the neighboring States where traffic and operating conditions were fairly similar, and also between different railroads in Wisconsin. The more elaborate the comparisons became, the more dissatisfied the Commission seems to have felt with this method as a final solution. More and more the Commission turned to a study of the real cost of the service,*^ and in order to use this method of determination, it was found necessary to consider the various plans for apportioning common or joint expenses among classes of freight traffic by a process entirely similar in its general principles to that pursued in separating the common expenses between the freight and passenger departments. This situation is well illustrated in the sugar rate cases.^^ After an extended discussion of the relation of the sugar rate to other rates of the same general character, and to the cost of this particular service in comparison with other branches, the Commission suddenly turned to a consideration of the cost actually incurred and finally decided the case upon the cost basis.^^ It is unfortunate from the scientific point of view that the Commission nowhere states the *^"But, as already alluded to, rate comparisons do not often constitute sufficient evidence upon which to decide cases of this character. Other facts, in addition to the rates, are usually required for a full understanding of the question at issue. While the kind of the evidence that may be needed will necessarily vary with the character of the questions that are involved, there is one class of data that is of the greatest importance whenever the reason- ableness of the rates is questioned, and that is, such facts as will tend, at least, to show the approximate cost to the carriers of performing the services in question." Decision 58, p. 9. See also Chippewa Sugar Company vs. Railway Companies, Decision 29, p. 24. *" Chippewa Sugar Company vs. Railway Companies, Decision 29. ^ "But important as the facts which have thus been examined may be, they are not the only ones upon which we may base our decision in this case. For the purpose of obtaining more definite information concerning both the units of transportation and units of service we have carefully analyzed the operating expenses of the roads. We have endeavored to fairly apportion these expenses between the different classes of traffic and to find some trust- worthy methods upon which they might be properly separated between terminal and movement expenses, and also by which both the terminal and the movement expenses may be equitably adjusted according to kind and volume of the traffic. We have also endeavored to ascertain the difference in the cost between the local and through traffic, and to find some basis upon which the movement expenses can be so adjusted that each of these classes of traffic is adequately provided for." Decision 29, p. 24. Railway Freight Rates. 23 exact process which it has adopted for pro-rating the expenses between different classes of freight traffic. It is clear, however, that the terminal expenses per carload are first found, that then the movement expenses are determined by assigning the actual expenditures so far as possible to particular classes of traffic, and that then the common expenses are apportioned separately for each class, different criteria being employed in each case.^^ In a general way the complete process adopted by the Wisconsin Com- mission is given in outline in the case "In re Rates on Pulp Wood." Since the method is stated in its barest outlines, the statement is here given in full : To determine even the approximate cost per unit of transportation to the carriers is very difficult, and can only be done through series of long and complicated calculations, most of which have been explained in former deci- sions. The first step necessarily involves a separation of the expenses between the different branches of traffic. Complicated as this is, it is yet our judgment that it can be accomplished with a fair degree of accuracy and in a manner that is fair to all concerned. The next step is to separate the expenses on the basis of which the traffic is handled, that is, between the cost of handling the traffic at the terminal and the cost of moving it between the terminals. In this case, as in the case of separating the expenses between the different branches of traffic, many items are met with which are common to both sides and which do not readily admit of exact distribution. But even these difficulties may be overcome. Upon close and detailed examina- tions of the various factors involved, some way can usually be found in which the common items can be fairly and equitably assigned. This is not a matter of opinion merely, but has been shown to be so in actual practice. The next step consists of finding some units upon which the various classes of these expenses, or the terminal and the movement costs, can be pro-rated, and the gross and net cost per any given quantity of the traffic be determined. The best units for this purpose would seem to be the loaded car. This must necessarily be so since freight is usually handled and moved in carloads. The terminal costs, for instance, may be pro-rated on the number of these cars and the movement expenses on their mileage. ** "Without going into details, which is impracticable here, it can be said that through the re-classification and re-arrangement of a large part of the operating expenses and by obtaining a great deal of operating and traffic data, in addition to the statistics which are usually found in the reports of the roads, we are able to ascertain the approximate cost per unit of trans- portation of both the terminal and movement expenses for lighter as well as for heavier carloads and for the way freight as well as the through haul. With the assistance of the classifications and tariffs now in effect a basis has also been developed upon which these costs may be adjusted according to the value of the products with a fair degree of accuracy." Decision 59, P- 30. 24 Yale Review. When the cost per car in turn for terminal expenses is pro-rated upon the freight in the car the amount of these expenses to each unit of the traffic is obtained. When the cost per loaded car per mile is pro-rated on the weight of both the car and the load the average cost per gross ton per mile of haul is found. This cost per gross ton, or other unit, can be used as the basis upon which the movement expenses per net ton or other unit is com- puted Under these methods it is possible to determine the average cost per net unit of traffic of handling the freight at the terminals, as well as of moving it between the terminals. Furthermore it is possible from the data as a whole to ascertain these costs under various kinds of loading or for lighter as well as for heavier loading. The fourth step involves such an adjustment of these costs as to apply to local as well as through business. In these operations, however, the terminal expenses are not involved. It is perfectly clear that these costs have no relation to the length of the haul. They appear to be as great for a carload going a hundred miles as for one going five hundred miles. The movement costs, however, vary with the distance and not far from in the same proportion. But the cost of handling way freight which makes fre- quent stops and slow time, is relatively much greater than the cost for through freight or traffic which is moved through from one place to another on faster schedules. To determine the difference in the cost as between through and local traffic, like all other apportionments of expenses, is far from an easy matter, but under a complete analysis of both the expenses and operating conditions, it can be done in a manner that would seem to be fair all around. In this manner it is possible to obtain approximately correct ideas of the cost per unit to the carrier for handling the traffic. This cost is undoubtedly the most important element in rate making. This is particularly true since it is possible to ascertain the same for less than carload as well as for carloads or for both smaller and larger shipments. The value of products is an client that in importance in this respect is second only to the cost As already pointed out, articles of high value can fairly bear higher rates than low priced ones, and in view of this fact it is only just that the charges levied for transportation should be relatively greater in the former case. It will be noticed that the system adopted by the Wisconsin Commission provides a double standard of reasonable rates; first, that of cost of service and, second, that of the value of the articles transported. In regard to the first, there can be, from the theoretical standpoint, little difference of opinion: each class of traffic should pay its own costs ; in other words, there should be no parasites on the freight service and no paupers transported in freight cars.*« The real difficulty in the application of this • Decision 89, p. 57- , ^ .j . • 1 • .u« *"In every rate case which we have heretofore decided involving the reasonableness of the rate in itself, we have acted upon the assumption which we regard as fundamental, that every branch of the railway service shall Railway Freight Rates. 25 principle is found in the method of keeping accounts and the absence of any absolute standard for distributing the common expenses. The method used by the Wisconsin Commission seems to be worked out upon a sound basis and to be sufficiently accurate for the purposes for which it is intended. It is, however, impos- sible to judge of this latter point in the absence of more detailed information as to its practical application in specific cases. The cost basis is, however, modified in its application by the Wisconsin Commission in accordance with the commercial value of the goods transported. This practice, if it can be justified at all, must be justified upon one or both of the following grounds : First, that the risks are greater in case of loss or damage and the care demanded in the transportation of valuable goods is thereby increased. Since loss, damage, and care in shipment are elements in the actual cost of transportation and show themselves in the greater cost of carriage of the more valuable goods, this method of justification must of course be rejected wherever the real costs of transportation have been accurately determined. Again, the more valuable goods, it is said, are able to bear a relatively higher rate. The consideration of this theory, which has become a classic in the American railway system of rates and is even openly approved by the Wisconsin Commission, the protagonist in the use of the cost of the service standard, is so involved from the economic standpoint that a brief and somewhat tentative state- ment only will be attempted here. It is of course obvious that the added cost of transportation for the more valuable goods will fall either upon the producer of the goods or upon the consumer, or will be shared by the two parties. It is also obvious that the higher price of transportation will further limit the use of the pay its own way and that every class of traffic within each branch shall, as far as commercial and competitive conditions permit, stand on its own bottom. While, technically, the law, as interpreted by the court up to the present moment, may not require this in all cases, we are convinced that the spirit of the law ddes require it. Equity positively demands it and rational social and economic theory supports it. In the case under consideration car- load freight is made to bear the total expense of carrying not only less than carload freight, but also of passengers. We do not know how great this expense is; the amount of it is immaterial. In our judgment such a prac- tice on the part of a common carrier is unlawful, inequitable, and economi- cally and socially parasitic." Decision 60, p. g. 26 Yale Review. goods and to this extent diminish the amount offered for trans- portation. Wherever an economic society is made up of indi- viduals of approximately equal wealth, the more valuable goods are either those whose quantity is strictly limited by nature and which may or may not be capable of being somewhat more freely produced, or those which answer the more urgent and pressing wants of society. In either case it would be a distinct economic gain to the community to have the rate of transportation low upon such goods. In a community composed of both poor and wealthy classes, the situation is somewhat different : here the higher priced goods may to a certain extent be those which the wealthy wish to use for immediate personal gratification or personal vanity and which do not contribute at all to their permanent comfort or well-being. In such cases the higher rate of transportation falls as a tax upon the producers or consumers of these commodities according as the production is monopolized or the reverse. Since most modern nations — those in which railway transportation has become general — have developed well-defined wealthy classes, it is evident that such a rate system is likely to act as a progressive tax upon such classes or upon the more prosperous business enter- prises. The burden of the higher rate will fall upon the producer or consumer according to the degree of monopoly power pos- sessed by the producer. In a perfect competitive society, all goods sell in the market at their cost of production: if, now, in such a society, any railway company should raise its rates on any group of commodities, such action would increase the cost of production of the goods on the market, the price would necessarily rise, the quantity of goods sold would be lessened, and the con- sumers would contribute to the railroad companies the amount of increase on each unit transported and sold. No perfect competi- tive society has ever existed, nor is any such promised in the immediate future; goods are produced and sold under fierce competition, under restricted competition, and under partial or almost complete monopoly. When goods are produced under monopolistic conditions, the producer fixes the price and deter- mines the amount of the output in such relation that his net profits are at a maximum; an increase in freight rates cannot under such conditions be shifted to the consumer and must there- fore be borne by the producer. When the production of goods Railway Freight Rates. 27 is partially monopolized, the increased cost of production will be shared by the semi-monopolistic producer and the final consumer. In either case the railroads profit at the expense of both the pro- ducer and the consumer of the goods in question.**^ The system is further justified from the economic point of view on the ground that the increased revenue from the more valuable goods enables the railroad to carry low-priced goods at less than cost where each class of traffic is charged with its proportion of the fixed expenses. That this is a possible situation is not open to question, but that any railroad carries low-class traffic at rates less than competitive or industrial conditions make necessary, is not probable. However, any railroad that has its transportation facilities only partially utilized is under economic pressure to secure more traffic from whatever source possible; higher rates on high-priced goods furnish it with a fighting fund which is often used to carry on a traffic war with a neighboring railroad. Under normal conditions, the railroad with the lowest cost of transportation will finally secure the competitive traffic. In this case, the railroad that is in a position to levy a tax upon the pro- ducers and consumers of the more highly valued goods is in a position to conquer or subjugate a competitor more fitted to survive and furnish transportation facilities to the community, through the use of a fund taken from the users of the more valu- able goods without rendering, from the social point of view, an equivalent for it. A more complete and searching analysis of this situation will convince the student of general social welfare that no system which permits a railroad company to secure a large surplus revenue from the goods most in demand by the community can be justified from the larger point of view. This system is, however, in almost universal use, is sanctioned by the letter of the law of the land as interpreted by the courts, and has therefore become an integral part of our industrial life. Transi- tion from it to the cost of service basis ought to be a gradual one ; but in the interests of general economic welfare of the future, the transition ought to be made. "Wherever the consumer bears any part of the increased rate, the sale of the goods will be less and the railroads will thus lose in quantity of freight transported while gaining in the rate. Wherever rates can be increased without decreasing the quantity of goods transported in like pro- portion, such action is likely to be taken. 28 Yale Review. V. It has been assumed in the discussion thus far, though without direct proof, that rates on certain classes of goods, viz., local traffic and valuable goods, are relatively high. It will be noticed that, unless the cost of the service can be found with reasonable accuracy, any assumption of this sort is purely hypothetical. The Wisconsin Railway Commission has developed a system that determines the approximate cost, but, owing to established industrial conditions, has not attempted to apply it except in a modified way. The cost of the service principle is, however, of the very greatest importance to the railways themselves. Mr. Haines calls attention to this fact and is authority for the state- ment that the railways have in the past lost millions of dollars through sheer ignorance of railway costs, by making rates below the cost of the service as well as below what the traffic would have borne.*^ Of the truth of Mr. Haines' statement there can be no reasonable doubt. Why, then, have the railways administrators not insisted that accounts be kept in such a way as to facilitate the process of finding the cost of the service, and why have they not developed a system comparable with those used in the best manufacturing and commercial establishments? The answer is evident. First, the operations are more complicated and there- fore the problem is more difficult of solution. Second, the railways administrators have in most cases been so fully occupied with taking care of the traffic offered that they have not felt the need of determining costs as a means of self -protection. Third, the railway officials have been trained in a school where the principal maxim has been "charge all the traffic will bear," and they have generally believed that the traffic will bear in nearly all cases somewhat more than the cost of the service. And, fourth, railway accounting, as all other accounting, has been developed for the chief purpose of protecting the proprietors' interest against fraud, mistakes and theft. It is only in recent years that administrators have begun to use the science of accounting as an aid to increased efficiency of the various departments and of the institution as a whole.*^ Some of the more progressive adminis- *■ Haines, "American Railway Management," p. 24-27. *• Duncan, "A Definition of Accounting." Journal of Accountancy, February, 1909. Railway Freight Rates. 29 trators are, however, giving cost accounting as applied to rail- ways the attention which its importance deserves, and it is entirely- safe to predict that, largely as a result of this recent movement, an orderly and equitable system of railway rates will be gradually developed in the United States. Perhaps the most important contribution to the science of railway accounting in connection with the cost of the service is to be found in the work of Mr. T. M. R. Talcott in the manage- ment of several of the southern railways, the results of which are published in a volume of less than one hundred pages.^*^ It is, of course, impossible to give anything more than a mere outline of Mr. Talcott's method of determining the cost of transporting goods and persons without reproducing a considerable portion of his book. In brief, the system is as follows: transportation includes three classes of service in varying proportions, viz., train mileage, car mileage, and gross ton mileage for both the passenger and the freight departments. Accounts must therefore be kept showing each of these items in both passenger and freight busi- ness. Wherever it is impossible to keep the expenses separate, they are apportioned between passenger and freight service as follows : ( I ) fixed expenses, including administration, taxes, maintenance of way, and interest on investment are divided on the basis of the relative gross ton mileage with proper corrections for the speed of the train service; (2) terminal expenses are directly separated for most items; (3) train expenses are directly sepa- rated in practically all cases; (4) car expenses are directly separated in the same way ; ( 5 ) gross tonnage expenses, covering fuel, water, and wear and tear of track, and apportioned on the basis of relative gross ton mileage with proper allowance for relative speed of trains. It is possible by this system, Mr. Talcott finds, actually to sepa- rate not less than 75 per cent, of all the expenses ; and he found, in applying this method of separation to a particular case for the remaining 25 per cent., that the passenger cost was 29^ per cent. ^ "Transportation by Rail : an analysis of the maintenance and operation of railroads, showing the character and cost of the service performed by railway companies in the maintenance of highways for commerce and as common carriers of passengers, freight, and the United States mails over such highways." 20 Yale Review. while that of the freight department was 70.5 per cent. Having determined the total cost of the freight service, Mr. Talcott pro- ceeded to analyze the cost of the various classes of freight traffic. This is accomplished by first finding "units of cost" of the freight service for the most important classes of freight ; then, using these units of cost, it is of course possible to find the total cost of addi- tional classes of service of any particular kind where the condi- tions approximate those for which the units of cost are known. By means of a large number of experiments the additional cost of increased speed, of curvature, and of grades was also deter- mined ; and, on the other hand, the saving due to heavier rails and larger and more powerful locomotives could be found for both the freight and the passenger service. Two further condi- tions were subjected to the same careful analytical test, viz., the relation to the cost of the service of weight and value in propor- tion to bulk, and also the relative cost of long and short distance traffic. • The method used in the first case is not presented in detail, but the general principle adopted may be stated approxi- mately as follows : for a given tonnage the cost of transportation varies directly with value, since the railway is the insurer of the goods while in its possession, and directly with the space occupied, since bulky goods reduce the proportion of the paying load to the gross tonnage. The second question is worked out in consider- able detail, but, owing to the fact that the data kept by the rail- road were not completely separated for the through and local traffic, certain, assumptions were made and only approximate results were reached. The general conclusions drawn from the statistical analysis of the operation are stated as follows : (a) If the number of tons of freight handled by each train is the same and the average load of one of them is reduced during its run without reduction in the average number of cars per train, the terminal, train and car expenses are the same per ton notwithstanding the difference in the average hauls and only the fixed and gross tonnage expenses are variable per ton mile. (b) If the number of tons handled by each train is the same, and not only the average load but also the number of cars is reduced during the run, the terminal and train expenses are the same per ton notwithstanding the difference in the average haul of the freight; and the fixed, car, and gross tonnage expenses are variable per ton mile. (c) If the number of tons handled by each train is not the same, whether the number of cars is the same or not, only the terminal expenses are the Railway Freight Rates. 31 same per ton and the fixed, train, car and gross tonnage expenses are variable per ton mile." As a result of this process, the approximate cost of transporta- tion per ton mile on the given railway of 189 miles was found to be as follows : Constants. Cents per ton. Cents per ton mile. 10 miles 61.98 6.198 50 " 9195 1.825 100 " 127.83 1.279 150 " 164.41 1.096 189 " 192.95 1.021 The cost per ton is thus found to be proportional, not to the distance, but to a certain function of the distance. This function varies with actual operating and traffic conditions, but it is inter- esting to note that Mr. Talcott finds it, for practical purposes, approximately proportional to the square root of the distance. The system inaugurated by Mr. Talcott and used for a period of years to determine the cost of transportation on a small railway may be applied to the operations of any railway, however extensive and however complicated its operations, by competent railway accountants or by any commission availing itself of the aid of such accountants, provided the necessary books are regularly and properly kept. It differs from the Wisconsin system chiefly in the use made of the gross ton mileage as a basis for pro-rating the fixed expenses, maintenance of way, and the cost of moving trains. Since records showing the gross ton mileage are not always kept by the railroads — and even if kept, are not usually available to the public — it is impossible to apply the two methods above described to a particular railway and secure a comparison of results. It seems probable, however, from a careful examina- tion of the two processes, that the final results in such a compari- son would not materially differ. VI. The chief difficulties encountered in determining the cost of transporting freight are thus, it will be noticed, not primarily economic or accounting, but commercial; it therefore follows " Talcott, "Transportation by Rail," p. 72. -2 Yale Review, that if all commodities could be reduced to a common unit com- parable with the passenger mile in passenger traffic, these difficulties would largely disappear. Such a plan has been pro- posed, discussed, and partially formulated, but with small expecta- tion of its immediate adoption by the railroads, owmg to the fact that it would to a considerable extent interfere with the present practice of charging what the traffic is supposed to be able to bear. Such a plan has no inherent difficulties and cer- tainly is no more complicated than the present system of classified and commodity rates. The real difference is this: The present system is the result of the experience of three-quarters of a century, and has become a part of our commercial and industrial system.' To formulate and adopt a universal freight unit in which the elements of weight, space, value and f ragibility should enter in proper proportion would constitute a revolution in the commercial world comparable to that great alteration of view- point which followed the discovery of the sphericity of the earth or of the circulation of the blood. The commercial world would, in all probability, adapt itself to the new system with less difficulty than was experienced in converting men to a rational view of the structure of the universe and of the human body. With the inauguration of such a system, competition in the industrial and commercial spheres would resume its normal condition to a much larger extent than is possible at present. The natural rivalry of manufacturers and merchants would then be directed, in the absence of obstructions imposed by an arbitrary system of rail- way rates, toward supplying the goods most dearly prized and therefore of highest commercial value, it being understood that the railroads would, under this system, serve all localities and all commodities on substantially similar terms. Discrimination between commodities and places, just as discriminations between persons, would, as a result, become a thing of the past. This is the goal toward which the industrial and commercial world is moving, and when it is reached, the "absolute test of a reasonable rate" will have been found. Maurice H. Robinson. The University of Illinois. 3 0112 062003451 THE YALE REVIEW A QUARTERLY JOURNAL FOR THE SCIENTIFIC DISCUSSION OF ECONOMIC, POLITICAL, AND SOCIAL QUESTIONS. Edited by Professors in POLITICAL SCIENCE AND HISTORY Yale University, New Haven, Conn. The Review is edited by Professors Henry Walcott Farnam, John Christopher Schwab, Irving Fisher, Guy Stevens Cal- lender, Henry Crosby Emery, Clive Day, Albert GAi,L(n\ ay Keller, Fred Rogers Fairchild. The subscription price is $3-°° Per year. Subscriptions may begin at any time. PUBLISHED BY YALE PUBLISHING ASSOCIATION, (Incorporated) 135 Elm Street, New Haven, Conn. All payments for subscriptions and business correspondence should be sent to the Yale Publishing Association, Inc., 135 Elm Street. New Haven, Conn.