AND LAWS OF ENGLAND. BY A MEMBER OF THE CIVICS CLUB OF BROWN UNIVERSITY. i t Published Midi y the auspices of the Club. PROVIDENCE : SIDNEY S. RIDER. l886. This pamphlet makes no pretensions to originality or exhaustive- ness. It was composed, along with several other papers similar in nature, solely for the behoof of the private circle of students whence it emanates, and is printed, not as superior to the others, hut as of more general interest at the present time. It presents a glimpse of an important topic on which, to many, larger literature is inaccessible. 9 ^ (oi-^TQ cr LAND LAWS OF ENGLAND. The laws of Primogeniture and Entail, which are the principal features of the present English land system, have • sprung, in the opinion of the most eminent authorities, from the old feudal system in the later stages of its develop- ment. Among the nations of antiquity whose laws we have, the only race to practice Primogeniture was the Jews, all other peoples giving equal rights to all the sons, but granting the eldest one the privilege of making the first choice in selecting his share of the property. The Hin- doos, the Germans, the Irish and the Anglo-Saxons gave no special preeminence to the first-born. Moreover, Primogeniture did not belong to the customs which the barbarians practiced on their first establishment within the Roman Empire, but among these peoples the male chil- dren were co-proprietors with their father, and the eldest son had an equal share in the common property. Sir Henry Maine says that “ an absolutely equal division of assets among the male children at death is the practice most usual with society at the period when family dependency n is in the first stage of disintegration.” Nor, though many laws, once supposed to be of native growth, have since been traced back to the Roman law, can Primogeniture be derived from that great source, for in this, “ when the suc- cession was ‘ab intestato/ and the group of co-heirs con- o 29220 4 sisted of the children of the deceased, they each took an equal share of the property.” From these proofs it is clear that Entail and Primogeni- ture had their beginning no farther back than *the feudal system, and it is safe to assert that they originated in this system, inasmuch as they were established in those coun- tries, and only in those countries, where the feudal system was established, and have been abandoned in the lands where this system has been abandoned. The cause of the origin of the custom has been very well stated by Adam Smith : “While land is considered as the means only of subsistence and enjoyment, the natural law of succession divides it, like these, among all the chil- dren of the family ; but when land was considered as the means, not of subsistence merely, but of power and protec- tion, it was thought better that it should descend undi- vided to one.” In the conquest of new countries, the chiefs parcelled out the newly acquired lands among their principal retain- ers, expecting that, in return, they would do military ser- vice for their lord. On the decease of any of these retain- ers it was naturally the eldest son who was best acquainted with the obligations due his lord, and moreover it was neces- sary that there be some one understood head of the family to lead it in peace and in war. This head of the family was in the majority of cases to be found in the person of the eldest son, who had had greatest experience in all these matters. He performed his duties not so much because he was looked upon as having exceptional rights, but because of his supposed superior merit ; and indeed in frequent cases younger brothers were selected for the position, showing that merit, not right, was the true criterion. 5 These leaders in family matters, instead of enjoying, as now many English landowners enjoy, riches, position, title, lux- ury and ease, were weighed down under a system of bur- dens that made their lives full of care and toil, with but a small amount of peace or pleasure. The precise year of the establishment of Primogeniture in England is uncertain, yet it is known that by the end of 4 the thirteenth century it was the almost universal custom, as was also the law of Entail. Yet it must be borne in mind that the law of Entail at this period gives no inde- , feasible right of inheritance as does the later statute. This right was instituted by the statute “ De Donis,” made in the reign of Edward I., by which, when a fee was granted to a man, the succession of his issue was secured against alienation, and the property had to be transmitted to his heirs directly. That this statute, “ De Donis,” wrought out the greatest evils, is clearly shown by its results as stated by Blackstone in his Commentaries : “ Children grew disobedient when they knew they could not be set aside ; farmers were ousted of their leases made by ten- ants-in-tail ; creditors were defrauded of their debts ; in- numerable latent entails were produced to deprive purcha- sers of the lands they had fairly bought ; and treasons were encouraged, as estates-tail were not liable to forfeiture longer than the tenant’s life.” In view of the disastrous effects of this statute, Parlia- ment, in the reign of Henry VIII., authorized tenants-in- tail to bar their issue by two methods, called respectively, “fines” and “common recoveries.” To explain what these laws were, I will quote, in substance, from Mr. Pol- lock’s Land Laws, first, in regard to the “common recov- ery ” : 6 The device, he says, in its simplest form, was of this nature : the tenant-in-tail (let us call him Littleton) being in possession, some person (say Brian), acting in concert with him, would bring the real action, called a “ writ of right,” for the recovery of the freehold, claiming himself to be the real owner. Littleton, instead of defending his title for himself, would “vouch to warranty” a third per- son (say Catesby), from whom he professed to have received his title, and who was supposed bound to warrant the tenant from all comers. Catesby was brought in as a party and acknowledged the warranty. Brian, the nominal plaintiff, then obtained leave of the court to confer privately with Catesby, thus providing a sort of carpenter’s scene to cover the production of the final effect. When Brian came back from his conference with Catesby, it was found that the lat- ter had disappeared. Thereupon judgment went by default against Catesby, and the lands were awarded to Brian as an estate in fee simple. Brian transfers the estate to Little- ton, and the process is brought to an end. In regard to the “fine,” Mr. Pollock says that it was “a more ancient proceeding, differing from a recovery in that the collusive action was not pursued to judgment, but compromised.” By the use of these processes the ownership and power of alienation of land were made more just and facile than they have ever been since ; for by them an owner could obtain a title to his land in fee-simple, and then alienate as he chose. Soon, however, family pride in holding large estates, and the desire for power, caused means to be devised for check- ing this freedom and keeping estates undivided. The first step in this direction was the substitution, in deeds of set- tlement, of the words, “first, or eldest son,” for “heir of 7 his body,” the effect of this change being, that the father took simply a life interest in the estate, which, at his decease, passed to the son. This idea was gradually fur- ther developed, so that, though the tenant-in-tail could not be deprived of his right to become eventually master of the property, yet his acquisition of it might be postponed one or even two generations. The next step was the establishment k of “ trustees to preserve contingent remainders, ” whose function it was to protect tenants-in-tail from being deprived of their lands by the wrong acts of previous ten- * ants. These are some of the leading changes which have been made in the laws of Entail and Primogeniture since their earlier stages ; and we will now look at some of the condi- tions which the present laws have caused. The best idea of these conditions can be obtained from what are known as the “ Doomsday Books,” a collection of statistics and returns, gathered and published at the request of the Earl of Derby, whose purpose it was to show that the extent to which the purchase of land and the holding of it in large estates is carried on, had been misrepresented. The “Doomsday Books” certainly show a most astonish- ing and, it would seem, alarming state of affairs ; for the extent to which land is amassed in individual hands is enor- mous, notwithstanding the fact that in the reports of the areas of estates, no mention is made of the acreage of woods, plantations, common lands, etc., which, if counted in, would swell the estates to vastly greater proportions. Some of these figures have been taken by Mr. Joseph Kay, in his pamphlet called “Free Trade in Land,” and I will quote them in part from him : The total extent of England and Wales is 37,243,859 8 acres. Of these acres, 66 men own 1,917,076; 100 per- sons own 3,917,641 ; 710 men own more than one-quarter; 874 own 9,267,031 ; and a class of men, about 4,500 in number, own 17,498,200, or more than one-half. In Scotland the condition of affairs is far worse. Out of a total area of 18,946,694 acres, one owner alone holds 1,326,000, to say nothing of 32,000 acres in England, mak- ing a grand total of 1,358,548. Seventy men own half of Scotland. Ireland is in the same state. Taking the twelve largest owners in each country, we find that in England they hold in all, 1,058,883 acres ; in Scotland, 4,339,722; in Ireland, 1,297,288. In the United Kingdom, the twelve largest owners hold 4,440,467 acres. Even Mr. Froude, the eager champion of the present laws, admits that “the House of Lords does own more than a third of the whole area of Great Britain. Two- thirds of it really belong to great peers and commoners, whose estates are continually devouring the small estates adjoining.” And this statement is supplemented by that of Lord Derby, that “the glass of peasant proprietors, formerly to be found in the rural districts, is tending to disappear.” The result of the law which grants this power of accumulation is, that the peasant, with no chance of ever possessing the land on which he is at work, with no possibility of ever having a home of his own, has lost the greatest incentive to labor and improvement on the land ; he will not waste his time, labor, or money on that which cannot be his, and which he may lose at any moment. All around him the rich and powerful are buying lands to enlarge their estates at whatever price, in order to gain power, fame and title. And this desire for large estates, considered with the scarcity of land in the market, creates 9 a most unhealthy inflation of the price of land, which can- not but be harmful to the community. But how is it that this land, when once in the possession of the rich, can be tied up, and transferred in large quanti- ties by the will of a single man ? Many believe, and that falsely, that the law of Primogeniture is the cause of this accumulation. Primogeniture means simply, that, in case a i man dies intestate, the property or land shall go to his legal heir, and this is easily seen to be distinct from any process of forming large estates. • Some persons believe that a man, by one will or deed, can entail land and keep it from the market in perpetuity ; this is a mistake. The law allows an owner to tie up his land, so that it cannot be sold during the lifetimes of any specified persons in existence when the will is made, or until the unborn child of one of these persons reaches the age of twenty-one. Thus by a single deed, a lord can pre- vent his estate from coming into the market for several generations after his own death, however expedient or imperative the sale might be. Mr. Kay gives a striking instance of the bad effects this power may cause, occurring in an estate in the south of England, of which he was him- self a trustee. A young titled lord had a valuable estate in fee-simple, the whole income belonging to himself. Upon his marriage, deeds were drawn up, giving him only a life interest in the estate, which, at his death, was to descend to his children in succession. The estate was divided into large farms and very valuable woods. Lord A was extravagant and reckless ; he lived as if his income were ten times what it really was ; he gambled and lost money, and finally fled from England. The remainder of the life interest, worth only the thinning of the woods, IO was sold to a Jew, who knew he would lose all as soon as Lord A died. This state of things lasted forty years; the farmers had no leases, and no security for expenditure ; they were unwilling to expend on the farm buildings. The Jew, in order to make as much money as possible, demanded exorbitant rents, and cut out of the beautiful park far more timber than any unembarrassed owner would have done, and so the estate was damaged more and more every year ; the tenantry were prevented from dealing fairly by the land ; there were no one to sup- port schools or the church, or to look after the large village of laborers upon the property ; all social progress and pros- perity were stopped ; the farm buildings fell into decay ; the land was not properly drained or cultivated ; the plan- tations were injured ; the mansion became dilapidated ; and all this was caused by the deeds which the law allowed the lord and his heirs to execute. The laws which grant this power of maintaining estates unbroken for generations, are three in number : (1) . The law which enables an owner, by will or deed, to prevent his estate being altered for years after his death. This is the law of Entail. (2) . The law by which, if a landowner dies intestate, the land descends undivided and unincumbered to his heirs. This is Primogeniture. (3) . The series of laws enabling landholders to lease portions of their estates for terms covering from ninety- nine to nine hundred and ninety-nine years, placing upon them restrictions binding until the lease expires. (1). The first law enables an owner to give his property to certain trustees, with instructions to pay his wife a cer- tain annuity for life, and to hand over the rest of the yearly income to himself. If now he becomes hopelessly in debt through extravagance or bad habits, he cannot sell the land and cancel his debts, but the income must be used to pay his creditors, the land remaining in the same hands. But besides allowing this stricture to be made on the land during the lord’s own life, the laws allow him to entail his property on his children’s children, and they in turn can do the same to their issue, often being enabled to restrict the sale of land for seventy-five or one hundred years by a single will. Moreover, the lord can place upon his heirs all sorts of restrictions as to the care of the property, such as the payment of certain annuities, and the management of mines, woods, etc. All this one man can do. But his heir wishes to keep the estate undivided as far as possible ; so he promises to his son a large allowance, if, when he reaches his twenty- first year, he will unite with his father in tying up the prop- erty as before. With the dazzling prospect of an imme- diate supply of money if he agrees, and the rather gloomy financial outlook if he refuses, the son naturally assents. Of these agreements between father and son, Mr. Cliffe Leslie says : “ It is commonly supposed that the son acts with his eyes open, and with a special eye to the contin- gencies of the future and of family life. But what are the real facts of the case ? Before the future owner of the land has come into possession ; before he has any experience of his property, or what is best to do, or what he can do in regard to it ; before the exigencies of the future are known to him ; before the character, number and wants of his children are learned, or the claims of parental affection or duty can make themselves felt, and while still very much at the mercy of a predecessor desirous of posthumous greatness and power, he enters into an irrevocable disposi- tion, by which he parts with the rights of a proprietor over his future property forever, and settles its devolution, bur- dened with charges, upon an unborn heir.” As the estate is to be undivided for many years, it is necessary that there should be many directions, in the will or deed, for the management of the land, and for proceed- ure in any possible emergencies. These directions may be in regard to cutting of woods, working of mines, erection of new buildings, repair of old ones, expenditures for char- ity, education, etc. And these “powers,” as they are called, are often so numerous and so complex in their rela- tions to each other, that the ablest lawyers sometimes can- not tell the exact legal condition of the estate. If legal minds cannot unravel these intricate knots, how can a lay mind grasp the situation ? (2) . The second law, that of Primogeniture, is that which, if the landowner die intestate, gives the entire prop- erty, without charges upon it, and undivided, to the land- lord’s heir. This law merely aggravates the tendency to the formation and continuation of large estates. Instead of being divided proportionally among all the relatives, as justice would seem to demand, the property must descend to one and only one heir, whether he be able to carry on the estate or not, and without the least regard for the needs and possible suffering of the others. (3) . By the third of these laws the landowner, without having the power to sell his land, can lease portions of it for terms of years from ninety-nine to nine hundred and ninety-nine, and subject to all sorts of conditions. Before the enactment of this law, an owner, after entailing his 3 property upon his issue for generations, had only a life interest, and since the day of his death was uncertain, the time at which a lease expired was equally uncertain, and no tenants would procure leases on such terms. In order to secure to landowners the power of letting their farms for a longer period of years, the Court of Chancery was authorized by Parliament to grant permits for leases extend- ing over ninety-nine or nine hundred and ninety-nine years. Not only does this law admit of the further tying up of estates, but the existence of leases, dating back one hun- dred or two hundred years, also greatly complicates the investigation and conveyancing of titles. These are some of the leading principles which affect land and its transmission. Now let us look at some of the evil results of these laws, results which, of course, are not invariable, but which often come to pass. I. In the first place, they prevent large estates from coming into the market, which would often do so if left unrestricted. In the case of Lord A , which Mr. Kay mentions, his estate would have been for sale forty years before it was, had there been no deed made at his mar- riage. And there are numbers of such cases in which the sale of the property, if possible, would be a vast advantage to all parties concerned. This plan of selling bankrupt estates has been tried in Ireland, and in two cases, cited by Mr. Kay, the tenants all bought their holdings, very many being able to pay a large per cent, down in cash. The London Times said : “ In every case great benefit had resulted from the purchase. It had been a 4 spur to indus- try and thrift,’ and the increased industry and activity required to pay off the loan will establish a habit for the future.” 14 II. A second evil is that if one of these deeds of trans- fer to the son has once been made, he knows that no mat- ter what his course of action may be, it is impossible for his father to disinherit him or otherwise discipline him, however much he may desire to do so. This can hardly conduce to a noble and useful life, or to proper respect for parents. Lord Bacon says : “ So, passing over considera- tions of humanity, let us now consider the discipline of families. And touching this I will speak modestly and under correction. Though I reverence the laws of my country, yet I observe one defect in them, and that is, there is no footstep of the reverend f potestas patria ’ which was so commended in ancient times. This only remains : if the father has any patrimony and the son be disobedient, he may disinherit him ; if he will not deserve his blessing, he shall not have his living. But this device of perpetui- ties has taken the power from the father likewise, and has tied and made subject the parents to the cradle, and so notwithstanding he has the curse of his father, yet he shall have the land of his grandfather.” III. Berkeley asks, “What right hath the eldest son to the worst education?” Careless fathers are encouraged in their carelessness by the knowledge that, whatever the son’s training, however he may conduct himself, and how- ever bad a reputation he may bring upon himself, he can never be deprived of his estates, or social position, nor can the future of the family be affected by his acts. The pres- ent laws have been described as tending “to establish in the centre of each family a magnificently fed and colored drone, the incarnation of wealth and social dignity, the vis- ible end of human endeavor, a sort of great Final Cause, immanent in every family.” Thus are kept at the head in i5 public affairs men who have looked upon labor as a dis- grace, and have grown up in luxury and ignorance. IV. In the great majority of cases, when the owner comes into possession of his property, through the death of his father or the previous tenant for life, he is already mar- ried and has a family of children. If, after paying the cur- rent expenses for the year, he has anything left from his s income, he is in a dilemma as to its disposition. He natu- rally desires to leave something to his younger children as well as to their older brother. But improvements on the 1 estate are needed, which, if carried out, must be paid for from his income. If the improvements are made, the children fail of their money ; and on the other hand, if the children’s interests prevail, the land must go unimproved, the latter being more often the case ; so that estates, pass- ing from hand to hand, are frequently in a little poorer con- dition at each transfer than at the preceding one. V. The law of Entail, and of Primogeniture as well, by conferring upon an owner the power of directing the man- agement of the estate for so many years, makes the deeds of transfer, when such are made, very long and expensive. Since no change can be made in the deed after the maker’s death, he must insert in it an almost innumerable number of directions and charges as to the care and disposal of all the different parts of the property, such as the working of mines, cutting of trees, sale of game, support of relatives, etc. These directions, when made in successive wills in ft regard to the ' same piece of property, often so cross and recross each other and become involved in such tangles, ^ that the ablest legal minds in England cannot unravel them and come to an agreement on their meaning. If the solic- itors are unable to come to a decision, there is nothing left i6 but to resort to the Chancery Courts. Often the process is so long that the estates in question are entirely con- sumed by solicitors’ fees, and the only question is, to which set of lawyers the estate belongs. VI. Then, in buying a piece of land the purchaser must know what his title is to be, and his solicitor, to answer this question, endeavors to find out whether all previous owners have given up all claim to the land, what disposi- tion they made of it, what restrictions were laid upon it, and how long they are to have effect, what leases and mort- gages have been made, and who hold them. But all this involves time, and time in England, as elsewhere, means money, the title costing not in proportion to the value of the estate, but in proportion to the time spent by the solic- itor, which may be, and frequently is, greater for a small estate than for a large one. Mr. Kay mentions a case in 1877, where a poor man bought three acres of glebe land and ^15 a year of rent charge, for which he had to pay ,£117, or $685, for the mere legal expenses attending the examination of the title and the deed of conveyance. Such cases are of course exceptional, yet very often the expense is so great as to prevent a reasonable man from investing in land. VII. But when finally the deed is completed, and the purchaser is congratulating himself on his new land and the fine bargain he has made, he is not absolutely certain that he cannot be ousted from his position by some one who had a prior claim on the estate, which his attorney over- looked, or which was concealed from him. A case of this kind occurred in the south of England, where a man, after a careful examination of the title, purchased a small estate, the former owner of which soon fled the country in a state 7 of hopeless bankruptcy. Shortly afterwards the new owner found that the estate had been mortgaged secretly in ,£1,200 to a third party, who now claimed his money; and the money had to be paid. If England would only adopt some such system of registration of deeds as is in use in this country and among many European nations, all uncertainty as to the security of titles would be reduced to s a minimum ; and that the expense of registering a deed would be a mere nothing as compared to the present cost, is shown by the fact that in England’s own colony of Aus- I tralia, the expense has been cut down ninety per cent, by this institution. VIII. But the cost of a title is not the only considera- tion in small pieces of land such as the poor and the mid- dle classes would be likely to purchase. It is almost impos- sible to get land. The large estates swallow it up regard- less of expense or need, and the poor man must either rent or emigrate. And this constant absorption of small estates by the greater ones causes immense harm ; for, by taking from a man all opportunity or power of ever being able to possess in his own right a strip of land which he may cul- tivate and on which he may build a cottage, they remove one of the greatest incentives to activity, industry, econ- omy and moral life. In addition to these manifestly harmful results which have been mentioned, there are several rights and powers which landowners, and owners of no other kind, have come A to possess, and which they do not fail to exercise. (i). The first of these powers is one derived from ancient feudal laws, and is called the “ Law of Distress,” by which, if a tenant fails to pay his rent for any reason whatever, whether sickness, laziness, famine or distress of i8 any kind, the landlord, or his agent, has full power to step in, without the long process of appeal to the courts, and seize a sufficient quantity of the tenant’s household goods, cattle, or agricultural implements, to satisfy the debt. To an owner of no other kind is this right given ; all other creditors must take an equal chance in the courts. (2) . Another privilege, also handed down from feudal times, is that known as the “ Law of Fixtures.” This law provides that, in case of a tenant, whether on a short or long lease, whatever improvements that tenant may make upon his land, for example fences, walls, drains, new build- v ings, etc., from the moment they are placed upon the land, become fixtures, and belong no longer to the tenant who . made them, bur to the landlord ; and this is true whether the improvement be fixed or of such a kind that it can be removed without injury to the estate. And one of the worst features of the law is that, as a general rule, as can be proved by the many cases tried in court on this subject, the tenants enter into leases and agreements concerning the land, without the slightest conception of what the law means, or in fact that it exists. (3) . Then, in the matter of game laws, the lord has a power over those found trespassing on his premises, which would be tolerated in no other country. A man caught in the act of poaching is tried before a magistrate, himself a landowner, who having the same interests at stake as the man on whose preserves the poaching was done, is not likely to let the offender go unpunished, and who often imposes a fine which utterly ruins him. In no other court would a judge be allowed to sit on the bench if he were ^ anything but a disinterested party. One very harmful result of England’s land policy is that 19 the wealthy landowners, who are also the leaders in politi- cal matters, gain the support of their tenants very often through patronage and the tenants’ dread of eviction. To secure the votes of the people the lords grant leases for only short periods, which work vast evils, for the man whose lease expires in a few years will not lay out money in improvements which may be taken from him at any time ; a most terrible lack of improvements has resulted ‘ from this practice. Great difficulty will be experienced in trying to reform . the land-laws, on account of the enormous wealth and in- fluence of the landowners in Parliament and elsewhere, and also from that proverbial indisposition on the part of an Englishman to attempt anything for which he has not the precedent established way back in the time of the Con- queror. The first place where reform should be attempted is in the law of Primogeniture, which should be repealed, a measure which even the champions of the present system are beginning to endorse, since it is among the poorer classes only that intestacy prevails ; and thus the abolition of this law would not affect them at all. And even if a large property should devolve upon several children, yet a fraternal agreement could easily be made by which the estate might be kept in the family undivided. But Primogeniture is not the only place where improve- ment can be made. The law of Entail has far greater A . influence for ill. It has been proposed to cut off that part of this statute which permits the entailing of estates upon unborn children, and limiting it. to only specified persons * in existence when the will or deed was made. This meas- ure would afford only a slight relief ; for when property 20 can be tied up for one hundred years, a reduction of twenty years does not touch the vital defect in the system, but would only set lawyers at work to devise some \vay of get- ting round the statute. For these and other reasons it seems better to sweep away entirely the law of Entail. This would not put an end to the power of settling property upon one’s heirs at pleasure, but it would destroy the power, given to one man to direct the administration of an estate for a century after his death. Following the abolition of this law would be increased parental- control, and a general betterment of • v those evils already mentioned as resulting from Entail. Moreover, estates now heavily encumbered by debts would come into the market, greatly to the advantage of the lord himself and of his creditors as well. Mr. Arthur Arnold gives a very good picture of the condition of a bankrupt landlord: “The nominal owners of several of the finest properties in England are now adjudicated bankrupts ; their lands are racked and impoverished, but those broad acres cannot be made free without the cooperation of the tenant-for-life with the next tenant-in-tail, who in some cases is a minor, and in others is unborn, and may never come into existence. But for every one of the landed gentry who is bankrupt, there are scores who are hopelessly embarrassed The cottages upon many estates are fever-nests and are few and far between ; the homesteads are insufficient, inconvenient, and in many cases in ruins ; the land is undrained, and there is no one with the interest ^ of a proprietor to look to the estate. The ostensible owner, the lord or the squi-re of the district, who is harassed ^ for subscriptions, and supposed to contemplate with the benign interest of a seignioral lord the welfare of all 21 around, who is the great man in the church and in the vi( lage, is in the dull reality of his own home merely a poor annuitant, with his eyes fixed, not upon the many fields and farms which in the rate-book bear his name, but upon the slender remnant of income which is all that charges or settlements have left him for the daily and hourly labor of providing for a family, for whom ten times his means would , seem insufficient. He and his eldest son have but one pleasure in the world, and as it appears to cost nothing, they think themselves meritorious in that they are content ^ with the sporting which the estate and the neighborhood afford. The younger children languish at home, well knowing that upon their father’s death they must find a new shelter, with very small fortunes.” The laws of Primogeniture and Entail are the chief cause of the troubles in the administration of land in Eng- land to-day; but besides the abolition of these, there are other reforms and improvements which should be made in order to make the sale and transfer of land more certain and simple, with less cost. Two of these changes are to be found in the questions of registration and conveyancing. If there had not been for so long a period the complicated series of wills and deeds entailing property upon future generations with an almost endless variety and number of directions, restrictions and charges, much of the tedious- ness and outrageous cost of conveyancing would have been uncalled for, and the title of an English estate would not ^ have needed to be “ enshrined in a mausoleum of parch- ment.” This better conveyancing would be greatly aided by better means of registration of title than at present pre- vail ; these means now consist in the records of the Court of Chancery, which are often very defective. Registration 22 can be made just as simple and easy in England as any- where else, yet it can have no beneficial effect if not made compulsory, and also convenient and cheap. Several movements in the direction of improvement have already been begun, and more are constantly being pro- posed. In 1833 the clumsy method of “ fines” and “ common recoveries ” was abolished and a tenant-in-tail now, by means of a deed enrolled in chancery, can make whomsoever he pleases possessor of his estates, in fee-sim- ple, if he has the freehold ; but if he has not this, he must get the consent of the tenant-for-life, who is then called “protector of the settlement.” This measure has caused great relief. To alleviate in some degree the difficulties, dangers and expenses caused by poor registration, many efforts have been made. Many times the subject has been discussed, yet the root of the matter has been left untouched. Reg- istries of deeds have been established, as for example, the one in 1862, in which state guarantee and simplicity were offered in future dealings to landlords who could prove their titles satisfactorily. Local registries have also been established, but with little success, the chief obstruction to their success being that they are not made compulsory by law. The certainty of a title under the present system is well set forth in an answer sent to the Real Property Com- missioners in reply to some inquiries from them: “It is possible to attain to such a degree of certainty as com- monly satisfies a prudent man in the ordinary business of life, but with considerable delay, difficulty and expense ; the great evil is not that titles are uncertain or unsafe, but that the investigation of them is difficult, tedious and costly.” A title is now held to be good when there have 23 been twelve years undisturbed possession, except when the claimants were disabled by infancy or some like reason from presenting their cause, in which case six more years are allowed. Another point where much remains to be done is in the matter of the disadvantages of strict settlements, of which Lord St. Leonards wrote : “ The present plan of a strict ^ settlement does not place land extra commercium , but within reasonable limits enables the owner to transmit it to all his posterity No man in this country can p justly complain that there is not sufficient land in the mar- ket on sale.” The great objection to these strict settle- ments is that no room is left to a tenant-for-life for improve- ments on his estate. The charges already placed upon him by his ancestors, have so narrowed his income that he has all he can do to support himself. In 1882 the Settled Land Act of Lord Cairns was passed, which gives the ten- ant-for-life certain powers of selling and leasing, subject to certain restrictions intended for safeguards to prevent abuse. The consent of the Court, however, is necessary to the sale of a mansion-house or an heir-loom. The money obtained from the sale of land may be devoted to improve- ments, the expenditure on which is under the eye of the Land Commissioners or the Court. By this act the life- tenant gets no benefit to himself, but only places his estate in a far better condition for his son to enter upon ; he may leave money entirely instead of land, if he pleases; in so * far can he alter the form which his son’s rights take, but he cannot alter the rights themselves. We have mentioned some of the laws which govern Eng- land’s land to-day, also some of the evils which these laws have caused, together with proposed remedies for them. 24 With all these harmful customs and laws swept away, and with better facilities of transfer, “ it is not too much to expect,” to quote Mr. Brodrick, “ that some links, now miss- ing, between rich and poor, gentle and simple, might be supplied in country districts ; that ‘ plain living and high thinking’ might again find a home in some of our ancient manor-houses, once the abode of landowners, but now ten- anted by mere occupiers ; that, with less of dependence ^ and subordination to a dominant will, there would be more of true neighborly feeling, and even of clanship ; and that posterity, reaping the beneficent fruits of greater social equality, would marvel, and not without cause, how the main obstacle to greater social equality— the Law and Custom of Primogeniture — escaped revision for more than two centuries after the final abolition of the feudal tenures.” UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS-URBANA 3 0112 061728710