UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LIBRARY AT URBANA-CHAMPAIGN BOOKSTACKS DZ CENTRAL CIRCULATION BOOKSTACKS The person charging this material is re- sponsible for its renewal or its return to the library from which it was borrowed on or before the Latest Date stamped below. You may be charged a minimum fee of $75.00 for each lost book. Theft, mutilation, and underlining of books are reasons for disciplinary action and may result in dismissal from the University. TO RENEW CALL TELEPHONE CENTER, 333-8400 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LIBRARY AT URBANA CHAMPAIGN APR 2 9 1998 AUG 3 1998 When renewing by phone, write new due date below previous due date. L162 330 3385 420 COPY 2 STX BEB FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 1420 Ioffe's Normal Cone and the Foundations of Welfare Economics: An Example M. Ali Khan AP! 1COQ College of Commerce and Business Administration Bureau of Economic and Business Research University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign BEBR FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 1420 College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Illinois at Urb ana -Champaign December 1987 Ioffe's Normal Cone and the Foundations of Welfare Economics: An Example M. Ali Khan, Professor Department of Economics Ioffe's Normal Cone and the Foundations of Welfare Economics: An Examplet by M. Ali Khan* November 1987 Abstract . We announce an example of an economy with an infinite dimen- sional commodity space for which the extension of the second fundamen- tal theorem of welfare economics is valid if marginal rates of substi- tution are formalized in terms of either the Clarke normal cone or the Ioffe normal cone but in which the former is strictly contained in the latter. This is in direct contradiction to the finite dimensional situation. tThis research is supported, in part, by a N. S.F. grant. The author is grateful for the comments and questions of D. Diaraantaras, L. Mckenzie, W. Thompson and the participants of the economic theory seminar at the University of Rochester. Errors are solely his. *Department of Economics, University of Illinois, 1206 South Sixth Street, Champaign, Illinois, 61820. Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign http://www.archive.org/details/ioffesnormalcone1420khan 1. Introduction In a recent paper, the author reported an extension of the so- called second fundamental theorem of welfare economics in which the marginal rates of substitution are formalized through the use of the Ioffe normal cone, see Khan [1987]. In particular, it was shown that under a mild constraint qualification and modulo scalar multiples, the Ioffe normal cones to the production and the "no-worse-than" sets at the respective production and consumption plans have a non-empty and non-zero intersection. If these sets are generated by dif f erentiable functions, the Ioffe normal cones reduce to singletons and the result yields the conventional necessary conditions for a Pareto optimal allocation as in Hicks [1939], Lange [1942], Allais [1943], Samuelson [1947] and Graaf [1957]. If these sets are convex, the Ioffe normal cones reduce to the cones conventional in the sense of convex analysis and the result yields the statement that Pareto optimal allocations can be sustained through profit maximization by producers and expen- diture minimization by consumers as in Arrow [1951], Debreu [1951, 1954], Malinvaud [1953] and Koopmans [1957]. Finally, since the Ioffe normal cone is contained in the Clarke normal cone, the result also generalizes recent work of Khan-Vohra [1987], Yun [1984], Quinzii [1986], Cornet [1986], which in turn generalized the earlier work of Guesnerie [1975]. The results in Khan [1987] are limited to an economy with a finite dimensional commodity space and were initially motivated by the con- sideration of an example of an economy with a production set without free disposal and for which the marginal rate of substitution at a -2- Pareto optimal production plan, as formalized by the Clarke normal cone at that plan, is the entire dual space. It was shown that the Ioffe normal cone at such a production plan is more in keeping with our intuitive notion of a marginal rate of substitution. In this note, we present an example of an economy with an infinite dimensional commodity space that furnishes an opposite conclusion. In particular, the economy has a production set without free disposal and for which the Ioffe normal cone at the Pareto optimal production plan is the en t i r e dual space, but the Clarke normal cone is a strict subset. Intuition gets somewhat stretched in an infinite dimensional setting but the Clarke normal cone at such a production plan does not seem unreasonable. Our example underscores the unpredictability of the Ioffe normal cone in an infinite dimensional setting and is based on Treiman [1983]. Section 2 reviews some basic concepts and Section 3 presents the example. Section 4 is devoted to three concluding remarks. 2. The Basic Concepts In this section we present the definitions of the Clarke and Ioffe cones. Since our example is set in an infinite dimensional space, we develop these definitions in the context of an arbitrary Banach space E. However, for concreteness , the reader may choose to think in terms of Euclidean n-space R or, for that matter, in terms of R . We begin with a tangential approximant of a set introduced by Bouligand [1932] and termed the contingent cone. It was first applied in economics by Otani-Sicilian [1977]. -3- Definition 2.1 The contingent cone of Y C E at y z Y is the set k k T (Y,y) = {x e C:_"»a sequence {t } of positive numbers with t ■*■ K k k k k and a sequence {x } with x ■*■ x such that (y+t x ) e Y for all k}. Definition 2.2 The Clarke tangent cone of Y - E at y z Y is the set T r (Y,y) = {x z E: For any sequence {t } of positive numbers with k k k k t + and any sequence {y } with y e Y, y + y, there exists a k k k k k sequence {x } with x ■*■ x such that (y +t x ) z Y for all k}. + Definition 2. 3 For any cone A - E, the polar cone A is the set {y z E*: _< for all x e A} where E is the topological dual of E. [Note that (R n )* = R n ]. We shall denote the polars of T (Y,y) and T (Y,y) by N (Y,y) and K. (, K N (Y,y) and refer to them as the contingent normal cone and Clarke normal cone respectively. For more details into these definitions, see Clarke [1983] and Khan-Vohra [1987]. Definition 2.4 The Ioffe normal cone to Y _ E at y z Y is given by k k k the set N (Y,y) = {x e E:^. a sequence {y } with y e Y, y ■*■ y and k k k x e N K ( Y >y ) with x * x} . For details, see Ioffe [1981, 1984] and Khan [1987]. The reader can check his understanding of these basic concepts by referring to the technology depicted as Y in Figure la. The con- tingent cone T (Y,y) is given by the shaded cone in Figure lb, the Ioffe normal cone N (Y,y) by the two arrows in Fig. lb and the Clarke a normal cone N (Y,y) by the cone enclosed by these arrows. The Clarke -4- tangent cone T (Y,y) is the set of all vectors making an obtuse angle with elements of N (Y,y) and the contingent normal cone N (Y,y) is zero. We conclude this subsection by mentioning a result due to Cornet that brings out the central position of the contingent cone. Theorem : Let Y be a nonempty closed set in R . Then T (Y,y) = n k k k {x e R : For all sequences {y } with y e Y, y ■*■ y, there exists k k k x e T (Y,y ) with x ■*■ x} . Proof: See Borwein-Strojwas [1985, Theorem 4.1]. 3. The Example We work in c , the space of sequences of real numbers converging to zero and endowed with the supremura norm. This is a Banach space with I as its dual (see, for example, Dunf ord-Schwartz [1957] for details and elementary properties). For any x,y in c , let x > y denote x. >_ y. for all coordinates i in N, the space of positive integers. Let c = {xec : x.>0 for all i in N}. £„ has an analogous meaning. o+ o i— 1+ The economy we present consists of c as the commodity space and two agents, a producer with production set Y «S c and a consumer with o e c as the endowment, X = {x e c : x„ > 0, x~ > 0} as the consurap- o o 2 — 3 — tion set and > as the preference relation on X. The production set Y is given by {tw: t > 0}VJ{ U A } _ M m meN -5- where A = {^ z} I " {- z + I A ~) ' {\ x + w}} mm m v -.. n Z n neN m [a,b) * A = {ta: t e [a,b) _~ R and a e A} z = (1, -1, 0, 0, .. . ) e c w = (0, 0, 1, -1, 0, ...) e c x = - e , . , n e N n n+4 and e. is a vector in c with all coordinates zero except for the ith l o coordinate which is unity. Note that Y is a technology capable of producing two outputs, the first and the third, and through the use of a countable number of inputs. More specifically, it consists of the technique w which can be operated at any nonzero level and the technique z which can be operated at any level — , m a positive integer. There is also the ra option of joint production of the first and third commodities but in this case "small" units of the third commodity require specialized inputs given by the elements of x . Lemma 3.1 Y is a non-empty, closed subset of c such that (i) Y ,c - {0}, (ii) Y \(-Y) = {0}, (iii) T (Y, -z) = {0}, (iv) 1 o+ K m T_(Y,0) = {tw: t > 0}, (v) N (Y,0) = I. . u — a 1 Note that (i) formalizes the impossibility of producing something from nothing and (ii) the property of "irreversibility." Furthermore, Y is not convex and does not satisfy the property of "free disposal," i.e., for any y e Y, y - (c ) d Y. For details of these properties, see the standard reference, Debreu [1959]. -6- Proof of Lemma 3.1 Nonemptiness of Y is is trivial and properties (i) and (ii) require routine computations. The shortest, though not necessarily the most transparent, proof of closedness, properties (iii) and (iv) can be had by the observation that Y satisfies all the assumptions required for Counterexample 3.1 in Treiman [1983]. (v) follows from Definition 2.4 and (iii). II Now observe that (0,0) e (c x c ) is a Pareto optimal allocation o o of our two agent economy. If not, there exists y e Y, y * 0, such that y _> 0. But this contradicts Lemma 3.1(i). Now the "no worse than" set at is given by c . Furthermore, N (c , 0) = -I. , . Since o+ C o+ 1+ N c (Y,0) = (T C (Y,0)) + = {p e li < 0}, we obtain = N_(Y,0) , (-N (c ,0)) = {pe£ : p. > (ieN) and p_ [p.} L L o+ 11 — J — 4 On the other hand, " = N (Y,0) , (-N (c .0)) = {pel : p. • (ieN)}. a a o+ 1- i — , '- v C The fact that -_ s , _ *J" is forbidden by the principal result in the finite dimensional setup in Khan [1987]. 4. Concluding Remarks Ioffe [1981] presents an alternative definition of the so-called Ioffe normal cone that may lead to a different object in infinite dimensional spaces from the one considered here. For any set Y . E and y e Y, denote such a cone by N (Y,y) where a -7- I k k k N (Y,y) = i{x e E: ZZ a sequence {y } with y ■*■ y, y e Y a Fe „ k k k k and x e N (Y , (y +F),y ) with x ■»• x} , and ..is the family of finite dimensional subspaces of E. However, it is easy to check that for the example presented in Section 3, N^Y.O) - I.. a i Borwein-Strojwas [1985] introduce the notion of compactly epi- Lipschitzian sets that includes the class of epi-Lipschitzian sets introduced in the context of the second welfare theorem by Khan-Vohra [1985]. It is easy to check that Y in the example in Section 3 is not compactly epi-Lipschitzian at the Pareto-optimal production plan con- sisting of zero. One simply needs the characterization of compact sets in c as given in Dunford-Schwar£-[1957 , IV. 13. 9]. o Finally, it is easy to manufacture examples of economies with an infinite dimensional commodity space in which the extension of the second welfare theorem fails in the sense that the normal cones, Clarke's or Ioffe's, at the Pareto optimal production and consumption plans have an intersection consisting solely of the zero vector. For one such example, simply take the negative of set presented in Klee [1963] as the production set plus initial endowment and the coordinate- wise ordering as the preference relation. The example presented in Section 3 is very different in spirit. Here the problem has to do with the Ioffe normal cone being "too large" rather than "too small." -8- References Allais, M. , 1943, A la recherche d'une discipline economique, vol. 1 (Ateliers Industria, Paris). Arrow, K. J., 1951, An extension of the basic theorem of classical welfare economies, Proceedings of the Second Berkeley Symposium (University of California Press, Berkeley). Borwein, J. and H. M. Strojwas, 1985, Tangential Approximations, Nonlinear Analysis 9, 1347-1366. Bouligand, G. , 1932, Introducton a la geometrie inf initesimale directe (Vuibert, Paris). Clarke, F. H. , 1983, Optimization and nonsmooth analysis (John Wiley, New York). Cornet, B. , 1986, The second welfare theorem in nonconvex economies, CORE Discussion Paper No. 8630. Debreu, G. , 1951, The coefficient of resource utilization, Econometrica 19, 273-292. Debreu, G. , 1954, Valuation equilibrium and Pareto optimum, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 40, 588-592. Debreu, G. , 1959, Theory of value (John Wiley, New York). Dunford, N. and J. T. Schwartz, 1967, Linear operators, Part I (Interscience, New York). Graaf, J. de Van, 1957, Theoretical welfare economies (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge). Hicks, J. R. , 1939, The foundations of welfare economics, Economic Journal 49, 696-712. Also Prefatory Note to reprint in 1984, Wealth and welfare: Collected essays on economic theory, vol. 1 (Basil Blackwell, Oxford). Guesnerie, R. , 1975, Pareto optimality in non-convex economies, Econometrica 43, 1-29. Ioffe, A. D. , 1981, Sous-dif f erentielles approchees de fonctions numerique, Coraptes Rendus Acad. Sci. Paris Ser. A-B, 292, 675-678. Ioffe, A. D. , 1984, Approximate subdif ferentials and applications I: the finite dimensional theory, Transactions of the American Mathematical Society 281, 389-416. -9- Khan, M. Ali, 1987, The Ioffe normal cone and the foundations of welfare economics, B. E.B.R. Working Paper No. 1388, University of Illinois. Khan, M. Ali and R. Vohra, 1985, Pareto optimal allocations of non- convex economies in locally convex spaces, B. E.B.R. Working Paper No. 1373, forthcoming in Nonlinear Analysis. Khan, M. Ali and R. Vohra, 1987, An extension of the second welfare theorem to economies with non-convexities and public goods, Quarterly Journal of Economics 102, 223-241. Circulated in 1984. Klee, V., 1963, On a question of Bishop and Phelps, American Journal of Mathematics 85, 95-98. Koopmans, T. , 1957, Three essays on the state of economic science (McGraw Hill, New York). Lange, 0., 1942, The foundations of welfare economics, Econoraetrica 10, 215-228. Malinvaud, E. , 1953, Capital accumulation and efficient allocation of resources, Econoraetrica 21, 233-268. Otani, Y. and J. Sicilian, 1977, Externalities and problems of non- convexity and overhead costs in welfare economics, Journal of Economic Theory 14, 239-251. Quinzii, M. , 1986, Renderaents croissants et equilibre generale, Ph.D. dissertation, Universite de Paris II. Samuelson, P. A., 1947, Foundations of economic analysis (Harvard University Press, Cambridge). Treiraan, J. S. , 1983, Characterization of Clarke's tangent and normal cones in finite and infinite dimensions, Nonlinear Analysis 7, 771-783. Yun, K. K. , 1984, Pareto optimality in non-convex economies and mar- ginal cost pricing equilibria, Proceedings of the First National Conference of Korean Economists. D/464 Ns * .* , Fig. la N (Y,y) a T K (Y,y) Fig lb HECKMAN LJ BINDERY INC. |s| JUN95 R,™„d To Picas? N. MANCHESTER, Bound -To -lkasc- | ND|ANA 46 g 62