1 © A PAPER READ BY WlLLIAM EDGAR SlMONDS AT AN OPEN MEETING OF THE CONNECTICUT STATE GRANGE, Hartford, Conn., Jan. 11, 1898. A substantial citizen of Connecticut, the head of a manufact- uring establishment, who averred with seeming candor that he had no prejudice in the matter, asked the substance of the above question of the present writer — in a letter. The question is one proper to be put, no matter what the motive of the questioner. Public moneys are not to be ex- pended except for good and sufficient reason — as a rule only for the public benefit. If there is no sufficient reason to justify the teaching of agriculture by a state institution it is time to close the doors of Storrs Agricultural College. If, on the other hand, a sufficient reason does exist it ought to be possible by search- ing to find it out. Let us enquire. The question which bars the way at the very threshold of the inquiry is, — do those fundamental and organic principles which lie at the foundation of the American social order justify the expenditure of public moneys for the education — of any sort — of the people in general? No one properly informed will doubt the competence of the jurist, Thomas M. Cooley, to answer that question. .At page 84 of “Cooley on Taxation” it is said: “It may be safely declared that to bring a sound education within the reach of all the inhabitants has been a prime ob- ject of American government from the very first. It was de- clared by colonial legislation and has been reiterated in consti- tutional provisions to the present day. It has been regarded as the imperative duty of the government; and when question 9 has been made concerning it the question has related not to the existence of the duty but to its extent. But the question of extent is one of public policy and addresses itself to the legis- lature and the people, not to the courts.” This statement by Judge Cooley is a self-evident truth to Americans. Education — the education of each individual so far as is practicable — is a matter of the highest possible public concern. The perpetuity of our free institutions rests absolutely upon education generally diffused; republican institutions are not self-executory; there are Central and South American Re- publics which have most admirable constitutions and laws on paper which will always remain mere paper so long as their present educational conditions continue. Education is the soil out of which has grown our marvelous material and social effici- ency. The control of education, even to forcing all the people to acquire it, and including the taxation of the whole community to furnish the means, is a power exercised by the state without question for hundreds of years. This exercise of a power abso- lutely requisite for the preservation of our free institutions, which has given justifying results — political, material and social — for centuries, and as to the propriety of which the people and the courts agree with substantial unanimity is something not now open to dispute. But granting the proposition just laid down, it may seem still possible to urge that however sound and justifiable it may be to expend public moneys for that kind of education which is useful to men in all callings of life, as for instance, in the teach- ing of reading, writing and arithmetic, it does not follow that it is justifiable to expend public moneys for teaching a special kind of education, of direct and immediate use only to a special class of people, such, for instance, as the science and art of agri- culture. The last sentence in the quotation from Judge Cooley’s re- marks deals with precisely such an attempted discrimination as that. He says — “the question of extent (of education) is one of public policy and addresses itself to the legislature and the people, not to the courts,” meaning that public moneys can properly and lawfully be expended for special education if the legislature sees fit so to order. 3 In examining other than superficially an attempted distinc- tion of the kind just mentioned it is proper at the outset to in- quire what education is, in its true essence, and why the body politic desires each individual to have it. There is a certain kind of basic education which is a practical necessity for every man in civilized society — that which comprehends reading, writ- ing and arithmetic. Every man needs that much of education in order that he may transact the most ordinary kinds of busi- ness. But the public does not specially care to furnish a man with that much of education simply because it is of personal value to him. The public interest in a man’s education is not a charitable thing; it is a matter of enlightened selfishness. The public only cares that a man shall have an education be- cause the having of it by him inures to the public good. That education which the public cares for necessarily includes this primary sort of education and it may, therefore, be dismissed from further consideration as regards the question with which we are now concerned. The present writer believes that education, in its real essence, consists in the acquirement of the habit of observation and study, and the habit of correct reasoning on whatThe mind perceives and what it conceives — to make which effective for most purposes needs to have added the capacity for clear and accurate expression. Incidentally, in the acquirement of an ed- ucation, one may lay away a great store of facts, but that, after all, is only an incident. The body politic desires the individual to have education because reason indicates and experience demonstrates that the great majority of those who have it are — by reason of the resulting development of their understanding and intelligence — devoted to the maintenance of free institu- tions ; they are apt to love order and justice and to give encour- agement to improvement and enterprise. Education is not, primarily and chiefly, the storing of the memory with facts. It is primarily and chiefly the improve- ment of man as a perceiving and reasoning machine. It is the improvement of the individual as a perceiving and reasoning machine, through education, at which the body politic aims. We are now ready to ask whether the science and art of 4 agriculture present a field suitable and profitable for observation and study, with phenomena and questions fit for and deserving of the application of man’s reasoning powers thereto. The question can be answered on the instant. The man who can name a better field for observation and study or he who can cite phenomena and questions which form better grist for a reasoner’s mill will well deserve the title of an original dis- coverer. The student of agriculture has a vast area of the whole kingdom of nature which not only invites but demands his observation and study, including the forecasting of the weather; the chemistry of widely differing soils, foods and plants under about all possible conditions of climate and temperature; the extremely subtle chemistry of cream setting and butter making; the physiology of plants and animals; irrigation and drainage with their effect on drought and moisture; the mystery of seed germination with the added mystery of growth to leaf, flower and fruit; determining which of the burrowing, creeping, walk- ing and flying things are friends to agriculture and which are foes ; the improvement of plants and animals through heredity, treatment and breeding; and so on and on. A catalogue of all the phenomena that a genuine student of agriculture must ob- serve and study would be extensive indeed ; and it is one of the plainest truths in the world that they furnish an unequalled grist for the application thereto of thought and reason, not only in their variety but in the value of the results, material and mental, possible to be obtained. The vital purpose of education is the training and energiz- ing of the faculties of observation and reason ; and the study of agriculture is quite as well adapted to the attainment of that purpose as any other study whatsoever. That proposition may have in it something of novelty for some persons, chiefly for the reason that education of the ad- vanced sort, heretofore, has mainly centered in a study of Greek and Latin with some addition of language, logic, philosophy, physics, physical science, mathematics and modern languages. The novelty of the proposition need not of itself distress any body. Certain of the physical sciences now have their acknowl- 5 edged places in the higher educational curriculum but it is not long ago that the ancient languages with the fringes just men- tioned — but not including physical science — had the field all to themselves and flouted the notion of sharing that field. The very beginning of the change, as regards the whole civilized world, seems to have been in 1T2T when Thomas Hollis, a Lon- don merchant, amidst jeers and sneers from the learned world of that day, persisted in his design to endow Harvard College with a “professorship of mathematics and physical science.” The establishment of this professorship at Harvard made no particular impression on the college world. The next step in a similar direction — this time distinctively recognizing industrialism — was tqken in 1816. Then Harvard College induced by the liberality of Count Rumford (originally Benjamin Thompson of Woburn, Mass.,) established a “new institution and professorship in order to teach by regular courses of academical and public lectures, accompained by proper ex- periments, the utility of the physical and mathematical sciences and for the extension of the industry, prosperity and happiness and the well-being of society.” The beginnings at Harvard under the Rumford professorship were not extensive; they con- sisted of four lectures a year; in 182T the professor resigned and the chair remained unfilled for seven years. The first sub- stantial addition of physical science to a college curriculum seems to have been made by the University of Virginia from 1818 to 1825 under Jefferson’s direct effort and as a result, in substantial measure, of what George Washington had said and written. The example set by this institution seems to have created a general demand for the teaching of those branches of learning in American colleges and it gradually came about. But practically it is only within the last seventy-five years that physical sciences have been permitted within the charmed circle which furnishes the higher education. The idea of getting the essential results of a genuine higher education by the teaching of agriculture — upon a good common school foundation — supplemented by economics, American po- litical history and thorough drill in the use of the English language, is far less novel to-day than was the idea of getting 6 it by teaching physical science seventy-five years ago. There- fore nobody needs to be disturbed by the proposition by reason of its novelty. The field of phenomena and fact offered by agriculture is broader and richer than that offered by any other single field whatsoever and it is a necessary consequence that when we have — as we shall have whenever the demand therefor is made effective — teachers as competent to instruct in that field as those now readily to be had for other fields, the results of the teach- ing of agriculture will be correspondingly rich and extensive. The possibilities of the case are, by no means to be judged by what has been accomplished at the very beginning of the enter- prise. In view of the great field of research and discovery there is in agriculture, the vast variety of phenomena it does and must continue to present for reasoning and experiment, and the value of the results both material and mental, possible to be obtained, it is presumptuous for the friend of the teaching of any other thing to assume or claim that there is any other field better fitted for that improvement of man as a perceiving and reason- ing machine which is the essential aim of education, so far as the public interest therein is concerned. It would be well for those who doubt the soundness of this proposition to review the investigations made by Lawes and Gilbert at Rothamsted dur- ing the last half century and their mental and material results; and a glance at Edward Atkinson’s letter on the “Marsden Process” in the “Country Gentleman” of Dec. 17, 1897, might be of value. Possibly what has already been said is sufficient to justify the expenditure of public moneys for the teaching of the science and art of agriculture but there are special reasons not yet mentioned which justify it. Agriculture is the great basic industry of the world. Most other industries are based and built upon it. Those industries which are not so based and built are yet dependent on it for their existence and prosperity. With the exception of the pro- ducts of the fisheries, and such game as comes from remaining areas of wildness, all our food is the product of agriculture. 7 With the slight exception of such furs, feathers, and skins as are taken from wild creatures, all our clothing is made from the products of agriculture. Food and clothing are the two great primal human necessities and they are the products of agricul- ture. Civilization is not possible without civilized agriculture. And no other industry can exist, in even a decent degree of effectiveness and proficiency, in the absence of agriculture. Thoughtful men, soberly mindful of the public welfare, have always recognized these truths. Washington showed his ap- preciation of them in his last message when he said: “It will not be doubted that with reference either to individ- ual or national welfare agriculture is a prime necessity. In proportion as nations advance in population and other circum- stances of maturity this fact becomes more apparent and renders cultivation of the soil more and more the object of pub- lic patronage. Institutions for promoting it grow up supported by the public purse, and to what other object can it be more dedicated with greater propriety ? ” And George William Curtis said: “ The test of national welfare is the intelligence and prosper- ity of the farmer.” Quotations to the same purport might be multiplied almost indefinitely but the words of these two wise and noble men suffice. Let some comparison be instituted between manufactures and agriculture, both as regards the United States and the state of Connecticut. By the census of 1890 (Census Abstract, p.141), there were 4,712,622 persons in the United States engaged in “manufacturing and mechanical industries,” a number which needs to be diminished one -half for the purposes of the present comparison (see page civ.-cvi., population vol., part 2,) exclud- ing 59,692 bakers, 205,028 blacksmiths, 105,747 shoe repairers, 45,988 builders and contractors, 104,951 butchers, 11,148 butter and cheese makers, 611,025 carpenters and joiners, 12,536 watch repairers, 494,696 dressmakers and milliners, 4,543 locksmiths and bell hangers, 1,176 hair workers, 158,701 masons, 218,988 painters and glaziers, 12,295 paper hangers, 19,962 photogra- phers, 38,932 plasterers, 28,206 plumbers, 7,023 roofers and slaters, 181,649 tailors and 12,713 upholsterers — in all 2,334,999 to be deducted, leaving the number of people engaged in man- ufactures 2,877,623, while the number engaged in agriculture (Census Abstract, p. 78) was (laborers, 3,004,061; apiarists, 1,733; dairy men and women, 17,895; farmers, planters and overseers, 5,281,557 ; gardeners, florists, nurserymen, etc., 72,- 601; stockraisers, herders and drovers, 70,729; other agricul- tural pursuits, 17,147 ; butter and cheese makers, 11,148) ; 8,476,911. And while the capital invested in “manufacturing and mechanical industries” (Census Abstract, p. 141), including twice the number of people actually engaged in manufactures, was 6,500 millions of dollars (16,525,156,486), that invested in agriculture (Census Abstract, p. 99) was some 16,000 millions ($15,982,267,689). These ratios do not obtain in Connecticut, but nevertheless the Connecticut ratios are not what they are generally supposed to be. The census of 1890 (Census Abstract, p. 99) gives Con- necticut farm valuations (land, fences and buildings, $95,000,- 595; implements and machines, $3,075,490; live stock, $9,974,- 618;) as $108,050,708, and the capital invested in “manufactur- ing and mechanical industries” (Census Abstract, p. 141) as $227,004,496. Eliminating, for reasons already stated, oneflialf of this as investment in “mechanical industries,” other than “manufacturing industries,” leaves the capital invested in man- ufactures in Connecticut little if any exceeding that invested in agriculture, a position that is strengthened by the Connecticut grand list for October 1, 1896, which gives “2,474,213 acres of land,” valued at $63,557,617, and “11,635 mills, distilleries, manufactories and investment in mechanical and manufacturing operations,” valued at $82,224,663. Increase both these items by the well-known margin between tax-list values and those which owners expect to realize under favorable conditions; decrease the larger sum by the amount which belongs to “me- chanical operations,” as distinguished from “manufacturing operations,” and the result will well accord with that deduced as above from the census reports. The census of 1890 (Census Abstract, p. 76,) gives the num- ber of people in Connecticut engaged in agriculture, fisheries and mining as 48,676. It elsewhere appears that something over 3,000 are to be credited to fisheries and almost none to 9 mining; so that Connecticut stands credited with upwards of 45,000 agriculturists, a figure that needs to be increased by add- ing bee-keepers, dairymen and daily women, cheese and butter makers, gardeners, florists, nurserymen, vine growers, stock raisers, herders and drovers. The 1890 census (Census Abstract, p. 141,) gives the num- ber of people in Connecticut engaged in “manufacturing and mechanical industries ” as 149,189, of whom (Pop. vol., part 2, p. cx.,) 85,804 are women. When this 149,189 is cut in half, to eliminate those engaged in “mechanical industries ” which are not “manufacturing industries,” and about one-third of the re- mainder are dropped to eliminate the children, the number of people engaged in manufactures in Connecticut exceeds little or not at all the number of people engaged in agriculture. But notwithstanding the vast preponderance of agriculture over manufactures in the United States at large, both in capital and workers, and the substantial equality of the two in Con- necticut, the earnings of manufacturing and other mechanical workers are in vastly the larger ratio. While some four and two-thirds millions of people engaged throughout the United States in “manufacturing and mechan- ical industries,” with a capital of 6,500 millions of dollars (Census Abstract, p. 141,) turned their labor into (19,372,487,283 gross product, less $ 5, 162, 044, 076 cost of materials=$4,165,- 393,207 net) some 4,000 millions of dollars of product, on the other hand some eight and a half millions of people engaged throughout the United States in agriculture, with a capital of some 16,000 millions of dollars (Census Abstract, p. 99), only realized ($2,460,107,454 farm products, less fertilizers $38,469,- 598=$2,421,637,856 net) some 2,500 millions of dollars which, at the manufacturing ratio — even with per capita equality of capital — would have been three times as much, or $7,513,793,276. And the returns for manufacturing labor in Connecticut are quite as much above those for agricultural labor as they are throughout the United States at large (Census Abstract, p. 99, 141). If these small agricultural earnings, taken with the fact that agriculture is the great necessary and basic industry, do not 10 constitute a justification for the fostering of agriculture by the expenditure of public moneys for the teaching of its art and science, then evidence and argument and reason are but vanity and vexation of spirit. If any man is inclined to say or to think that Connecticut can afford to neglect her agricultural interests in view of the wealth and prosperity which have come to her through manu- factures, it will be better than well enough to remember that manufactures can never in the future be, relatively to other industries, what they have been in the past. The capacity for the production of manufactures is almost unlimited, both here and elsewhere, but there is no possibility of a corresponding increase of a market for those manufactures. The present man- ufacturing capacity of the world is fully equal to its consuming capacity. Meanwhile other states in America, and foreign nations as well, are developing manufacturing industries with a rapidity which surely foretells a competition for Connecticut amounting to a limitation in the near future if not to distinct repression. The decline of the cotton manufactures of New England has already begun; that of heavy manufactures of iron will soon follow. Along with the general development of manufactures and commerce throughout the world, economic and social relations grow increasingly complex and delicate ; disturbances in those relations will in the future be of more frequent occurrence than heretofore; their influence will be more widely spread, and their disastrous effects more lasting. Agriculture, as a gainful industry, has an element of stabil- ity which will be lacking in the manufacturing industry of the future. The area of cultivable land is a fixed quantity while the population of the earth, under improved and improving hy- gienic conditions, is increasing at a rate unequalled in the world’s history. All these people must have food wrung from the bosom of mother earth and no man can add an acre of surface to the globe. It will be very strange if there are not periods within the next half century when that stability characteristic of agri- culture proves the mainstay of communities ordinarily depend- 11 ent in large part on manufactures. Neither Connecticut nor any other manufacturing state can afford to neglect its agricul- ture. After years of consideration and debate, Congress, in 1862, entered deliberately upon the policy of fostering agriculture by providing endowments for its teaching. In 1887 and 1890 Con- gress added to those endowments and the states generally have with equal deliberation availed themselves of the aid thus prof- fered. The condition of the development of this congressional enterprise down to 1896, is indicated, with some omissions, in a little pamphlet issued by the United States Department of Agriculture entitled “Statistics of Agricultural Colleges and Experiment Stations, 1896.” This pamphlet gives the following list of State Institutions enjoying the Federal grants under the Acts of Congress of July 2, 1862 and August 30, 1890. Alabama. — State Agricultural and Mechanical College, (Alabama Polytechnical Institute) at Auburn; State Normal and Industrial School, at Normal. Arizona. — University of Arizona, at Tucson. Arkansas. — Arkansas Industrial University, at Fayette- ville. California. — University of California, at Berkeley. Colorado. — The State Agricultural College, at Fort Col- lins. Connecticut. — Storrs Agricultural College, at Storrs. Delaware.— Delaware College, at Newark; State College for Colored Students, at Dover. Florida. — Florida Agricultural College, at Lake City; Florida State Normal and Industrial College, at Tallahassee. Georgia. — Georgia State College of Agriculture and Me- chanic Arts, at Athens; Georgia State Industrial College, at College. Idaho. — University of Idaho, at Moscow. Illinois. — University of Illinois, at Urbana. Indiana. — Purdue University, at Lafayette. Iowa. — Iowa State College of Agriculture and Mechanic Arts, at Ames. 12 Kansas. — Kansas State Agricultural College, at Manhattan. Kentucky. — Agricultural and Mechanical College of Ken- tucky, at Lexington; State Normal School for Colored Persons, at Frankfort. Louisiana. — Louisiana State University and Agricultural and Mechanical College, at Baton Rouge; Southern University and Agricultural and Mechanical College, at New Orleans. Maine. — Maine State College of Agriculture and the Me- chanic Arts, at Orono. Maryland. — Maryland Agricultural College, at College Park. Massachusetts. — Massachusetts Agricultural College, at Amherst. Michigan. — Michigan State Agricultural College, at Agri- cultural College. Minnesota. — The University of Minnesota, at Minneapolis. Mississippi. — Mississippi Agricultural and Mechanical Col- lege, at Agricultural College ; Alcorn Agricultural and Mechan- ical College, at Westside. Missouri. — College of Agriculture and Mechanic Arts of the University of the State of Missouri, at Jefferson City ; Lincoln Institute, at Jefferson City. Montana. — The College of Agriculture and Mechanic Arts, at Bozeman. Nebraska. — The University of Nebraska, at Lincoln. Nevada.- -Nevada State University, at Reno. New Hampshire. — The New Hampshire College of Agri- culture and the Mechanic Arts, at Durham. New Jersey. — Rutgers Scientific School (The New Jersey State College for the Benefit of Agriculture and the Mechanic Arts, at New Brunswick.) New Mexico. — The New Mexico College of Agriculture and Mechanic Arts, at Mesilla Park. New York. — Cornell University, at Ithaca. North Carolina. — The North Carolina College of Agri- culture and Mechanic Arts, at West Raleigh; The Agricult- ural and Mechanical College for the Colored Race, at Greens- boro. 13 North Dakota. — North Dakota Agricultural College, at Fargo. Ohio. — Ohio State University, at Columbus. Oklahoma. — Oklahoma Agricultural and Mechanical Col- lege, at Stillwater. Oregon. — State Agricultural College of Oregon, at Cor- vallis. Pennsylvania. — The Pennsylvania State College, at State College. Rhode Island. — Rhode Island College of Agriculture and Mechanic Arts, at Kingston. South Carolina. — The Clemson Agricultural College, at Clemson College. South Dakota. — South Dakota Agricultural College, at Brookings. Tennessee. — University of Tennessee, at Knoxville. Texas. — Agricultural and Mechanical College of Texas, at College Station; Prairie View State Normal School, at Prairie View. Utah. — The Agricultural College of Utah, at Logan. Vermont. — University of Vermont and State Agricultural College, at Burlington. Virginia. — Virginia Polytechnic Institute (State Agricult- ural and Mechanical College), at Blacksburg; Hampton Normal and Agricultural College, at Hampton. Washington. — Agricultural College and School of Science of the State of Washington, at Pullman. West Virginia. — West Virginia University, at Morgan- town; The West Virginia Colored Institute, at Farm. Wisconsin. — University of Wisconsin, at Madison. Wyoming. — University of Wyoming, at Laramie. The pamphlet gives “ value of permanent funds and equip- ment of land grant colleges, 1896,” as exhibited on the next two pages. Value of Permanent Funds and Equipment of Land-grant Colleges, 1896 . © 3 a 05 ©.S' £ S=l 3 ^ o' OO oo OO OOOr oooc OOOr ooon: ooooc OO 'O 'OOO oo : h :ooo do :cf :dod O O O O O L- oo_ :cq_ :©j©t- m'o'ido'HH :oo ioho NH® : 'H H n©ot~ ^oo® HOOin oohch :oooot|( ©OI>©Cq '©00©l> mot-on :©oo©h OOOOO 'OOO 'OtMOOOOOQOO ©oho© :ooo iroooooooomo lOCfliOOO t>rHCOI>cd iioio :oxooooor oo :oo :cq*idido5 © H • H H CQ CQ Cq & \ \ \ iH :hooo«ooo^o^®o , 'tt-SCOOOOmOOifflO ^tJOOCOLOOONOOXO ©OH© oqcoo ddt>© ©ox© ©cm© t'- d h i.'- COML’Ol «• ooo t-ooo dddd OOOOO OOOOK5 edoo 0 ©© IMOOO 050010 C0000500000 ©©©HOOOOO ©^©xinco©©_©in cq' O' o' h o' id o' o' oo' H© inH NON 05010 t>oo 5 IMO05 NCi o' OH HffiH 000050 oooooo dooHo OCONffl iO O in H O Hio'o'o'od cq h COOOOOOOGOO N000000050 oioHododdd H005000i0r-0 05©t~00005t>0 o' o' o' c? of id o' io“ oo' OlO (M whh HOOIOOOOOOOOOHH MOOHocooooooon 0 10 005 OeCOOiOOOOHM h'h'h oo ldooido cc'dfd'idafio' Hcsc-cqcoxcqcq o f — 1 05 cq o H (NIOIM05H HCOHH OOOOOOOOOOOOO OOOOO OOOOOO 'OOOO 'OOOO oooo 0 -o oooooooooooo oooooo : © © © © :oooo oddoocf ddddididdddddddodiddd :ddod :dddo ©CO©' OOOCOOKOOOOOOSOIOONOO : in qqqq ido'cdd cf of i o' o' o' t> i> m' o' o' o' t> c-' id h' cq' o' x' 10 ' : t> o' i> of cq'm'co'ad Cqn XMH iHHOhJlrft'JliM cqn ;H©in ;hhhh o h cq : in : cs®q a £<© §h bo x^S odH 83 C* u CO p 1 1 ® o §«2 £ 2,2 £ ¥ 5 05=2 d 3x flH i- cS © s 5 © cs ce C5© 050 i>© Is a. 9 ® CO ce ce ® o © a ® fg&SSS .2 © dg^cog^ocecs^ce.s H □ H rt H /I'l r-^ n — 1 , co o cq m o cc 05 o m m o o in d co h" d co QOiCOOH ®oomoe© cdo*t> cf idcq' mncsoox H co m m h h •oo :oo :oo ■ ©© :oo :©‘id : oh , >n mo coo ido c-o mo H®“ H>n HO oeoo OHO «»© coin os' © © _ tc a 03 a ■ 2 (§'S © CS ® •OOO :oot> :©HC5 ■oeoo :©cqx : m'co'cq' ■cqn . cq h o © m m o t>oi>t~© cq^oiocqin i>©'x'ed© HH©HX mo h © © ,a h 2 § -tw So® a -r-sPS mooo m ooo 05000 h'x'o'o' OXXH O © 3 © +S & &.rH rS ^ S 2 §ggog®^ |p 2 ‘ s § cs S 5 ®S ©3 Si-s 2 27 ; ^ uiu 'LJ r “ ^ ^ ‘d t> $l] p H H »rH M ® O CO CO ® ^ ^ h § ® 13 s s og © © Value of Permanent Funds and Equipment of Land-grant Colleges, 1896. ( Continued .) Miscella- neous equipment. § ;s fis \%%% ill; 1 niocf© : 20,437.17 2,000.00 3,000.00 ■8 IS ;§ ;S :© :c :O lr % \ 2.500.00 1.500.00 9.752.00 100.00 14,963.54 50,000.00 8,000.00 12,000.00 12.60 10,000.00 12,000.00 30.000. 00 65.000. 00 50,000.00 8,000.00 50.000. 00 10.000. 00 $1,055,607.00 Apparatus. : :1 iggggs :s liiri :i oooW X .cs 9,000.00 26, 9( 27,500.00 15.000. 00 30.000. 00 1,500.00 50.000. 00 2,000.00 200,000.00 10.000. 00 © © © 1C ctT rH th Buildings. $1,623,916.79 72,554.49 40.000. 00 82.500.00 20.000. 00 52.600.00 600,000.00 122,100.00 194.000. 00 33.000. 00 80.000. 00 159.400.00 314,707.91 157.308.00 474,561.26 139.000. 00 404.000. 00 135.000. 00 215.000. 00 25,000.00 1,000,000.00 100.000. 00 © © g X 00 to to g 1 m Farm and grounds owned by the insti- tution. $99,218.91 19.500.00 5,000.00 25.000. 00 5,000.00 14.250.00 80.000. 00 15.000. 00 15.000. 00 89.000. 00 106,370.00 48.320.00 26.800.00 15.000. 00 30.000. 00 52.000. 00 10.000. 00 40,000.00 2.750.00 150,000.00 3.270.00 © X eo“ © CC oc Land-grant of 1862 still un- sold. $155,000.00 : :8 © © X OS © «• Other permanent funds. $5,588,398.43 :8 : it i :o : |t| § :o § :g2 o ;io rH /OT 8 ig § ; g i t> : « : (M ; © © 1> © co“ 10 •<# 11 Other land-grant funds. ig ig I 230,000.00 © © to to © ' : ii ! ; < i i| 111 i i IP I i :§s III 111 135.500.00 344.312.00 285,000.00 90,000.00 302,000.00 © © ©