AMEBIC AN SOCIETY OF CIVIL ENQINEERS. INSTITUTED 1852. TRANSACTIONS. INTERNATIONAL ENGINEERING CONGRESS, 1904. THE CONCURRENT DEVELOPMENT OF TRAFFIC ON IMPROVED WATERWAYS AND ON RAILROADS. Congress Paper No. 30. By Edward P. North, M. Am. Soc. C. E., New York City, U. S. A. Discussion of the Subject by Leo Sympher, Berlin, Germany. Lionel B. Wells, Manchester, England. Th. Hoech, Kolberg, Germany. Edward P. North, New York City, TJ. S. A. NoTX.— Figures and Tables in the text are numbered consecutively through the papers and discussions on each subject. 5 1%^ TRANSACTIONS AMERICAN SOCIETY OF CIVIL ENGINEERS. J^ INTERNATIONAL ENGINEERING CONGRESS, $r 1904. Paper No. 30. THE CONCURRENT DEVELOPMENT OF TRAFFIC ON IMPROVED WATERV^AYS AND ON RAILROADS. By Edward P. North, M. Am. Soc. C. E., New York City, U. S. A. Although there is a general, if not exact, knowledge that the average yield of wheat per acre in the United States (13 bushels) is only about 43% of the yield in the United Kingdom, decidedly less than half the yield of Holland and Belgivim, 61% of the German yield, and 71% of that of France, the assertion is so constantly made that the phenomenal prosperity of this country is due to its superior fertility and unequaled natural advantages, that there is a nearly universal acceptance of this untrustworthy statement as to fertility. The habit of accepting authorities rather than refer- ring to facts has led public opinion nearly as far astray, if we take the output of coal and iron as a standard for productive wealth, as is usual. We find on comparing the United States with the United King- dom of Great Britain and Ireland, that, although we surpassed Great Britain in our make of pig iron in 1890, and mined more coal in 1899, having since made more pig iron than both England and Germany, and nearly equaled the product of the world in 1880, /^ 54106 476 TEAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. our output of iron per capita in 1900 was but 83% of the British, and we mined only 58% as much coal. The production of coal and iron in the United States, and in four European countries, both for equal areas and per capita in 1900, is set forth in Table 1, in which the area and population of Alaska and our non-contiguous islands have been omitted, and the area, production and population of Luxemburg, are added to those of Germany: TABLE 1. Production of Coal and Piq Iron. Coal Mined. Pig Iron Produced. Tons per square mile. Tons per capita. Tons per square uUe. Pounds per capita. United States 79.56 1 865.98 714. 161.24 2 073.24 3.17 5.49 2.65 .86 3.48 4.55 74.25 40.61 18.10 89.73 406 United Kingdom 489 Germany 332 155 Belgium 888 Here it is seen that our natural advantages are not sufficiently greater than those of our neighbors to explain our superior pros- perity. The possession of a large area of from cheap to free land has undoubtedly been an important factor in our increased popu- lation, and in our aggregate wealth, but the influence of this advantage has been greatly diminished since some time before our development gained such impetus, and our 14% of foreign-born population, arriving as it has lately almost entirely without capital, must have decreased our wealth per capita. Our population and wealth, as ascertained by our Census Bureau, have increased as follows for the years mentioned: Population. Aggr^ate Wealth. peT^pita 1870 38 559 371 $30 068 518 000 $779.83 1880 50155 783 42 642 000 000 850.20 1890 62 222 250 65 037 091000 1038.57 1900 76 303 387 94 300 000 000 1235.86 TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 477 The aggregate wealth has increased in a partially satisfactory ratio, but during the past 30 years the wealth of individuals in this country has been augmented by less than 60 per cent. In one great source of national wealth, however, viz.: Cost of transportation, which is not a natural product, the United States has an undisputed advantage over all other countries. Shortly before his death, Mulhall said that the average rate received by railroads of different countries for transporting a ton of freight one mile was, reduced to cents: United Kingdom, 2.80; Italy, 2.50; Russia, 2.40; France, 2.20; Germany, 1.64; Belgium, 1.60; Holland, 1.56; United States, 0.8. Acceptance of this statistician's figures as approximately correct, will immediately show that our low cost of internal transportation has probably been the principal cause of our augmented wealth; an augmentation that was greater in the decade ending with 1900 than during the 80 years preceding 1870. For not only does a low freight rate allow more to be divided between producer and consumer, but it has a more potent effect in inviting the production of commodities which with higher freight charges could not reach consumers; thus adding greatly to the employment offered to labor and capital. Data showing the beneficent effect of low freight rates on pro- duction have not been compiled, and any estimate is as liable to be governed by enthusiasm as by knowledge. But reliance is placed on "Poor's Manual," the United States Census returns, and those of the Bureau of Statistics, in submitting Table 2 as showing the direct contributions made by our railroads to the wealth of the Nation. The highest freight rate during this period was, in 1886, 1.067 cents, and the lowest, 1899, 0.726; since which time the rate has increased by about 5% to 0.764. If our rates had remained as in 1885 we would have paid $3 500 000 000 more for transporting our freight than we did, and if our freight rates had been equal to those of England, as stated by Mulhall, and with as large a volume of business possible at such rates, the cost would have been nearly $33 000 000 000 greater, or more than our increase in wealth during the last decade. There is no doubt that our railroad freight rates are the lowest in the world, and this is probably true also of our coastwise freight rates. Nor 478 TEArnC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. is there reason to doubt that the low cost of assembling and dis- tributing our commodities has had an important influence on their production and consumption. TABLE 2. Railroads of the United States. Years. 1886-89 1890-94 1895-99 1900-02 ^■2 53 2 596. 717.4 841.6 1 116. 60.528 83.524 6 104.. S71 148.915 -4 5 CD « iS'SS gg |i 602.4 764. 817.2 1 125. 113 116 124 133 « t. B •w 0,0 aj 03 o 0.995 0.915 0.783 0.755 Note.— Figures in 2d, 3d and 4th columns should be multiplied by 1 000 000. It is noticeable that we have reached this distinctive position as transporters with the highest wages paid for labor known, and until lately with a higher cost for materials than our neighbors and competitors. But both the high wages and high prices have, by stimulating production and consumption, added to the volume of freight moved and reduced its cost. One influence making for our general prosperity, which should not be lost sight of, is the universal desire for useful development, which, at least avowedly, has governed our financial projects. In 1840, the French economist, Michel Chevalier, wrote after a visit to this country: "There are certainly wild speculators, blind and desperate gamblers here also; but the objects of their schemes are almost always objects of utility. The spirit of speculation has strewn this country with useful works — canals, railroads, turnpikes, with manu- factories, farms, villages and towns; amongst us it has been more rash, wild and foolish and much less productive in useful results. It is with us mere stock -jobbing." A like view was held as late as May 26th, 1899, by The Engineer, which said: TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 479 "Another phase of the national character has not received half the attention it deserves. Such a man as Hooley is impossible in the United States. * » * The drift of speculation is different. Company mongering as it is practiced here has no existence in the United States. There is plenty of dishonesty and wrong doing, but it is wholly different in kind, and on the whole very much less harm- fuL Nay, indeed, it is very often indirectly beneficial. Thus, for example, the formation of a copper trust leads to the development of new sources of supply, and the ultimate cheapening of the metal." While it is possible the last quoted view would not be written to-day, the effect on our freight rates of over 100 years of steady devotion to developing our transportation and production should not be overlooked. And it is possible we are better able to endure some stock-jobbing of the Hooley kind than other peoples. Accompanying our general honesty of purpose we have had until lately freedom from those laws based on the theory of vested interests which are used both to prevent improvements and solidify monopolies, while our development has been aided by subsidies of various kinds from both State Governments and the General Govern- ment, to which local aid has often been added. Since our organization as a nation we have been pre-eminent for the energy and persistence with which we have developed and im- proved such aid to our wealth as is offered by water transportation. Improvement of the Mohawk west of Schenectady, the precursor of the Erie Canal, commenced with the adoption of our constitution, and concurrently the navigation of many streams falling into the Atlantic was improved and extended. Our canal-building era was virtuaUy inaugurated by the building of the Erie Canal connecting the navigable waters of the Hudson River with all of our Great Lakes under legislation by the State of New York in 1816. The great influence of this canal after its completion in 1825, with its branches, on land values, and its success as a channel for transporta- tion, led not only to more or less successful efforts to connect the James, the Potomac, the Delaware and the lakes above Niagara with the affluents of the Mississippi, and to many less important projects, but also to such an enlargement of the Erie Canal, author- ized in 1835, that the burden of boats could be increased from 40 to 240 tons. The improvement of rivers, mentioned above, was generally 480 TRAFFIC ON WATEBWAYS AND RAILROADS. made by companies operating under State Charters. The canals were generally built directly by the States in which they were situated, but were sometimes aided by National land grants or appropriations of money. Tolls were charged on both rivers and canals, and are still charged on some State Canals. The canals of the State of New York were not made toll free until 1883. Nearly all of these canals assisted materially in the development of the country through which they passed, but as few of them were navigable by boats of over 60 tons burden their value to the public quickly fell after the trains on competing railroads could carry more than the boats. But in their time they added largely to those margins over the cost of living which formed the capital necessary for building the railroads that sui)erseded them. The net area of lands granted by Congress to States, Territories and Corporations has been : In aid of railroads, 162 000 000 acres ; in aid of canals, 4 433 000 acres ; in aid of wagon roads, 2 554 700 acres ; 168 987 700 acres in all. On the 6th of April, 1802, the United States entered on its policy of River and Harbor Improvements with an appropriation of $30 000 for the improvement of the Delaware River. Up to March 3d, 1903, the sums appropriated on this account have reached the aggregate of $451 344 907.20. During the 58 years ending with 1860 but a little more than $16 500 000, or less than 4% of this sxim, had been appropriated. Taking the appropriations for these improvements by decades we have: 1861-70 $17 290 445.80 1871-80 60 440 417.96 1881-90 Ill 687 724.36 1891-1900 175 372 564.22 1901-March 3d, 1903 70 067 231.24 Approximately 55% of this sum has been expended on the improvement of rivers, 35% on harbors and 10% on canals. Mr. Alfred Noble, in his address as President of the American Society of Civil Engineers, June 9th, 1903, puts the total expenditure by Government for all harbors and waterways on the Lakes above Niagara, as $68 000 000. Of this sum probably a5out $40 000 000 has gone to Lake harbors. TRAFFIC ON WATEEWAYS AND RAILROADS. 481 Excepting a few instances, and then but for a short time, the rivers, harbors and canals improved and built by our Government have been absolutely free from charges for their use. While a large proportion of the money expended for improvements has gone to important centers, and the main lines of distribution, minor streams and small harbors, have not been neglected, as advised by many who vainly endeavored to direct public opinion. On the contrary, they have secured about their full share of consideration and the country has not been robbed by the city, to the loss of both. Although two short roads had been built or commenced before this, our trunk line railroad building was inaugurated consequent on "a meeting of a number of citizens to take into consideration the best means of restoring to the City of Baltimore, that portion of the Western Trade, which has lately been diverted from it by the introduction of Steam Navigation, and by other causes," held in the City of Baltimore, February 12th, 1827. This meeting resulted in a charter for building a railroad from Baltimore to the Ohio River. At substantially the same time, May, 1828, Congress appropriated $1 000 000 in aid of the Chesapeake and Ohio Canal, which was also to connect the waters of Chesapeake Bay with the Ohio. The Hudson and Mohawk Eailroad, which has developed into the New York Central and Hudson River Eailroad, was built to abridge the delay to canal traffic caused by the 22 locks between the Hudson River and the Schenectady level of the Erie Canal. The Boston and Albany was built to divert trade at the Eastern terminue of the Erie Canal from New York to Boston. The South Carolina road was projected to connect the harbor of Charleston, with the Ohio at Cincinnati. The first roads were built under special charters, which wore generally obtained without difficulty, except in such cases as the Pennsylvanian's objection to the Baltimore and Ohio reaching Pittsburg, on the no doubt honest plea that there could not be traffic enough for two roads. The menace to invested capital, now so strenuously insisted on, is a doctrine hardly 25 years old with us. Afterwards the more enlightened States passed general railroad laws, under which any persons filing the requisite papers became a body corporate, and could make the necessary surveys, and biiild as much road as they could finance. It is believed that only one 482 TRAFFIC ON AVATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. State, New York, ever penalized a railroad. The Utica and Schenectady, now a part of the New York Central and Hudson Uiver Railroad, was for a time prohibited from carrying freight, ■whether the canal was closed by ice or not, and the railroads which "formed that system paid canal tolls to the State on all freight -carried until 1851. The Government of the TTnited States gave a great impetus to railroad building by its legislation of September 20th, 1850, giving to a trunk line railroad between Lake Michigan and the Gulf of Mexico, substantially, six square miles of land for each linear mile built. This aid was so continued that every State and Territory west of the Mississippi and five States east of it, viz., Alabama, Illinois, Mississippi, Michigan and "Wisconsin, are in- debted to land grants, in a greater or less degree, for their trans- portation facilities. In aid of the Texas Pacific the land grant was 40 square miles, through the Territories, per mile of road. The Union and Central Pacific Railroads, with some of their branches, in addition to a land grant of 20 square miles per mile of road, amounting to nearly 32 000 000 acres, secured a loan of Government 6% 30-year bonds, varying with the difiiculty of construction from $16 000 and $32 000 to $48 000 per mile. This loan was in the aggregate $62 652 952, of which the Union Pacific received $27 236172 and the Central Pacific received $25 885120. These loans were repaid with outstanding interest in or about 1898, excepting a small default on the part of one of the branch roads. This combined aid was sufficient to induce the Union Pacific to build 535 miles in one year and 20 days. The accompanying diagrams. Figs. 1 and 2, made by F. W. Hewes, Esq., for Scribner's, "The American Railway," show the development of our railroads in 1850 with the influence of land grants in 1860 and 1870, the year after the first Pacific Railroad was completed. The direct and indirect influence of land and credit subsidies can be plainly seen by comparing these diagrams with a railroad map of to-day. They have probably hurried the settlement of the West by fully 20 years. But the fact that the Homestead law was passed in 1862 should not be overlooked in this connection. The British Government, according to the report of a "Com- TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 483 mittee on Contract Packets" made in 1863, subsidized its main lines of steamers "to afford a rapid, frequent and punctual com- munication with those distant ports which feed the main arteries of British commerce, etc."; refusing aid to, if not oppressing, internal communication. On the other hand, the Government of the United States, and also individual States, coimties and localities, subsidized its turnpikes, watercourses and railroads almost entirely for the improvement of internal communications, and neglected or oppressed our efforts to reach distant ports. England is pre-emi- nent as a ship building and ship sailing country, but its people pay the highest internal freight rates known. America now has a contemptible merchant marine, but its internal freight is handled at a rate unapproached in other countries. If, as has been lately urged, our Government was unable to develop at one time both foreign and internal communications, it has apparently adopted the most profitable alternative, though our annual payments to foreigners for over-sea freights are said to exceed the receipts from either Custom dues or the Internal Revenue tax. While the land subsidies granted by our Government in aid of turnpikes, canals, colleges, etc., have not generally hurried the lands granted into cultivation, it is noticeable that in the case of land granted to railroads the recipients have had a financial interest, strong enough to be a governing interest, in its quick distribution in small holdings, as the possible ultimate value of the land is secondary to the development of traffic on the road. And the Immi- gration Bureau is greatly aided in its efforts by low freight rates. As the cost of transportation is vital in the eyes of the prospective buyer, its cost has been kept down on non-competitive branches. The beneficent results following the practices of the land-grant aided raib-oads have not, however, prevented the "friends of the plain people" exhibiting fierce opposition to the development of our unsettled areas through the aid of land grants or other forms of subsidies. Under the combined influences of local. State and National encouragement with the competition from watercourses which were being increased in capacity, the mileage of our railroads has increased as given in Table 3, to which is added the population per mile, and the total of our foreign commerce in merchandise for the years mentioned : 484 TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 485 486 TRAFFIC ON WATEEWAYS AND EAILEOADS. TABLE 3. Total mileage. Bunt per decade. Inhabitants per mile of railroad. Foreign commerce, excluding gold and Sliver. 1830 23 2 818 9 021 30 626 52 922 93 282 166 664 175 170 194 334 203 132 ■2795 6 203 21 605 22 296 40 340 73 892 27'686 8 798 560 000 6 057 2 571 1 027 729 538 375.7 371.0 389.5 389.0 $134 391 691 1840 221 927 688 1850 317 885 252 1860 687 192 176 1870 828 730 176 1880 1 503 593 404 1890 1 647 139 093 1892 1900 2 244 424 266 1903 2 445 860 916 The niunber of inhabitants per mile of road is interpolated for 1892, when it was at the minimum; since that date the number has increased by almost 5 per cent. In the six years including 1893 and '98, only 11 640 miles were built or about 26.5% of the average yearly building in the preceding decade. This decreased building was partly due to a well known loss of commercial confidence during the years mentioned, and possibly to a rumored imderstanding between financiers interested in railroads, that no more competing lines should be encouraged. This understanding was arrived at before 1890, and the fact that in the six years above mentioned 46 646 miles of railroad were sold under foreclosure proceedings, will probably for some time aid in curtailing the extension of rail- roads in this country. The free development of railroad building and the fall in freight rates have also been impeded by the action of State Railroad Com- missions. The first of these, for the State of Maine, was appointed in 1853. There are now 34 of them. At first their action was doubtless beneficent, but in some States the appointment of com- missioners seems a perquisite of the railroads, and, as notably in the State of New York, it seems virtually impossible for an oppressed community to secure better accommodations or lower rates by investing their own money in a raiboad which may reduce the profits of an existing line. All such efforts being apparently held by the commissioners, as well as the stockholders of existing lines, to be a piratical venture and a speculative strike of more or less colossal magnitude. TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 487 The value of our Railroad Commissions generally to vested interests, may be partly judged from the subjoined table showing the density of traffic, freight rates, etc., for 1900 in the 8 groups into which "Poor's Manual" divides our railroads. TABLE 4. •• w r t-i 'ii •6 p :2 M ©■ A o d H d a i si* H M ■3.H Hi 1^ Groups: No. of States T. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. with commis- sions 6 66 465 5 592 017 1 116 530 IT 100 17-) 4 2*9 015 15 985 581 5 268 205 8 791983 5 230230 8 929 832 5 768 060 10 462 835 5 609 315 6106128 3 Area 717 060 Population Miles of R. R 8 020 479 7 501 22 385 41 138 21917 16 211 37 530 32165 15 486 Tons per mile of R. R 6980 1.16 17 951 0.61 5 521 0.69 2 879 0.69 4167 0.83 1936 1.00 2628 0.95 1 791 Ton-mile rate 0.97 Population per mile of R. R.... 715.3 764.2 388.6 401.1 550.8 278.8 289.8 195.0 Square miles per mlleof K. R.... &86 5.21 6.05 12.24 1420 20.47 18.94 46.30 This table is not submitted as conclusive, but it may be noticed that the railroads of New England, dominated by the most respect- able and highly appreciated Commission, exact the most onerous charges on traffic known in this country, and have driven nearly all heavy manufacturing out of their territory. The Interstate Commerce Commission is directed by the General Government to take cognizance of discriminations and combina- tions in restraint of transportation as administered for the general good, but it is not empowered to encourage railroad building as a remedy for injustice. In fact, the Government of the United States has no right of eminent domain in any State of the Union, and as it has alienated nearly all its land, cannot encourage railroad building outside of the Territories.* Note. —The author is indebted to Mr. Brooks Adams for the following correction: "The United States Hovernment has plenary powers over interstate commerce, and may. therefore, build any roads it likes, provided they are interstate; may charter cor- porations; may take State roads, and may police them." 488 TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. A considerable percentage of the 451 million dollars appropri- ated by the General Government for the improvement of rivers and harbors, has been expended on isolated or semi-isolated projects, where the statistics covering the consequent development of traffic are not available without great research. In other cases like the 18 500 000 net tons of freight traffic found 12 years ago on the Hudson River, or the 11 610 000 tons of freight carried on 11 improved tributaries of the Ohio in 1902, as reported by the Depart- ment of Commerce and Labor, no idea of the cost of freightage is given. Nor are the rates charged on the total traffic of the Great Lakes given in the report of the same Department, which gives the average arrivals and departures in domestic trade for the two years 1902-03 for which statistics have been gathered as 74 390 000 and 74 340 000 net tons of f reiglit. During the same two years the average imports of foreign merchandise at these Lake ports have been valued at $61 187 000 and the exports at $88 076 000. As the natural depth at most harbors on the Great Lakes was about 6 ft., and not more than 8 ft. could be carried over the St. Clair Flats, above Detroit, this large traffic would be impossible without the increased depths made by the expenditures authorized by the various River and Harbor bills. The first appropriation, 1823, was for the harbor of Erie. Ohio followed in 1825 with appro- priations for Cleveland and Fairport. Buffalo did not get an appro- priation from the General Government until 1826; Chicago in 1833, and the St. Clair Flats received its first appropriation, $20 000, in 1852. In the last mentioned year, Congress gave the State of Michigan 750 000 acres of public land in aid of a canal connecting Lake Superior with Michigan, Huron and Erie. This canal, built for the State by an incorporated company to which the land was trans- ferred, was opened June 18th, 1855, with two locks of 9 ft. lift, each 350 by 70 by Hi to 12 ft., to overcome the 18 ft. difference of level at the Falls of St. Mary, or, as it is generally known, the "Soo." The General Government took over this canal from the State of Michigan, June 9th, 1881, and completed the "Weitzel" lock, 515 by 80 by 17 ft., September 1st, 1881, and the "Poe" lock, 800 by 100 by 22 ft., August 3d, 1896. The Canadian Government had in the mean- time built a lock 900 by 60 by 22 ft., opened September 9th, 1895. TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 489 These figures are from the "Statistical Eeport on Lake Commerce," 1903. The depths of Lake channels, in general, have been less than the depths on the lock sills. Tolls amounting to $778 128.41 were collected on the 19 414 242 net registered tons of shipping passing through the canal in the 26 years, including 1880, that the canal remained State property. They were 6 cents per net registered ton until 1871, 4i cents until 1879, and after that 3 cents. Since 1880 the traffic through both the American and Canadian locks has been free. We are fortunate in having the net tonnage passing through the canal from its opening, and since 1887 the IT. S. Engineers in charge of the canal, with the co-operation of those in charge of the Canadian Canal, have kept and published statistics which are among the most valuable in the history of transportation. From these data Tables 5, 6 and 7 have been compiled. TABLE 5.— Freight Tons Passing the Sod. Year. Tons. Total Value. Value per Ton. 1851.... 12 600 88 000 585 000 1568 000 8889 000 2S 403 065 34 674 487 $1 675 000 6000 000 13 000 000 30 000 000 128 000 000 289 916 865 349 405 014 $183.00 68.00 22.00 19.00 14.50 10.80 10.08 1861 1871 1881 ;;!.■.■;■■■■ 1891 1901 1908 T^BLE 6.— Net Eegistered Tonnage Passing the Locks at Sault Ste. Marie (The Soo). Year. Tonnage. Year. Tonnage. Year. 1876 Tonnage. f Year. Tonnage. Year. Tonnage. 1856 106 296 1865 409 062 1259 534 ! 1886 3 086 937 1896 16 806 781 1866 101 458 1866 458 680 1S?6 1 541 676 1886 4 219 897 1896 17 249 418 1867 180 820 1867 556 899 1877 1489 216 1887 4 897 698 1897 17 619 988 1858 219819 1868 482 563 1878 1667136 1888 5 130 659 1898 18 622 7.')4 1859 858 642 1869 624 885 1879 1677 071 1889 7 221936 1899 21 9.'i8 847 1860 403 657 1870 690 826 1880 1734 890 1890 8 454 486 1900 82 316 884 1861 276 689 1871 752 101 1881 2 092 767 1891 8 400 686 1901 24 626 976 1862 859 612 1872 914 735 1882 2468 088 1898 10 647 208 1902 31955 582 1868 507 434 1878 1204 446 1883 2 042 259 1898 8 949 754 1908 87 786 444 1864 671488 1874 1070 867 1884 8997 887 1894 18110 366 490 TRAFFIC ON WATERWAYS AND R.ULROADS. i W"fr^*i "-^s :g2 ^2 SS»— o^vico Mc ^§S3 >C5— to •- S) :c o OS5 s 3d to CJt &3 c: 00 02 IXCC-l*- l^CSI-'CT . -} -^ »} C5 f3 t cc *^ :cots;=ts «.£C;S30 >i&ooot& cn<{'ts>E> iiik isgtg SSSc 5(xacoDOO -Q-^acoo ^ OCSoSiE. l-i>Ui:05 *»O!0S^ -^QC-IO 3 X -^ lO --S iS:x3 S.f' p o O O O ^ 1-1 o o o V'?D':^coio ccot'ctco 5 5 5£g 1^ -" 2 „ 2^2.* ciH-x xei^o JXCCO'*^ C503w Ml KK«S xSS3 otEESsS Soox-j tsxo-^ ^^ (a CD VI «cocnver ton-mile. . . 781 Population per square mile 16,89 537.59 Population per mile 01 railroad Gkoijp I. Miles of railroad Freight hauled Length of haul Rate per ton-mile. . . Population per square mile Population per mile of railroad 60.42 670.99 6 476 30 186 233 59.81 1.56 7 Oil 41 5294 970 69.40 1.37 70.82 670.48 7 659 42 183 240 79.99 1.24 7 8« 54 337 873 82.94 1.16 84.24 718.06 7 738 54 260 898 85.91 1.18 Group n. Miles of railroad operated 17 794 189 619 916 91.50 0.84 19 314 302 5S0 992 84.89 0.82 121.36 782.22 21 890 337 037 563 89.52 0.71 24 710 413 573 1»1 105.86 0.61 146.80 692.27 23 425 Freight hauled 527 874 019 Length of haul 105 30 Rate per ton-mile. . . 067 Population per square mile 100.88 Population per mile of railroad 774.39 Geoup III. Miles of railroad operated Freight hauled Length of haul Rate per ton-mile. Population perj square mile 46.01 Population per mile' of railroad. 446.31 42 1991 182 124 264 144.44 0.89 50 936 204 659 671 136.28 0.79 54.10 284.48 53 732 215 784 762 138.10 0.76 58 087 820 631700 137.73 0.69 64.80 275.67 60154 896 044 799 138.42 0.70 Group IV. Miles of railroad operated ! Freight hauled i Length of haul \ ■ Rate per ton-mile . . . ' Population peri square mile 28.63 Population per mile of railroad. 747.98 10 806 15 888 029 107.77 1.85 14 556 35 185 795 111.46 1.03 27.65 5C9.68 20 443 45 800 646 185.72 0.79 22.625 65 547112 161.69 0.69 82.77 388.60 24 784 60 168 159 160.49 0.78 512 DISCUSSION ON AVATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. Mr North. TABLE 12— (Conti7iued). Groop V. Miles of railroad oi)erated Freight hauled Length of haul Rate per ton-mile . . . Population per square mile Population per mile of railroad 27.04 9 249 19 197 613 102.43 1.43 9 569 780 161 98.38 1.04 32.36 788.73 10 329 26 779 193 137.37 0.89 9 694 40 391 899 141.35 0.83 921.12 Geoup VI. Group VIII. Miles of railroad operated Freight hauled Length of haul Rate per ton-mile. . . Population per square mile Population per mile of railroad 1.94 271.81 5 835 5 503 588 161.74 3.27 7 376 937 953 191.53 1.56 3.17 307.61 10 849 11 690 185 289.29 1.81 13 576 23 524 092 249.55 0.97 240.17 10 812 50 268 899 145.58 0.83 Miles of railroad operated 19 541 27 690 116 132.32 1.74 28 356 38 272 891 176.26 1.35 10.86 291.92 31 744 43 655 714 166.88 1.34 32 550 63 015 069 197.01 1.00 13.72 321.44 36 712 Freight hauled 93 844 012 Length of haul 179 37 Rate per ton-mile,. . 1 00 Population per square mile 8.43 416.94 Population per mile of railroad Group VII. Miles of railroad operated 11 666 16 835 340 159.15 1.46 20 859 81 633 0(M 301.33 1.06 8.17 338.60 33 507 53 918 571 199.77 1.04 33 370 61411037 182.27 0.95 10.02 261.28 25 892 Freight hauled 77 831 015 Length of haul 201 95 Rate per ton-mile. . . 91 Population per square mile 5.01 347.35 Population per mile of railroad 12109- 23 334 944 224.92 1.16 The only noticeable improvement in England for over half a century that competes has been the Manchester Ship Canal. And Mr, Wells tells us that in 10 years the shipping entering the Mersey has increased by 66%, only about one-third of this increase going into the canal. It does not seem possible that the railways between Liverpool and Manchester, which joined in the fight against the canal, have had no increase of traffic through the business de- veloped by this increase of tonnage. Comparing the services per capita in 1882 and 1900, as men- tioned above, it will be seen that the service of 1900 would have DISCUSSION ON WATERWAYS AND RAILROADS. 513 cost US $7.10 more per capita if the rate of 1882 had been charged. Mr. North. This is not only an addition of this amount to the net income of every man, woman and child, but it also gives a bounty of about 50 cents per ton on the consumption of our yearly products. And while our area is an important factor in our long hauls, the low cost of the service enters largely into both the length of haul and the quantity of our marketed products. It is doubtful if under the artificially high cost of transportation in Great Britain the adult males in that country could pay for a service of 1S6* ton-miles. / / / 9" Apparently no more economies in transportation in the service / of the public are to be made by our railroad companies. For over 20 years a propaganda has been preached for restrictions to rail- road building. The chief advocates are those who at one and the same time demand cheapness and denounce "ruinous competition." They have been successful in convincing the greater part of the ^-oters in the City of New York that a canal bringing 8 000 000 tons to their wharves will be of more service than one bringing 20 000 000 tons. And they are hoping to prevent inconvenient competition by curtailing or abolishing those appropriations for the improvement of our water courses that have in the past paid profits on expendi- ture unapproached by other large investments, either ISTational or private. Our legislators, executives and publicists are proposing plans for control which do not even suggest a reduction in the cost of transportation. None of them have the courage to advocate a return to our one time free railroad building, which would allow the cost of freightage to be governed by the best management rather than by the desires of stoclcholders. The nation that will take our wealth from us by cheaper trans- portation is not yet apparent, but its unexpectedness may be partly gauged by reference to an assertion made by the late A. S. Hewitt, in 1870, when our freight rate was possibly the highest in the world, that England would probably continue to make more than half the pig iron of the world. ^