SENATE 63d Congress \ 1st Session / / Document l No. 131 COMPULSORY WORKMAN’S COMPENSATION LAW ADDRESS OF * HON. GEORGE SUTHERLAND UNITED STATES SENATOR FROM UTAH TO THE THIRD ANNUAL CONVENTION OF INTERNATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF CASUALTY AND SURETY UNDERWRITERS CHATEAU FRONTENAC, QUEBEC, CANADA THE ECONOMIC VALUE AND SOCIAL JUSTICE OF A COMPULSORY AND EXCLUSIVE WORKMEN’S COMPENSATION LAW w PRESENTED BY MR. CHAMBERLAIN July 14, 1913. — Ordered to be printed 7 Jk (4 4.M-.F 33 [. L COMPULSORY WORKMEN’S COMPENSATION LAW. Mr. President and Gentlemen of the Convention : Conditions produce opinions which, when sufficiently potential, find expression as law. Changed opinions naturally result from changed conditions, and as conditions are never at a standstill it follows that the law of one generation never quite satisfies the sentiment of the generations which follow. It is the business of the lawmaker to de- termine — and sometimes determine at his official peril — out of the multitude of opinions that from time to time develop which of them are sufficiently substantial to be given statutory expression. The general demand for a wiser and juster adjustment of the burden re- sulting from accidental injury sustained by workmen in their employ- ment presents to the legislator one of these problems, the correct solu- tion of which not only requires him to know what is demanded but to understand the conditions out of which the demand arose. Blackstone, writing 150 years ago, includes master and servant, along with husband and wife, parent and child, guardian and ward, in a class whose reciprocal obligations result from status rather than from contract. The explanation of this classification is probably to be found in the fact that prior to Blackstone’s day the servant’s du- ties were generally of a domestic character, but with the vast exten- sion and diversification of industry the relationship of employer and employed has radically changed, until it is no longer predominatingly domestic in character but has become more generally a relation apart from the household. As a consequence, the contractual conception of the relation of each to the other has more and more supplanted that which originally flowed from the notion of status. This has been strikingly manifested in the evolution of the law of liability for per- sonal injury, which has resulted, until recent years, from judicial as distinguished from legislative activity, and nearly every development of which is rooted in the notion of contract. The rule by which the master was held liable for an injury to the servant, caused by the former’s negligence, was based upon his im- plied contract to furnish safe appliances and a safe place to work, to provide safe methods and to exercise reasonable care to protect the latter from injury. The countervailing rule that the servant could not recover where the injury resulted from observed or clearly ob- servable dangerous conditions was based upon the implied under- taking of the servant to assume the risk of such conditions — the fel- low-servant doctrine being probably a branch of this general rule. 3 4 COMPULSORY WORKMEN'S COMPENSATION LAW. These various rules of the common law originated at a time when all the circumstances of the employment were of a simple and open character ; but as complicated machinery has more and more taken the place of hand labor, as the powerful and indirectly applied forces of steam and electricity have been substituted for the simple and direct power furnished by water and horses, as the master has been more and more removed from direct contact with the servant through the device of corporate organization and the interposition of supervising agents, as the servants of the same master — originally few in number and working side by side — have grown to an army, no longer ac- quainted with one another, these rules have come to be largely with- out justice or justification. From time to time they have been modi- fied by judicial interpretation and the invention of exceptions. In recent years this process has been accelerated by legislative action. Thus, because of the injustice of relieving the master from liability where the negligence in question was that of a superior servant o"r of one engaged in a separate and distinct class of work, the follow- servant doctrine has been modified bv the introduction of the vice- principal and separate-department doctrines. As it has been borne in upon the consciousness of the legislator that the laborer in modern industry in this day of sharp competition is not quite free to accept or refuse work at his pleasure, the doctrine of assumption of risk has been modified or overthrown ; and in this way the former common- law defenses of the master have been abrogated or have undergone radical alteration. The whole process indicates that the vice of applying the common-law system to modern industrial conditions arises not so much from its details as from the inapplicability of its fundamental doctrines. Legislation which continues to recognize the general applicability of the system and attempts by the introduction of modifications and exceptions to reconcile it to the utterly different conditions of our day is not a remedy but a palliative merely. Thoughtful students of the subject have come to recognize that what is needed is not to lop off dead or superabundant branches, but to cut up the tree by the roots and substitute for the entire growth of em- ployers’ liability the new system of workmen’s compensation. We have thus swung round the circle from the ancient notion of the master’s duties based upon status, through that of employer’s liability based upon contract and its statutory modifications, to the broader conception of the absolute right of the injured workman to compensation from the enterprise in which he is employed and to whose success he contributes his work for the sake of the wages as the owner contributes his capital for the sake of the dividends, and we are brought round again to the idea of status, only it is now the status of industry and workman instead of the status of master and servant. In this new conception there is consistently no place for any part of the old common-law system. Workmen’s compensation and employers’ liability proceed upon wholly different, if not irreconcilable, principles. Employers’ liabil- ity for personal injury is based upon negligence, against the existence of which, by implication of law, the employer has contracted. Work- men’s compensation is based entirely upon the relationship which the injured workman bears to the employment in which he is injured. While statutes have been passed depriving the employer of the common-law defenses or modifying them to a more or less radical ex- COMPULSORY WORKMEN'S COMPENSATION LAW. 5 tent, under all of them the necessity of showing negligence on the part of the employer remains. The inherent evils of the common- law system of liability for negligence are generally conceded, among the most prominent being: (1) That the enforcement of the em- ployee’s rights results in great waste and in great delay. The employee, being generally unable to pay any counsel fees in the event of failure, is compelled to submit to the payment of exorbitant con- tingent fees in the event of success. Litigation, because of the crowded condition of the court dockets and for other reasons, is pro- longed indefinitely. In the meantime the employee, if able to work, must often live in enforced idleness because his old employer will not furnish him work and others from sympathy with the employer do not do so. The result is that even if a large or extravagant judgment is obtained, more than half of it goes to the lawyer and for other expenses, and the expenditure of the remainder is largely anticipated by living expenses. (2) Upon the happening of an injury a condi- tion of antagonism between employer and employee at once arises. The employee, naturally desirous of securing as large a payment as possible, consciously or unconsciously, exaggerates the facts tending to show the employer’s negligence, and the employer upon his side exaggerates the facts tending to minimize his own negligence or emphasize some affirmative defense. Out of this double distortion the truth does not appear. If the employee is honest enough to tell the exact truth he may not recover and too often he does recover by deliberate untruth or by coloring the facts with the ingenious aid of counsel. Thus conscientious truth suffers and dishonesty is re- warded. The measure of damages is so uncertain, so much is de- pendent upon the bias or caprice of individual jurors, that verdicts for similar injuries differ in amount to the widest possible extent. (3) In a large proportion of the cases, particularly in death claims, the recipient of the money resulting from settlement or judgment is wholly inexperienced in handling considerable sums, and it is often quickly frittered away or lost in unwise investment, in which case, as well as where no recovery can be had at all, the unfortunate em- ployee or his dependents, in case of death, become to a greater or less degree a charge upon the charity of society. In addition to this, the litigation is carried on at great public ex- pense. In the United States probably one-fifth of the time of courts i and juries is taken up with this class of litigation. The foregoing may be exemplified by the following case, the facts of which are not at all out of the ordinary : An engineer on a western railroad was killed, leaving a widow and three young children. Before the body of the dead engineer had been laid away the widow was importuned by an agent of a firm of personal-injury lawyers to put her case into their hands, upon an agreement to pay them 50 per cent of the amount recovered. This she did, and suit was brought. At the end of three years of litigation a judgment of $10,000 in her favor was paid. Of this amount she received $5,000 and her lawyers the other $5,000. In addition to the $10,000 the litigation had cost the railroad company, as nearly as can be estimated, $2,500 more. It had cost the State $625, taking a proportionate part of the salary of the judge, the expense of maintaining the court, the fees of the jurors, and so on. Thus it will be seen that in order to get $5,000 into the hands of the widow and children the railroad and the State 6 COMPULSORY WORKMEN'S COMPENSATION LAW. together had expended $13,125. Long before the judgment was paid the widow had exhausted her financial resources and had been com- pelled to do hard and unaccustomed labor in order to support her- self and family. A part of the money which she received went to pay debts which she had incurred. She was a woman wholly unac- customed to business and unfamiliar with investing money. She was surrounded by friends who knew precisely what she ought to do with the money, and at the end of 18 months she found herself without a dollar, the very existence of herself and children dependent upon such poorly paid work as she could do and upon public or private charity. And yet this widow was far more fortunate than the vast majority of her sisters similarly situated, more than half of whom receive no compensation whatever. An exhaustive inquiry carried on by the Federal commission ( appointed to investigate this subject discloses that the average amount paid by the railroads in the United States to the dependents for a j death claim is $1,221, from which lawyers’ fees and other expenses * must also be deducted. These are some of the evils of the system of employers’ liability. How can they be most effectively and justly eliminated? It is obvious that a mere alteration of the details of the common law will not be of any considerable economic value. It is true that by abrogating or modifying the common-law defenses the field of the employee’s opportunity for successful litigation is broadened, but the field of opportunity for waste is at the same time also extended. It is likewise true that some employees who are not now able to recover solely because a negligent employer can establish a good defense will under these alterations be able to recover, but it is safe to say that more than one-half of the workmen who are injured and a still greater proportion of the dependents of those who are killed will still be unable to recover because of their inability to establish the employer’s negligence or because the accident is due to the em- ployee’s sole negligence or to the ordinary risks of the employment. Under the simple conditions which at one time existed the majority of accidents which happened were due to somebody’s want of care, because there were no inherent dangers in the use of manual tools and simple appliances in the usual way and under the usual circumstances; but in this day of complex appliances, rapidly moving machinery, and the press and stress of abnormal hurry, a very large proportion of all accidents are due to general conditions, for which no one is specifically to blame. At a time when, if accidents happened, they were generally the result of clearly ascertainable negligence, there was both wisdom and justice in making negligence the controlling element in the right to recover ; but now that the conditions under which the work of our day is performed are such that the greatly preponderating propor- tion of accidents are due to inherent dangers, or to a complex and confusing set of circumstances in which negligence is either not present or not traceable or exercises only a minor influence, the element of negligence has ceased in fact to constitute the usual determining cause of industrial accident, and there has resulted a growing opin- ion that it should no longer be regarded in law as the determining factor controlling the employee’s right to recover. The German accident statistics, which have been gathered with the most painstaking care, in this connection are most illuminating. COMPULSORY WORKMEN^ COMPENSATION LAW. 7 These statistics are gathered from the experience of a vast body of workers, aggregating to-day many millions, and they cover many hun- dreds of thousands of accidents. In the year 1887 the percentage of accidents which were due to the negligence of the employer was 20.47 per cent; those due to the negligence of the employee, 26.56 per cent; due to the contributing negligence of both, 8.01 per cent; and due to the inevitable risks of the industries and other causes, 44.96 per cent. In the year 1897, 10 years later, there was due to the negligence of the employer 17.30 percent ; to the negligence of the employee, 29.74 per cent; of both, 10.14 per cent; and to the inevi- table risks, etc., 42.82 per cent. Ten years later, in 1907, the num- ber due to the fault of the employer was 16.81 per cent ; to that of the employee, 28.89 per cent; to both parties, 9.94 per cent; and to the inevitable risks, etc., 44.36 per cent. Applying these figures to our own country — and there is no reason why they should not approximately apply — under the most liberal j employers’ liability law which we have, recoveries may be had by employees in considerably less than one-third of the accidents which happen, the remainder, more than two-thirds, being due to inevitable risk, the sole negligence of the employee, or other causes not involv- * ing negligence on the part of the employer. The labor bureau of Wisconsin has given the result of their inves- tigation of 318 representative cases of personal injury, in which it was found that 52.10 per cent were due to the hazard of the industry, A rather careful examination of such statistics as we have in this country convinces me that on the average approximately one-half of all accidents resulting in personal injury or death are due to the hazard of the industry and that not more than 25 per cent are due to the sole or contributing negligence of the employer. It must be apparent, therefore, that no matter how the system of employers’ liability may be modified, so long as the employer’s negligence re- mains as a prerequisite to recovery, either by far the greater pro- portion of all injuries must go without compensation or many verdicts must be based upon untruthful evidence or rendered in disregard of facts. Neither alternative is to be contemplated with satisfaction. The truth is we have been thinking in terms of negligence so long that it is difficult to rid ourselves of the notion that personal fault on the part of somebody is always a necessary prerequisite to a just lia- bility. The subject must be approached from new angles. The great industries of to-day are engaged in producing commodities or in ren- dering services for the general public. The consumers of these com- modities or the recipients of these services are justly obligated to pay what they cost plus a fair return upon the investment. The w T ear and tear of machinery, the cost of the labor employed, every item of ex- pense entering into their production or rendition is properly taken into consideration in arriving at the amount to be paid. The injury of a workman resulting in loss of earning ability or death as truly enters into the cost of production as the breaking of a piece of ma- chinery, only in the latter case the industry bears the expense, no matter how the loss occurs, while in the former the industry pays when the owner is at fault, and the workman pays in every other case. There is no reason why the industry should not bear the expense in all cases, collecting it in the last analysis from the consumer just as it collects every other item of expense entering into the production. 8 COMPULSORY WORKMEN^ COMPENSATION LAW. In earlier times, when few men were employed by the same em- ployer and few were engaged in each occupation, the number of accidents and consequently their cost could not be foreseen. From the standpoint of anticipation that was wholly a matter of chance. But dealing with modern conditions', where vast numbers are em- ployed and a vastly extensive field is covered, we are able to predict almost exactly not only how many accidents will occur in the course of a year but to classify them according to the extent of their severity. Thus we know that in the railroad service of the country where seventeen hundred thousand men are employed, about four thousand will be killed every year and about seventy-five or eighty thousand will be injured to a greater or less degree. In other words, by the vast extension of the field within which these accidents occur the doctrine of chance has stepped out and the law of averages has stepped in as the controlling rule. It is the unvarying and certain operation of this law of averages upon all human activities that con- stitutes the value of all our statistics ; that makes insurance a business of scientific accuracy ; that in all our large affairs enables us to walk sure-footedly toward the future. There is, therefore, no longer any difficulty in determining what the aggregate cost to any given large industry the payment of compensation will be where the schedule of amounts is prescribed, and this cost can be easily and exactly included in the price of the commodity or service. In the case of the small industries, insurance, mutual or otherwise, gives opportunity for the operation of the law of averages by bringing a sufficient num- ber of employers into the same field of risk. Whenever a workman is injured so that his ability to earn a living is impaired or destroyed, somebody must bear the burden, and the extent of the burden is precisely the same no matter how the accident was caused. The theory of employers’ liability is to put the entire burden on the employer when his causal negligence can be established and to leave the entire burden on the employee in all other cases, while the theory of workmen’s compensation is to equalize the burden by paying the injured workman half wages, or approximately that, in every case of injury, however caused, and for a period proportioned to the extent of the injury. Such a rule results in average justice, which the more or less haphazard enforcement of the system of neg- ligence liability does not, since a majority of injuries go without any compensation, while of the remainder some are fairly, some are inadequately, and some are extravagantly compensated. I have already stated that these two theories of employers’ liability and workmen’s compensation proceed upon wholly different prin- ciples. It follows that any attempt to ingraft one upon the other is unsound. The law of workmen’s compensation, therefore, should afford the sole remedy. In other words, it should be compulsory and exclusive. An elective law is a legislative absurdity. Indeed, it is in effect no law, since “ law is a rule of civil conduct commanding what is right and prohibiting what is wrong.” The so-called elective law commands nothing — prohibits nothing. It proceeds upon the notion that it is right that the employer should be obliged to pay and the employee should be obliged to receive definite and fixed compensation for a personal injury, independently of fault, and then permits both parties' to do as they please about it by allowing them to elect in advance whether they will be bound by the law of compensation or COMPULSORY WORKMEN^ COMPENSATION LAW. 9 the law of liability. Indeed, where the elective form has been adopted the justice and wisdom of compulsion is recognized by prescribing penalties for a failure to accept it, the usual provision being that if the employer elects not to be bound he shall be liable as at common law stripped of all the common-law defenses and that if the employee elects not to be bound he shall be entitled to the common-law remedy burdened with all the common-law defenses. Such legislation has been justly characterized as “ the highwayman’s law.” Ostensibly it allows those who are affected to accept or decline; in fact, it coerces acceptance at the muzzle of the legislative revolver. Every consideration of justice and economy likewise demands that the law should be exclusive; that is to say, it should not permit, after the accident has happened, a choice of remedies on the part of the employee. These considerations may be briefly stated as follows : 1. It is unjust to the employer, since its effect is to compel him to respond for such unlimited and sometimes extravagant damages as a jury may see fit to impose, whenever his negligence can be estab- lished, and then superadds a liability to pay the definite amounts prescribed by the law in all cases where he is without fault, includ- ing those where the injury was due entirely to the negligence of the employee. There is, to say the least, grave doubt whether such a law is not so arbitrary in character that the Supreme Court of the United States would declare it void as constituting a denial of due process of law. The exclusive law is based upon perfectly defensible considerations of mutual burden and mutual advantage. It compels the employer to pay definite compensation in all cases, but relieves him of the liability to respond in unlimited damages in some cases. \ It deprives the employee of his right to recover unlimited damages in some cases, but gives him in exchange the right to recover definite compensation in all cases. The effect of it is to make the employer an insurer of the safety of his employees in a fixed and limited amount, but to leave in his treasury the fund theretofore available for the payment of indefinite damages to assist him in meeting the new obligations. It gives to the employee an insurance policy in exchange for the gambler’s chance, and in effect says to him, “ You may hereafter sustain an injury, which may or may not be due to your employer’s negligence. You may be able to recover damages or you may not be able to recover anything. This law guarantees you the certainty of compensation in place of the uncertainty of damages .” 2. By making the law exclusive larger compensation can be given than would be possible if a choice of remedies were allowed, since it is manifest that if the employers’ liability to pay unlimited damages in case of negligent injuries be continued and in addition he be com- pelled to pay large compensation in all other cases his industry will be taxed beyond its capacity to pay. It must be frankly recognized that the compensation law substitutes the communistic idea of benefit for the whole class in place of the individualistic theory which per- mits a minority of the class to recover much and the majority little or nothing. The justification for a compulsory and exclusive work- men’s compensation law rests in the conception that the workmen employed in any enterprise are industrial soldiers, who being in- jured in its service are entitled to be cared for to a fair and equitable extent, having in view the ability of the industry to pay. Theoretic- 10 COMPULSORY workmen's COMPENSATION LAW. ally, therefore, we are to consider that we have a fund, which, how- ever large, is still limited ; that this fund is to be distributed among the workmen who sustain injury resulting in disability and the de- pendents of those who sustain injury resulting in death; that this fund is to be distributed not for the purpose of penalizing the em- ( ployer, but for the purpose of aiding the injured, and that finally it is better that everybody injured should receive compensation than that only a portion of those injured should receive damages and the remainder nothing. 3. The double remedy will result in a continuation of the great waste which it is one purpose of the compensation law to avoid. To allow an election of remedies is to permit the injured employee to still remain a bone of contention between the personal-injury lawyer, who urges him to sue for the sake of the contingent fee involved, and the claim agent, who seeks to make inadequate settlement in order to save the treasury of his company. Suits will go on as here- tofore. Half of the amount recovered will be lost on its way from the treasury of the company to the pockets of the employees. The unfortunate feeling of antagonism between employer and emploj^ee, which now results, will continue without abatement. The expense to the taxpayer incident to the trial of personal-injury cases will still continue. 4. To allow an election of laws or a choice of remedies destroys one of the most pronounced advantages of the compensation prin- ciple, namely, the element of certainty. So long as we allow the em- ployee to seek damages upon the basis of the employer’s fault or the employer to defend upon the basis of the employee’s negligence, just so long will the uncertainty of the lav/suit counteract the cer- tainty of the fixed schedule and just so long will the fund which should be husbanded and utilized for the benefit of all be frittered away for the benefit of some. A compulsory and exclusive law saves the vast sum which is now wasted and which would continue to be wasted under a composite system for distribution among those who are injured. Expense will be saved to employer and employee and to the public. The only individuals who will suffer will be the personal-injury lawyer and his lawsuit hunting agents. 5. A compulsory and exclusive law will, in my judgment, prove a powerful aid in the prevention of accidents. Under the liability system the employer and the employee are interested in exaggerating or concealing the real facts in so far as they tend to prove or dis- prove negligence, the employer coloring and distorting them in one direction and the employee coloring and distorting them in the opposite direction. Between the two the precise truth as to how the accident occurs is effectually concealed. When the employer knows that he must pay and the employee knows that he must receive a cer- tain prescribed sum wholly irrespective of the way in which the acci- dent happened, neither will have any reason for misrepresentation, and we shall be able to ascertain the cause of the accident, and know- ing why and how it happened we shall be able to prescribe remedies which will have a tendency to prevent similar accidents in the future. After all, the vital objection to the liability system is that it does not in the main permit of average justice, and this is particularly so in death claims Avhere by the death of the employee quite often the evidence which would have established liability is lost. The conse- COMPULSORY WORKMENS COMPENSATION LAW. 11 quences to the dependent family of an engineer who is killed as the result of his own negligence are precisely the same as where there is no negligence at all or where the employer is at fault. Both families have lost a provider and both must be cared for. It is certainly more in consonance with sound public policy to require that both families shall be compensated within fair and reasonable limits than that the employer should be penalized for the benefit of one family at the expense of the other. Experience is always a more valuable guide to human conduct than precept. Every country in Europe except one has abandoned the theory of employers’ liability based upon fault and substituted that of compensation for accidental injury based upon status alone. These laws have been in operation in some of these countries for many years — in England for IT years, in Germany for more than a quarter of a century. If they did not on the whole work well, if they were not of superior benefit to the employee over the old sys- tem, we should expect that long ago there would have been serious efforts for their repeal, but, on the contrary, the workmen in these countries have repeatedly indorsed their principles and declared in favor of their continuation. It is furthermore significant that among the scores of official and nonofficial commissions, committees, and civic organizations in our own country which have investigated the subject, upon most of which bodies both employer and employee have been represented, practically all have reported in favor of the principle of compensation as opposed to that of employers’ liability. If a widespread consensus of opinion, based upon long experience, careful investigation, and earnest desire for a wise and just solution of a great problem can ever establish anything, surely it may be taken for granted that the desirability of Avorkmen’s compensation is no longer open to dispute. The demand for a more or less automatic adjustment of compensa- tion for accidental injuries to workmen is but one of the many phases of a world- wide movement for the readjustment of the relations of labor to capital and of both to society more in consonance with modern notions of social justice. The thought behind this movement is that if society en masse for the general welfare may command the self- effacing loyalty of each of its constituent units society in turn must shape and preserve conditions which will protect each unit in the unequal struggle for individual well-being. There is a groAving feeling that the individualistic theory has been pushed with too much stress upon the dry logic of its doctrines and too little regard for their practical operation from the humanitarian point of view. We are discovering that we can not always regulate our economic and social relations by scientific formulae, because a good many people perversely insist upon being fed and clothed and comforted by the practical rule of thumb rather than by the exact rules of logic. In the rebound, however, from the old notion Avhich, carried to its final conclusion, compels each not only to wage his own battle for existence and happiness, even though he fall in the fight, but which bids him lie where he falls, there is danger that Ave may go too far in the opposite direction and while helping the weak, which is good, encourage the indolent, which is bad. We must be careful that in the effort to relieve ourselves of the burdens which bear us doAvn we 12 COMPULSORY WORKMEN'S COMPENSATION LAW. do not take away the stimulating necessity of personal effort which compels us to rise. We must find at our peril the happy mean be- tween the hardship which breaks and the coddling which saps our strength. That in our righteous anxiety to minimize human suffer- ing we may miss this crucial point is one of the grave dangers which the great civilized nations face to-day. The unfortunate must be cared for ; the soldiers of industry who fall must be lifted up, but no deadlier check could be put upon the upward march of civilization than to embark upon such a scheme of emotional socialism as would put upon the backs of the strong not only the care of those who can not but of those who can but will not bear their own burdens. In framing our laws we must never lose sight of the vital distinc- tion between helplessness, which is a misfortune, and laziness, which is a vice. It is a lovely thing to give in case of need, but it is a far more important thing to so adjust conditions that giving will not be necessary. Laws which afford financial aid for the old and sick and unfortunate who can not help themselves are necessary and righteous, but laws which, by insuring safe and healthful and remunerative work for the young and strong, enable them to care for themselves in time of misfortune and sickness and old age are better. Laws which compel industry to pay, irrespective of negligence, for acci- dents which entail injury and loss of earning ability or death are commendable and desirable, but laws which will prevent the acci- dents are far more so. Clean, sanitary hospitals for those who are torn and mangled by defective machinery or diseased by unwhole- some surroundings are necessary and p-ood, but safe machinery and sanitary workshops are better still. In other words, in dealing with industrial conditions, the prime duty of society, and therefore the prime study of the lawmaker, should be to prevent or minimize the evils which give rise to the necessity for assisting the helpless, for in law as in medicine the homely maxim holds good, that “ an ounce of prevention is worth a pound of cure.” o