Report of the Committee on Franchises of the National Municipal League^^ Submitted at the Conference for Good City Government Held at Toronto, November, 1913 To the National ^M^unicipal League: Your committee on franchises begs to submit the following report: It has been suggested that the growth of the state commission idea is rendering the subject of franchises of diminishing impor¬ tance to the public. It is our view that just at present there is a tendency toward too great centralization in the control of public utilities. The idea of state regulation has gained great headway, and under some of the forms of public utility laws being en¬ acted, or recommended for enactment, the powers of the municipalities to control local utilities, either through franchise contract or through regulation by means of ordi¬ nances or local commissions, are being se¬ riously curtailed or taken away entirely. Nevertheless, we cannot recall a time when a greater number of interesting local fran¬ chise situations presented themselves to the various cities of the country than now. The National Municipal League has always been friendly to the idea of municipal home rule, and the home rule movement has been gain¬ ing very considerable headway in recent years. It is especially important, therefore, in the judgment of your committee, that the League should inquire carefully into the significance of this counter movement for exclusive state control in the matter of pub¬ lic utilities, hitherto regarded as one of the most important fields for municipal activity. Upon this matter, as well as upon certain other fundamental issues involved in the general problem of public utility franchises, the League should be prepared to throw light and furnish leadership. Municipal Home Rule in Its Relation to the Control of Public Utilities The public utility laws providing for ex¬ clusive state regulation do not necessarily and directly strike at the principle of muni¬ cipal ownership, although in some cases they bring municipally owned utilities under supervision to the same extent as utilities owned and operated by private corpora¬ tions. Nevertheless, there are certain fea¬ tures of exclusive state regulation which tend to make the municipalization of utili¬ ties more difficult, and to that extent inter¬ fere with one of the most fundamental pro¬ visions of the home rule program. Several points are made in favor of ex¬ clusive state regulation. It is said that at the present time there are practically no utilities of a purely local character. Local telephone systems overlap municipal boundaries and are linked up with long distance telephones reaching to distant cities and even transcending state limits. Street railways frequently operate beyond the city limits and even form the nucleus of a great network of interurban lines. Since the development of hydro-electric power, electric current for local distribution is in many cases brought from far distant sources and the same transmission lines often serve many different cities. The same is true of natural gas supplies. It is urged that these conditions make municipal con¬ trol of these utilities illogical and imprac¬ ticable. It is also said that public service corpora¬ tions receive their charters from the state, and, therefore, must be regulated by state 1 authority. On behalf of the corporations it is urged that regulation of rates and ser¬ vices involves a corresponding obligation for the protection of the investment, and that such protection is impossible unless the regulating authority is an independent state body, not subject to immediate political pressure from the voters who as consumers of a particular utility clamor for lower rates and better services irrespective of the ef¥ect upon the company’s financial interests. It is also said that only the very largest cities are able to bear the expense of sup¬ porting local commissions equipped for sci¬ entific regulation Ind that even where a city could afford this expense it is seldom willing to incur it. It cannot be denied that these arguments have considerable weight. In the opinion of your committee, however, it would be a mistake to forego entirely, on account of these arguments, the principle of municipal home rule and take away from the muni¬ cipal authorities all control over public util¬ ity services within the city limits. Several considerations may be urged in behalf of this view. Granting the undisputed facts as to the development of interurban, state-wide and even national utility systems, it remains true that what are commonly known as pub¬ lic utilities are primarily urban in their character and that they are developed pri¬ marily in relation to one or more urban cen¬ ters. After all, almost every important city furnishes not only the nucleus, but the major part, of the business of the public utilities operated within its limits. With the extension of public utilities to rural and semi-rural districts and with the growth of cities so that in many cases they touch each other, sanitary drainage and the supply of water, both of which are generally rec¬ ognized as proper municipal functions, over-reach local boundaries as far as any other utilities. From the standpoint of the city, at least so long as it maintains itself as a separate political unit charged with the performance of cooperative functions for the benefit of its inhabitants, the supply of all the standard utilities will remain a mat¬ ter of vital local concern, and the transfer of all control of these services, so long as they remain under private ownership, to a distant administrative authority will be in fact as well as in theory a distinct violation of the principle of municipal home rule. It may also be urged on general principles that the control of all public functions should be localized' as much as possible. In this way only can the active and intelligent interest of the voters be aroused and main¬ tained, and the entire machinery of govern¬ ment be kept close to the people for whose benefit it has been created. Also, in this way only can advantage be taken of the local knowledge and the local interest which, given a sound public opinion, are of incalculable benefit in public administration. This consideration would lead us to give the benefit of the doubt to local rather than state regulation and to extend the principle oi state control only so fast and so far as the facts make it logical and practically necessary to appeal to a central authority. The soundness of this view is supported by a consideration of the results that would follow from the strict application of the opposite policy. As already noted, many utilities are not merely interurban, but in¬ terstate, and according to the logic of those who favor exclusive state control, the utili¬ ties that overlap state boundaries should be subject to exclusive national control. This argument would in some cases even require international control for public utilities op¬ erated in border cities. It may further be urged, as a practical matter, that the more powerful the corpora¬ tions become and the more widespread their services, the more important it is that they should be directly answerable to the local communities which they serve. It may eas¬ ily be possible that an appointive state com¬ mission will fall more or less completely under the domination of the powerful inter¬ ests which control the public utilities of the state, and thus the very machinery provided for the regulation of utilities be captured by the interests presumed to be regulated by it. This is a very real danger. It may be neces- . sary to array against the powerful financial interests of the companies the direct mass interest of the local consumers in order to preserve the vitality of the regulatory func¬ tion. It should never be forgotten that pub¬ lic utility corporations exist to serve the people, not to control them. After careful consideration of the va¬ rious arguments for and against exclusive state regulation, including the arugments presented at the Los Angeles conference by the Hon. John M. Eshleman on the side of state regulation and by Lewis R. Works, Esq., on the side of local regulation, we are of the opinion that in most cases regulation cannot be either logical or effective without the active cooperation of both- state and local authorities. It is dear that in a large city with a powerful and highly developed local government upon which devolves the obligation of meeting the complex problems of urban life and of actively guiding the development of the community along ra¬ tional and progressive lines, it would be a mistake to divest the local authorities of all control over public utilities, even though operated by private corporations. First of all, a city must havcincontrol of its streets. This necessity becomes more acute as cities increase in population and the congestion of street traffic and of the surface, underground and overhead street uses develops. Then, too, when the problems of conges¬ tion of population become serious, a city finds it necessary actively to initiate and control the development of its public utili¬ ties, particularly its local transportation sys¬ tem. No adequate city planning is possible without effective control of the development of the public utility systems. Moreover, as a city increases in size the utilities that in rural communities and in smaller towns are luxuries, come to be ab¬ solute necessities of life. Not only must the people of large cities have the various utilities, but they must have a high grade of service at fair rates. So long as we stand for the idea of throwing upon the people of a city the re¬ sponsibility for working out their own mu¬ nicipal salvation under home rule, we can- 'not for a moment accept the proposition' that the entire control of the utilities using the city streets should be transferred to a distant authority not politically responsible' to the people of the city, and not thoroughly acquainted, by residence in the city, witN local conditions and local needs. At the same time it is clear that in the country and in small towns, the public authorities are wholly lacking in equipment for the regulation and control of public utility corporations. This is especially true where utilities of an interurban or state¬ wide character merely p’ass through the local communities. For a country town to attempt to regulate an interurban railroad, except as to the most rudimentary questions relating to the occupation of the streets, would be illogical and practically impos¬ sible. It appears to be desirable, therefore, that the state public service commission should be given general jurisdiction over public utilities throughout the state, so that there shall be no “twilight zone” within which the companies may escape adequate regulation. We are of the opinion, how¬ ever, that at least every city of sufficient importance to enjoy powers of home rule in the framing of its charter should have the right to establish a separate depart- ment, bureau or commission for the purpose of supervising the utilities operating within its limits, to such extent as may be neces¬ sary for the protection of the distinctively local interests of the community.^ Even m the largest city, with the best equipped util¬ ity department, the state commission should still have jurisdiction over certain impor- t3,rit matters# speaking generally, all those elements of regulation which have to do with the activi¬ ties of corporations as such and which in- i vite uniform treatment without reference to widely varying local conditions will naturally fall to the lot of the state com¬ mission. These matters include the regula¬ tion of stock and bond issues, the fixing of a uniform system of accounts, the require¬ ment of public reports and the determina¬ tion of certain fundamental questions which relate to the stability of the invest¬ ment. On the other hand, the city, if it chooses to exercise it, should have broad power of control in all matters relating to the occupation of the streets and the char¬ acter of the services rendered and should be in a position to municipalize the utilities whenever it desires to do so, and for that purpose should have a continuing right to enter into franchise contracts by the terms of which municipalization can be made practicable. A state-wide,public utility law which pro¬ vides that every franchise granted by local authorities shall be an indeterminate per¬ mit, terminable only upon purchase of the property of the utility at a price fixed by the state commission, is, in our judgment, inadequate to protect the interests of the city, and in fact tends strongly to hamper the city in future efforts to municipalize the utilities. This might not be true if the law should provide for the taking over of utilities subject in part to outstanding in¬ debtedness. But in so far as such a law makes it necessary, for all time to come, that when a city wishes to municipailze it must pay in cash the entire value of the property in a lump sum before taking pos¬ session, a serious obstacle is placed in the way of future acquisition of utilities. The rapid increase of municipal debt for non¬ revenue-producing investments is a notor¬ ious development of the present day. It is also notorious that the legitimate investment in practically every utility, to say nothing of the unearned increment of land values and the possible allowance by a state commission or by the courts for going value and de¬ velopmental expenses, is piling up year by year. A state law, therefore, that would prevent a city, once having granted a fran¬ chise, from ever resettling its relations with the particular utility by means of a new franchise contract, with provision for the amortization of all or a part of the pur¬ chase price out of earnings, or with the option to take over the property subject tO' outstanding indebtedness, is a bad law from the standpoint of municipal home rule in general and of municipal control of public utilities in particular. While we do not favor, as a general principle, competition between municipal and private plants, we believe that a city should have the right to build a competing plant rather than buy out an existing util¬ ity at an exorbitant price built up by allow¬ ances for franchise values, good will, lost investments and other intangible elements- often claimed by the companies. If the purchase price is not fixed in accordance with the terms of a franchise contract, the city ought not to be compelled to buy the existing plant as a preliminary to municipal ownership except on the basis of the actual, legitimate investment, with proper allow¬ ance for depreciation. There are certain elements of regulation which lie on the border-line between state and local functions. One of these is the regulation of rates. We are inclined to the opinion that the fixing of rates, which has to do fundamentally with the protection of the investment as well as with the rights of the patrons of the utility, should be recog¬ nized as a function in which local and state authorities may properly cooperate. Any city which does not choose to invite the state commission to assume jurisdiction in the fixing of local utility rates and which is willing to bear the expense of an adequate investigation of the facts upon which scien¬ tific rate regulation is based should have the right to fix local rates either by con¬ tract or by ordinance, subject in either case to an appeal to the state commission to de¬ termine whether or not the city has made an adequate investigation and whether or not the rates fixed would injuriously affect the rights of individual consumers outside the city limits or of other communities necessarily or conveniently served by the same utility plant or system. In the inter¬ est of intelligent cooperation between city and state authorities, it might be a good thing to require the state commission to 4 loan its experts to cities for rate investiga¬ tions for a reasonable compensation wher¬ ever the city does not choose to maintain a local commission or employ its own tech¬ nical assistance. Another matter requiring the cooperation of local and state authorities is the exten¬ sion of street railways and other utilities to keep pace with the growth of population and the development of suburban areas. Here the interest of the city is fundamental, while at the same time the investors have a right to protection against the arbitrary demands of local land speculators and over- zealous aldermen. The extent to which state control of utili¬ ties is necessary and the extent to which local control is possible vary greatly in dif¬ ferent parts of the country. In states where cities are widely separated, each ur¬ ban community naturally forms a more or less independent utility center, and muni- pal control may be developed to a great ex¬ tent without interfering with the rights of other communities. Moreover, in the case of a great city where the bulk of the service of any particular utility is rendered within the corporate limits, the city’s overwhelm¬ ing “majority interest’^ in the utility re¬ quires the city, for its own protection, to maintain a large measure of local control. Under other circumstances, where cities are bunched together, as they are in eastern Massachusetts and northern New Jersey, it is obvious that unless some new form of co¬ operation among neighboring municipalities is developed, state control of the utilities will necessarily go much further than is necessary where cities are physically re¬ mote from one another. In view of these various considerations, we suggest that where a city has assumed actively to exercise the functions of regu¬ lation, it shall have substantially final au¬ thority with relation to the occupation of the streets, the quality of service rendered and the nature of the franchise contract which it may desire to make for the purpose of facilitating the transfer of the property from private to public ownership. In all matters where an appeal lies from the de¬ cision of the local authorities, as in the matter of rates or extensions, and in all matters where the state commission has pri¬ mary jurisdiction, especially in (juestions relating to competition, accounts and pub¬ licity, we suggest that the local department or commission, representing the city’s inter¬ est and its intelligence on public utilities, have the right to appear officially before the state commission to present the city’s case. In other words, in certain important lines of regulation the city should have final authority; in certain other matters the city should have 'primary jurisdiction, and, in case of appeal, should have the right to be represented officially before the state com¬ mission by its local utility experts; while in still other matters the jurisdiction of the state commission should be regarded as nor¬ mal and complete, but even in these matters the city should have the right to appear in its corporate capacity to make suggestions or to protest against any proposed action affecting utilities that operate within the city limits. We shall now proceed to discuss certain important questions that arise in connec¬ tion with franchise contracts between cities and public utility companies. Control and Financing of Extensions We believe that a public utility within a given urban community is a natural monop¬ oly, and that one of the first and absolutely essential obligations of such a monopoly is to extend its services to meet all the legiti¬ mate needs of the community. In prac¬ tically every city where the street railway situation presents an acute problem, one of the greatest difficulties is found in the ab¬ sence of public control in the matter of ex¬ tensions. To a much less extent the prob¬ lem of extensions also affects the other principal utilities. There is nothing which the people of a growing city so insistently demand as extensions of the street railway system, and there is no point where the street railway companies more strenuously refuse to recognize public initiative and control than in this matter of building ad¬ ditional lines. A few cities have covered the problem of extensions more or less suc¬ cessfully in their franchise contracts. This is notably the case in Chicago and Cleve¬ land, and the principle is recognized in the new subway contracts in New York. We are often told that under private in¬ itiative American cities have much less to complain of as to the lack of proper street railway extensions than the British cities, where, in many cases, the street railway systems are owned and operated by the mu¬ nicipality. It is true, undoubtedly, that in many cities during certain periods there has been a ’liberal expansion. It is prob¬ able that in some cities, even without the stimulus of competition, there has been an over-building of street car lines. It is to be noted, however, that street railway ex¬ pansion in American cities has not always been determined by an intelligent regard for the interests of the community as a whole. So long as private corporations, organized for profit, have the initiative with regard to all extensions, it is to be expected that additional construction will be undertaken only where it promises to add to the profits of the enterprise. In other words, a street railway corporation will not of its own volition extend a line for an additional half-mile when all the people who would be accommodated by the extension would simply be receiving addi¬ tional service without being required to pay additional fares. Congestion of population, except at the very heart of the city, is ex¬ tremely profitable to the street railways. It is patent to everybody that it requires something more than a purely selfish or profit-seeking motive to compel an adequate and logical expansion of a city’s transit facilities as the public need arises. In dealing with the problem of exten¬ sions without any procedure fixed by fran¬ chise contract, the city can only guess what the company’s controlling motives are and must cast about for substantial inducements with which to overcome the company’s financial reluctance. Threatened or real competition has often been used to secure extensions, but competition has almost in¬ variably proven to be an unsatisfactory and expensive weapon for the city to use. In many cases extensions have been forced upon a corporation as the price of the re¬ newal of franchise rights. This method is of course impossible wherever the perpet¬ ual or indeterminate franchise without time limit is in use. Often, also, a situation arises where the company is greatly in need of additional privileges for its own accom¬ modation, and at such times it is possible for the city to drive a bargain by exacting grudged extensions and other concessions as a consideration for the granting of the privileges applied for. An even more difficult and subtle situa¬ tion arises where the company is induced for special reasons to make extensions which, from the community point of view, are premature. Such extensions are either made for the sake of helping the real estate speculations of the officials, or principal stockholders of the company, or else they are made by reason of subsidies given to the company by other persons interested in certain real estate developments. With¬ out any public supervision, the policy of re¬ quiring the owners of benefited property to pay for certain street railway extensions has acquired considerable standing in some cities. Indeed, it is well known that certain street railway systems have been over- expanded for the benefit of certain real estate interests, with the result that for many years the prematurely constructed lines are a financial drag upon the system as a whole, and tend to hinder the construc¬ tion of other extensions which, in the gen¬ eral interest of the community, ought to be built. The problem of extensions is a delicate and difficult one. Obviously some power of initiative as well as of veto on the part of the public authorities is necessary. At the same time it is clear that any company could be driven into bankruptcy by the arbi¬ trary exercise on the part of the local au¬ thorities of unlimited control over exten- * 6 sions. The construction of an extension means an additional capital investment, and the power of the city to order a private company to build an extension is the power to compel the stockholders to put more capital into the enterprise, either out of their own pockets or out of the proceeds of bond issues. While it is our opinion that the local authorities should have the right to initiate extensions, it seems to us neces¬ sary that the company should have an ap¬ peal to an impartial authority, preferably the state public utilities commission, for a review of the question of the necessity and financial feasibility of any particular ex¬ tension ordered by the city authorities. It should not be necessary for the city to show that any particular extension which public need demands would be self-support¬ ing as a separate part of the street railway system, but the earning power of the entire system and the effect of the extension upon the financial condition of the company, taken as a whole, should be among the de¬ termining factors. In many cases it may be found that an extension is desirable, the cost of which would, nevertheless, prove an unreasonable drag upon the system as a whole if paid out of capital account. Under such conditions, the persons who will receive the greatest financial benefit from the construction and operation of the extension are, undoubt¬ edly, the owners of the land that will be made valuable for residential or business purposes by reason of the extension. In our opinion, therefore, provision should be made by which an extension could be built out of the proceeds of special assessments, or directly by the property owners, in cases where the construction of the extension would not otherwise be justified, but where the operation of the extension without the burden of fixed charges would not be an un¬ reasonable burden upon the street railway system as a whole and would be of benefit to the community. Recently, there has been considerable agitation in a number of cities for the use of the assessment plan in the construction of utility distributing systems under public ownership. The same principle should apply, so far as assessments are concerned, whether the utility is to be owned by a cor¬ poration or by the city, and in neither case should the portion of the cost of the plant contributed by the abutters be added to capital account. In this way the general public would get the benefit of lower charges or better service, and, when a pri¬ vate plant was municipalized, the city would get the benefit in a lower purchase price. With the growth of the great cities, ele¬ vated railroads assume large importance locally—though everybody wishes that it were possible to dispense with them in nar¬ row streets and 'crowded residence sec¬ tions. When elevated railroads are built in streets, the abutters often recover heavy damages on account of the interference with their “easements of light, aid and ac¬ cess.” It might help to get rid of the ele¬ vated roads where they are not wanted, and, in any case, would lighten the burden on the transportation system involved in the removal and relocation of expensive structures, if the principle of special assess¬ ments for benefits were applied to pay the cost of relocations. Certainly, this could be done with justice where the property to be assessed for the benefits of the removal had already been compensated for the dam¬ ages due to the original erection of the structures. Duration of Franchises In Los Angeles last year (1912) there was considerable controversy among the local people as to whether the indeterminate franchise should be with or without a maximum time limit! While there has been a strong development of sentiment in recent years in favor of the indeterminate fran¬ chise as a general principle, there appears to be in some quarters a strong counter sen¬ timent against it, unless it has a maximum time limit. This counter sentiment is based on the fear that without any time limit at all the indeterminate franchise will prac- tically amount to a perpetual franchise. The pure indeterminate franchise, as found in the street railway law of Massachusetts and in the District of Columbia, merely pro¬ vides that the rights of a company may be terminated at any time at the option of the public authorities. This form of the inde¬ terminate franchise makes no provision for the purchase of the property of a utility at the time the franchise is terminated. The Wisconsin type of indeterminate permit follows Massachusetts and the District of Columbia in not establishing any maximum time limit, but includes the provision that a franchise shall not be terminated unless, at the time of termination, the city acquires the property of the utility at a price to be fixed by the state icommission. At the same time the public utilities act of Wiscon¬ sin gives municipalities full power to ac¬ quire and operate utilities. It is clear that the Wisconsin type of indeterminate franchise is a sufficient guar¬ anty of the integrity of the investment, so that, from the standpoint of the companies, there can be no reason to complain of it, if they once grant that investments in public utilities are devoted to a public use and should be subject to public control. The advocates of ultimate municipal ownership, however, see considerable danger in the indeterminate permit of the Wisconsin type, for the reason that the franchise runs on forever, unless the city finds itself in a position to pay in cash for the entire value of the utility, and the longer the city waits the greater will be the sum required to effect a purchase. Possibly, under the Wisconsin indetermi¬ nate permit a city, in making an original grant of a new franchise, might provide for the amortization of the cost, or a part of the cost, out of earnings within a specific period, or perhaps provide for taking over the property subject to outstanding bonds, or provide that payment shall be accepted in whole or in part, in bonds secured upon the property itself, and not a charge against, the general credit of the city. But it is to be noted that if the city imprudently fails. in its original grant, to make any such con¬ tract provision, it is forever debarred from revising the terms of the grant and compel¬ ling the company to enter into a new con¬ tract under which municipal ownership could be made easy. Chicago, Cleveland and New York, in their recent street railway and rapid tran¬ sit settlements, have granted indeterminate franchises within maximum time limits. Chicago provides for the accumulation of a street railway purchase fund out of the city’s share of the profits. This provision appears to be wholly inadequate, although it recognizes a correct principle. Cleveland provides that if the franchise is ever per¬ mitted to come within fifteen years of ex¬ piration without being renewed, the com¬ pany may begin to charge the maximum fares set forth in the franchise schedule, and use all surplus for the amortization of capital. The New York subway contracts provide explicitly for the amortization of the entire capital within a definite term of years, and so at the expiration of the con¬ tracts the subways and their equipment will come into the possession of the city without payment at that time. In our opinion, it is important that the franchise should be granted for a definite maximum term, sub¬ ject to the right of the city to terminate the grant in case it is willing to purchase the property at a fair price prior to the ex¬ piration of the grant. The pure indeter¬ minate franchise would be relieved of some of its dangers if the policy of requiring public utilities to adopt an amortization scheme for the gradual reduction of their capital investment for the benefit of the city should be embodied in the general law as a universal and positive obligation. Amorlization of the Investment Out of Earnings Experience has demonstrated that one of the most dangerous, and at the same time one of the most powerful, tendencies of the private management of public utilities is to overload the capital account. Aside from the deliberate watering which was a com- mon feature of public utility financing in days gone by, it is customary among utility men to stretch the powers of reasoning to the utmost limits for the purpose of justify¬ ing the inclusion of additional items in the capital account. While it is difficult to de¬ fend this policy when stated broadly, it seems very easy for a mind friendly to over-capitalization to invent excuses for carrying out the policy in any particu¬ lar case. It is not our intention in this report to go into the merits of the tem¬ porary capitalization of such items as development expenses, losses due to ob¬ soleteness and inadequacy, etc. We desire, however, to state emphatically that in our opinion the experience of the utilities of the country, and perhaps especially the trans¬ portation utilities, has been such as to give a distinct warning against the policy of per¬ manently capitalizing superseded property, accumulated deficits and intangible ele¬ ments of value. Whatever may be neces¬ sary in an adjustment of the capital ac¬ count, fair alike to the investor and to the public, we are of the opinion that all these elements—sometimes included in appraisals in excess of the permanent value of the physical property—should be written out of capital within a comparatively short period of years. The tendency of the investment to bulge is one that should be as firmly re¬ sisted as the tendency to overload a city with debt representing in part improve¬ ments that have outlived their usefulness. This policy of holding down the capital ac¬ count is in our opinion necessary: (i) in order that the investment itself may be safe and stable; (2) in order that rates may be kept within reasonable limits; and (3) in order that the purchase price, which is the touchstone of the franchise contract from the standpoint of possible municipal owner¬ ship, shall be brought within the limits of the city’s financial ability. There may be a legitimate difference of i opinion as to the advisability of requiring the amortization of the entire capital ac¬ count of a public utility while it is being held under private ownership. It should be made perfectly clear that the amortiza¬ tion we refer to is not the amortization of the company’s bonds for the benefit of its stockholders, but the amortization of the investment itself, represented by both stocks and bonds, as a process for the gradual transfer of the ownership of the property from private to public hands. Some of those who are ready to commit the cities now to a definite policy of ultimate muni¬ cipal ownership of public utilities, insist that the amortization process should be set in motion and should be carried through to its ultimate limit as will be done under the New York subway contracts. On the other hand, those who desire only to keep the cities in a position where municipal owner¬ ship will be financially practicable at any time are inclined to oppose the idea of amortization of the entire investment un¬ der the terms of the franchise. They say that the intangible elements and the super¬ seded property should by all means be amortized so that the intrinsic value of the property for operation will at all times be sufficient security for the purchase price. They believe that as a result of this conser¬ vative relation between the capital value as represented at any time in the purchase price and the actual value of the tangible property, it would be possible for any city which had properly conserved its credit to take over the utility and raise all the funds necessary for the purpose, either by the issuance of self-sustaining bonds exempted from the debt limit, or by the issuance of bonds against the property and earnings of the utility itself. As between these two theories as to the extent to which the amortization policy should be carried, your committee does not feel called upon to choose at.this'time, but all of us favor going at least as far as the second would carry us. We believe that the time is ripe for urging the recognition of the amortization principle in all fran¬ chise contracts, and would further state that in our opinion the tendency will be to amortize too slowly and too little rather than the reverse. 9 Resettlement of Outstanding Franchises Within the past few months the threat¬ ened repeal of the franchises granted under the so-called Rogers Law in Ohio some years ago has created an intense discussion of the question of good faith in the rela¬ tions between the public authorities and the franchise-holding corporations, especially in Cincinnati. It is claimed by the pro¬ ponents of the proposed repeal that such action may be lawfully taken under an old section of the Ohio constitution which pro¬ vides that no special privilege shall ever be granted which is not subject to revocation by the General Assembly. The usual alle¬ gations of over-capitalization, bad service, corrupting political influence, etc., have been urged against the Cincinnati company as furnishing sufficient reason why the al¬ leged option reserved by the constitution should be exercised. We do not desire to give judgment upon the merits of the Ohio case, but we desire to call atten¬ tion to the fact that the ethics involved in an attack upon outstanding long-term or perpetual franchises by legislation, liti-^ gation, bargaining or other forms of co¬ ercion, is bound to be an issue of far-reach¬ ing importance in many states and cities in the near future. The existence of per¬ petual franchises in the public streets, or of such franchises running past the life of a generation, has come to be considered as being wholly contrary to-sound public pol¬ icy and inimical to the future welfare of the cities. It has been hoped that the disadvantages of the perpetual franchise could in some measure be overcome by the exercise of continuous regulation through the police power. One of, the primary difficulties in the way of the success of this policy is that no adequate means has yet been devised and proved to require companies enjoying perpetual, irrevocable franchises actually to extend their lines and render the service which the growth of the community de¬ mands when it demands it. The tenacity with which the companies resist the relo¬ cation of street car lines involving the sur¬ render of any portion of any line for which perpetual rights are claimed is a continuing obstacle in the way of the proper develop¬ ment and control of the transit system in any city where perpetual franchises are outstanding. We do not deem it necessary at this stage of public enlightenment to urge at length the iniquity of perpetual public utility franchises in public streets. If, however, it is true that the perpetual franchise is a perpetual men¬ ace to essential public control and reason¬ able service, it follows not only that no perpetual franchises should be granted, but that means should be devised to recover those now outstanding. In fact, the attempt to mix perpetual franchises with short-term or indeterminate franchises in the same city is a good deal like the attempt to mix oil and water. As a rule, where important perpetual franchises exist they are the old franchises, on the central streets, repre¬ senting the* most profitable field of opera¬ tion. No city can ever adequately control the development of its transit system, for example, unless it can control the portion of the transit system that operates in the business district. It seems to us largely futile, therefore, for charter commissions to write into new charters elaborate pro¬ visions governing the granting of new fran¬ chises, which, if they apply at all, will apply only to outlying areas, to relatively unim¬ portant extensions, or to competing lines in the back streets. A charter full of fran¬ chise safeguards that apply only to future grants, while the entire profitable area of the city is already occupied by utilities op¬ erating under perpetual rights is a delusion in law-making. Therefore, in our opinion, it is essential to the proper development of the utilities of any city and to the full realization of the principles of public control, that, in all cases where the outstanding franchises run in perpetuity or for unreasonably long pe¬ riods, the city should definitely set about de¬ vising means for recapturing them. While it is our opinion that every legitimate in¬ vestment in a necessary public utility should 10 be carefully protected, *vve do not believe that franchises as such should be irrevoca¬ ble, or that they should have special value apart from their function of giving life to the property of the utility. There is a well-established rule of law that all grants involving franchise rights in the streets should be construed strictly and strongly in favor of the public. In many jurisdictions this rule has come to be known chiefly by the exceptions to its enforcement. We believe that it is a sound rule and should be strictly applied, especially in all cases involving franchises the terms or conditions of which are clearly contrary to sound public policy. We think, therefore, that the municipal and state authorities are justified in using legislation, litigation, tax¬ ation, negotiation and all other available means to secure the termination of perpet¬ ual* and very long-term franchises, and to compel a readjustment of outstanding rights on the basis of thorough-going protection of the investment under the terms of new franchises which will recover to the city the control vitally necessary to its future welfare. It was supposed that the Greater New York charter, adopted some sixteen years ago, inaugurated a fairly up-to-date and enlightened franchise policy so far as fu¬ ture grants were concerned. Yet since that time the city granted for practically noth¬ ing a street railway franchise to a terminal freight railroad to operate in certain streets in South Brooklyn. This franchise was granted for a period of twenty-five years, with the grantee having the right of re¬ newal for another period of twenty-five years upon readjustment of the rental. To-day New York city, less than ten years after making this grant, is devising a plan for a municipal railroad along the Brook¬ lyn water front including the route covered by this franchise; and the franchise itself, which the city now thinks of buying back, has been appraised at over two million dol¬ lars. We do not believe that it is possible for cities to treat perpetual franchises or 999-year grants as worth the face value claimed for them by their owners, and at the same time attempt, either by negotiation or by condemnation, to acquire the utilities, paying the alleged value of the perpetual franchises. We regard it as highly im¬ politic and unethical for the city to per¬ petuate these burdens upon the future so long as there are means left within the power of the state, or the city, to destroy or at least greatly reduce these illegitimate franchise values, which, if capitalized, could never be sustained either under pri¬ vate or under public ownership, except on the basis of exorbitant rates or subsidies from taxation. In the foregoing we have discussed as briefly as possible a few of the major points involved in the franchise problems of the country which are now in process of solu¬ tion. There are many other points which might properly be discussed in this report. We have limited ourselves, however, to a few points in order- that our recommenda¬ tions should stand out more clearly and avoid the confusion of fundamental prin¬ ciples with less important details. Respectfully submitted, Delos F. Wilcox, Chairman. Robert Treat Paine, James W. S. Peters, Abraham E. Pinanski, Charles Richardson, Clinton Rogers Woodruff, Committee on 'Franchises. While agreeing in the main with the able views presented in this report, I doubt the wisdom, at the present time, of lodging in any state commission any control of the capitalization, or of the rates of public utilities in the larger cities, especially west of New York State. Edward W. Bemis.