. .'..Jv '- -\ ",'¦¦.¦ :- .. THE DECENTRALISATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY GEROID TANQUARY ROBINSON REPRINTED FROM POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY Vol. XXXVI, No. 3, September, 5921 M<; r- '.; NEW YORK PUBLISHED BY THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE ! 1921 ¦»— -n -*-«*" "'.'¦¦ .¦¦."¦ ¦ . '£=*i Stf 'Y^LH«¥IMH¥IEI^SIIir¥o Anonymous Gift s£S THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY BY GEROID TANQUARY ROBINSON n « REPRINTED FROM POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLT Vol. XXXVI, No. 3, September, 1921 NEW YORK PUBLISHED BY THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE 1921 THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY1 BECAUSE of the condition of low visibility created by the hopes and fears that cluster around the Russian revolu tion and the subsequent experiment in Communism, it is perhaps impossible for anyone, however favorably placed, to give at this time an adequate answer to the question, " What has actually happened in Russia, and why ?" Popular interest demands that Communism shall be treated as a world-problem of the future, and yet the Communist experiment itself, in so far as it can now be brought within the bounds of knowledge,. is primarily a Russian problem of the past. The great concen tration of interest upon what may happen, is certainly a prime obstacle to the understanding of what has happened, for the atmosphere of agitation and counter-agitation is most uncon genial to sound scholarship. Nevertheless it may not be impossible to formulate even now a few of the problems that must be solved if the history of re cent years in Russia is ever to be made comprehensible. To begin with, it may be said that the conventional treatment of the history of this period by chronological stages is subject ta some of the same disabilities that attend the division of the his tory of the United States into four-year periods, with the names of the presidents for chapter-headings. In the one case as in the other, the chronological method makes for a concentration of attention upon political activities at the capital, and a very- 1 Bolshevik Russia. By Etienne Antonelli. Translated from the French by Charles A. Carroll. New York, Alfred A. Knopf, 1920. — xi, 307 pp. The Russian Workers' Republic. By Henry Noel Brailsford. New York Harper & Brothers, 1921.— x, 274 pp. The Russian Peasant and the Revolution. By Maurice G. Hindus. New York Henry Holt and Company, 1920. — xii, 327 pp. The Crisis in Russia. By Arthur Ransome. New York, B. W. Huebsch Inc. 1921. — xiv, 201 pp. Bolshevism: Practice and Theory. By Bertrand Russell. New York Har- court, Brace and Howe, 1920. — 192 pp. 454 THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY 455 skimpy handling of developments in the provinces. Hence it seems advisable to suggest a primary division of the subject into four parallel phases, which may even be referred to, for the sake of emphasis, as four distinct revolutions — the agrarian, the industrial, the commercial, and the political. Next, it may be said that each of these revolutions has passed through a period of destruction, followed by a period of construction. In what stage, then, was each of the revolutions at the time of the Bol shevik coup d'etat, and in what direction was each proceeding? Has there been, in any case, a change of direction since the coup d'etat; if so, what were the causes of the change; what specific means were used in effecting it; and what measurable results have been produced ? Although the various analytical studies suggested by these questions can in themselves produce no substitute for a syn thetic account of the revolution, they are the necessary pre liminaries to any adequate synthesis. Hence Mr. Maurice G. Hindus's recent volume on The Russian Peasant and the Revo lution would be a welcome addition to the literature of the period, even if it did nothing more than suggest the possibility of treating the agrarian revolution, not as a purely incidental matter, but as a more or less autonomous movement, with a history of its own. If the promise of the title is not fully realized in the text, one may be sure that the fault does not lie chiefly with the method of approach. Mr. Hindus opens his volume with a sketch of the "pain fully picturesque " conditions in a Russian village, followed by a brief account of the rise of serfdom and a more extended discussion of the hardships which the peasants have suffered since the promulgation of the Emancipation Act in 1861. The picture of peasant misery is rather freely drawn, in a manner calculated to appeal to the popular taste, and yet the founda tion of statistical facts is very solidly built. The partial expro priation of the emancipated peasantry from the lands they had occupied as serfs, the levying of excessive redemption dues upon the lands allotted to the peasants after the emancipation,. the shortage of every facility for the improvement of agricul ture, and the efforts of the peasants to supplement the insuffi- 456 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY [Vol. XXXVI cient income from their allotments by domestic industry and by wage-work — these are some of the subjects discussed in the four chapters which form the most substantial portion of the book. The conditions described correspond somewhat to those created in England by the later enclosures, except that in Russia industry had not been sufficiently developed to afford a large outlet for the labor-surplus. When the mir or village commune comes up for examina tion, the author loses much of his sureness of touch. The spheres of communistic and bureaucratic activity under the old regime are not clearly defined, and a tendency to minimize the importance of the mir becomes immediately apparent. It is stated that the mir might " elect its shepherds for the sum mer " ; it might " exercise its own discretion in levying the amount of grain each member was to contribute to the village granary — a sort of grain-bank where in winter and spring the needy might borrow rye, barley, oats, for seed and bread " ; it might " build its own blacksmith shop and windmill, and choose its own smith and miller". The mir was also the owner of forests and pastures, which were generally used in common, and of arable lands, which were periodically redistributed for cultivation by individual families. However, Mr. Hindus allows himself to say that " in the larger and more significant aspect of the individual and social life of the peasant, the mir was de prived of the privilege of formulating its own will " ; and yet it should be self-evident that even under the old regime the free functions of the mir were of surpassing importance. Bureau cratic officials were simply meddlers in the life of the village, but the mir was a living organism that gave promise of being able to live by itself, if the opportunity should ever come. The opportunity did come at last, when the land-hunger of the peasants had been redoubled by privations incident to the war, and the Autocracy had fallen before a light puff of wind blowing through the streets of Petrograd. The agrarian revo lution which had died down after the jacqueries of 1905 now broke out once more. The dispossession of the landlords be gan in real earnest. The Constitutional Democrats had a plan for stopping the process by a careful redistribution of lands, No. 3] THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY 457 with compensation to the owners. The Social Revolutionaries would have called a halt in the process of expropriation until the Constitutional Assembly met. Kerensky formed local and central committees to settle disputes, and then began at the last moment to prepare a decree of expropriation which he never had the opportunity to issue. At two o'clock in the morning of their second day in power, the Bolsheviki declared : " All private ownership in land is abolished immediately, without any indemnification." Mr. Hindus discusses the land-programs of the various parties in detail, and perhaps too seriously. What one would really like to know is, what — in detail — was going on in the provinces where the peasants were making their own revolution, first in direct opposition to the will of the Government, and finally with its approval. Mr. Hindus gives little help here — but perhaps the data are not yet available. Further than this, one would like to know whether the un controlled agrarian revolution was proceeding toward individual proprietorship, or toward a considerable enlargement of the functions of the mir. Mr. Hindus does not find it necessary to establish the decay of the mir as a preliminary to his advance ment of the theory that nearly all the peasants favor the indi vidual ownership of land. In fact he himself says that com paratively few peasants took advantage of the imperial ukase of November, 1906, which gave them the opportunity to " emerge " from the mir and to claim their share of the com munal lands as private property. Ever since the overthrow of the Tsar, the peasants have been quite free to do what they pleased with the mir. Apparently no one knows exactly what they have done, but in the absence of any proof to the con trary, it may perhaps be safe to assume that the mir became more important, as the central government became less so. The communism of the village, with its system of individual cultivation, and of private property in the products of the soil, is of course quite different from Bolshevik communism, but it is also quite different from Mr. Hindus's individualism. In time it will perhaps be recognized as the constructive principle of the agrarian revolution. 458 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY [Vol. XXXVI For on account of what was going forward in the shops and factories of Russia during the period of political disintegration, one must trust to incidental references in volumes that deal primarily with events at the capital. There is real need for a book on the industrial revolution, but if any such book has yet appeared, it has not come to the writer's notice. However, it seems to be pretty generally agreed that the collapse of the central political authority opened the way for a process of ex propriation by the industrial workers which proceeded in par allel with the land-seizures of the peasants. The factory coun cils corresponded roughly with the village communes, and in the one case as in the other the spontaneous action of the revo lutionists seems to have produced a high degree of decentral ization, with a corresponding development of local organs of economic self-government. In most accounts of the period, the factory councils have received more attention than the vil lage communes, but no one appears to know just what propor tion of the industrial plants of the country were already in the hands of these councils when the Bolsheviki came to power in Petrograd. In the absence of specific facts, the acknowledged difficulty which the Bolsheviki experienced in establishing cen tral industrial control will give a general notion of the strength of the movement for " self-determination " in the factories. The commercial revolution has not been treated anywhere as a specific movement, and perhaps does not deserve to be so treated. While the destruction of the old systems of agricul tural and industrial production seems to have been due almost exclusively to the action of the peasants and the workers, there is little evidence that the dissolution of the distributive system was caused by any positive activity on the part of those en gaged in its operation. Indeed the decay of trade and com merce seems to have been in part a by-product of the blockade and the decrease in domestic industrial production, and in part the result of destructive attacks from without. Thus the trad ing group did not develop within itself any such constructive principle as that which operated in the village communes and the factory councils. The societies for cooperative distribution were perhaps the sole exception to this rule. No. 3] THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY 459 If this speculative analysis of the trend of events in Russia is accepted as tolerably sound, in spite of the manifest incom pleteness of the data upon which it rests, it will then become apparent that the destruction of the old economic order was inevitable, whatever the attitude of the Government might be. If revolutionary destruction was inevitable, then civil war was inevitable, with all the hardships entailed by the disorganization of industry and commerce, and the diversion of energy into military channels. Under the pressure of such conditions, the revolutionists would necessarily be drawn together for the pur poses of self-protection. If the new leaders could not stop the process of destruction, the question of prime importance was, would they accept as their final guide the constructive princi ples embodied in the mir, the factory council and the cooper atives, departing from these principles only in so far as was absolutely necessary to meet the economic and military needs of the moment, or would they attempt to effect a fundamental alteration in the course the revolution had naturally taken? The answer to this question was supplied by the political revolution which brought the Bolsheviki to power. This revo lution is called " political ", because in the beginning it resulted simply in the replacement of one impotent government by another. Now, for the first time, the political wind blew with the tide, and even accelerated its movement. In his volume on Bolshevik Russia, M. Etienne Antonelli says that before any official action was taken by the Bolsheviki, the soldiers had already made peace, the peasants had seized the lands, and the workers had created committees which claimed exclusive con trol of the factories. Elsewhere he characterizes the Bolsheviki as the "accidental instruments of an inevitable evolution", and says that they asserted " a policy of direct and voluntary organ ization from the bottom up, by means of free and self-deter mined action by the proletariat ". However, this was only the beginning of the story. If at first the mass of the workers and the peasants were either pro- Bolshevik or indifferent to Bolshevism, it was because they be lieved that the new government would permit the revolution to take its course. In this they were not altogether correct, for as 460 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY " [Vol. XXXVI M. Antonelli says, the Bolsheviki were " socialists, . . . con cerned with the social organization of the whole community ; ' Power to the Soviets ' for them was a means ; for the mass of the people it was an end ". In other words, the Bolsheviki, or as they are now called, the Communists, had constructive aims of their own which differed somewhat from those already ex pressed in the action of the masses. In order to achieve their aims, the Communists proposed to complete the destruction of the bourgeois State and to erect a powerful proletarian State in its place. The existing Soviets or Councils of revolutionary workers, soldiers and peasants had already given some vague promise of the political reunification of the country, but thus far most of the workers and peasants had gotten along fairly well without paying any attention to the State. Now, however, the Communists said that it must be rebuilt on a new founda tion, and used as an instrument for the final suppression of the propertied class. The process of destroying the old State had begun in March, 1917; the process of constructing the new State began with the Bolshevik coup d'etat; the history of this double process is the history of the political revolution. M. Antonelli's volume is primarily a history of Bolshevik politics during the months immediately following the coup. It is by no means a satisfactory account, for it is badly organized, and somewhat too heavily weighted with superfluities about the Slav soul. Nevertheless it should be said that the author's fair-mindedness is well established by the answer he gives to the question, " Could the Bolshevik leaders be bribed [by Germany] to perform a task opposed to their political convictions ? " In these times, such a question as this has hardly more than an antiquarian interest. The facts of prime importance in Bolshevik political history are those which have to do with the gradual narrowing-down of the class of " active citizens ", and the establishment of a complete Communist dictatorship. As has been said already, the agrarian and industrial revolutions belonged in the beginning to the mass of the peasants and the workers. The accession of the Bolsheviks was regarded as a confirmation of the control of the masses. The Soviet Consti tution seemed to accept this situation, for it restricted suffrage No. 3] THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY ^Qi to the workers, and grouped these worker-citizens primarily in accordance with their economic interest as producers ; in the agricultural regions, the village was the basic unit ; in the towns, the shop-organization or the trade union. Upon this foundation there was erected a complicated system of indirectly elected Soviets, heading up finally in the All-Russian Congress. On the basis of evidence contained within the Constitution itself, one may say that the whole system was pretty thoroughly gerry mandered for the purpose of increasing the influence of the industrial proletariat. Just where the line fell between the ur ban and rural forms of organization is by no means certain, but a consideration of the census leads one to suppose that it would have been tolerably easy for the industrial element to maintain a position of control by the peaceable use of the constitutional means provided. Unfortunately, however, a considerable pro portion of the industrial workers still insisted upon the main tenance of a high degree of autonomy in the factories. If a centralization of power in the new State was to be achieved, these recalcitrants also must be deprived of their influence — a result finally accomplished by an informal suspension of the Soviet Constitution and a practical restriction of political life to the 600,000 members of the Communist Party. If no adequate account of these changes has yet been written, it is partly because the friends and enemies of Communism have been so much occupied with explaining why the changes were made. On the one hand, one hears that civil war and Allied intervention inevitably called up a dictatorship for the defense of the nation. On the other, one is told that the Com munist leaders imposed the dictatorship of their own free will, for some fell purpose not specifically named. The truth prob ably lies somewhere between these two statements, and rather nearer the former than the latter. On this subject, one can get but little light from such a vol ume as Bertrand Russell's Bolshevism : Practice and Theory. Mr. Russell entered upon his investigation of conditions in Russia with an avowed predilection for Anarchist Communism, and apparently also with a feeling of heavy responsibility for the effect his findings might have in Western Europe. In his 462 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY [Vol. XXXVI book he occupies himself chiefly with an appraisal of Bolshe vism as a means of attaining the "fundamental economic recon struction " he desires ; he tends from first to last to treat the revolution in all its aspects as a Bolshevik revolution, and to regard a Bolshevik revolution, not as something inevitable, but as something that one may take or let alone, as one pleases. Now, as a matter of course, Mr. Russell is at liberty to say, if he will, " I am compelled to reject Bolshevism for two reasons : first, because the price mankind must pay to achieve Commu nism by Bolshevik methods is too terrible ; and secondly be cause, even after paying the price, I do not believe the result would be what the Bolsheviki profess to desire." He is even at liberty to transfer the theory of full, free and conscious self- determination to past history, though fewer people will follow him in this. However he produces a most confused impression when he says that the Bolshevik outlook on life is the outcome of the cruelty of Tsarism and the savagery of the Great War ; that this Bolshevik outlook is " the ultimate source of the whole train of evils" in Russia; that the Bolsheviks are specifically accountable for provoking war and causing material disaster; that war and material disaster gave rise to most of the disagree able features of the Bolshevik regime; and that " in Russia, the methods of the Bolsheviki were probably more or less unavoid able ". In fact Mr. Russell's investigations seem to have yielded, not one theory, but several theories, of the part played by the Bolsheviki in the revolution. His appraisal of Bolshevik theory doubtless has some importance as a polemic document in the West, where Bolshevism is still nothing more than a theory, but his volume does not contribute materially to an understand ing of the situation in Russia, where Bolshevism is, for him, a well-nigh inexplicable fact. If the reader follows Mr. Russell to the very end, and agrees with him in all respects, he will not want Bolshevism in his native land, but neither will he under stand the nature of Bolshevik power in the ex-Empire of the Tsars. Upon the authority of two competent observers who visited Russia in 1920 — Mr. Ransome and Mr. Henry Noel Brailsford — one may say that in Russia the Communist Party is, for all No. 3] THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY 463 practical purposes, the State. Since the party is not in any sense an economic organism for the production or distribution of goods, but a political organism for the control of the revo lution, it is apparent that political activity still has some im portance in Russia. In this state of affairs, the constitution and methods of the Communist Party are matters of the great est importance in the history of the revolutionary movement as a whole. In his recent book on The Russian Workers' Repub lic Mr. Brailsford supplies a description of the party which suggests comparison with a religious order, and calls to mind Mr. Russell's statement that Bolshevism is a type of religious fanaticism. According to Mr. Brailsford, the existing dictator ship is based upon the perfect discipline and the heroic rash ness of the party-members. A careful scrutiny of candidates, a long and rigorous novitiate, and a periodic purging of the party-rolls fits the membership for duty as " shock troops " wherever, at the front or in the factories, there is work of par ticular danger or difficulty to be done. " Such democracy as there is in Russia exists within the Communist Party, and not outside it. It is a grave mistake to suppose that Lenin rules as an autocrat. Every new departure of Russian policy, whether internal or external, is debated at the elected con gresses of the Party and its elected executive is the real con trolling power. . . . The vote of the Party Congress . . . closes all debate, and the minority submits absolutely." Com munist majorities in the Soviets are secured by various legal and illegal means, sometimes simply by denying the opposition the use of the press and of public halls for the conduct of its campaign ; and in the Soviets the Communists vote " as one man ", in accordance with decisions already reached in their own party-meetings. In The Crisis in Russia, Mr. Arthur Ransome presents a less complete account of the methods used by the Communists to control the Soviets and the government, but one that agrees in all essential respects with that of Mr. Brailsford. When matters of policy have once been decided in the man ner described, the Government is immediately faced with the task of making the decision effective. Mr. Brailsford and Mr. 464 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY [Vol. XXXVr Ransome are agreed that propaganda is of primary importance- here, though both admit that force is used where propaganda does not produce the desired results. The army is of course the Government's most powerful weapon; Mr. Brailsford says that it will sooner or later be entirely in the control of Com munist officers. Mr. Russell stresses rather heavily the impor tance of the Extraordinary Commission ; Mr. Brailsford says the Commission admits having shot 8,500 prisoners before March 5, 1920, while Mr. Ransome expresses the belief that this or ganization is by no means the chief support of the dictatorship. Naturally such agencies as the schools, the press, and the theater are often used and abused for political purposes, and yet Mr. Brailsford is able to say, " It may be honestly claimed,. I think, for the Soviet Administration that it has a better record in its relations to art and culture, generally, than any other government in the civilized world." It goes without saying that the intellectual life of Russia during the revolution can be treated historically as a mere annex to politics only in so far as the Communists have made it so, through the exercise of gov ernmental control. The means for the exercise of the dictatorship which have thus far been mentioned are those that operate through the government upon all the people alike, without special reference to economic function or organization. That is to say, these means of control are the political manifestations of the political power of the Communist Party. The history of the develop ment of the Communist Party itself and of these means of con trol has an important place in the history of the political revo lution, and yet it has already been said that the political revo lution was of minor importance, as compared with the economic changes that accompanied it, altered its course, and were at last in some measure deflected by it. In the opinion of Mr. Brailsford, the agrarian revolution came as the inevitable result of misery and oppression, and civil war and industrial collapse followed naturally in its train. The industrial workers were drawn off into the army, or went back to the land, and the government was soon faced with a labor-shortage which, Mr. Brailsford says, has since been at the "No. 3] THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY 465 l>ottom of all its difficulties. Mr. Ransome also discusses the labor-shortage at considerable length, and both writers are agreed that in the absence of some central agency, revolution ary or counter-revolutionary, for the conscription of industrial workers and the requisitioning of food, industry would have come completely to a halt, the towns would have been depopu lated, civilization itself would have been extinguished, and Russia would have been thrown open to colonization and ex ploitation by Western Europe. Mr. Ransome even fears that the dissolution of Russia might involve the whole continent in the same fate. He looks upon the Communist Government as the only agency now capable of halting this process of dissolu tion, and the avowed purpose of his argument is the prevention of any conflict that might result in the overthrow of that gov ernment. All this involves much speculation; and certainly one is not ¦obliged to accept the identification of civilization with town- life maintained by requisition and conscription. However it is fairly clear that although the village communes and the factory councils were quite capable of performing the destructive work of the revolution, and would doubtless have carried this work through to a conclusion without governmental help, or in spite •of governmental hindrance if hindrance had been offered, they -were not capable of defending themselves during a long period of slow and entirely natural reconstruction. Thus a partial alteration of the course of the industrial revolution was neces sary for purposes of defense, and in this sense it was inevitable. What was especially required to meet the needs of the moment was not so much a political dictatorship which would affect all the people of the country, as an industrial dictatorship which would prevent the whole fabric of urban society from going to pieces. In a very real sense, the Communists chose the inevitable, and the history of their conquest of Russian in dustry is perhaps the most important chapter in the annals of the new regime. The nature of the methods employed is by no means clear, but it is extremely significant that the party does not now exert its control of industry solely through the mechanism of the Soviets and the government. The system of 466 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY [Vol. XXXVI Soviets certainly exercises a considerable degree of control over industrial affairs, particularly through the Supreme Council of National Economy. On the other hand, the factory councils are not only bound together in territorial groups in the Soviet system, but are organized industrially in national unions, with the provision that organized labor as such shall have a consid erable degree of control over wages and working conditions,. and some share also in the actual management of plants and industries, either directly or through representation in the Supreme Council and other Soviet institutions. Since most of the Communists, perhaps nearly all of them, are members of these factory councils, they are in a position to control the in dustrial unions and the National Trade Union Congress from the inside by the same means they have employed for the con trol of the system of Soviets ; and, according to Mr. Brailsford, this is approximately what they are doing. Thus it appears that in any account of the industrial revolution under the new regime, the history of the unions cannot properly be subordin ated to that of the government. If both the unions and the government are nothing more than mechanisms employed by the Communist Party to make its will effective, it is nevertheless important that the principle of national organization by indus tries still does service in company with that of organization by districts and provinces. Under Communist control, two notable changes have taken place in the actual conduct of industry ; management has been to some extent centralized, and industrial conscription has been instituted. Mr. Ransome reports that in 1920 the centralization of management was the subject of bitter controversy, with the prospect that the factories would eventually be placed in the control of "bourgeois specialists", who, for all practical pur poses, would be responsible to the State alone. Mr. Brailsford says, " individual management is now [in 1920] the rule, though the Workers' Councils survive". According to Mr. Ransome, all stages of industrial conscription existed simultaneously in Russia in 1920; the tremendous difficulty of the labor-problem is indicated by his statement that the number of workmen in Moscow in 1919 was only 105,000, as against 157,000 in 19 18. No. 3] THE DECENTRALIZATION OF RUSSIAN HISTORY 467 Statistical studies of the operation of conscription, and of in dustrial output under various conditions of technical direction and labor-control, would furnish invaluable material for a his tory of the industrial revolution. Mr. Brailsford and Mr. Ran some supply figures on production and transportation which are of great interest at the moment, but naturally the data are hardly full enough to be of permanent value to the historian of the Revolution. If the history of the industrial revolution is somewhat obscure, that of the commercial revolution is certainly far more so. The exchange of commodities seems to have been less system atically organized than their production, for at one time private traders, cooperative societies and governmental agencies for the requisition and rationing of food were operating simultaneously. Evidence of a tendency to eliminate confusion is contained in Mr. Brailsford's statement that the official cooperative organiza tion now represents the whole body of the citizens as consum ers, and has been brought under Communist control by methods similar to those employed in the conquest of the Soviets and the industrial unions. If this is literally true, then the history of the third organ of the dictatorship demands as much attention as has habitually been given to the unions. However one sus pects a certain inaccuracy in this reference to " the whole body of the citizens ", for the place of the peasants in the official co operative organization remains undefined. The peasants were a most important factor in the cooperatives of pre-revolutionary days; if they no longer participate, how did the Communists dispose of them ; if they are still included, does this mean that the mir is now the basis of the cooperative organization in the agricultural districts? Does the cooperative system have local institutions of its own among the industrial workers ; or does the factory council function as a primary unit, as it does in the system of Soviets and the system of unions? The answers to these questions, together with statistics on the origin, amount and destination of imports and domestic manufactures and foodstuffs handled by the organs of distribution, would consti tute some of the material for a history of the commercial revo lution under the Communists. 468 POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY The action of the Communist Party in dealing more or less systematically with the individual as a citizen, as a producer, and as a consumer, through three separate organs of the dicta torship — the Soviets, the unions, and the cooperatives — natur ally facilitates the treatment of the revolution in parallel phases ; and it is certainly no fault of the Communists that the movement must still be treated, not in three phases only, but in four. The peasants are citizens, producers, and consumers, and yet their influence in the Soviets is minimized even by the Constitution, now suspended ; the system of industrial unions makes no place for any agricultural workers except those on the few Soviet farms which are organized and managed like factories ; and the status of the peasants in the official cooperative organization is, to say the least, uncertain. In other words, the agricultural revolution still holds very much to its original course as a spon taneous and unorganized movement for the seizure of the land, with the promise of an increase in the importance of the mir as an incidental result. Even without an effective central control of agriculture, the Communists can perhaps defend the country and, in exchange for foreign and domestic manufactures, secure enough of the peasants' food products to maintain the life of the towns under conditions which — they say — will eventually make all the towns men into Communists ; but at best this would simply broaden the non-agricultural basis of the dictatorship. The unorgan ized masses of the peasants would still stand between the Com munists and their objective ; and it is the very essence of Com munist theory that the dictatorship shall be maintained until complete Communism is achieved. What, then, of the future ? The question is an engaging one, and no author here mentioned has missed the opportunity to answer it. Mr. Brailsford's speculations are, like the rest of his book, most interesting. However, information on the sub ject is extraordinarily scarce, and one is not disposed to attempt at the moment a careful analysis of prophecy. Geroid Tanquary Robinson. Columbia University. THE ACADEMY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE IN THE CITY OF NEW YORK The Academy of Political Science is affiliated with Columbia University and is composed of men and women interested in polit ical, economic and social questions. The annual dues are five dollars. Members receive the Political Science Quarterly and the Proceedings of the Academy and are entitled" to free admission to all meetings, lectures and -receptions under tr^e auspices of the Academy. Subscribers to the Quarterly are enrolled as subscrib ing members of the Academy. Communications regarding the Academy should be ad dressed to The Secretary of the Academy of Political Science, Columbia University. THE POLITICAL SCIENCE QUARTERLY 2 Managing Editor Parker Thomas Moon i The Quarterly follows the most important movements of foreign pol itics but devotes chief attention to questions of present interest in the United States. On such questions its attitude is nonpartisan. Every article is signed ; and every article, including those of the editors, expresses simply the personal view of the writer. Each issue contains careful hook reviews by specialists, and in March, June and December numerous recent publications are characterized in brief book notes. In September is printed a Supplement-, con sisting of a valuable record of political events throughout the world. ^ Communications in reference to articles, book reviews and exchanges should be addressed to the Political Science Quar terly, Columbia University, New York. Intending contributors are requested to retain copies of articles submitted,, as the editors disclaim responsibility for the safety of manuscripts. If accom panied by stamps, articles not found available will be returned. Subscriptions should be forwarded and all business com munications addressed to The Academy of Political Science, Columbia University, New York. Yearly subscription, including Supplement, five dollars ; single number, not including Supplement, one dollar. Supplement consisting of Record of Political Events, one dollar. Back numbers and bound volumes can be obtained from The Academy of Political Science, Columbia University, Hew York. 3 9002 08954 0695